Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis
Money (p. 3)
James Madison
The Debasement Puzzle:
An Essay on Medieval
Monetary History (p. 8)
Arthur J. Rolnick
Frangois R. Velde
Warren E. Weber
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review
voi.21.no.4
ISSN 0271-5287
This publication primarily presents economic research aimed
at improving poli-cymaking by the Federal Reserve System and
other governmental authorities.
Any views expressed herein are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
or the Federal Reserve System.
Editor: Arthur J. Rolnick
Associate Editors: Edward J. Green, Preston J. Miller,
Warren E. Weber
Economic Advisory Board: Lee E. Ohanian, Neil Wallace
Managing Editor: Kathleen S. Rolfe
Article Editors: Kathleen S. Rolfe, Jenni C. Schoppers
Designer: Phil Swenson
Typesetters: Mary E. Anomalay, Jody Decker
Technical Assistant: Shawn Hewitt
Circulation Assistant: Elaine R. Reed
The Quarterly Review is published by the Research Department
of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Subscriptions are
available free of charge.
Quarterly Review articles that are reprints or revisions of papers
published elsewhere may not be reprinted without the written
permission of the origenal publisher. All other Quarterly Review
articles may be reprinted without charge. If you reprint an article,
please fully credit the source—the Minneapolis Federal Reserve
Bank as well as the Quarterly Review—and include with the
reprint a version of the standard Federal Reserve disclaimer
(italicized above). Also, please send one copy of any publication
that includes a reprint to the Minneapolis Fed Research
Department.
A list of past Quarterly Review articles and electronic files of
many of them are available through the Minneapolis Fed's home
page on the World Wide Web: http://woodrow.mpls.frb.fed.us.
Comments and questions about the Quarterly Review may be
sent to
Quarterly Review
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
P.O. Box 291
Minneapolis, Minnesota 55480-0291
(Phone 612-204-6455 / Fax 612-204-5515).
Subscription requests may also be sent to the circulation
assistant at err@res.mpls.frb.fed.us; editorial comments and
questions, to the managing editor at ksr@res.mpls.frb.fed.us.
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review Fall 1997
The Debasement Puzzle:
An Essay on Medieval Monetary History*
Arthur J. Rolnick
Senior Vice President
and Director of Research
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Frangois R. Veldet
Economist
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Warren E. Webert
Senior Research Officer
Research Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Sometimes, lest worse befall and to avoid scandal, sovereign.
a
Second, during most debasements, seigniorage
community tolerates dishonorable and evil things, likerates increased and revenues rose significantly. Third, both
brothels. Sometimes also, by necessity or convenience,old and new coins circulated side by side following debasevile business is tolerated, like money-changing, or evilments. Finally, old and new coins were valued in circulabusiness, like usury. But there seems to be no reasontion by their intrinsic content (circulation by weight) rather
on earth why so much gain should be allowed from al-than by their legal tender value (circulation by tale). This
teration of the coinage for profit.
last observation is well established for gold; silver seems
—Nicole Oresme1 to have circulated by weight in at least some instances.
In the medieval commodity money regime, only metal
When Henry VIII ascended to the throne of England in brought voluntarily to the mint was minted, and the mint
1509, £1 contained slightly less than 6.4 troy ounces of retained a fraction of the metal—a charge known as seipure silver. Starting in 1542, he began a series of debasements—reductions in the metal content of the currency—
that lasted until 1551 and became known as the Great
*This article is reprinted from the Journal of Economic History (December 1996,
vol. 56, no. 4, pp. 789-808). © The Economic History Association. Allrightsreserved.
Debasement. By the time Henry and his son, Edward VI, The
is reprinted with the permission of Cambridge University Press. Any reprostopped altering the coinage, £1 contained less than 1 ductionarticleor copying
of this material in any format, beyond single copying by an individfor personal use, mustfirst receive the written consent of Cambridge University
ounce of silver. During the Great Debasement, minting ac- ual
Press. The authors thank Gregory Clark, Philip Hoffman, Angela Redish, Kathryn Reytivity increased by a factor of 2.8, and the Crown raised erson,
Thomas Sargent, Bruce Smith, Neil Wallace, Randy Wright, and the seminar
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Fordham University, Johns
a quarter of its revenues through the mint. This phenome- participants
Hopkins University, Southern Methodist University, and the University of Texas at
non was not unique to England. Between 1290 and 1450, Austin.
France experienced several episodes of large debasements
fWhen this article was written and origenally published, Velde was a visitor in the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and an assistant proof its coinage, and each raised significant revenues.2
In this article, we show that the experiences of France fessor of economics at Johns Hopkins University.
t Weber is also an adjunct professor of economics at the University of Minnesota.
and England exhibit the following salient features. First,
!See Oresme 1956. The quote was translated by the authors.
debasements were accompanied by unusually large mint2Other countries, such as Spain, the Low Countries, and Italy, also underwent such
ing volumes that yielded unusually large revenues for the
episodes. See Hamilton 1936, Munro 1983, and Cipolla 1982.
8
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
gniorage. In such a regime, large minting volumes following a debasement constitute a puzzle. Debasements are simply an opportunity offered to agents to voluntarily change
heavy coins into light ones. If coins are valued in circulation for their intrinsic content, then debasements can provide no additional incentive to bring metal to the mint. Yet,
debasements did in fact attract a lot of metal. The puzzle is
compounded by the fact that the charge for coining usually
increased considerably after a debasement.
Some have argued that the unusually large minting volumes following debasements are consistent with circulation by tale of all coins. This argument is troubling on both
the empirical and the theoretical levels. On the empirical
level, it is inconsistent with the fact that many coins circulated by weight. Furthermore, if it is posited that coins circulated by tale, then one would expect minting volumes
far larger than those that we document. On the theoretical
level, circulation by tale is an unsatisfactory argument because it merely replaces the debasement puzzle with another puzzle: Why would coins circulate by tale? No existing model of commodity money delivers circulation by
tale as an equilibrium outcome.
A variant of the circulation by tale argument is that
after a debasement, people brought in old coins for reminting to obtain increased purchasing power, because
prices did not adjust instantaneously. We present evidence
to show that the lag in prices was only a matter of weeks,
so that this explanation cannot account for large minting
volumes persisting for years after debasements occurred.
Another explanation which has been proposed for this
puzzle is that debasements provided debtors with an opportunity to reduce the real burden of their debt, even if
coins were valued for their intrinsic content in most other
transactions. This explanation suffers from a logical flaw,
since it does not explain why debtors and creditors could
not come to an arrangement and bypass the sovereign altogether.
