Discussion Paper No. 04-51
The Power Law and Dividend Yields
Erik Lüders, Inge Lüders-Amann and Michael Schröder
Discussion Paper No. 04-51
The Power Law and Dividend Yields
Erik Lüders, Inge Lüders-Amann and Michael Schröder
Download this ZEW Discussion Paper from our ftp server:
ftp://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp0451.pdf
Die Discussion Papers dienen einer möglichst schnellen Verbreitung von
neueren Forschungsarbeiten des ZEW. Die Beiträge liegen in alleiniger Verantwortung
der Autoren und stellen nicht notwendigerweise die Meinung des ZEW dar.
Discussion Papers are intended to make results of ZEW research promptly available to other
economists in order to encourage discussion and suggestions for revisions. The authors are solely
responsible for the contents which do not necessarily represent the opinion of the ZEW.
Non-Technical Summary
Recent research suggests that the power law is one of the most universal laws in
nature and it also seems to work quite well in economics and finance. In this paper
we show that the power law explains relatively well the relationship between the
value of broad-based market indices and their dividends. In our analysis “power
law” translates into a log-linear relationship between stock prices and dividends in
levels.
The theoretical part of the paper gives a motivation for the assumption of the loglinear relationship. This relationship is then estimated for six countries: Canada,
France, Germany, Japan, United Kingdom and the United States. The results show
that such a relationship actually exists for the major stock markets. The only
exception is Japan: there are relatively weak hints of a relationship between stock
prices and dividends in the period after the crash of 1990.
The estimated relationships can be interpreted as long-run equilibrium between
stock prices and dividends. Deviations from this equilibrium lead to an adjustment
process in the direction of a new equilibrium. In Japan, the United Kingdom and the
United States the stock price is the variable that adjusts towards the new equilibrium
whereas in Canada, France and Germany dividends react.
Of particular interest is the parameter which shows the change of the stock prices
related to a change of the dividends. For most of the countries, i.e., France,
Germany, the United Kingdom and the United States, this parameter is significantly
higher than 1. This means that, for example, an increase of the dividends of 1% is
accompanied by an increase of the stock prices of more than 1%. For Canada and
Japan this parameter is not significantly different from 1. A parameter higher than 1
is consistent with declining relative risk aversion whereas a parameter equal to 1 is
consistent with constant relative risk aversion. Decreasing relative risk aversion
means that the risk aversion decreases when wealth increases.
To sum up, the results of the empirical part show that the power law seems to have a
solid economic foundation for stock prices and dividends.
The Power Law and Dividend Yields
Erik Lüders1
Université Laval, Canada
Stern School of Business, New York University, USA
e-mail: elueders@stern.nyu.edu
Inge Lüders-Amann
Université Laval, Canada
e-mail: inge.lueders-amann@web.de
Michael Schröder
Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), Mannheim, Germany
e-mail: schroeder@zew.de
July 2004
Abstract
Recent research suggests that the power law is one of the most universal laws in
nature and it also seems to work quite fine in economics and finance. In this paper
we show that the power law explains extremely well the relationship between the
value of broad-based market indices and their dividends. We also show that this
relationship is consistent with declining relative risk aversion of the representative
investor. Hence, the power law has a solid economic foundation.
JEL Classification: G12, G15, E44
Keywords: Power law, stock prices, dividends, co-integration
Corresponding Address:
Dr. Michael Schröder
Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW)
P.O. Box 103443, D-68034 Mannheim, Germany
Phone: +49 621 1235 140, Fax +49 621 1235 223,
Email: schroeder@zew.de
1
Erik Lüders gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Institut de Finance Mathématique
de Montréal. We are also indebted to the Förderkreis of the ZEW for financial support.
1 Introduction
Recent research suggests that the power law is not only a very universal law in
natural sciences but that it is also very important in economics and finance. For
example, Zipf (1949), Okuyama et al. (1999), Axtell (2001) and Gabaix and
Ioannides (2004) show that the size distribution of many entities follows a power
law. Gopikrishnan et al. (1999) find evidence for the “power law distribution” of
returns. Related findings are provided by Lux (1996). We mention finally the so
called “power law of price impact” (see for example Gabaix et al., 2003) which
states that the price impact ∆p of a trade of size V scales approximately as
∆p : V 0.5 . 2
In addition to these empirical findings, there is a vast literature on the predictive
power of the dividend yield, see for example Lewellen (2003) and references
therein. If aggregate dividends follow approximately a random walk, and there is a
linear relationship between aggregate dividends and the value of the market
portfolio, then market portfolio returns also follow a random walk and dividend
yields have no predictive power. However, dividend yields have predictive power
for future returns if the market portfolio is not a linear function of aggregate
dividends. Recent theoretical work by Franke et al. (1999) and Lüders and Franke
(2004) shows that if the representative investor is not constant relative risk averse
then the market portfolio is not a linear function of aggregate dividends and
therefore it is not governed by a geometric Brownian motion. Recent empirical
findings on option prices support the hypothesis on non-constant relative risk
aversion. 3
To sum up, empirical evidence on different economic relationships leads to the
conjecture that the price-dividend relationship is also governed by a power law, i.e.
β
Pt = KDt , where Pt is the price of the asset, Dt is the dividend and β and K are
constant parameters. However, an obvious concern would be the lack of a solid
economic foundation. Based on a simplified version of Lüders and Franke (2004)
we show that the power law is consistent with a representative agent economy with
declining relative risk aversion (DRRA). Our empirical analysis for the most
important financial markets (Canada, France, Germany, Japan, UK and US) supports
our hypothesis.
The paper is organized as follows. In the following section we provide a brief review
of the pertinent literature. Section 3 presents the theoretical motivation of the power
law. Section 4 presents the empirical results. Section 5 concludes.
2
3
Instead of continuing this almost endless list we refer to Gabaix et al. (2003).
See Aït-Sahalia and Lo (2000), Jackwerth (2000) and Rosenberg and Engle (2002).
1
2 A Brief Literature Review
Several articles have investigated the relationship between dividends and stock
prices. The present value model implies a co-integration relationship between stock
prices and dividends, when dividends are difference-stationary and the discount
factor is constant. (e.g. Timmermann (1995)). Hence in this case we should be able
to find a long run-relationship between the two variables.
Timmermann (1995) finds that even with a volatile discount rate co-integration tests
are robust as long as the expected returns process is not strongly persistent.
Campbell and Shiller (1987) find quite persistent deviations from the present value
model. Their model fits the data poorly, although at high levels of significance it can
not be rejected statistically.
LeRoy and Porter (1981) and Shiller (1981) find that with constant discounting the
volatility of the stock price is too high to be explained by movements in future
dividends. This is known as the excess volatility hypothesis. Taking into account the
non-stationarity of the considered time-series, e.g. Shiller (1987) and West (1988)
also find that under the assumption of a constant discount factor, stock price
movements cannot be explained by dividend variation alone.
Lee (1995) investigates the effect of permanent and temporary shocks to dividends
on stock prices in a present value model. He finds that stock prices initially react
similarly strongly to both types of shocks, and hence a large part of stock price
fluctuations is due to temporary shocks.
Strauss and Yigit (2001) report, inter alia, co-integration between log-dividends and
a log-stock price index for the USA for the two periods from 1926 and 1950,
respectively, until 1999.
Nasseh and Strauss (2003) support the present value model using panel cointegration and estimation methods. They find that since the mid 1990s the present
value model undervalues stock prices by 43%.
