No 2015-19 – October
Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
The effect of servitization
on manufacturing firm performance
Matthieu Crozet & Emmanuel Milet
Highlights
In 2007, about 70% of the French manufacturing firms produced some services for third parties. This share
is growing over time.
These servitized firms are larger (in terms of total production and employment), produce more goods and
are more profitable.
There is a causal impact of servitization on firm performance: Firms that start selling services experience an
increase in their profitability, employment, total sales and sales of goods.
These positive effects of servitization strategies are mainly visible for small businesses.
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in service?
Abstract
The servitization of the manufacturing sector refers to the evolution of manufacturers' capabilities to offer services
as a complement to or a substitute for the goods that they produce. A vast literature has described these strategies
and has shown that this phenomenon is widespread and growing in most developed economies. However, very little
systematic evidence of the extent or consequences of servitization based on a comprehensive dataset of firms exists.
In this paper, we provide such evidence using exhaustive data for French manufacturing firms between 1997 and
2007. We find that the vast majority of French manufacturers sell services in addition to producing goods. The shift
toward services is growing steadily but at a slow pace. We also provide evidence of a causal impact of servitization
on firm performance. Controlling for various sources of endogeneity bias, we find that firms that start selling services
experience an increase in their profitability between 3.7% and 5.3%, increase their employment by 30%, increase
their total sales by 3.7%, and increase their sales of goods by 3.6%. The results hold for most industries, although
some heterogeneity exists.
Keywords
Servitization,Deindustrialisation,Firm performance.
JEL
L23, L25, L6.
Working Paper
CEPII (Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et
d’Informations Internationales) is a French institute
dedicated to producing independent, policyoriented economic research helpful to understand
the international economic environment
and challenges in the areas of trade policy,
competitiveness, macroeconomics, international
finance and growth.
CEPII Working Paper
Contributing to research in international
economics
© CEPII, PARIS, 2015
All rights reserved. Opinions expressed
in this publication are those of the
author(s) alone.
Editorial Director:
Sébastien Jean
Production:
Laure Boivin
No ISSN: 1293-2574
CEPII
113, rue de Grenelle
75007 Paris
+33 1 53 68 55 00
www.cepii.fr
Press contact: presse@cepii.fr
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Should everybody be in services?
The eect of servitization on manufacturing rm performance
Matthieu Crozet
and Emmanuel Milet
y
There are no such thing as service industries.
There are only industries whose service components
are greater or less than those of other industries.
Everybody is in services.
Theodore Levitt (1972).
1.
Introduction
The servitization of the manufacturing sector refers to the evolution of manufacturers
capabilities to oer services, as a complement to or a substitute for the goods they
produce.
This trend is not recent and has been identied and documented since the
1980s (Vandermerwe and Rada, 1988). It is observed in all OECD countries and also in
developing countries (Pilat et al., 2006; Neely et al., 2011). Examples of manufacturing
rms selling services are numerous: from small businesses oering repair and after-sales
services to Rolls Royce, which made power by the hour a package of support services
1 or Apple, whose strategy is to oer
2
to consumers an ecosystem combining physical devices with online services.
for aircraft engines a core element of its strategy,
The deeper integration of the production of goods and services is highly relevant for policymakers in high-income countries who worry about the decline of manufacturing production
and employment in their economies.
3 Economic analyses based on a representation of the
economy as a collection of independent sectors often view the decline of the manufacturing sector as an ineluctable shift of resources toward the services sector (Baumol, 1967;
Ngai and Pissarides, 2007; Acemoglu and Guerrieri, 2008). However, this representation
as well as the ensuing industrial policies neglect the fact that the boundary between manufacturing and services is very blurry
4 and that complementarity between services and
manufacturing may be key to economic success.
Univ Paris Sud, Universite Paris-Saclay and CEPI, (matthieu.crozet@cepii.fr)
y University of Geneva, (emmanuel.milet@unige.ch)
1 Rolls-Royce
earns its keep not just by making world-class engines, but by selling power by the hour" a
complex of services and manufacturing that keeps its customers' engines burning. If it did not sell services,
Rolls-Royce could not earn enough money from selling engines", The Economist (Jan. 8th, 2009).
2 Between
2002 and 2010, Apple sold over 206 million iPods and over one billion songs through the iTunes
Music Store (Benedettini et al., 2010).
3A
recent report by the European Commission argues that European Commission (2014) A digital tran-
sition is underway across the global economy and industrial policy needs to integrate new technological
opportunities such as cloud computing, big data and data value chain developments, new industrial applications of internet, smart factories, robotics, 3-D printing and design.
4A
fact underlined decades ago by Stigler (1956): There exists no authoritative consensus on either the
boundaries or the classication of the service industries.
increasing importance of the services sector.
1
See Fuchs (1968) for an early discussion of the
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Of course, the shift toward services has important consequences for rms; it aects their
business models and how they approach consumers (Oliva and Kallenberg, 2003; Reinartz
and Ulaga, 2008; Cusumano et al., 2015).
This shift also provides a way to restore
5 Wise and Baumgartner
manufacturers' competitiveness in both local and global markets.
(1999) argue that Downstream [service] markets oer important benets besides large
new sources of revenue. They tend to have higher margins and to require fewer assets
than product manufacturing.
And because they tend to provide steady service-revenue
streams, they're often countercyclical.
Clearly, in manufacturing today, the real money
lies downstream, not in the production function.
Previous studies of the consequences of servitization have identied various channels
through which rms can benet from this strategy.
Servitization can enable rms to
dierentiate their product from those of their competitors (Baines et al., 2009), increase
customer loyalty (Baines and Lightfoot, 2013), and lead to higher market values (Fang
et al., 2008) or higher protability (Neely, 2008; Suarez et al., 2013; Visnjic et al., 2014).
However, little systematic and robust evidence of the impact of servitization on rm performance exists, and this question remains controversial. Prior research has shown that
most of the expected benets of servitization (higher revenues, higher protability) does
not materialize in many cases.
6 Furthermore, most of the available empirical evidence is
based on rm-level case studies or a limited sample of relatively large rms. These approaches have the advantage of allowing in-depth analysis of the business strategies and
channels through which servitization operates.
However, they lack the general validity
that would allow inferences to be drawn from their results. Our paper is complementary
to the existing literature in this regard. Our study is based on a comprehensive sample
of rms, which covers all manufacturing sectors and naturally includes a large proportion of micro and small businesses. Our data contains detailed balance sheet information
for more than 50,000 servitized and non-servitized French manufacturing rms over the
19972007 period. A key feature of our database is that it provides information on the
sales (to third parties) of goods and services separately. This very large database allows
the precise quantication of the evolution of the servitization of French manufacturing
over the course of a decade; it also oers a means to estimate the causal impact of
servitization on rm performance precisely, controlling for self-selection eects and other
sources of endogeneity bias.
5 Cusumano
et al. (2015) distinguish between services that are oered as complements to the product sold
by the rm and those that are substitutes. Within complementary services, they further distinguish between
smoothing services whose purpose is to ease the purchase of the product (nancing, insurance, basic
training) and adapting services whose purpose is to alter the good to the specic needs of customers.
While smoothing services can easily be standardized, adapting services are highly customized as the
knowledge required to provide the service is dicult to separate from detailed knowledge of the product
itself .
The Power by the Hour Rolls Royce product is an example of services that substitute for the
purchase of the good. Customers buy the use of the engine rather than the engine itself, while Rolls Royce
ensures that it is functional at any time.
6 This
service paradox is described by (Gebauer et al., 2005) as follows: Most product manufacturers
are confronted with the following phenomenon: Companies which invest heavily in extending their service
business, increase their service oerings and incur higher costs, but this does not result in the expected
correspondingly higher returns. Because of increasing costs and a lack of corresponding returns, the growth
in service revenue fails to meet its intended objectives. We term this phenomenon the `service paradox' in
manufacturing companies. Visnjic et al. (2014) argue that the service paradox is likely to arise when rms
move from product-related services to customer-oriented services.
2
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
The empirical literature has typically found an ambiguous relationship between servitization
and rm performance. Fang et al. (2008) use data on 477 publicly listed manufacturing
companies and nd a U-shaped relationship between the share of services of total sales
and rm market value.
Benedettini et al. (2013) analyze the characteristics of about
200 manufacturing rms from the manufacturing sector.
After controlling for rm age
and size, they nd a negative correlation between the number of services oered by rms
and their survival probability.
Eggert et al. (2011) examine 414 German companies in
the mechanical engineering industry and link product innovation and servitization to rm
protability.
They nd that when combined with product innovation, oering services
supporting the product leads to higher protability.
Finally, the work closest to ours in
terms of data and methodology is the analysis provided by Suarez et al. (2013).
They
look at the eect of servitization on operating prots using a sample of slightly fewer than
400 rms in the prepackaged software products industry and nd a convex relationship
between the share of services of total sales and overall operating margins.
Their study
covers a longer period than ours (19902006), but it is limited to one industry. We depart
from several features of their analysis. First, we use a large sample of French rms that
covers all manufacturing industries and allows us to assess how the impact of servitization
varies by industry and type of rm. Second, we focus on the shift toward services rather
than on the degree of servitization. Indeed, our results indicate that rm performance is
mainly aected by the decision to engage in the provision of services rather than by their
importance relative to total sales.
Third, we look at several measures of performance:
protability, employment, total sales, and production sales of goods. This latter indicator
of performance leads to us to discuss the complementarity or substitutability of goods
and services.
Fourth, thanks to the detailed nature of our data, we can implement a
very precise micro-econometric estimation strategy, which addresses self-selection bias
and reverse causality.
Finally, our contribution is twofold.
First, we exploit our comprehensive database to
document the extent of servitization in the French manufacturing sector. We show that
in all French manufacturing industries, the share of services of total sales has increased
substantially between 1997 and 2007. This increase is driven by two components: faster
growth among servitized rms and a tendency for each rm to increase its share of services
of total sales. Second, we assess the causal eect of engaging in services sales on rm
performance.
We explicitly tackle unobserved heterogeneity using a lagged dependent
variable (LDV) model and reverse causality issues using instrumental variables. We nd
that rms that start selling services experience a signicant boost in their protability,
ranging between 3.7% and 5.3%.
