Monetising Privacy
Monetising Privacy
Monetising Privacy
Ac(u) (1 )Ac(u)
| |
( )
we have a symmetric equilibrium with
j d d
j
= ,
*
and q p p
B A
= =
* *
. Firms subsidise consumers and make zero profits.
42
This
equilibrium is efficient since ) (u c q A > implies that the gains from high data requirements are
higher than consumers cost. Efficiency thus requires that both firms choose d .
With
Ac(u) s q s
1
Ac(u) (1 )Ac(u)
| |
firms play a market segmenting asymmetric
equilibrium with d d
A
=
*
and d d
B
=
*
. In this equilibrium consumers with u u =
i
buy from firm
A while others buy from firm B. For prices it holds that
* *
A B
p p > . Note, however, that this
equilibrium is inefficient as efficiency still requires that all consumers provide a large amount
of personal data.
Case 2: Now, turn to the case that )) ( ), ( ( u u c c q A A e .
In this case we get two asymmetric equilibria with the firm, which chooses d d
j
=
*
attracting
all consumers with u u =
i
. These equilibria are efficient as q only outweighs the increased
cost for one group of consumers and firms make positive profits.
Case 3: The final case left is that ) (u c q A s .
If in addition
q >
1
1
Ac(u) Ac(u)
| |
holds, we again get an inefficient market segmentation
in an asymmetric equilibrium with d d
A
=
*
and d d
B
=
*
. Prices are now such that
* *
B A
p p < and
profits are positive.
If
q < min Ac(u),
1
1
Ac(u) Ac(u)
| |
( )
, we get an efficient equilibrium with j d d
j
= ,
*
and
0
* *
= =
B A
p p . Firms make profits equal to zero.
Summarising the cases we get asymmetric equilibria with positive profits for intermediate
values of q, which are efficient only if )) ( ), ( ( u u c c q A A e . For very high (low) values of q we
get efficient symmetric equilibria with both firms choosing the high (low) data requirement. In
the laboratory and field we test whether there is a significant share of consumers with a high
privacy concern that choose a privacy-friendly firm, if both firms are differentiated from each
other.
42
Subsidisation occurs when firms provide consumers with a platform where they can store information and earn
money with it; see also Lohr, S. (2010), You Want My Personal Data? Reward Me for It, New York Times, 17 July
2010, https://www.nytimes.com/2010/07/18/business/18unboxed.html
22
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
5.2.1.2 General version with positive transportation costs
We now solve a general version of the one-period model with positive transportation cost.
The firms pricing strategies now change drastically, because they are ex-ante differentiated.
We solve the game by backward induction, starting with consumers choices for given sets of
data requirements and prices.
Solving for the critical consumer (denoted with superscript c), who is indifferent between the
two firms A and B, depending on the type yields:
r
d c d c p p
i
B
i
A
i
B A
i
c
c c
c
2
) , ( ) , (
2
1
) (
u u
u
+
=
Market shares can now be denoted by:
)) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ( ) ( u u
c c
j
i i j L n + =
with location 0 ) ( = A L and 1 ) ( = B L .
Then solving for firm Bs reaction function in prices yields:
p
B
-
=
1
2
(r + p
A
+ (c(u,d
A
) c(u,d
B
)) +(1 )(c(u,d
A
) c(u,d
B
)) qo
B
)
The pricing function indicates the following:
- The higher the cost firm B imposes on consumers compared to the cost firm A imposes
on them, the lower will be firm Bs price.
- Firm Bs optimal prices increase, if the unit transportation cost r rises, as it becomes
more costly to choose the firm which is located further away from ones own location.
- The decision to have a high data requirement and the pricing decisions are strategic
substitutes. Thus, if firm B requires d ,
-
B
p decreases.
Comparing profits under the two different data requirements leads to the following decision:
> A + A
=
-
otherwise ,
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if ,
d
q c c d
d
B
u u
Note that ) , ( ) , ( ) ( d c d c c
i i i
u u u = A and thus firm Bs data requirement decision is
independent of As data requirement.
In the next step, solving for As pricing function in general yields:
p
A
-
=
1
2
(3r (c(u,d
A
) c(u,d
B
)) (1 )(c(u,d
A
) c(u,d
B
)) qo
A
qo
B
)
Under q c c > A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u comparing As profits for the different data requirements
leads to the following equilibrium:
23
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
(d
A
-
= d, p
A
-
=
3r
2
),(d
B
-
= d, p
B
-
=
5r
4
)
If q c c < A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u , the same comparison of profits leads to the equilibrium:
(d
A
-
= d, p
A
-
=
3r 2q
2
),(d
B
-
= d, p
B
-
=
5r 4q
4
)
In both equilibria we obtain market shares of:
n
A
-
=
3
8
, n
B
-
=
5
8
Note that both equilibria are symmetric and efficient in terms of comparing the benefits from
high data requirements and the average cost for providing personal data. Symmetry comes
from the fact that once a certain data choice is optimal for one of the firms it also has to be
optimal for the other firm, as these choices balance the firms benefits from high data
requirements and the negative impact on their demand.
5.2.2 Two-period model
In this model consumers not only make a choice on the firm, but also whether to have
personalisation or not. This leads to the following maximisation problem for the consumers:
b c d c i j r p v u
i j i t j
t
i
j j
| | u u
|
+ =
=
) , ( )) , ( ( ) ( max arg
,
2
1
, ,
2 1
with 1 = | if the consumer opts for personalisation and 0 = | otherwise as well as 1 =
if
2 1
j j = , and
2 1
if 0 j j = =
,
i.e. the benefit from personalisation b can only be received if
the same firm is chosen in both periods. In the laboratory experiment, we call these buyers
loyals.
The firms profit function is the sum of the firms profits in both periods with consumers
buying at price
t j
p
,
plus the exogenous benefit q if d d
j
= for each consumer. Thus firms
maximise:
( ) q d p n
j t j t j
t
j
d p p
j j j
) ( ) ( max arg
, ,
2
1
, ,
2 , 1 ,
o + = H
=
Again, it holds that } 1 , 0 { ) ( e
j
d o with 1 ) ( = d o and 0 ) ( = d o and we will write
j
o for ) (
j
d o .
The consumers decisions to have their products personalised are influenced by a trade-off
between the costs and benefits of personalisation. A consumer only chooses a personalised
product if b c
i
< ) 1 , (u . But as consumers can only realise the benefit under the condition that
2 1
j j = rational expectations may lead them to strategically avoid personalisation in order to
prevent being locked in in the second period.
43
This can be the case if, for instance, the price
43
We note that a more realistic assumption might be that consumers are not aware that personalisation can lead
to lock-in. However, in the laboratory, most participants behaved rationally. We observed few switchers that
stored their data, but still switched.
24
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
differences are such that the firm charging a lower price in the first period charges a higher
price in the second period. If the net difference is higher than the net benefit for the
consumer, this consumer may choose not to have the product personalised although
b c
i
< ) 1 , (u . Due to this reason, there can be no equilibria in which consumers personalise and
switch firms in the model.
Turning to the different cases and defining ) 1 , ( ) ( u u c b b = A , we have to consider the
following three scenarios (note that ) 1 , ( ) 1 , ( u u c c s also implies ) ( ) ( u u b b A > A ):
a) No consumer chooses to get a personalised product: ) ( ) ( 0 u u b b A > A >
b) Only those with a low concern choose to personalise: ) ( 0 ) ( u u b b A > > A
and do not
switch
c) All consumers have their product personalised 0 ) ( ) ( > A > A u u b b
and do not switch.
5.2.2.1 Special case with transportation costs equal to zero
Again, we start by considering the case with transportation cost of zero, which mimics the
online environment of the experiment. Comparing the one- and two-period model and
considering the impact of personalisation on the firms decisions with respect to their data
requirements, we have two counteracting effects. On the one hand firms have a higher
incentive to differentiate their products by choosing different data requirements, which
increases the parameter range, where inefficient equilibria exist. Only by differentiating are
firms able to make positive profits in both periods.
On the other hand, personalisation abates this effect as it allows firms to make positive profits
even if they choose the same data requirements. These profits require transferring surplus
from consumers to the firm, but as the possibility of personalisation increases welfare,
consumers may still be better off in equilibrium. To analyse these two effects we first consider
the case in which no consumer opts for personalisation. The impact of personalisation is
analysed in the next subsection, where we assume that only consumers with u have an
incentive to opt for personalisation. In the following, we restrict the analysis to the case with
no personalisation as well as the case with a share of consumers personalising.
5.2.2.1.1 No personalisation: ) ( ) ( 0 u u b b A > A >
The range of inefficient market segmentations, where consumers with a low (high) privacy
concern choose the firm with the high (low) data requirement, increases in this scenario.
44
This is due to the fact that differentiating from the competitor becomes more attractive, as
there is two times the surplus to be extracted from consumers, compared with the one-period
model. Still, symmetric equilibria, which are efficient, exist if is sufficiently high or low. In
the first case it becomes too attractive to choose the high data requirement, while in the
second case it becomes too prohibitive to impose high costs on consumers, so that firms
44
A detailed formal analysis is provided in the appendix of this report.
q
25
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
rather refuse to differentiate. For intermediate values of q the asymmetric equilibria are
efficient.
5.2.2.1.2 Personalisation with ) ( 0 ) ( u u b b A > > A
We solve the model for different kinds of parameterisations. Starting with an intermediate
value of , we derive several different kinds of equilibria. Similar to the case with
) ( ) ( 0 u u b b A > A > these equilibria are symmetric for either high or low values of . For
intermediate values of we get asymmetric equilibria. However, due to the lock-in effect
even symmetric equilibria allow firms to make positive profits, as they are able to extract
some surplus from their consumers, without losing too many of them to the competitor.
For other parameterisations, i.e. for
3
2
) ( = A u c ,
3
1
) ( = A u c and
4
1
= as well as
4
3
= , we
obtain the result that only asymmetric equilibria exist for a wide range of parameters q and b.
In all cases except for one, Firm A chooses to be the firm with the high data requirement. Only
in one case, where q is comparably low, does Firm A choose to be the firm with the low data
requirement.
45
Firms choices are simulated in the laboratory and field by implementing
different situations, i.e. situations where firms are similar in their offers and situations where
they differ on the data requirements. The experiment would otherwise have become too
complicated, also from a data protection point of view.
46
Comparing the firms profits shows that Firm B may lose its second mover advantage, which is
usually found in models where firms compete on prices and decide sequentially. This is due to
the fact that in an equilibrium, where consumers are segmented, Firm A (being the first
mover) is able to secure all consumers with a low concern. These consumers react more
strongly to price increases, but as they are at the same time choosing to get their product
personalised, they are also prone to lock-in. Therefore, firm A is able to extract more surplus
from its consumers in the second period and thereby can gain higher overall profits under
most parameterisations.
5.2.2.2 General version with positive transportation costs
Under the scenario that no consumer chooses to have the product personalised, we get a
simple repetition of the pricing game. Thus, the equilibria are as in the one-period model with
j p p
j j
=
- -
,
2 , 1 ,
. In all cases where at least some of the consumers have an incentive to choose
personalisation the solution of the second period requires solving the whole game. The reason
is that consumers who choose to personalise base their decision of firm choice in the first
period on the expected prices in the second period: with rational expectations no consumer
who anticipates that it is optimal for him to buy from different firms would opt for
45
However, one may also be able to replicate the result of symmetric equilibria in case of extreme values of q, if
less parameters were fixed.
46
For example, we would have to introduce strategic players (participants) that act as firms. However, in an
experiment with true personal data disclosed, we create additional data protection problems, if other participants
(and not the experimenter) collect this information.
1/ 2 =
q
q
26
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
personalisation. As along as consumers anticipate rather high price differences in the second
period, avoidance of personalisation may be the optimal behaviour.
47
Moreover, as the
fraction of consumers who opted for personalisation in the first period also determines the
equilibrium prices in the second period, second-period prices and first-period decisions and
demands are interdependent. The implied maximisation problem of the firms becomes rather
complex; therefore we focus on the case with ) ( 0 ) ( u u b b A > > A , as it features consumers
who choose to personalise as well as those who refuse personalisation. Using the result from
the one-period model with positive transportation costs, we also restrict the analysis to
symmetric equilibria. As already provides differentiation between firms, the
differentiation tool of choosing different data requirements becomes obsolete. Thus, if it is
beneficial for one of the firms to choose it is also beneficial for the other. We still have
two different scenarios as equilibrium candidates. The first is one where not all consumers
with u opt for personalisation, but instead switch the firm they buy from. The second
scenario is such that all consumers with u opt for personalisation and do not switch firms.
Concerning the first candidate and taking into account equilibria with both interior and corner
solutions for the firms pricing decisions, we can show that no equilibrium exists where some
of the consumers with u switch. With interior solutions the difference between firms optimal
prices is too low in order to compensate consumers for losing their personalisation benefit,
which means that none of them would want to switch (the respective equilibrium does not
exist). Considering corner solutions, where firms set the maximum price within certain
intervals, all consumers would either choose Firm A or Firm B in the second period. However,
the maximum prices, which allow for such a scenario, are also not part of an equilibrium, as it
gives the firm which would be without consumers in the second period high incentives to
marginally reduce its price in order to attract at least some consumers who did not
personalise.
Turning to the second scenario, where all personalising consumers are loyal and focusing on
interior equilibria in which both firms serve both types of consumers, the analysis shows that
the firms equilibrium profits do not depend on or on . These results resemble the results
obtained in the one-period model. They are based upon the fact that the firms pricing
behaviour is driven by the marginal profits from attracting additional consumers. Moreover,
analysing the firms profits with respect to , i.e. the fraction of consumers who do not
personalise, shows that the firms profits are the higher the lower and thus the higher the
number of personalising consumers. Intuitively, the more consumers that personalise the
more consumers are locked in in the second period and the higher the firms equilibrium
prices and profits. A similar but more complex reasoning holds for the firms pricing strategies
in the first period. Although firms try to attract a high number of personalising consumers by
charging low prices, firms also take into account that price competition in the second period
47
In order to focus on the differences in data requirements and prices in the experiment, we avoided prices
changes from one period to the next. The participants were informed that prices remained constant. Note that i n
the laboratory the two-period model without transportation costs was implemented.
0 r >
j
d d =
q b
27
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
tends to be less intense if the firms market shares in the first period are rather symmetric.
This holds especially for Firm , which can anticipate that the price Firm will choose in
the second period is the higher the more personalising consumers Firm has attracted in the
first period. The last effect dominates the first and the firms first-period equilibrium prices
will be the higher the more consumers personalise. Summarising these results indicates that
while the consumers benefits from personalisation do not affect the firms pricing strategies
directly, personalisation induces different strategic effects, which soften price competition
and lead to higher firms profits.
The Annex contains the technical background of this model.
B A
A
28
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
6 The privacy experiments
We now discuss the design, experimental protocol and results from the different types of
experiments we conducted: the laboratory experiment, hybrid and field experiment. These
are complementary to each other. The laboratory is a controlled environment, where the
participants know that they are part of an experiment. Participants are students at a
university in Berlin. The hybrid is a combination of laboratory and field, because we invited
students from the experimental pool to a website on the Internet, where they could do a
purchase transaction online without coming to the laboratory. Finally, in the field the
participants do not know that they are part of an experiment and they must not be students,
but come from the Internet-using population as a whole.
6.1 Translation of the model into the experiment
We implemented a simplified two-period version of the model without transportation costs.
The implementation is described in detail below. In essence we tested the following aspects:
whether there are different types of consumers with different privacy concerns, as well as
their firm choice and switching behaviour. The following situations were implemented:
- Two-period version of the model with zero transportation costs and with both firms
choosing the same data requirements and prices. This version contains the
personalisation option for consumers as well as constant prices;
48
- Two-period version with one firm choosing a low data requirement and the other a
high data requirement either with or without price differences. This version also
contains the personalisation option and constant prices.
There were two real private companies (Event Sales and Cine Sales) offering the tickets over
the Internet. Their offers were placed right next to each other in order to obtain a scenario
with no transportation costs. Note that strategic firm behaviour as in the model was not
implemented in the laboratory, because the firms were computerised. Moreover,
participants were informed that prices do not change across periods. This restriction was
implemented to preclude participants disclosing their personal data to other (human)
participants, which could create severe data protection problems outside of the laboratory.
6.2 Laboratory experiment
Laboratory experiments are widely used in economics for the analysis of economic incentives
and decisions of individuals by involving them in real tasks and actions. Moreover, they can be
used to test theories or assumptions of theories. The actions of individuals do have real
monetary and information implications for the individuals, which makes this research very
different from survey-based research; see section 3 of this report.
48
To enable a focus on and a testing of the reaction of consumers with respect to the difference in the data
requirements only, we held the prices constant across periods. This was necessary in order to reduce the
variation in stimuli.
29
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
6.2.1 Place, time period and participants
We conducted the experiment at the Technical University of Berlin in Berlin, Germany,
between June and November 2011.
49
Altogether 443 students of different disciplines
participated, which makes this experiment the largest laboratory experiment on the
economics of privacy to date. The students who participated are registered in a student pool
and they were invited to the lab sessions with a neutral email invitation. While they knew that
they were participating in an experiment, they were aware that they were carrying out
transactions on a live website on the Internet. They had no details about the ultimate purpose
of the experiment and did not know that it was about personal data disclosure in particular.
6.2.2 Design of the laboratory experiment
The invitation was framed in a neutral way by referring to an economic experiment only. This
way, we avoided pre-selection effects that might arise if the experiment only attracted
individuals who were interested in privacy matters.
50
Participation was voluntary. After
admission to the laboratory, the participants were given the instructions for the experiment.
These instructions explained the rules of the experiment in simple terms. After signing the
consent form to participate, each participant started the experiment by doing a brief
comprehension test that allowed us to ensure that instructions were well understood by the
students. Participants used a website in the laboratory that is similar to the field website. The
website is an Internet portal of providers of cinema tickets. On this website, they could
choose a cinema and showing and then purchase the ticket from one of the two firms
providing the tickets (Figure 2 shows a screenshot from the field experiment, Table 1 shows
the different treatments). The difference between the firms is described below. After the
finalisation of the purchase, the participants could repeat the transaction if they wanted to
buy a second ticket. Only the repetition ensures that we can observe switching behaviour and
it ensures that we implement the two-period model.
N No ot te e: : I In n t th he e l la ab bo or ra at to or ry y, , h hy yb br ri id d a an nd d f fi ie el ld d, , a al ll l c co om mp po on ne en nt ts s o of f t th he e c co om mp po os si it te e t tr ra an ns sa ac ct ti io on n w we er re e
r re ea al l, , m me ea an ni in ng g t th he e c co ol ll le ec ct ti io on n o of f p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a, , t th he e c ci in ne em ma a t ti ic ck ke et ts s s so ol ld d a an nd d t th he e p pa ay ym me en nt t w wi it th h
t th he e p pa ar rt ti ic ci ip pa an nt ts s o ow wn n m mo on ne ey y. . P Pa ar rt ti ic ci ip pa an nt ts s w we er re e n no ot t d de ec ce ei iv ve ed d, , e ei it th he er r a ab bo ou ut t t th he e t tr ra an ns sa ac ct ti io on n, , t th he e
f fi ir rm ms s, , t th he e d da at ta a c co ol ll le ec ct ti io on n, , o or r d da at ta a u us sa ag ge e. .
Participants could compare the offers of the two firms and choose the offer they liked best or
not purchase at all, because purchase was voluntary. We varied the differences between the
two firms in order to extract the effects of one firm requesting more information than the
other or the effect of different data usages. Regardless of the firm chosen, each purchase was
subsidised by the experimenters by 2, resulting in residual prices as low as 3 per cinema
ticket even for peak cinema times.
49
Two pilots were conducted, one in June and one in July. The main sessions then took place in August, September
and November.
50
This interest or motivation could be associated with experimental outcomes and therefore bias the results
obtained in this study.
30
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Figure 2 Order summary and choice of firms
At the end of the experiment the participants filled out an exit questionnaire, paid the
subsidised ticket price, obtained the ticket/s and left the laboratory. A show-up fee was paid
out and set off against any outstanding payments for the purchases made. Individuals who did
not purchase anything obtained only the show-up fee, as is common in experimental
research. Note that the participants had to pay the outstanding balance with their own
money. This way we avoided budget effects and gambling arising from money given to the
participants upfront, before the experiment took place.
In order to extract the effect that differences in data requirements between firms make on
purchase behaviour, we varied the stimulus. The situations with a varied stimulus were then
compared to a basic control treatment in which the firms are similar. Next, the difference
between the offers of the two firms were either: (a) differences in number of data items
required from the participant; (b) differences in data items required and differences in prices;
(c) differences in data usage, while both firms have the same prices; and (d) differences in
data usage and prices; see Table 1.
We conducted two pilot sessions with 48 participants aimed at testing the design. In the
treatments with price difference and different number of items, the privacy-invasive firm
31
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
charged a ticket price 0.50 below its competitor.
51
The pilots showed that a 0.50 price
difference leads to a noticeable variation in behaviour of the participants; they do not all
choose the same firm, but vary in their choice.
Table 1 Variation in treatments
Treatment Settings (Variations)
1 Difference in data usage
Difference in prices
Privacy policy exists at both firms
2 Difference in data usage
Same prices
Privacy policy exists at both firms
3 Difference in number of data items
Difference in prices
Privacy policy exists at both firms
4 Difference in number of data items
Same prices
Privacy policy exists at both firms
5 Same information items
Same prices
Privacy policy exists at both firms
In the basic control treatment (5 in Table 1), the firms are identical with regard to the prices
and/or their data requirements. This is our benchmark scenario. In the other treatments,
either the prices or the data requirements are varied. Note that prices remain constant from
one period to the next in all treatments.
Difference in data requirements: Both firms in the experiment always asked for a minimum
set of personal data such as full name, email address and date of birth. Depending on the
treatment, the stimulus in data collection was either: (a) the collection of additional data
items (such as mobile phone number) by the privacy-unfriendly firm; or (b) the usage of the
email address for advertising at the privacy-unfriendly firm.
In order to create incentive compatibility, we implemented a lie detection device that
ensured truthful revelation of actual personal data by participants. While this can affect
external validity, it ensures that individuals have a real privacy concern. As explained above, if
participants have the opportunity to misstate personal information, they can cushion
potentially negative effects arising from its disclosure. We introduced a mechanism in which
we verified the students personal data. Participants knew that once they provided wrong
information their payoff would collapse to zero. Any incorrect personal data was detected
51
We chose this to be below the 1 Euro price difference in Beresford et al. (2010).
32
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
with 100% probability, because the research assistants checked the data provided by all
buyers in the laboratory.
6.3 Results from the laboratory experiment
As stated, there were 443 participants in the laboratory experiment including 24 participants
in the second pilot, where we did identity verification.
52
Of these 443 people, 40.41% were
women and 59.59% men. In the general population in Germany, there are 51% women and
49% men. However, in the German population there is a higher share of men (about 80%)
who use the Internet, compared to 70% of women.
53
Summary statistics: The purchase statistics are given in Table 2. Across the whole sample
(n=443), 251 individuals did not buy any tickets, 40 bought only one and 152 bought two
tickets, which is a relatively high share of two-time buyers (57%). Among those who bought
two times, 142 (93.42%) stayed with the firm they had chosen in the first period and only 10
switched (6.58% of two-time buyers).
54
Therefore, by far the larger share remained with the
same company. Note that this is the sample across all treatments, some of which have
variations in prices or data requirements, although there is no variation over the two periods
in those.
Furthermore, there is no significant difference in terms of privacy concern or interest in data
protection between the buyers and non-buyers. This means that the purchase action does not
seem to introduce a pre-selection effect in terms of attracting only individuals that have little
to no privacy concern or little to no interest in data protection.
55
In the analysis below, we disaggregate the different treatments, because these differences
influence the decision of individuals in terms of which company they choose. Interestingly,
there were 10 people who switched from one firm to another. Whereas 9 people switched
from Firm 1 to Firm 2, one person switched from 2 to 1. Three of the 10 switchers did not
store data and seven individuals stored data, but still switched to the other company in the
second period to buy their tickets there. These people had to re-enter the information at the
new company. Note that the instructions clearly explained to individuals that prices remained
constant across periods. In the exit questionnaire, we could probe the reasons for switching.
All switchers recognised that they had bought from different firms. Some mentioned that they
randomised, because prices were the same; others wanted to try out the other firm.
Therefore, there seems to be no systematic behavioural bias.
52
We did two pilots for the experiment: one without identity verification and one with identity verification. Only
data of the latter was included in the laboratory dataset.
53
Initiative D21 e. V.; TNS Infratest (2008, 2011): (N)Onliner-Atlas.
54
Those that stayed with the same firm were defined by us as loyals and those two-time buyers that did not
were defined as switchers. If we refer to both types of buyers (loyals and switchers), we refer to two-time buyers.
55
We conducted the Mann-Whitney test on differences in medians as well as t-tests to analyse if there is a
difference between the group of non-buyers and the group of buyers who bought at least one ticket in either
period. The latter variable also included two-time buyers.
33
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Table 2 Overview statistics (whole sample, all treatments)
Overview Statistics
Number
Percentage of
total
Bought at Firm 1
(privacy-friendly)
Bought at Firm 2
(privacy-
unfriendly)
Participants (across periods, percentage of total)
- Did not buy any ticket 251 56.66 - -
- Bought one ticket 40 9.03 - -
- Bought two tickets 152 34.31 - -
Total 443 100.00
Two-time buyers
No. of two-time buyers 152
- of which are loyal to same firm 142 93.42 59 (41.55%) 83 (58.45%)
* loyals who stored data 27 (45.76% of 59)
49 (59.04% of 83)
- of which are switchers
10
6.58
9 persons switched from Firm 1 to 2; one
person switched from 2 to Firm 1
Total 152 100.00
6.3.1 Privacy concern and interest in data protection
In the questionnaire, we collected answers to a number of questions related to the
participants purchase experience, trust and risk perceptions as well as data protection.
Moreover, we used the instrument developed in Smith et al. (1996) on measuring the privacy
concern of individuals. The instrument is a battery of 15 questions, where answers are given
on a Likert scale, ranging from strong disagreement to strong agreement with higher values
denoting higher concern. We have calculated the average and median across individuals (see
Figure 3 for the average).
This figure shows that the there is a high frequency of individuals (over 361 out of 443
participants) with an elevated privacy concern. Note that we posed these 15 questions in an
exit questionnaire. When using data from the whole sample, the privacy concern (median) is
weakly correlated with the choice of the firm in period 1 (Pearson coefficient 0.0953, p-
value=0.0449). But the choice is not correlated with the average privacy concern.
Apart from the 15 questions used for calculating the privacy concern, we asked one additional
question on the interest in the practices of organisations with regard to protecting personal
data. The answers to this question were not used in the computation of the privacy concern.
34
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
The overwhelming majority of participants in the laboratory experiment revealed that they
are either interested or very interested in whether a firm protects their information (about
93%). Only about 0.7% of participants stated that they are not interested at all if
organizations that collect personal data also protect this information.
Figure 3 Privacy concern among participants
6.3.2 Monetising privacy
Do some people pay for privacy? Meaning, do some individuals value their privacy enough to
pay a mark-up at the firm which collects less information? Or asked in a different way, would
it pay for firms to differentiate according to the concern for privacy of consumers? In order to
analyse this question, we conducted a number of statistical tests that allowed us to compare
the different aforementioned treatments. To obtain results, we compare the average
outcome of the treatment and control group in terms of purchases conducted at Firm 1.
56
For
example, we can compare the basic control treatment 5 with identical firms (same data
requirements and same prices) with the treatment 4 (different number of data items and
same prices).
57
In the latter treatment, one firm requests more information than the other,
meaning that both firms are differentiated. Since participants are randomly assigned to
treatments we can be sure to capture a causal effect. If we compare the treatment 4 (same
prices and different number of data items) to treatment 3 (different prices and different
number of data items) we are able to extract the effect of a price difference in terms of shares
of purchases at firms that differ on the number of data items they collect. In the following, all
numbers are rounded; see Table 3 and 4.
Comparison of treatment 4 and treatment 5: We now compare the situation in which firms
are identical (treatment 5) to the situation where they vary on the number of items they
56
Switchers were encoded in the variables that measured purchases as missing values. We also ran the test with
inclusion of switchers in these variables, but the test results do not change much.
57
The privacy policies were always equal at both firms to avoid introducing an additional stimulus.
1 1
4
11
22
43
107
175
79
0
5
0
1
0
0
1
5
0
2
0
0
F
r
e
q
u
e
n
c
y
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Privacy concern - average
35
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
collect (treatment 4). We vary only one stimulus (number of data items collected) from one
treatment to the next such that we can be sure of the effect of the stimulus. Moreover, both
firms offers are located right next to each other on the website, such that the difference in
data collection is rather obvious to the buyer. We find that the market share of Firm 1, the
privacy-friendly firm, is significantly higher in treatment 4 compared to treatment 5.
Table 3 Overview of buyers and their purchases at both firms: all
Treat
ment
Number
of parti-
cipants
(no.
buyers)
No.
buyers
Total
no.
tickets
sold
Firm 1
(tickets
purchased) Total no.
tickets
over two
periods
(Firm 1)
Firm 1
%-share
of all
tickets
sold
(col. 4)
rounded
Firm 2
(tickets
purchased)
Total no.
tickets
over two
periods
(Firm 2)
Firm 2
%-share of
all tickets
sold
(col. 4)
rounded
Zero, one
or two
tickets
bought
Period
1
Period
2
Period
1
Period
2
(1) (2) (3)** (4)** (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)
1
***
104
(51)
0 - 53
1 - 7
2 - 44
95
7 5
12
13%
42
41
83
87%
2
68
(32)
0 - 36
1 - 9
2 - 23
55
20 14
34
62%
10
11
21
38%
3
***
80
(37)
0 - 43
1 - 6
2 - 31
68
12 9
21
31%
25
22
47
69%
4
69
(31)
0 - 38
1 - 4
2 - 27
58
26
22
48
83%
4
6
10
17%
5
122
(41)
0 - 81
1 - 14
2 - 27
68
27 15
42
62%
13
13
26
38%
Total 443
344 92 65 157 Avg. 50% 94 93 187 Avg. 50%
*
There is no difference between firms in treatment 5; in all other treatments Firm 2 is the privacy-unfriendly firm.
**
Column
(3) adds up to the number of buyers in column (2). The column means that in treatment 1, seven buyers bought one ticket
and 44 bought two tickets. Column (4) is based upon these numbers.
***
In these treatments, price differences exist.
The difference between the treatment groups is statistically significant based upon the Mann-
Whitney tests at the conventional .05-significance level.
58
If there are no price differences and
data requirement differences, over 60% of market share in terms of purchases is picked up by
Firm 1. This increases to 83% if there are differences in data requirements. If we do the
analysis only with loyals, ignoring one-time buyers, the share of tickets sold to loyals of Firm 1
is higher in treatment 4 compared to treatment 5. Thus, if it is very obvious that one firm
collects more information than the other, all else being equal, a majority of purchases are
made at the privacy-friendly firm.
58
In more technical terms, the null hypothesis of the Mann-Whitney test is that there is equality in medians. If the test result is
not significant, this null cannot be rejected, such that there is not a detectable difference between the groups. We also
conducted Chi
2
-tests as well as t-tests. These results were significant as well, but are not reported here.
36
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
This is in line with the literature stating that consumers take privacy protection into account,
once it is more salient in the purchase (Tsai et al. 2010; Gideon et al. 2006). In our case, the
differences in data collection efforts are obvious in treatment 4. Since consumers had the
offers right next to each other, they could compare which information was required from
them by the firms.
Comparison of treatment 3 and treatment 4: Next is the comparison of the situation where
firms vary on the number of data items they collect (treatment 4) with the situation in which
they vary on the data items and prices (treatment 3). In the latter case, the privacy-friendly
Firm 1 charges 0.50 more compared to its privacy-unfriendly competitor. The share of tickets
sold by the privacy-friendly firm now decreases strongly (from 83% to 31%) from treatment 4
to 3. The difference between the treatments is statistically significant based upon the Mann-
Whitney tests. This means that the market share of the privacy-friendly firm is significantly
reduced, once a competitor charges a lower price, while collecting more information. This
result also holds if we only account for loyals. The market share of Firm 1 decreases from 84%
to 29% between treatment 4 and 3. However, we also observe a significant share of purchases
still conducted at Firm 1, despite the fact that these customers have to pay a higher price. This
holds for about a third of buyers.
Table 4 Overview of buyers and their purchases at both firms: loyals
Treat
ment
Number
of parti-
cipants
(no. buyers)
No. buyers
who
bought
two tickets
at the
same firm
Total no.
tickets
sold
to loyals
col.
(6)+(9)
No. of
loyal
buyers
picking
Firm 1
No. tickets
sold to
loyals
by Firm 1
Firm 1
% share of
all tickets
sold to
loyals
(6)%(4)
rounded
No. of
loyal
buyers
picking
Firm 2
No.
tickets
sold to
loyals
by Firm 2
Firm 2
% share of
all tickets
sold
(10)%(4)
(1) (2) (3)** (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
(9)
(10)
1
***
104
(51)
43 86
4
8
9%
39
78
91%
2
68
(32)
20 40
12
24
60%
8
16
40%
3
***
80
(37)
31
62
9
18
29%
22
44
71%
4
69
(31)
25
50
21
42
84%
4
8
16%
5*
122
(41)
23 46
13
26
57%
10
20
43%
Total
443 142 284 59 118 Avg. 48% 83 166 Avg. 52%
*There is no difference between firms in treatment 5. Individuals who did not choose Firm 1 either choose Firm 2 or no firm.
**This variable excludes two-time buyers, who switched firms. ***In these treatments, price differences exist.
37
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Comparison of treatment 2 and treatment 5: Again in treatment 5 firms are identical,
whereas in treatment 2 they differ on data usage only. We find that there is not a significant
difference between the two treatment groups. The Mann-Whitney test was not significant
and the result is analogous if only loyals are used in the analysis.
Comparison of treatment 1 and treatment 2: Finally, we compare the treatment, where firms
only differ on data usage (treatment 2) and on data usage and price (treatment 1). Since we
vary only one stimulus (price differences) from one treatment to the next we can be sure of
the effect of this variation. Similar and in line with the above observations, the market share
of Firm 1 is higher in treatment 2 (62%) than in treatment 1 (13%), considering all one- and
two-time sales across both periods. This difference is statistically significant. The share of
loyals purchases at Firm 1 is higher in treatment 2 (60%) compared to treatment 1 (9%).
All in all, we observe the following regularities in the laboratory experiment: in treatments
without a price difference (treatments 5, 4, 2), the privacy-friendly firm is able to snatch a
higher share of the market, i.e. a higher share of purchases made by participants. In
treatments where there is a price difference between firms (treatments 1, 3) the privacy-
unfriendly firm obtains a greater market share. The result is similar if we conduct the analysis
only for loyals. A higher share of the sales to loyals of the privacy-friendly firms occurs in
treatments without price differences. However, once the privacy-unfriendly firm charges a
lower price, it can obtain a greater share of all ticket sales to loyals.
59
6.4 Field and hybrid experiment
The field and hybrid experiment is complementary to the laboratory experiment. For the field
and hybrid experiment, we used an experimental website with the same features as in the
laboratory. While hybrid participants were invited to the experimental website, visitors in the
field did not know that they were part of an experiment.
6.4.1 Place, time period and participants
We conducted the field experiment between September and December 2011. The website
featured advertising. Within the time frame we had 2,300 visitors, 87 of which chose a firm
(choosers), including 10 buyers. One of the reasons for this low number might be the credit
card payment facility. Implementing direct debit would have been too risky for this project,
but would probably have reduced the number of non-buyers. We will primarily use the
number of choosers for the analysis. The hybrid is a mixture of laboratory and field, as the
invitations were directed to individuals in different pools at different universities in Germany.
We invited the students to the experimental website.
Participation was voluntary. The invitations were sent out in November to TU Berlin students
(roughly 900 registered students who had not already participated in the lab); ESMT (about
300 registered students); and Heinrich-Heine University in Dsseldorf (about 1,300 registered
59
Note that this result holds for a price difference of 0.5 and a ticket price of about 7. We did not make tests
with other price differences (or ticket prices) as this would have required a greater number of sessions.
38
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
students). The hybrid experiment ran until the end of December as well. Of 750 individuals
who were on the website, 52 chose a firm including 16 bought tickets. In addition, we invited
friends to the experimental website. Hybrid participants and friends obtained an extra link,
which helped us to identify them in order to separate them from the pure field visitors, which
were not personally invited, but found the website on the Internet.
6.4.2 Design of the field and hybrid experiment
The websites used for the hybrid and field experiment were exactly the same as for the
laboratory experiment, with the only difference being the graphical design to make it more
attractive for visitors. In order to attract buyers to the field website, we had to take a number
of advertising measures. For example, after launching the website, we started advertising on
the Google, Facebook, VZNetworks, Yahoo and Bing networks and introduced film teasers.
One of the outcomes of the field experiment is that it is notoriously difficult to attract
potential customers to a new website, because the setting is real and risk aversion of
individuals could prevent them from trying out purchases. Because of the low number of
buyers, we refrained from sending out questionnaires. However, we have enough
observations on choice of a firm in the field, i.e. visitors chose a firm, and typed in their
personal information.
6.5 Results from the field and hybrid experiment
For the analysis, we used data from both types of deployments, field and hybrid. This way, it
was possible to compare treatments 3 and 4 as well as 4 and 5 (see Table 5). As stated above,
the field data are generated in a more natural environment, where we cannot influence
external factors that might also influence the individuals decisions. Therefore, it is important
to run experiments in the laboratory as well in order to extract the effects in a more
controlled environment. We are particularly interested in whether the share of all choosers
(one- and two-time choosers) varies with the treatment as above and whether the same is the
case for loyals, i.e. two-time choosers of the same firm. Note that we work with data on
choice behaviour; i.e. individuals who chose a firm, entered their data and then either made
the purchase or for some reason did not make a purchase.
Comparison of treatment 4 and treatment 5: We compare the situation of two identical firms
(treatment 5) with the situation where they differ only on the number of data items they
collect (treatment 4), analogous with the laboratory experiment. In this comparison we find
that there is no significant difference between the two treatment groups, because the Mann-
Whitney test was not significantly different from zero.
60
However, this result is significant at
the 0.1 significance level when only using data on loyals, i.e. people who chose the same firm
two times, while ignoring one-time choosers. We find that the share of loyal choosers of the
privacy-friendly firm is significantly higher in treatment 4 compared to treatment 5 (42%
60
In more technical terms, the null hypothesis of the Mann-Whitney test is that there is equality in means. If the
test result is not significant, this null cannot be rejected, such that there is not a detectable difference between
the groups.
39
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
versus 19%). However, in the field treatment 4 the privacy-unfriendly firm has a greater share
among loyals.
Table 5 Overview of choosers at Firm 1 and Firm 2 in the field and hybrid experiments
Treatment
No.
of participants
All choosers All loyal choosers
Choose
Firm 1
(%, rounded)
Did not choose
Firm 1
(%, rounded)
Choose
Firm 1
(%, rounded)
Did not choose
Firm 1
(%, rounded)
3
**
67 42
58
5
95
4 29 90 10 42 58
5
*
43 16
84
19
81
*There is no difference between firms in treatment 5. Individuals who did not choose Firm 1 either chose Firm 2 or no firm.
** In this treatment, price differences exist.
Comparison of treatment 3 and treatment 4: To extract the effect of a price difference we
compare a situation of two firms that collect different amounts of information, but have equal
prices (treatment 4) to the situation, where they collect different amounts of information and
charge different prices (treatment 3). In treatment 4, the privacy-friendly firm is chosen much
more often than not (90%). In treatment 3 the share is 42% for Firm 1. Through the price
difference is just 0.50, the share in consumers choices drops. There is a statistically
significant difference in medians between the two treatment groups with respect to the
choice of Firm 1 across both periods.
61
This is similar in the case where we use only observations on the loyals who chose the same
firm two times. The share in this market is higher for the privacy-friendly firm in treatment 4
(42%), compared to the situation where the rival charges a lower price (5% only) in treatment
3.
From comparing the treatments 3, 4, 5 in the laboratory and the field for all purchases, we
find that the privacy-friendly firm has a much larger market share, if the differences in data
collection are obvious and prices are the same. However, once prices change and a privacy-
unfriendly competitor charges a lower price the privacy-friendly firm loses market share. But
more than a third of purchases by consumers show that they are willing to pay a mark-up at
the privacy-friendly firm. In case of loyals a comparison shows inconsistencies, as more two-
time buyers pick Firm 2, the unfriendly firm, than Firm 1 in the field treatment 4.
6.6 Assumptions used for the experiments and caveats
The laboratory and the field experiments rely on a number of assumptions. Future research
could focus on relaxing these assumptions. In order to reduce the complexity of the
theoretical model, we introduced a number of limitations, i.e. we have limited the model to
the case of two firms and consumers of two types, with high and low privacy concerns. This is
61
We applied the Mann-Whitney test just as in the laboratory.
40
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
a simplification, because there are a greater variety of privacy types among consumers.
Moreover, in the model consumers are sophisticated, but in the real world they might not
anticipate that personalisation could lock them in and lead to higher prices in future periods.
But there are also a number of caveats related to the empirical research conducted here.
Research studies based on random sampling of participants generalise to the population from
which the sample was drawn. Our research, which follows the common design for economic
experiments, is not based on a random sample.
We worked for the laboratory with
participants registered at the experimental pool of the Technical University of Berlin. While
participation in the experiment was based upon a neutral invitation, there is an element of
self-selection in terms of motivation to come to the experiment. However, once in the
laboratory, participants were randomly assigned to a treatment.
It is debatable whether results obtained on students in a laboratory environment can be
generalised to the general population. In general, results from the laboratory are considered
to be a useful tool in providing qualitative evidence (Levitt and List 2006). Only to a small
extent could we observe more natural behaviour in the field. In fact the field experiment
would have needed a much longer running time in order to collect more observations on
choice and especially purchase behaviour. One of the questions is whether the experimental
manipulation is in fact the main cause of the observed choices of participants (internal
validity). It relates to other factors that could potentially cause change in choice/behaviour.
We have conducted tests on whether the participants in the different treatments were drawn
from the same population in terms of age and gender (such that there is no bias due to a
selection effect). These tests showed no bias in selection. And we are also planning to conduct
tests of ranking and whether participants tend to choose the firm located on the left-hand
side. These will be part of a future research study.
41
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
7 Conclusions and recommendations
This study is focused on economic transactions; that is, economic exchange intermediated by
money, where the disclosure of personal information is a by-product and at times gets the
consumer a discount. This excludes transactions which we consider to be social exchange,
such as social networks, voluntary participation in anonymous surveys and usage of free
services on the Internet. Therefore, the presented research should not be generalised to other
populations or transactions that individuals conduct with regards to their personal data.
In order to reduce the complexity of the theoretical model used herein, we introduced a
number of assumptions. Future research could focus on relaxing these assumptions. For
example, we have limited the model to the case of two firms and consumers of two types,
with high and low concern. This is a simplification, because we can assume that there is a
greater variety of privacy types among consumers, as in fact we observed during this study.
Moreover, in the model consumers are sophisticated, but in the real world they might not
anticipate that personalisation could lock them in and lead to higher prices in future periods.
We implemented a simplified version of the model in the laboratory and field. For example,
we implemented the version of the model with no transportation costs by placing the offer of
the two service providers right next to each other. At the moment, it is too difficult for the
consumers to compare different information practices of online service providers. This is
exactly the area where we would propose that policy-makers ought to improve transparency
for consumers.
R Re ec co om mm me en nd da at ti io on n 1 1 I If f t th he er re e a ar re e l li it tt tl le e t to o n no o d di if ff fe er re en nc ce es s i in n t th he e p pr ri ic ce es s o of ff fe er re ed d b by y s se er rv vi ic ce e
p pr ro ov vi id de er rs s o on n h ho om mo og ge en ne eo ou us s g go oo od ds s, , a a c co om mp pe et ti it to or r w wh ho o h ha as s a a r re ed du uc ce ed d d da at ta a r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt t ( (p pr ri iv va ac cy y- -
f fr ri ie en nd dl ly y s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er r) ) c ca an n o ob bt ta ai in n a a c co om mp pe et ti it ti iv ve e a ad dv va an nt ta ag ge e a as s l lo on ng g a as s t th hi is s t ty yp pe e o of f
d di if ff fe er re en nt ti ia at ti io on n i is s o ob bv vi io ou us s t to o t th he e c co on ns su um me er r. . T Th he e r re ea as so on n i is s t th ha at t c co on ns su um me er rs s c ca an n b by y c ch ho oo os si in ng g t th he e
s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er r w wi it th h a a l lo ow we er r d da at ta a r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt t r re ed du uc ce e t th he ei ir r c co os st ts s o of f d di is sc cl lo os su ur re e o of f p pe er rs so on na al l
d da at ta a. .
R Re ec co om mm me en nd da at ti io on n 2 2 T Th he e r re eg gu ul la at to or ry y f fr ra am me ew wo or rk k s sh ho ou ul ld d a al ll lo ow w f fo or r s su uf ff fi ic ci ie en nt t f fl le ex xi ib bi il li it ty y t th ha at t
o on nl li in ne e s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er rs s c ca an n o of ff fe er r d di if ff fe er re en nt t m me en nu us s r re eg ga ar rd di in ng g p pr ri ic ce es s a an nd d p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a
r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt ts s: : f fr ro om m p pe er rs so on na al li is se ed d s se er rv vi ic ce es s w wh he er re e i id de en nt ti if fi ic ca at ti io on n i is s r re eq qu ui ir re ed d a an nd d a as s s su uc ch h m mo or re e
p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a i is s c co ol ll le ec ct te ed d t to o l le es ss s p pe er rs so on na al li is se ed d s se er rv vi ic ce es s w wi it th h f fe ew we er r r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt ts s f fo or r c co ol ll le ec ct ti io on n
o of f p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a. . I In n f fa ac ct t, , i it t s sh ho ou ul ld d b be e r re eq qu ui ir re ed d i if f n no o o ot th he er r l le eg ga al l r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt ts s r re es st tr ri ic ct t t th hi is s i in n
s sp pe ec ci if fi ic c c ca as se es s o or r a ar re ea as s s su uc ch h b ba an nk ki in ng g t th ha at t s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er rs s a al ls so o o of ff fe er r s se er rv vi ic ce es s w wi it th ho ou ut t
i id de en nt ti if fi ic ca at ti io on n o of f c cu us st to om me er rs s, , i in n o or rd de er r t to o l li im mi it t t th he e c co ol ll le ec ct ti io on n o of f p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a. .
If it is obvious which online service provider collects less personal information a significant
share of the market is gained by the privacy-friendly service providers, given that the prices
are similar and the products are similar. This observation was especially pronounced in the
field experiment.
An increase in transparency of information practices of firms must to be accompanied by an
increase in price transparency. Prices should be advertised excluding any discounts for which
42
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
consumers are only eligible by providing additional personal data. Moreover, if personal data
are used for price discrimination, the consumer should be informed about the fact that this is
taking place and what type of discrimination is used.
R Re ec co om mm me en nd da at ti io on n 3 3 T Th he e d di if ff fe er re en nc ce es s i in n d da at ta a r re eq qu ui ir re em me en nt ts s, , d da at ta a p pr ro ot te ec ct ti io on n a an nd d p pr ri iv va ac cy y
p po ol li ic ci ie es s m mu us st t b be e m ma ad de e m mo or re e v vi is si ib bl le e t to o c co on ns su um me er rs s i in n o or rd de er r t to o e en na ab bl le e c co om mp pa ar ri is so on n o of f t te er rm ms s
b be et tw we ee en n o on nl li in ne e s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er rs s. . T Th he e m mo or re e s st ta an nd da ar rd di is se ed d a an nd d s si im mp pl le e t th he es se e t te er rm ms s a ar re e, , t th he e
e ea as si ie er r c co om mp pa ar ri is so on n w wi il ll l b be e. .
I If f d da at ta a p pr ra ac ct ti ic ce es s a ar re e d di if ff fi ic cu ul lt t t to o c co om mp pa ar re e, , t th he e t te er rm ms s o of f t tr ra ad de e f fo or r p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a m mi ig gh ht t n no ot t
i in nf fl lu ue en nc ce e t th he e d de ec ci is si io on n o of f t th he e c co on ns su um me er r, , w wh ho o w wo ou ul ld d o ot th he er rw wi is se e p pa ay y a at tt te en nt ti io on n t to o p pr ri iv va ac cy y i is ss su ue es s. .
I In n t th hi is s c ca as se e, , t th he e c co on ns su um me er r t te en nd ds s t to o i ig gn no or re e t th he em m b be ec ca au us se e o of f t th he ei ir r c co om mp pl le ex xi it ty y. . T Th he e r re es su ul lt t i is s t th ha at t
o on nl li in ne e s se er rv vi ic ce e p pr ro ov vi id de er r c ca an nn no ot t u us se e p pr ri iv va ac cy y s se et tt ti in ng gs s t to o f fi it t c co on ns su um me er r p pr re ef fe er re en nc ce es s t to o o ob bt ta ai in n a a
c co om mp pe et ti it ti iv ve e a ad dv va an nt ta ag ge e. .
R Re ec co om mm me en nd da at ti io on n 4 4 P Pe er rs so on na al l p pr ro of fi il le es s a ar re e o of ft te en n t th he e b ba as se e f fo or r p pe er rs so on na al li is sa at ti io on n o of f p pr ro od du uc ct ts s o or r
s se er rv vi ic ce es s. . I If f p po or rt ta ab bi il li it ty y o of f p pr ro of fi il le es s a am mo on ng g f fi ir rm ms s i is s m ma an nd da at te ed d, , c co on ns su um me er rs s w wi il ll l f fa ac ce e d de ec cr re ea as se ed d
s sw wi it tc ch hi in ng g c co os st ts s a an nd d b be en ne ef fi it t f fr ro om m i in nt te en ns si if fi ie ed d p pr ri ic ce e c co om mp pe et ti it ti io on n i in n t th he e m ma ar rk ke et t. . H Ho ow we ev ve er r t th he e
t tr ra an ns sf fe er r o of f p pr ro of fi il le es s s sh ho ou ul ld d b be e c co on nd di it ti io on ne ed d o on n t th he e c co on ns se en nt t o of f t th he e c co on ns su um me er r a an nd d i in n a ac cc co or rd da an nc ce e
w wi it th h p pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a p pr ro ot te ec ct ti io on n l le eg gi is sl la at ti io on n. .
The majority of the participants in the study express their concerns for privacy (section 6.3.1).
However, the results of the experiments show that when there is a price differentiation the
consumers show a tendency to choose cheaper services/goods.
R Re ec co om mm me en nd da at ti io on n 5 5 P Pe er rs so on na al l d da at ta a p pr ro ot te ec ct ti io on n a an nd d p pr ri iv va ac cy y i is s a a h hu um ma an n r ri ig gh ht t. . T Th he e E Eu ur ro op pe ea an n
C Co om mm mi is ss si io on n, , E EU U M Me em mb be er r S St ta at te es s a an nd d d da at ta a p pr ro ot te ec ct ti io on n a au ut th ho or ri it ti ie es s s sh ho ou ul ld d e en nf fo or rc ce e a a c cl le ea ar r a an nd d
c co on ns si is st te en nt t l le eg ga al l d da at ta a p pr ro ot te ec ct ti io on n f fr ra am me ew wo or rk k. .
43
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
8 Glossary
This glossary is complementary to the glossary of terms in ENISA (2011b: 38) and the
definitions of key terms in ENISA (2011c: 9). These are only working definitions in the context
of this study.
Addressability: The firms ability to reach consumers based upon their personal data. The
degree of addressability can be represented as the proportion of consumers at each point in
the market who are in the firms database; the firm can offer these consumers customised
prices. (Source: Chen and Iyer 2002).
Behaviour-based pricing: Behaviour-based pricing is a mechanism whereby a firm uses a
consumers previously observable behaviour to set prices based upon this personal
information.
Customisation: Customisation refers to a consumers own specification of product features to
purchase. The customer and not the firm initiate customisation. This is the main difference to
personalisation (Source: Arora et al. 2008).
Data protection: Data protection denotes the legal and regulatory codes enacted to protect
personal information of individuals.
Lock-in: Lock-in effects arise where consumers are prevented from switching easily and
without costs to another provider.
Personalisation: Personalisation refers to a firms tailored product offerings to an individual
consumer based on its data about that consumer. This research follows this terminology and
uses the word personalisation for the strategy analysed. The firm and not the consumer
initiates personalisation. This is the main difference from customisation (Source: Arora et al.
2008).
Privacy: The term denotes a social convention of keeping specific personal data private, i.e.
not releasing it to the public. In the context of this study, the term denotes the asymmetric
distribution of personal information between market participants.
Privacy Policy: Privacy policies are terms set by firms, which inform about their personal data
handling practices. Consumers who read these terms are informed about the terms of trade
for their personal data.
Targeting: A firm's targetability is the ability to predict the preferences and purchase
behaviour of consumers for the purpose of customising prices or product offers (Chen,
Narasimhan and Zhang 2001).
44
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
9 References
Acquisti, A. (2010) The Economics of Personal Data and the Economics of Privacy, OECD Roundtable on the Economics of
Personal Data and Privacy, December 1.
Acquisti, A. and Varian, H. (2005) Conditioning Prices on Purchase History, Marketing Science 24(3): 367381.
Akura, T.M. and Srinivasan, K. (2005) Customer Intimacy and Cross-Selling Strategy, Management Science 51: 10071012.
Akerlof, G.A. (1970) The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism, The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 84(3): 488500.
Arora, N., Drze, X., Ghose, A., Hess, J.D., Iyengar, R., Jing, B. and Joshi, Y. (2008) Putting one-to-one marketing to work:
Personalization, customization, and choice, Marketing Letters 19(3-4): 305321.
Beresford, A.R., Kbler, D.and Preibusch, S. (2010) Unwillingness to Pay for Privacy: A Field Experiment, WZB Working Paper.
BITKOM (2010) 12 Millionen Deutsche machen Falschangaben im Web, http://www.bitkom.org/de/presse/66442_62102.aspx
Bohnet, I. and Frey, B.S. (1997) Identification in Democratic Society, Journal of Socio-Economics 26(1): 2538.
Bohnet, I. and Frey, B.S. (1999) The Sound of Silence in Prisoners Dilemma and Dictator Games, Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 38(1): 4357.
Calzolari, G. and Pavan, A. (2006) On the Optimality of Privacy in Sequential Contracting, Journal of Economic Theory 130(1):
168204.
Charness, G. and Gneezy, U. (2008) Whats in a Name? Anonymity and Social Distance in Dictator and Ultimatum Games,
Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 68(1): 2935.
Chen, Y. and Iyer, G. (2002) Research Note: Consumer Addressability and Customized Pricing, Marketing Science 21(2): 197
208.
Chen, Yuxin, Narasimhan, C. and Zhang, Z.J. (2001) Individual Marketing and Imperfect Targetability, Marketing Science 20:
2341.
Conitzer, V., Taylor, C.R. and Wagman, L. (2010) Online Privacy and Price Discrimination, Economic Research Initiatives at
Duke Working Paper No. 79 (July).
DellaVigna, S. (2009) Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field, Journal of Economic Literature 47: 315372.
Dewan, R., Jin, B.and Seidmann, A. (2000) Adoption of Internet-Based Product Customization and Pricing Strategy, Journal of
Management Information Systems 36(17:2): 928.
Dodds, S. (2008) Welfare Implications of Confidentiality and Consent in Privacy Regulation, Mimeo, Carleton University.
ENISA (2011a) Privacy, Accountability and Trust Challenges and Opportunities, 2011,
http://www.enisa.europa.eu/act/it/library/deliverables/pat-study
ENISA (2011b) Survey of accountability, trust, consent, tracking, security and privacy mechanisms in online environments,
Jan. 31, 2011, www.enisa.europa.eu/act/it/library/deliverables/survey-pat
ENISA (2011c) Managing multiple electronic identities, April 20, 2011,
www.enisa.europa.eu/act/it/library/deliverables/mami
Eurobarometer (2011) Attitudes on Data Protection and Electronic Identity in the European Union, SPECIAL
EUROBAROMETER 359, http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/archives/ebs/ebs_359_en.pdf
Fudenberg, D. and Villas-Boas, J.M. (2006) Behavior-based price discrimination and customer recognition, T. Hendershott (ed.)
Economics and Information Systems, Vol. 1, Handbooks in Information Systems Series, Amsterdam, Elsevier, pp. 4147.
Giannetti, C. and Jentzsch, N. (2011) Disclosure of Personal Information under the Risk of Privacy Shocks, Mimeo,
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1988854
Gideon, J., Cranor, L., Egelman, S. and Acquisti, A. (2006) Power Strips, Prophylactics, and Privacy, Oh My!, Institute for
Software Research (Paper 24), http://repository.cmu.edu/isr/24
Hermalin, B. and Katz, M. (2006) Privacy, Property Rights and Efficiency: The Economics of Privacy as Secrecy, Quantitative
Marketing and Economics 4(3): 209239.
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K. and Smith, V.L. (1996) Social Distance and Other-regarding Behavior in Dictator Games, American
Economic Review 86(3): 653660.
45
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Hui, K.-L. and Png, I.P.L. (2006) The Economics of Privacy, in Economics and Information Systems, T. Hendershott (ed.),
Amsterdam, Elsevier, pp. 471-497.
Huberman, B.A., Adar, E. and Fine, L.R. (2005) Valuating Privacy, IEEE Security & Privacy 3(5): 2225.
Jenni, K.E. and Loewenstein, G. (1997) Explaining the Identifiable Victim Effect, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 14(3): 235
257.
Jentzsch, N. (2007) Financial Privacy An International Comparison of Credit Reporting Systems, Heidelberg, Springer-Verlag.
Kahn, C.M., McAndrews, J. and Roberds, W. (2000) A Theory of Transactions Privacy, Working Paper 2000-22, Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Krahnen, J.P., Rieck, C. and Theissen, E. (1997) Messung individueller Risikoeinstellungen, Center for Financial Studies Working
Paper, www.ifk-cfs.de/fileadmin/downloads/publications/wp/97_03.pdf
Lee, D.-J., Ahn J.-H. and Bank, Y. (2011) Managing Consumer Privacy Concerns in Personalization: A Strategic Analysis of
Privacy Protection, MIS Quarterly 35(2): 423444.
Levitt, S.D. and List, J.A. (2007) What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences Reveal about the Real
World?, Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(2): 153174.
Pfitzmann, A. and Khntopp, M. (2000) Anonymity, Unobservability, and Pseudonymity A Proposal for Terminology,
avaialble at; http://dud.inf.tu-dresden.de/Anon_Terminology.shtml
Preibusch, S. (2006) Personalized Services with Negotiable Privacy Policies, CHI 2006 Workshop on Privacy-Enhanced
Personalization, 22 April 2006, Montral, Canada pp. 2938.
Smith, H. Jeff, Milberg, Sandra J. and Burke, Sandra J. (1996) Information Privacy: Measuring Individuals Concerns about
Organizational Practices, MIS Quarterly 20(June): 167196.
Stole, L. (2007) Price Discrimination and Competition, in M. Armstrong and R. Porter, Handbook of Industrial Organization,
Vol. 3, Amsterdam, Elsevier, pp. 22212299.
Tsai, J.Y., Egelman, S., Cranor, L. and Acquisti, A. (2010) The Effect of Online Privacy Information on Purchasing Behavior: An
Experimental Study, Information Systems Research, 22(June), 254268. Available at:
http://isr.journal.informs.org/cgi/doi/10.1287/isre.1090.0260.
Villas-Boas, J.M. (1999) Dynamic competition with customer recognition, RAND Journal of Economics 30(4): 604631.
Zhang, J. (2011) The Perils of Behavior-Based Personalization, Marketing Science 30(1): 170186.
46
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
10 Annex. Technical appendix
The technical appendix illustrates how the predictions and equilibria described in the report
are derived.
One-period model with r=0
Consider first the decisions of the consumers. With 0 r = each consumer maximises its utility
which leads to
1 if ( , ) ( , )
( ) 1/ 2 if ( , ) ( , )
0 if ( , ) ( , )
c c
A i A B i B
c c c c
i A i A B i B
c c
A i A B i B
p c d p c d
i p c d p c d
p c d p c d
u u
u u u
u u
+ < +
= + = +
`
+ > +
)
Turning to firms' decisions we first analyse different scenarios and then characterize the
optimal decisions of firm A.
Scenario A d d
A
= : Considering different data requirement decisions of firm B and its
potentially optimal pricing decisions leads to the following profits for
B
and
A
:
In order to earn positive profits, firm
A
has to ensure that
B
reacts as described in the third
line. Thus firm A will try to set
p
A such that
} , { max
2 1 3
B B B
H H > H
Taking into account different parameter constellations, the above inequality leads to
> A
A > > A A
+ A s A A > A A
+ A > A A >
=
q c
c q c c q
q c c c q q c c
q c c c q
p
A
) ( if 0
) ( ) ( if )) ( (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( and ) ( if ) ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( and ) ( if 0
1
1
u
u u u
u u u u u
u u u
Scenario B d d
A
= : Proceeding as above we obtain:
) 1 )( ( )) ( ( :
0 ) ( :
0 :
3 3
2 2
1 1
u
u
+ = H A + = H =
= H A + = H =
= H + = H =
q p c p d d
c p d d
q p d d
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
Analyzing
} , { max
2 1 3
B B B
H H > H
leads to the following pricing decisions of firm
A
| |
| | | |
| |
A s A > A
A > A > A A A
A > > A A
A >
=
q c c q c q
q c c q c c c
c q c q c
c q q
p
A
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( and ) ( if
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( and ) ( if ) ( ) (
) ( ) ( if ) (
) ( if
1
1
1
1
1
1
u u u
u u u u u
u u u
u
47
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Substituting these prices in firm
A
's profit function and comparing its profits, we get the
following equilibrium data requirement decisions and equilibrium profits
| |
| |
| | ) ( ) ( if 0
) ( ) ( if ) 1 ( ) ( ) (
) (
) ( ) ( ) 1 ( if ) ) ( (
) ( ) ( ) 1 ( if )) ( )( 1 (
) ( ), (
)) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
)) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ( if 0
) (
1
1
1
1
1
1
u u
u u u u
u
u u u
u u u
u u
u u u u
u u
u
c c q d d d d
c c q q c c d d d d
c q
c c q q c d d d d
c c q c q d d d d
c c q
c c q q c c d d d d
c c q d d d d
c q
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A A s = H = =
A A > + A A = H = =
A s
A + A s A = H = =
A + A > A = H = =
A A e
A A s A A = H = =
A A > = H = =
A >
One-period model with 0 > r
Solving by backward induction we first turn to the consumers and compute the location of the
indifferent consumers, given any combination of prices and data requirements.
>
e
=
+
otherwise 0
1 ) ( if 1
] 1 , 0 [ ) ( if
) (
2
) , ( ) , (
2
1
c
c
B c
i
A c
i
B A
c
i
c
i
c
r
d c d c p p
i
c
i
i
i u
u
u
u u
This leads to the following market shares for firm A and B:
A B
c c
A
n n
i i n
=
+ =
1
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u
Then, solving for firm Bs price reaction function yields:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( (
2
1
B B A B A A B
q d c d c d c d c p r p o u u u u + + + =
-
Now, comparing profits under the two different data requirements leads to the following:
= + + + + = H
= + + + = H
= H
d d q d c d c d c d c p r
d d d c d c d c d c p r
B A A A r B
B A A A r B
B
2
8
1
2
2
8
1
1
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( ( :
))) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( ( :
u u u u
u u u u
Thus, firm Bs data requirement decision will be:
> A + A
=
-
otherwise
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if
d
q c c d
d
B
u u
Then regarding firm A, we can compute the pricing function:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 (
2
1
B A B A B A A
q q d c d c d c d c r p o o u u u u =
-
This leads to the following profits:
48
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
2
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 (
16
1
B A B A B A A
q q d c d c d c d c r
r
o o u u u u + = H
We now have to consider two different cases separately:
1. Case: q c c > A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u
Taking into account firm Bs decisions, we get the following price for A:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 (
2
1
A A A A
q d c d c d c d c r p o u u u u =
-
This in turn leads to the comparison of the following profits:
= + = H
= = H
= H
d d q d c d c d c d c r
d d
A r A
A
r
A
A
2
16
1
2
16
9
1
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 ( :
:
u u u u
As in this case q c c > A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u , we get as the optimal data requirement decision:
d d
A
=
-
Collecting the decisions, the equilibrium in this case is:
)
4
5
, ( ),
2
3
, (
r
p d d
r
p d d
B B A A
= = = =
- - - -
2. Case: q c c < A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u
In this case the pricing function is:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 (
2
1
q q d c d c d c d c r p
A A A A
=
-
o u u u u
Thus, the profits, which have to be compared, are now:
= = H
= + + = H
= H
d d
d d q d c d c d c d c r
A
r
A
A r A
A
16
9
2
2
16
1
1
:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 ( : u u u u
As in this case it holds that q c c < A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u , we can state:
d d
A
=
-
This gives the following equilibrium:
)
4
4 5
, ( ),
2
2 3
, (
q r
p d d
q r
p d d
B B A A
= =
= =
- - - -
In both equilibria market shares are equal to:
8
5
,
8
3
= =
- -
B A
n n
Two-period model with r=0
Scenario a): ) ( ) ( 0 u u b b A > A >
To characterise the equilibria in the two-period model we start with the second period where
we analyse the firms pricing decisions for
B A
d d d d = > = and
B A
d d d d = < = . We then turn
to the first period where we analyse both the firms' pricing decisions as well as the firms'
profits for different data requirement decisions of firm
B
. Using these results and comparing
49
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
the profits of firm
A
with d d
A
= and d d
A
= allows us to determine the equilibrium in the
overall game. Note further that
B A
d d = leads to zero profits in both periods.
Second period prices and profits
a) d d d d
B A
= > = : Using the potentially optimal pricing decisions of firm
B
, firm
B
's and
A
's
second period profits are given by
)) ( ( ; 0 :
) 1 )( ( ; )) ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u
u
c q
q p c p
c p
A B
A A A B
A A B
A = H = H
+ = H A + = H
= H A + = H
As in the one-period model, firm
A
tries to induce firm
B
to set its prices such that firm
A
earns the highest possible profit. Comparing profits and calculating firm
B
's best response as
well as the implied profit of firm
A
, we get the following pricing decisions of firm
A
:
| |
| | | |
| |
A A s
A A + A s A A
A A + A > A
=
) ( ) ( if
) ( ) ( ) ( if ) ( ) (
) ( ) ( ) ( if ) (
1
1
1
1
1
1
2 ,
u u
u u u u u
u u u u
c c q q
c c c q c c
c c c q c
p
A
Using these prices the firms' second period profits are given by
| |
| |
| |
| |
| | | |
| |
A A s A
A A + A s A A
A A + A >
= H
A A s
A A + A s + A A
A A + A > A
= H
) ( ) ( if ) (
) ( ) ( ) ( if ) ( ) (
) ( ) ( ) ( if 0
) ( ) ( if 0
) ( ) ( ) ( if ) 1 ( ) ( ) (
) ( ) ( ) ( if ) (
1
1
1
1
1
2 ,
1
1
1
1
2 ,
u u u
u u u u u
u u u
u u
u u u u u
u u u u
c c q q c
c c c q c c
c c c q
c c q
c c c q q c c
c c c q c q
B
A
b) d d d d
B A
= < = : Employing the potentially optimal pricing decisions of firm
B
, firm
B
's and
A
's second period profits are given by
q c
p c q p
c q p
A B
A A A B
A A B
A = H = H
= H A + = H
= H A + = H
) ( ; 0 :
; ) 1 ))( ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2
2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u
u
Proceeding as above and calculating the firm
B
's best response and the implied profit of firm
A
, we get the following pricing decisions of firm
A
:
| |
| | | |
| |
A A s A
A A s A A
A A >
=
) ( ) ( ) 2 ( if ) (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if 0
1
1
1 1
1
2 ,
u u u
u u u u
u u
c c q q c
c c q q c c
c c q
p
A
The firms' second period profits can be written as
50
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
| |
| |
| |
| |
| | | |
| |
A A s
A A s A A
A A > A
= H
A A s A
A A s A A
A A >
= H
) ( ) ( ) 2 ( if 0
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if ) ( ) (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if ) (
) ( ) ( ) 2 ( if ) (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if 0
1
1
1
1
1
2 ,
1
1
1
1
2 ,
u u
u u u u
u u u
u u u
u u u u
u u
c c q
c c q c c
c c q c q
c c q q c
c c q q c c
c c q
B
A
First period prices and firm B 's data requirement decision
In order to calculate the firms' pricing decisions in the first period as well as firm
B
's profit
given either d d
B
= or d d
B
= we have to consider the second period profits given above.
a) d d
A
= : In this case there are
4
different parameter constellations to be analysed.
Case 1): | | ) ( ) ( ) (
1
u u u
c c c q A A + A > ; Employing firm
B
's potentially optimal pricing decisions
in the first period as well as the second period profits given above we get the following overall
profits for firm
B
and
A
:
) ( ) ( ; 0 :
) ( ) 1 )( ( ; )) ( ( :
) ( ; ) ( :
0 ; :
4 4
1 ,
3
1 ,
3
2
1 ,
2
1
1 ,
1
u u
u u
u u
c q c q d d
c q q p c p d d
c q c p d d
q p d d
A B B
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
A + A = H = H =
A + + = H A + = H =
A = H A + = H =
= H + = H =
Using
2 1
B B
H > H and comparing profits shows that firm
A
is not able to induce firm
B
to
choose
d
. Hence, we get d d
B
= and
0 = H = H
B A
Case 2): | | | | ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) (
1
1
u u u u u u
c c c q c c c A A + A > > A A + A
; Here overall profits for
firm
B
and
A
are given by
| |
| | q c c q p c c c p d d
q c c c c c p d d
q p d d
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 )( ( ; ) ( ) ( )) ( ( :
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) ( :
0 ; :
1 ,
3
1 1 ,
3
2
1 1 ,
2
1
1 ,
1
u u u u u
u u u u u
+ A A + + = H A A + A + = H =
+ A A = H A A + A + = H =
= H + = H =
Again, employing
2 1
B B
H > H and comparing profits shows firm
A
can ensure itself strictly
positive profits by inducing firm
B
to choose d d
B
= only if 5 . 0 s . In this case the firms'
profits are given by
| |
| | q c c
c q c q
B
A
) 1 ( ) ( ) 2 )( (
) 1 (
) ( ) ) ( )( 2 3 (
1
1
2
u u
u u
A A
= H
A A +
= H
51
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Case 3): | | | | ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) (
1
1
1
u u u u u
c c q c c c A A > > A A + A
; Proceeding as above we have
| |
| | q c c q p c c c p d d
q c c c c c p d d
q p d d
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ) 1 )( ( ; ) ( ) ( )) ( ( :
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) ( :
0 ; :
1 ,
3
1 1 ,
3
2
1 1 ,
2
1
1 ,
1
u u u u u
u u u u u
+ A A + + = H A A + A + = H =
+ A A = H A A + A + = H =
= H + = H =
Using
1 2
B B
H > H ,firm
A
sets its first period price such that
3 2
B B
H = H which leads to
| |
| | ) ( ) (
1
2
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( 2
u u
u u
c c
q c c
B
A
A A
= H
+ A A = H
Case 4): | | q c c > A A
) ( ) (
1
1
u u
c c c c c q c c A A A A A > > A A
;
In this case the firms' profits are given by
| |
| | q c c p c c c q p d d
q c c c c c q p d d
p d d
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
u u u u u
u u u u u
A A + = H A A + A + = H =
A A = H A A + A + = H =
= H = H =
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) 1 ))( ( ( :
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) ( :
0 ; :
1 ,
1
1 ,
3
1
1 ,
2
1 ,
1
Using
1 2
B B
H > H firm
A
sets
p
A,1
such that
3 2
B B
H = H which leads to
52
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
| |
| | ) ( ) (
1
2
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( 2
u u
u u
c c
q c c
B
A
A A
= H
A A = H
Case 3):
| | | | ) ( ) ( ) 2 ( ) ( ) ( ) (
1
1
1
u u u u u
c c q c c c A A > > A A A
A A + = H A A + A + = H =
A A = H A A + A + = H =
= H = H =
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) 1 ))( ( ( :
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ; ) ( ) ( ) ( :
0 ; :
1 ,
1
1 ,
3
1
1 ,
2
1 ,
1
and thus
2 1
B B
H > H . Using
1 3
B B
H = H leads to
| | ) ( 2 ) (
1
) 2 1 ( ) ( ) 1 ( 2 ) (
u u
u u
c q c
q c c
B
A
A + A
= H
+ A A = H
Case 4): | | ) ( ) ( ) 2 (
1
1
u u
c c q A A s
; Analyzing
q c p c q p d d
q c c q p d d
p d d
A A A B B
A A B B
A A B B
A + = H A + = H =
A = H A + = H =
= H = H =
) ( ; ) 1 ))( ( ( :
) ( ; ) ( :
0 ; :
1 , 1 ,
3
1 ,
2
1 ,
1
u u
u u
reveals
2 1
B B
H > H . Comparing
1
B
H and
3
B
H shows that firm
A
is not able to induce firm
B
to
choose
d
. Hence, we get d d
B
= and
0 = H = H
B A
Collecting these results and comparing the profits of firm
A
for d d
A
= and d d
A
= we can
deduce the profit maximising data requirement decision of firm
A
and thus the overall
equilibrium of the game. However, we first have to compare the critical values of
q
which
leads to
| | | |
| | | | 6 . 0 ) ( ) (
1
) ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
1
) 2
) ( ) 1 ( ) (
1
) ( ) (
1
) ( ) 1
s A A
+ A > A A
A A > A A + A
u u
u u u
u u
u u
u
c c c c c
c c c c c
| | | | ) ( ) (
1
) ( ) ( ) (
1
) ( ) 3 u u
u u u
u c c c c c c A A
A > A A
+ A
53
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
| | | |
| | | |
| | | | ) ( ) ( ) 2 (
1
1
) ( ) (
1
1
) 6
2 . 0 ? ) ( ) ( ) 2 (
1
1
? ) ( ) (
1
) ( ) 5
4 . 0 ? ) ( ) (
1
1
? ) ( ) (
1
) ( ) 4
u u
u u
u u
u u
u
u u
u u
u
c c c c
c c c c c
c c c c c
A A
> A A
A A
A A
A
A A
A A
A
Assuming | | 6 . 0 , 4 . 0 e we get the following outcomes:
| |
| | | |
| |
| | | |
| |
| |
| | | |
| |
| |
| | | |
| |
| | | |
| |
0
) ( ) ( ) 2 (
1
1
.) 7
) 2 1 ( ) ( ) 1 ( 2 ) (
0
) ( ) ( ) 2 (
1
1
) ( ) (
1
1
.) 6
) 2 1 ( ) ( ) 1 ( 2 ) (
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( 2
) ( ) (
1
1
) ( ) (
1
) ( .) 5
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( 2
) 1 ( ) ( ) ( 2
) ( ) (
1
) ( ) ( ) (
1
) ( .) 4
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( 2
) ( ) ) ( )( 2 3 (
1
1
) ( ) (
1
) ( ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
1
.) 3
) ( ) ) ( )( 2 3 (
1
1
) ( ) 1 ( ) (
1
) ( ) (
1
) ( .) 2
0
) ( ) (
1
) ( .) 1
= H = =
> A A
+ A A = H = =
= H = =
A A
> > A A
+ A A = H = =
+ A A = H = =
A A
> > A A
A
A A = H = =
+ A A = H = =
A A
A > > A A
+ A
A A = H = =
A A +
= H = =
A A
+ A > > A A
A A +
= H = =
A A > > A A + A
= H = =
A A + A >
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
d d d d
q c c
q c c d d d d
d d d d
c c q c c
q c c d d d d
q c c d d d d
c c q c c c
q c c d d d d
q c c d d d d
c c c q c c c
q c c d d d d
c q c q d d d d
c c c q c c
c q c q d d d d
c c q c c c
d d d d
c c c q
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u
u u
u u
u u
u u u
u
u u
u u
u u
u u u
u u
u u
u u
u
u u
u
54
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
The symmetric equilibria in case 1) and 7) are again efficient. The asymmetric equilibria are
efficient for intermediate values of
q
only. For instance in case 2), as the upper bound is
larger than ) (u c A , the equilibrium is inefficient as soon as ) (u c q A > . However, if
q
is
smaller than ) (u c A the equilibrium is efficient. In the other cases the asymmetric equilibrium
can be inefficient, if
q
is close to one of the limits.
Scenario a): ) ( 0 ) ( u u b b A > > A
We start with the assumption of symmetric data requirements d d d
B A
= = and d d d
B A
= =
. Here the effect of personalisation is very pronounced as firms would otherwise make second
period profits of zero in a symmetric equilibrium. Therefore let us turn to second period
profits:
i) Assume first period market shares are 5 . 0
1 , 1 ,
= =
B A
n n . Then we have to compare the
following profits
0 ;
) )( 1 ( ; ) ))( 1 ( 1 (
) ))( 1 ( 1 ( ; ) )( 1 (
3
2 , 2 ,
3
2 ,
2 , 2
1
2
2 , 2 , 2
1
2
2 ,
2 , 2
1
1
2 , 2 , 2
1
1
2 ,
= H + = H
+ = H + = H
+ = H + + = H
A A B
A A A B
A A A B
q b p
q p q p
q p q b p
Comparing the profits of firm
B
, calculating the optimal price
2 , A
p leads to the following
profits
>
>
= H
>
>
= H
+
1 ) 6 ( if
) 6 ( 1 if
;
1 ) 6 ( if
) 6 ( 1 if ) 3 (
4
) 1 (
1
) 1 ( 2
1
2 ,
4
) 1 (
2
1
1
2 ,
2
2
b
b
S
B b
S
A
b
ii) If first period prices are
1 , 1 , B A
p p < , then all consumers buy at firm
A
in period 1. Thus,
second period profits are given by
0 ;
) 1 )( ( ; ) (
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
= H + = H
+ = H + = H
A A B
A A A B
q b p
q p q p
Therefore, we get
= H = H
1
and
2
2 ,
2
2 ,
b
b
S
B
S
A
iii) If first period prices are
1 , 1 , B A
p p > , then all consumers buy at firm
B
in period 1 which
leads to
0 ;
) ( ; ) 1 )( (
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
= H + = H
+ = H + + = H
A A B
A A A B
q p
q p q b p
and
|
|
.
|
\
|
= H = H 1
1
and ) 1 (
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
b b
S
B
S
A
55
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Note that in all cases no consumer, who has chosen personalisation in the first period,
switches in the second period.
Turning to the first period we get the following overall profits
( )
( ) ( )
> H + +
= H + +
< H
= H
> H
= H + +
< H + +
= H
1 , 1 ,
2
2 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1
2 , 1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
3
2 ,
1 , 1 ,
2
2 ,
1 , 1 ,
1
2 , 1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
3
2 , 1 ,
if
if
if
;
if
if
if
A B
S
A A
A B
S
A A
A B
S
A
S
A
A B
S
B
A B
S
B A
A B
S
B A
S
B
p p q p
p p q p
p p
p p
p p q p
p p q p
Comparing these profits we again have to consider different cases:
Case 1): ( ) > 6 1 ; Substituting the above given second period profits, overall profits can
be written as
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
> + +
= + +
<
= H
>
= + +
< + +
= H
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1
) 1 ( 2
1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
if
if 3
if ) 1 (
;
if
if
if
A B A
A B A
A B
A
A B
A B
b
A
A B A
B
p p b q p
p p b q p
p p b
p p b
p p q p
p p b q p
Comparing these profits and calculating the best response of firm
B
and the optimal price
p
A,1 leads to
( )
q b p
A
=
1
1 2
1 ,
and the following profits
= H = H
1
and ) 1 ( b b
S
B
S
A
Case 2): 1 ) 6 ( > ; Again, using the above given second period profits, we get
( )
( )
( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
> >
< >
= + +
<
= H
>
= + +
< + +
= H
3
1
1 , 1 , 1 2
1 4 1
3
1
1 , 1 , 1
2 1
1 , 1 , 4
1
1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
1 ,
1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 4
1
1 , 2
1
1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
1 ,
and if
and if 1
if
if ) 1 (
;
if
if
if 2
2
A B
A B
A B A
A B
A
A B
A B A
A B A
B
p p b
p p b
p p b q p
p p b
p p b
p p b q p
p p b q p
Comparing these profits and calculating the best response of firm
B
and the optimal price
p
A,1 leads to
( )
( ) ( )
( )
>
<
=
3
1
1 2
1 5 1
3
1
1
1 2
2 ,
if
if
q b
q b
p
A
and the following profits
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
>
<
= H
>
<
= H
+
3
1
1
3
1
1
3
1
1 2
1 4 1
3
1
if
if
;
if
if ) 1 (
b
b
b
b
S
B
S
A
Now, we turn to the case where
B A
d d d d = > = . Again we start with the second period and
analyse the firms' profits given different market shares in period 1.
56
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
i) If first period market shares were either such that only consumers with u u =
i
or all
consumers regardless of their type bought from firm
A
then second period profits are given
by:
q c
q p c p
c b p
A B
A A A B
A A B
+ A = H = H
+ = H A + = H
= H A + = H
) ( ; 0 :
) 1 )( ( ; )) ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u
u
The optimal pricing decisions of firm
A
and the implied profits for both firms are given by
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
<
> > + A A
< + A A
= H
< + A
> > + + A A
<
= H
< A
> >
<
=
+ A A +
A + A + A A +
A + A
+ A A +
A + A + A A +
A + A
+ A A +
A + A + A A +
+ A A
A + A
+ A A
q
q b c c
q b c c
q q c
q q b c c
q
q c
q
q
p
b c c
b c c b c c
b c c
A
B
b c c
b c c b c c
b c c
A
A
b c c
b c c b c c b c c
b c c b c c
A
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u
u u
u
1
1
1
1
1 1
1
2 ,
1
1
1
1
1
2 ,
1
1
1
1
1 1
2 ,
if 0
if
if
if ) (
if ) 1 (
if 0
if
if
if
ii) If in contrast all consumers bought from firm
B
in the first period, second period profits are
given by
) ) ( ( ; 0 :
) 1 )( ( ; )) ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
q c b
q p c p
c b p
A B
A A A B
A A B
+ A = H = H
+ = H A + = H
= H A + + = H
u
u
u
Prices and profits are given by
( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( )
( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
< A +
> A + A A
= H
< A + + A
> A +
= H
< A + A
> A +
=
A A
q c b
q c b b c c
q c b q c b
q c b
q c b c b
q c b
p
A
B
A
A
b c c
A
u
u u u
u u
u
u u
u
u u
if 0
if
;
if ) (
if 0
;
if
if
1 2
2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
Now, we turn to the first period pricing decisions when data requirements are asymmetric.
We get the following overall profits:
57
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
( )( ) ( ) ( )
( )
A + < H
A + < s A + H + +
A + > H + +
= H
A + < H + A +
A + < s A + H + A +
A + > H
= H
u
u u
u
u u
u u u
u
c p p
c p p c p q p
c p p q p
c p p c p
c p p c p c p
c p p
A B
A
A
A B A
A
A A
A B
A
A A
A
A B
A
B A
A B A
A
B A
A B
A
B
B
1 , 1 ,
2
2 ,
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1
2 , 1
1 , 1 ,
1
2 , 1
1 , 1 ,
2
2 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1
2 , 1
1 , 1 ,
1
2 ,
if
if 1
if
if
if
if
In order to analyse the firms' decisions we again have to distinguish different cases concerning
the value of
q
.
Case 1):
( ) ( )
( )
u u
A + A
<
1
b c c
q ; This leads to
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
A + <
A + > A
A + < s A + +
= H
A + < A A + A +
A + > + A A
A + < s A + + A A + A +
= H
u
u u
u u
u u u u
u u u
u u u u u
c p p
c p p c q
c p p c p q p
c p p b c c c p
c p p b c c
c p p c p b c c c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 , 1 1 ,
if 0
if
if 1
if
if
if
Solving for firm
A
's price and plugging back into the profit functions yields
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) u u
u u u u
u u
u u
+ + A A
= H
A + A + > + A A +
A + A + <
= H
A A
1 1 2
1
2 if 1 2
2 if 0
1
1
2
1
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
2 1 ,
2
2
b c c
c c b q q c c b
c c b q
c c b p
AA
B
AA
A
A
Case 2): ( )
( ) ( )
( )
u u
u
A + A
> > A +
1
b c c
q c b ; Now, profits are
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
A + <
A + > + + A A + + A
A + < s A + + + A A + +
= H
A + < A A + A +
A + > + A A
A + < s A + + A A + A +
= H
u
u u u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u u
u u u u u
c p p
c p p q b c c q c
c p p c p q b c c q p
c p p b c c c p
c p p b c c
c p p c p b c c c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 , 1 1
if 0
if ) 1 (
if ) 1 ( 1
if
if
if
Then, we get:
58
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) u u
u u u u
u u
u u
+ + A A
= H
A A + + > + A A +
A A + + <
= H
A A
+
1 1 2
1
1 2 1 if 1 2
1 2 1 if 0
1
1
2
1
2
1 2
1
1
1
1 2
1
2 1 ,
2
2
b c c
c c b q q c c b
c c b q
c c b p
AA
B
AA
A
A
Case 3):
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) u
u u
c b q
b c c
A + > >
+ A A + 1
; For these values of
q
, we have the following profits:
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
A + < + A
A + > + + A A + + A
A + < s A + + + A A + +
= H
A + < A +
A + > + A A
A + < s A + + A A + A +
= H
u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u
u u u
u u u u u
c p p q c b
c p p q b c c q c
c p p c p b q c c q p
c p p c p
c p p b c c
c p p c p b c c c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 , 1 1
if
if ) 1 (
if 1 1
if
if
if
These profits lead to
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ) 1 (
1
) (
1
u u u
u u
u
+ + A A + + A = H
+ A A
= H
A =
q b c c q c
b c c
c p
AA
A
AA
B
A
Case 4): ( ) q c b > A + u ; In this case, profits are
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( )
( )( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
A + < + A
A + > A
A + < s A + + A +
= H
A + < A +
A + >
A + < s A + A +
= H
u u
u u
u u u
u u
u
u u u
c p p q c b
c p p c q
c p p c p q c q p
c p p c p
c p p
c p p c p c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
if ) (
if ) ( 2
if ) ( 1
if
if 0
if
Prices and profits are given by:
( ) ) ( 2 and 0 ; ) (
1 , 1 , 1 ,
u u c q c p
AA
A
AA
B A
A = H = H A =
Finally, assume
A B
d d d d = > = . We proceed as in the previous case.
i) If first period market shares were either such that only consumers with u u = or all
consumers regardless of their type bought from firm
B
we get the following scheme
59
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
q b c
p c b q p
c q p
A B
A A A B
A A B
A = H = H
= H A + + = H
= H A + = H
) ( ; 0 :
; ) 1 ))( ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u
u
This leads to the following second period outcomes
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )( )
( )( )
( )( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )( ) ( )( )
( )( )
( )
( )( )
( )
( )( ) ( )( )
( )( )
>
> > A + A
> A + A
= H
> A
> > A A
>
= H
> A
> >
>
=
A A
A A A + A
A + A
A A
A A A + A
A + A
A A
A A A + A + A A
A + A + A A
q
q c c b
q c c b
q q b c
q q b c c
q
q q b c
q
q
p
c b c
c b c c b c
c b c
A
B
c b c
c b c c b c
c b c
A
A
c b c
c b c c b c q b c c
c b c q b c c
A
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u u
u
u u
u
1
) ( ) ( 2
1
) ( ) ( 2 ) ( ) ( 1 1
) ( ) ( 1 1
3
2 ,
1
) ( ) ( 2
1
) ( ) ( 2 ) ( ) ( 1
) ( ) ( 1
3
2 ,
1
) ( ) ( 2
1
) ( ) ( 2 ) ( ) ( 1 1 1
) ( ) ( 1 1 1
2 ,
if 0
if ) ( ) (
if ) ( ) (
if ) (
if 1
if 0
if ) (
if
if
ii) If all consumers bought from firm
A
in the first period we get
q c
p c b q p
c q p
A B
A A A B
A A B
A = H = H
= H A + = H
= H A + = H
) ( ; 0 :
; ) 1 ))( ( ( :
0 ; ) ( :
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u
u
And thus
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
A + <
A + > A A
= H
A + < A
A + >
= H
A + < A
A + >
=
+ A A
) ( if 0
) ( if
) ( if ) (
) ( if 0
) ( if ) (
) ( if
1
4
2 ,
4
2 ,
1
2 ,
u
u u u
u u
u
u u
u
u u
c b q
c b q b c c
c b q q c
c b q
c b q q c
c b q
p
A
B
A
A
q b c c
A
Turning to the first period, profits and prices are given by:
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( )
( )
A < H
A < s A H +
A > H +
= H
A < H + + A
A < s A H + + A
A > H
= H
u
u u
u
u u
u u u
u
c p p
c p p c p p
c p p p
c p p q c p
c p p c p q c p
c p p
A B
A
A
A B A
A
A A
A B
A
A A
A
A B
A
B A
A B A
A
B A
A B
A
B
B
1 , 1 ,
3
2 ,
1 , 1 , 1 ,
3
2 , 1
1 , 1 ,
4
2 , 1
1 , 1 ,
3
2 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 ,
3
2 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
4
2 ,
if
if
if
if
if 1
if
60
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Again, we have to consider different parameter constellations:
Case 1):
( )( )
u u
A A
<
1
) ( ) ( 2 c b c
q ; Analysing the profit functions
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
A < A
A > A + A
A < s A A +
= H
A < + A
A >
A < s A + A
= H
u u
u u u
u u u
u u
u
u u u
c p p q b c
c p p q c c
c p p c p q b c p
c p p q c p
c p p
c p p c p q c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 , 1 ,
if
if 2
if
if
if 0
if 1
leads to the following price
p
A,1 and overall profits
( )
( ) ( ) 0 and 2
1 , 1 ,
1 ,
= H A + A = H
A =
AB
B
AB
A
A
q c c
q c p
u u
u
Case 2):
( )( )
u u
u
A A
> > A +
1
) ( ) ( 2
) (
c b c
q c b ; In this case we have
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
A < A A
A > A + A +
A < s A A A +
= H
A < A + A + + A
A >
A < s A A + A + + A
= H
u u u
u u u
u u u u
u u u u
u
u u u u u
c p p q b c c
c p p q c c b
c p p c p q b c c p
c p p c c b q c p
c p p
c p p c p c c b q c p
A B
A B
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
if 1
if 2 1 1
if 1
if
if 0
if 1
The optimal price
p
A,1 and the firms' profits are given by
( ) ( )( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )( ) ( )( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( )
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
+ A A >
+ A A <
= H
+ A A > A + A
+ A A < A + A +
= H
+ A A > A A
+ A A < A A +
=
2
1 2
1
1
2
1 2
1
2
1 2
1
2
1 2
1 1
2
1 2
1 1
2
1 2
1 1 1
1 ,
1 2 1 1 if
1 2 1 1 if 0
1 2 1 1 if 2 1 2
1 2 1 1 if 2 1 1
1 2 1 1 if 1
1 2 1 1 if 1
u u
u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u u u
b c c q b
b c c q
b c c q q c c b
b c c q q c c b
b c c q q c c
b c c q q c c b
p
AB
B
AB
A
A
Case 3):
( )( )
) (
) ( ) ( 1
u
u u
c b q
c b c
A + > >
A + A
; Profits can be written as
61
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
A < A A
A > A
A < s A A A +
= H
A < + A A + + A
A > A A
A < s A + A A + + A
= H
u u u
u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u u
u u u u u
c p p q b c c
c p p q c
c p p c p q b c c p
c p p b c c q c p
c p p b c c
c p p c p b c c q c p
A B
A B
b
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
2
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
if 1
if
if 1
if
if
if 1
The implied pricing decision of firm
A
and the firms' profits are given by
( ) ( )( ) ( )
( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u
c c b
c c q q b c c
c c q q c c b
q c c p
AB
B
AB
A
A
A A +
= H
A A > A A
A A < A + A
= H
A A =
2
1
1 if 1
1 if 2 1 2
1
1
1
1
1 ,
Case 4):
( )( )
q
c b c
<
A + A
u u ) ( ) ( 1
; In this final case, we obtain
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( ) ( )
( )
A <
A > A
A < s A
= H
A < + A A + + A
A > A A
A < s A + A A + + A
= H
u
u u
u u
u u u u
u u u
u u u u u
c p p
c p p q c
c p p c p p
c p p b c c q c p
c p p b c c
c p p c p b c c q c p
A B
A B
b
A B A A
A
A B A
A B
A B A A
B
1 , 1 ,
1 , 1 ,
2
1 , 1 , 1 , 1
1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
1 , 1 ,
1
1 , 1 , 1 ,
1
1 ,
if 0
if
if
if
if
if 1
As well as
( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) q c c b
q c c p
AB
B
AB
A
A
+ A A +
= H = H
A A =
u u
u u
2
1
and 0
1
1
1 ,
With all these different cases in mind, we now turn to the firms' data requirement decisions,
which are made at the beginning of the first period. To make the model more tractable we
derive these decisions for a couple of different parameter values which feature the
characteristic results, instead of the whole range of parameters.
We start with an intermediate value of 5 . 0 = . Under this assumption, a choice of d d
A
=
leads to the following comparison for firm
B
's profits:
( ) ( )
( ) ( ) d d b c c q
d d b c c q
B
S
B
AA
B
B
S
B
AA
B
= H s H + A A >
= H > H + A A s
: 2 2 3
: 2 2 3
u u
u u
62
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
In contrast, d d
A
= implies that we have a symmetric equilibrium for low values of
q
only:
d d c b q
d d c b q
B
S
B
AA
B
B
AA
B
AS
B
= H s H A + >
= H > H A + s
: ) (
: ) (
u
u
Considering the decision of firm
A
and evaluating the firms' profits for all parameter
constellations we get
q c c b d d d d
c c q c b
b d d d d
b c c q c c
b d d d d
b c c q b c c
b d d d d
b c c q
A B A
A B A
A B A
A B A
+ A A + = H = =
A A > > A +
= H = =
A A > > A A
= H = =
A A > > A A
= H = =
A A <
) ( 2 ) ( 3
) ( ) ( 2 ) ( ) 4
3
2 ) ( ) ( 2 ) ( ) ( 2 ) 3
3
2 ) ( 2 ) ( 3 2 ) ( ) ( 2 ) 2
3
2 ) ( 2 ) ( 3 ) 1
u u
u u u
u u u u
u u u u
u u
q b c c d d d d
c b q c c b
q c c b d d d d
c b q c b
A B A
A B A
2
3
) ( ) (
2
1
) ( ) ( ) ( 2 ) 6
) ( 2 ) ( 3
) ( ) ( ) 5
+ + A A = H = =
A + > > A A +
+ A + = H = =
A + > > A +
u u
u u u
u u
u u
b d d d d
q b c c
q b c c d d d d
c c b q b c c
A B A
A B A
3
2 ( 2 ) ( 3 ) 8
2
3
) ( ) (
2
1
) ( ) ( 2 2 ) ( 2 ) ( 3 ) 7
= H = =
< + A A
+ + A A = H = =
A A + > > + A A
u u
u u
u u u u
As a second parameterisation of the model we choose
3
2
4
1
) ( , = A = u c and
3
1
) ( = A u c .
Starting with d d
A
= and analysing firm
B
's best response we get
d d b q
d d b q
B
B
= + >
= + s
: 4
: 4
2
1
2
1
Again, equilibrium candidates are asymmetric, except for sufficiently high
q
. With d d
A
= we
obtain
d d b q
d d b q
B
B
= + >
= s
: 4
: 1
2
1
6
19
Thus, all possible equilibria are asymmetric, except for the case in which if
q
is sufficiently
low. Assuming different values of
b
and
q
leads to the following results:
63
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
9
7
6
17
2
1
2
1
9
7
4
5
1 , 2
1
2
1
4
5
2
1
2
1
12
19
2
1
1 , 2
1
2
1
: 1 , 1
2 : 1 ,
: , 1
: ,
3 : 0 , 1
: 0 ,
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AB
B
AB
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
As a third parameterisation we consider
3
2
4
3
) ( , = A = u c and
3
1
) ( = A u c . Again considering
different values of
b
and
q
we get the following equilibria
23 : 1 , 1
: 1 ,
23 : , 1
: ,
23 : 0 , 1
: 0 ,
6
47
2
25
3
13
2
1
12
91
2
1
2
25
12
49
2
1
2
1
3
22
2
25
6
23
2
1
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
= H = H = = = =
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
AA
B
AA
A B A
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
d d d d q b
One can see that in a any of the examples firm
A
will choose d d
A
= , with firm
B
's response
given by d d
B
= . This leaves both firms with positive profits.
Two-period model with 0 > r
Scenario a): ) ( ) ( 0 u u b b A > A >
For both periods we get the same pricing functions as in the one-period model:
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( (
2
1
, , B B A B A t A t B
q d c d c d c d c p r p o u u u u + + + =
-
) )) , ( ) , ( )( 1 ( )) , ( ) , ( ( 3 (
2
1
, B A B A B A t A
q q d c d c d c d c r p o o u u u u =
-
Comparison of profits for the data requirement decisions also yields again:
> A + A
=
-
otherwise
) ( ) 1 ( ) ( if
d
q c c d
d
j
u u
Thus, we have two equilibria. If q c c > A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u :
t
r
p d d
r
p d d
t B B t A A
= = = =
- - - -
),
4
5
, ( ),
2
3
, (
, ,
and if q c c s A + A ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( u u :
t q
r
p d d q
r
p d d
t B B t A A
= = = =
- - - -
),
4
5
, ( ),
2
3
, (
, ,
64
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
The similarity to the one-period model is due to the fact that without personalisation the
second period is just the repetition of the first periods pricing decision. As there is no lock in,
there is no additional surplus to be distributed.
Scenario b):
) ( 0 ) ( u u b b A > > A
Using the result from the one-period model that both firms choose the same data
requirement, we focus on the case with d d d
B A
= = . With d d d
B A
= = we would get the
same results expect that equilibrium prices are reduced by
q
.
Solving the model with backward induction, we first have to analyse the firms' and consumers'
behaviour in the second period. Taking into account that all types consumers may switch in
the second period, we first show that there are no equilibria in which consumers with u do
actually switch. We then characterise the equilibria where all consumers of type u opt for
personalisation and do not switch in the second period.
Equilibrium with both types of consumers switching:
First we show that an equilibrium in which consumers with u u =
i
switch firm does not exist.
We first consider the case in which consumers, who have bought from firm A in the first
period, buy from firm B in the second period.
In order to do so we construct indifferent consumers for both types:
,2 ,2
2
( )
2
A B c
r p p b
i
r
u
+ +
=
,1 ,1
1
( )
2
A B c
r p p b
i
r
u
+
=
,2 ,2
2
( )
2
A B c
r p p
i
r
u
+
=
,1 ,1
1
( )
2
A B c
r p p
i
r
u
+
=
Note that
2
( )
c
i u denotes an indifferent consumer of type u , who is indifferent between
buying from firm A in both periods and switching from A to B. This means
1
( )
c
i u is thought of
as being indifferent between switching from A to B and staying with B in both periods. For
consumers of type u , ) (u
c
t
i denotes the indifferent consumer in period t.
To start with the firms pricing decisions we use the part of the profit function, which relates
to the second period. Thus, we get:
2 , 2 , 2 , j j j
p n = H
According to the indifference conditions above, we can rewrite the second period profit
function as:
( ) ( )
2 , 2 2 2 ,
) ) 1 ((
A
c c
A
p i i u u + = H
65
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
( ) ( )
2 , 2 2 2 ,
)) 1 ( ) 1 )( 1 ((
B
c c
B
p i i u u + = H
For firm B we derive the optimal reaction function, by plugging in the indifferent consumers
and differentiating the profit function with respect to price:
2
) 1 (
2 ,
2 ,
A r
B
p b r
p
+
=
By doing the same for firm A and plugging in Bs reaction we derive:
2
) 1 ( 3
*
2 ,
b r
p
A
+
=
Plugging back into the reaction function above we then derive:
4
) 1 ( 5
*
2 ,
b r
p
B
=
For the second period indifferent consumers we thus get:
r
b r
i
c
8
) 3 1 ( 3
) (
2
u
+ +
=
( )
r
b r
i
c
8
)) 1 ( ( 3
2
u
=
Now, let us turn to the first period. We now consider the following profit functions:
( ) ( )
2 , 1 , 1 1 1 ,
) ) 1 ((
A A
c c
A
p i i t u u + + = H
( ) ( )
2 , 1 , 1 1 1 ,
)) 1 ( ) 1 )( 1 ((
B B
c c
B
p i i t u u + + = H
Again, we derive the reaction function for firm B:
2
) 1 (
1 ,
1 ,
A r
B
p b r
p
+ +
=
This leads to the optimal pricing for firm A and in turn also for firm B:
2
) 1 ( 3
*
1 ,
b r
p
A
=
4
) 1 ( 5
*
1 ,
b r
p
B
+
=
Then we again get the location of indifferent consumers in the first period:
( )
r
b r
i
c
8
) 3 1 ( 3
1
u
+
=
( )
r
b r
i
c
8
)) 1 ( ( 3
1
u
+
=
By construction we would require ( ) ( ) u u
c c
i i
2 1
> . However, this does not hold here and thus
optimal pricing decisions lead us to a contradiction.
66
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
For the case of consumers switching from firm B to firm A, we get the similar results, which
are derived accordingly. For the second period we now get:
2
) 1 ( 3
*
2 ,
b r
p
A
=
4
) 1 ( 5
*
2 ,
b r
p
B
+
=
( )
r
b r
i
c
8
) 3 1 ( 3
2
u
+
=
For the first period, the results are now:
2
) 1 ( 3
*
1 ,
b r
p
A
+
=
4
) 1 ( 5
*
1 ,
b r
p
B
=
( )
r
b r
i
c
8
) 3 1 ( 3
1
u
+ +
=
Again, the necessary condition that ( ) ( ) u u
c c
i i
2 1
< holds is violated.
Now, let us consider the possible corner solution, in which one firm sets a second period
price, such that all consumers choose this firm. Therefore, assume any first period market
share
1 , A
n and any second period price
2 , A
p . If firm B wants to get all consumers in the second
period, it has to choose a strategy r b p p
A
m
B
=
2 , 2 ,
in order to compensate the consumer for
whom choosing B is least favourable. Note that firm A would make zero profits in this period.
Therefore, it could just lower the price according to a standard undercutting- argument until
profits are driven out of the market. In such a situation firm B could choose to sacrifice a few
consumers, but making positive profits on all other consumers with a slight increase of
2 , B
p .
Thus, switching to another strategy as
m
B
p
2 ,
is beneficial for firm B and thus one would have to
consider candidates for an interior solution again.
62
But as these candidates have already been shown to lead to contradictions, we are able to
conclude that this type of equilibrium does not exist in this game.
Equilibrium with only consumers with a high concern switching:
Turning to the equilibria where only consumers with u switch, we first characterise the firms'
pricing strategies in the second period. We then turn to the first period decisions of the
consumers and the firms.
62
A similar argument can be constructed for firm A as well.
67
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
Calculating the firms' pricing decisions in the second period, we have to take into account that
the firms' demand functions are kinked. More precisely, while the indifferent consumer ) (
2
u
c
i
is given by
)
`
)
`
+
=
r
r p p
i
A B c
2
, 0 max , 1 min ) (
2 , 2 ,
2
u
firms also have the option to set their prices such that consumers with u would switch. Note
that although this pricing strategy cannot be part of an equilibrium we nevertheless have to
specify the induced profits as we have to calculate all deviation profits in the second period.
Using 0 ) ( > A u b and assuming that all consumers with u opted for personalisation, the
indifferent consumer ) (
2
u
c
i is given by
> =
s s
s =
=
+
+ +
)) ( 2 1 ( if } 1 , min{ : ) (
)) ( 2 1 ( )) ( 2 1 ( if ) (
)) ( 2 1 ( if } , 0 max{ : ) (
) (
2 , 2 , 2
2
2 , 2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 2
2
2 , 2 ,
2 , 2 ,
u u
u u u
u u
u
c
A B r
b r p p
c
c
A B
c c
c
A B r
b r p p c
c
i r b p p i
i r b p p i r b i
i r b p p i
i
A B
A B
where ) (u
c
i denotes the consumer with u who was indifferent between buying from firm
A
and firm
B
in the first period.
Using ) (
2
u
c
i and ) (u
c
i the firms' profits in the second period can be written as
| |
| |
| |
> + = H
s s + = H
s + = H
= H
)) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
)) ( 2 1 ( )) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
)) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( ) 1 ( ) (
2 , 2 ,
2
2 2 ,
3
2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 2 ,
2
2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 2 2 ,
1
2 ,
2 ,
u u u
u u u u
u u u
c
A B
c
c
A A
c
A B
c c c
A A
c
A B
c c
A A
A
i r b p p i i p
i r b p p i r b i i p
i r b p p i i p
as well as
| |
| |
| |
> + = H
s s + = H
s + = H
= H
)) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( 1 )( 1 ( )) ( 1 (
)) ( 2 1 ( )) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( 1 )( 1 ( )) ( 1 (
)) ( 2 1 ( if ) ( 1 )( 1 ( )) ( 1 (
2 , 2 ,
2
2 2 ,
3
2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 2 ,
2
2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 2 2 ,
1
2 ,
2 ,
u u u
u u u u
u u u
c
A B
c
c
B B
c
A B
c c c
B B
c
A B
c c
B B
B
i r b p p i i p
i r b p p i r b i i p
i r b p p i i p
We are now maximising
2 , B
H with respect to
2 , B
p and let
-
2 , B
p denote the optimal price for
firm B , i.e.
2 , 2 ,
max arg :
B B
p H =
-
and note that
-
2 , B
p - depending on the parameter
constellations- is given by one of the following prices
) ) 1 ( (
2
1
max arg :
)) ( 2 1 ( :
)) ( 1 (
1
)) ( 2 1 ( (
2
1
max arg :
) ) 1 ( (
2
1
max arg :
2 ,
3
2 ,
3
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 ,
2 ,
2
2 ,
2
2 ,
2 ,
1
2 ,
1
2 ,
b r p p
i r b p p
i r i r p p
b r p p
A B B
c
A
c
B
c c
A B B
A B B
u
u
+ + = H =
+ =
+ = H =
+ = H =
68
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
where
c
B
p
2
2 ,
is the highest price
2 , B
p such that no consumer with u switches. Using
-
2 , B
p and
turning to firm
A
, firm
A
's profit function can be written as
| |
| |
| |
= + = H
= + = H
= + = H
= = H
= H
- -
-
- -
- -
3
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 4
1
3
2 ,
2
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 2
1
2
2 ,
2
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 4
1
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 , 4
1
1
2 ,
2 ,
if 3 ) 1 (
if ) (
if )) ( 1 ( 2 )) ( 2 ( (
if 3 ) 1 (
B B A A r A
c
B B
c
A A r
c
A
B B
c c
A A r A
B B A A r A
A
p p r b p p
p p i p p b
p p i r i r p p
p p r b p p
u
u u
Note for later reference, that
2 , A
H is linearly increasing in
2 , A
p as long as
c
B B
p p
2
2 , 2 ;
=
-
.
Furthermore, undercutting firm A and inducing some consumers with u to switch by
choosing
1
2 , 2 , B B
p p =
-
becomes more attractive for firm B the higher the price of firm A.
Analysing
2 , A
H and calculating the optimal price
-
2 , A
p for firm A we get the following set of
possible equilibrium prices
{ }
c
B B B B
c
A
B B B B
c
A
i
A
j
A
c
A
c
A A A A A
p p p
p p p
j p
p p p p p p
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
2
2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
1
2 ,
2 , 2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
3
2 ,
2
2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
for such that
as well as for such that
and 3 , 2 , 1 with max arg :
with , , , ,
= H = H
= H = H
= H =
e
-
-
-
-
Taking into account that we are looking for an equilibrium in which consumers with u do not
switch, we can focus on
p
A,2
2
and
p
A,2
c1
as well as
p
A,2
c2
which are given by
| |
| |
)) ( 4 3 ( ) )) ( 1 ( 2 )( 1 ( 2 2 3
) ( 2 )) ( 1 ( 2
1
) 1 )( ( 2 2
2
2
2 ,
1
2 ,
2
2 ,
u u
u u
c c c
A
c c c
A
c
A
i r b i r b b b p
i r i r b r b p
i
r
p
+ + =
+ + + =
+ + =
Turning to the first period, we start with the decisions of the consumers. While the indifferent
consumer with u is again given by
} 1 },
2
, 0 { max { min ) (
1 , 1 ,
1
r
r p p
i
A B c
+
= u
the indifferent consumer with u , i.e. ) (u
c
i , is implicitly given by the solution of the following
equation (assuming interior solutions)
)) ( 1 ( 2 ) ( 2
2 , 1 , 2 , 1 ,
u u
c
B B
c
A A
i r p p b i r p p b =
- -
where the second period equilibrium prices
-
2 , A
p and
-
2 , B
p are functions of ) (u
c
i (see above).
Solving this equation for the candidate equilibrium prices we get, assuming again ) 1 , 0 ( ) ( e u
c
i
69
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
| |
| |
| |
1 , 1 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2 / 3
1 , 1 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
1
2 , 2 ,
1 , 1 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
2 , 2 ,
2
1
) ( and
) ( )) ( ( 2
) 2 1 ( 2
1
) ( and
5 ) ( 4 ( 2
) 5 3 ( 2
1
) ( and
A B
c c
B B
c
A A
A B
c
B B
c
A A
A B
c
B B A A
p p r b
r
i p p p p
b r p p r r
r
i p p p p
r p p r
r
i p p p p
+ + = = =
+ + +
+
= = =
+ +
+
= = =
- -
- -
- -
u
u
u
Given the second period profits as well as ) (u
c
i , we are now able to specify the firms' overall
profits:
| |
| |
- -
- -
= =
= =
H + + = H
H + + = H
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 ,
,
2 , 1 1 ,
,
2 , 1 1 ,
)) ( 1 )( 1 ( )) ( 1 (
) ( ) 1 ( ) (
B B A A
B B A A
p p p p
B
c c
B B
p p p p
A
c c
A A
i i p
i i p
u u
u u
Using these profit functions and calculating the firms' optimal prices reveals that the
equilibrium prices are given by
2
2 , 2 , A A
p p =
-
and
2
2 , 2 , B B
p p =
-
as long as is high enough. To
be more specific, using the same parameter constellations as in the case with zero
transportation costs and calculating the firms' profits for all possible deviations, shows that
4 / 1 > suffices to guarantee that the firms' pricing decisions in the first period lead to an
interior equilibrium with
2
2 , 2 , A A
p p =
-
and
2
2 , 2 , B B
p p =
-
in the second period. Solving for the
optimal first period prices
-
1 , A
p and
-
1 , B
p , we get that the firms' reduced profit functions do
not depend on q and b . More precisely, we obtain
| |
| |
r
i i p
r
i i p
B B A A
B B A A
p p p p
B
c c
B B
p p p p
A
c c
A A
2 2
,
2 , 1 1 ,
2
,
2 , 1 1 ,
)) 14 ( 3 19 ( ) 7 (
)))))) 25 892 ( 10999 ( 53252 ( 83307 ( 47424 ( 8901 ( 2
)) ( 1 )( 1 ( )) ( 1 (
)) 14 ( 3 19 ( ) 7 (
)))) 4 87 ( 4 1937 ( 1834 ( 473 (
) ( ) 1 ( ) (
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 ,
2 , 2 , 2 , 2 ,
u u
u u
+ + +
+ + + + + +
=
H + + = H
+ + +
+ + + +
=
H + + = H
- -
- -
= =
- -
= =
- -
Differentiating
-
H
A
and
-
H
B
with respect to reveals that both profits are decreasing in .
Intuitively, the higher , the lower is the fraction of consumers who choose personalisation
and thus the lower the fraction of consumers who are locked-in in the second period. Since
second period equilibrium prices decrease in an increase in reduces the firms' profits.
Considering first period decisions, firm
B
can anticipate that the price firm
A
will choose in
the second period is the higher the more personalising consumers firm
A
has attracted in the
first period. Firm
B
's incentive to increase its first period demand by choosing a rather low
price is therefore higher for an increased , i.e the lower the number of consumers who opt
for personalisation. Taking these effects together, shows that equilibrium prices in both
periods and thus the firms' profits decrease with .
2
Study on monetising privacy
An economic model for pricing personal information
P.O. Box 1309, 71001 Heraklion, Greece
www.enisa.europa.eu