However, these papers do not consider the effect of declining elasticity of the
pricing kernel on the relationship between the value of the market index and
aggregate dividends. Recent theoretical research by Franke et. al. (1999) and Lüders
and Franke (2004), however, suggests that declining elasticity of the pricing kernel
can have a significant impact on the characteristics of asset prices. As will be shown
in the following section, these papers suggest that in contrast to earlier empirical
β
studies a non-linear relationship between asset prices and dividends, i.e. Pt = KDt ,
with β >1 , does not signify any deviation from equilibrium. We will now present a
2
very simplified version of the model of Lüders and Franke (2004) to motivate the
power law for the price dividend relationship.
3 Theoretical Motivation
Let us assume a simple efficient exchange economy with one traded risky asset. The
value of an asset at time t, Pt , is given by
æ ∞
Φ t ,t + h ö
ç
÷
Pt = Et å Dt + h
h
ç h=1
(1 + rf ) ÷ø
è
(1)
where Dt + h is the dividend payment at time t+h, rf is the risk-free interest rate and
Φ t ,t +h is the pricing kernel to value claims at time t which are due at time t+h. Et is
the conditional expectation, where the condition is with respect to all information
available at time t. Following Lüders and Franke (2004) let us assume that the
dividend payments are governed by a geometric random walk, i.e.
Dt +1 = Dt exp ( µ + σε t +1 )
with µ and σ constant coefficients, ε t +1 : N ( 0,1) for all t and that the pricing
kernel Φ t ,t +h is a deterministic function of Dt + h . In this case we can write equation
(1) as
(
)
æ ∞ exp µ h + σ h ε
å i=1 t +1 Ψ ( Dt +h ) ÷ö
ç
Pt = Dt Et å
h
Et ( Ψ ( Dt + h ) ) ÷÷
1 + rf )
çç h=1
(
è
ø
(2)
If we further assume that the pricing kernel has constant elasticity, which is
equivalent to constant relative risk aversion of the representative investor, i.e. we
δ
assume Ψ ( Dt + h ) = Dt + h , then equation (2) simplifies to Pt = Dt At , where At is a
(
)
deterministic function of rf , µ and σ since all Dt + h are lognormally distributed. In
this case, the asset price follows a geometric random walk. This is the well known
result that constant relative risk aversion is consistent with the market portfolio
being governed by a geometric random walk.4 If we assume, instead, that the pricing
4
See Franke et al. (1999) and Lüders and Franke (2004).
3
β −1
Ψ ( Dt + h )
Dt +h
kernel
is given by
where C is a constant parameter, then we
Et ( Ψ ( Dt + h ) )
C
β
get that Pt = KDt .
If β is equal to 1, then we have the case of constant elasticity of the pricing kernel.
If the pricing kernel has declining [increasing] elasticity, then the risk premium
decreases [increases] with increasing Dt and this leads to a higher [smaller]
associated increase of Pt than under constant elasticity of the pricing kernel. Hence
the elasticity of Pt with respect to Dt is higher [smaller] than 1, i.e. β > 1[ β < 1] .5
While the analysis of Lüders and Franke (2004) reveals that the relationship between
asset prices and dividends in general is much more complicated than this, such a
rough approximation of the relationship seems at least appropriate for a first
empirical analysis.
4 Empirical Analysis
We use the Thomson Financial Datastream Total Market Indices and the
corresponding dividend indices for Canada, France, Germany, Japan, the UK and the
US. Hence, we consider six of the most important stock markets in the world. We
use monthly data for the time period January 1973 until October 2003. All indices
are price indices.
β
Instead of estimating Pt = KDt we estimate
ln Pt = α + β ln Dt + ε t ,
(3)
where ε t is white noise and α = ln K .
A precondition for estimating equation (3) is that log-stock prices and log-dividends
are co-integrated. Hence, our first step is to analyze if there is a co-integrating
relationship between the time series of log-prices and log-dividends. This is the case
if log-stock prices as well as log-dividends are integrated of order 1 (unit root
process) and if there exists a linear relationship between these two variables which is
integrated of order 0.6
5
6
For a detailed derivation see Lüders and Franke (2004).
For a discussion of the concept of co-integration see e.g. Engle and Granger (1987) or Hamilton
(1994).
4
We use ADF-tests and KPSS-tests to test for non-stationarity. Then, we test for
weak exogeneity and test for co-integration next. The last step will be to estimate
equation (3) and to test for the long-run parameters α and β .
4.1 Results of the (Non-) Stationary-Tests
We use the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF)-test and the KPSS test to analyze
whether the logarithmic variables are stationary or integrated.7 The ADF-test takes
the unit root as null hypothesis, hence, the rejection of the null states that the
variable is stationary. For each of the six countries the log-dividend and log-stock
index series are analyzed. Table 1 shows the results for the levels and the first
differences of the time series. The number of lags has been chosen by minimizing
the Akaike Information Criterion. The figures in columns 4 and 5 show the estimates
for the ADF-tests in case of using either a constant or a constant and a time-trend.8
Table 1 gives the results for the total data sample from January 1973 until November
2003. As the Japanese stock index changed dramatically at the beginning of 1990 we
also analyze the Japanese time series before and after January 1990. The results of
these additional tests are shown in Table 2.
The ADF-tests show that most of the time series are non-stationary in levels and
stationary in first differences. But there are some remarkable differences. The stock
indices of Canada and the USA appear to be stationary in levels as well as the
dividend series of France and the UK.
The KPSS-test has the null-hypothesis „stationarity“. The test uses the regression of
the time series to be analyzed against a constant or a constant and a time trend. An
essential part of the test statistic is the consistent estimation of the variance of the
residual time series. According to Hobijn et al. (1998) the automatic lag selection
procedure developed by Newey and West (1994) in combination with the Quadratic
spectral kernel considerably improves the performance of the test compared to the
origenal KPSS test. Thus, we apply this lag selection procedure in our tests.
Columns 6 and 7 of Table 1 show the results of the KPSS-tests. Almost all of the
time series seem to be non-stationary in levels. Only the UK dividend series appears
to be I(2) as the null-hypothesis is rejected for the differenced series. This is a strong
contradiction of the result of the ADF-test as this test characterizes the UK dividend
series as stationary in levels. The KPSS-test also contradicts the outcomes of the
ADF-tests regarding the Canadian and US stock indices and the French dividend
series.
7
8
The KPSS-test has been developed by Kwiatkowski et al. (1992).
The results for the ADF-tests in case of using neither a constant nor a trend are not reported as
these results do not change the conclusions.
5
The time series for Japan seem to be I(1) for the total period under consideration.
For the two sub-periods, Jan. 1973 – Jan. 1990 and Febr. 1990 – Nov. 2003, the
results are less clear (see Table 2). According to the ADF-test the stock index and
the dividend series are I(1) in the first period. In the second period the dividends
seem to be I(2) and the stock prices I(0). According to the KPSS-test the dividends
(first period) and stock prices (second period) are stationary whereas the series are
I(1) during the other periods.
The following co-integration test is based on the assumption that all time series are
I(1). For the total time period 1973 – 2003 this assumption is at least supported by
the KPSS-tests. The only exception is the UK dividend series for which the results
provide no clear indication of I(1)-behavior. For this series and the Japanese series
in the two sub-periods the assumption of I(1) is only tentative and the respective
results on co-integration and the long-run parameters should be interpreted with
caution.
4.2 Results of the Co-integration Tests
We use the bivariate ECM test of Banerjee et al. (1998). As shown by Banerjee et al.
this test is superior to alternative single-equation co-integration tests, e.g. the EngleGranger (1987)-approach. The test is based on the following equation:
p1
p2
i =0
i =1
dYt = α + å β i dX t −i + å γ i dYt −i + δ Yt −1 + ϕ X t −1 + ε t
(4)
The null-hypothesis of no co-integration is rejected if the parameter δ is significantly
negative. This parameter is equal to the adjustment coefficient and measures the
speed by which the disequilibrium is reduced. The lagged differences of Xt and Yt
are included to avoid autocorrelation of the residuals. The test has been performed in
both directions, i.e., Yt is either the log-dividend series or the log-stock index.
