El 1404

You are on page 1of 4

VOL. 9, NO.

4 APRIL 2014

DALLASFED

Economic Letter
Central Bank Transparency Anchors Inflation Expectations
by J. Scott Davis, Adrienne Mack and Mark A. Wynne
entral banks in most developed countries, responding to the financial crisis that began in 2007, have pushed interest rates to zero (or close to it) and embarked on a range of unconventional monetary measures. These policies have boosted the size of the central banks balance sheets to extraordinary levels, both in absolute terms and as a share of gross domestic product. Such actions could have been expected to lead to significant increases in actual and expected inflation. Yet to date, in most of the countries that implemented these policies, actual inflation remains close to, if not below, central banks targets, and inflation expectations remain well anchored. The Federal Reserves rate-setting Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has greatly increased the amount of communication about its decisions over the last two decades.1 This major change was part of a broader Fed move toward greater transparency. Central banks have long realized the importance of independence, transparency and credibility to successfully maintain low and stable inflation. Students of central banking have long maintained that greater policymaking transparencydesirable as part of sustaining independent central bank

A high statistical correlation can be found between the level of policy transparency among central banks and the anchoring of ination expectations.

accountabilityalso yields significant dividends in terms of the conduct of monetary policy. Specifically, it was argued that greater transparency would increase central bank credibility and help anchor inflation expectations. Moreover, it allows a central bank to take extraordinary measures in certain circumstances without the public fearing that policymakers had abandoned their commitment to price stability. In fact, a high statistical correlation can be found between the level of policy transparency among central banks and the anchoring of inflation expectations.

Central Bank Transparency


Researchers Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen sought to quantify various aspects of central bank transparency and combine them into a single index that could be tracked over time.2 They looked at five dimensions of transparencypolitical transparency, economic transparency, procedural transparency, policy transparency and operational transparency. Political transparency involves how open a central bank is about its policy objectives. The researchers ask three questions. First, is there a formal statement of the objective or objectives of monetary policy? (In the case of the Fed, the FOMC has a dual mandate for full

Economic Letter
employment and price stability.) Second, is the primary objective quantified? And third, are there explicit institutional arrangements between the central bank and the government? Regarding economic transparency, three questions are also posed. First, are economic data relevant for the conduct of monetary policy publicly available? Second, does the central bank disclose the economic model or models that it uses for policy analysis? And third, does the central bank regularly publish its own macroeconomic forecasts? Procedural transparency, the third dimension, involves how monetary policy decisions are undertaken. Three more questions are asked. First, does the central bank provide an explicit policy rule or strategy that describes its policy framework? Second, does it give a comprehensive account of its deliberations within a reasonable amount of time? And third, does the central bank disclose how it reached its rate-setting decision? Policy transparency is the fourth aspect of transparency that Dincer and Eichengreen include in their index. Three questions follow. Are decisions about the adjustment to the main operating target or instrument announced promptly? Does the central bank provide an explanation of its decisions when it announces them? And does the central bank disclose an explicit policy inclination after every policy meeting? Operational transparency is the final dimensionagain, with three questions. Does the central bank regularly evaluate to what extent its main operating targets have been achieved? Does the central bank regularly provide information on unanticipated macroeconomic disturbances that affect the policy transmission process? And does the central bank offer an evaluation of the policy outcome in light of its macroeconomic forecasts? Dincer and Eichengreen score the answers to the questions with a 0, or 1. Summing the 15 scores, they arrive at an aggregate index that ranges from 0 (least transparent) to 15 (most transparent). For 2010, the Federal Reserve System scored 11, putting it in the top 10 central banks in terms of transparency that year. The European Central Bank also scored 11, and the Sveriges Riksbank (central bank of Sweden) took the top spot with a score of 14.5. Among member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), Mexico rated a 6, the lowest score of the group. Over the past 15 or so years, there has been a general movement toward greater transparency, according to a review of the DincerEichengreen measure for major central banks and for an average of 20 countries with independent central banks (Chart 1). 3

Over the past 15 or so years, there has been a general movement toward greater transparency, according to a review of the DincerEichengreen measure for major central banks and for an average of 20 countries with independent central banks.

Anchoring Ination Expectations


The anchoring of inflation expectations refers to a change in what people anticipate about inflation in some future

Chart

Central Banks Become Increasingly Transparent

Index of central bank transparency


13 12 Greater transparency 11 10 9 8 7

U.K. U.S. Euro zone Average of 20 countries Japan 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

SOURCE: Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, Bank of Korea Working Paper no. 2013-21, September 2013.

Economic Letter Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas April 2014

Economic Letter
period in response to temporary and/or unexpected inflation today. Thus, if expectations are perfectly anchored, then beliefs about future inflation shouldnt change following a temporary increase in prices for instance, following a sudden rise in oil and gas prices. However, if they arent perfectly anchored, then even a temporary shock to prices today can feed long-term inflation expectations and affect price and wage stability for years to come.4 Because expectations are not typically observed, gauging how anchored they are can be challenging. Some survey data on inflation expectations do exist, and market expectations can be inferred from the yields on nominal and real (inflationadjusted) bonds. But these data are available for only a handful of countries. An alternative measure of the extent to which inflation expectations are anchored may be constructed for a wide range of developed and developing countries.5 It assesses how much people raise their long-term expectations when actual inflation is 1 percentage point higher than anticipated. If there is no change in inflation expectations following a surprise increase in prices, then the index takes a value of zero and inflation expectations are perfectly anchored. The average value of the anchoring index across the same 20 countries depicted in Chart 1 is plotted for 1998 2007 (Chart 2). The smaller the index value is, the more anchored are inflation expectations. For the average country in the sample, there was a steady fall in this index over the 10 years. In 1998, when actual core inflation turned out to be 1 percentage point higher than expected, people raised their long-term inflation expectations by 0.10 percentage points. By 2007, they would raise long-term inflation expectations by only 0.02 percentage points following the same unexpected increase.

An alternative measure of the extent to which ination expectations are anchored may be constructed for a wide range of developed and developing countries.

Aiding Monetary Policy


Has the move toward greater central bank transparency helped anchor inflation expectations and made it easier to realize monetary policy? For the average country in the sample, inflation expectations became better anchored between 1998 and 2007, as indicated by the data used in Charts 1 and 2. The 19982007 average transparency index value plotted against the average value of the anchoring index for the 20 countries in the sample shows that countries with more transparent central banks have more anchored inflation expectations (Chart 3). The inflation anchoring index fallsmeaning expectations are more anchoredas the transparency index rises. Cross-country differences in central bank transparency explain 44 percent of the cross-country differences in inflation expectation anchoring, statistical analysis shows. This finding is in line with the results from other studies showing a strong tie between central bank transpar-

Chart

Ination Expectations Become More Anchored Over Time

Anchoring of ination expectations


.12 .10 .08 .06 .04 .02 0 Greater anchoring

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

SOURCES: Cross-Country Variation in the Anchoring of Inflation Expectations, by Scott Davis and Adrienne Mack, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Papers, no. 21, 2013.

Economic Letter Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas April 2014

Economic Letter

Chart

Transparency Linked to Ination Expectations in Advanced Countries

Anchoring of ination expectations


1 .9 .8 .7 .6 .5 .4 .3 .2 .1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 Index of central bank transparency Greater transparency 12 14 Greater anchoring

SOURCES: Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, Bank of Korea Working Paper no. 2013-21, September 2013; Cross-Country Variation in the Anchoring of Inflation Expectations, by Scott Davis and Adrienne Mack, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Papers, no. 21, 2013.

ency and reduced inflation and inflation volatility.6

Policy Benets
Over the past two decades, the Federal Reserve System has become much more transparent about how it formulates and conducts monetary policy. Other central banks similarly changed their practices over the period. One of the main arguments for greater transparency in policy deliberations is that it helps anchor inflation expectations. The evidence supports this argument. Among advanced countries, a review shows a strong relationship between an index of central bank transparency and one measuring the anchoring of inflation expectations. The fact that transparent

central banks such as the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England can maintain stable inflation expectations despite extraordinary measures and an unprecedented amount of monetary easing over the past five years is a testament to the benefits of monetary policy transparency and credibility. Davis is a senior research economist, Mack is a senior research analyst and Wynne is an associate director of research and vice president in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Notes
See A Short History of FOMC Communication, by Mark A. Wynne, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 8, no. 8, 2013.
1

See Central Bank Transparency: Where, Why and With What Effects?, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, in Jean-Philippe Touffut, ed., Central Banks as Economic Institutions, Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar, 2008, pp. 10541; Central Bank Transparency: Causes, Consequences and Updates, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, Theoretical Inquiries in Law, vol. 11, no. 1, 2010; Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, Bank of Korea Working Paper no. 201321, September 2013. 3 The 20 countries are Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg, Mexico, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom and the United States. The transparency index for the euro zone is a gross domestic product-weighted average of Eurosystem central banks in 1998 and a measure for the European Central Bank from 1999 onward. 4 See Relating Commodity Prices to Underlying Ination: The Role of Expectations, by J. Scott Davis, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 6, no. 14, 2011, and Ination Expectations Have Become More Anchored Over Time, by J. Scott Davis, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 7, no. 13, 2012, for a discussion of the role that ination expectations play in the price-setting process and how the 1970s temporary shocks to oil prices, combined with unanchored ination expectations, led to years of high ination. 5 See Cross-Country Variation in the Anchoring of Ination Expectations, by Scott Davis and Adrienne Mack, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Papers, no. 21, 2013. 6 Central Bank Independence and Transparency: Evolution and Effectiveness, by Christopher Crowe and Ellen E. Meade, European Journal of Political Economy, vol. 24, no. 4, December 2008, pp. 76377; and Central Bank Transparency: Causes, Consequences and Updates, by Nazire Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen, Theoretical Inquiries in Law, vol. 11, no. 1, 2010.
2

DALLASFED

Economic Letter

Mine Ycel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research E. Ann Worthy, Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision Anthony Murphy, Executive Editor Michael Weiss, Editor Jennifer Aferbach Associate Editor Ellah Pia, Graphic Designer

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System. Articles may be reprinted on the condition that the source is credited and a copy is provided to the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy