Abstract
This paper studies the impact of transparency in the mortgage market on the underlying real estate market. We show that geographic transparency in the secondary mortgage market, which implies geographic risk based pricing in the primary market, can limit risk-sharing and make house prices more volatile. Ex ante, regions prefer opaque markets to enable insurance opportunities. We discuss the implications for risk based pricing and house price volatility more generally. In addition, we investigate the specific conditions under which competitive lenders would optimally choose to provide opaque lending, thus reducing volatility in the real estate market. We show that in general the opaque competitive equilibrium is not stable, and lenders have incentive to switch to transparent lending if one of the geographic regions has experienced a negative income shock. We propose market and regulatory mechanisms that make the opaque competitive equilibrium stable and insurance opportunities possible.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
In 2008, Fannie Mae briefly implemented a “Declining Markets Policy” by restricting the maximum CTLV for properties located within a declining market to five percentage points less than the maximum permitted for the selected mortgage product. Fannie Mae ended this policy in a few months.
For a discussion of the liquidity of the MBS market and its benefits as measured in the TBA market see Vickery and Wright (2010).
DGH argue that while symmetry of information about payoffs is essential for liquidity, transparency is not and opacity actually contributes to liquidity as symmetric information can be achieved through shared ignorance. Highly nontransparent markets can be very liquid (19th century clearinghouses, currency). When it is possible to obtain information about an asset, people invest in finding information differentially, resulting in lower overall liquidity.
This is in contrast to Akerlof (1970) who shows that transparency is good in markets that suffer a “lemons” problem. Informing all parties who the lemons are will make the market function more smoothly.
References
Anctil RM, et al. (2010) Does information transparency decrease coordination failure? Games and Economic Behavior 70.2:228–241
Akerlof GA (1970) The market for Lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q J Econ 84(3):488–500
Beltran DO, Cordell L, Thomas CP (2013) Asymmetric information and the death of ABS CDOs. International Finance Discussion Papers
Bouvard M, Chaigneau P, Motta ADe (2012) Transparency in the financial system: rollover risk and crises. Available at SSRN 1973673
Case KE, Shiller RJ (1989) The efficiency of the market for single-family homes
Dang TVi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2012) Ignorance, debt and financial crises. Unpublished, Yale SOM
Dang TVi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2013) The Information Sensitivity of a Security
Dang T Vi, Gorton G, Holmstrm B (2012) Haircuts and Repo Chains, working paper
Dang T Vi, et al. (2013) Banks as secret keepers. Working paper. Columbia University, Yale University, MIT, University of Pennsylvania and. NBER
Downing C, Jaffe DM, Wallace N (2005) Information asymmetries in the mortgage-backed securities market. AFA 2006 Boston Meetings Paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=722423 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.722423
Duca JV, Muellbauer J, Murphy A (2010) Housing markets and the financial crisis of 20072009: lessons for the future. Journal of Financial Stability 6.4:203–217
Farhi E, Tirole J (2012) Information, tranching and liquidity. Institut d’conomie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse
French K, Baily M, Campbell J, Cochrane J, Diamond D, Duffie D, Stulz R (2010) The Squam Lake Report, Fixing the Financial System
Gorton GB (2008) The panic of 2007 no. w14358, National Bureau of Economic Research
Hirshleifer J (1971) The private and social value of information and the reward to inventive activity. Am Econ Review 61.4:561–574
Holmstrom B (2012) Presidential Address, Econometric Society, ASSA meetings, Chicago, January 5–8, 2012
Hurst E, Keys B, Seru A, Vavra J (2014) Regional Risk Sharing Through the U.S. Mortgage Market
Pagano M, Volpin P (2010) Securitization, disclosure and liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming
Poterba JM,Weil DN, Shiller R (1991) House price dynamics: The role of tax policy and demography. Brook Pap Econ Act:143–203
Vickery J, Wright J (2010) TBA trading and liquidity in the agency MBS market. FRB of New York Staff Report:468
Acknowledgments
Dr. Pavlov acknowledges financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. Dr.Wachter acknowledges the assistance from the Research Sponsors Program of the Zell/Lurie Real Estate Center at Wharton.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix: 2 periods, 2 states
Appendix: 2 periods, 2 states
Transparent Mortgage Markets
The lender gets \({L_{0}^{j}}{R}\) if the borrower repays, and p 1 j H if the borrower defaults.
Assume city A starts with the low income shock and city B starts with the high income shock: \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{L}\), \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{H}\).
If we denote the ratio \(\frac {{p_{t}^{A}}}{{p_{t}^{B}}}\) with θ t , then the income shock effects imply that θ 1 < θ 0. Without loss of generality let assume that θ 0 = 1, then the income shock effects are depicted in the fact that θ 1 < 1.
The probability city A will have a low shock next period is given by:
\( P\left \{ {y_{1}^{A}}=y_{L} | {y_{0}^{A}}= y_{L} \right \} =\frac {1+\rho }{2} \)
Where ρ ∈ [−1, 1] is the auto-correlation for income. We assume income follows a two-state Markov Chain:
For simplicity we assume that the spatial correlation in income shocks is perfectly negative ρ A, B = −1, so whenever city A has a bad shock, city B will have a good shock vice-versa.
In a transparent market, the lender’s expected profit to city j is:
The zero expected profit condition implies:
\({L_{0}^{A}} = \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {L_{0}^{A}} R + \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}}H\) ⇔ \({\kern 11pt} {L_{0}^{A}} \left (1- \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) R \right ) = \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{A}} \) ⇔ \({\kern 11pt} {L_{0}^{A}} = \frac { \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H } { \left (1- \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) R \right ) } {p_{1}^{A}}\)
Likewise,
In an opaque market, the lender’s zero profit condition is:
\( L_{0} = \frac {1}{2} \eta L_{0} R \cdot \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2}\right ) + \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{A}}\\ {\kern 11pt}+ \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) L_{0} R + \frac {1}{2} \eta \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) H {p_{1}^{B}} \) ⇔ \({\kern 11pt} L_{0} = \frac {1}{2} \eta L_{0} R\\ {\kern 11pt}+\frac {1}{2} \eta H \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} {\kern 11pt}+ \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ]\) ⇔ \({\kern 11pt} L_{0} \left (1 - \frac {1}{2} \eta R \right ) = \frac {1}{2} \eta H \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} + \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ] \) ⇔ \({\kern 11pt} L_{0} = \frac { \frac {1}{2} \eta H } { \left (1 - \frac {1}{2} \eta R \right ) } p_{1} \)
Where \(p_{1}= \left [\left (\frac {1+\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{A}} + \left (\frac {1-\rho }{2} \right ) {p_{1}^{B}}\right ]\), and we have \({p_{1}^{A}}<p_{1}<{p_{1}^{B}}\), also notice that in the opaque market case, each city receives the same loan L 0.
Proposition 1
If ρ > 0, then
if ηR > 1:
if ηR < 1: \({L_{0}^{A}} > L_{0} > {L_{0}^{B}}\) If income is negatively correlated ρ < 0, then signs are reversed. But this is not the case we are interested in.
The case we study has ρ > 0 and ηR > 1. Plugging this into the equilibrium price function: \({p_{0}^{j}} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{j}} - H \right )\) Since the loan to city A under transparency is smaller than the loan to city A under opacity \({L_{0}^{A}}<L_{0}\) , the transparent price is lower than the opaque price: \(p_{0}^{A,trans} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{A}} - H \right ) < \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + L_{0} - H \right ) = p_{0}^{A,opaque} \) Likewise: \(p_{0}^{B,trans} = \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + {L_{0}^{B}} - H \right ) > \frac {1}{\gamma } \left (\alpha + {y_{0}^{j}} + L_{0} - H \right ) = p_{0}^{B,opaque} \)
NOTE: we have assumed that city A starts with a bad income shock at time 0 and city B starts with a good income shock. Ex ante with probability \(\frac {1}{2}\) we have \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{L}\) and \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{H}\) , and with probability \(\frac {1}{2}\) we have \({y_{0}^{A}}=y_{H}\) and \({y_{0}^{B}}=y_{L}\) . However, ex ante neither city knows which state of the world they will start in they will prefer opacity to have smoother house prices.
The lesson from this model is that a geographically transparent mortgage market has more volatile house prices which are more strongly correlated to local risks.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Pavlov, A., Wachter, S. & Zevelev, A.A. Transparency in the Mortgage Market. J Financ Serv Res 49, 265–280 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-014-0211-9
Received:
Revised:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-014-0211-9