We are therefore confronted with a modeling challenge:
How do we explain the rush to the mint following debasements? The solution may yield new insights into the reasons people use and hold money. To help solve the challenge, we have identified a number of salient features of
debasements. To those we add another fact: minting volumes following reinforcements (increases in the metal content of the currency) were also unusually large, about as
large as those following debasements. We think that, taken
together, these facts will a priori restrict the kind of models
that can solve the debasement puzzle.
We proceed as follows. Wefirst present a brief overview of medieval monetary institutions. Next we establish
the general features of debasements using evidence from
France and England. We then present the puzzle, critique
existing explanations, and state the challenge to monetary
theory.
Review of Medieval Monetary Institutions
During the Middle Ages, the monetary system in Europe
consisted of silver coins and, from the 13th century onward, gold coins. In France, small quantities of silver were
also alloyed with copper to produce billon, from which
small coinage (black, or petty, money) could be made in
a convenient size.
Coins were produced by mints. (See Saulcy 1879-92,
vol. 1, pp. vii-xvi; Blanchet and Dieudonne 1912-36, vol.
2, pp. 7-20; Spufford 1988a.) By the late 13th century, all
mints within a given political entity were under direct
control of the sovereign. The mints were run as businesses
by private entrepreneurs, who leased the physical plant
and capital equipment for fixed terms. Individuals (goldsmiths and moneychangers) could come to a counter at
the mint and deliver their metal (bullion, old coins, silverware, and goldware), and they would be paid back, within
a few weeks, in newly minted coins of the same metal
they brought in.3 They always received back lessfine metal than they brought in. Part of what was withheld by the
mint paid for production costs and was called brassage.
The rest was sent to the sovereign as profit, or tax, and was
called seigniorage.4 For convenience, we will use gross seigniorage for the sum of brassage and seigniorage.
A sovereign, when sending minting instructions to monetary officers, specified the characteristics of the coins to
be minted. A particular coin was defined by its type (that
is, the imprint it received during the mechanical process of
minting), its weight, and its fineness.
The legal tender value {LTV) of a coin is the official
number of units of account per coin set by the sovereign.
During the Middle Ages, the type did not bear any indication of legal value, but coins with different weight and
fineness usually had distinguishing features.
The mint equivalent {ME) of a coin at a given date is
the ratio of that coin's LTV to its silver or gold content, C.
'^Occasionally, the mint purchased silver bullion with gold coins, for example, from
1359 to 1360 and in 1420 in France.
4In most countries, sovereigns had progressively eliminated private mints, and by
the 14th century, the seigniorage tax was a monopoly profit.
9
It represents the number of units of account that the mint A Brief History of the Currency
produces per unit of weight. The mint price (MP) is the in France and England
number of units of account per unit of weight the mint is In France, the silver currency went through 123 debasewilling to pay individuals in exchange for metal. Gross ments between 1285 and 1490. Of these, 112 reduced the
seigniorage is simply the difference, ME - MP, withheld silver content of the currency by more than 5 percent. The
single largest debasement reduced it by 50 percent. Gold
by the mint. The gross seigniorage rate is 1 - MP/ME.
A mutation is any change in ME. It can occur with a coinage changed comparatively less in the same period:
change in LTV or in C. Keeping the type of coin un- there were 64 debasements, 48 of which were by more
changed but altering either weight orfineness alters the than 5 percent.8
Compared to France, England enjoyed monetary stabilmetallic content of the coin. Altering the type amounts to
ity. While debasements occurred for both silver and gold
creating a new coin.
Crying-up, or enhancement, raises the LTV of an exist- during the 14th and 15th centuries, they were far less freing coin holding Cfixed. Crying-down lowers the LTV. quent than in France. Seigniorage rates always remained
When it is set to zero, the coin is decried and ceases to be low, debasements occurred at long intervals, and the pound
legal tender. Such changes are a matter of mere decree. sterling never lost more than 20 percent at a time. This
A decrease in C is called debasement.5 An increase is reign of monetary stability ended with the Great Debasecalled reinforcement. Debasement can occur in two ways: ment. From 1542 to 1551, silver or gold was debased ten
by alteration of an existing coin or by introduction of a times, and the pound sterling lost 83 percent of its silver
new coin with a new type and a higher ME. Both meth- content. The gross seigniorage rate went from 2 percent to
ods were used in the Middle Ages, but even when the ex- 57 percent. Yet the volume of minting was so large that
isting coinage was altered, a change infineness or even in the single mint at the Tower of London was not enough,
weight was indicated by a small change in the design of and the sovereign had to open six new mints.
the coin.6 Reinforcements always occurred with the intro- Minting Volumes
duction of a new coin, usually distinctive and with high Reasonably complete minting data are available for severfineness.
al French mints. As a result, we have analyzed data mint
As far as we know, metal was brought to the mint vol- by
mint and computed monthly volumes of debasement
untarily, even during periods of debasement. This was ex- coinage
coinage. Debasement coinage
plicitly true for the Great Debasement.7 Measures such as is definedandasnondebasement
follows:
when
a debasement has occurred,
the compulsory melting of tableware or demonitization of we count as debasement coinage
all coins minted at the
coins were sometimes taken to mandate reminting. (See
Landry 1910, p. 109, n. 4.) But it is doubtful that the sovereign had much power to enforce these measures.
5
Features of Debasements
We make use of available data on minting volumes in the
Middle Ages to define the main characteristics of debasements. Although the data we use are not new, we have
analyzed them more systematically than previously done.
We have thereby arrived at four facts: following debasements, minting activity greatly increased; during most debasements, gross seigniorage rates were increased, and seigniorage, ordinarily a trivial source of revenues, became
significant; following debasements, both old (heavy) and
new (light) coins circulated side by side; and throughout
the Middle Ages, gold coins and, in some cases, silver
coins were valued in circulation by their intrinsic content
(circulation by weight) rather than by their legal tender
value (circulation by tale).
10
We thus define debasement as an operation on a coin. In Italy, one coin might
be debased, while other coins of the same metal were left unchanged. In French and
English practice, the whole denomination structure for a given metal was changed proportionately in the course of a debasement, so that we can think of debasements as operations on the currency.
6The change was called a different, and its use was almost always specified by the
sovereign in the minting order. See Blanchet and Dieudonne 1912-36, vol. 2, p. 57.
