Final One Nos
Final One Nos
Final One Nos
This Module examines each of the three disciplines in turn and the other
provisions of the Agreement on Agriculture.
Other WTO agreements also discipline trade in agricultural products. Those
with the biggest impact on trade in agricultural products are: the GATT
1994; the Agreement on Safeguards or the Safeguards Agreement; the
Agreement on Import Licensing Procedures or the Import Licensing
Agreement; the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and
Phytosanitary Measures or the SPS Agreement; the Agreement on
Technical Barriers to Trade or the TBT Agreement and, the Agreement on
Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights or the TRIPs
Agreement.
These agreements, along with the Agreement on Subsidies and
Countervailing Measures or the SCM Agreement and the Agreement on
Implementation of Article VI of the GATT 1994 or the Antidumping
Agreement are also briefly examined.
2.1
Introduction
The Agreement on Agriculture is one of the key agreements within the WTO
system. Its importance is reflected by its presence as the first Agreement
annexed to the Marrakesh Agreement establishing the WTO.
The Agreement on Agriculture is fairly short, with only 21 Articles and 5
Annexes. The 21 Articles are rather surprisingly divided into 13 Chapters.
This form of the Agreement on Agriculture probably reflects the sensitivity
of the sector and the difficulty in achieving agreement among WTO
Members.
The specific agricultural commitments made by WTO Members are not
found in the Agreement on Agriculture, but in Article II Country
Schedules of the GATT 1994. Both the Agreement on Agriculture and the
Country Schedules must be examined together to understand a WTO
Members commitments on agriculture.
The Agreement on Agriculture applies to agricultural products. Agricultural
products are defined in Annex 1 of the Agreement on Agriculture. This
definition makes reference to the Harmonized System of product
classification. In practice, agricultural products are those within Chapters 1
to 24 of the Harmonized System less fish and fish products, as well as some
specific products which come from the soil. Forestry products are not
included.
The definition of agricultural product covers not only basic agricultural
products such as wheat, milk and live animals, but the products derived from
them such as bread, butter, oil and meat, as well as all processed agricultural
products such as chocolate, yoghurt and sausages. The coverage also
includes wines, spirits and tobacco products, fibres such as cotton, wool and
silk, and raw animal skins destined for leather production.
The Agreement on Agriculture has three main parts: Part III on market
access; Part IV on domestic support (subsidies) and Part V on export
subsidies. Each of these parts are examined in turn.
2.2
Market Access
2.2.1
Introduction
Market access simply means the right which exporters have to access a
foreign market. The WTO agreements allow WTO Members to protect their
markets. In practice market access refers to the ways in which that
protection can be implemented. In the WTO framework it is a legalistic
term indicating the government-imposed conditions under which a product
may enter a country and be released for free circulation within that country
under normal conditions.
The specific border measures to protect markets allowed under the
Agreement on Agriculture are tariffs and tariff rate quotas. A tariff is a
duty or tax. Although there are several different forms of tariffs, the major
ones used in agriculture are ad valorem (calculated as a percentage of the
value of the goods), specific (a unit tax based on quantity) and mixed (a
combination of these two). A tariff rate quota is a specific volume (quota) at
which a product can enter a market at a tariff rate which is different (lower)
than the over- quota tariff.
A tariff is a trade barrier that takes the form of a government tax imposed
on goods (usually imports and occasionally on exports) when they cross
borders. Like internal taxes, a tariff generates revenue for the government of
the importing country.
A tariff rate quota is a quantity of imports or exports within which a lower
tariff applies. A higher tariff applies above the volume of the quota (the
over- quota tariff).
2.2.2
Tariffication
Prior to the Uruguay Round, border protection for agricultural products was
not always in the form of tariffs. In addition to tariffs, other non-tariff border
measures were applied. A core element of the Uruguay Round negotiations
was the agreement to convert these other types of border protection
mechanisms into tariffs. This process was called tariffication.
Tariffication is the process of conversion of all non-tariff market protection
measures into the tariff equivalent. The tariff equivalent to a non-tariff
barrier is the difference between the average domestic price and the average
world market price.
Many exporting developing countries, which did not, or were not able to
undertake detailed examinations of the drafts, found themselves faced with
prohibitively high tariffs on the products which they intended to export.
Because of the use of a reference period when the difference between the
world market price and the domestic price was wide, tariffication, in many
cases, resulted in high tariffs anyway. In addition, some WTO Members set
lower tariffs on raw materials and higher tariffs on processed agricultural
products so as to protect domestic processing industries. These three side
effects of tariffication are known as dirty tariffication, tariff peaks and
tariff escalation.
However, most of the principal agricultural exporting Members considered
that, even if the process of tariffication resulted in high tariffs, the benefits
of fixing tariffs and removing variable levies outweighed the disadvantages.
Dirty tariffication is the use, during the tariffication process, of
artificially- high domestic prices and artificially-low world market prices in
order to set a particular tariff at a level higher than it should be.
Tariff peaks are considered to be rates set higher than the rates across
the same product group or product sector. For some products, which
governments consider sensitive, tariff rates remain very high.
If a country wants to protect its processing or manufacturing industry, it can
set low tariffs on the imported raw materials used by the industry (cutting
the industrys costs) and set higher tariffs on finished products to protect the
goods produced by its domestic processing industry. This is known as tariff
escalation.
The tariffs agreed at the end of the negotiations were then included in each
WTO Members Country Schedule. The legal status of a WTO Members
Schedule of Concessions was addressed by the Appellate Body in the EC
Computer Equipment case, where it was held that:
() a Schedule is () an integral part of the GATT 1994 () Therefore, the
concessions provided for in that Schedule are part of the terms of the treaty.
As such, the only rules which may be applied in interpreting the meaning of
a concession are the general rules of treaty interpretation set out in the
Vienna Convention.7
The Appellate Body in the Korea Dairy case insisted on the fact that the
WTO agreements are one treaty and therefore all provisions (including the
Country Schedules) ought to be interpreted harmoniously and in an effective
manner, in order to ensure that no clause or provision is reduced to
inutility.
The Panel Report in the Korea Various Measures on Beef dispute
proceeded to a determination of the obligations of the Republic of Korea
under the WTO Agreement as a whole with regard to each measure and
concluded:
Koreas Schedule does not constitute an exception to other GATT
provisions, but rather qualifies Koreas obligations under the WTO
Agreement.
2.2.3
Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture prohibits the use of agriculturespecific non-tariff measures. In particular, Article 4.2 of the Agreement on
Agriculture provides that:
Members shall not maintain, resort to, or revert to any measures of the kind
which have been required to be converted into ordinary customs duties,
except as otherwise provided for in Article 5 and Annex 5.
Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture has been clarified by the Chile
The Appellate Body in the Chile Price Band System dispute noted
that:
Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture should be interpreted in a way
that gives meaning to the use of the present perfect tense in that provision particularly in the light of the fact that most of the other obligations in the
Agreement on Agriculture and in the other covered agreements are
expressed in the present, and not in the present perfect, tense. In general,
requirements expressed in the present perfect tense impose obligations that
came into being in the past, but may continue to apply at present. As used in
Article 4.2, this temporal connotation relates to the date by which Members
had to convert measures covered by Article 4.2 into ordinary customs
duties, as well as to the date from which Members had to refrain from
maintaining, reverting to, or resorting to, measures prohibited by Article
4.2. The conversion into ordinary customs duties of measures within the
meaning of Article 4.2 began during the Uruguay Round multilateral trade
negotiations, because ordinary customs duties that were to compensate
for and replace converted border measures were to be recorded in
Members draft WTO Schedules by the conclusion of those negotiations.
These draft Schedules, in turn, had to be verified before the signing of the
WTO Agreement on 15 April 1994. Thereafter, there was no longer an option
to replace measures covered by Article 4.2 with ordinary customs duties in
excess of the levels of previously bound tariff rates. Moreover, as of the date
of entry into force of the WTO Agreement on 1
January 1995, Members are required not to maintain, revert to, or resort
to measures covered by Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture.11
If Article 4.2 were to read any measures of the kind which are required to
be converted, this would imply that if a Member -for whatever reason- had
failed, by the end of the Uruguay Round negotiations, to convert a measure
within the meaning of Article 4.2, it could, even today, replace that measure
with ordinary customs duties in excess of bound tariff rates. But, as Chile
and Argentina have agreed, this is clearly not so. It seems to us that Article
4.2 was drafted in the present perfect tense to ensure that measures that
were required to be converted as a result of the Uruguay Round - but were
not converted- could not be maintained, by virtue of that Article, from the
date of the entry into force of the WTO Agreement on 1 January 1995.12
The Panel and the Appellate Body in the Chile Price Band System dispute
did not think that the provisions of Article 4.2 of the Agreement on
Agriculture should be read to include only those specific measures that were
singled out to be converted into ordinary customs duties by negotiating
partners in the course of the Uruguay Round. In particular, the Appellate
Body stated that:
The wording of footnote 1 to the Agreement on Agriculture confirms our
interpretation. The footnote imparts meaning to Article 4.2 by enumerating
examples of measures of the kind which have been required to be
converted, and which Members must not maintain, revert to, or resort to,
from the date
of the entry into force of the WTO Agreement. Specifically, and as both
participants agree, the use of the word include in the footnote indicates
that the list of measures is illustrative, not exhaustive. And, clearly, the
existence of footnote 1 suggests that there will be measures of the kind
which have been required to be converted that were not specifically
identified during the Uruguay Round negotiations. Thus, in our view, the
illustrative nature of this list lends support to our interpretation that the
measures covered by Article 4.2 are not limited only to those that were
actually converted, or were requested to be converted, into ordinary customs
duties during the Uruguay Round.13
Furthermore, the Appellate Body in the Chile Price Band System dispute
noted that:
() Article 4.2 not only prohibits similar border measures from being
applied to some products, or to some shipments of some products with low
transaction values, or the imposition of duties on some products in an
amount beyond the level of a bound tariff rate. Article 4.2 prohibits the
application of such similar border measures to all products in all cases.14
Variable import levies are complex systems of import surcharge. They are
aimed at ensuring that the price of a product in the domestic market remains
unchanged regardless of price fluctuations in exporting countries.
Discretionary import licensing is the requirement to obtain a permit to
import a product. This normally involves an administrative procedure
requiring the submission of an application or other documentation to the
relevant administrative body as a condition for importing.
Through voluntary export restraints, a country agrees to limit its exports to
another country to an agreed maximum within a certain period.
Agricultural state trading enterprises are enterprises which have been
granted exclusive or special rights, or privileges that are not available to
commercial firms, thus distorting trade in a competitive market.
10
duties that result from the application of Chiles price band system take the
same form as ordinary customs duties does not imply that the underlying
measure is consistent with Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture.19
However, Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture does not prevent the
use of non-tariff import restrictions consistent with the provisions of the
GATT
1994 or other WTO agreements which are applicable to general trade in
goods (industrial or agricultural). Such trade-restrictive measures include
those maintained under the balance-of-payment provisions (Article XIX of
the GATT
1994), general exceptions (Article XX of the GATT 1994), the SPS
Agreement,
the TBT Agreement, or other general, non-specific WTO
provisions.
Annex 5 to the Agreement on Agriculture provides a major exception with
respect to the general tariffication requirement. Under this provision, the
obligation to convert protective measures into customs duties was deferred
by six years for certain products and in particular rice. The exception no
longer applies.
2.2.4
Tariff Modification
Once tariffs are negotiated, WTO Members agree to bind those tariffs.
This means that WTO Members are not normally allowed to impose import
duties in excess of the bound tariffs inscribed in each countrys Schedule
of Concessions.
The bound level of tariffs can be changed in accordance with the procedure
set out in Article XXVIII of the GATT 1994. As WTO Members are
allowed to apply a lower tariff than the bound level, Article XXVIII is only
invoked when a WTO Member wants to raise the tariff so as to increase
market protection.
A WTO Member may modify or withdraw a concession in a Schedule either
by agreement with the affected countries, or unilaterally. The exporting
WTO Members which might be affected by the modification or withdrawal
of the binding of the tariff have certain rights of negotiation and
compensation. In addition, according to Article XXVIII:2, the WTO
Member changing the tariff must endeavour to maintain a general level of
reciprocal and mutually advantageous concessions not less favourable to
trade than that previously applicable. This means that if a tariff is raised,
some compensation must be given in another sector (i.e., by lowering
another tariff) so as to allow a rebalancing of the levels of trade
concessions.
11
2.2.5
Tariff Reductions
WTO Members agreed in the Uruguay Round that once the tariffs were
fixed, they would agree to reduce these tariffs over time, i.e., over six to ten
years starting on the date of the coming into effect of the Marrakesh
Agreement in
1995. The tariff reductions were fixed at the time of the conclusion of the
Uruguay Round and are also set out in each WTO Members Country
Schedule.
2.2.6
It was foreseen that the high tariff levels resulting from the tariffication
process could turn out to be more protective than their non-tariff
predecessors. Negotiators recognized that the use of the 1986 to 1988
reference period would result in prohibitively high tariffs. These high
tariffs were likely to disrupt existing trade.
WTO Members were therefore obliged to ensure that a certain amount of
domestic consumption would continue to be supplied by imports. All WTO
Members agreed to open up their markets to imports for at least 3 per cent of
the domestic consumption in 1995, and for 5 per cent by 2000.
The maintenance of existing trade levels was ensured by means of current
access quotas. In addition, minimum access commitments were created to
allow new import opportunities for products previously covered by a nontariff barrier.
Both these commitments were administered through the
establishment of tariff-rate quotas (TRQs).
12
The value of a quota volume, and the in-quota and over-quota tariffs are
defined in each WTO Members tariff schedules. In a given period, a lower
in- quota tariff is applied to the first number of units of imports and a higher
over- quota tariff is applied to all subsequent imports.
Tariff quotas are not considered quantitative restrictions because, at least in
theory, they do not limit import quantities. One may always import by
paying the over-quota tariff.
TRQs usually generate a quota rent. In fact, the right to import within the
quota results in a profit over and above the profit available in normal trade.
This extra profit results from the fact that the protected market price is
usually higher than the world market price. The necessity to administer the
TRQs is a consequence of the fact that the demand to trade within the quota
is often greater than the supply. The allocation of the TRQs among supply
countries and the distribution of licences to the quota to traders determine
who gets the benefit of this quota rent or super profit.
Quota rent is a profit which results from the difference between the
domestic price and the world price inclusive of the in-quota tariff.
2.2.7
TRQ Administration
13
2.2.8
If these two preconditions are met, a WTO Member may invoke the special
safeguard clause, according to Article 5.1(a) and 5.1(b) of the Agreement
on Agriculture, where either:
14
There are therefore two alternative grounds for invoking the special
safeguard provision: surges in the volume of imports and falling import
prices. However, not every rise in the volume or every fall in the price of
imports entitles countries to resort to Article 5. In each case, there are set
threshold levels, which are called volume triggers or price triggers.
Article 5.8 of the Agreement on Agriculture provides
that:
Where measures are taken in conformity with paragraphs 1 through 7
above, Members undertake not to have recourse, in respect of such
measures, to the provisions of paragraphs 1(a) and 3 of Article XIX of the
GATT 1994 or paragraph 2 of Article 8 of the Agreement on Safeguards.
Thus, a WTO Member may choose between the special safeguard measures
under Article 5 of the Agreement on Agriculture or the general safeguards
under the GATT 1994 Article XIX in accordance with the implementation
requirements of the Agreement on Safeguards. However, if a WTO Member
chooses to introduce special safeguards, it cannot have recourse to general
safeguard measures.
The special safeguards provisions for agriculture differ from the general
safeguards. In agriculture, unlike with normal safeguards:
The special agricultural safeguards can only be used on products that were
tariffied. These amount to less than 20 per cent of all agricultural products.
But they cannot be used on imports within the tariff quotas, and they can
only be used if the WTO Member reserved the right to do so in its Schedule
of agricultural commitments. This might explain why, in practice, the
special agricultural safeguards have been used only in relatively few cases.
The two special safeguards mechanisms (i.e., price and volume safeguards)
may not be invoked concurrently. They are available to WTO Members for
use for the duration of the agricultural reform process as determined under
Article 20 of the Agreement on Agriculture. The Agreement on Agriculture
does not specify how long the reform process will (or should) last.
15
16
2.2.9
Dispute Settlement
In the dispute EC Poultry (WT/DS69)27 Brazil complained about the
allocation of an EC tariff-rate quota for frozen poultry meat and the use by
the EC of a special safeguard measure under the Agreement on
Agriculture. The dispute involved the interpretation of the ECs tariff
schedule and its relationship with a separate bilateral agreement between
the EC and Brazil, which provided for a global annual duty-free tariff-rate
quota for frozen poultry meat. Brazil argued that as a result of the
agreement, the tariff-rate quota should be allocated exclusively to Brazil and
not shared on an MFN basis with other WTO Members. The WTO Panel
found, and the Appellate Body upheld, the Panels finding that the
agreement was not part of WTO law and therefore could not be applied
directly as law in WTO dispute resolution. Further, the Appellate Body
interpreted the relevant EC Tariff Schedule. As the EC was bound by its
tariff schedule which provided for MFN non- discriminatory treatment,
Brazil could not seek preferential treatment on the basis of tariff
concessions negotiated bilaterally. The Appellate Body also found that the
ECs administration of this tariff quota did not violate the WTO
Agreement on Import Licensing Procedures. Finally, the Appellate Body
interpreted the special safeguard provision in Article 5 of the Agreement on
Agriculture. It decided that the calculation of the import price, which
determines whether to apply the special safeguard measure, must not
include custom duties. It further found that the EC could not use
representative price to determine the c.i.f. import price of an individual
shipment.
The Panel in Chile Price Band System (WT/DS207)28 examined a
complaint brought by Argentina concerning Chiles price band system,
which imposed
17
variable tariffs on imports of wheat, wheat flour, edible vegetable oils and
sugar. Under the Chilean price band system, additional duties were imposed
on imported commodities if market prices in markets of concern to Chile
fell below an administratively-administered price band. Chile argued
that the scope of application of Article 4.2 was limited to measures which
had actually been converted or requested to be converted into customs
duties during the Uruguay Round - which had not happened in the case of
price band systems. The Appellate Body did not agree with this view. It
found that the scope of the measures covered by Article 4.2 was not limited
to those described by Chile, but that the language of Article 4.2 was intended
to cover a broad category of measures. The Appellate Body found support
for its interpretation in Article 5.1 and footnote 1 to Art. 4.2. The Appellate
Body addressed the question whether the PBS was a border measure similar
to a variable import levy and minimum import prices within the
meaning of footnote 1 to Article 4.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture. In
order to determine similarity, the Appellate Body used what it called an
empirical approach: do two or more things have likeness or resemblance
sufficient to be similar to each other? It then compared the Chilean PBS
with the two measures and noted similar features as to a lack of
transparency and the possible effect of impeding the transmission of
international price developments to the domestic market. Though
recognizing certain dissimilarities, the Appellate Body regarded the
similarities to be sufficient to qualify the PBS as a similar border
measure within the meaning of footnote 1 to Article 4.2. Therefore, the
WTO Appellate Body upheld the Panels finding that Chiles price band
system is a border measure that is similar to variable import levies and
minimum import prices.
18
3. AGRICULTURAL SUBSIDIES
3.1
Introduction
The Agreement on Agriculture seeks to ensure that agricultural trade is not
distorted through the use of subsidies.
Agricultural support measures are classified as belonging to two major
groups:
3.2
Domestic Support
In WTO non-legal terminology, domestic subsidies to agricultural products
are identified by special boxes which are given the colours of traffic
lights: Green meaning permitted because they have no, or minimal,
distortive effect on trade; Amber meaning possibly legal or illegal
because of their trade- distortive nature; and Blue meaning possibly tradedistorting but permitted as the measures are linked to production limitation
programmes.
3.2.1
Amber Box
Measures
19
20
Even though the reduction commitments are applicable generally over all
agricultural commodities, the calculation of AMS is made on the basis of the
spending on specific commodities during a reference period. The two basic
criteria for valuing support are its effect on prices and its cost to the
government. Both budgetary outlays (i.e., the money spent by governments
to support a product) and revenue foregone by governments or their agents,
whether at national or sub-national level, are included in the AMS
calculation.
Annex 3 of the Agreement on Agriculture provides that three types of
support are to be included in the calculation:
21
For example, this can be the case for market price support measures which
cannot be calculated by applying the AMS method, because no external
reference price can be determined. In that case, an equivalent measurement
of support will be calculated.
3.2.2
Exempted Measures
22
Any measure not shown to satisfy the conditions for exemption under
Annex
2 or Article 6 of the Agreement on Agriculture is required to be included in
the calculation of the current total AMS for the year in question.
3.2.2.1 Green Box Exemption
Annex 2 of the Agreement on Agriculture sets out general criteria and
conditions for exemption to the commitment to reduce domestic subsidies.
Measures which fall within the terms of Annex 2 are known as the Green
Box. Green Box support measures are considered economically neutral.
Therefore, the WTO does not impose any financial limitation to this type of
domestic support.
The subsidies falling under this category are non-actionable (in other words,
immune from challenge) by virtue of Article 13 of the Agreement on
Agriculture (the Due Restraint or peace clause provision). In particular,
the domestic support measures that fully conform to the provisions of
Annex 2 to the Agreement on Agriculture are considered non-actionable
subsidies for purposes of countervailing duties during the implementation
period of the Agreement on Agriculture (defined, for purposes of the peace
clause, as the nine-year period commencing in 1995).
The fundamental requirement to qualify for a Green Box exemption is that
support measures should have no, or at most minimal, distorting effects on
trade or production.
Accordingly, all measures for which exemption is claimed must conform to
the following basic general criteria:
23
Direct payments
24
Payments for relief from natural disasters are also included in the Green
Box. These payments are allowed only if producers show a production
loss that exceeds 30 per cent of the average of production and will
compensate for not more than the total cost of replacing production loss.
Article 7.1 of the Agreement on Agriculture provides that WTO Members
are under an obligation to ensure that all Green Box measures are
maintained in conformity with the conditions set out under Annex 2. Any
measure not shown to satisfy the conditions for exemption is required,
under Article 7.2 of the Agreement on Agriculture, to be included in the
calculation of the current total AMS for the year in question.
3.2.2.2 Blue Box Measures
The Blue Box exemption category is contained in Article 6.5 of the
Agreement on Agriculture. It covers any support measure that would
normally be in the Amber Box, but which is placed in the Blue Box if
the support also requires farmers to limit their production.
Therefore, Article 6.5 of the Agreement on Agriculture exempts from
reduction commitments certain direct payments to farmers which are tied to
production- limiting programmes.
The following
fulfilled:
criteria
must
be
25
26
27
Background
28
1981
1991
2001
20
10
0
Tropic al
P roduc t s
Tem perat e
P roduc t s
S eafood, Fruit s
, V eget able s
and Flowers
Other
P roc es sed
P roduc t s
50
40
30
Average Ad Valorem
Tariff
20
10
0
A us tralia
US
EU
Jordan
3).
40
40
Intermediate
Intermediate
30
Raw
Raw
20
20
10
0
0
QU
D
QU A
AD
C
C anad
anad aa
Jap
Jap an
an
UUSS
EU
EU
LarLar
g g e Ot herOt her Lo w erLo
e
d i d d l Me id d l
wM
eri M
MInco
i dd
mel e
d
l e me Inco me
Inco
e Inco Inco Cme
o unt ri C
Inco
me
es
o unt ri es
me
CCo ount
o unt
untririeses CCo
unt riri es
es
Average Tariff
4.1
10.9
Maximum Tariff
238.0
50.0
Standard Deviation
13.5
10.1
9.9
350.0
European Union
19.0
506.3
27.3
Republic of Korea
39.9
917.0
107.9
Brazil
13.2
55.0
5.6
Costa Rica
14.2
154.0
18.0
Morocco
67.4
376.5
70.6
Indonesia
8.9
170.0
25.6
Malawi
16.5
25.0
8.5
Togo
15.6
20.0
6.1
Uganda
13.6
15.0
3.2
26.5
Tariff
rate
quotas
Tariff rate quotas (TRQs) on imports, implemented in the
Uruguay
Round Agreement
on Agriculture for sectors in which nontariff barriers were converted
into tariffs, are a complicating factor. Countries agreed to allocate
quotas for imports up to 5 percent of domestic consumption
(minimum access quotas) and to safeguard current levels of
access if imports exceeded 5 percent of consumption (current
access quotas). Countries were to permit imports under the quota
at lower tariffs (called the in-quota tariff), whereas imports over
the quota would face the higher MFN tariff. In-quota tariffs,
unlike over-quota tariffs, were neither bound nor reduced
in the Agreement on Agriculture. The average over-quota bound
tariff of
115 percent is substantially higher than both the average in-quota
tariff and the average tariff for all of agriculture, both of which are
59 percent.
But TRQs are the source of a host of potential problems. First,
because they protect about 50 percent of OECD agricultural
production, it would be unwise to allow all the products they
protect to be deemed Sensitive Products, as was suggested in some
proposals before the July 2004 Framework Agreement. Second,
many quotas are not filled, suggesting that reductions in over-quota
tariffs may have less impact than might otherwise be expected.
Actual problems with TRQs are evident, as well. The first-come,
first-served approach to their administration (used by many
countries), for example, sometimes causes imports to be rushed
and
domestic prices to fall. Import licenses allocated on demand allow
high-cost firms to operate, while licenses allocated on the basis of
historical shares fail to ensure competition. Some state trading
enterprises have been known to import low-quality products for
animal feed to fulfill their obligations yet continue to protect their
domestic farmers. More problems abound from a plethora of
additional regulations. For example, seasonal licenses, time limits,
limits per firm, and a domestic purchase requirement all impose
extra costs on importing firms. These and several other regulations
were found (de Gorter and Klianga 2005) to affect over $30 billion
in trade. For these reasons, it is doubtful that the path to wider
market access in agriculture lies through TRQs.
35
18
8
7
6
5
5
4
12
100
Source: Unpublish ed GTAP mod el resu lt s b y K. An d erson and E. Valen zu ela, World Bank
(153%)
100
100
80
Bound
60
Applied
40
20
0
U co
i
US A C
A
on kye
EAN ni
anadaS
U Tur
re
b
T
A
SS
-
A
a
er
apan ndi
EF ksi t J
Ko
agh
100
100
80
80
Average Tariffs
60
40
20
00
Japan
Japan
Turkey
EU
EU
Norw ay
ay Canada
Canada
Norw
US
US
Hungar yy Mex
Mex ic
ic o
o
Hungar
Turkey
Proposed cut
10
0
1
0
0
90
80
80
USA
G-20
G-20
7
700
EU
EU
6
600
50
40
30
G-10
G-10
2
200
10
0
0
0
10 20
20
10
30
30
40 50
50
40
60 70
70
60
80 90
90 100
100 1
1 10
10 1
12
20
0 13
13 0
0 140
140 1
15
50
80
USA
USA
55 00
EU
44 00
G-20
33 00
20
G-10
10
0
0 10
15
20
30
40
50
60
70 80
9 0 1 0 0 1 1 0 120 13 0 1 40 1 5 0
Source: Marcos Jank, Institute for International Trade Negotiations (ICONE), 2005.
countries, the liberalization of applied duties is reduced by twothirds overall and much more in Canada, Japan, and Republic of
Korea. The cut in applied tariffs falls even moreby 80 percent. A
tariff cap would help reduce the losses to liberalization resulting
from designations of Sensitive and Special Products,
particularly by bringing about substantial reductions on cereals.
Clearly, if the Doha Round is to be successful in increasing market
access, it will be important to ensure (a) that only a small share of
products is accorded special treatment, (b) that substantial
reductions in protection are made even on these products, or (c)
that the number of products is restricted in a more meaningful way
than by restricting the number of tariff lines.
Another design issue related to the simple tiered formula is the
discontinuities between bands that can result from a system of
higher cuts for tariffs in bands with higher tariff rates. Assume, for
example, a tariff threshold of 90 percent. If there were a 10
percentage point difference between the rates of cut, tariffs just
over that threshold would end up nearly 10 percentage points below
tariffs at the threshold. One possible solution to this problem is to
implement a tiered formula similar to that of a progressive income
tax, whereby higher marginal rates of reduction are made on tariffs
in higher tariff bands. Another possibility is a rate of cut that
increases with the height of the tariff.
Recent reform proposals by the U.S. (2005), the G-20 (2005), the EU (2005)
and the
G-10 (2005) have elaborated considerably on the Framework.
These proposals specify tiered formulas for tariff reduction with
maximum reduction rates in industrial countries of 90 percent, 75
percent, 60 percent and 45 percent respectively. In developing
countries, the cuts are smaller, and increases in cuts take place from
higher tariff levels. The relationship between the proposed cuts is
shown in figures 6 and 7. The proposals also differ crucially in
the number of sensitive products allowed; the U.S. proposed
1 percent of tariff lines, the EU has proposed 8 percent and the G10
has proposed 10 or 15 percent. Jean, Laborde and Martin (2005)
show that even 2 percent of sensitive products can almost
eliminate the market access gains resulting form a tiered formula.
Policy
options
If governments wish to promote development through increased
market access, they have several options:
Impose an overall reduction in average tariffs to ensure that the tiered approach
is effective and as a further guard against the adverse effects of the Sensitive and
Special Product categories.
Build progressivity into every tariff band to ensure reduction in
tariff escalation and avoid discontinuities or overlap between
tariffs in the bands.
Convert all specific tariffs into ad valorem equivalents using a
transparent methodology that will not allow a clandestine
increase in protection.
Encourage full participation by developing countries, especially as
Special
Products designations could reduce their liberalization substantially.
Require reductions in in-quota tariffs, or eliminate them
altogether. In-quota tariffs can put a significant brake on the
trade liberalizing effects of quota
expansion.
Increase minimum access quotas from 5 percent to 10 percent
of domestic consumption in the base year.
Expand current access quotas, which account for 58 percent of
trade under TRQs. Because minimum access quotas frequently
go unfilled, an expansion in current access quotas may be more
effective.
Do not leave to importing countries the choice of whether to
reduce over- quota tariffs or expand quotas. Research shows
that the minimum trade expansion under each scenario is far
less than either the tariff reduction or quota expansion scenario
alone, so governments wishing to protect farmers can do so
more easily if given the choice.
Switch all TRQs to applied tariffs with no limits on imports,
or require the licenses to be auctioned. Quota underfill frequently
indicates potential problems with administration methods.
Phase out TRQ regulations such as time limits, past trading
performance, limits per firm, seasonal quotas, and domestic
purchase requirements because they impose costs on importing
firms and may contribute to high rates of underfilled quotas.