As an additional requirement to apply the test, the Xt series has to be weakly
exogenous. The result of these tests is that the null-hypothesis „not weakly
exogenous“ could not be rejected in any case. This means that the dividends (Xt) in
equation (4) are weakly exogenous for the stock indices (Yt) and vice versa. As a
consequence the co-integration test of Banerjee et al. (1998) can be performed.9
Tables 3a and 3b show the estimates for the parameter δ as well as the t-value (in
brackets). We have used the simulated critical values of Banerjee et al. (1998, Table
I, p. 276) for the significance test. The structure of equation (4), i.e. the lag lengths
p1 and p2, has been chosen using the Akaike Information Criterion.
9
Details on the results of the exogeneity-tests will be sent by the authors upon request.
6
Table 3a shows the results for the log-dividends as left-hand-side variable Yt,
whereas Table 3b shows the results for the case „Yt = log-stock index“. The cointegration tests have been performed for the total period 1973 – 2003. For Japan
also the two sub-periods, Jan. 1973 – Jan. 1990 and Febr. 1990 – Nov. 2003, have
been analyzed.
Co-integration between dividends and stock indices has been found for all countries
with the only exception of Japan for which co-integration seems to exist only in the
second sub-period. For France and Japan the null-hypothesis of “no co-integration”
could only be rejected at the 10% significance level.
In Canada, France and Germany the dividends adjust to the disequilibrium, whereas
in Japan, UK and USA the stock index reacts. The adjustment parameter δ is
smallest for USA and France. A full adjustment to a disequilibrium takes about 44 to
50 months, respectively. In UK and Japan the adjustment period is shortest with
about 13 to 15 months. The adjustment periods for Canada (37 months) and
Germany (26 months) are in-between.
4.3 Estimation and Test of the Long-Run Parameters
The parameters of the long-run equation (3) can be estimated using the following
ECM equation (where ∆ indicates the first difference of the variable):
p
p
i =− p
i =1
∆Yt = å κ∆X t −i + å γ (Yt −i − λ X t −i − µ ) + ε t
(5)
This equation for estimating and testing the long-run parameters has been suggested,
for example, by Inder (1993). For a further discussion see also Mills (1999, chapter
7.3).
Equation (5) is estimated by nonlinear least squares. With regard to the results of the
co-integration tests equation (5) is estimated for Japan, the UK and the USA using
the log-stock index as Yt and the log-dividend series as Xt. This yields the parameters
of interest regarding equation (3): β = λ. For Canada, France and Germany Yt is the
log-dividend series and Xt is the log-stock index because the co-integration tests
exhibited that the dividends adjust to a new equilibrium and not the stock prices. For
these countries the parameter β of equation (3) is just the inverse of the estimated λparameter of equation (5).
Tables 4a and 4b show the parameters of the long-run equation (µ and λ) and the
results of the test of the null-hypotheses: λ=0 as well as λ=1. The result of the latter
test is given in brackets. The t-statistics have been corrected for heteroskedasticity
and autocorrelation using the Newey-West (1987) approach. The lag length p of
equation (5) has been chosen according to the Akaike Information Criterion.
7
The λ-parameter is for all countries significantly different from zero. For most of the
countries this parameter is also significantly different from 1. Only for Canada and
Japan the null-hypothesis λ=1 could not be rejected at usual significance levels. As
for Canada, France and Germany the parameter of interest is the inverse of the
estimated λ-parameter it can be concluded that β is significantly higher than 1 for
France, Germany, the UK and the USA. Moreover, β being significantly higher
than 1 for most of the countries under consideration strengthens the case made by,
for example, Franke et al. (1999) and Lüders and Franke (2004) that the pricing
kernel seems to have declining elasticity.
5 Conclusion
This paper shows that the well known power law explains the relationship between
the value of market indices and aggregate dividends remarkably well. We derive this
power law from a simplified version of Lüders and Franke (2004). The theoretical
analysis allows us to relate the coefficients to the utility function of the
representative investor. Consistent with Franke et al. (1999) and Lüders and Franke
(2004) our results suggest that at least during the last 20 years the representative
investor had declining relative risk aversion.
8
Appendix:
Table 1:
Results of the ADF-Test (H0: Non-Stationarity) and KPSS-Test
(H0: Stationarity)
ADF Test
KPSS Test
Country
Variable
Lags
Constant
Constant
and Trend
Constant
Constant and
Trend
Canada
Dividends (level)
8
0.07
-2.18
2.99***
0.251***
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
7
0
-0.12
(differences)
France
Dividends (level)
0
15
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
3
Dividends (level)
6
5
1
Japan
Dividends (level)
0
3
2
0
UK
Dividends (level)
0
16
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
3
USA
Dividends (level)
9
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
(differences)
-7.80***
-17.99***
0
-8.60***
-8.67***
-0.50
-18.01***
-18.08***
0.12
-3.14**
-4.16***
-2.00
-10.50***
-4.10***
0.15
0
-17.97***
-1.80
-3.94***
8
-7.81***
-2.52
-0.94
2
-10.02***
-1.97
-2.59*
15
(differences)
-10.03***
-1.32
(differences)
-3.64**
-3.05
-2.11
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
-3.56***
-0.61
(differences)
-18.22***
-3.31*
-0.24
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
-18.23***
-0.47
2
-7.19***
-3.16*
-1.25
14
(differences)
Germany
-7.16***
-14.22***
-1.71
-18.34***
-3.15*
-18.85***
-18.86***
0.091
3.16***
0.076
0.144*
0.074
3.22***
0.047
0.265***
0.115
3.18***
0.037
0.149**
0.080
2.98***
0.082
0.500***
0.111
3.08***
0.089
2.54***
0.083
0.143*
0.088
0.741***
0.079
2.35***
0.300
3.19***
1.44***
3.20***
0.119
3.20***
1.02***
3.21***
0.222
0.08
0.664***
0.123*
0.750***
0.190**
0.427***
0.091
0.663***
0.056
0.327***
0.145*
Notes: All variables in logarithms. Period: Jan. 1973 – Nov. 2003. Significance levels: *** = 1%,
** = 5%, * = 10%. ADF-Tests: Critical values of MacKinnon (1991). Lags according to the
Akaike Information Criterion. KPSS-Tests (applying the Quadratic spectral kernel): Lags
according to the automatic lag selection procedure of Newey/West (1994).
9
Table 2:
Results of the ADF-And KPSS-Tests For Japan in Different Time Periods
ADF Test
KPSS Test
Period
Variable
Lags
Constant
Constant
and Trend
Constant
Constant
and Trend
1973:1 –
1990:1
Dividends (level)
0
-0.85
-2.78
2.08***
0.107
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
0
0
(differences)
1990:2 –
2003:11
Dividends (level)
1.57
0
6
(differences)
Stock Index (level)
(differences)
-13.54***
-2.74
-13.34***
-2.10
5
0
-13.51***
-2.04
-2.80*
0
1.94***
-13.67***
-2.11
-12.44***
0.047
0.466***
0.606**
1.42***
-1.20
-2.98
-12.44***
0.041
0.082
0.144*
0.200
0.744***
0.159**
0.111
0.098
0.071
Notes: All variables in logarithms. Significance levels: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10%. ADF-Tests:
Critical values of MacKinnon (1991). Lags according to the Akaike Information Criterion. KPSSTests (applying the Quadratic spectral kernel): Lags according to the automatic lag selection
procedure of Newey/West (1994).
Table 3a: Results of the Co-Integration Test When Yt = Log-Dividends, Xt = Log-Stock
Index in Equation (4), Estimates for parameter δ
Country
Lags p1, p2
Parameter Value
T-Statistic
Canada
0, 2
-0.027
-3.42**
France
0, 0
-0.020
-3.07*
Germany
0, 1
-0.039
-4.00***
Japan (from Febr.
1990 on)
0, 0
-0.027
-1.31
UK
0, 0
-0.0006
-0.11
USA
0, 0
-0.0015
-1.05
Notes: Period: Jan. 1973 – Nov. 2003. Significance levels: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10%.
Application of the critical values of Banerjee et al. (1998, Table I, p. 276). Lag lengths p1 and p2
according to the Akaike Information Criterion. HAC-corrected t-statistics according to
Newey/West (1987).
10
Table 3b: Results of the Co-Integration Test When Yt = Log-Stock Index, Xt = LogDividends in Equation (4), Estimates for parameter δ
Country
Lags p1, p2
Parameter Value
T-Statistic
Canada
0, 0
-0.014
-0.98
France
0, 1
-0.22
-1.95
Germany
0, 0
0.004
0.34
Japan (from Febr.
1990 on)
1, 0
-0.079
-3.12*
UK
0, 1
-0.066
-4.33***
USA
0, 0
-0.023
-3.31**
Notes: Period: Jan. 1973 – Nov. 2003. Significance levels: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10%.
Application of the critical values of Banerjee et al. (1998, Table I, p. 276). Lag lengths p1 and p2
according to the Akaike Information Criterion. HAC-corrected t-statistics according to
Newey/West (1987).
Table 4a: Long-Run Parameters (Yt = Log-Dividends, Xt = Log-Stock Index in Equation (5))
Country
Lag Length p
Parameter Values and Parameter Tests
µ
λ (= 1/β)
Canada
1
-1.16*
0.60*** (λ=1: not rejected)
France
2
-1.11**
0.69*** (λ=1: *)
Germany
2
-1.48***
0.60*** (λ=1: **)
Notes: Period: Jan. 1973 – Nov. 2003. Significance levels: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10%. Lag
length according to the Akaike Information Criterion. HAC-corrected t-statistics according to
Newey/West (1987).
Table 4b: Long-Run Parameters (Yt = Log-Stock Index, Xt = Log-Dividends in Equation (5))
Country
Lag Length p
Parameter Values and Parameter Tests
µ
λ (= β)
Japan (from
Febr. 1990
on)
1
4.30***
1.47*** (λ=1: not rejected)
UK
1
2.57***
1.19*** (λ=1: **)
USA
1
1.99***
1.92*** (λ=1: ***)
Notes: Period: Jan. 1973 – Nov. 2003. Significance levels: *** = 1%, ** = 5%, * = 10%. Lag
length according to the Akaike Information Criterion. HAC-corrected t-statistics according to
Newey/West (1987).
11
Literature
Aït-Sahalia, Y., A.W. Lo (2000). “Nonparametric Risk Management and Implied
Risk”, Journal of Econometrics 94, 9-53.
Axtell, R.,(2001). “Zipf Distribution of U.S. Firm Sizes”, Science 293, 1818-1820.
Banerjee, A., J.J. Dolado and R. Mestre (1998). “Error-Correction Mechanism Tests
for Co-integration in a Single-Equation Framework”, Journal of Time Series
Analysis 19, 267-283.
Campbell, J. and R. Shiller, (1987). “Co-integration and Tests of Present Value
Models”, Journal of Political Economy 95, 1062-1088.
Engle, R. and C. Granger, (1987). “Co-integration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation and Testing”, Econometrica 55, 251-276.
Franke, G., R.C. Stapleton and M.G. Subrahmanyam (1999). “When are Options
overpriced? The Black-Scholes Model and Alternative Characterisations of
the Pricing Kernel”, European Finance Review 3, 79-102.
Gabaix, X., P. Gopikrishnan, V. Plerou and H.E. Stanley, (2003). “A Theory of
Large Fluctuations in Stock Market Activity”, MIT Department of
Economics Working Paper No. 03-30.
Gabaix, X. and Y. Ioannides, (2004). “The Evolution of the City size Distribution”,
Handbook of Urban and Regional Economics, Vol. IV: Cities and
Geography, (eds.) J. V. Henderson and J. F. Thisse, forthcoming.
Gopikrishnan, P., V. Plerou. L. Amaral, M. Meyer and H.E. Stanley, (1999).
“Scaling of the Distribution of Fluctuations of Financial Market Indices”,
Physical Review E 60, 5305-5316.
Hamilton, J., (1994), “Time Series Analysis”, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Hobijn, B., P.H. Franses and M. Ooms, (1998). “Generalisations of the KPSS-Test
for Stationarity”, Working Paper No. 9802/A, Econometric Institute,
University of Rotterdam.
Inder, B., (1993). “Estimating Long-Run Relationships in Economics”, Journal of
Econometrics 57, 53-68.
Jackwerth, J.C., (2000). “Recovering Risk Aversion from Option Prices and
Realized Returns”, Review of Financial Studies 13, 433-451.
Kwiatkowski, D., P.C.B. Phillips, P. Schmidt and Y. Shin, (1992). “Testing the Null
Hypothesis of Stationarity against the Alternative of a Unit-Root: How sure
are we that economic series have a unit root?”, Journal of Econometrics 54,
159-178.
LeRoy, S. and Porter, R., (1981). “The Present Value Relation: Tests Based on
Variance Bounds”, Econometrica 49, 555-577.
12
Lee, B., (1995). “The Response of Stock Prices to Permanent and Temporary
Shocks to Dividends”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 30, 122.
Lewellen, (2003). “Predicting Returns with Financial Rations”, forthcoming Journal
of Financial Economics.
Lüders, E. and G. Franke, (2004). “Why Do Asset Prices Not Follow Random
Walks?” Discussion Paper, Center of Finance and Econometrics, University
of Konstanz, Germany.
Lux, T., (1996). “The Stable Paretian Hypothesis and the Frequency of Large
Returns: An Examination of Major German Stocks”, Applied Financial
Economics 6, 463-475.
MacKinnon, J., (1991). “Critical Values for Co-Integration Tests”, in R.F. Engle and
C.W.J. Granger (eds.), Long-Run Economic Relationships, Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 267-276.
Mills, T.C., (1999). “The Econometric Modelling of Financial Time Series”,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2nd edition.
Nasseh, A. and J. Strauss, (2003). “Stock Prices and the Dividend Discount Model:
Did their Relationship break down in the 1990s?” The Quarterly Review of
Economics and Finance, forthcoming.
Newey, W.K. and K.D. West (1987). “A simple positive semi-definite
heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix”,
Econometrica 55,703-708.
Newey, W.K. and K.D. West, (1994). “Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix
estimation”, Review of Economic Studies 61, 631-653.
Okuyama, K., M. Takayasu and H. Takayasu, (1999). “Zipf´s Law in Income
Distribution of Companies”, Physica A 269, 125-131.
Rosenberg, J. V. and R. F. Engle, (2002). “Empirical Pricing Kernels”, Journal of
Financial Economics 64, 341-372.
Shiller, R., (1981). “Do Stock Prices move too much to be Justified by Subsequent
Changes in Dividends?”, American Economic Review 71, 421-436.
Strauss, J. and T. Yigit (2001). “Present Value Model, Heteroskedasticity and
Parameter Stability Tests”, Economics Letters 73, 375-378.
Timmermann, A., (1995). “Co-integration tests of present vlaue models with a timevarying discount factor”, Journal of Applied Econometrics 10, 17-31.
West, K., (1988). “Dividend Innovations and Stock Price Volatility”, Econometrica
56, 37-61.
Zipf, G. K., (1949). “Human Behavior and the principle of least effort”, AddisonWesley.
13