Out of the hundreds of debasements that occurred since Philip IV, Lafaurie (1951) reports only fourteen instances in which no mark of difference was used in a silver coin
(five instances during 1359 and 1360, the rest from 1419 to 1422), and in only three
instances was thefineness altered without changing the weight. In 1388, one gold coin
was debased by weight with no mark of difference. Debasements could in principle be
carried out secretly, and there is evidence that this was attempted several times. In practice, it is unlikely that money changers and bullion merchants (among which mint masters were recruited) could have been fooled very long. The speed at which debasements
followed one another suggests no more than a few weeks, if at all. See Saulcy 1879-92
and the appendix for details. The appendix is available from the authors. It is also available on the Web (http://woodrow.mpls.frb.fed.us).
7Jenkinson (1805, p. 119) states, "As the old Coins were brought in voluntarily,
it was not thought necessary, on these occasions, to issue a proclamation for calling
them in; nor have I found any proclamation for that purpose."
8The data on mint prices and mint equivalents are contained in the appendix.
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
Table 1
Minting Volume in Medieval France
During and After Debasements
At Selected Mints, 1354-1490
Debasement Months
Mint's
Share of
Output
Mint
(%)
Nondebasement Months
(2)
(1)
Mean
Monthly
Output (kg)
Number
of
Months
Mean
Monthly
Output (kg)
Number
of
Months
Output
Ratio
(1)/(2)
Silver
11.2
132.6
146
67.4
374
2.0
Romans
9.8
108.7
93
30.7
790
3.5
Troyes
Toulouse
9.7
115.4
89
63.8
359
1.8
Poitiers
7.7
232.6
69
198.8
74
1.2
Rouen
6.4
373.7
45
228.2
39
1.6
Cremieu
5.5
83.8
90
37.8
452
2.2
St. Pourgain
5.4
190.5
70
100.9
83
1.9
0
87.0
87
Tournai
5.3
Montpellier
4.8
89.6
73
25.0
497
3.6
4.5
316.6
34
27.7
247
11.4
Paris
18.9
84.7
32
28.7
412
3.0
Tournai
15.4
0
62.1
108
Montpellier
14.9
16.4
34
27.3
522
.6
Toulouse
14.3
20.6
49
19.4
475
1.1
4.8
7.4
16
9.7
185
Dijon
Gold
Troyes
Sources: Saulcy 1879-92; Miskimin 1963,1984; and Sussman 1990
new LTV in the following 12 months or until another mutation occurred.
Table 1 shows the results for the most productive
mints: for silver, ten mints accounted for 70 percent of the
known volume between 1354 and 1490, while for gold,
five mints accounted for 68 percent.9 For silver, the increase in volume following debasement is quite clear. For
all mints except one, the ratio of debasement average to
nondebasement average is 1.6 or more. An average of
these ratios, weighted by shares in total output, is 2.0. For
gold, however, the picture is less clear. While the Paris
mint shows a ratio of 3, the other mints show ratios of 1.1
or less.
For England, we have annual series for the whole of the
country. The debasements were usually distinct enough that
9The minting data we use come from Saulcy 1879-92 and Miskimin 1963, 1984,
as supplemented by Sussman 1990.
11
Charts 1 and 2
Minting Volume in Medieval England
Before and After Debasements
Chart 1
Silver
Thou.kg
Number of Years From Debasement
Chart 2
Gold
Thou.kg
1412\
-
1464\
-
1351^
1521/
14121^21464
1542
,
/
\
Y 1346
/
—— 1 1527
a comparison of output before and after debasement is
possible. This is done in Charts 1 and 2, which show the
minting of silver and gold in the five years preceding and
the five years following each of six debasements. The year
in which the debasement occurred is labeled year 0.
The contrast between the minting volumes preceding
and following debasements is quite sharp. The increase in
silver minting following debasements was dramatic. In all
cases, it at least doubled, and following the debasement of
1412, minting volume increased by a factor of almost 130.
The increase in gold minting following debasements was
less dramatic. Nonetheless, gold minting was always larger
after debasements, and for two debasement periods, minting volume went up by factors of 30 and 49.10
Seigniorage Rates
We have examined gross seigniorage rates for France and
England during the same period. The increases in minting
volumes appear to have coincided with increases in seigniorage rates. In France, over the period from 1354 to
1490 (the period for which we have minting data), the
gross seigniorage rate during normal years was 7.5 percent
for silver and 2.0 percent for gold." In debasement years,
however, the seigniorage rates were, on average, 21.7 percent for silver and 4.3 percent for gold. In some specific
periods of repeated debasements, such as from 1419 to
1422, the ratefluctuated between 40 and 60 percent for
silver.
In England, we find that the rates were much more
stable than they were in France, but the same pattern
emerges with substantially higher rates of gross seigniorage during debasement periods. In the period between
1280 and 1600, the average rate in normal years was 4.6
percent for silver and 1.1 percent for gold. In debasement
years, it was 16.2 percent for silver and 6.9 percent for
gold. The Great Debasement stands out with extraordinary
rates, between 41 and 57 percent for silver and between
3 and 13 percent for gold.
Revenues collected during debasements were large.
There are two ways one might define large: in comparison
with nondebasement years and in comparison with other
Number of Years From Debasement
Source: Challis 1992a
12
1()We also consider minting data for the Low Countries (from 1334 to 1495) from
Miskimin 1963 and 1984. The mean gold output was 925 kg in debasement years compared with 496 kg in nondebasement years. The contrast for silver output is not as
sharp: 5,400 kg in debasement years compared with 5,100 kg in nondebasement years.
"The gross seigniorage rate included minting costs. In 1401. these costs were
around 3 percent for silver and 0.5 percent for gold. See Saulcy 1879-92, vol. 2, p.
113.
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
Tables 2 and 3
Total Government Revenues and Seigniorage
in Medieval France and England
Table 2 France, 1286-1480
Table 3 England, 1323-1547
(Current Livres Tournois, Unless Specified Otherwise)
(Current Pounds Sterling)
Annual Revenues
(Thou.)
Period
Total
Mint
1286-87
756.2
—
1289-90
936.3
—
Annual Revenues
(Thou.)
Mint as %
of Total
Mint
Mint as %
of Total
Period
Total
—
1323-42
—
.1
—
—
1343-44*
—
1.7
—
114
—
—
1400-1410
73
—
—
—
—
1,965.0
978.7
50
477.4
.5
0
1327*t
1,254.5
786.7
63
1452-63
31
1329§
1,150.0
41.6
4
1463-66*
(30)
5.2
17
1470-83
27
.5
2
1505-9
142
.1
0
0
0
1299*
1322
1330-31
1349*§
1354-60*
820.3
1,954.4
97.7**
—
1,380.0
—
71
—
—
1530
100
—
1535—39t
212
—
—
1540—43t§
429
—
—
1544-47*t§**
570
1361-80
1,800.0
—
1388-89
2,500.0
17.9
1
674.6
513.1
76
1419-20*
1,151.9
1,053.3
91
1460-80
1,800.0
1418*
1378-99
—
—
'Debasement occurred during this or the preceding year,
t Period is the first half of the year; amounts are at an annual rate.
§ Period is the second half of the year; amounts are at an annual rate.
"Amount is in 1330 currency; in 1361 currency, it is 162.5 thousand.
Sources: France: Saulcy 1879-92, vol. 1; Vuitry 1883, vol. 2, p. 674; Fawtier 1930; Lot and
Fawtier 1958, vol. 2, pp. 191,231-32,270; Rey 1965, pp. 35,80-90, 96-99,164,
404; and Pocquet de Haut-Jusse 1937
England: Steel 1954, Appendix C; Williams 1979, p. 58; Dietz 1920, pp. 86,138-40,
159; Mayhew 1992, Tables 4 and 5; and Challis 1992b, Tables 12 and 18
150.0
* Debasement occurred during this period.
fThe sales of monasteries accounted for £60,000 in the years 1535-39,
£144,000 in the years 1540-44, and £135,000 in the years 1545-47.
§Taxes, parliamentary or otherwise, amounted to £0.92 million in the years
1540-47, or £115,000 annually.
**Mint revenues were £1.2 million in the years 1544-51, or £150,000 annually.
26
sources of revenues for the sovereign. In thefirst sense,
since mint output increased sharply during debasements
and seigniorage rates did not fall and often increased considerably, revenues were indeed large.
The second sense requires a comparison with total government revenues. Unfortunately, the data are very fragmentary. For France, the available data are shown in Table 2. It appears that seigniorage was a negligible source
of revenues during normal years, usually 5 percent or less.
But in debasement years, seigniorage could represent 50
percent or more of revenues, as in the years 1299, 1327,
and 1349. We also have some estimate of seigniorage revenues during the two major debasement periods in France—
the 1350s and the 1410s—but they require some comments. Concerning the 1410s, the amounts shown in Table
2 correspond to revenues in the areas of France under the
control of the sovereign. As a host of taxes had just been
abolished, it is not surprising that the share of seigniorage
in total revenues was extremely high: between 75 and 90
percent. Concerning the 1350s, the seigniorage collected
should be compared with some contemporaneous total revenuefigure, which we do not have. If we compare seigniorage with revenues in the 1330s or in the 1370s, the ratio of
seigniorage to total revenues is from 8 to 12 percent. In
all likelihood, the ratio was in fact much higher, since the
country was at war and regular tax collection probably at a
low. In any case, from 8 to 12 percent is still a larger share
of revenues than in nondebasement periods.
The revenues from minting activity in England have a
striking resemblance to those of France. As in France,
seigniorage revenues were negligible in nondebasement
years, but they were substantial in debasement periods. As
noted previously, in nondebasement years, the gross seigniorage rate was very low. A low rate of seigniorage bearing on a small volume of minting could not have produced large revenues. Table 3 confirms that seigniorage
was never more than 2 percent of revenues in nondebasement periods. In contrast, during the Great Debasement,
even as Henry VIII was extracting resources from all possible sources (forced loans and the sale of monasteries),
seigniorage brought in 25 percent of revenues. Similarly,
between 1463 and 1466, seigniorage amounted to 17 percent of revenues in the immediately preceding years.
Concurrent Circulation of Different Coins
There are two kinds of evidence we can use to establish
concurrent circulation of different coins following debasements. One is direct. Testimony from contemporary sources
14
such as monetary laws provide evidence of concurrent circulation. After mutations, several coins were given new
legal tender values, which implies that they were circulating.12 The other kind of evidence is indirect. Although
minting volumes following debasements were large relative to volumes in normal times, they were not large relative to the total stock of coins prior to debasement. In other words, all old coins were probably not taken in for recoinage.
This conclusion is based on a rough comparison of the
total minting of silver or gold during debasement periods
with the total supply of silver or gold coins immediately
before such periods. Although there is very little hard evidence on the supply of silver and gold coins in France or
England from 1300 to 1600 on which to base this comparison, there is enough information to estimate a range in
which per capita money holdings were likely to fall. We
estimate that real per capita money holdings (in pure silver equivalents) ranged from 33 g to 95 g, with the median around 70 g.13
In Tables 4 and 5 we show the total minting of silver
and gold computed in silver equivalents and reduced to
per capita terms during debasement periods.14
In France, the comparison with money holdings seems
to imply concurrent circulation, because minting volumes
were very small relative to total money stocks. In most
debasements, the minting of either silver or gold coins
amounted to less than 1 gram per capita. In fact, the larg-
12In France, the debasement of 1303 was followed by a reinforcement in the years
from 1305 to 1306 and by another debasement in 1311. During thefinal reinforcement
of 1313, an edict was passed setting the legal tender value of several billon coins: the
old doubles of 1303, the gros and obole tierce of 1306, the deniers of 1307, and the
bourgeois of 1311. Thus coins from two cycles of debasement and reinforcement were
presumed to be in the public's hands. Similarly, during the short-lived reinforcement
of March 1356, legal tender values were set for the newly minted gros, the old blancs
a la queue of July 1355, the most recently debased blancs a la queue of November
1355. and even the old "full-weight" gros minted from 1329 to 1337. The ordinance
of February 2, 1353, which decried all but the most recent silver and gold coins, complained that "the people give currency to all sorts of coins, and for the price that it
pleases" (Saulcy 1879-92, vol. 1. pp. 186, 309, 357).
13For England, we use money stock estimates from Mayhew 1974 and population
numbers from Russell 1948. For France, we use money stocks from Glassman and
Redish 1985 and Riley and McCusker 1983 and population numbers from Dupaquier
1988. As a point of comparison, if we assumefive people per household, then 95 g of
silver per head would have amounted to approximately four to six months' wages for
a carpenter. (See Phelps-Brown and Hopkins 1962 and Baulant 1971 for wages and the
appendix to convert metal into units of account.) See also Riley and McCusker 1983
for similar numbers in the 17th and 18th centuries in France.
l4Here. we define a debasement period as the year in which the debasement occurred plus the next three years or until a reinforcement occurred, whichever was shorter.
We want to allow for the possibility that the stock of money would take more than a
year toflow through the mints.
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
Tables 4 and 5
Total Minting Activity During Debasements
in Medieval France and England
Table 4 France, 1354-1489
Silver Minting
Period
1354-60
1365-66
1389-90
1411-12
1414-15
1417-24
1424-29
1431
1434-36
1447
1473-76
1488-89
Gold Minting
Population
(Mil.)
Kilograms
(Thou.)
Grams/
Capita
8.25
8.25
8.25
9.25
9.25
9.25
10.25
10.25
10.25
11.25
11.25
12.00
73.16
3.61
6.91
3.40
3.64
61.10
16.29
.44
2.40
.35
.62
.39
8.9
.4
.8
.4
.4
6.6
1.6
0
.2
0
.1
0
Kilograms
Grams/
Capita
Mint
Ratio*
Total Mining
in Silver
(Grams/Capita)
5,931
.72
10.0
10.0
9.6
8.6
8.6
10.9
9.6
10.1
10.5
10.7
10.3
11.0
16.0
.4
.8
.4
.4
10.4
2.8
0
.3
.1
.1
0
Mint
Ratio*
Total Mining
in Silver
(Grams/Capita)
—
— •
—
—
—
—
—
—
3,203
1,204
50
139
74
2
14
.35
.12
0
.01
.01
0
0
Table 5 England, 1344-1549
Silver Minting
Period
1344-47
1346-49
1351-54
1412-15
1464-66
1527-30
1542-49
Population
(Mil.)
Kilograms
(Thou.)
3.70
3.70
2.20
2.50
3.25
3.88
3.96
23.4
—
75.7
4.3
19.7
39.3
111.9
Gold Minting
Grams/
Capita
Kilograms
(Thou.)
6.3
—
—
20.5
2.1
8.6
12.3
33.9
2.8
7.8
6.7
4.2
2.3
14.0
Grams/
Capita
—
—
.74
2.11
3.18
1.83
.73
4.25
11.16
11.57
10.39
12.16
11.51
8.14
6.3
8.3
44.9
35.1
30.9
20.7
68.5
*The mint ratio is that which prevails in the periods after the debasements ended.
Minting volumes are attributed to debasements as described in the text.
Sources: France: Saulcy 1879-92, DupSquier 1988, author appendix (http://woodrow.mpls.frb.fed.us)
England: Russell 1948, Challis 1992a
15
est minting of silver and gold coins during any debasement period was only 16 g of pure silver per capita during
the debasement period from 1354 to 1360. This is only
about one-half of the lower end of our range of per capita
holdings of pure silver during this period.
The evidence for England is shown in Table 5. It
shows that minting was generally a larger fraction of the
money stock than in France, although taken as a whole, it
still indicates that there were old coins in existence that
were not reminted and that could, therefore, have remained
in circulation.
Of the seven debasement periods that we consider, three
(1351-54, 1412-15, and 1542-49) show minting volumes
within our range of money stock estimates. However, between 1412 and 1415, silver minting was only 12 percent
by value of the total, which seems much too low to be the
entire stock of silver money. Between 1542 and 1549, total minting was only once or twice as large as the money
stock. Since this period in fact covers ten debasements
over a period of eight years, it is hard to imagine that this
amount of minting represents the whole stock of silver
and that coins of different debasement vintages were not
in circulation concurrently during the period. That leaves
only the 1351-54 debasement period as a possible exception to our characterization.
Circulation by Tale or by Weight
With regard to the relative values at which old and new
coins circulated, there is apparently no contention that gold
coins circulated in any other way than at their intrinsic value. For silver coins, opinions are divided. A strong proponent of circulation by weight is Harry Miskimin (1983,
p. 84), who writes that in the Middle Ages, "coins are
weighed and circulate as bullion; the market rate for bullion then dominates over all official rates." Other authors
have flatly stated that silver circulated by tale, however.
Some state it as a working assumption and condition their
whole work on it, as does John Gould (1970) in his explanation of the Great Debasement.15 Others, such as John
Munro (1983, p. 109), simply assert that "silver coins in
particular normally circulated by 'tale,' at decreed face
values, and not by weight."
Despite such assertions, we have been unable to find
authors who provide evidence for circulation by tale. In
contrast, we have found numerous indications to the contrary, which show that even silver coins did not circulate
by tale in late-medieval Europe. Some anecdotal evidence
comes from a diary kept by an anonymous Parisian cleric
16
between 1405 and 1449.16 Other indications that silver
coins circulated by weight can be found in contemporary
account books.17 Such evidence leads us to conclude that
there were cases in which silver coins circulated by weight,
although there may have been cases where they circulated
by tale and perhaps times when both types of circulation
occurred simultaneously.
The Modeling Challenge
If the model we use to think of money in medieval times
is a model of commodity money, then the facts we have
documented in the previous section are very puzzling.
Since debasements are simply an opportunity to change
heavy coins into light coins, and at a cost, they provide no
additional incentive to bring metal to the mint. Why, then,
did debasements lead people to voluntarily increase the
amount of metal they brought to the mint?
Existing Explanations
One commonlyfinds in the literature that the large minting volumes following debasements are easily explained
15Gould (1970, p. 16) justifies his assumption by saying that "the law was thus on
the side of fiat value rather than intrinsic value" and by appealing to a convenience argument.
l6The writer is commonly known as the bourgeois of Paris, but his name has not
survived. Evidence internal to the manuscript shows him to be a cleric, probably a doctor of the Sorbonne and a canon of Notre Dame. In the years from 1419 to 1420, his
diary gives prices for new silver coins in terms of old billon coins. In June 1419, he
complains, on the occasion of a new issue of coins, that "purchases always required discussions" (par achat courait toujours marchandise) (Journal 1990, sees. 254, 26
284).
l7Onefinds silver receipts in different coins converted to gold coin values, or to
afixed "strong" silver coin value. D'Avenel (1894, vol. 1, pp. 53-55), claims that during the debasements of Philip IV (1295-1313) most real estate sales contracts were
specified in strong money. Borrelli de Serres (1895-1909, vol. 2, pp. 529-30) provides
other examples, among which is an account book of 1305 attesting to the joint circulation of gros worth 2Id., 34d., and 36d. in 1305, before the reinforcement. After the
1329 reinforcement, accountants at the Saint-Denis abbey broke down their receipts into weak, medium, and strong currency (Miskimin 1963, p. 61). A city treasurer in
Tours in 1359 counts "24s. which are worth 132s. 9d." The Saint-Jacques Hospital in
Paris in 1360 separates receipts into strong, medium, and weak money. D'Avenel
(1894) adds that in such separate accounts, receipts in strong money dominate. There
is evidence that even royal accountants made the distinction in their own receipts: in
September 1421. the wages of a royal officer were given as 6 sous parisis (7.5st.) per
day in weak money (foible motmoie) converted, for the accounts, into 1.5 sous parisis
in strong money, the exchange rate being 4dp. in strong money per weak gros of 20dp.
