Gender Differentials in Literacy in India: The Intriguing Relationship With Women's Labor Force Participation
Gender Differentials in Literacy in India: The Intriguing Relationship With Women's Labor Force Participation
128143, 2008
! 2007 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2007.02.017
Summary. Contrary to expectations from either human capital or gender empowerment perspectives, analyses across 409 Indian districts show that girls have relatively lower literacy compared to
boys in areas where more women are in the labor force. The most likely explanation is that areas
with higher womens labor force participation are also areas with higher girls labor force participation; these higher rates of girls labor depress their literacy and education. Gender inequalities in
literacy are therefore an exception to the usual egalitarian impacts of womens labor force participation and remind us again of the multidimensionality of gender inequalities.
! 2007 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
Key words Asia, India, gender, womens labor force participation, literacy, spatial autocorrelation
1. INTRODUCTION
Womens participation in the labor force has
long been central to research on gender inequalities (Boserup, 1970). Much of this research has
sought to understand how labor force participation contributes to womens status and to the
reduction of gender inequalities. General models
of gender inequality (e.g., Chafetz, 1984) tend to
emphasize the importance of womens economic
roles in determining their position in other
spheres, from household bargaining to representation in state governance. Empirical research
has found that womens labor force participation is associated with less bias against girls in
child mortality (Kishor, 1993; Rosenzweig &
Schultz, 1982), better health for girls (Thomas,
1994), and with more say in some household
decision making (Dharmalingam & Morgan,
1996; Jejeebhoy & Sathar, 2001; Malhotra &
Mather, 1997). Of course, many conditions
may limit the liberating impacts of work outside
the household (e.g., who controls the income
from such work), and, even in the best of circumstances, outside work usually implies a dual burden for wives and mothers.
Nevertheless, it is less often asserted that
womens labor force participation actually
128
129
Table 1. Literacy rates in percents for all ages combined, by sex: India, 19612001
Year Total percent Women percent Men percent Percentage point difference Difference in log odds ratios
1961
1971
1981
1991
2001*
22.2
27.8
34.6
42.1
65.4
11.6
17.2
23.1
31.1
54.2
32.1
37.7
45.4
52.3
75.8
20.5
20.5
22.3
21.2
21.7
!1.3
!1.1
!1.0
!0.9
!1.0
130
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Kerala
Punjab
Assam
West Bengal
Tamil Nadu
Karnataka
Maharashtra
Andhra Pradesh
Orissa
Madhya Pradesh
Gujarat
Bihar
Himachal Pradesh
Haryana
Uttar Pradesh
Rajasthan
Source: Vanneman and Barnes (2003).
!0.13
!0.44
!0.45
!0.49
!0.74
!0.75
!0.77
!0.81
!0.85
!0.97
!0.98
!1.03
!1.05
!1.07
!1.08
!1.61
Second, general theories of gender stratification emphasize the strengthened bargaining position of women who have independent access
to economic resources, enabling them to better
resist some aspects of patriarchal domination.
Labor force participation usually implies expanded network ties and independent exposure
to the broader society that also raises womens
bargaining position both within and outside the
household. For instance, a study by Dharmalingam and Morgan (1996) on two villages in
South India showed that in the village where
womens labor force participation was high,
women were more likely to have greater mobility, have greater spousal communication, and
better control over their households resources
compared with the village where womens labor
force participation was low.
These conflict models apply best for adult
inequalities. Nevertheless, if we assume that
mothers are more apt than fathers to bargain
for their daughters schooling, then mothers
increased bargaining power through economic
empowerment might lead to more schooling
for their daughters (Thomas, 1994).
A broader, contextual argument traces gender inequalities in schooling to general cultural
evaluations of womens worth, which may be
improved by womens labor force participation. This more indirect influence depends
less on the interpersonal dynamics within
households and more on the general expectations of equal treatment in the society. To
the extent that these general expectations of
equality are influenced by economic roles such
as labor force participation, we would expect
Table 3. Means and standard deviations for the variables used in the analysis: districts in India, 1991
Variable
Gender difference in log literacy odds
Gender ratio adult main: non-main
Odds of women being in exogamous unions
Log ratio boys literacy/illiteracy 1014
Education effort
Housing index
Percent urban in a district
Percent landless in a district
Percent SC in a district
Percent ST in a district
Percent Muslims in a district
Southern states
Log ratio 014 boys, main/non-main
Log ratio 014 girls, main/non-main
Source: Vanneman and Barnes (2003).
Mean
Std. Dev.
Minimum
Maximum
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
409
!0.94
!2.26
1.66
1.47
27.22
35.33
21.73
36.34
16.13
10.47
11.08
0.20
!3.10
!3.77
0.44
0.95
0.92
0.99
11.84
14.38
16.66
18.11
7.56
17.88
11.50
0.40
0.70
1.06
!2.38
!4.98
!0.27
!0.44
8.52
4.77
0.00
1.03
0.00
0.00
0.07
0.00
!6.10
!6.47
0.16
!0.30
4.48
4.82
84.09
88.88
100.00
81.13
51.76
94.75
70.45
1.00
!1.56
!1.76
131
132
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
133
134
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
using methods specified by Ord (1975) that calculate a log likelihood function incorporating
alternative estimates of the spatial autocorrelation of the residuals across adjacent districts.
The autocorrelation estimate that minimizes
this function is selected and then used to calculate the coefficients and their standard errors.
(a) Dependent variables
The Indian census defines a literate person as
one who can both read and write with understanding in any language. . . In operation, the
census mostly accepts the households own
claims to literacy without testing for understanding. Partly because of this minimal
requirement, we supplement our analyses with
an examination of gender differentials in
matriculation from secondary school. There
may be additional reasons why the gender
inequalities at matriculation may differ from
the literacy differentials. Cultural restrictions
on adult womens mobility might restrict adolescent girls school attendance but have less
impact on younger girls primary education.
We have measured the gender gap in literacy
by comparing the logged odds of girls 1014
being literate with the logged odds of boys
1014 being literate:
"
#
F literate =F illiterate j
Lj Ln
M literate =M illiterate j
where
Lj = The sex difference in literacy.
Fliterates = Number of literate girls in age
groups 1014.
Filliterates = Number of illiterate girls in age
groups 1014.
Mliterates = Number of literate boys in age
groups 1014.
Milliterate = Number of illiterate boys in age
groups 1014.
As noted in the discussion of national literacy
rates (Table 1), the difference in logged odds
has some advantages over the difference in percentages since it is not mathematically constrained to be small when literacy rates are
very low or high. These constraints could be
important for Indian data since literacy rates
vary so widely across the country. For example,
if boys are 95% literate and girls 90% literate,
there is only a five percentage point difference,
but illiteracy is still twice as common for girls.
The difference in logged odds captures these
gender inequalities better at the high and low
literacy levels than does the percentage difference. For example, the 9095% difference is
equivalent in log odds to a 5068% difference
at lower literacy levels.
The 1014-age category specifies a group who
would have acquired literacy recently, reflecting
current conditions in the district. Yet, this is
still an age by which most people are likely to
have acquired literacy. Across India, 69% of
the 1014 age group are literate compared to
57% in the 79 age group, 64% in the 1519
age group, and 56% in the 2024 age group.
In 1991, 60% of Indian girls 1014 were literate, compared to 77% of Indian boys. The
girls odds of being literate (1.48:1) were less
than half the boys odds (3.35:1). The odds varied widely across India. In several Kerala districts where childrens literacy was nearly
universal, girls had a slight advantage over
boys. In the Northeast predominantly tribal
state of Meghalaya, girls literacy, 59%, also exceeded boys literacy, 57%. But in most districts, girls literacy lagged behind boys. The
largest gaps were found in Rajasthan; in Jalaur
district, for instance, 63% of boys were literate
compared to only 14% of girls.
(b) Independent variables
(i) Female share of the labor force
Calculations of womens labor force participation rates are sensitive to the definitions of
the labor force. The Indian Census includes
two measures of labor force participation.
Main workers are defined as those who were
economically productive (i.e., not household
work or production for household consumption) for the major part of the year. Marginal
workers are those who worked during the past
year but for less than six months. The marginal
worker category typically includes a higher proportion of women and children than does the
main worker category. We report the results
of the analyses using the main worker definition. We also re-calculated the analyses using
the broader definition that includes both main
and marginal workers; the results are almost
identical.
On average, 21% of the labor force is female,
but this varies from about 2% in western Uttar
Pradesh (UP) districts to over 45% in the hill
districts of Uttaranchal. We use a ratio measure
of womens share of the labor force rather than
the simpler labor force participation rate. In
practice, the two are highly correlated. Because
mens labor force participation rates vary only
!
"
adult female workersmain =adult female non-workers
adult male workersmain =adult male non-workers
135
136
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
Model 1
Model 2
Constant
!1.349***
!1.072***
(!6.80)
0.191***
!4.47
!0.146***
(!5.81)
!0.175**
(!3.31)
0.041***
(3.82)
0.007***
(3.65)
0.004!
(1.96)
!0.000
(!0.30)
0.006***
(5.40)
0.000
(0.18)
0.002!
(1.89)
!0.001
(!0.77)
!0.024
(!0.32)
!0.336***
(!7.68)
0.285***
(5.63)
0.769***
(21.31)
(!9.34)
!0.078**
(!3.12)
!0.141***
(!5.19)
!0.233***
(!4.39)
0.052***
(4.62)
0.008***
(3.98)
0.005*
(2.13)
!0.001
(!0.32)
0.006***
(5.18)
0.002
(0.90)
0.002!
(1.81)
0.001
(0.54)
!0.079
(!1.07)
0.818***
(26.37)
Not applicable.
Note: Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Source: Vanneman and Barnes (2003).
!
p < 0.1.
* p < 0.05.
** p < 0.01.
*** p < 0.001.
137
138
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
139
Table 5. Maximum likelihood estimates of selected independent variables on the gender gap in literacy and
matriculation ages 2024: districts in India, 1991
Variable
Literacy without
child labor
Constant
!2.225***
(!11.45)
!0.109***
(!4.15)
!0.141***
(!4.88)
!0.073
(!0.41)
0.077
(0.82)
!1.751***
(!7.28)
0.111*
(2.42)
!0.143***
(!5.20)
0.061
(0.32)
0.106
(1.13)
Literacy with
child labor
0.007***
(4.41)
0.010***
(3.65)
!0.225
(!1.41)
0.006***
(4.44)
!0.001
(!0.33)
0.002!
(1.65)
!0.001
(!0.61)
0.095
(1.08)
0.817***
(!26.31)
0.006***
(4.14)
0.009***
(3.62)
!0.244
(!1.60)
0.005***
(4.32)
!0.002
(!1.00)
0.001
(1.35)
!0.003!
(!1.82)
0.133
(1.62)
!0.274***
(!5.85)
0.270***
(5.26)
0.796***
(23.91)
Matriculates without
child labor
!2.299***
(!7.63)
!0.092***
(!3.64)
!0.176***
(!6.33)
Matriculates with
child labor
!2.305***
(!7.04)
0.007
(0.16)
!0.179***
(!6.49)
0.473*
(!2.00)
!0.523*
(!2.20)
!0.082
(!1.33)
!0.092
(!1.50)
0.006***
(4.31)
0.011***
(4.42)
0.082
(0.52)
0.003**
(2.79)
0.000
(0.05)
!0.001
(!0.49)
!0.002
(!1.35)
!0.040
(!0.47)
0.006***
(3.96)
0.011***
(4.44)
0.089
(0.57)
0.003**
(2.71)
0.000
(!0.20)
!0.001
(!0.54)
!0.003!
(!1.80)
!0.014
(!0.180)
!0.122*
(!2.58)
0.080
(1.63)
0.787***
(22.97)
0.802***
(24.54)
Not applicable.
Note: Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Source: Vanneman and Barnes (2003).
!
p < 0.1.
* p < 0.05.
** p < 0.01.
*** p < 0.001.
140
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
participation have lower levels of girls matriculation relative to boys just as they have lower
relative levels of girls literacy. 8 Similarly, most
of the other coefficients in the equation for
girls relative matriculation are quite similar
to the coefficients for girls relative literacy.
The factors that impede girls literacy appear
to impede girls higher levels of education.
The effects of girls and boys work are similar
for gender differentials in matriculation as for
differentials in literacy. The effect sizes are, surprisingly, somewhat smaller for the matriculation differentials when one might have expected
that work would have been more of an obstacle
for adolescent girls schooling than for young
girls. Nevertheless, districts where more girls
work are districts where fewer girls matriculate
relative to boys. Adding the effects of girls work
again changes the sign of the coefficient for
womens work to positive, although not statistically significant as was the case for girls literacy.
On the whole the results for matriculates reinforce the results obtained for literacy.
4. DISCUSSION
The results of our analyses are interesting and
rather unexpected. A widening gender gap in
education is associated with higher proportions
of women in the labor force. Theories as disparate as human capital and feminist empowerment would suggest that adult womens
employment should encourage girls education.
In India, this is not the case. In fact, girls literacy is further behind boys literacy in districts
with more adult womens employment. The best
explanation for this seems to be that the more
adult women who work, the more girls who
work. Where girls are in the labor force, they
have less of a chance of attending school and
learning to read and write. We suspect,
although we could not test, that the greater demands for daughters housework in households
where their mothers work outside the house also
helps mediate this effect of womens labor force
participation on lower girls education.
The linkage between child labor and schooling has been much debated recently (Anker,
2000; Basu, 1999). Work does not necessarily
imply withdrawal from school. Many children
both attend school and engage in economically
productive work before and after school hours,
or during school vacations. Sometimes the
additional income from child labor can finance
school expenses (Patrinos & Psacharopoulos,
141
NOTES
1. The 1991 data offer some advantages in completeness. We believe these relationships between womens
labor force participation and gender differentials in
literacy reflect enduring constraints on Indian households. We have tested a similar model with 1981 data,
although with a somewhat different measure of economic development, and find a similar pattern of results.
(Results available on the website.)
2. These include Arunachal Pradesh, Delhi, Goa,
Manipur, Meghalaya, Nagaland, Pondicherry, Sikkim,
and Tripura. The two island territories, Lakshadweep,
and the Andaman and Nicobar Islands, have been
dropped because their lack of contiguous neighbors
precludes their inclusion in the spatial autocorrelation
adjustments. In addition, the small disconnected district
of Daman and Diu is not included in the analysis.
3. This can be shown algebraically (where G = the
ratio of literate to illiterate girls and B = the ratio of
literate to illiterate boys):
X
bi xi :
1
lnG=B b0 b1 ln B
X
ln G b0 b1 ln B ln B
bi xi
X
b0 b1 1 ln B
bi xi :
142
WORLD DEVELOPMENT
REFERENCES
Agarwal, B. (1994). A field of ones own: Gender and land
rights in South Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Anker, R. (2000). Conceptual and research frameworks
for the economics of child labour and its elimination.
Geneva: International Labour Office.
Arnold, F., Kishor, S., & Roy, T. K. (2002). Sexselective abortions in India. Population and Development Review, 28(4), 759785.
Banerji, R. (1997). Why dont children complete primary
school? A study of a low income neighborhood in
Delhi. Economic and Political Weekly, 32, 20532063.
Barro, R. J. (2001). Human capital and economic
growth. American Economic Review, 91(2), 1217.
Basu, A. (1992). Family size and child welfare in an
urban slum: some disadvantages of being poor but
modern. In Cynthia Lloyd (Ed.), Fertility, family
size, and structure: Consequences for families and
children. New York: The Population Council.
Basu, K. (1999). Child labor: Cause, consequence, and
cure, with remarks on international labor standards.
Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 10831119.
Basu, K., & Van, P. H. (1998). The economics of child
labor. American Economic Review, 88(3), 412427.
Behrman, J. R., Foster, A. D., Rosenzweig, M. R., &
Vashishtha, P. (1999). Womens schooling, home
teaching, and economic growth. Journal of Political
Economy, 107(4), 682714.
Beneria, L., & Sen, G. (1981). Accumulation, reproduction, and womens role in economic development:
Boserup revisited. Signs: Journal of Women in
Culture and Society, 7(2), 279298.
Beteille, A. (1986). The concept of tribe with special
reference to India. European Journal of Sociology, 27,
297318.
Beutel, A. M., & Axinn, W. G. (2002). Gender, social
change, and educational attainment. Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 51(1), 109134.
Boserup, E. (1970). Womens role in economic development. New York: St. Martins Press.
Carr, R. V., Wright, J. D., & Brody, C. J. (1996). Effects
of high school work experience a decade later:
Evidence from the National longitudinal survey.
Sociology of Education, 69(1), 6681.
Chafetz, J. S. (1984). Sex and advantage: A comparative,
macrostructural theory of sex stratification. Totowa,
NJ: Rowman and Allenheld.
143