Their employment increases by 30%, total sales by
3.7%, and sales of goods by 3.6%. These results hold for most industries, although some
heterogeneity exists. Additionally, these results are primarily driven by small and medium
enterprises, while the estimation for a sample of large rms produces less signicant results.
In the next section, we describe the dataset. We then describe the change in servitization
in French manufacturing industries in section 3.
In section 4, we present our empirical
strategy and our results. We conclude in section 5.
3
CEPII Working Paper
2.
Should everybody be in services?
Data
We use rm-level information from the BRN (Bénéce Réels Normaux) database. The
database is compiled by the French scal authority (Direction Générale des Impôts) and
provides rm information such as employment, value added, capital stock, prots, investments, industry classication, and geographic location. Of particular interest for this
paper, the BRN dataset reports detailed information on rm sales. Individual sales are split
into three mutually exclusive categories: sales of production of goods, sales of production
of services and sales of merchandise (goods purchased and sold without transformation).
Note that these are sales to third parties, i.e., to consumers outside of the rm.
7 It is
important to note that in this paper, we are interested in the servitization of French manufacturing rms, i.e., in the fact that manufacturing rms sell services to third parties.
We are not interested in the production of services for own accounts.
8 Our data cover
the 19972007 period. The raw dataset provides information on 67,385 manufacturing
rms. The average rm employs 55 workers and generates a turnover of
e12
million.
This dataset is very large, but individual data are noisy and sometimes report values that
we consider highly dubious. For instance, some rms change their industry classication
every year, moving from one 2-digit sector to another. This complicates the design of an
appropriate control group, as we want to compare rms operating in the same industry.
The dataset also contains information on rms that report no production, no value added,
or no employment. To cope with these issues, we trim the data based on several factors.
First, we keep rms reporting strictly positive sales, employment or value added.
step reduces the size of the dataset quite substantially.
This
Second, we select those rms
whose capital to labor ratio and value added per worker are not greater than a hundred
times the median ratio in their industry.
9 We are left with 50,530 manufacturing rms.
In this sample, the average rm employs 60 workers and has total sales of approximately
e13
million.
In our sample of manufacturing rms, 76% report selling some services.
These rms
account for approximately 90% of the total value added and employment in our sample.
Among the rms that report positive sales of services, 22% report more sales of services
than sales of (produced) goods, and 12% report only selling services. There are several
explanations for these two somewhat surprising facts.
Some rms may be misclassied
and registered as manufacturing rms although their main activity is services. Other rms
may have given up the production of goods to focus on the provision of services while
still selling goods that they buy from other rms.
7 The
It is important to note that French
dataset does not provide information on the type of service sold by rms. Services and product sales
are indistinctly exports or domestic sales. Note that for rms that belong to a group, they can be sales to
other aliates or to subsidiaries of the group.
8 Lodefalk
(2013) considers the purchase and the production of services in Swedish manufacturing rms
over the 19752005 period.
9 Firms
report such extreme values of these ratios for two reasons. The rst obvious reason is misreporting;
the second is related to how rms manage their capital. Consider the following example: For tax purposes,
a rm may decide to create an entity whose only purpose is to own its real estate assets. In this setting,
the rst rm is producing goods and employing workers but appears to have little or no capital. The second
rm, which is entirely linked to the rst, has a (potentially large) capital stock with few (if any) workers.
Depending on how the boundaries of the rms are dened, we are left with two apparently distinct entities,
both with capital to labor ratios that do not actually reect the activities of the rm.
4
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
rms are not automatically reclassied when their main activity changes partly because
collective labor agreements are dened at the sector level, which can make reclassication
costly and cumbersome for both employers and employees. To better describe this dual
activity of French manufacturing rms, we dene the service intensity of a rm as the
share of services of total production sales. The service intensity ranges from 0 (pure goods
producers) to 1 (pure services producers). In gure 1, we present the kernel distribution
of service intensity (on a log scale) for the manufacturing rms in our sample in 1997 and
2007. The striking feature of this distribution is its bi-modality. This feature is present in
10
both years and is observed in each manufacturing industry (see gure 2).
Most of manufacturing rms are mainly goods producers (they produce and sell more
goods than services).
In 2007, rms with a service intensity below 50% accounted for
84% of the rms in our sample and for 90% of both value added and employment. Figure 1
also reveals that the distribution remained quite stable between 1997 and 2007.
Density (log scale)
2
4
6 810
Figure 1 Distribution of the Service Intensity (share of services of production sales)
for French Manufacturing Firms in 2007
0
.2
.4
.6
Share of services in total output
1997
.8
1
2007
To dig deeper into the changes in the distribution of service intensity over time, we
computed a transition matrix between 1997 and 2007 (see table 8 in the appendix). In
this table, we retained a constant sample of rms and allocated them to bins based on
their initial service intensity in 1997 and their service intensity in 2007. To understand how
to interpret the gures reported in the table, let us consider the rst row of the table: We
nd the share of rms that had a service intensity of exactly 0% in 1997. Adding all shares
reported in this row, the table indicates that this was the case for 22% of the rms in our
sample. By 2007, a majority of these rms (11.98% of the total sample) remained fully
10 Our
database covers 21 2-digit industries. In the econometric analyses presented in sections 3 and 4, we
systematically control for 2-digit industry xed eects. However, to facilitate the exposition, we group the
2-digit industries into 7 broad categories.
5
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Density (log scale)
5
1015
Figure 2 Distribution of the Service Intensity by Industry in 2007
0
.2
.4
.6
Share of services in total output
I
V
II
VI
.8
III
VII
1
IV
We grouped industries into large sectors using the NACE-Rev1 industry classication (indicated in parentheses). I: Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco (15, 16). II: Manufacture of textiles and
leather products (17, 18, 19).
III: Manufacture of wood and wood products; manufacture of pulp, paper
and paper products; publishing and printing (20, 21, 22).
IV: Manufacture of chemicals, chemical prod-
ucts and man-made bers; manufacture of rubber and plastic products (24, 25). V: Manufacture of other
non-metallic mineral products, basic metals and fabricated metal products (26, 27). VI: Manufacture of machinery, electrical, optical and transport equipment (29, 30, 31, 31, 33, 34, 35). VII: Manufacturing, n.e.c.
We omitted rms in the manufacture of coke, rened petroleum products and nuclear fuel industry (23), as
only 4 rms existed in 2007.
specialized in the production of goods, while the rest (about 10% of the total sample)
were selling some services in 2007.
Among the latter, a vast majority (7.42% of the
sample) had sales of services that accounted for less than 10% of their total production
sales. This is a salient feature of the matrix: Most rms do not change their production
mix much.
Approximately 60% of rms lie on the diagonal of the table.
Only 23% of
rms are located strictly above the diagonal, meaning that they substantially increased
their service intensity between 1997 and 2007, and only 17% of the rms decreased their
service intensity. Finally, very few rms completely changed their production mix during
this period: Only 3.5% of the rms moved from a low service intensity in 1997 (below
10%) to more than 90% of services in 2007 (0.25+1.30+0.42+1.57=3.54).
Together, gures 1 and 2 and table 8 convey the following message.
two distinct types of rms in the French manufacturing sector:
We encounter
Firms that are mainly
goods producers (with a service intensity below 50%) and those that are specialized in
the provision of services. The distribution of these two types of rms is quite stable over
time, and very few rms move from one type to another.
As the focus of this paper
is the production of services by manufacturers, we consider rms that are mainly good
producers (i.e., those that have always a service intensity below 50%). All rms that sell
6
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
more services than goods in at least one year are excluded from our sample. This leaves
us with a sample of 39,814 manufacturing rms, which remains quite similar to the raw
dataset.
In this sample of goods producers, the average rm employs 66 workers and
generates
e14 million in total sales.
The average rm in this sample is slightly larger than
in the raw dataset, although the dierence is not statistically dierent.
It is important
to notice that excluding rms with a share of services above 50% has no consequences
for our econometric analysis of the impact of servitization presented in section 4.
As
our identication strategy relies on rms switching from zero to positive sales of services,
rms with a service intensity above 50% typically provide services every single year in our
sample and thus do not contribute to the identication process.
3.
The servitization of French manufacturers
This section gives an overview of the degree of servitization of French manufacturing over
the decade from 1997 to 2007.
Table 1 Summary Statistics
All rms
(1)
# Firms
Servitized rms
1997
2007
97-07
1997
2007
97-07
25,660
22,675
-1.23
17,826
15,740
-1.24
69.4
69.4
1,443
1,274
86.9
89.9
Share (%)
(2)
Employment
Total (thousand)
1,661
1,417
-1.58
Share (%)
Average
(3)
Turnover
e,
Total (
million)
64.7
62.5
-0.35
80.9
81.0
+0.0
294.3
378.0
+2.53
261.0
350.2
+2.99
88.7
92.6
Share (%)
Average (
(4)
e,
thousand)
Production of goods
e,
Total (
million)
11.5
16.7
+3.81
14.6
22.3
+4.27
261.4
325.2
+2.21
229.0
298.0
+2.67
87.6
91.6
Share (%)
Average (
(5)
(6)
e,
10.2
14.3
+3.48
12.8
18.9
+3.95
Average (%)
47.44
49.0
+0.31
48.4
50.5
+0.42
Average (%)
3.1
3.2
+0.33
4.5
4.6
+0.34
Median (%)
0.5
0.6
+2.47
1.4
1.6
+1.76
0.07
0.07
0.08
0.08
Protability
thousand)
-1.23
Service intensity
Std. dev.
97-07
corresponds to the annualized growth rate between 1997 and 2007.
The sample is rms
producing mainly goods (i.e., whose service intensity is below 50% over the period). Servitized rms
report strictly positive sales of services.
In table 1, we present some descriptive statistics for the population of servitized and
11 In the left part of the table,
non-servitized French manufacturing rms in our sample.
11 All
these gures are computed from the sample of rms that are mostly producers of goods (i.e., those
7
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
we show statistics for servitized and non-servitized rms, and we restrict the sample to
servitized producers in the right part of the table.
The rst line illustrates the rapid
deindustrialization of French economy. Between 1997 and 2007, the number of rms in
our sample decreased by almost 12% (equivalent to an annual growth rate of -1.23%),
and the number of workers employed in our sample of manufacturing rms decreased by
14.7% (-1.58% per year). Table 1 also shows that servitized rms are, on average, larger
than pure manufacturers. In 2007, they employed 81 workers, on average, compared to
62.5 for pure manufacturers.
Servitized rms are also larger in terms of turnover, they
produce and sell more goods, and they are more protable. All these dierences will be
studied in detail in the next section.
Figure 3 better illustrates the extent of servitization across manufacturing industries, using
three dierent indicators.
Panel (a) shows the proportion of manufacturing rms that
produce services in 1997 and in 2007. It conrms that servitization is a quite common
strategy among French manufacturing rms:
Almost 70% of the rms in our sample
produce some services for third parties. This gure varies substantially by sector, ranging
from 54% in the food, beverage and tobacco industry to 88% in the chemical and plastic
products industry. The share of servitized rms has increased in every industry between
1997 and 2007, with the exception of the wood, paper and printing industry. While a very
large majority of rms are servitized in all industries, most of them sell very few services.
This pattern is visible in panel (b), which displays the average service intensity in each
industry. In 2007, the service intensity is equal to 3.2% for the manufacturing sector as
a whole.
Again, there is some heterogeneity across manufacturing industries.
For the
average rm in the food, beverage and tobacco industry, services account for 1.3% of
production sales, while they account for 5% in the mechanical and electrical equipment
industry (which here includes optical and transport equipment).
12 Finally, panel (c) shows
the importance of services to the total production of manufacturing industries. It reports
the average service intensity weighted by the production of each rm. These gures are, on
average, larger than those in panel (b), suggesting that larger rms have on average higher
levels of service intensity. In 2007, services accounted for 5.5% of the total production
sales of the manufacturing sector compared to 4.2% in 1997.
Services accounted for
around 2.5% of total production sales in the food, beverage and tobacco industry and up
to 8.1% of production sales in the mechanical and electrical equipment industry in 2007.
This measure of the scope of servitization shows a steady rise over the decade, as shown
in gure 4.
The gure displays the evolution of the weighted average service intensity
between 1997 and 2007 along with the share of employment at servitized rms.
We
take 1997 as the reference year, so the vertical axis can be read as growth rates.
The
weighted average service intensity was 30% larger in 2007 than in 1997, and the share of
employment at servitized rms grew by an average of 0.3% per year over the period.
with a service intensity below 50%). Table 7 in the appendix displays exactly the same statistics computed
from the complete sample of rms.
12 Logically,
retaining the (relatively few) rms that produce more services than goods in the sample greatly
changes the average level of service intensity but does not aect the median value much. For 2007, table 7
in the appendix reports an average service intensity of 23.1% and a median of 3.2%.
8
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Figure 3 The Extent of Servitization in French Manufacturing Industries
(a) Share of servitized rms
(b) Average service intensity (unweighted)
1-Food, Beverage, Tobacco
1-Food, Beverage, Tobacco
2-Textile, Leather
2-Textile, Leather
3-Wood, paper, printing
3-Wood, paper, printing
4-Chemical, plastics
4-Chemical, plastics
5-Mineral, metal products
5-Mineral, metal products
6-Mechanical & electrical equip.
6-Mechanical & electrical equip.
7-n.e.c.
7-n.e.c.
All manufacturing
All manufacturing
0
.2
.4
.6
2007
.8
0
.01
.02
1997
2007
(c) Share of services in industry production
1-Food, Beverage, Tobacco
2-Textile, Leather
3-Wood, paper, printing
4-Chemical, plastics
5-Mineral, metal products
6-Mechanical & electrical equip.
7-n.e.c.
All manufacturing
0
.02
.04
2007
.06
.08
1997
1
.99
1
1.1
1.01
1.2
1.02
1.3
1.03
1.4
1.04
Figure 4 Aggregate Servitization and Employment: 19972007
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
Average servitization - Weighted (left axis)
Employment in servitized firms (right axis)
2007
.03
.04
1997
.05
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
The global trend toward services shown in gure 4 contains two potential sources of
change: a generalized shift toward services in individual rms and a composition eect
due to the fact that rms with a high service intensity may grow faster than other rms.
We isolate the rst source of variation by estimating the following equation:
Service Intensity = + + ;
it
t
(1)
it
t; ,
which controls for any rm characteristic constant over time, is a rm xed eect; is a
set of year dummies; and is the error term. We omit the dummy for the year 1997 so
that the estimated coecients on the dummies measure the yearly average change in
where
Service Intensity
i
it
is the share of services of total sales of rm
i
at time
i
t
it
t
service intensity within each rm with respect to 1997. We display the results graphically
in gure 5 where we plot the coecients on each
t
along with a 95% condence interval.
A positive (and statistically signicant) coecient means that, on average, rms have
increased their service intensity with respect to their initial level in 1997.
The dashed
line represents an estimation with simple OLS, while the solid line shows the estimates
obtained from a linear regression wherein observations have been weighted by the average
employment of the rm over the period. All the coecients are positive and statistically
signicant and increase over time. This means that the growing importance of services in
the total production of manufacturing rms is not entirely driven by faster relative growth
among servitized rms.
On the contrary, each rm has increased its service intensity
between 1997 and 2007 by an average of 1.5 percentage points. In 1997, the (weighted)
average service intensity was 4.2%. An average increase of 1.5 percentage points in each
rm represents an average increase of 35% over the decade (or 3% per year).
0
.005
.01
.015
.02
Figure 5 Firm-level Servitization: 19972007
1998
2001
2004
Weighted estimates
4.
2007
Non-Weighted estimates
The impact of servitization on manufacturing rm performance
In this section, we analyze the interaction between servitization and rm performance.
The following two subsections address two questions:
Do servitized rms outperform
pure manufacturers, and do rms that shift toward services improve their performance?
10
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
We retain four indicators of performance:
protability (which we proxy by EBITDA
Earnings Before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation, and Amortization divided by value added),
13
employment, turnover, and the production sales of goods.
4.1.
Servitization premia
Before we estimate the causal impact of servitization on performance, we provide evidence
of the magnitude of the performance gap between servitized and non-servitized rms. To
assess the dierences between the two groups of rms precisely, we have to remove
possible composition eects and compare rms in the same year and industry.
This is
accomplished by estimating the following equation:
P erf ormance =
=49
X
k
i ;t
k
=0
] ; +1] d] ; +1]
k k
k k
;i ;t
1 + Employment
i ;t
1+ + ;
where Performancei ;t is a variable characterizing the performance of rm
j;t
i
(2)
i ;t
in year
t:
rm
i 's protability (as a percentage), (log) employment, (log) turnover, and (log) sales of
goods at time t .
is a 2-digit industryyear dummy, and
is the error term. The
dummies d] ; +1]
1 are dened as follows:
j;t
k k
;i ;t
d] ; +1]
k k
i ;t
;i ;t
1=
1
0
if
k < Service Intensity k + 1; k 2 [0%; 49%]
d] ; +1] 1 takes the value 1 if the service intensity of
]k ; k + 1], where k varies from 0% to 49%.The coecients
Each of the 50 dummy variables
rm
i
] ; +1]
k k
lies in the interval
i ;t
otherwise
k k
;i ;t
on these dummies are estimated, taking the performance of non-servitized rms
as a reference. They are interpreted as the average performance gap (i.e., the premium)
between pure manufacturers and rms with a given service intensity within the same year
and industry.
Because protability, turnover, and total sales of goods are likely to be
correlated with rm size, we control for lagged employment in those regressions.
14
The results are presented in gures 6 and 7. We graphically report only the coecients
] ; +1]
k k
along with the 95% condence interval.
Dark/plain circles represent signicant
coecients while light/hollow circles represent coecients that are not statistically different from zero at the 95% level. It is noteworthy that around 87% of servitized rms in
our sample are included in the rst ten dummies (i.e., services account for less than 10%
of their production sales). In gure 6, we display the protability premia of being servitized rms. These premia are positive and statistically signicant, and they are remarkably
stable over the range of service intensities. Regardless of the service intensity, servitized
rms exhibit greater protability of 3.5 percentage points with respect to non-servitized
rms of comparable size in their industry. In 2007, the median prot rate was 46%. An
increase of 3.5 percentage points is equivalent to a 7.6% increase. The coecients
13 We
] ; +1]
k k
do not consider sales of products that are bought and sold without transformation by the rm. See
Bernard and Fort (2013) on a description of factoryless goods producers, i.e. rms who do not produce
themselves the goods they sell, but are involved in the design and coordinate their production.
14 The
premia are very similar when we do not control for employment.
11
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
become non-signicant for rms with service intensities greater than 30%. Very few rms
have a service intensity above 30% in our sample, which may explain the non-signicance
of these coecients.
Panel (a) of gure 7 shows the premia in terms of employment. The estimated coecients
] ; +1] are all positive and statistically signicant.
k k
Their magnitude decreases with service
intensity, but they remain positive. In panel (b), we show how (the log of ) turnover of
servitized rms compares with that of pure manufacturers. The results appear similar to
those in panel (a). For service intensities below 30%, the premia are signicant, positive,
and stable.
For high levels of service intensity, the premia seem small, but the small
number of rms in these categories sharply reduces the precision of the estimates.
On
average, servitized rms with a service intensity below 30% generate almost 20% more
revenue than do non-servitized rms. In panel (c), we consider the sales of goods. The
estimated coecients
] ; +1] are positive and signicant for low levels of service intensity.
k k
They become negative and statistically signicant once the service intensity is greater than
20%. The positive and signicant coecients reveal that rms selling few services have
larger sales of goods than rms that do not sell services at all. On average, rms with a
service intensity below 10% sell 16% more goods than pure goods producers. Recall that
most of the servitized rms in our sample (87%) have service intensity below 10%. The
negative coecients on
] ; +1] when the service intensity is greater than 20% therefore
k k
concern very few rms. These results indicate a dual relationship between the production
of services and the production of goods, which can be complements or substitutes. On
the one hand, the provision of services is complementary to the production of goods when
services represent a very small proportion of total rm production. On the other hand,
some rms tend to specialize in the production of services, increasing their provision of
services in lieu of goods production.
12
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
-10
-5
0
5
10
Figure 6 Relative Protability of Servitized Firms
0
10
20
30
% of services in total production
40
50
Figure 7 Relative Performance of Servitized Firms (employment, turnover, and production of goods)
(b) Turnover (log)
-.5
-.4
-.2
0
0
.5
.2
1
.4
(a) Employment (log)
20
30
% of services in total production
40
0
50
10
20
30
% of services in total production
0
.5
(c) Sales of goods (log)
-.5
10
-1
0
0
10
20
30
% of services in total production
13
40
50
40
50
CEPII Working Paper
4.2.
Should everybody be in services?
The causal impact of servitization: empirical strategy
The premia reported in gure 7 deliver two key messages.
First, servitized rms have
better performance than non-servitized rms: They are larger (in terms of employment
and production) and more protable.
Second, with the exception of the production of
goods, service intensity does not inuence the premia much. Selling services is associated
with better performance, even when they represent a very small share of rm sales. The
premia do not increase with the share of services of total output. Together these results
suggest that the decision to start selling services is what really matters, while the decision
to sell more or fewer services does not seem to correlate with rm performance. Building
on this observation, our causal analysis will focus on the decision to start selling services
rather than on changes in the service intensity.
15
The premia shown above are simple OLS estimates and suer from patent endogeneity
problems. Our rst concern is that some confounding factors could be simultaneously correlated with both the decision to start selling services and rm performance. The decision
to start selling services may be motivated or inuenced by changes in rm environments
(e.g., changes in competition pressure, technological changes, evolution of public regulations, improvement of transport and telecommunication infrastructures). The decision
may also depend on unobserved rm-level characteristics, such as manager ability and past
experiences. Failing to control for these confounding factors can seriously bias estimates.
The second concern is reverse causality induced by self-selection. Do rms decide to sell
services because they have good performance or do they have better performance because
they also sell services to their consumers? The bias may occur in both directions. On the
one hand, servitization may be a selective process whereby only the highest-performing
rms nd it protable to sell services. This mechanism will be observed, for instance, if
rms have to invest in and allocate some managerial resources to start selling services.
These investments may not be aordable to rms with low prots or strong nancial
constraints. They may also be non-protable for rms with low competitiveness because
the potential commercial gain they expect from selling services may not compensate for
the xed investment cost. In this case, the OLS estimates would be biased upward. On
the other hand, a negative relationship between ex ante rm performance and the decision
to start selling services may also exist. When facing a negative shock, rms may try to
restore their market shares and prots by shifting their production toward services in order
to generate additional revenues and/or to add value to the good they sell. If the decision
to start selling services is a defensive strategy for declining rms, we would expect the
16
OLS estimates to be biased downward.
Our response to these endogeneity problems is twofold. First, we control for unobserved
confounding factors that may simultaneously inuence the decision to sell services and
rm performance. The traditional method to address unobserved variables is to use rm-
15 In
unreported regressions, we also examined how changes in the share of services of total sales aect
rm performance. The estimations produced volatile and non-robust results, which conrms the ambiguous
impact of service intensity on rm protability shown by Suarez et al. (2013).
16 Breinlich
et al. (2014) provide empirical evidence in favor of such a defensive strategy. They show that
increasing competition pressure resulting from lower European manufacturing taris caused British rms to
shift into the provision of services and out of the production of goods.
14
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
level xed eects in a dierence-in-dierences approach. This is not the most appropriate
method in our case.
Dierence-in-dierences estimators are based on the assumption
that the most relevant unobserved confounders are time-invariant, which may not be true
here.
It is very likely that rms that decide to sell services have recently experienced
some specic shock: a negative shock that reduced their protability, a positive shock
that provided them the resources needed to invest in a new activity, or simply a change
in their management team or ownership structure that may inuence their strategies and
performance in some undetermined way.
17 In this case, the most appropriate econometric
strategy is to estimate an LDV model in which all relevant omitted variables (including
those that are time varying) are controlled for by the lags of the dependent variable.
Compared to a xed eects model, an LDV model oers better control for self-selection
18
and the ensuing reverse causality bias.
In addition, we introduce year
industry xed
eects to capture unobserved determinants that may inuence performance in a given year
and 2-digit industry (e.g., changes in technology, regulations, infrastructures, competitive
environment). Our preferred specication is:
P erf ormance = 1(serv 1 ) +
i ;t
#X
Lags
i ;t
k
k
=1
P erf ormance
where Performancei ;t measures the performance of rm
the value one if the rm
i
sells services at
t
i
k
+ 1+ + ;
in year
i ;t
t
j;t
(3)
i ;t
(i.e., protability,
1 ) is a dummy variable taking
1 and zero otherwise; 1 is a vector of
employment, turnover, or production of goods);
1(serv
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
control variables, which are all lagged by one period to avoid simultaneity issues;
2-digit industry xed eects; and
a set of year
i ;t
j;t
is
is the error term. As the accuracy
of the parameter estimates tends to increase with the number of lags of the dependent
variable (Wilkins, 2015), our preferred specication includes three lags (i.e.,
19 The coecient of interest,
in equation (3)).
#Lags = 3
, measures the average treatment eect
(ATE), i.e., the observed impact of sales of services on Performancei ;t .
The LDV model, by explicitly controlling for the trend of past rm-level performance,
addresses the omitted variables issue and helps alleviate concerns about reverse causality
bias. Nevertheless, reverse causality bias may persist if rms start selling services because
they anticipate changes in their performance. For instance, rms innovating in products
17 The
literature has emphasized the role of organizational changes in successful transitions to services.
When moving toward services, rms often need to change their organizational structures and business
models. These changes are costly, and rms may fail to implement them successfully, thus leading to the
previously describedservice paradox. Bowen et al. (1989) argue that managers in manufacturing companies
are often reluctant to adopt service-specic values, as these values contradict traditional manufacturing
goals and practices, such as standardization and eciency. This point is also made by Gebauer and Fleisch
(2007), who argue that managers are highly risk-averse when it comes to replacing their traditional productoriented values with service-oriented values, a point also raised in Mathieu (2001) and Eggert et al. (2011).
See Vargo and Lusch (2008) for a description of the goods-dominant and service-dominant logics in
manufacturing rms.
18 As
a robustness check, we also estimate a xed eects regression. The results, which are consistent with
those obtained by the LDV model, are shown in appendix table 9.
19 Our
results are robust to the use of only one or two lags.
15
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
20 To identify a causal link between servitiza-
may also decide to sell services with them.
tion and rm performance, we need a suitable instrumental variable, that is, a measure
correlated with the decision to start selling services but uncorrelated with the dependent
variable. This is not an easy task with the data at hand, as any information on the rm's
balance sheet is very likely to be correlated with its performance. Hence, we propose an instrument based on the assumption that management practice spillovers exist across rms.
We consider that rms observe and imitate their competitors and are more likely to start
21 For each rm
selling services if comparable rms in the neighborhood already do so.
and year
i
t in our database, we compute the number of servitized rms in its industry and
the decile of size (measured as the average number of workers over the period) weighted
by the geographic distance to
i.
The distance between rms is the geodesic distance
22 For rms located in the
between the cities in which the two headquarters are located.
same city, we use a measure of the internal distance of the city equal to
where
A is the area of the city in km2 (Mayer and Zignago, 2011).
(2=3) A=,
p
Hence, our instrument
23 We lag the instrument by two
varies by year, 2-digit industry, city, and rm size decile.
24
periods, as our endogenous variable is the decision to sell services at
.
t 1
A legitimate concern about the instrument is that it may be directly correlated with
rm performance. Indeed, if selling services inuences the competitiveness of rms, then
changing the number of service suppliers in the neighborhood of a rm is very likely to alter
the competition pressure it faces and thereby its performance. In this case, the exclusion
restriction is not veried, and no inference can be drawn from the empirical results. Our
empirical strategy addresses this issue in two ways.
First, our instrument is lagged by
two periods with respect to the dependent variable, Performancei ;t . This should eliminate
simultaneity bias that would lead to violation of the exclusion restriction.
Second, our
rst- and second-stage regressions control for the past performance of rms (in
t 2).
t 1 and
Any eect of our instrumental variable on past performance is therefore captured
by these lags.
It is quite unlikely that our instrumental variable inuences the current
performance of rms without inuencing its performance in
t
1 or t 2, a factor for
which we explicitly control.
Finally, we need to dene an appropriate control group given that our objective is to assess
the impact of starting to sell services on rm performance. We compare the performance
of rms that shift toward the provision of services to the performance of rms that do
not (or have not yet started). In other words, we do not consider rms that sell services
throughout the period.
20 Eggert
We also omit rms that stop selling services to avoid mixing
et al. (2011) and Visnjic et al. (2014) show that servitization is more likely to generate better
performance when it is coupled with product innovation.
21 A
vast empirical literature has shown that scanning the external environment to obtain information about
competitors' practices is a determinant of management innovation at the rm level.
See, for instance,
Audretsch and Feldman (1996); McEvily and Zaheer (1999); Mol and Birkinshaw (2009) and Fu (2012).
22 The
2
French territory is divided into more than 36,500 cities with an average surface area of only 14.9
km . This high level of administrative fragmentation makes our measure of distance between rms quite
precise and oers substantial variation in the instrument across rms.
23 We
also performed robustness analyses with an alternative instrument: the share of servitized rms in the
same industry located in the same or surrounding départements (France is divided into 95 départements).
The (unreported) results are very close to those reported in the paper.
24 Our
instrument is therefore lagged by only one period with respect to the endogenous variable.
rst-stage regression also includes all other explanatory variables and year
16
industry xed eects.
The
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
the eects of shifting into services from those of shifting out of services.
Given these
restrictions and the large number of lags (#Lags=3), the econometric identication relies
on a sample of 6,392 individual rms and a total of 34,243 observations. Note that our
results are robust to less restrictive alternative samples (see table 10 in the appendix).
In the following, the average treatment eect (ATE),
maximum likelihood with endogenous treatment,
in equation (3), is estimated by full
1(serv
i ;t
1 ).
The rst-stage equation is
a probit regression, which predicts the probability of treatment (i.e., the probability that
a rm starts selling services). In all specications, the instrument provides a good t in
the rst stage. The instrument has a signicantly positive impact on the probability of
producing services and passes the usual validity tests.
4.3.
Baseline econometric results
4.3.1.
Protability
We begin our presentation of the econometric results by examining the impact of servitization on the protability of rms in detail.
The benchmark results are displayed in table 2. The coecient on
of starting to sell services in the previous year.
1(serv
i ;t
1 ) is the ATE
Columns (1) and (4) show simple OLS
estimates of the relationship between the lagged servitization dummy and the prot rate,
excluding and including control for lagged employment, respectively. These specications,
which do not take into account omitted variable or reverse causality issues, yield simple
25 The estimates
premia of servitization that are comparable to those shown in gure 7.
conrm the existence of a signicant premium. The protability of rms that start selling services is 4.2 percentage points higher than that of pure manufacturers (4.4 when
controlling for lagged employment). In the sample used for the regressions, the average
prot rate is 45.7%, which implies a premium on the prot rate between 9.2% and 9.6%,
depending on whether we control for the number of employees. In columns (2) and (5),
we control for the lagged values of the prot rate in order to account for selection eects.
Unsurprisingly, the ATE decreases, conrming that most of the premium comes from
self-selection. The impact of servitization remains positive but is much smaller. Starting
to sell services is associated with an increase in the prot rate of between 0.4 and 0.47
percentage points.
In columns (3) and (6), we properly control for endogeneity by instrumenting the decision
to start selling services.
The ATE is between 1.7 and 2.4 percentage points, which
corresponds to a causal increase in the prot rate between 3.7 and 5.3%. The fact that
the instrumental variable estimation provides a larger ATE reveals a negative endogeneity
bias, which suggests that the shift toward the provision of services is driven by a quite
strong defensive motive.
It seems that, everything else equal, rms that start selling
services anticipate a relative decline in their protability.
Tables 9 and 10 in the appendix present a series of robustness checks.
use alternative estimators and sets of controls.
25 The
In table 9, we
In line (1), we control for potential
results shown in gure 7 are slightly dierent because they are based on sample of observations that
is not restricted by the use of lagged variable or a precise control group.
17
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
determinants of protability:
the lagged rm market share (the rm's sales of goods
divided by the total sales of goods in the same industry) and the interaction between
this market share and the lagged industry-level Herndahl index, which captures the level
26 The ATE is 2.46, which is not statistically dierent from
competition in the industry.
the benchmark regression (2.427, in column (6) of table 2). In lines (2)(4), we report
the ATE obtained using a xed eect estimator instead of an LDV model.
In line (2),
we control only for the lagged employment level and do not instrument the treatment
variable.
Line (3) shows the ATE using an instrumental variable, and line (4) further
controls for the rm's market share and its interaction with the Herndahl index.
The
ATEs are always positive and signicant, which conrms that starting to sell services
boosts rm protability. Again, we observe that the instrumental variable estimates are
substantially greater than the OLS estimates. Note also that the xed eects estimates
are systematically larger than those of the LDV models. With xed eects, the ATE is
approximately 4.6 (cf. lines (3) and (4) of table 9) compared to 2.4 with the LDV model
(cf. column (6) of table 2). This is consistent with the bracketing properties of these two
estimators, as described by Angrist and Pischke (2008). If the correct model is an LDV
model, then xed eects will result in the overestimation of a positive treatment eect.
However, if the most important omitted variables are time invariant, the correct model
is a xed eects model, and the LDV estimator will result in an underestimation of the
treatment eect.
While we argue that the correct specication in our case is the LDV
model, it is useful to think of our estimates as lower bounds of the true causal eect.
In table 10, we test the robustness of our benchmark results to an alternative sample of
rms. In our benchmark regression (table 2), we exclude rms that always sold services or
that stopped selling services over the study period. We focused on the subsample of rms
that either never sold services and that started to sell services. In line (1) of table 10, we
exclude all rm that produced services during the year t-2. In other words, we use a sharper
denition of the treatment. We exclude from the sample all treated rms once they have
been treated (i.e., once they have started to produce services), and we estimate the
impact of shifting toward services in the year after the shift but not in the following years.
In line (2), we add to our benchmark sample rms that stop the production of services,
and in line (3), we replicate our benchmark regression using the sample of rms that
are always observed in our database (i.e., we exclude rms that appeared or disappeared
between 1997 and 2007). We conrm that servitization has a positive inuence on rm
protability.
The point estimates obtained from these alternative samples are slightly
larger than that reported in table 2. This further conrms that our preferred result is a
conservative estimate of the impact of servitization on rm protability.
4.3.2.
Employment, turnover and production of goods
We now turn to the inspection of the impact of servitization on alternative indicators of
rm performance. We re-estimate equation (3) using level of employment, turnover and
production of goods as alternative dependent variables. The baseline results are shown in
table 3.
As a robustness check, we report the xed eects estimates in table 11.
The
results conrm the positive impact of servitization. Once again, the xed eects estimates
26 We
do not include the Herndahl index on its own because it is fully captured by the industry
eect.
18
year xed
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Table 2 Impact of Servitization on Firm Protability Benchmark Results
Dep. var.: Proti ;t
Estimator:
1(serv
1)
i ;t
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
OLS
LDV
LDV-IV
OLS
LDV
LDV-IV
a
(0.284)
Proti ;t
a
4.179
0.468
(0.109)
1
a
0.601
(0.011)
Proti ;t
2
a
0.183
(0.010)
Proti ;t
3
a
0.127
(0.008)
Ln Employmenti ;t
2
34,243
34,243
0.014
0.740
Wald test (p-value)
All regression include industry
theses are clustered by industry
Coecients on
4.418
(0.322)
0.599
1(ser v
i ;t
a
1
)
year.
0.399
(0.374)
0.601
(0.011)
0.182
2.427
0.183
0.597
0.127
(0.008)
0.181
34,243
a
(0.010)
a
0.125
(0.008)
c
a
(0.010)
a
(0.010)
a
a
(0.578)
a
(0.011)
a
(0.010)
0.126
a
(0.112)
a
-0.296
R
Notes:
a
1
# Obs.
1.669
a
(0.008)
b
0.084
-0.122
(0.151)
(0.042)
(0.078)
34,243
34,243
34,243
0.014
0.740
-0.0951
-0.156
(0.000)
(0.000)
year xed eects.
Robust standard errors in paren-
Signicance levels:
c
<0.1,
: p
b
<0.05,
: p
are the average treatment eects (ATEs).
a
<0.01.
: p
Columns (3) and
(6) report full maximum likelihood estimations, where the treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
), is
instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-weighted sum of servitized rms in the corre-
sponding industry and size decile. The Wald test ( =0) is below 10%, indicating that we can
reject the null hypothesis of no correlation between the treatment and the outcome errors.
are a bit larger than those of the LDV (except for employment), which implies that the
27
ATE shown in table 3 is a conservative lower bound of the true causal eect.
As for protability, we nd a signicant, positive causal impact of servitization on rm
outcomes. Because each dependent variable is in logarithmic form, the magnitude of the
estimated impact of starting the production of services is given by the exponent of the
ATE. On average and relative to pure manufacturers, rms that start producing services
exp(0:263)
= 1:30), turnover
increase their level of employment by approximately 30% (
by 3.7%, and sales of goods by 3.6%. The magnitude of these causal eects might seem
very large, especially the impact on the number of employees. However, one has to keep in
mind that most rms in our sample are small businesses. The marginal eects estimated
here apply to relatively small values.
For instance, the median rm in our sample has
no more than 9 employees. A 30% increase in the number of employees represents two
additional jobs for the median rm.
4.4.
Extensions
All econometric results shown above point in the same direction. They conrm that servitization has a positive causal impact on the performance of manufacturing rms. These
27 For
the sake of conciseness, we do not report all robustness analyses. We have also checked the robustness
of these results to alternative models, samples of rms and control groups.
All unreported estimates
corroborate those shown in table 3. They are available from the authors upon request.
19
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Table 3 Impact of Servitization on Firm Employment, Turnover, and Production of
Goods Lagged Dependent Variable Model
Dep. variable
(1)
Employment
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
a
(0.019)
34,243
-0.593 (0.000)
a
(0.009)
34,243
-0.069 (0.001)
a
(0.008)
34,243
-0.072 (0.000)
ATE
0.263
(2)
Turnover
0.036
(3)
Prod. goods
0.035
Notes:
industry
Lagged
dependent
variable
models
with
3
lags,
controlling
for
year xed eects in all regressions and for lagged employment in (2) and
(3). The treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
), is instrumented by the (2-year lagged)
distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in the corresponding industry and
size decile.
and 3).
industry
Estimators: two-step (line 1) and full maximum likelihood (lines 2
The (std.
err.)
column reports robust standard errors clustered by
year. Signicance levels:
c
: p
<0.1,
b
: p
<0.05,
a
: p
<0.01.
econometric results contrast with the many case studies that highlight the diculties
companies experience with reaping the benets of a servitization strategy (Gebauer et al.,
2005; Martinez et al., 2010) However, our estimates are only average eects, which may
hide heterogeneity by industry or rm type. In this section, we evaluate the consequence
of starting to sell services on the long-run performance of various sub-samples of rms.
These more detailed results indicate that the impact of servitization on rm performance
is much less systematic than suggested by our benchmark regressions.
4.4.1.
Long-run eects
As emphasized in the literature, selling services is associated with long-term investments
with consumers, and the benets of servitization may take time to materialize.
Our
baseline specication has considered rm performance in the year following a move toward
services. Thus, our results may miss some of the long-run eects of servitization. In the
following table, we present results for how rm performance is aected at
t +3
28
by the move toward services.
t + 1, t + 2 and
The results indicate that the consequence of servitization on rm protability are spread
over time. Our benchmark results indicate that in the year after a shift toward services,
servitized rms increase their prot rate by 2.42 percentage points compared to pure
manufacturers (see table 2). Table 4 shows that this gap grows steadily for at least three
years, reaching 4.3 percentage points by year
t + 3.
The impact on employment is also
persistent, but the dynamics are clearly dierent, as the eect decreases slowly over time.
Four years after the switch, we still observe a signicant causal impact of servitization on
exp(0:138) 1
= 14:8%), but this eect is half the size of
that observed the year following the switch (exp(0:263)
1
= 30:1%). The impacts on
the number of employees (
turnover and production of goods also fade over time but at faster rates. Four years after
the shift toward services, the causal eect of servitization on production is very small
and barely signicant, and the impact on the production of goods is no longer visible.
All together, these results suggest that the supply of services does not really support
the production of goods over the long run. Servitization seems to be mainly a strategy
that leads rms to focus on their most protable activities and/or to dierentiate their
28 Because
of data limitations, we cannot estimate the impact of servitization over a longer period.
20
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
products further in order to charge higher margins.
Table 4 Impact of Servitization on Firm Performance Long-run Eects
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
(1)
2.6246
(0.962)
27,851
-0.183 (0.015)
(2)
3.204
a
(1.239)
22,360
-0.232 (0.015)
(3)
4.306
a
(1.004)
17,486
-0.314 (0.000)
(4)
0.194
a
(0.020)
27,851
-0.458 (0.000)
(5)
0.161
a
(0.022)
22,360
-0.400 (0.000)
(6)
0.138
a
(0.024)
17,486
-0.351 (0.000)
(7)
0.027
a
(0.010)
27,851
-0.056 (0.013)
(0.015)
22,360
-0.027 (0.466)
ATE
a
(8)
0.013
c
(9)
0.016
(0.009)
17,486
-0.037 (0.054)
(10)
0.023
b
(0.010)
27,851
-0.043 (0.052)
(11)
-0.002
(0.040)
22,360
0.013 (0.895)
(12)
0.013
(0.009)
17,486
-0.025 (0.223)
Notes:
Dependent variable
+1
+2
Prot +3
ln(Emp:) +1
ln(Emp:) +2
ln(Emp:) +3
Proti ;t
Proti ;t
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
ln(T urnover ) +1
ln(T urnover ) +2
ln(T urnover ) +3
ln(P rod:goods ) +1
ln(P rod:goods ) +2
ln(P rod:goods ) +3
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
i ;t
Lagged dependent variable models with 3 lags, controlling for lagged employment
(except for lines 46) and industry
year xed eects. The treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
),
is instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in the
corresponding industry and size decile.
Estimators:
full maximum likelihood (lines 13 and
712) and two-step (lines 46). Column (std. err.) reports robust standard errors clustered by
industry
year. Column ( ) reports the value of
and the corresponding p-value of the Wald
test of the exogeneity of the instrumented variables. Signicance levels:
a
: p
4.4.2.
c
<0.1,
: p
<0.01.
b
<0.05,
: p
Results by rm size
In table 5, we examine whether the impact of servitization diers by rm size. We report
the ATE estimated from samples of micro, small, and medium and large rms, as dened
by the European Commission.
29
For each of the four performance measures, we observe quite strong eects for micro
and small businesses.
For micro rms, starting to produce services is associated with
an increase in the prot rate of 2.8 percentage points (which corresponds to an average
increase of approximately 6% given the average level of the prot rate for this group
of rms).
Starting to sell services also increases employment, turnover and production
for these rms.
The impact on employment is particularly large (25%) but represents
a limited number of new jobs given the small size of these rms.
In our sample, the
30 so the estimated impact of servitization
median micro rm employs only 5 workers,
corresponds to an increase of 1.25 workers in this category. For small rms, the impact
on protability if larger. The ATE is more than 3.1 percentage points, which corresponds
to an average increase in the prot rate of 7.2%. Employment grows by more than 38%,
which represents slightly less than 7 new jobs in the median small rm.
29 Firms
31
are classied according to their average number of employees over the observation period. Micro
rms have no more than 10 employees. Small rms have between 11 and 50 employees, and medium and
large rms have more than 50 employees.
30 The
31 The
average number of workers in this class of rm is very close to the median: 5.48.
median number of workers in this category 18.
21
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
In contrast, we do not observe a signicant impact of servitization on the performance of
medium and large rms (i.e., rms with more than 50 employees). This non-signicance
may be due to the relatively small number of rms in this category (especially of switching
rms), which reduces the precision of the estimates. This pattern may also indicate that
rms that have managed to grow without feeling the need to produce services perform
particularly well in the production of goods.
Table 5 Impact of Servitization on Firm Protability, Employment, Turnover, and
Production of Goods By Firm Size
Dep. variable
ATE
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
Firm type
(# employees)
(1)
Protability
(2)
Protability
a
(0.590)
18,643
-0.161 (0.000)
micro (1-10)
c
(1.274)
12,519
-0.222 (0.043)
small (11-50)
2.786
3.127
2.300
> 50)
(3)
Protability
(1.632)
3,081
-0.196 (0.177)
large (
(4)
Employment
0.226
a
(0.158)
18,643
-0.449 (0.000)
micro (1-10)
(5)
Employment
0.327
a
(0.030)
12,519
-0.823 (0.000)
small(11-50)
(6)
Employment
-0.038
(0.082)
3,081
-0.199(0.000)
large (
a
(0.011)
18,643
-0.068 (0.000)
micro (1-10
a
(0.021)
12,519
-0.185 (0.002)
small(11-50)
(7)
Turnover
0.030
(8)
Turnover
0.086
(9)
Turnover
(10)
0.022
Prod. goods
(11)
Prod. goods
(12)
Prod. goods
Notes:
0.023
> 50)
> 50)
(0.126)
3,081
-0.082 (0.819)
large(
b
(0.011)
18,643
-0.063 (0.000)
micro (1-10
a
(0.017)
12,519
-0.180 (0.000)
small(11-50)
(0.123)
3,081
-0.467 (0.185)
0.083
0.168
> 50)
large(
Lagged dependent variable models with 3 lags, controlling for lagged employment and
industry
year xed eects. The treatment variable is instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-
weighted sum of servitized producers in the corresponding industry and size decile. Estimators: Full
maximum likelihood (lines 13 and 712) and two-step (lines 46). Column (2) reports robust standard errors clustered by industry-year.
Column (4) reports the value of
P-value of the Wald test of the exogeneity of the instrumented variables.
<0.1,
p
4.4.3.
b
: p
<0.05,
a
: p
and the corresponding
Signicance levels:
c
:
<0.01.
Results by industry
Moving toward supplying services to consumers is very likely to depend on the characteristics of the product being sold or on the type of competition prevailing within an industry.
Using the same dataset, in Crozet and Milet (2014), we show that servitization is more
widespread in industries that produce heterogeneous goods.
32 Fang et al. (2008) provide
evidence that adding a service to the core product of the rm leads to higher market
value, especially in industries with overall low growth and high volatility of sales.
In a
widely cited article, Teece (1986) argued that services do not loom large in the early
stages of an industry.
32 We
This inuenced the vision that services are benecial when rms
use data on the rm-level exports of goods from French customs data and use Rauch (1999)'s
classication to distinguish between dierentiated and homogenous goods.
We nd a positive log-linear
relationship between the average share of services of the industry's output and the share of dierentiated
products in this industry.
This argument is in line with Anderson et al. (1997), who argue that rm
performance depends on the degree of heterogeneity of their product. In their paper, they link measures of
productivity to customer satisfaction (which takes into account the standardization versus the customization
quality of the product).
22
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
enjoy a well-established base of customers and as dierentiation of the product becomes
increasingly dicult. This view has been recently challenged by authors, such as Suarez
et al. (2013) and Cusumano et al. (2015), who note that services can be oered before,
during, or after the purchase of the good.
33 To show how the impact of servitization
diers by sector, we have assigned each rm in our database to a broadly dened sector
34 The results are reported in ta-
and estimated equation (3) for each group separately.
ble 6. Table 12 in the appendix shows the comparable results obtained for the sample of
micro and small businesses.
Again, this table conveys a more complex message about the consequence of servitization.
At rst sight, this table conrms the positive impact of servitization on rm performance,
as a very large majority of the estimates are signicantly positive (of the 28 estimates
reported in this table, 16 are signicantly positive, 8 are non-signicant, and only 4 are
negative).
However, the results dier substantially across sectors and reveal both the
complexity and the diversity of the servitization strategies discussed in the literature. We
can identify three patterns:
1. Servitization has a positive impact on all four indicators of performance. This is the
case for agri-food (1) and other manufacturing not elsewhere classied (7). For these
two industries (particularly the latter group), the estimated impact is quite large but
close to that of the pooled results.
2. Servitization increases the sales of goods (and more generally rm size) but not the
prot rate. This is clearly the case for mineral and metal products (4) as well as for
textile (2) (wherein turnover and sales of goods, but not employment, are positively
aected). Here, sales of services are positively correlated with sales of goods. However,
the service oering is not a strategy that increases protability, either because producing
complementary services is not enough to provide a signicant competitive advantage or
because the cost of organizing services activities outweighs (at least over the short-run)
the competitive gains.
3. Servitization increases protability, but a substitution eect between services and goods
prevails. This is the case for wood products, paper and printing (3) and chemicals and
plastics (4).
35 The substitution eect observed suggests that the decision to supply
services is a part of a broader strategy in which the rms focus on their most protable
activities or markets.
33 A
36
very often-cited example is IBM, which introduced the rst computers for businesses in the 1950s.
These products were expensive and unknown to consumers. IBM engaged in leasing contracts, which were
combined with maintenance, and pay-for-usage contracts. Services preceded and substituted for the sale of
these products.
34 All
35 For
regressions control for 2-digit industry xed eects.
the latter sector, the results are less clear than suggested by table 6. The negative impact on turnover
and sales of goods shown in table 6 is entirely driven by the largest rms. Table 12 shows that for micro
and small rms in this sector, servitization increases production.
36 Note
that we nd no signicant impact in sector 6 (machinery, electrical, optical and transport equipment),
except a small and very imprecisely estimated coecient for the number of employees.
surprising result is mostly due to the behavior of the largest rms.
This perhaps
When we consider only micro and
small rms, we obtain a positive and signicant impact of servitization on protability and employment (see
table 12).
23
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Table 6 Impact of Servitization By Sector
ATE
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
1 Food, Beverage, Tobacco
Protability
Ln Employment
5.070
a
(0.511)
10479
-0.390 (0.000)
0.178
a
(0.034)
10479
-0.376 (0.000)
b
(0.013)
10479
0.214 (0.095)
c
(0.013)
10479
-0.066 (0.054)
-1.268
(2.339)
1258
0.065 (0.629)
Ln Turnover
0.026
Ln Prod. goods
0.024
2 Textile, Leather
Protability
Ln Employment
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
0.070
0.225
(0.116)
1258
-0.116 (0.662)
b
(0.073)
1258
0.357 (0.003)
a
(0.079)
1258
-0.373 (0.006)
0.214
3 Wood, Paper, Printing
Protability
6.632
a
(2.040)
4776
-0.453 (0.05)
Ln Employment
-0.080
(0.112)
4776
0.265 (0.365)
a
(0.031)
4776
0.745 (0.000)
a
(0.031)
4776
0.748 (0.000)
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
-0.353
-0.357
4 Chemicals, Plastics
Protability
9.690
a
(0.987)
1527
-0.630 (0.000)
Ln Employment
-0.185
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
(0.256)
1527
0.584 (0.381)
-0.237
b
(0.093)
1527
0.564 (0.025)
-0.248
b
(0.097)
1527
0.566 (0.025)
2.860
(3.040)
9941
-0.173 (0.443)
c
(0.050)
9941
-0.217 (0.099)
(0.019)
9941
-0.076 (0.106)
(0.029)
9941
-0.035 (0.622)
5 Mineral, Metal Products
Protability
Ln Employment
0.096
Ln Turnover
0.044
b
Ln Prod. goods
0.023
b
6 Machinery, Electrical Equip.
Protability
1.220
(0.917)
4309
-0.028 (0.634)
c
(0.105)
4309
-0.462 (0.096)
Ln Turnover
0.021
(0.019)
4309
-0.035 (0.163)
Ln Prod. goods
0.021
(0.016)
4309
-0.044 (0.023)
Ln Employment
0.190
7 Manufacturing, n.e.c.
Protability
a
(1.942)
1953
9.085 (0.000)
b
(0.179)
1953
-0.749 (0.050)
a
(0.058)
1953
-0.191 (0.134)
a
(0.057)
1953
-0.178 (0.133)
7.997
Ln Employment
0.387
Ln Turnover
0.102
Ln Prod. goods
0.093
Notes: Lagged dependent variable model with 3 lags, controlling for lagged
employment and industry
year xed eects. All lines report estimates by
full maximum likelihood (except for employment: two steps), where the
treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
),
is instrumented by the (2-year lagged)
distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in the corresponding industry
and size decile. Column (std. err.) reports robust standard errors clustered
by industry
year. Signicance levels:
c
<0.1,
: p
b
<0.05,
: p
a
<0.01.
: p
CEPII Working Paper
5.
Should everybody be in services?
Conclusion
Servitization is growing everywhere, yet empirical evidence of its impact on rm performance remains scarce (Baines and Lightfoot, 2013).
We contribute to lling this gap
by documenting the extent and evolution of servitization in the French manufacturing
sector between 1997 and 2007 using a large dataset of more than 50,000 servitized and
non-servitized rms. We rst documented that the vast majority of French manufacturing
rms report positive sales of services. While the share of servitized rms remained quite
stable over the 19972007 period, we nd that the share of services of total production
sales increased in all industries and, on average, in each rm. We showed that servitized
rms are more protable, employ more workers, and have higher total sales than nonservitized rms. These premia depend greatly on whether rms sell services, but they do
not vary with the share of services in production sales. Building on this result, we adopted
a micro-econometric approach to assess the causal impact of engaging in the production
of services on rm performance.
We nd that, compared to rms that produce goods
only, rms that start selling services increase their protability by 3.7% to 5.3%, increase
their number of employees by 30%, and boost their sales of goods by 3.6%.
From an
academic perspective, several interesting questions that are beyond the scope of this paper are raised. Firms that complement their products with services have shifted toward
a new business model.
Their activities have become a mix of goods and services and
no longer produce only tangible products.
This raises the question of the relevance of
unique industry classications based on the main activity of a rm. How should rms that
produce as many goods as services be classied? On a more theoretical note, this paper
raises the question of how to dene the production functions of such rms. It also calls
into question the denition and proper calculation of the total factor productivity of these
rms.
References
Acemoglu, D. and Guerrieri, V. (2008). Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic
Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 116(3):467498.
Anderson, E. W., Fornell, C., and Rust, R. T. (1997). Customer Satisfaction, Productivity, and Protability: Dierences Between Goods and Services. Marketing Science,
16(2):129145.
Angrist, J. and Pischke, J.-S. (2008).
Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's
Companion. Princeton University Press.
Audretsch, D. B. and Feldman, M. P. (1996).
R&D Spillovers and the Geography of
Innovation and Production. American Economic Review, 86(3):63040.
Baines, T. and Lightfoot, H. (2013). Made to Serve: How Manufacturers Can Compete
Through Servitization and Product Service Systems. Wiley.
Baines, T., Lightfoot, H., Benedettini, O., and Kay, J. (2009).
The Servitization of
Manufacturing: A review of literature and reection on future challenges. Journal of
Manufacturing Technology Management, 20(5):547567.
Baumol, W. J. (1967). Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban
Crisis. American Economic Review, 57(3):415426.
25
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Benedettini, O., Clegg, B., Kafouros, M., and Neely, A. (2010).
The Ten Myths of
Manufacturing. What Does the Future Hold for UK Manufacturing?
Report prepared
for the engineering and physical science research council.
Benedettini, O., Swink, M., and Neely, A. (2013). Firm's Characteristics and Servitization
Performance: A Bankruptcy Perspective.
University of cambridge, cambridge service
alliance working paper.
Bernard, A. B. and Fort, T. C. (2013). Factoryless Goods Producers in the U.S. NBER
Working Papers 19396.
Bowen, D. E., Siehl, C., and Schneider, B. (1989).
A Framework for Analyzing Cus-
tomer Service Orientations in Manufacturing. The Academy of Management Review,
14(1):pp. 7595.
Breinlich, H., Soderbery, A., and Wright, G. C. (2014).
From Selling Goods to Selling
Services: Firm Responses to Trade Liberalization. C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers 10116.
Crozet, M. and Milet, E. (2014). The Servitization of French Manufacturing Firms. CEPII
Working Paper 2014-10.
Cusumano, M. A., Kahl, S. J., and Suarez, F. F. (2015).
and the Competitive Strategies of Product Firms.
Services, Industry Evolution,
Strategic Management Journal,
36(4):559575.
Eggert, A., Hogreve, J., Ulaga, W., and Muenkho, E. (2011).
Product Innovations, and Firm Protability:
Industrial Services,
A Multiple-group Latent Growth Curve
Analysis. Industrial Marketing Management, 40(5):661 670.
European Commission, T. (2014). For a European Industrial Renaissance, Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, The Council, The European
Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions.
Fang, E., Palmatier, W. R., and Steenkamp, J.-B. E. (2008). Eect of Service Transition
Strategy on Firm Value. Journal of Marketing, 72(5):114.
Fu, X. (2012). Foreign Direct Investment and Managerial Knowledge Spillovers through
the Diusion of Management Practices. Journal of Management Studies, 49(5):970
999.
Fuchs, V. R. (1968). The Service Economy. Number 87. NBER.
Gebauer, H. and Fleisch, E. (2007). An Investigation of the Relationship Between Behavioral Processes, Motivation, Investments in the Service Business and Service Revenue.
Industrial Marketing Management, 36(3):337 348.
Gebauer, H., Fleisch, E., and Friedli, T. (2005).
Overcoming the Service Paradox in
Manufacturing Companies. European Management Journal, 23(1):1426.
Lodefalk, M. (2013). Servicication of Manufacturing - Evidence from Sweden. International Journal of Economics and Business Research, 6(1):87113.
Martinez, V., Bastl, M., Kingston, J., and Evans, S. (2010). Challenges in Transforming
Manufacturing Organisations into Product-service Providers. Journal of Manufacturing
Technology Management, 21(4):449469.
Mathieu, V. (2001). Service strategies within the manufacturing sector: benets, costs
and partnership. International Journal of Service Industry Management, 12(5):451475.
Mayer, T. and Zignago, S. (2011). Notes on CEPII's Distances Measures: The GeoDist
26
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Database. CEPII Working Papers 2011-25.
McEvily, B. and Zaheer, A. (1999).
Bridging Ties: A Source of Firm Heterogeneity in
Competitive Capabilities. Strategic Management Journal, 20(12):11331156.
Mol,
M. J. and Birkinshaw,
J. (2009).
The Sources of Management Innovation:
When Firms Introduce New Management Practices.
Journal of Business Research,
62(12):12691280.
Neely, A. (2008). Exploring the Financial Consequences of the Servitization of Manufacturing. Operations Management Research, 1(2):103118.
Neely, A., Benedittini, O., and Visnjic, I. (2011).
The Servitization of Manufacturing:
Further Evidence. Euoma conference, cambridge.
Ngai, L. R. and Pissarides, C. A. (2007).
Structural Change in a Multisector Model of
Growth. American Economic Review, 97(1):429443.
Oliva, R. and Kallenberg, R. (2003). Managing the Transition from Products to Services.
International Journal of Service Industry Management, 14(2):160172.
Pilat, D., Cimper, A., Olsen, K., and Webb, C. (2006). The Changing Nature of Manufacturing in OECD Economies. STI Working Paper 9.
Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks Versus Markets in International Trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1):735.
Reinartz, W. and Ulaga, W. (2008).
How to Sell Services More Protably.
Harvard
Business Review, 86(5):9098.
Stigler (1956).
Trends in Employment in the Service Industries.
National Bureau of
Economic Research, General Series n.59.
Suarez, F. F., Cusumano, M. A., and Kahl, S. J. (2013).
Services and the Business
Models of Product Firms: An Empirical Analysis of the Software Industry. Management
Science, 59(2):420435.
Teece, D. J. (1986). Proting from Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration,
Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy. Research Policy, 15(6):285305.
Vandermerwe, S. and Rada, J. (1988). Servitization of Business: Adding Value by Adding
Services. European Management Journal, 6(4):314324.
Vargo, S. L. and Lusch, R. F. (2008).
From Goods to Service(s):
Divergences and
Convergences of Logics. Industrial Marketing Management, 37(3):254 259.
Visnjic, I., Wiengarten, F., and Neely, A. (2014). Only the Brave: Product Innovation,
Service Business Model Innovation, and Their Impact on Performance.
Journal of
Product Innovation Management, page DOI: 10.1111/jpim.12254.
Wilkins, A. S. (2015). To Lag or Not to Lag? Re-evaluating the Use of Lagged Dependent
Variables in Regression Analysis. mimeo.
Wise, R. and Baumgartner, P. (1999).
Go Downstream in Manufacturing.
Business Review, 135.
27
Harvard
CEPII Working Paper
6.
Should everybody be in services?
Appendix
6.1.
Summary statistics complete sample
Table 7 Summary Statistics - Sample including Firms with a Share of Services of Total
Sales above 50%
All rms
(1)
# Firms
Servitized rms
1997
2007
97-07
1997
2007
97-07
31,603
28,258
-1.11
23,345
21,007
-1.02
73.9
74.6
1,677
1,473
88.0
91.0
Share (%)
(2)
Employment
Total (thousand)
1,905
1,618
-1.62
Share (%)
Average
(3)
Turnover
e,
Total (
million)
60.27
57.27
-0.51
71.8
69.7
-0.28
333.1
415.8
+2.24
298.8
387.6
+2.64
89.7
93.2
Share (%)
Average (
(4)
e,
thousand)
Production of goods
e,
Total (
million)
10.5
14.7
+3.39
12.8
18.4
+3.69
281.0
334.6
+1.76
247.6
307.0
+2.17
88.1
91.7
Share (%)
Average (
(5)
(6)
e,
8.9
11.8
+2.91
10.6
14.6
+3.22
Average (%)
47.0
48.7
+0.35
47.7
49.8
+0.43
Average (%)
17.0
18.3
+0.72
23.1
24.5
+0.62
Median (%)
1.0
1.3
+2.63
2.6
3.2
+2.05
0.37
0.37
Protability
thousand)
-1.29
Service intensity
Std. dev.
97-07 corresponds to the annualized growth rate between 1997 and 2007.
This sample of rms
produces mainly goods (i.e., whose service intensity is below 50% over the period) or mainly services.
Servitized rms are rms reporting strictly positive sales of services.
28
CEPII Working Paper
6.2.
Should everybody be in services?
Transition matrix
Table 8 Transition Matrix - Change in Service Intensity between 1997 and 2007
from to 0% bin1 bin2 bin3 bin4 bin5 bin6 bin7 bin8 bin9 bin10
0%
11.98 7.42 0.40 0.17 0.11 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.25
5.89 39.49 2.78 0.82 0.40 0.17 0.15 0.10 0.06 0.08 0.42
bin1
bin2
0.23 1.79 1.17 0.47 0.18 0.12 0.05 0.04 0.01 0.04 0.03
bin3
0.09 0.63 0.45 0.42 0.20 0.14 0.07 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.05
0.04 0.26 0.13 0.21 0.19 0.12 0.11 0.07 0.02 0.01 0.05
bin4
bin5
0.03 0.13 0.07 0.11 0.13 0.18 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.01 0.04
bin6
0.01 0.11 0.03 0.06 0.05 0.11 0.12 0.08 0.04 0.04 0.07
bin7
0.01 0.06 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.05 0.08 0.10 0.08 0.08 0.05
bin8
0.02 0.08 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.12 0.09 0.12
bin9
0.02 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.08 0.14 0.23
0.08 0.31 0.06 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.08 0.13 2.36
bin10
100%
0.83 1.38 0.22 0.18 0.12 0.12 0.14 0.13 0.13 0.15 1.63
Notes: Constant sample of 29,909 rms.
Lines refer to the service intensity in 1997, while
columns refer to the service intensity in 2007.
intensity.
100%
1.30
1.57
0.24
0.13
0.13
0.09
0.08
0.10
0.16
0.20
1.96
3.81
Bins are dened as 10% intervals of service
Firms in bin5 have a service intensity between 40% and 50%.
The rst and last
columns (0% and 100%) refer to rms that produced either only goods or only services,
respectively, in 2007.
6.3.
Robustness checks
Table 9 Impact of Servitization on Firm Protability Alternative Controls and Estimators
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
Method
a
(0.592)
34,243
-0.158 (0.001)
LDV-IV
a
(0.165)
34,243
-
FE
a
(0.669)
34,243
-0.152 (0.000)
FE -IV
a
(0.665)
34,243
-0.153 (0.000)
FE-IV
ATE
(1)
(2)
2.459
1.693
(3)
4.585
(4)
4.597
Notes:
Stoppers and continuously servitized rms are excluded.
reports the robust standard errors clustered by industry
value of
Controls
3
1
1
2
Column (std.
err.)
year. Column (4) reports the
and the corresponding P-value of the Wald test.
P-values below 10% indicate
that we can reject the null hypothesis of no correlation between the treatment errors
1 = lagged
2 = 1 , lagged market share and interaction between lagged market
share and lagged industry-level Herndahl index; 3 = 2 , Prot
1 , Prot
2 and
and the outcome errors. Column (6) indicates the set of control variables:
employment level;
i ;t
Proti ;t
3.
i ;t
Line (1) reports lagged dependent variable model estimates. Lines (2), (3)
and (4) report rm-level xed eects estimates. Lines (1), (3) and (4) report the full
maximum likelihood estimates of the ATE, where the treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
),
is instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in
the corresponding industry. Line (2) reports the OLS estimates. All regressions include
industry
year xed eects. Signicance levels:
c
29
<0.1,
: p
b
<0.05,
: p
a
<0.01.
: p
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Table 10 Impact of Servitization on Firm Protability Alternative Samples
ATE
std. err.
(0.878)
27,415
-0.123 (0.018)
c
(1.834)
72,034
-0.207 (0.154)
a
(0.899)
22,304
-0.213 (0.003)
b
(1.375)
17,300
-0.171 (0.045)
a
(1.499)
51,232
-0.421 (0.000)
(1)
2.575
2.953
(4)
(5)
Samples
a
(2)
(3)
(p-value)
# Obs.
3.168
3.457
5.803
Starts
With
All
only
stops
years
X
X
X
X
X
X
X
Notes: Lagged dependent variable model with 3 lags, controlling for lagged employment and
industry
year xed eects.
treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
All lines report estimates by full maximum likelihood, where the
1
), is instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-weighted sum
of servitized producers in the corresponding industry. Column (std. err.) reports robust stan-
dard errors clustered by industry
year. Column (4) reports the value of
and the corresponding
P-value of the Wald test of the exogeneity of the instrumented variables. Line (1) uses the
2.
t
sample of rms that were not producing services at
those that always produce services.
Line (2) includes all rms except
Line (3) replicates the benchmark regressions shown in
column (6) of table 2 for the panel of rms active from 1997 to 2007.
Lines (4) and (5)
replicate the regressions shown in lines (1) and (2) for the panel of rms active from 1997 to
2007. Signicance levels:
c
<0.1,
: p
b
<0.05,
: p
a
<0.01.
: p
Table 11 Impact of Servitization on Firm Employment, Turnover, and Production of
Goods Fixed Eects Estimates
Variable
(1)
(2)
(3)
Employment
Turnover
Prod. goods
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
a
(0.032)
34,243
0.026 (0.7418)
a
(0.014)
34,243
-0.093 (0.000)
a
(0.014)
34,243
-0.095 (0.000)
ATE
0.068
0.116
0.087
Notes: Fixed eects model controlling for industry
year xed eects in all re-
gressions and for lagged employment in (2), (3), and (4). The treatment variable
is instrumented by the (2-year lagged) distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in the corresponding industry and size decile.
Estimator: two-step (line
1) and full maximum likelihood (lines 2 and 3). The (std. err.) column reports
robust standard errors clustered by industry
value of
year. The last column reports the
and the corresponding P-value of the Wald test of the exogeneity of
the instrumented variables. Signicance levels:
30
c
<0.1,
: p
b
<0.05,
: p
a
<0.01.
: p
CEPII Working Paper
Should everybody be in services?
Table 12 Impact of Servitization by Sector Micro and Small Businesses
ATE
std. err.
# Obs.
(p-value)
1 Food, Beverage, Tobacco
a
(0.437)
9952
-0.375 (0.000)
a
(0.028)
9952
-0.337 (0.000)
a
(0.012)
9952
-.101 (0.001)
a
(0.013)
9952
-0.102 (0.000)
Protability
-0.920
(2.427)
1105
0.141 (0.848)
Ln Employment
0.118
Protability
Ln Employment
4.879
0.156
Ln Turnover
0.040
Ln Prod. goods
0.039
2 Textile, Leather
(0.135)
1105
-0.195 (0.103)
a
(0.064)
1105
-0.382 (0.001)
a
(0.073)
1105
-0.362 (0.002)
(1.970)
4430
-0.458 (0.004)
Ln Turnover
0.234
Ln Prod. goods
0.232
3 Wood, Paper, Printing
Protability
6.889
a
a
Ln Employment
0.265
(0.054)
4430
-0.576 (0.000)
Ln Turnover
-0.363
(0.033)
4430
0.750 (0.000)
0.037
(0.047)
4430
-0.084 (0.428)
10.012
(1.392)
1187
-0.649 (0.000)
0.128
(0.129)
1187
-0.240 (0.501)
b
(0.121)
1187
-0.559 (0.070)
c
(0.131)
1187
-0.517 (0.114)
Ln Prod. goods
a
4 Chemicals, Plastics
Protability
Ln Employment
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
a
0.252
0.233
5 Mineral, Metal Products
Protability
Ln Employment
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
3.334
(2.598)
9216
-0.200 (0.298)
a
(0.030)
9216
-0.575 (0.000)
a
(0.009)
9216
-0.120 (0.000)
a
(0.010)
9216
-0.108 (0.000)
0.236
0.065
0.056
6 Machinery, Electrical Equip.
Protability
Ln Employment
2.759
c
(1.545)
3601
-0.120 (0.249)
a
(0.042)
3601
-0.358 (0.000)
0.151
Ln Turnover
0.030
(0.023)
3601
-0.054 (0.122)
Ln Prod. goods
0.028
(0.022)
3601
-0.059 (0.060)
(2.074)
1671
-0.566 (0.000)
7 Manufacturing, n.e.c.
Protability
Ln Employment
Ln Turnover
Ln Prod. goods
8.348
a
a
0.417
0.118
b
0.124
(0.155)
1671
-0.771 (0.015)
(0.072)
1671
-0.234 (0.107)
(0.061)
1671
-0.257 (0.031)
Notes: Lagged dependent variable model with 3 lags, controlling for lagged
employment and industry
year xed eects.
All lines report estimates
by full maximum likelihood (except for employment: two-step estimator),
where the treatment variable,
1(ser v
i ;t
1
), is instrumented by the (2-year
lagged) distance-weighted sum of servitized producers in the corresponding
industry and decile of size.
Column (std.
errors clustered by industry
year. The last column reports the value of
err.)
reports robust standard
and the corresponding P-value of the Wald test of the exogeneity of the instrumented variables. Signicance levels:
c
: p
31
<0.1,
b
: p
<0.05,
a
: p
<0.01.