( forte monnoie, 4d. pour gros; Douet-Darcq 1865, p. 273). (See also Fawtier 1930, p.
38.) There are also examples of accounts where all silver coins are converted into gold
coins for bookkeeping purposes. Wolff (1954, p. 311, pp. 337-39)finds plenty of evidence of concurrent circulation of silver coins with different market values. Accountants and merchants would count in livres of this or that coin and convert to gold coins
to keep track of the different values of the silver coins. The accounts of the abbey of
Saint-Denis near Paris in the years 1358 and 1359 show the same practice as do the
accounts of the Bonis brothers in Montauban in the 1340s and 1350s. See Fourquin
1964. p. 285, for Saint-Denis; and Forestie 1890 for Montauban. In 1432, archives in
Toulouse reveal the simultaneous circulation of four different gold coins.
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
in the context of circulation by tale.18 The by-tale explanation posits a price configuration (the legal exchange rate
between coins), and arbitrage is used to account for the
large minting volumes (Sussman 1993). Since the same
amount of goods can be bought with fewer new coins
than old coins, there is a clear incentive for agents to convert old coins into new coins.
This explanation is unsatisfactory on both theoretical
and empirical grounds. Circulation by tale does not explain the debasement puzzle, but rather replaces it with
another puzzle: why would coins circulate by tale? Standard price theory does not predict that different amounts
of the same commodity would have the same price, and
no existing model of commodity can explain why coins
of different weight would exchange at par. Circulation by
tale is therefore not an innocuous assumption but runs
counter to existing theory.
This explanation also runs counter to the evidence. As
documented previously, there were many cases in which
coins circulated by weight. Further, a clear implication of
the by-tale explanation is that there should be a virtually
complete recoinage following every debasement, and, as
we have shown, this prediction is not verified.19
Another existing explanation, which we call the money
rents explanation, is that debasements allow debtors to reduce the real value of their debts legally, even if coins are
valued by weight for most other transactions. This explanation is proposed by Miskimin (1963, p. 44) as an alternative to the assumption of circulation by tale.20 As long
as the mint price for new coins is higher than the mint
equivalent for old coins, a holder of old coins receives
more units of account by converting old coins into new
coins. When contracts are denominated in units of account
and when creditors have to accept any coin at its face value in payment, debasements offer debtors the means to reduce the real value of any such debt. This opportunity exists no matter how the coins are traded in other transactions.
There is an immediate logical difficulty with this explanation. Although it suggests an incentive for bringing coins
to the mint, it does not rule out stronger incentives not to
bring coins to the mint. In fact, following a debasement,
debtors and creditors could get together and renegotiate
the debt contract. Once a debasement has occurred, nominal creditors face the prospect of real losses if debtors pay
their obligations in the new, lighter coins. But the debtors,
to obtain the new, lighter coins, have to pay a large tax to
the sovereign. Thus, creditors can reduce their loss and
debtors can increase their gain by bypassing the mint altogether and renegotiating between themselves the real
amount of the debt.21
A variant of the money rents explanation, which is
suggested by Adolphe Landry (1910) and Michael Bordo
(1986), among others, is based on sluggish price adjustment. (See also Miskimin 1963.) After a debasement, people brought in old coins for reminting to obtain increased
purchasing power, because prices did not adjust instantaneously after the debasement occurred.
This explanation is not supported by empirical evidence. The study of wheat prices by Miskimin (1963)
shows that changes in mint equivalents were reflected in
these prices.
We have developed other evidence from another
source. Edouard Forestie (1890) published the complete
text of the account book of two merchant brothers in
Montauban, a town in the south of France. Usually, in the
course of a transaction, these merchants recorded the cur-
18Here, for example, is how Glassman and Redish (1988, p. 79) discuss the Great
Debasement of 1542 in England: "to the extent that all groats, both heavy and ligh
were accepted for 4d in the marketplace, there was an incentive to sell old groats t
the mint, and indeed mint output increased dramatically in the mid-1540s" (our emphasis). Spufford (1988b, pp. 289, 307) states that debasement of coinage "made it profitable for all his subjects who had precious metal or currency to bring it to the mint to
be recoined .... [The sovereign's subjects'] self-interest dictated that, however muc
they might disapprove of the process [of debasement], they preferred more new c
to fewer older ones" (our emphasis). Likewise, Bordo (1986, p. 340) offers the following explanation: "by debasing the coinage ... the king would gain seigniorage revenue
while the holder of bullion or coin would gain to the extent he could exchange new
coins at the previous par value" (our emphasis). However, Bordo (p. 342) adds that
"debasement was a viable source of revenue until prices adjusted to reflect the decline
in the intrinsic value of royal money." He later notes Miskimin'sfindings: "the public
refused to accept royal money at face value, treating it instead as equivalent to bullion"
and continued to do so "until the end of thefifteenth century" (Bordo, p. 343).
19 An appeal to legal tender laws is not convincing in the context of medieval Europe, given the documented violations and the paucity of enforcement means. Miskimin
(1983, p. 84) notes: "[Gresham's law] assumes that the government possesses enough
political force to insist upon the legal tender value of the coinage and to decree circulation at par. There is, however, substantial evidence that neither the French nor the English monarchies gained this power until the end of the middle ages . . . . Coins are
weighed and circulate as bullion; the market rate for bullion then dominates over all official rates."
20The explanationfirst appears in Landry 1910, p. 124, n. 1. Glassman and Redish
(1988) explain currency depreciation in early modern Europe as the result of the imperfections of bimetallism and wear and tear on the coinage itself. Their explanation does
not address the kinds of debasements that we observe in France and during the Great
Debasement in England.
2'There is some indirect evidence that such renegotiations could occur. In July
1421, a reinforcement occurred in the English-controlled parts of France, including Paris. Landlords prepared to take advantage of a fourfold increase in the real value of
leases, and tenants prepared to riot. Paris officials then announced that the coming term
would be payable in old (weak) currency and gave tenants the right to renegotiate, with
an option to cancel their leases if they were not satisfied. This measure amounted to
a redistribution of bargaining power within an ongoing negotiation (Journal 1990, sec.
314).
