The Economic Crisis of 1619 To 1623
The Economic Crisis of 1619 To 1623
The Economic Crisis of 1619 To 1623
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Economic History Association and Cambridge University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The Journal of Economic History.
http://www.jstor.org
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
P. KINDLEBERGER
The
149
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
150
Kindleberger
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
151
innocent onlookers whose good money was being exchanged for bad.7
Kippen is "to tilt," and while Wippeis in fact a seesaw, wippen, the
verb, is "to wag." Kipper-und Wipperzeitwas analogous to Cockney
rhyming slang such as hurley-burley.The words even generated offspring in such expressions as Kipperei (the act of debasement), Kippergeld (Geld meaning money), and Kippermunze(Munze being coins
and also mints). Auswippenmeant to select out good coins to hoard or
export. Redlich explains that Kippergeldwas not clipped so much as
debased by alteringits denomination,weight, metal, or fineness. Most
of the trouble arose not from "crying up" existing coins with higher
denominationsbut from hoardingand remintinggood coins and minting
new ones of lighter weight, baser metal, or both.
SUPPLIESOF PRECIOUSMETALS
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
152
Kindleberger
Lubeck. Other copper came to Europe from Japan, and the price fell
almost by one-half. In Germany, nevertheless, copper came to be in
short supply as German mints used more and more: musical instruments, kettles, pipes, gutters, and even church bells and baptismal
fonts, some of them stolen, were dumpedinto the melting pot.'0
These surges in the supply of first one metal then another changed
their relative prices and, as mentioned, created severe Gresham's
Law-type problems in Europe. The drying up of New World gold
supplies and the spurtof silver importsruinedthe silver mines in central
Europe that had producedfor mints such as that of the Slick family in
Joachimstal (from whence came thaler, later transmogrifiedinto "dollar"). The bulge in the supply of copper led Spain, exhaustedfinancially
by war and drained of silver, seriously to debase its currency. From
1599to 1606, the Spanish monarchycoined 22 million ducats in vellon,
a copper alloy. The bankruptcyof the Spanish treasury in 1607, which
destroyed its credit and led to the failure of the Fuggers and a number
of Genoan bankers, elicited a royal promise to the Cortes to coin no
more copper-a promise kept for ten years. In 1617 to 1619, the
monarchyobtained permissionof the Cortes to resume and coined five
millionducats in copper. Two years later another 14 millionwere added.
Spain experienced financialcrises at the level of the monarchyin 1557,
1575, 1596, 1607, 1627, and 1647-though not, on this showing, in 1619
to 1623. That it avoided the latter crisis may have been a benefit of the
truce with Hollandthat lasted from 1607to 1621,easing the strainon the
budget. In the private sector, however, a continuous squeeze was felt.
In the mid-sixteenth century there were 50 or 60 operators importing
silver in ingots. By 1615, only eight were left, four of which went
bankrupt shortly thereafter; by 1620, only three remained. Redlich
mentions that the Spanish monarchy'scrisis of 1627was an echo of the
Kipper- und Wipperzeit."
THE MONETARYPOROSITYOF SMALL STATES
Metallic standards, of course, have an inherent potential for divergence between the nominalvalue of a coin and its actual value as metal.
Moreover, coin passed readily over the borders of states and through
the gates of cities despite attemptsof kings, princes, dukes, counts, and
the like to control it. The result was, in most jurisdictions, a mishmash
of coins of variedorigins. A centuryand a half after the time in question,
in his digression on banks of deposit and especially the Bank of
10
Heckscher, Economic History of Sweden, pp. 79, 85, 105; Spooner, Monetary Movements in
France, p. 46; and Langer, Kulturgeschichte, p. 30.
" Spooner, Monetary Movements in France, p. 38; Ehrenberg, Fuggers, p. 334; Parker, Thirty
Years' War, p. 77; Vilar, Gold and Money, p. 141; and Redlich, Die deutsche Inflation, p. 12.
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
153
'3
Schdttle, "Mfinz- und Geldgeschichte," p. 82; Opel, Deutsche Finanznoth, p. 216; and
pp. 242-43; and Tilly, Financial Institutions in the Rhineland, chap. 2, esp. pp. 20-21.
