Barro DeterminantsDemocracy
Barro DeterminantsDemocracy
Barro DeterminantsDemocracy
Citation
Published Version
doi:10.1086/250107
Accessed
Citable Link
http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:3451297
Terms of Use
Determinants of Democracy
Robert J. Barro
Harvard University
A panel study of over 100 countries from 1960 to 1995 finds that
improvements in the standard of living predict increases in democracy, as measured by a subjective indicator of electoral rights. The
propensity for democracy rises with per capita GDP, primary
schooling, and a smaller gap between male and female primary
attainment. For a given standard of living, democracy tends to fall
with urbanization and with a greater reliance on natural resources.
Democracy has little relation to country size but rises with the
middle-class share of income. The apparently strong relation of
democracy to colonial heritage mostly disappears when the economic variables are held constant. Similarly, the allowance for
these economic variables weakens the interplay between democracy and religious affiliation. However, negative effects from Muslim and nonreligious affiliations remain intact.
An expansion of political freedommore democracyhas opposing effects on economic growth. On the positive side, democratic
institutions provide a check on governmental power and thereby
limit the potential of public officials to amass personal wealth and
to carry out unpopular policies. But on the negative side, more democracy encourages rich-to-poor redistributions of income and may
enhance the power of interest groups. Consequently, the net effect
of democracy on growth is uncertain. (See Sirowy and Inkeles [1990]
and Przeworski and Limongi [1993] for surveys of theories that relate democracy to economic growth.)
My previous cross-country empirical work, as summarized in Barro
(1997), finds a nonlinear effect of democracy on growth. Growth is
initially increasing in an index of electoral rights, but the relation
[ Journal of Political Economy, 1999, vol. 107, no. 6, pt. 2]
1999 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/99/10706S-0010$02.50
S158
determinants of democracy
S159
S160
determinants of democracy
S161
S162
determinants of democracy
S163
(1)
S164
determinants of democracy
S165
TABLE 1
Regressions for Electoral Rights and Civil Liberties Indexes
Dependent Variable
Independent Variable
5-year lag of dependent variable
10-year lag of dependent variable
Log(GDP)
Years of primary schooling
Gap between male and female primary
schooling
Urbanization rate
Log(population)
Oil country dummy
R2
Observations
Electoral Rights
(1)
Civil Liberties
(2)
.608
(.041)
.102
(.040)
.058
(.016)
.0134
(.0059)
.047
(.013)
.095
(.048)
.0080
(.0044)
.094
(.031)
.62, .76, .67
.76, .76, .56
76, 88, 102
102, 103, 100
.536
(.041)
.148
(.039)
.054
(.014)
.0143
(.0051)
.043
(.011)
.075
(.041)
.0012
(.0038)
.096
(.027)
.63, .81, .77
.82, .75, .70
76, 88, 102
102, 103, 100
Note.The systems have six equations in which the dependent variables are the values of the electoral
rights or civil liberties indexes for 1972, 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, and 1995. The five-year lag refers to 1965,
1972, 1975, etc. The 10-year lag refers to 1960, 1965, 1972, etc. The lagged values used for 1960 and 1965
(from Bollen [1990]) are the same in the two equations. The variables GDP (real per capita GDP), primary
schooling (years of attainment for persons aged 25 and over at the primary level), the gap between male and
female primary schooling, urbanization rate, and population refer to 1965, 1970, etc. The oil dummy equals
one for countries designated as oil-exporting by the IMF and zero otherwise. Each system contains a different
constant for each time period. The estimation, by the SUR technique, weights countries equally but allows
for different error variances in each period and for correlation of these errors over the periods. Standard
errors of the estimated coefficients are shown in parentheses. The R 2 values apply to each period individually.
The figures on urbanization are the standard ones reported by the World Bank.
S166
The system also contains a measure of country size, the log of the
five-year earlier level of population. It is, however, not apparent a
priori whether a larger place is more or less likely to be democratic.
One problem of interpretation is that country size is endogenous,
as argued by Alesina and Spolaore (1995). Places that are too large
to be manageable are likely to have split apart sometime in the past.
The first observation from column 1 of table 1 is that the estimated
coefficient on the five-year lag of electoral rights is 0.61 (standard
error 0.04) and that on the 10-year lag is 0.10 (0.04). Thus democracy is highly persistent over time, but about 25 percent of the adjustment to a target position (determined by the other variables) occurs
over five years, and nearly 70 percent occurs over 20 years.9
The results are broadly supportive of the idea that more prosperous places are more likely to be democratic. The estimated coefficients on log(per capita GDP) and the level of primary schooling
are each significantly positive, 0.058 (0.016) and 0.013 (0.006), respectively.10 The first coefficient means that a doubling of per capita
GDP (corresponding roughly to a one-standard-deviation change)
would raise the electoral rights indicator by 0.04 in the short run
and by 0.14 after the full lagged adjustment occurs. (Note that a
shift by one Freedom House category corresponds to a change by
0.17 in the electoral rights index.) The second coefficient implies
that an additional year of average school attainment (roughly a onestandard-deviation shift) raises the electoral rights indicator by 0.01
in the short run and 0.04 in the long run.
Democracy is also negatively and significantly related to the gap
between male and female primary attainment, with an estimated
coefficient of 0.047 (0.013). That is, more equal educational opportunity across the sexes raises the target level of democracy. Quantitatively, a rise in the male-female gap by 0.6 year (about a onestandard-deviation change) lowers the electoral rights index by 0.03
in the short run and 0.10 in the long run. One interpretation of this
relation is that the spread between male and female attainment is
a proxy for general inequality of schooling and income. However,
the inclusion of explicit measures of educational and income inequality (discussed below) does not eliminate the explanatory power
9
These results apply when the coefficients of the lagged dependent variables are
interpreted in terms of a partial-adjustment model. Difficulties can arise here if the
lagged dependent variables pick up effects of serially correlated error terms. However, at least when the lagged dependent variables are included as regressors, the
residuals from the equations for electoral rights exhibit negligible correlations over
time.
10
School attainment of persons aged 25 and over has slightly more explanatory
power than attainment of persons aged 15 and over.
determinants of democracy
S167
of the gap between male and female schooling. Perhaps more promising is the idea, reminiscent of Tocqueville (1835), that expanded
educational opportunity for females goes along with a social structure that is generally more participatory and, hence, more receptive
to democracy.
The oil country dummy is significantly negative, 0.094 (0.031),
thereby indicating that the high level of per capita GDP associated
with oil production does not have the usual positive linkage with
democracy. The estimated coefficient implies that, in the long run,
for given values of per capita GDP and the other explanatory variables, an oil country would have an electoral rights indicator that was
lower by 0.32 (nearly two categories on the Freedom House scale).
It seems plausible that this result for oil would extend to natural
resource availability more generally. To test this idea, I introduced
the measure of natural resource intensity suggested by Sachs and
Warner (1995), the ratio of primary-product exports to total exports.11 However, this variable is insignificant if added to the system
shown in column 1 of table 1, 0.022 (0.033), and the oil dummy
remains significant, 0.090 (0.035). One problem with the export
ratio variable is that it reflects a countrys choices on which production activities to focus. Possibly a better measure of exogenous natural resource availability would outperform the oil dummy.
The estimated coefficient of the urbanization rate is negative and
marginally significant, 0.095 (0.048). Thus once indicators of the
standard of living are held constant, the association between urbanization and democracy switches sign and becomes negative. This result means that, for a given standard of living, it is not true that more
rural places are less likely to be democratic.
The estimated coefficient on the log of population is positive and
marginally significant, 0.0080 (0.0044).12 Thus there is some indication that larger places are more likely to be democratic. However,
as mentioned before, this result might reflect the endogeneity of
country size.
The system shown in column 1 of table 1 allows for different intercepts in each of the equations, that is, for 1972, 1975, and so on.
The estimated coefficient for each dateexpressed as a deviation
from the (unweighted) average interceptis shown in column 1 of
table 2. Column 2 of the table shows the unweighted mean of the
electoral rights index at each date for the observations that are included in the regression sample.
11
The value for 1970 enters into the first two equations, that for 1975 in the next
two, and that for 1985 in the last two.
12
A countrys land area is insignificant if it is added to the regressions as another
indicator of country size.
S168
Year
1972
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
.092
.047
.043
.035
.023
.038
Sample Mean of
Electoral Rights Index
(2)
(.024)
(.019)
(.020)
(.016)
(.017)
(.022)
.54
.47
.54
.58
.59
.64
Note.Col. 1 shows the estimated constant term for the indicated date from the
system in col. 1 of table 1. The estimate is expressed as a deviation from the average
of the constants over the six periods. The standard error of the coefficient estimate
is shown in parentheses. The p-value for the hypothesis of equal constant terms is
.0000. Col. 2 is the mean of the electoral rights index over the sample included in
the regression system for the indicated date.
Health Indicators
TABLE 3
Additional Determinants of Democracy
Independent Variable
1. Log(life expectancy at birth)
2. Infant mortality rate
3. Years of upper schooling
Gap between male and female schooling
p-value
4. Income inequality (Gini coefficient)
5. Share of middle class in income
6. Educational inequality
7. Ethnolinguistic fractionalization
8. Rule-of-law index
9. Dummy for former colony
10. Dummy for British colony
Dummy for French colony
Dummy for Spanish colony
Dummy for Portuguese colony
Dummy for other colony
p-value
11. Muslim religion fraction
Protestant religion fraction
Hindu religion fraction
Buddhist religion fraction
Miscellaneous eastern religion fraction
Jewish religion fraction
Nonreligion fraction
Other religion fraction
p-value
Regression Coefficient
.129
.44
.008
.010
.76
.15
.26
.008
.055
.031
.018
.031
.020
.007
.022
.032
.33
.093
.006
.049
.003
.081
.035
.244
.103
.002
(.079)
(.30)
(.011)
(.024)
(.09)
(.15)
(.046)
(.028)
(.057)
(.018)
(.018)
(.026)
(.022)
(.048)
(.034)
(.026)
(.031)
(.050)
(.047)
(.072)
(.072)
(.089)
(.050)
Note.The indicated groups of explanatory variables are added, one at a time, to the system for the
electoral rights index shown in col. 1 of table 1. (Regression 8 applies only to the three periods that start
with the value of the electoral rights index for 1985.)
Life expectancy at birth applies to 196569, 197074, etc. The infant mortality rate applies to 1965, 1970,
etc. Upper schooling (from Barro and Lee [1996]) is the years of secondary and higher schooling for persons
aged 25 and over in 1965, 1970, etc. The Gini coefficient for income inequality and the income share of the
middle class (the three middle quintiles of income) are taken from Deininger and Squire (1996) and apply
around 1970 in the first two equations, around 1980 in the next two equations, and around 1990 in the last
two equations. A higher number for the Gini coefficient signifies more inequality. Educational inequality
(from Barro and Lee [1996]) is the standard deviation of log(1 years of schooling) for the population
aged 15 and over in 1965, 1970, etc. The ethnolinguistic fractionalization variable, which runs between zero
and one, is a measure of heterogeneity of language and ethnicity. The number, observed once for each
country, represents the probability that two randomly selected persons come from different groups; hence,
a higher value signifies more heterogeneity. See Taylor and Hudson (1972, table 4.15) and Mauro (1995)
for a discussion of these data. The rule-of-law index, discussed in Knack and Keefer (1995) and available for
198297 from Political Risk Services, is a subjective indicator of the extent of maintenance of the rule of law.
The variable runs from zero to one, with a higher value indicating a more favorable environment.
Colony is a dummy for countries that are former or present colonies; any country that was independent
before 1776 is designated as a noncolony. In regression 10, dummies for former British, French, Spanish,
Portuguese, and other colonies are added together to the system from col. 1 of table 1. Colonial status is
based on the most recent ruler; e.g., the Philippines is attributed to the United States rather than to Spain.
In regression 11, the fractions of the population affiliated with eight major religious groups are entered
together into the system from col. 1 of table 1. The left-out religion category is Catholic (including Eastern
Orthodox). The religion data pertain to 1970 (in the first three equations) and 1980 (in the last three equations) and come from Barrett (1982). The Protestant group includes Anglicans, marginal Protestants ( Jehovahs Witnesses, Mormons, and new-age cults), and cryto-Christians (secret believers in Christ not professing
publicly). Eastern religions include Chinese folk religions, Shinto, Confucianism, and new-religions. The
nonreligion category comprises those professing no religion and atheism. Other religions include Parsis,
Spiritists, tribal religions, indigenous third-world Christians not of western importation, and Bahais. Jains and
Sikhs are classed with Hindus.
S170
living. The estimated coefficient is positive but only marginally significant, 0.13 (0.08). With life expectancy included, the estimated
coefficients of log(per capita GDP) and average years of primary
schooling become less significant; the estimated coefficients are now
0.042 (0.018) and 0.011 (0.006), respectively. Thus it is difficult to
sort out precisely the measures of standard of living that matter for
democracy.
Similar results apply if the infant mortality rate is used as a measure of health status instead of life expectancy. Regression 2 of table
3 shows that the estimated coefficient of the infant mortality rate is
0.44 (0.30).
B. Upper-Level Schooling
Regression 3 in table 3 includes two additional schooling variables:
the average years of schooling for persons aged 25 and over at the
secondary and higher levels and the gap between male and female
schooling for persons aged 25 and over at these levels. These variables are individually and jointly insignificant, as shown, whereas
the estimated coefficients on primary schooling remain significant
(0.014 [0.006] for years of schooling and 0.051 [0.016] for the gap
between males and females). Hence, it appears to be early education
that matters for democratization. Similar results apply to the determination of fertility rates and health status. However, as discussed
in Barro (1997), rates of economic growth and investment relate far
more to secondary and higher schooling than to primary education.
C. Inequality of Income and Schooling
Regression 4 of the table includes measures of income inequality,
as gauged by Gini coefficients for the distribution of income. (A
higher Gini coefficient signifies more inequality.) The data come
from the careful compilation of information assembled by Deininger and Squire (1996).14 The underlying values were categorized
as applying around 1970, 1980, and 1990 and were entered accordingly into the regression system (see the note to table 3). Because
of the limited availability of data on income distribution, the inclusion of the Gini coefficient substantially reduces the number of observations: to 51 for the 1972 equation, 56 for 1975, 60 for 1980 and
14
The regressions use their high-quality observations, which exclude observations based on incomplete geographical coverage or incomplete measures of income. I have added to their high-quality set some observations that Deininger and
Squire excluded because of incomplete references to primary sources.
determinants of democracy
S171
1985, and 68 for 1990 and 1995. Within this truncated sample, the
estimated coefficient on the Gini coefficient is negative but only marginally significant, 0.15 (0.09). However, in this reduced sample,
some of the variables from the basic specification are also statistically
insignificant: average years of primary schooling, the urbanization
rate, the log of population, and the oil dummy. In any event, there is
some indication thatfor given measures of the standard of living
greater income inequality predicts less democracy.
Many researchers stress a positive interaction between the size of
the middle class and the extent of democracy. To check this relation,
regression 5 of table 3 includes in the regression system the share of
income accruing to the middle three quintiles (also compiled from
Deininger and Squire [1996]). Because of the more severe limitation on data by quintile shares, this sample was even smaller than
that for the Gini coefficient. (With the middle-class variable included, the numbers of observations for the various dates are 38,
40, 51, 51, 65, and 65.) The estimated coefficient of the middleclass share is positive, 0.26 (0.15), but only marginally significant.
However, in this sample, the estimated coefficients of average years
of primary schooling, urbanization rate, the log of population, and
the oil dummy are even less significant.
If the Gini coefficient is entered along with the middle-class share,
then the estimated coefficients are 0.05 (0.24) for the Gini (the
wrong sign) and 0.32 (0.38) for the middle-class share. The
middle-class variable also appears to be the more important indicator of inequality when it is entered jointly with the share of the lowest
or highest quintile. Thus there is some evidence that the weight of
the middle class is the aspect of inequality that matters most for democracy.
Another possibility is to use recently assembled data on educational attainment at seven levels to construct measures of schooling
inequality (see n. 6 above). Regression 6 of table 3 uses as an independent variable the standard deviation of log(1 years of schooling)15 for the population of both sexes aged 15 and over. This variable is observed for 1965, 1970, and so on. The estimated coefficient
is close to zero, 0.008 (0.046). The estimated coefficients of primary schooling remain significant here: 0.013 (0.006) for average
years of schooling and 0.046 (0.016) for the male-female gap. If
the Gini coefficient for years of schooling is used as an alternative measure of educational inequality, then the findings are similar. Hence, these results indicate that the primary enrollment vari15
The value one can be thought of as the effective years of educational human
capital possessed by a person with no formal schooling.
S172
Knack and Keefer (1995) discuss a variety of subjective country indexes of property rights and legal/political structure that have been
prepared for fee-paying international investors by International Country Risk Guide. The concepts covered include quality of the bureaucracy, political corruption, likelihood of government repudiation of
contracts, risk of government expropriation, and overall mainte16
Most of the data come from Miklukho-Maklaya Institute (1964), as reported in
Taylor and Hudson (1972, table 4.15). See Mauro (1995) for a discussion.
determinants of democracy
S173
nance of the rule of law (also referred to as law and order tradition). The various time series cover 198297 and are available for
a fee from Political Risk Services of Syracuse, New York. The general
idea of these indexes is to gauge the attractiveness of a countrys
investment climate by considering the effectiveness of law enforcement, the sanctity of contracts, and the state of other influences on
the security of property rights. Although these data are subjective,
they have the virtue of being prepared contemporaneously by local
experts. Moreover, the willingness of customers to pay substantial
amounts for this information is perhaps some testament to their validity.
Among the various series available, the indicator for overall maintenance of the rule of law17 seemed a priori to be the most relevant
for investment and growth. My previous empirical work (Barro 1997)
confirms that this indicator is an important predictor of economic
growth.
The connection between democracy and property rights is unclear, as stressed by Sirowy and Inkeles (1990) and Przeworski and
Limongi (1993). The simple correlations between the electoral
rights and rule-of-law indicators are .64 in 1982, .55 in 1985, .60 in
1990, and .49 in 1995. These correlations are much smaller than
those between the electoral rights and civil liberties indexes (see
below).
Regression 8 of table 3 checks out the relationship between electoral rights and the rule of law by entering lagged values of the ruleof-law index into the equations for democracy. Since the data on
the rule of law begin in 1982, this system includes the equations for
electoral rights for only 1985, 1990, and 1995. (The second lag of
the dependent variable is excluded here.) The values for the rule
of law in this system apply to 1982, 1985, and 1990. The result is that
the estimated coefficient on the rule-of-law variable is positive but
insignificant, 0.031 (0.057). Thus, when the measures of standard
of living are held fixed, there is not much timing evidence that better
maintenance of the rule of law promotes electoral rights. (However,
the rule of law can stimulate electoral rights indirectly by promoting
economic growth.)
The rule-of-law measure can also be viewed as the dependent variable in a system in which the independent variables are its own lags
and the lags of the other variables, including the electoral rights
index. (Three equationsfor 1985, 1990, and 1995are used
here.) In this setting, electoral rights turn out to enter with a positive
17 The indicator was initially measured in seven categories on a zero to six scale,
with six the most favorable. The scale has been revised here to zero to one, with
zero indicating the worst maintenance of the rule of law and one the best.
S174
Colonial Status
Noncolony
Colony
British colony
French colony
Spanish colony
Portuguese colony
Other colony
All countries
Number of
Countries
Electoral
Rights Index*
32
106
53
23
16
5
9
138
.69
.46
.54
.26
.60
.30
.36
.52
B. Religious Affiliation
Primary Religious Affiliation
in 1980
Catholic
Muslim
Protestant
Hindu
Buddhist
Miscellaneous eastern religions
Jewish
Nonreligion
Other religion
All countries with data on religion
Number of
Countries
Electoral
Rights Index*
53
32
21
5
4
3
1
1
16
136
.60
.26
.80
.66
.56
.46
.86
.10
.30
.51
Note.See the discussion in the text and table 3 for definitions of colonial status and religious
affiliation. Panel B shows averages for 197595 of the electoral rights index for groups of countries
in which the most common religious affiliation in 1980 is of the indicated type.
* Average for 197595.
Colonial History
determinants of democracy
S175
with the United States rather than with Spain, Rwanda and Burundi
are attached to Belgium rather than to Germany, and several Caribbean countries are related to Britain rather than to Spain. The classification treats as noncolonies places such as South Korea, Taiwan,
Hungary, and Poland, which were occupied by a foreign power for
some periods.
Panel A of table 4 shows that the 32 noncolonies are more likely
to be democratic (average value for the electoral rights indicator
from 1975 to 1995 of 0.69) than the colonies (average value of 0.46).
Within the colonies, the former possessions of Britain and Spain are
substantially more democratic than those of France, Portugal, and
other countries. (The former Spanish colonies in Latin America
would, however, look less democratic at some earlier dates.)
In the statistical analysis, with the measures of standard of living
held constant, regression 9 of table 3 shows that a dummy variable
for colonial status (one for former colony, zero for noncolony) is
negative but statistically insignificant, 0.018 (0.018). Moreover, regression 10 shows that a breakdown among British, French, Spanish,
Portuguese, and other colonies fails to generate any significant coefficients. The p-value for joint significance of the five colony dummies
is .33. These results, in conjunction with table 4, suggest that the
influence of former colonial status on democratic tendency mostly
works indirectly through effects on the standard of living, as measured here particularly by per capita GDP and primary schooling.
These indirect links with colonial history are worth further study.
G. Religion
Religious affiliation has also been stressed as an important determinant of democracy (see Huntington 1991, pp. 7185; Lipset 1994,
p. 5; Boone 1996, pp. 2528). Unfortunately, however, the theory
of the interplay between religion and political structure is even less
developed than other aspects of the theory of democracy.
To check for a connection between religion and political freedom, I use data compiled by Jong Wha Lee on the fractions of a
countrys population in 1970 and 1980 affiliated with nine major
groups:18 Catholic (including Eastern Orthodox), Muslim, Protes18
The underlying data, from the World Christian Encyclopedia (Barrett 1982), are
estimates of professed affiliation in 1970 and 1980. (Figures are also available for
1900.) This information takes no account of regularity of church attendance or
amounts spent on religious activities. The data provided in the encyclopedia are
compiled from the most authoritative local sources, published or unpublished, including government censuses of religion. A large part of the data was collected directly by the editors, who visited virtually all the countries over the years 196575.
The basic concept of a religious adherent is that the person professes to believe in
the religion when government censuses or public opinion polls ask the question
S176
determinants of democracy
S177
S178
determinants of democracy
S179
TABLE 5
Actual and Long-Run Values of Democracy
Democracy 1975
Country
Algeria
Benin
Botswana
Cameroon
Central African Republic
Congo
Egypt
Gambia
Ghana
Guinea-Bissau
Kenya
Lesotho
Liberia
Malawi
Mali
Mauritius
Mozambique
Niger
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Sudan
Swaziland
Tanzania
Togo
Tunisia
Uganda
Zaire
Zambia
Zimbabwe
Barbados
Canada
Costa Rica
Dominican Republic
El Salvador
Guatemala
Haiti
Honduras
Jamaica
Mexico
Nicaragua
Panama
Trinidad and Tobago
United States
Argentina
Bolivia
Brazil
Chile
Colombia
Ecuador
Guyana
Paraguay
Peru
Democracy 1995
Actual
Projected
Gap
Actual
Projected
Gap
.17
.00
.83
.17
.00
.33
.17
.83
.00
.17
.33
.33
.17
.00
.00
.83
.17
.00
.00
.17
.17
.50
.17
.17
.17
.00
.17
.00
.00
.33
.17
1.00
1.00
1.00
.50
.83
.50
.17
.17
1.00
.50
.33
.00
.83
1.00
.50
.17
.50
.00
.83
.00
.50
.33
.17
(.14)
.23
.26
.08
.03
.15*
.06*
.09
.04
.32
.08
(.03)
.03
.20
.33
.19
.19
.14
.20
.55
.22
.37
.08**
.06
.14
.10
(.01)
.01
.18
.65
.82
.49
.31
.21
.32
.16
.27
.49
.32
.35
.44
.64
.95
.57
.15
.43
.49
.36
.36
.40
.30
.29
(.31)
.23
.57
.08
.03
.01
.78
.09
.30
.01
.09
(.03)
.03
.63
.17
.19
.19
.03
.03
.05
.06
.20
.09
.06
.03
.10
(.01)
.32
.02
.35
.18
.51
.19
.62
.18
.01
.11
.51
.18
.02
.44
.20
.05
.07
.02
.07
.49
.48
.36
.10
.04
.12
.17
.83
.83
.00
.67
.50
.17
.00
.50
.67
.00
.50
.00
.83
.83
1.00
.67
.67
.00
.50
.00
1.00
.00
.17
.33
.17
.17
.33
.00
.67
.33
1.00
1.00
1.00
.50
.67
.50
.33
.67
.83
.50
.50
.83
1.00
1.00
.83
.83
.83
.83
.50
.83
.83
.50
.33
.26
.36
.75
.44
.21
.56
.48
.33
.33
.33**
.40
.81
.28
.34
.79
.40
.36
.39
.44
.38
.78
.47
.65
.33**
.22
.53
.34
.16
.16
.49
1.00
(1.23)
.85
.62
.62
.66
.28
.62
.75
.89
.49
.82
.96
(1.30)
.87
.51
.82
.79
.82
.76
.66
.71
.61
.09
.47
.09
.44
.45
.06
.31
.33
.17
.33
.40
.31
.55
.49
.21
.27
.31
.39
.06
.38
.22
.47
.48
.00
.05
.37
.01
.16
.51
.15
.00
(.23)
.15
.12
.05
.16
.06
.04
.08
.39
.01
.01
.04
(.30)
.04
.32
.01
.04
.32
.08
.17
.21
.28
S180
TABLE 5 (Continued )
Democracy 1975
Country
Uruguay
Venezuela
Bahrain
Bangladesh
China
Hong Kong
India
Indonesia
Iran
Iraq
Israel
Japan
Jordan
South Korea
Malaysia
Nepal
Pakistan
Philippines
Singapore
Sri Lanka
Syria
Taiwan
Thailand
Austria
Belgium
Cyprus
Denmark
Finland
France
West Germany
Greece
Hungary
Iceland
Ireland
Italy
Malta
Netherlands
Norway
Poland
Portugal
Spain
Sweden
Switzerland
Turkey
United Kingdom
Yugoslavia
Australia
Fiji
New Zealand
Papua New Guinea
Actual
.33
.83
.17
.00
.00
.67
.83
.33
.17
.00
.83
.83
.17
.33
.67
.17
.33
.33
.33
.83
.17
.17
.83
1.00
1.00
.50
1.00
.83
1.00
1.00
.83
.17
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
.17
.33
.33
.83
1.00
.67
1.00
.17
1.00
.83
1.00
.67
Projected
.50
.21
.25
.12*
.12
.10
(.19)
.11
.05
.50
.76
.02
.25
.13
.22
.16
.44
.01
.30
.13
.25
.35
.68
.83
.36
.83
.93
.76
.91
.45
.80
.56
.68
.70
.30
.75
.80
.62
.44
.61
.70
.86
.28
.77
.44
.83
.33
.81
.34
Democracy 1995
Gap
Actual
.17
.62
.25
.12
.54
.74
(.53)
.06
.05
.33
.07
.14
.08
.53
.05
.17
.11
.32
.54
.04
.08
.48
.32
.17
.14
.17
.10
.24
.09
.38
.64
.44
.32
.30
.70
.25
.20
.46
.10
.27
.13
.14
.39
.23
.27
.17
.50
.19
.33
.83
.67
.17
.67
.00
.50
.50
.00
.17
.00
1.00
1.00
.50
.83
.50
.67
.67
.83
.33
.50
.00
.67
.67
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
1.00
.33
1.00
.17
1.00
.50
1.00
.83
Projected
.82
.51
.47
.55
.54
.92
.48
.38
.31
.04
.96
(1.21)
.45
.94
.77
.45
.50
.86
.79
.81
.57
.96
.95
(1.07)
(1.16)
.93
(1.20)
(1.30)
(1.12)
(1.26)
.79
(1.01)
.97
(1.10)
(1.05)
(1.09)
(1.12)
(1.04)
.94
(1.06)
(1.11)
(1.20)
.75
(1.19)
.81
(1.18)
.83
(1.13)
.54
Gap
.02
.15
.30
.11
.54
.42
.02
.38
.14
.04
.04
(.21)
.05
.10
.27
.22
.17
.03
.45
.31
.57
.30
.28
(.07)
(.16)
.07
(.20)
(.30)
(.12)
(.26)
.21
(.01)
.03
(.10)
(.05)
(.09)
(.12)
(.04)
.06
(.06)
(.11)
(.20)
.42
(.19)
.64
(.18)
.33
(.13)
.29
Note.Actual values pertain to the electoral rights index. Projected values are based on the estimated
system shown in table 1, col. 1. The 1975 projection is [1/(1 coefficient of first lag of electoral rights
coefficient of second lag of electoral rights)] (estimated value based on explanatory variables other than
the lagged dependent variables included in the 1975 equation). The 1995 projection is formed analogously.
Values in parentheses are linearly fitted values that lie outside the range (0, 1). Values shown in bold have
a magnitude of at least .33.
* Projected value for 1975 uses 1975 schooling values because of missing data for 1970.
** Projected value based on estimated schooling value for persons aged 25 and over based on available
data for persons aged 15 and over.
S181
S182
predicts substantial democratization for Turkey, which was surprisingly nondemocratic in 1995.
VII. Concluding Observations
The data for a large panel of countries confirm the Lipset/Aristotle
hypothesis, which says that a higher standard of living promotes democracy. This relation shows up when democracy is represented by
electoral rights or civil liberties and when the standard of living is
measured by per capita GDP, primary school attainment, the gap
between male and female primary schooling (which enters negatively), and the importance of the middle class. Democracy does not
relate significantly to school attainment at the secondary and higher
levels. For a given standard of living, democracy tends to fall with
urbanization and a greater reliance on natural resources but has
little relation to country size.
The apparently strong relation of democracy to colonial heritage
mostly disappears when the measures of standard of living are held
constant. Similarly, the allowance for standard of living weakens the
interplay between democracy and religious affiliation. However, negative effects from Muslim and nonreligious affiliations remain intact.
Given the strength of the Lipset/Aristotle hypothesis as an empirical regularity, it is surprising that convincing theoretical models of
the relation do not exist. Thus development of such a theory is a
priority for future research.
At an empirical level, it would be especially interesting to investigate further the relation of democracy to inequality, colonial status,
and religion. Hopefully, the development of satisfactory theories of
the determination of democracy will suggest additional empirical
linkages that ought to be explored.
References
Alesina, Alberto, and Spolaore, Enrico. On the Number and Size of Nations. Manuscript. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ., October 1995.
Aristotle. Politics. Translated by H. Rackham. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
Univ. Press, 1932.
Barrett, David B., ed. World Christian Encyclopedia: A Comparative Study of
Churches and Religions in the Modern World, ad 19002000. Oxford: Oxford
Univ. Press, 1982.
Barro, Robert J. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical
Study. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1997.
Barro, Robert J., and Lee, Jong Wha. International Measures of Schooling
Years and Schooling Quality. A.E.R. Papers and Proc. 86 (May 1996): 218
23.
Bollen, Kenneth A. Political Democracy: Conceptual and Measurement
Traps. Studies Comparative Internat. Development 25 (Spring 1990): 724.
determinants of democracy
S183