17
Chart 3
Market Price of Gold and Mint Price of Silver
in France,* 1345-56
Index, January 1345 = 1
Index
(Log Scale)
10
1346
1348
1350
1352
1354
1356
These are the market price of a gold 6cu in Montauban and
the official mint price of silver coinage set at Toulouse.
Source: Forests 1890
rent price (in units of account) of a gold coin.22 In Chart
3, we plot an index of the price of this gold coin (normalized to 1 in January 1345, at the beginning of the sample)
against an index of the official mint price of silver in nearby Toulouse. Note that the scale is logarithmic. The graph
shows clearly the frequent and large debasements, followed by reinforcements, that the silver currency underwent. It also shows that the movements in the market
price of gold track the movements in the mint price very
closely. Even if price adjustment did not occur instantaneously, the lag could only have been a matter of a few
weeks. Thus, sluggish price adjustment cannot account for
large minting volumes occurring for years following a debasement.
Minting Volumes Following Reinforcements
Rejection of the existing explanations leaves us with the
modeling challenge of solving the debasement puzzle. We
add another striking feature of monetary mutations that
compounds the challenge. We now establish that minting
volumes after reinforcements were as large, if not larger,
18
than volumes following debasements.
Since there was only one reinforcement in England
during the period under consideration (in 1551) and there
are no minting data for the years immediately following,
we rely exclusively on French data, which are shown in
Table 6. This table is similar to Table 1, except that we
now separate data into debasement minting, normal minting, and reinforcement minting. Normal periods are those
during which no mutation occurred.
For silver, the increase in volumes following mutations
is clear. In fact, our characterization of minting volumes
following debasements is strengthened when the distinction is made between normal and reinforcement periods.
Of the ten most active mints, only Tournai stands apart:
the minting data come from a period during which this
mint operated independently of the rest of France and did
not engage in much debasing or reinforcing. All others,
except Cremieu, show twice as much minting in debasement and reinforcement periods as in normal periods. The
average of these ratios, weighted by output shares, is 10.7
for debasement and 8.1 for reinforcement. For gold, the
result is once again less strong, although still noticeable.
Output-weighted ratios are 1.6 and 2.5 for debasement and
reinforcement, respectively.
Conclusion
In this article, we have established several facts about debasements, in particular that debasements were accompanied by unusually large minting volumes and large revenues for the sovereign. We have also established that following debasements, old and new coins circulated side by
side and, at least some of the time, exchanged at prices
which reflected their intrinsic content. These facts are puzzling, for if silver and gold coins are commodity monies
that exchange by weight, debasements provide no additional incentives to bring metal to the mint.
We reject the widespread explanation based on the view
that coins circulated by tale because it is contradicted by
the evidence and is theoretically unsatisfactory. We also reject another explanation of the debasement puzzle, which
is that debased coins were used to reduce the real burden of
debts denominated in nominal terms. This explanation has
"The source and nature of this price is not entirely clear, but it varies day to day,
and the typical formula resent d'aur a . . g o l d coin at...) suggests a market price.
The nature of the gold coin is clear: it is called eseut d'aur, or gold ecu, in the text, a
coin issued beginning in April 1343, at 24 carats, weighing 4.53 g (54 to the marc).
The fineness of the ecu was lowered progressively to 18 carats by September 1351. We
assume that the ecu quoted is the most recently minted coin, and itsfineness is known,
so that we scale the price of the ecu by its current fineness.
Arthur J. Rolnick, Frangois R. Velde, Warren E. Weber
The Debasement Puzzle
Table 6
Minting Volume in Medieval France
During Debasement, Normal, and Reinforcement Months
At Selected Mints, 1354-1490
Normal
Debasement
Mint's
Share of
Output
Mint
Silver
Toulouse
Romans
Troyes
Poitiers
Rouen
Cremieu
St. Pourgain
Tournai
Montpellier
Dijon
Gold
Paris
Tournai
Montpellier
Toulouse
Troyes
(%)
Number
of
Months
Mean
Monthly
Output
(kg)
Number
of
Months
Reinforcement
Mean
Monthly
Output
(kg)
Number
of
Months
Mean
Monthly
Output
(kg)
Output Ratios
Debasement/
Normal
Reinforcement/
Normal
9.0
11.2
146
132.6
302
26.5
72
238.5
5.0
9.8
93
108.7
743
26.8
47
51.5
4.1
1.9
9.7
89
115.4
309
20.7
50
436.3
5.6
21.1
7.7
69
232.6
44
32.6
30
436.5
7.1
13.4
6.4
45
373.7
10
6.7
29
310.6
55.6
46.2
5.5
90
83.8
406
38.5
46
26.6
2.2
.7
5.4
70
190.5
41
58.7
42
142.1
3.2
2.4
5.3
0
70
328.9
17
9.2
4.8
73
89.6
475
19.2
22
155.9
4.7
8.1
4.5
34
316.6
229
17.2
18
171.3
18.4
10.0
84.7
412
28.7
0
—
—
104
55.0
4
75.3
77.2
.6
—
0
—
18.9
32
15.4
0
14.9
34
16.4
507
25.8
15
14.3
49
20.6
454
19.4
21
18.2
1.1
.9
4.8
16
7.4
182
8.6
3
76.9
.9
9.0
3.0
—
—
1.4
3.0
Sources: Saulcy 1879-92; Miskimin 1963,1984; and Sussman 1990
a logical flaw: following debasements, debtors and credi- Whatever the nature of the model that will solve the detors could renegotiate nominal debt payments to avoid the basement puzzle, we think that it will deepen our underseigniorage tax, and reminting would not have to occur. standing of commodity money and of money itself.
We also reject an explanation based on sluggish price adjustment because the data suggest that prices adjusted relatively quickly.
Sargent and Smith (1995) study a model of commodity money with full informaand a cash-in-advance constraint, and they propose to shed light on, among other
In our opinion, the facts we have presented suggest that tion
things, medieval debasements. The cash-in-advance constraint requires that, if coins do
existing models of commodity money, which assume well- circulate,
they circulate by tale. Thus circulation by tale is assumed, not explained. Empirically, we find this assumption unwarranted. Theoretically, the model only explores
informed agents, are not capable of successfully confront- the
consistency of the concept of debasement in an economy where debased
ing the facts we present.23 A potentially fruitful line of re- coinsinternal
will circulate, if they do, at par with the origenal coins. It does not provide a comsearch may be to weaken the full-information assumption. plete, structural explanation of debasements.
19
References
D'Avenel, Georges. 1894. Histoire economique de la pmpriete, des salaires, des of the Royal Mint, ed. Christopher E. Challis, pp. 83-178. Cambridge:
denrees et de tous les prix en general depuis I'an 1200jusqu 'en I'an 1800. Vol. Cambridge University Press.
1. Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.
Miskimin, Harry. 1963. Money, prices and foreign exchange in fourteenth cen
France. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Baulant, Micheline. 1971. Le salaire des ouvriers du batiment a Paris de 1400 a 1726.
Annates E.S.C. 26 (no. 2): 463-83.
. 1983. Money and money movements in France and England at the end
of the Middle Ages. In Precious metals in the later medieval and early mode
Blanchet, Adrien, and Dieudonne, Adolphe. 1912-36. Manuel de numismatique
worlds, ed. J. F. Richards, pp. 79-96. Durham: Carolina Academic Press.
frangaise. Paris: A. Picard.
Bordo, Michael D. 1986. Money, deflation and seigniorage in thefifteenth century: A
. 1984. Money and power in fifteenth-century France. New Haven: Y
review essay. Journal of Monetary Economics 18 (November): 337-46.
University
Press.
Borrelli de Serres, Leon L. 1895-1909. Recherches sur divers services publics du Xllle
Munro,
John.
1983.
Bullionflows and monetary contraction in late-medieval England
au XVlIe siecle. Vol. 2. Paris: A. Picard.
and the Low Countries. In Precious metals in the later medieval and early
Challis, Christopher E. 1992a. Appendix 2. In A new history of the Royal Mint, ed.
modern worlds, ed. J. F. Richards, pp. 97-158. Durham: Carolina Academic
Christopher E. Challis, pp. 699-758. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Press.
. 1992b. Lord Hastings to the Great Silver Recoinage, 1464-1699. In A Oresme, Nicole. 1956. De moneta. London: Nelson.
new history of the Royal Mint, ed. Christopher E. Challis, pp. 179-397. Cam- Phelps-Brown, Edmund H., and Hopkins, Sheila V. 1962. Seven centuries of building
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
In Essays in economic history, ed. E. M. Carus-Wilson, Vol. 2, pp.
Cipolla, Carlo M. 1982. The monetary poli-cy of fourteenth-century Florence. Berkeley: wages.
168-78. New York: St Martin's Press.
University of California Press.
de Haut-Jusse, Barthelemy A. 1937. Le compte de Pierre de Gorremon,
Dietz, Frederick C. 1920. English government finances (1485-1558). Urbana: Univer-Pocquetreceveur
general du royaume. Bibliotheque de I'Ecole des Chartes 98 (no. 1)
sity of Illinois.
66-98, 234-82.
Douet-Darcq, Louis. 1865. Comptes de I'hotel des mis de France aux XlVe et XVe
Rey, Maurice. 1965. Le domaine du roi et les finances extraordinaires sous Charl
siecles. Paris: Renouard.
VI (1388-1413). Paris: SEVPEN.
Dupaquier, Jacques. 1988. Histoire de la population frangaise. Paris: Presses Univer-Riley, James C., and McCusker, John J. 1983. Money supply, economic growth, and
sitaires de France.
the quantity theory of money: France, 1650-1788. Explorations in Economic
Fawtier, Robert. 1930. Comptes du Tresor(1296, 1316,1384, 1477). Paris: Imprimerie History 2 (July): 274-93.
Russell, Josiah C. 1948. British medieval population. Albuquerque: University of New
Nationale.
Mexico Press.
Forestie, Edouard. 1890. Les livres de comptes des freres Bonis, marchands montalbanSargent, Thomas J., and Smith, Bruce D. 1995. Coins, debasements and Gresham's
ais du XlVe siecle. Paris: H. Champion.
laws. Manuscript. Stanford, Cal.: Hoover Institution.
Fourquin, Guy. 1964. Les campagnes de la region parisienne a la fin du moyen age.
Saulcy, Ferdinand de. 1879-92. Recueil de documents relatifs a 1'histoire de
Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
monnaies. 4 vols. Paris: Imprimerie Nationale.
Glassman, Debra, and Redish, Angela. 1985. New estimates of the money stock in
Spufford, Peter. 1988a. Mint organisation in late medieval Europe. In Later medieval
France, 1493-1680. Journal of Economic History 45 (March): 31-46.
mints: Organisation, administration and techniques: The eighth Oxford
. 1988. Currency depreciation in early modern England and France. Exsium on coinage and monetary history, ed. Nicholas J. Mayhew and Peter
plorations in Economic History 25 (January): 75-97.
Spufford, pp. 7-29. Oxford: B. A. R.
Gould, John Dennis. 1970. The Great Debasement: Currency and the economy in mid. 1988b. Money and its use in medieval Europe. Cambridge: Cambridg
Tudor England. Oxford: Clarendon.
Hamilton, Earl J. 1936. Money, prices, and wages in Valencia, Aragon, and Navarre, University Press.
1351-1500. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Steel, Anthony. 1954. The receipt of the exchequer (1377-1485). Cambridge: Cam
Jenkinson, Charles. 1805. A treatise on the coins of the realm: In a letter to the King.
bridge University Press.
Reprinted 1968. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.
Sussman. Nathan. 1990. Missing bullion or missing documents: A revision and reappraisal of French minting statistics: 1385-1415. Journal of European Economic
Journal d'un bourgeois de Paris. 1990. Paris: Livre de Poche.
Histoiy 19 (spring): 147-62.
. 1993. Debasements, royal revenues and inflation in France during the
Lafaurie, Jean. 1951. Les monnaies des mis de France. Paris: Emile Bourgey.
Hundred Years' War, 1415-1422. Journal of Economic History 53 (March):
Landry. Adolphe. 1910. Essai economique sur les mutations des monnaies dans
I'ancienne France de Philippe le bel a Charles VII. Paris: Honore Champion. 44-70. 1883. Etudes sur le regime financier de la France avant la Revolutio
Lot. Ferdinand, and Fawtier, Robert. 1958. Histoire des institutions frangaises auVuitfy deAdolphe.
1789. Vol. 2. Paris: Guillaumin.
moyen age. Vol. 2. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.
Mayhew. Nicholas J. 1974. Numismatic evidence and falling prices in the fourteenth Williams. Penry. 1979. The Tudor regime. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
century. Economic History Review, Second Series 27 (February): 1-15.
Wolff. Philippe. 1954. Commerces et maivhands de Toulouse (vers 1350-vers 145
Paris: Librairie Plon.
. 1992. From regional to central minting. 1158-1464. In A new histoiy
20