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
154
Kindleberger
17
18
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
155
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
156
Kindleberger
Wuttke, "Zur Kipper-und Wipperzeitin Kursachsen," pp. 120-21, 136; and Redlich, Die
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
157
Kreise
Burgundy
Circle
Lower-Rhine
Rhine
LUBECK
MECKLENBU-e1
,=
Circle
a)
Circle
Westphalia
Lower Saxony
Circle
E- MBERk
FLANDERS?0
/g
\-)
>
~~~~~~~~tRI's:
Sr~ankfurt
.<n jBrusses
o
Cambrai
HESE
NASSAU
LUXEMBERG
UpperRhine Circle
PSILESA
?Prague
-N
WORMSCtR
~BOHEMIA
VI)J....
PrnK~~~~~~~~s
~~~~
BRFLZ
MORAVIA
ESBRG
(()RURG
AUG2B
Vi
Swabian Circle
VIenna
(
BAVARIA
Bavarian Circle
Austrian Circle
Territory nt
Involvedin Circl.
C
gift Sitesof
ImperialDiets
.,
Empre
POLAND
)BUSIK0PLN
BRANDENBURG
BRUNSWIbK
?FranconianCircle
AUSTRI
HUNGARY
"
d
,
SWISS CONFEDERATION/
TIROL
VENICE
SAVOY
Y'
FIGURE I
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
158
Kindleberger
32
33
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
159
Florins
Kreutzers
1582
1587
1590
1594
1
1
1
1
8
9
10
11
1596
1603
1604
1605
1607
1608
1609
1
1
1
1
1
1
24
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
2
2
2
24
26
28
28
24
30
30
30
32
48
4
8
20
1610
1613
1614
1615
1616
1617
1618
1619
1620
a
b
June 15
July 7
Dec. 19
Sept.
Aug.
March
Nov. 1
Nov. 17
Oct.
Dec.
June
Nov. 9
Date
1621
Florins
Kreutzers
Jan.
Feb.
March
April
2
2
2
2
20
24
30
36
12
May 25
48
14
14
15
16
20
22
May 31
June
July
Aug.
Aug. 10
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.
Dec. 20
Jan. 18
Jan. 27
Feb. 10
March
March 12
June 16
Oct.
Nov.
April
1622
1623
3
3
3
4
3
4
5
5
6
3
7
4
10
10
6
3
5
6
1
15
6
15
0
15a
30a
oa
30a
30a
15
30b
30
Oc
Oc
0
15
0
0
30d
Nuremberg
Augsburg
c Vienna
d
of the death penalty, the city council got it down to 10 gulden. But the
various sources fail to agree narrowlyon rates, not unexpectedly given
a country with a primitivetransportand communicationnetwork.36
A historian of the Swabian experience and its central city, Ulm,
suggests that the first invasion of debased money came from Italy and
especially Switzerlandas early as 1580.The entry point for the northern
Italian noble counterfeiters and those of Graubundenin Switzerland,
especially the Bishop of Chur, was at Lindau on the Bodensee (Lake
Constance). The same account, however, records that three upper
circles-Swabia, Franconia, and Bavaria-found the counterfeitingof
36
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
160
Kindleberger
38
Langer,Kulturgeschichte,p. 30.
Schottle, "Munz- und Geldgeschichte,"p. 84.
41 Langer, Kulturgeschichte,p. 80. Furthermint numbersare given by, among others, Opel,
"Deutsche Finanznoth,"pp. 226-27.
39
40
42
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
161
141-43; Gaettens, Geschichte des Inflationen, p. 83; Redlich, Die deutsche Inflation, p. 14; and
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
162
Kindleberger
when the silver content of coins was lowered more than gold, and again
in 1611, when the price of all gold coins was raised45to bring a large
volumeof silverto the mintfrom 1601to 1611,andnone from 1611to 1630;
(4) the trialin the StarChamberin 1617and 1618of 18 foreignmerchants
for smugglingcoin out of Englandto the fantasticextent of ?7 million,
which may have been a blunderingattemptto stop the flow of interest
paymentsto Hollandbut also possibly led to a halt in Dutch lendingto
London and contributedto the financialcrisis there in 1621.46
The loss in exports of woolen cloth gets special stress in the
contemporarydocuments, as exports fell from 127,000pieces in 1614to
45,000 in 1640 after having risen from 100,000pieces in 1600. Further
causes of the "spectacular British crisis of the 1620s" have been
adduced:bad harvests, plague, and the disastrousloss of 11 ships, some
filled with silver, in the Far EasternDutch-Britishwar of 1618and 1619.
