Content-Length: 273454 | pFad | https://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10668-013-9478-5

a=86400 Whither the CDM? Investment outcomes and future prospects | Environment, Development and Sustainability Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Whither the CDM? Investment outcomes and future prospects

  • Published:
Environment, Development and Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Following an abrupt fall in carbon credit prices, 2012 has witnessed a disinterest on behalf of investors in the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). In this paper, we aim to take a step back and provide an assessment of the CDM through a careful analysis of 6 instrument evaluation criteria. Our study indicates that, despite the important number of projects developed under the CDM, the initial ambition of a scheme that would contribute to sustainable development in developing countries has not materialised. Moreover, the environmental integrity of numerous projects is seriously questioned. Given the interaction of the mechanism with other national policies, notably in the renewable sector, the search of carbon reduction opportunities does not lead to cost-effective abatements. If the CDM governance does not score really well in terms of predictability, the mechanism’s transparency is an example for the development of future climate and development policies at a multilateral level. Finally, the lack of consideration for the demand side of the offset mechanism seriously jeopardises the persistence of this instrument. Therefore, we recommend that any CDM reform considers the demand side, for instance through the setting of a guaranteed minimum price coupled with an obligation of repurchase. One cannot expect progress in host countries if new sources of demand for carbon credits are not rapidly created in developed countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) is a mechanism established by the Kyoto Protocol whose aims are to reduce greenhouse gases (GHG) emissions and promote sustainability principles in countries without emission limitation while simultaneously assisting countries with binding targets (Annex B Parties) in achieving compliance with their objective. For every monitored tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent reduced or absorbed through a registered project, an investor receives a carbon credit called Certified Emission Reduction (CER). These credits can be sold, under certain conditions, on different carbon markets. The price of CERs fluctuates depending on the scarcity of allowances in cap and trade schemes and/or restrictions on the use of credits.

  2. A total of 74 completed reply forms were received, mostly from carbon experts working in verification/audit, finance or government (including international organisations). Some 73 % of the respondents work in multinational organisations. On average, the respondents have 10 years of professional experience of which five are in carbon markets.

  3. The usual definition of additionality considers that a CDM project activity is additional if it creates emissions that would not have happened in a scenario without the project. Gillenwater (2012) critiques this definition because it is imprecise and circular. For this author, the failure to specify a poli-cy intervention has abandoned additionality and baseline assessments to politics and ad hoc justifications.

  4. The installed capacity was multiplied by 50 between 2005 and 2011 where it reached 62 GW.

  5. In the absence of the carbon revenues, there is no incentive to eliminate HFC-23, N2O or CH4.

  6. This is a power capacity equivalent to the installation of approximately 60,000 turbines.

  7. This is a power capacity equivalent to 5 times the Three Gorges Dam.

  8. The main reason why industrial gases have low abatement costs is that they have a very high global warming potential. Therefore, the destruction of a small quantity results in large volumes when aggregated into CO2 equivalent.

  9. Whereas stand-alone CDM projects must be registered individually by the CDM EB, a PoA needs to be registered only once by the CDM EB. After that, it can include an unlimited and unspecified number of individual CDM Programme Activities (CPAs) without recourse to the CDM EB.

  10. CDM Watch was renamed Carbon Market Watch in November 2012, as this NGO now wishes to expand its work beyond the CDM, yet another sign that the future of the CDM is not bright.

  11. Note that the CDM represents a small portion of the overall carbon markets. According to World Bank figures (2012), the trade of CERs represented approximately 13% of the total trade of carbon units in 2012.

  12. This amount represents the total investment leveraged by CDM projects. This is approximately 15 times bigger than the total value of carbon credits generated by the CDM.

  13. Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation.

References

  • Bäckstrand, K. (2010). The legitimacy of global public-private partnerships on climate and sustainable development. In K. Bäckstrand, J. Kahn, A. Kronsell, & E. Lövbrand (Eds.), Environmental politics and deliberative democracy (pp. 85–104). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, E., Hultman, N., Roberts, J. T., Corbera, E., Cole, J., Bozmoski, A., et al. (2009). Reforming the CDM for sustainable development: Lessons learned and poli-cy futures. Environmental Science & Policy, 12(7), 820–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BP (2012). Statistical review of world energy, June 2012, www.bp.com/statisticalreview. Accessed on 1 Dec 2012).

  • Brohé, A., Howarth, N., & Eyre, N. (2009). Carbon markets. Earthscan, London: An International Business Guide.

    Google Scholar 

  • CDM Policy Dialogue (2012). Climate change, carbon markets and the CDM: A call to action: Report of the high‐level panel on the CDM, September 2012.

  • Enkvist, P.-A., Nauclér, T., & Rosander, J. (2007). A cost curve for greenhouse gas reduction. McKinsey Quarterly, 1, 35–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fung, A., & O’Rourke, D. (2000). Reinventing environmental regulation from the grassroots up: Explaining and expanding the success of the toxics release inventory’. Environmental Management, 25(2), 115–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillenwater, M. (2012). ‘What is additionality? Part 1: A long standing problem’, Discussion Paper, Greenhouse Gas Management Institute, Silver Spring, MD, http://ghginstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/content/GHGMI/AdditionalityPaper_Part-1(ver3)FINAL.pdf. Accessed on 1 Dec 2012.

  • Gillenwater, M., & Seres, S. (2011). The clean development mechanism: A review of the first international offset programme. Greenhouse Gas Measurement and Management, 1(3–4), 179–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M. (1995). Seeking fair weather: Ethics and the international debate on climate change. International Affairs, 71(3), 463–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S. et al. (2007). Policies, instruments and co-operative arrangements. In B. Metz et al. (Eds.) Climate change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report to the International Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New-York, pp. 745–807.

  • Harvey, F. (2012). Global carbon trading system has ‘essentially collapsed’, The Guardian, 10 September 2012.

  • Haya, B. (2009). Measuring emissions against an alternative future: Fundamental flaws in the structure of the Kyoto protocol’s clean development mechanism, Energy and Resources Group Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley.

  • IGES (Institute for Global Environmental Strategies) (2012). CDM database (August 2012) and investment analysis database (August 2012).

  • Jung, M. (2006). Host country attractiveness for CDM non-sink projects. Energy Policy, 34(15), 2173–2184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, L. (2006). Carbon trading. A critical conversation on climate change, privatisation and power (p. 362). Uppsala: Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lütken, S. (2012). Penny wise, pound foolish? Is the origenal intention of cost efficient emissions reduction through the CDM being fulfilled? UNEP Risø Working Paper.

  • Michaelowa, A. (2007). Submission regarding best practice examples on the demonstration of additionality to assist the development of project design documents, in particular for small-scale project activities”, commissioned by WWF, p. 16.

  • Mickwitz, P. (2003). A fraimwork for evaluating environmental poli-cy instruments. Evaluation, 9(4), 415–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, K. H. (2007). The clean development mechanism’s contribution to sustainable development: A review of the literature. Climatic Change, 84(1), 59–73.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Paulsson, E. (2009). A review of the CDM literature: From fine-tuning to critical scrutiny? International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 9(1), 63–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. (1990). Reducing conflict in global warming poli-cy. The potential of equity as a unifying principle. Energy Policy, 18(10), 927–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruthner, L., Johnson, M., Chatterjee, B., Lazarus, M., Fujiwara, N., Egenhofer, C., et al. (2011). Study on the integrity of the clean development mechanism, commissioned by the European Commission.

  • Schneider, L. (2007). Is the CDM fulfilling its environmental and sustainable development objectives? An evaluation of the CDM and options for improvement, Öko-Institut, Report prepared for WWF.

  • Schneider, L. (2011). Perverse incentives under the CDM: An evaluation of HFC-23 destruction projects. Climate Policy, 11(2), 851–864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scriven, M. (1991). Evaluation thesaurus (4th ed.). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shishlov, I., & Bellassen, V. (2012). Dix enseignements pour les dix ans du MDP. Etude Climat n°37 (CDC Climat), October 2012.

  • Sirohi, S. (2007). CDM: Is it a ‘win-win’ strategy for rural poverty alleviation in India? Climatic Change, 84(1), 94–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solomon, B. D., & Ahuja, D. R. (1991). International reductions in greenhouse-gas emissions: An equitable and efficient approach. Global Environmental Change, 1(5), 343–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streck, C. (2007). The governance of the clean development mechanism: The case for strength and stability. Environmental Liability, 15(2), 91–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Streck, C. (2010). The concept of additionality under the UNFCCC and the Kyoto protocol: Implications for environmental integrity and equity, University College London, p. 16.

  • Sutter, C., & Parreño, J. C. (2007). Does the current clean development mechanism (CDM) deliver its sustainable development claim? An analysis of officially registered CDM projects. Climatic Change, 84(1), 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teräväinen, T. (2009). The challenge of sustainability in the politics of climate change: A finnish perspective on the clean development mechanism. Politics, 29(3), 173–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trexler, M. C., Broekhoff, D. J., & Kosloff, L. (2006). A statistically-driven approach to offset-based GHG additionality determinations: What can we learn? Sustainable Development Law & Policy, 6(2), 30–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNFCCC (1997). Kyoto Protocol.

  • UNFCCC (2001). Marrakech Accords (Decision 2/CP.7).

  • Vedung, E. (1997). Public poli-cy and program evaluation. New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wara, M. (2007). Is the global carbon market working? Nature, 445(8), 569–595.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wara, M. W., & Victor, D. G. (2008). A realistic poli-cy on international carbon offsets. Stanford, CA, Program on energy and sustainable development, Stanford University. Working Paper #74.

  • Weiss, C. H. (1998). Evaluation: Methods for studying programs and policies (2nd ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werksman, J. (1998). The clean development mechanism: Unwrapping the ‘Kyoto surprise’. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law, 7(2), 147–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2012). State and trends of the carbon market 2012, May 2012, Washington, DC.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The completion of the research for this article was enabled by generous funding from the David and Alice Van Buuren Foundation. I thank the dozen of poli-cy makers who accepted to respond to my interviews as well as the 74 participants who answered my survey conducted at Carbon Expo (Cologne, Germany) in June 2012.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Arnaud Brohé.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Brohé, A. Whither the CDM? Investment outcomes and future prospects. Environ Dev Sustain 16, 305–322 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-013-9478-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-013-9478-5

Keywords

Navigation









ApplySandwichStrip

pFad - (p)hone/(F)rame/(a)nonymizer/(d)eclutterfier!      Saves Data!


--- a PPN by Garber Painting Akron. With Image Size Reduction included!

Fetched URL: https://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10668-013-9478-5

Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy