V Sharan Chapter 4
V Sharan Chapter 4
V Sharan Chapter 4
Eichengreen, B. Ed. (1986) , The Gold Standard in Theory and History, New
Methuen.
-,
"
V 5 ~ oJv(JvV\J I~ E-J
---,---------,---
g Objectives
a floating-rate regime, exchange rate -is determined by market forces. The present chapter
us discusses the process of its determination, although in the beginning, it acquaints the
aders with the basics of how exchange rates are quoted. In particular, the chapter attempts:
"To explain how exchange rates are quoted in spot and forward markets.
To explain the distinction between nominal, real and effective exchange rates.
-To present how demand and supply forces determine the exchange rate in spot market.
To show how SOme macroeconomic variables, such as inflation rate and interest rate influence
the exchange rate.
:Tq show how the interest rate differential influence the forward exchange rate and to evaluate
the interest rate parity theory in _this _context.
to show how covered/uncovered interest arbitrage takes place when interest rate differential
ie gold standard to the adjustable peg under the Bretton Woods system
'"
76
for a floating-rate, regime and especiaUy for those who deal in foreign exchange.
However, in the beginning, let us understand' the fundamentals of exchange rate
quotation, so that we may bette:rliriderstarid the exchange rate determination'
process.
EXCHANGE RATE.QUOTATIONS
In a forei~ exch~nge market where different currencies are bought and sold, it is
'essential to know the ratio between different currencies; or how many units of one
currency will equal one unit pf another currericy. The ratio between two currencies
is known as an exchange rate. The various exchange rates are regularly quoted in
ne";'spapers and periodicals.
'
,
Solution
US $ 1~ 45 = US $ 0.0222~.,
If indirect quote is US
direct quote?
':77
..
above example, the spread is ~ 0.30 per US dollar. The bid-ask spread is often
'
(4.1)
~.
;IU,;
Solution
~ 1IUS
- . ,. $ 0.025 : ~ 40mS $.
.~
~::~:fiBj ~'.
~
Chapter
Sql[JtitJn .
,;,0.0123 x 40,50
0:50 = X
.. '.
x';" 40:00.
If the forward rate is lower than the spot rate, it will be a case of forward
discount. On the contrary, if the forward rate is higher than the spot rate, it would
'be known as forward premium. Forward premium or discount is expressed as an
annualised percentage deviation from the spot rate. It is computed as follows:
(4.2)
39.80
- 40.00 x W
360 = -0. 06 or 6 per cent fiorwar d d'Iscount.
'40.00
The swap quote, on the other hand, expresses only the difference between the spot
quote and the forward quote. It can be written as follows:
Spot
One month
Three months
~ 40;00-30
~ (20)-(10)
~ (40)-(20)
It may be noted'that decimals are not written in swap quotes.
:; ,.
TT.Buy . Bill,Buy
'Tl'Sell
BillSell
TCBuy~. CCY,Buy
Aush-an;";"Dori~
..
.
. .
30
(X. - 45)= 0.12. ~ 45 x 360
.
.'
~=
38.6400,
Forward, rate
In the above quotes, it is found that the longer the maturity, the diffElreniiaI h
' WIt
. h Ionger represents
te
. t h e ch ange m
. t h e fiorwar d ra t es. A
greater IS
gam,
diff~rencEJ.Qf'
maturity, the spread too gets wider. This is because ofuncertaintYfciiW'a:rdahds~ot
in the future that increases with lengthening of maturity. The ;r~!eS?ilJigedI:lY '.
change in forward rates' may be upwards or downwards. With spot.r~tes~own in
.
terms
of
such movements, d
Ispanty
anses b etween spo t an d fiorwar d rates.
annualised
This is known as the swap or forward rate differential.
percentage,
45 + OA5/or x= 45,45
Cross Rates
Sometimes the value of a currency in terms of another one is not known directly.
In such cases, one currency is sold for a common currency; and again, the common
currency. is exchanged for the .desired currency. This is kn0:w n . as cross Cross exchange
rate tradmg and the rate estabhshed between the two currenCIes IS known rate'.betyieen two
as the cross rate. Suppose, a newspaper quotes ~ 35.00-35.20IUS $; and currenCi~sis
at, the same time, it quotes Canadian $ 0.76-0.78IUS $ but does not fou~doutthrough
.
their value. In a
quote the exchange rate between the rupee and the CanadIan dollar. common currency.
Thus the rate of exchange between the rupee and the Canadian dollar ....,-,----'---"-
will be found through the common currency, the US dollar. The technique is similar
for both spot and forward c.ross rates.
46.32/C$
The buying rate of the Canadian dollar in India can be found through buy
the Indian rupee for the US dollar at ~ 35.001US $ and selling the Canadian do
for US dollar at C$ 0.78IUS $. This means that
.
~
44.87-46.32/C$
In this case too, the selling rate of one currency is divided by the buying rate
another currency and vice versa. Suppose, one month forward rate in case of t
two currencies is ~ 34.50-34.80IUS $ and C$ 0.79-0.83fUS $. The forward rate'E~'
the Canadian dollar in terms of the rupee can be found as
}
~
34.80/C$0.79 = ~ 44.05/C$ ,
34.50/C$ 0.83 =
41.57
and P* are domestic and foreign price indices. If the price index in India
,USA rises from 100 in 1998 to 120 and 110, respectively in 2001 and if
inal exchange rate between the two currencies between the two dates
'at ~ 40lUS $, the real exchange rate will move to:
40.00 x 120/110 = ~ 43.64!US $
floating-rate regime, as discussed in Chapter 3, the nominal exchange rate
'automatically with a change in the price level. But in a fixed-rate regime,
not happen so because the rate is administered. As a result, there arises
between the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange rate.
111
,
Thit~~t~g'i~d:34p~~ia.~~.~rid~li;~biggest't;~d~paitf1er~~h8.~irigi~spect;i~~r
''':.J".
S'
~~ I '
outth~
.,
>Szt
D
D'
Q,Q2Q3
A 1
~..,,.l-.
.......... I"T.n.
the supply of the dollar increases to S', the exchange rate will again'~~j)'
'{ 40lUS $. Quite evidently, the frequent shifts in the demand and supply conditi~
cause the exchange rate to also adjust frequently to a new equilibrium.
tm
Impact of Inflation
It is normally the inflation rate differential between the two countri
that influences the exchange rate between the two currencies. The influeIl'
determiiledby ihe' of inflation rate finds a nice explanation in the Purchasing Power Pan
p'urchasingpower
(PPP) theory (Cassel, 1921; Officer, 1976). This theory suggests that'
of the ,iwo ';;
'any,given time, the rate of exchange between two currencies is determiri
currencies. '
by their purchasing perwer. If e is the exchange rate and PA and PB "
the purchasing power of two currencies, A and B, the equation can be written'
E:'I"Ptheorysh?ws
exchange rate . "
e = PAIPB
"'~
~tigh changes in the exchange rate. Suppose the price of a commodity soars in
ia to ~ 125, the arbitrageurs will buy that commodity in the USA and sell it in
:a to earn a profit of~ 25. This will go on till the exchange rate moves to ~ 2.51
s if the Indian commodity turns costlier, its export will fall. At the same time, ,
import price being cheaper, its import from' the USA will expand. Higher
'rt will raise the demand for the US dollar in turn raising its value vis-a.-vis
:upee.
owever, this version of the theory, which is known as the absolute version,
s good if the same commodities are included in the same proportion in the
iestic 'market basket and the world market basket. If it is not, PPP theory will
'hold good despite the law of one price holding good. Moreover, this theory does
':cover the non-traded goods and services where transaction cost is significant.
In~17latio.ftal
Financial Management
In view of the above limitation, another version of this theory has evolv
which is known as the relative version of the PPP theory. The relative version stat~k
that a change in exchange rate that would retain the original level of relative pr"
of tradable to non-tradable goods in the economy, would establish an equilibri
exchange rate. It further states that the exchange rate between currencies of a
, two countries should be a constant multiple of the general price indices prevaili
iz: them. In other words, percentage change in exchange rate should equal t
percentage change in the ratio of price indices in the two countries. To put it
an equation,
e!eo = (1 + I A )tl(l + IB)t
wb.ere IA and IB are the rates of inflation in country A and country B, eo is the val
of A's currency in terms of one unit of B's currency in the beginning of the peri
and et is the spot exchange rate in period t.
For example, inflation rate in India is 5 per cent and that in USA 3 p.er ce
and if the initial exchange rate is ~ 40lUS $, the value of the rupee in a two-ye
period will be
'
e2 = 40(1.05/1.03)2
or
~ 41.571US $
Such an inflation-adjusted rate is known as the real exchange rate. This mea,
that if the real exchange rate is constant, currency gains or losses from nomi"
exchange rate changes will be offset by the difference in relative rates of inflati
Sometimes when a government sticks to a particular exchange rate without carin,gj
for prevailing inflation, a gap emerges between the real and the nominal exchang~
:-ates which results in lowering of export competitiveness and in turn, the tra'q.~,
deficit. This is why, this theory suggests that a country with high rate of inflati4'
should devalue its currency relative to the currency of the countries with low~;
inflation rates. Again,.it is the real exchange rate, and not the' nominal excharile:
rate, that has a bearing on the performance of the economy.
:i)~
erts differ on how changes in interest rate influence the exchange rate. The
,ible price version of the monetary theory explains that any rise in domestic
est rate lowers the demand for money, and the lower demand for money in
.ion to the supply of money causes depreciation in the value of domestic currency.
sticky price version of the monetary theory has a different explanation which
at a rise in interest rate increases the supply of loanable funds which leads
eater supply of money and a depreciation in domestic currency. At the same
e, however, it shares the views with the balance of payments approach where'
ligher interest rate at home than in a foreign' country attracts, capital from
oad in lure of higher return and the inflow of foreign currency results in increase
'Lhe supply of foreign currency and raises the value of domestic currency.,
However, suggests Fisher, this proposition cannot be thought of in isolation of
,ation, inasmuch as inflation negates the return on capital to be received. If the
;rest rate is 10 per cent and the rate of inflation is 10 per cent, the real return
:apital would be zero. This is because the gain in the form of interest is cancelled
by the loss on account of inflation. In fact, since it was Irving Fisher who
,.r
88
decomposed nominal interest into two parts-the real interest rate and the exp
fisher Effect
rate of inflation, the relationship between these two elements is
explains that
as the Fisher Effect.
nominal interest
The Fisher effect states that whenever an investor thinks 0
rate is the'
.
investment, he is interested in a particular nominal interest rate
~'::~s~~a~~ 7ri::
covers bot~ the ~xpected inflation and the required real interest
iriflation rate.
MathematIcally, It can be expressed as
1 + r = (1 + a)(1 + I)
where
r = nominal interest rate,
a =real interest rate, and
I = expected rate of inflation.
Suppose the required real interest rate is 4 per cent and the expected ra
inflation is 10 per cent, the required nominal interest rate will be:
1.04 x 1.10 - 1 = 14.4%
Suppose, the interest rate in the USA is 4 per cent and the inflation rate in
is 10 per cent higher than in the USA. A US investor,will be tempted to inv
India only when the nominal interest in India is more than 14.4 per cent.
ing volume of capital in India will push down the interest rate. The capital
'11 continue till the real interest rate in the two countries becomes equal.
eanS that the process of arbitrage helps equate the real interest rate across
ies, and since the real interest rate is equal in different countries, the country
igher nominal interest rate must be facing a higher rate of inflation.
,r this type of arbitrage, however, it is necessary that the capital market be
neous throughout the world so that the investors do not differentiate between
mestic capital market and the foreign capital markets. In real life, such
eneo us capital market is not found in view of government restrictions and
economic policies in different countries. As a result, interest rates vary
countries. Mishkin (1984) confirms this view and finds that investors have a
liking for the domestic capital market in order to insulate themselves from
'exchange risk; and so, there will be no arbitrage even if real interest rate on
securities is higher. Again, the Fisher effect holds good normally in case of
aturity government securities and very seldom in other cases (Abdullah, 1986).
empirical tests present different results. Gibson (1970, 1972)
'ma and Schwert (1977) find the result in 'favour of the Fisher effect; while
dies of Mishkin (1984) and Cumby and Obstfeld (1984) do not support it.
A)= (I+IA)
l+r
_
-
(_
1+
1+I
rB'
(48)
.
se further that at the beginning of the period, interest rate in India is 7 per
s against 4 per cent in the USA. At the end of the period, interest rate in
India will rise to an extent that will equate approximately the inflationra
differential. In order to find out the change in interest rate, the following equati6'"
may be a p p l i e d : ' ' ' ' ' '
e/eo = 1 + rINd1 + rUSA
Basing on the above equation, we have
41.94/40 = (l + rIND)/1.04
or
. or
1+
rIND =
1.09
rIND = 0.09 or 9%
.
,f,f
If the rate of interest in India rises to 9 per cent, the interest rate different'
between the two countries will be: 1.0911.04 or 4.81 per cent which will
approximately equal to the inflation rate differential which is 1.08/1.03
4.85 per cent.
l.b~06/l..66X43.9L
= (l
+ rA)/(1 + rB) - 1
(4.10)
_ ...
.F A
{1 + -1} + 8
rA
1 +rB
(4.11)
Ie interest rates in India and the USA are respectively 10 per cent and 7 per
'he spot rate is ~ 40lUS $. The 90-day forward rate can be calculated thus,
F = 40 {1.1 0 _ I} + 40
4 1.07
F
=~
40.281US $
means that the higher interest rate in India will push down the forward
.
.the rupee from 40 to 40.28 a dollar.
r~
~:.
~,
.,
::;:r::'
92..
CI,apter 4
:~
':,.'1
~,~~
:~~{~tt~n~.~~~fl~~~\"'.
. 3-mo"t!>
.C
'
'
."
.<:,:,."",~;:/:I':'(S;"~"';'.,,:'~',t"::':,:~>.',:::h::,;\,'
i i t , n ' 'ii,':";:?:
; ~ill be covered iilterest arbitrage insofar as the int~restJ,"ft,e~Il~:f~~:~~,
rateparitY}~9i-~ri,l, " ..
fO<W>!""!!r~fI~;~?~\03?;\{;~~fi'
,::;..
~:
':.,
}~.
If the forward rate differential is not equal to the interest rate differential, cove'
interest arbitrage will begin and it will continue till the two differentials beco
,
'.
'
approximately equal. In other words, a positive interest rate differen
Covered
Interest,.
tA
t "r,,:e m t' e
arbitrage involves In a c~untry'.1~ 0:ff:set b'
y annual'Ised fi0:r:ward d'ISCOun.
~ega
borrowing and
rate dlfferentlalls offset by an annualised forward premIUm. Fmally,
IElndipgintv;O,
two differentials will be equal. In fact, this is the point where the forw
m~Iketsand als!? ',' rate is determined.
,bUYing,
spot and" ,
.
sellingfoiwardthe
To e~lam
the process of covered .
mterest '
arbItrage,. suppose,
re~pective
spot rate IS ~ 40/US $ and the three-month forward rate IS ~ 40.28
currencies .so as" $ involving a forward differential of 2.8 per cent. The interest rate i
tQad~~n parity ,
per cent in India and 12 per cent in the USA involving interest
con
.I'=al
. 1s are no t eq'
, Itlons.'
Wllerenti 0f 5. 37 per cent. S'mce t h e two d'=
iHerentla
covered interest arbitrage will begin. The successive steps shall be as follow
Borrowing in the USA, say, US $ 1,000 at 12 per cent interest
Converting the US dollar into the rupee at spot rate to get ~ 40,000/
Investing ~ 40,000 in India at 18 per cent interest
Selling the rupee 90-day forward at ~ 40.28/$
Mter three months, liquidating the ~ 40,000 investment which would
~,41,800
,
.
Selling ~ 41,800 for US dollars at the rate of ~ 40.28/US $ t
US $1,038
"OJ
Repaying loan in the USA which amounts to US $ 1,030
The first two actions narrow the interest rate differential, while 3 and 4 wid~
forward rate differential.
However, the real life experience shows that the two differentials-interest
e and forward rate-are equal only approximately and not precisely. It is because
interest rate parity theorem assumes ,no transaction cost, no tax rate differences
political stability. But the assumptions do not hold in real life.
First of all, there is always transaction cost involved in selling a currency spot
buying it forward. The transaction cost, which is manifest in the bid-ask
ad, forces forward rate differential to deviate from the expected one: The
saction cost, which is involved also in borrowing and investing, influences the
tive interest rate and thereby the interest rate differential.
Secondly, there is disparity in the tax rate on interest income in different
tries. Such a disparity allows the interest rate differential to deviate from the
cted one.
ast but not least, if there is political unrest in the country where the funds
,invested, the cost of investment will be greater and this will influence the
, est rate differential.
'
Uncovered interest
arbit<agedoes not
involve forward ,. '
rnark~f , '
transactions as
interest-rate
~iffeire.niial,leads ".
to <::hangesin
future.spbtrate.
8)/8
(4.12)
8 e+l i~ the expected future spot rate, and R A and R B are the interest rates
ntrY,A and Country B.
long as equality is not reached, the arbitrageurs will go for uncovered interest
ge and reap profits. Suppose the interest rate on the Indian treasury bill is
cent and that on the UK treasury bill is 4.0 per cent and so the interest
ifferential is 2.88' per cent. If the investor expects a depreciation of
Chapter 4
4.0 per cent in the future spot rate of Indian rupee helshe will invest in the UK
treasury bill because a fixed amount of British pound will fetch greater amount of
Indian rupee at a future date. This will go on till the two differentials are equal.'
This is uncovered interest arbitrage.
I
'~~~f~,;t~r~,~i1f~~f~~1
(v)
Even the covered interest arbitrage does hardly help achieve interest rate
parity. The reasons are:
(a) There is transaction cost involved in the arbitrage process which the
IRP theory does not take Into account.
(b) Control on capital account transactions is found in many countries that
hinders a smooth arbitrage process.'
.
e~cha~~e{ate.;g.t:pr:~.sen
.arpit~~g!~?r~'~r~':t~lli~~~%j~
N~ei~iny~st~eIlt.znatUI'~~ir"
~~;#1~ilt~t'1h:~~:~~i~~~!~6?
'~O~@"r
.. ,..
,.""
~~i~Wj~l'll'itili
parity,';;
'.<.i':
'-'.
1';,
+/'f;i)'; . (
The IRP theorem explains the forward rate differential in terms of interest rate
differential between two countries and emphasises the role of arbitrageurs who
help equalise the two differentials and help determine the no-profit forward exchange
rate. The proponents of the modern theory feel that it is not only the role of the
arbitrageurs but of all participants in the foreign exchange market, such as
e traders and hedgers and speculators, that influences the forward exchange
teo If they are taken into account, the forward exchange rate may differ from the
o-profit forward exchange rate as explained by the IRP theorem (Grubel, 1966;
toll, 1968).
The proponents of this theory explain the role of all the different participants.
e can present a simple illustration here. Suppose, the forward rate of the British
ound in relation to the US dollar. is expected to be higher than the no-profit
orward rate, then the arbitrageurs will be selling the British pound forward for
:he US dollar. In the reverse case, they will buy the pound forward for US dollars.
e larger the difference between the two rates, the greater will be the size of
,rward purc;hase or sale by the arbitrageurs.
The arbitrageurs are risk-averse, but the traders are fully risk-averse. They
over their transaction exposure either through forward market hedge or money
arket hedge or through both. So when the forward rate of the British pound is
ing to appreciate, the British exporter will sell the dollar forward if the export
II is invoiced in US dollars.
'. Speculators, however, are risk-takers. They have their own perception of exchange
te changes. If they expect that the future spot rate of the British pound in
lation to the US dollar will be higher than the forward rate, they purchase the
lund forward. On the maturity, they buy pounds and with the pound, they purchase
~llars at the future spot rate thus making a profit. On the contrary, when future
lot rate of the pound is expected to be lower than the forward rate, they will sell
le pound forward. On the maturity, they sell the pound at the forward rate, get
'''\e US dollaJ;., convert the US dollar into pounds "at the future spot rate and make
profit. The greater the expected difference between the two rates, the larger will
. the size of their forward purchase and sale. Thus, the activities of different
rticipants will force the forward rate of exchange with different intensity. The
Uilibrium rate will be established where different forces will come to eqUIlibrium.
:other words, the equilibrium forward rate is represented by a weighted average
:the no-profit forward rate of exchange and the expected future spot rate.
~
'~
iii
[e~present
. '.'
.'
".
'<{~,
'<
.........................
,"\j
~.
.~:.lvt6~f~ci:;;6~Ch~tiCkYPrice Version:' : .
. .' .. '
.. .
i'~]3~':Ri#'iI:liriteresf;ate4ireater irinowof~ai?ital--.nippreciationof
cUijeIlcy.:,
. ..... .... . ' ; . . '
......>
.j'4:!Ri~e,in:interest:rat~.~iIlcreasein
" ".
domestic
::~~~~!~4~~f~~~~;';S~~'Y . .
C.).?*e~tiSi~s~I!le{o/~i+thi~srea.se'7'preater
deInand
forf~reign fmancial
:~s~ts;;~'1~p'r~~i~~i?~~r.doWe~tissvrie~SY":i:. ' ,
~?l'~~~l1:;fiI!,a.!lci~J.a.~s~t1i'pei:!:lgIIWr~
r tsky '.~' . demand f()r .them decreases
~;a:ppreCiatlon.ofd~m:estic.':.suITe.ncY.. ,
. .. .'
.
' i .. '
t us begin with the balance of payments approach (Allen and Kennen, 1978) that
ggests that an increase in domestic price level over the foreign price level makes
,reign goods cheaper. It lowers export earnings and boosts the import bill. Lower
port reduces the supply of foreign exchange, and at the same time, greater
port increases the demand for foreign exchange and domestic currency depreciates
s a result. Similarly, growth in real national income causes larger imports if
arginal propensity to import is positive. Larger import will cause greater demand
r foreign currency and thereby depreciation in the value of domestic currency.
Increase in domestic interest rate, on the contrary, causes greater capital inflow
at increases the supply of foreign exchange and thereby causes appreciation in
.~he value of domestic currency. The first two factors influence the current account,
hile the third factor influences the capital account.
However, the empirical study of Pearce (1983) shows that none of the above
mentioned variables was very significant in the case of exchange rate between the
Canadian dollar and the US dollar. On this ground; he has suggested for an alternative
theory..
' .....
i;;..cUn:e:ncy.
'3i
.",
.Monetary Approach
The flexible-price version of the monetary approach emphasises the role of demand.
: and supply of money in determining the exchange rate (Frenkel, 1976). The exchange
rate between two currencies, according to this approach, is the ratio of their values
determined on the basis of the money supply and money demand positions of the
two countries. The demand for money--'--either in domestic economy or in a foreign
economy-is positively related with prices and real output and negatively related
with the rate of interest. Any increase in money supply raises the domestic price
level (based on the quantity theory of money) and the resultant increase in price
level lowers the value of the domestic currency. But if the increase in money supply
is lower than the increase in real domestic output, the excess of real domestic
output over the money supply causes excess demand for money balances and leads
to a lowering of domestic prices which causes an improvement in the value of
domestic currency. This explanation thus runs contrary to the balance of payment
approach where increase in real output causes depreciation in the value of domestic
currency through greater imports. Again, the monetary approach is different from
the balance of payments approach in the sense that the former explains that a rise
in domestic interest rate lowers the demand for money in the domestic economy
relative to its supply and thereby causes depreciation in the value of domestic
currency, However, the critics of this theory argue that since the purchasing power
parity theory is not applicable in the short run, this theory does not hold good in
such cases.
Dornbusch (1976), the proponent of the sticky price version, feels that the
simple assumption of the flexible price version that the PPP holds continuously
and the real exchange rate never changes is unrealistic. In the real life, real
exchange rate has changed at least in the short run, although the variability of
nominal exchange rate has been greater. He assumes further that the pace of
adjustment of asset prices is faster than the pace of adjustment of goods prices.
Thus, when the goods prices are sticky, it is necessary for the asset prices to move
more than in the flexible price case for attaining a temporary equilibrium.
'."'9&:'
The sticky price version bas proved that gradual adjustment of goocis prices
following a monetary shock imparts a "dynamic adjustment path" to the. exchange
rate. The real exchange rate alters in the short run but returns to the originalleve.l
in the long run on. account of PPP deviations.
.
The sticky-price version makes a more detailed study of interest rate differential.
The interest rate differential has three components. One denotes that when interest
rate rises, the money balances held by the public come to the money market lured'
by the high interest. The increase in money supply leads to currency depreciation.
The other denotes that if interest rate rises, financial institutions release more
funds into the money market as a result,thevalue of domestic currency depreciates.
The third isthat a rise in interest rate stimulates the capital flow into the country
that, similarly as in the balance of payments approach, causes appreciation 'in the
value of domestic currency.
Th~ sticky price version is based on at least three assumptions. The first is the
perfect capital mobility which means that the interest rate parity conditions prevail.
The second is the slow price adjustment. The third is the element of certainty.
which mean.s that the traders are aware ofthe fact when shocks will be hitting the
market and how to respond to them.
'. he above mentioned variables also change leading to a shift in the desired balance
the investment portfolio. Thus the two-way interaction continues until equilibrium
reached. The equilibrium is, however, s h o r t - l i v e d . ' .' ...............,..... ,
Again, when a country's wealth increases, holding of foreign assets VlJeallt~;7ttfh,~9t!:.ii. i
.
d d
dec'
.'
h' h
exp all)S ". at, .....'.",'
Iso Increases, an
eman Lor !oreIgn currency goes up w IC causes inc~eas~iiiti'W~~lth'
epreciation in the value of domestic currency. In this context, the possibility )e~~~:f9~~fI)an9i)i
;f substitution effect cannot be completely negated; because it outweighsf8qW~ii~n~,s~'7ts,
. e impact .of wealth effect.
. . The portfolio balance approach is more dan9i.~h'~~t~bY~O.
eprsCia IOn. In
i'
. . ....
Exchange rate denotes the ratio between the value of two currencies. It is
quoted in newspapers eIther in a direct or in an indirect'way. The quote
shows buying .:md selling rates. The difference between the two, kno~ as
spread forms the banks' income. The quote also shows the spot quote and
the forward quote. The difference between the two is either forward premium
or forward discount. The cross rate between two currencies is established
through a common currency.
.
In a floating-rate. regime, rate of exchailge IS determined by the forces of
supply and demand. With higher demand for, or lower supply of, a foreign
currency, its value appreciates vis-a.-vis the domestic currency.
Various different factors influence the demand and supply forces, important
among them being the inflation rate and interest rate differentials. The PPP
theory suggests that the higher the inflation rate, thelower is the value of
currency. Again, the real interest rate tends to equalise, but it is the differing
inflation rate that creates nominal interest rate differential. A higher interest
. rate encourages inflow of capital and the value of domestic currency rises.
The monetary authorities try to stabilise the value of currency through
intervention in the foreign' exchange' market.
In a forward market, the rate of exchange is determined by the interest rate
differential that finds a place in the Interest Rate Parity theory. This theory
tells us that the interest rate differential equals the forward rate differential.
If these two differentials are not equal, covered inte:rest arbitrage begins
and equalises the two. In case of uncovered interest arbitrage, the arbitrageur
takes into account, the expected future spot rate and not the forward rate.
These different variables as discussed above form the basis for the explanation
of different theories that essentially concern exchange rate determination.
The balance of payments approach links exchange rate behaviour with the
changes in capital and current account of the balance. of paYments. The
monetary theory lays emphasis upon the demand for, and supply of, money
as a factor influencing the exchange rate. However, the sticky-price version
of the monetary approach gives a more detailed explanation of interest rate
differential. The portfolio balance approach inCludes also the holding o.nancial
assets-domestic and foreign bonds-that influences the exchang~ rate.
CASE STUDY
INDI~
.~
The. High Level Committee on Balance of Payments, commonly known as the Rangaraja
Committee (1992), suggested a dual exchange rate system or a mix of official and market rat~
at least for a year before finally stepping into a managed floating exchange rate system in Mare:
1993. The managed float inVOlves essentially RBI's intervention in the foreign exchange maf~
either directly through the purchase and sale of US dollars or indirectly through making chang'lS1
in the repo rate and the resultant size of liquidity in the monetary and financial system. It is-fdft
that the new system of exchange rate along with reforms in trade and investment policies helpl'
boost up trade and investment (Sharan and Mukherji, 2001), but the oscillations in exchar\~e
rate at times could not completely be ruled out.;~\:
Trend in the Exchange R a t e . , ! :
'.%"
As regards the movements in the exchange rate, Table CS4.1 shows that the annual averagj
v.alue of rupee vis-a.-vis US dollar tended to depreciate all along from 31.37}{i)'
FY 1993-94 to 48.40 in FY 2002-03, although then appreciated moving in the range of 44:2'
and 45.95 dUring FYs 2003-07. In FY 2007-08, rupee appreciated at a rapid pace making
average of 40.24 a dollar. But again, the rupee depreciated during the following two finan'
years, although there was some' appreciation in FY 2010-11.
TABLE CS4.1
FY
,IUS $ (Average)
FY
,IUS $ (Average)
FY
1993-94
1994-95
1995-96
1996-97
1997-98
1996-99
31.37
31.4
33.45
35.5
37.17
42.07
1999-00
2000-01
2001-02
2002-03
2003-04
2004-05
43.33
45.68
47.69
48.4
45.95
44.93
2005-06
2006-07
2007-08
2008-09
2009-1b
2010-11
$ Exchange Ra
,IUS $ (Avera
44.26
45.25
40.24
45.99
47.42
45.52
For the appreciation of rupee during FY 2007-08, it was primarily the inflow of large amo
of foreign direct investment and foreign portfolio investment that helped increase the supplY.,
dollars i.n the foreign exchange marKet. When the foreign institutional investors began makil
disinvestment in the wake of the sub-prime crisis, the rupee tended to depreciate fast duringtl
first half of FY 2008-09. By October 2008, rupee fell to 50.29 a dollar. Thus, it is primarily t.
demand and supply forces that help determine the exchange' rate.
.
Probing still deeper, it is found that the standard deviation of daily. spot rate remai
confined to a level of 0.04-0.1 till FY 2001-02. In fact, the exchange rate oscillations to s
a low degree led some of the experts to analogise the managed floating regime in India
a fixed exchange rate regime for all practical purposes (Baig, 2001; Patnaik, 2003). Ra
Mohan (rbLorg) has also presented the coefficient of variation of daily spot rate beginning f
March 1995 to March 2007 and is of the view that instability in the daily spot rate was cc;mfi
between 0.1 Cind 0.3 except for March 1995, March 1996 and March 2004 when it was, respecti
2.5, 1.8 and 1.1.
Managed float, by its very nature, could not avoid exchange rate risk and the result..
forward trading to hedge the risk. Forward rates are expected rates in the future. The Iiterat
on the issue whether or not the forward rate is an unbiased indicator of future spot rate is
hlhCigen,1975; Edwards, 1982; Hansen and Hodrick, 1983). Again, there are many studies
how that the widening/narrowing of interest rate differential has influenced the forward
ang e rate of Indian rupee (Chakrabarti, 2006; Patnaik, et aI., 2003; Sharma and Mitra,
). Their discussion is not explained here; nevertheless, it can be said that the average
unt on forward rate of rupee-both 3-month and 6-month-was about 4.0 per cent per
m between late 1997 and mid-2004. To be more precise, it was 3.7 per cent for 3-month
ard and 3.8 per' cent for 6-month forward (Chakrabarti, 2006). From June 2004 onward,
ard premium was evident that was as high as 3.0 per cent by August 2004 but then it tended
ecline to less than 2.0 per cent by June 2005 and further to less than 1.0 per cent by
ber 2005. At the close of FY 2005-06, it ascended again to over 3.0 per cent but then
11k to less than one per cent by July 2006. (RBI, 2006). During FY 2006-07, the forward
ia increased reflecting growing interest rate differential in view of increased domestic interest
. In March 2007, one-month, three-month and six-month premia were, respectively,
per cent, 5.14 per cent and 4.40 per cent. In fact, it was because of the changes in the
ro-economic variables that the spot rates and the forward rates tended to oscillate. In
2007-08,because of continuous off-loading of forward position by the exporters, the
month, three-month and six-month premia tended to decline and reached, respectively,
per cent, 2.75 per cent and 2.50 per cent.
ring Stability in the Exchange Rate
issue of financial stability attained significance in the late 1990s in view of keeping at bay
spill-over effects of the turbul~nce in the South-East Asian financial markets and also the
ening of the financial crisis in Russia. The RBI announced a set of policy measures in June
. These measures emphasised on the RBI's role of meeting mismatches between the
nd and supply of foreign currency through market intervention, allowing the foreign institutional
tors (Fils) to manage their exchange rate exposure through undertaking foreign exchange
r on their incremental investment, advising traders .and banks to monitor their foreign currency
tion and allowing domestic financial institutions to buy back their debt from international
cial market. Foreign Exchange Management Act (FEMA) replacing the Foreign Exchange
lation Act (FERA) came into force from Jane 1, 2000. It aimed at promoting an orderly
pment and maintenance of the foreign exchange. market in India. The Act provides transparent
s relating to the RBI's approval for acquiring and holding of foreign exchange and the limits
hich foreign exchange is admissible to current / capital account transactions from the
point of full current account convertibility and growing convertibility on capital account.
In fact, it is the very macro-economic policy, especially the monetary measures and the
inistrative measures that have helped ensure stability in the foreign exchange market through
ncing the supply of, and demand for, the foreign currency. For example, when normal
al inflows .faltered, the State Bank of India raised US $ 4.2 billion through the issue of
rgent India Bonds during August 1998 and another US $ 5.5 billion through the issue of
Millennium Deposits during October-November 2000. However, the RBI's role in the form
arket intervention has been the most significant one. It has already been mentioned how
intervenes in the foreign exchange market, but it needs some more details about the extent
tervention .. Looking at the figures in the recent past in Table CS4.2, it is evident that the
aunt of the purchase of foreign currency ranged between US $ 15,239 million and
$ 55,418 million annually during FYs 2000-06. Similarly, the sale of foreign currency varied
een US $ 7,096 million and US $ 24,940 million during this period. The FY 2006-07 was
ular in the sense that the RBI bought US dollars, and never sold them. The quantum. of
hase was $ 26.824 billions that helped check at least to some extent the rupee from
reciating. As a ratio of turnover in the foreign exchange market, the size of intervention
led between 3.9 per cent and 0.4 per cent. All this shows that the RBI has taken pains to
lid mismatches between demand and supply of foreign currency in the market and thereby
ring in stability in the exchange rate. Unnikrishnan and Mohan (2003) probe deeper into this
e and find that beginning from January 1996 to March 2002, the RBI adopted a "leaning
'<',::~~::::tr,.'
1~2
Chapter 4 Exchange
.against the wind" approach which is evident from a negative correlation between the exchange
rate and net dollar purchases. It thereby stressed more on checking volatility in the foreig
exchange market rather than simply checking appreciation/depreciation of the currency.
In FY 2007-08, the purchases of dollars were far larger than the sales in view of the fact
that the rupee had appreciated. But when the rupee depreciated during the following two financial
years, the sale of dollars turned larger. In FY 2010-11, the table turned and the purchase oi
dollars was greater since the rupee had tended to appreciate.
TABLE CS4.2
million
Year
Purchase
Sale
Net (Purchase-Sale)
2000-01
2001-02
2002-03
2003-04
2004--05
2005-06
2006-07
2007-08
2008-09
2009-10
2010-11
28,202
22,822
30,639
55,418
31,398
15,239
26,824
79,696
26,563
4,010
2,450
25,846
15,668
14,927
24,940
10,551
7,096
2,356
7,154
15,712
30,478
20,847
8,143
26,824
78,203
-3,492
-2,635
1,690
3.9
2.7
2.9
. 3.8
1.4
0.5
0.4
0.7
0.8
0.6
0.7
1,493
61,485
6,645
760
QUESTIONS
1. What do you mean by managed floating exchange rate regime? Why was it adopte
in India?
.
2. Comment on the trend of the exchange rate of rupee during the managed floatin
. regime.
3.. How was fluctuation in tile rupee/dollar exchange rate controlled?
..,
. RevIEW QUESTIONS
Objective-Type Questions
. 1. State whether true (T) or false (F):
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
Rat~
Mechanism
hort-Answer Questions
Distinguish between:
(a) direct and indirect quote of exchange rate
(b) buying and selling rate
(c) outright forward quote and swap quote
How do you compute the forward rate differential?
What is bid-ask spread? How is it computed?
What is cross rate? How is it computed?
g-Answer Questions
1. Explain the PPP theory. Is it applicable to both short term and long term?
2. What do you mean by Fisher effect? Is it true that interest rate differential
equals inflation rate differential?
Explain. the IRP theory. Is it sufficient to explain the forward exchange
rate?
"The spot exchange rate in: a floating-rate reginie is determined by the
supply and demand forces." Explain.
Examine different theories of exchange rate determination.
Explain covered interest arbitrage with suitable example.. Is it different
from uncovered interest arbitrage?
Numerical Problems
'Aliber, RZ. and C.P. Stickney (1975), Accounting Measures of Foreign Exchange
Exposure: The long and short of it, The Accounting Review, L, 4-57.
USA
"-v~
Unit
Goods
~.~*
II
Unit
Goods
20
10
Wheat
Rice
20
Wheat
Exchange rate
~~_.
US $ Price / Unit
Rice
~, Price/Unit;~
40
80
40lUS $
5. The exchange rate between rupee and US $ is '{ 40lUS $ at the en.l
of Period 1. The rate of inflation in India and the USA is 6 per cent
3 per cent, respectively." What is the likely exchange rate at the end 0"
Period 2?
"
"
ana;
"",~
~"
~t;
6. If the nominal rate of interest is 15 per cent and the rate of inflation is
per cent, what would be the real interest rate?
...
.
;
7. Calculate the forward differential if the spot rate is '{ 40lUS $ and t
3-month forward rate is 40.501US $.
8. Calculate the 3-month forward rate, if the spot rate is ~ 46IUS $; thi
interest rate in India and the USA is, respectively, 6 per cent and 3 p
cent.
9. The spot exchange rate between Indian rupee and US dollar in 1995 w
~ 30lUS $ when the price index in both the countries was 100. By 200
rupee depreciated to 45IUS dollar and at the same time, the price ind,
moved up during this pe"tiod in India and USA to 110 and 125, respectivel
.Find out the extent 'of change in nominal and real exchange rates.
.
Allen, P.R and P.B. Kennen (1978), The Balance of Payments, Exchange Rate and
Economic Policy, Athens (Georgia), Centre for Planning and Economic Research.
Baig, T. (2001), "Characterising Exchange Rate Regimes in Post-crisis East Asia",
Technical Report, WP/Ol/152, IMF, Washington, DC.
" isignano, J. and K. Hoover (1982), Some Suggested Improvements to a Simple
Portfolio Balance Model of Exchange Rate Determination with Special Reference
to US Dollar/Canadian Dollar Rate, Archiv Weltwirtschaftliches, CXVIII,
19-37.
.assel, G. (1921), The World's Monetary Problems, London, Constable.
hakrabarti, R {(2006), The Financial Sector in India: Emerging Issues, New Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
ihmbY, RE. and M. Obstfeld (1984), Internatio~al Interest Rate and Price Level
\ Linkages under Flexible Exchange Rates: A review of the evidence, in J.li'.O.
Bilson and RC. Marston (Eds.), Exchange Rate Theory and Practices, Chid-go,
Univ. of Chicago Press, pp. 121-152.
ombusch, R. (1976), Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal ofPolitical
Economy, LXXXIV, 1161-1176.
dison, H. (1985), The Rise and Fall of Sterling: Testing alternative models of
exchange rate determination, Applied Economics, XVII, 1003-1021.
.
wards, S. (1982), "Exchange Rates and 'News': A Multicurrency Approach", Journal
. of International Money and Finance, 1, 211-24.
.
.ma, E.F. and G.W. Schwert (1977), Asset Returns and Inflation, Journal of
:Financial Economics, V, 115-146.
nkel, J.A. (1976), A Monetary Approach to Exchange Rate: Doctrinal aspects
and empirical evidence, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, LXXXVIII,
200-224.
nkel; J.A. and RM. Levich (1975), Transaction Costs and Interest Arbitrage:
Tranquil and turbulent periods, Journal of Political Economy, LXXXIII,
325-338. '
son, W.E. (1970), Price Expectations Effects on Interest Rates, Journal ofFinance,
XXV, 19-34.
.
(1972), Interest Rates and Inflationary Expectations, American Economic
Review, LXII, 854-865.
REFERENCES
>
Abdullah, F.A. (1986), Financial Management for the Multinational Firm, Englew
Cliffs, Prentice Hall International, p. 59.
Adler, M. and B. Lehmann(1983), Deviations from Purchasing Power Parity.in t
Long Run, Journ.al of Finance, XXXVIII, 1471:-1487.
Aliber, RZ. (1973), The Interest Rate Parity ,Theorem: A reinterpretation, Jour
of Political Economy, LXXXI, 1451-i459.
4y, LH. and G. Duffey (1975), The Random Behaviour of Flexible Exchange
Rates, Journal ofInternational Business Studies, VI, 1-32.
bel, H.G. (1966), Forward Exchange, Speculation and the International Flow of
apital, Palo Alto, Stanford University Press.
sen, L.P. and RJ. Hodrick (1983), "Risk-averse Speculation in the Forward
oreign Exchange Markets: An Econometric Analysis of Linear Models" in
.A. Frenkel (Ed.), Exchange Rates and International Macroeconomics, Chicago:
. niversity of Chicago Press.
Isard, P. (1977), Row Far We Can Push the Law ofOne Price, American Economic
Review, LXVII, 942-948.
Kohlhagen, S.W. (1975), "The Performance of Foreign Exchange Markets:
1971-74", Journal of International Business Studies", 6, 33-39.
MacDonald, R (1988), Floating Exchange Rates: Theories and evidence, London,
Unwin, pp. 201-219.
Marston, RC. (1976), Interest Arbitrage in the Euro-currency Markets, European
Economic Review, VII, 1-13.
.
McKinnon, RL (1969), Portfolio Balance and International Payments Adjustment,
in RA Mundell and AK. Swoboda (Eds.), Monetary Problems in International
Economy, Chicago, Univ. of Chicago Press, pp. 199-235.
--(1979), Money in International Exchange, Oxford: Oxford University Press,
pp. 117-137.
Mishkin, F. (1984), Are Real Interest Rates Equal Across Countries? An empirica
investigation of international parity conditions, Journal of Finance, XXXIX,
1345-1358.
Mundell, R (1961), "The International Disequilibrium System", Kyklos, 14;
15~72.