The many causes (and remedies) cited suggest that the crisis was
overdeterminedin the minds of contemporaries,so it is difficultat this
remove and in the absence of sufficientfinancialdata to form a solid
judgment. Feaveryearsuggests that the Gresham's-Lawundervaluation
of silver was more importantthan the decline in cloth exports, because
the continued inflow of gold to the mint implies that the balance of
paymentscannot be blamed.47The exchange of an equal value of silver
for gold was a blow to the "effective monetarycirculation"because of
the far greater use of silver than gold in ordinarytransactions.48
I have some difficultyin acceptingthe analysis that the debasementof
German and Polish coins led to the English commercial difficulties,
because the debasement affected primarilythe subsidiarycoinage and
not those of larger denominationsuch as the silver Reichstaler or the
gold ducat normallyused to settle balances in internationaltrade. These
coins may have been so widely hoarded, however, that the effective
exchange rate ran to the gulden(or florin)ratherthan to the higherunits
of account. As I have alreadynoted, and as has been recently analyzed
for later inflations,inflationcan be accompaniedby export surpluses at
a stage frequentlyencounteredwhen the external depreciationexceeds
the rise of domestic prices.49Evidence from the Swabian Circle, at a
considerable distance from the seacoast, indicates concern over local
export surpluses. Ulm, Biberach, and Uberlingenrestrictedthe export
Feaveryear,The Pound Sterling, pp. 88-89.
Barbour,CapitalismandAmsterdam,pp. 122-23.Amongthose convictedandfinedwas Philip
Burlamachi,a royal exchangerof Italianstock, who was born in France, began his career in the
Netherlands,and arrivedin Englandin 1605.See Judge, "PhilipBurlamachi."
47 Thirskand Cooper,Economic Documents, chaps. 1, 5, 6; Wilson, Transformation of Europe,
45
46
p. 53; Chauduri, English East India Company, pp. 60-61; and Feaveryear, The Pound Sterling, p.
89.
Supple, CommercialCrisis, p. 173, italics in the original.
Hoszowski, Les prix a Lwow, p. 64. For a modern statement, see Bernholz, "Currency
Competition."
48
49
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
163
of foodstuffs, hay, cattle, and yarn and confined sales to local markets
following a "policy of supply," the rationalefor which was developed
in Italy in the eighteenth century.50Closer to the time I am concerned
with, Biberachclad its civil servantsin uniformsof Meissen cloth rather
than the English cloth that "had become too dear, and must be paid for
in ducats, doubloons, Rose Nobles and other hard talers, all of which
requireda large agio."51 Shortages in Swabia became so acute that the
authoritieson one occasion commandeereda shipmentpassing through
on its way to Switzerlandand sold the goods on the local market.
THE INCIDENCEOF DEBASEMENTAND INFLATION
Schottle, "Die grosse deutsche Geldkrise,"p. 41; and Stuart,Free Tradein Tuscany.
Schottle, "Die grosse deutsche Geldkrise,"p. 41.
52
Parker, Thirty Years' War, p. 49; Braudel, Structure of Everyday Life, p. 463; and Klima,
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
164
Kindleberger
TABLE 2
PRICESOF SELECTEDFOODSTUFFS,AUGSBURG, 1618-1624
Rye
1618
1619
1620
1621
1622
1623
1624
787
952
1153
2636
6516
2357
1938
473
544
552
1337
3729
1271
1054
Pennies per
Quart
1006
n.a.
1428
1720
6065
2895
1568
21.0
21.0
19.0
20.0
n.a.
26.2
21.0
196
189
203
420
560
140
157
35.0
35.0
38.5
84.0
224.0
52.3
52.5
21.0
n.a.
24.5
70.0
n.a.
52.5
42.0
84.0
96.7
100.6
129.5
369.2
121.0
108.0
3.50
3.50
3.50
3.50
2.65
2.67
3.01
Although we lack cost-of-living indices for that portion of the population using market rather than natural or barter economies, a crude
estimate of real income is possible using journeyman masons' daily
wages and the price of rye in Augsburg.The rough correlationof food
prices in Table 2 provides some limitedjustificationfor takingthe price
of rye as a proxy for the cost of living; it is likely, too, that bread
1C1 *
5000
50000
1000
10000
500
5000
I 00
1 000
'|
'U
'
C&D
D
'
500
100
-Ir
1550
50
1600
50
FIGURE
1700
I0
I0
50
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
165
Augsburg
Southern England
1611
1612
1613
1615
1617
1619
1621
1622
1625
1627
77
82
105
78
129
118
52
34
55
68
100
90
85
85
88
95
102
90
80
95
Source: For Augsburg, calculated from daily summer wages of journeyman masons and the price
of rye by Elsas, Geschichte der Preise, vol. 1, pp. 731-32, 395; for southern England, calculated
from Phelps Brown and Hopkins, "Seven Centuries of Prices," pp. 312-13.
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
166
Kindleberger
. .
profits than of Hippocrates and Galenus, judges forget the law, hang their
practices on the wall and let him who will read Bartholusand Baldus. The same
is true of other learnedfolk, studyingarithmeticmore than rhetoricand philosophy; merchants, retailers and other trades-people push their businesses with
short goods, which are then markedwith a mint stamp.55
56
Bogucka, "MonetaryCrisis," p. 146;Schottle, "Die grosse deutsche Geldkrise,"pp. 47, 52; and
Langer, Kulturgeschichte, p. 30.
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
167
64
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
168
Kindleberger
accelerate its minting.65The same five cities tried to join with northern
Germancities in the endeavor, but without result.
Action, when it came, began in the north with the Hanseatic cities.
Hamburgand Lubeck concludeda minttreatyin 1618.They werejoined
in January1620by the Duke of Mecklenbergin the Lower Saxon Circle
and by the city of Bremen in agreementwith Wismar. The Reichstaler
was set at 42 schillings(equalto groschen), but raisedin Aprilto 48. The
Kreistag at Lunebergin April 1621set up a commission on the minting
question. It reportedback belatedlyin 1623with recommendationsthat,
once adopted, constituted the decisive act in ending the Kipperzeitin
the Lower Saxon Circle.66
The Upper Saxon Circle came along only in 1623, but in one fell
swoop ratherthan step by step. The gradualmodel, which was followed
by the Swabian, Franconian,and Bavariancircles, was termed on one
occasion by Schottle a "gigantic error" and later "unwise."67 Many
mints in Upper Saxony had stopped producingKippergeldin 1622 and
1623because its passers could no longerget people to accept it. In June
1623, the Elector of Saxony broughttogetherthe various officialboards
and asked them five questions about currency policy. The commission
reportedthe next day in a memorandumof 26 pages that recommended
returningto the ImperialOrdinanceof 1559and setting the Reichstaler
at 24 groschen. In the following days the Elector ordereda recoinageon
that basis and the reinstitutionof the minttrials, which had been allowed
to lapse for five years.68
Shaw states that a great imperialdeputationof all the circles was
convenedin 1623to establishthe finalreturnto the AugsburgOrdinanceof
1559,but this is not treatedin the GermanliteratureI have consulted.The
valueof 1 florin,30 kreuzerto the Reichstalerlastedwith minorexceptions
as the standarduntil the Zinnaische standardof 1 florin, 45 kreuzer,
establishedin 1669in an attemptto stabilizethe currencyonce more, well
afterthe end of the war. Therewas then a still furtherdepreciationin the
Leipzig standardof 1690to 2 florins,or 120kreuzer.69
It is of some interest that Ulm producednew copper coins while the
stabilization was being worked out on a silver basis, and that in the
Upper Saxon Circle a limitedamountof credit money began to circulate
after Kippergeldcould no longer be placed-an importantstep, Wuttke
claimed, in the development of German monetary relations.70These
steps toward providing some sort of circulating medium after all
65
66
67
Schottle, "Die grosse deutsche Geldkrise," p. 53; and Schottle, "Munz- und Geldgeschichte," p. 92.
68
69
70
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
169
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
170
Kindleberger
either feathering his own nest or drunk. In any case, the invasion of
ElectoralSaxony in the ThirtyYears' Warmade any paymentof debt by
the impoverished populace impossible.73In general, different circles
and the states and cities within them workedout differentsolutions over
a period of years stretchingwell beyond the 1648Treaty of Westphalia.
The Swabian Circle laid down a rule as early as March 1622calling for
creditorsto get back when they invested-good money for good, bad for
bad-following not the letter of the law but the dictates of Christian
love. There were many exceptions to the 1622 rule, especially where
official fiscal interests were affected, and the authorities were still
strugglingwith the issue three decades later when it was decreed that all
debts remainingfrom the period were to be cut in half. Kassel in Hesse
promulgated an effective and equitable solution set out in detail by
Redlich over three pages.74One distinction was drawn between debts
contracted in money and in goods. Authorities and courts were overwhelmed for years. The comparisonholds, of course, not only with the
period after the inflationof 1919to 1923, when holders of propertyand
those who had repaid debt gained substantiallywhereas wealth in the
form of money and governmentdebt was wiped out, but also with the
Lastenausgleich associated with the Monetary Reform of 1948 after
World War II, which together reduced all fixed claims to wealth by 90
percent and imposed a mortgageof 50 percent on real property.
CONCLUSION
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
171
Banque et credit en Italie, vol. 2, pp. 149-52, 187; and Elsas, Geschichte der Preise.
77 Friedrichs,Urban Society in an Age of War, p. 148.
78 Spooner, Monetary Movements in France, p. 65.
79
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
172
Kindleberger
REFERENCES
Attman, Artur,AmericanBullion in the EuropeanWorldTrade,1600-1800(Goteborg,
1986).
Barbour, Violet, Capitalismand Amsterdamin the Seventeenth Century(paperback
edn., Ann Arbor, MI, 1966).
Bernholz, Peter, "Currency Competition, Inflation, Gresham's Law and Exchange
Rate," Journal of Institutionaland TheoreticalEconomics, 145 (Sept. 1989), pp.
469-88.
Bisson, ThomasN., Conservationof Coinage:MonetaryExploitationand Its Restraint
in France, Catalonia and Aragon, c 1000-1225A.D. (Oxford, 1979).
Bogucka, Maria, "The Monetary Crisis of the XVIIth Century and Its Social and
PsychologicalConsequencesin Poland," Journalof EuropeanEconomic History,
4 (Spring 1975),pp. 137-52.
Braudel,Fernand, The Structureof EverydayLife, vol. 1 of Civilization& Capitalism,
l5th-18th Century(New York, 1986).
Braudel, Fernand, The Wheels of Commerce, vol. 2 of Civilization & Capitalism,
15th-18thCentury(New York, 1986).
Chaudhuri,K. M., TheEnglishEast India Company:TheStudyof an EarlyJoint-Stock
Company, 1600-1640(London, 1965).
de Roover, Greshamon Foreign Exchange:An Essay on Early English Mercantilism
(Cambridge,MA, 1949).
dtv (Deutscher TaschenbuchVerlag), Atlas zur Weltgeschichte,Karten und Chronologischer Abriss, vol. 1, Von den Anfangen bis zur Franzoischen Revolution
(Munich, 1964).
de Vries, Jan, The Economy of Europe in the Age of Crisis, 1600-1750 (New York,
1976).
Ehrenberg,Richard,Capitaland Finance in the Age of the Renaissance:A Study of the
Fuggers, translatedfrom the 1898Germanedn. (New York, 1928).
Einaudi, Luigi, "The Theory of ImaginaryMoney from Charlemagneto the French
Revolution," translatedfrom the Italianof 1936,in F. C. Lane and J. C. Riersma,
eds., Enterpriseand Secular Change (Homewood, IL, 1953),pp. 229-61.
Ellis, Howard E., GermanMonetaryTheory,1905-1933(Cambridge,MA, 1934).
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
173
Elsas, M. J., Umriss einer Geschichte der Preise und Lohne in Deutschland, 3 vols.
(Princeton, 1979).
Gaettens, Richard,Geschichte des Inflationen,2nd edn. (Minden, 1986).
Glamann, Kristof, "European Trade, 1500-1750," in Carlo M. Cipolla, ed., The
Fontana Economic History of Europe: The Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries
(Cambridge,MA, 1954).
Henning, Friederich-Wilhelm, Das vorindustrielle Deutschland, 800 bis 1800 (Pader-
born, 1974).
Hobsbawm, E. J., "The Crisis of the Seventeenth Century," in Trevor Aston, ed.,
Crisis in Europe, 1560-1660: Essays from Past and Present (London, 1965), pp.
5-58.
(Paris, 1954).
Judge, A. V., "PhilipBurlamachi:A Financierof the ThirtyYears' War," Economica,
6 (Nov. 1926),pp. 285-300.
Kellenbenz, Hermann, Sephardim an der unteren Elbe: Ihre wirtschaftliche und
politische Bedeutung von Ende des 16. bis zum Beginn des 18. Jahrhunderts
(Wiesbaden, 1958).
Kindleberger,C. P., "InternationalPropagationof FinancialCrises:The Experienceof
1886-1893," in C. P. Kindleberger, Keynesianism vs. Monetarism and Other
Essays in Financial History (London, 1985), pp. 226-39.
Kindleberger, C. P., Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, 2nd
1978),pp. 375-86.
Langer, Herbert, Kulturgeschichte des 30 jahriges Krieges (Leipzig, 1978).
Macauley, Thomas Babington, History of Englandfrom the Accession of James II, vol.
4 (London, 1948).
Olson, Mancur,"Some Questionsabout the WeimarRepublicand Possible Parallelsin
the Developed Democracies Today," in Peter Koslowski, ed., IndividualLiberty
and Democratic Decision-Making (Tubingen, 1987), pp. 127-41.
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
174
Kindleberger
M. Cipolla, ed., The Fontana Economic History of Europe: The Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries (Glasgow, 1974), pp. 529-94.
(Cambridge,MA, 1976).
Redlich, Fritz, De Praeda Militari: Looting and Booty, 1500-1815, Beihefte 39 to
Viertelsjahrschrift fur Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 1956.
Redlich, Fritz, Die deutsche Inflation des fruhen 17. Jahrhunderts in der zeitgenossischen Literatur: Die Kipper und Wipper (Cologne, 1972).
Romano, Ruggerio, "Italy in the Crisis of the Seventeenth Century," in Peter Earle,
ed., Essays in European Economic History, 1500-1800 (Oxford, 1974), pp. 185-98.
Schottle, Gustav, "Die grosse deutsche Geldkrise von 1620-23 und ihr Verlauf in
Oberschwaben,"
31 (1922-1924),pp. 54-128.
Shaw, William A., The History of Currency (London, 1895).
1493-1725(Cambridge,MA, 1972).
Steinberg,SiegfriedHenry, "The ThirtyYears' War:EconomicLife," in Encyclopedia
Britannica, 14thedn. (1968), vol. 21 (Soelman-Timmins),p. 1060.
Stuart, James Montgomery, The History of Free Trade in Tuscany, with Remarks on Its
Progress in the Rest of Italy (London, 1876).
Supple, Barry E., "Thomas Mun and the CommercialCrisis, 1623," Bulletin of the
Institute of Historical Research, 27 (May 1954), pp. 91-94.
Supple, Barry E., "Currency and Commerce in the Early Seventeenth Century,"
Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 10 (May 1957), pp. 239-55.
Supple, Barry E., Commercial Crisis and Change in England, 1600-1642 (Cambridge,
1959).
Thirsk, Joan, and J. P. Cooper, eds., Seventeenth-Century Economic Documents
(Oxford, 1972).
Tilly, Richard, Financial Institutions and Industrialization in the Rhineland, 1815-1870
1965),pp. 59-75.
van der Wee, Herman, "IndustrialDynamics and the Process of Urbanizationand
De-urbanizationin the Low Countriesfromthe Late MiddleAges to the Eighteenth
Century: A Synthesis," in Herman van der Wee, ed., The Rise and Decline of
Urban Industries in Italy and the Low Countries (Late Middle Ages-Early Modern
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
175
Vilar, Pierre, A History of Gold and Money, 1450-1920, translated from the 1969
Spanishoriginal(London, 1976).
Wilson, Charles, The Transformation of Europe, 1558-1648 (Berkeley, 1976).
This content downloaded from 208.94.131.72 on Tue, 26 Jan 2016 21:01:25 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions