Slippery Slope
Slippery Slope
Slippery Slope
CITATIONS
READS
150
1,523
3 authors, including:
Erich Kirchler
University of Vienna
218 PUBLICATIONS 2,546 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Ingrid Wahl
Ferdinand Porsche FernFH
9 PUBLICATIONS 270 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Abstract
A framework for tax compliance is suggested in which both the power of tax authorities and trust
in the tax authorities are relevant dimensions for understanding enforced and voluntary compliance.
Dynamic interactions between power and trust are considered. Using the framework as a conceptual
tool, factors studied in previous research, such as nes, audit probabilities, tax rate, knowledge, attitudes, norms and fairness are reviewed and discussed with reference to the power and trust dimensions. Using the framework as an operational tool, approaches of responsive regulation to increase
tax compliance are discussed.
2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
JEL classication: H26
PsycINFO classication: 4270; 2960
Keywords: Taxation; Compliance; Authority; Power; Trust; Social behavior
1. Introduction
Paying taxes is a duty for citizens. The primary interest of the state is that citizens
follow this duty and behave in compliance to the tax rules, regardless of the motives for
0167-4870/$ - see front matter 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.joep.2007.05.004
211
compliance. However, the same behavior can result from dierent motives: (a) citizens can
comply because they calculate the costs for non-compliance as being too high, or (b) citizens can comply because they feel obliged to do so as members of the community.
Depending on the motives, a dierent approach to tax regulation would be required.
Purely economic factors such as audit rates and nes have shown inconsistent eects on
tax compliance, for various reasons. First, the assumption that taxpayers are trying to
avoid taxes whenever it pays must be doubted. Many studies show that a vast majority
of citizens are willing to pay taxes. Second, most taxpayers seem to take the legitimacy
of the tax system for granted. They believe in the overarching objectives of the government
and pay their share without considering possibilities to avoid or to evade taxes. The following paper presents a framework that integrates such perspectives, gives a review of
studies on tax compliance, and discusses regulatory strategies.
2. A framework for tax compliance
The framework suggested here starts from the idea that the tax climate in a society can
vary on a continuum between an antagonistic climate and a synergistic climate. In an
antagonistic climate, taxpayers and tax authorities work against each other; in a synergistic climate, they work together. The antagonistic climate can be characterized by a cops
and robbers attitude on both sides: tax authorities perceive the taxpayers as robbers
who try to evade whenever they can and need to be held in check; taxpayers feel persecuted
by the authorities (cops) and feel it right to hide (Braithwaite, 2003a). In such a climate,
the social distance (Bogardus, 1928) is likely to be large, with little respect and little positive feelings towards the regulatory authorities on behalf of individuals and groups. Voluntary compliance is likely to be negligible, and individuals are likely to resort to
rational weighing of the costs and benets of evading. The synergistic climate can be
characterized by the idea that tax authorities perform a service for the community, and
are a part of the same community the individual taxpayers belong to. The authorities
approach could be described as a service and client attitude, as it is propagated in
New Public Management. Authorities aim for transparent procedures and for respectful
and supportive treatment of taxpayers. For example, in Switzerland a friendly and respectful treatment of taxpayers by authorities has been recognized for a long time as an important means to enhance tax compliance (Feld & Frey, 2005). In such a climate, social
distance is likely to be low, voluntary compliance is likely to prevail, and individuals
are less likely to consider the chances of evading, and more likely to contribute their share
out of a sense of obligation.
From that starting point, the framework proceeds with the idea to think about tax compliance along two major dimensions: the power of tax authorities and the trust in tax
authorities. These dimensions and their interactions jointly inuence the level of tax compliance (Kirchler, 2007). Tyler (2006) follows a similar line of argumentation when, in his
conclusion, he distinguishes two dierent ways of how authorities could gain cooperation
from the public. The rst way claims that the threat of punishment could encourage compliance. However, incentives for compliance and coercion for non-compliance are not
always eective mechanisms for creating and maintaining compliant behavior. The second
way claims that perceived competence in managing problems could activate citizens to aid
the authorities. Considering authorities as having legitimacy leads to citizens feeling
obliged to adhere to decisions, policies, and rules (Tyler, 2006).
212
Enforced
tax compliance
Maximum
Compliance
High
Trust
Minimum
in authorities
High
Power
of authorities
Low
Low
Fig. 1. The slippery slope framework: enforced tax compliance and voluntary tax compliance depending on the
power of the authorities and trust in the authorities.
213
214
compliance are only found at the extremes of maximum power or maximum trust, which
in reality are unattainable. In other areas, a certain downward pull seeks to reduce compliance. This pull results from the reciprocal inuences of power and trust described
above, and from asymmetries between gaining and losing of trust and power. A downward
spiral is easily conceivable: if trust in the tax authorities decreases, any action on their
behalf will be interpreted as less legitimate than before. A regular audit would be interpreted as a deliberate action and a sign of mistrust, which in turn makes it legitimate to
seek opportunities to reduce payments and to reduce support for the authorities. Tax
authorities would react by conducting a more thorough audit to ferret out the hidden
reserves. This would be considered proof that they treat the individual taxpayer dierent,
i.e., unfairly from the individuals view, and which again reduces trust and cooperation.
An upward spiral is possible, but seems much harder to obtain because obtaining trust
is more dicult than losing it. When achieved, however, an increase in trust could contribute to power of authorities by honest taxpayers supporting the authorities, and by needing
fewer resources for monitoring. Seeing dishonest taxpayers punished would increase trust
on behalf of the honest taxpayers.
Quite obviously, an antagonistic or a synergistic climate is related to the dimensions of
the framework presented here. It would be dicult to identify a clear causal relationship
between them, and it is more likely that they form a reciprocal relationship. For example,
a synergistic climate with a service and clients approach can increase both trust in and
power of the authorities; at the same time, measures that increase trust can contribute to a
synergistic climate.
The framework presented in Fig. 1 can be used as a conceptual tool and as an operational tool. As a conceptual tool it may serve to understand the importance of determinants of tax behavior and the ambiguous eects reported in empirical research. As an
operational tool it can be used to develop strategies of eectual interaction between tax
authorities and taxpayers; for example, authorities should aim at increasing trust by communicating a service and clients attitude (e.g., locating the reason for non-compliance
by phoning taxpayers, Feld & Frey, 2005). The next section will consult the slippery
slope framework as a conceptual tool to review previous research on factors inuencing
tax compliance. The nal section will consult the slippery slope framework as an
operational tool and explore regulatory strategies that tax authorities can adopt.
3. The slippery slope framework as a conceptual tool to organize previous research
In the tradition of tax compliance research, a number of factors have been considered
important for explaining compliance. We present a review on existing ndings and discuss
them with regard to the dimensions of power and trust in the slippery slope framework.
3.1. Audit probabilities
Studies on the impact of audit probabilities on tax compliance found rather weak
eects. Fischer, Wartick, and Marks (1992) review summarizes inconsistent ndings on
audit probabilities and tax compliance. For example, threatening taxpayers in a eld
experiment (Slemrod, Blumenthal, & Christian, 2001) with close examination of their
upcoming returns increased tax compliance just for low and middle-income taxpayers,
but decreased it for high-income taxpayers. Furthermore, laboratory experiments varying
215
audit probabilities found low negative eects of audit rates on evasion, especially for precise percentage information on audit probabilities instead of indicating high, middle, and
low probabilities (Spicer & Thomas, 1982). In contrast, other experiments report that
imprecise information increases tax compliance (Friedland, 1982). Dierent survey studies
found signicant and non-signicant low positive relations between audit probabilities
and tax compliance (e.g., Mason & Calvin, 1978; Song & Yarbrough, 1978; Spicer
& Lundstedt, 1976; Warneryd & Walerud, 1982).
Within the current framework, it would be argued that not the objective audit probability is important, but the subjectively perceived probability and its interpretation. A
review on tax compliance and audit probabilities (Andreoni, Erard, & Feinstein, 1998)
showed that objective audit probabilities have little eect on compliance, and concluded
that subjectively perceived probabilities may be mediated via psychological variables.
Prior audits, i.e., direct experience, also have a weak impact on tax compliance. An
explanation is that prior audits may not turn out as badly as taxpayers initially feared
(Andreoni et al., 1998). The subjective probability of being audited would be an indicator
for the power of authorities; however, the same level would be interpreted dierently
depending on the trust in the authorities. An individuals risk aversion, according to
our framework, would be of relevance primarily under conditions of low-trust; with
high-trust in the authorities, it would become irrelevant because the tendency to calculate
probabilities and payos is replaced by following a common norm.
3.2. Fines
Empirical studies on the impact of nes on tax compliance did not nd the clear picture
theoretical analyses provide. In sum, the relation of nes and tax compliance also shows
inconsistent ndings (Fischer et al., 1992). Some experiments showed that nes are slightly
higher related to tax compliance than audit probabilities are (e.g., Park & Hyun, 2003).
Keeping constant the expected value of a tax-like game, but changing audit probabilities
and nes for non-compliance, showed that compliance increased signicantly with higher
nes, but not with higher audit probabilities (Friedland, Maital, & Rutenberg, 1978).
Other experiments, on the contrary, showed that nes and tax compliance are not related,
but audit probabilities and tax compliance are (Friedland, 1982; Webley, Robben, Elers,
& Hessing, 1991).
In the current framework, it would be argued that the interpretation of nes matters. In
an antagonistic climate, nes can be a part of the game of cops and robbers; in a synergistic climate, they can be perceived as an adequate retribution for behavior that harms
the community. Fines are therefore connected to trust and power. Fines that are too low
could be perceived as indicator that the authorities are weak and unable to control the
wrongdoers, undermining trust among honest taxpayers. Fines that are inappropriate
because a taxpayer involuntarily made a mistake resulting from ambiguous tax laws, or
nes that are exorbitantly high, would undermine the perception of retributive justice
and induce tax evaders to try even harder to regain their losses incurred by those nes.
3.3. Tax rate
Economic models of rational compliance decisions provide either mixed predictions of
the eect of the marginal tax rate on compliance, or predict that increased tax rates would
216
increase compliance (Allingham & Sandmo, 1972). On the contrary, most empirical
research nds that higher tax rates decrease compliance or provides mixed results. Some
studies (Pommerehne & Weck-Hannemann, 1996; Weck-Hannemann & Pommerehne,
1989) demonstrate that evasion increases with increasing marginal tax rates. Also Clotfelter
(1983) and Slemrod (1985) found that the marginal tax rate has a signicant eect on underreporting. In Porcanos (1988) study, the tax rate had no eect on evasion and underreporting. Laboratory experiments with varying tax rates frequently found tax rate increases
leading to higher evasion (Alm, Jackson, & McKee, 1992; Collins & Plumlee, 1991; Friedland et al., 1978; Park & Hyun, 2003). However, Alm, Sanchez, and deJuan (1995) found
the opposite in a Spanish sample, and Baldry (1987) did not nd a signicant eect at all.
Within the current framework, the impact of the tax rate would depend on the degree of
trust. When trust is low, a high tax rate could be seen as an unfair treatment of taxpayers,
as an attempt at taking from the taxpayers what is rightly theirs. When trust is high, the
same level of tax rate would be interpreted as contribution to the community, which in
turn again prots each individual. In the rst case, the tax rate would be interpreted as
the wielding of power by some remote oce; in the second case, as a joint agreement
within the community.
3.4. Subjective tax knowledge and participation
Tax knowledge is positively related to tax compliance. Schmolders (1960) found that
agreement with governmental activities and scal policy was higher in highly educated
groups. Also other authors accepted that longer education increases the knowledge about
taxation, but without considering the content of education (Kinsey & Grasmick, 1993;
Song & Yarbrough, 1978; Spicer & Lundstedt, 1976; Vogel, 1974). An Australian survey
(Niemirowski, Wearing, Baldwin, Leonard, & Mobbs, 2002) found that subjective evaluation of tax knowledge was signicantly linked to tax-related values, attitudes towards tax
compliance, and behavior intentions. Several studies found that reduced complexity and
higher knowledge increased tax compliance (Clotfelter, 1983; Groenland & van Veldhoven, 1983; Kirchler & Maciejovsky, 2001; Park & Hyun, 2003; Wahlund, 1992; Warneryd
& Walerud, 1982). A study manipulating tax knowledge of students (Eriksen & Fallan,
1996) found that with acquiring additional knowledge on tax rules in a class, tax compliance increased and tax evasion decreased.
A related topic is the degree of participation in decision processes concerning taxes.
Direct democracy has a positive eect on tax compliance. The more inuence citizens have
on the budgeting process, the more they will try to get information about the tax system
and consider consequences in the long run (Frey & Kirchgassner, 2002). For example, in
Swiss cantons in which citizens can inuence the budgetary policy in direct legislation, tax
compliance is higher than in cantons in which citizens have no inuence (Pommerehne &
Weck-Hannemann, 1996). Feld and Kirchgassner (2000) reported a dierent type of communication among citizens who are directly involved in political decisions, and between
citizens and their representatives. Informed citizens will accept tax increases when the
expenditures of the government are justied (Frey & Kirchgassner, 2002). Overall, tax evasion is lower in direct than in representative democratic systems (Kirchgassner, Feld, &
Savioz, 1999).
In the current framework, it is argued that subjective tax knowledge and participation
in the use of taxes is positively correlated with trust, whereas poor understanding and
217
misunderstanding are positively correlated with distrust. Thus, higher knowledge concerning taxes leads to higher compliance and poor knowledge concerning taxes leads to higher
non-compliance. Because tax laws are often criticized to be too complex to be fully understood, increasing taxpayers literacy by simplication of the tax laws, by training and education, and by increased taxpayer service will increase trust in authorities and will
therefore lead to increased voluntary tax compliance. Knowledge about taxation practices
can also contribute to the perceived power of authorities; for example, knowing that tax
ocers have conducted a large number of tax audits and detected several cases of fraud
can make them appear eective and powerful. Perception of ineectiveness, on the other
hand, can reduce perceived power, pointing to the importance of information policy on
part of tax authorities.
3.5. Attitudes toward taxes
Studies on tax psychology often focus on attitudes and tax compliance. The theory of
reasoned action (Fishbein & Ajzen, 1975) and the theory of planned behavior (Ajzen,
1991) incorporate attitudes as one of the determinants predicting behavior. Attitudes
represent the positive and negative evaluations that an individual holds of objects. It is
assumed that attitudes encourage individuals to act according to them. Thus, a taxpayer
with positive attitudes toward tax evasion is expected to be less compliant than a taxpayer
with negative attitudes. Attitudes towards tax evasion are often found to be quite positive.
Surveys conducted in Germany (Schmolders, 1960, 1964) found that about half of the
responders compared deliberate tax evaders with cunning business men, whereas only
about one-third referred to tax evaders as thieves and deceivers. Many studies on tax evasion found signicant, but weak relationships between attitudes and self-reported tax evasion (e.g., Orviska & Hudson, 2002; Trivedi, Shehata, & Mestelman, 2004). A model of tax
evasion behavior developed by Weigel, Hessing, and Elers (1987) considers social and
psychological conditions, including attitudes and moral beliefs about tax evasions propriety, as antecedents of tax compliance. Data collected from ned tax evaders and honest tax
payers showed that attitudes explain in part self-reported tax evasion, but are insignicant
predictors of actual behavior. However, the correlations between self-reported tax noncompliance and attitudes are signicant but fairly weak. These ndings suggest a rather
complicated relationship between tax evasion and attitudes, nevertheless we can be condent in our general prediction that if tax attitudes become worse, tax evasion will
increase (Lewis, 1982, p. 177).
In the current framework, attitudes are important for both the power and the trust
dimension. On the one hand, favorable attitudes will contribute to trust in authorities
and consequently will enhance voluntary tax compliance. On the other hand, attitudes
towards the authorities will be relevant for the interpretation of the use of power as benevolent or malicious. Tax attitudes in general also depend on the perceived use of the money
collected, and therefore are connected to knowledge.
3.6. Personal, social, and national norms
Besides attitudes, norms are important determinants of tax compliance. Behavioral
intentions are determined also by subjective norms (Ajzen, 1991; Fishbein & Ajzen,
1975). Norms are behavioral standards on three dierent levels: (a) the individual level,
218
(b) the social level, and (c) the national level. On the individual level, norms dene
internalized standards on how to behave. Individual norms are related to moral reasoning, authoritarianism and Machiavellianism, egoism, norm dependency, and values.
There is considerable overlap between individual norms, values, and tax ethics: the
more developed the moral reasoning or tax ethics, the more likely is voluntary compliance (Baldry, 1987; Jackson & Milliron, 1986; Trivedi, Shehata, & Lynn, 2003).
For example, nance ocers and self-employed taxpayers with a very strong orientation towards self-interest reported low tax ethics and high non-compliance
(Kirchler & Berger, 1998).
On the social level, norms are usually dened as prevalence or acceptance of tax evasion among a reference group (Wenzel, 2005). Social norms are related to the behavior
of reference groups, e.g., friends, acquaintances, or vocational group. If taxpayers
believe that non-compliance is widespread and approved behavior in their reference
group, they are likely to be non-compliant as well. For example, in a semi-structured
interview study in Great Britain, social norms were found among the most important
factors related to tax compliance (Sigala, Burgoyne, & Webley, 1999). The relationship
between social norms and tax compliance is complex. Wenzel (2004) argues that social
norms should elicit concurring behavior only when taxpayers identify with the group to
whom the norms are ascribed. Taxpayers then internalize the social norms and act
accordingly. Several studies showed that emphasizing social norms of reference groups
increases tax compliance (Cullis & Lewis, 1997; Sigala et al., 1999; Warneryd & Walerud, 1982; Webley, Robben, & Morris, 1988). Allowing participants to discuss in a
tax experiment increased tax compliance, whereas without discussion tax compliance
decreased (Alm, McClelland, & Schulze, 1999). Moreover, some authors (Taylor,
2003; Wenzel, 2005) argue that communicating social norms on the collective level will
increase voluntary tax compliance.
On the level of national norms, norms become cultural standards, often mirrored in the
actual law. Several authors suggest that trust in political leadership and administration
will lead to voluntary tax compliance when favorable national norms are established
(e.g., Fjeldstad, 2004; Frey, 1992; Pommerehne & Frey, 1992; Torgler, 2005; Tyler,
2001a, 2001b). In general, if the norms held by taxpayers favor tax compliance, voluntary
tax compliance will result.
In the current framework, norms encompass both power and trust. First, national
norms nd their expression in tax laws and the role given to tax authorities, having
a direct inuence on their power. Second, social norms such as the belief that tax evasion is a petty crime and widespread hinder the work of tax authorities, in particular
when there is no countervailing norm of community. A norm where all citizens are perceived as contributing their fair share would certainly help to increase trust in the
authorities.
3.7. Perceived fairness
When asked what they think about the tax system, citizens most often communicate
fairness concerns (e.g., Braithwaite, 2003c; Rawlings, 2003; Taylor, 2003). In a similar
vein, Andreoni et al. (1998) claim that incorporating morals and social dynamics in
economic theory is essential. A conceptual framework for fairness considerations
(Wenzel, 2003) suggests to dierentiate three areas of fairness, as in social psychology:
219
(a) distributive justice, which refers to the exchange of resources, both benets and cost,
(b) procedural justice, which refers to the process of resource distribution, and (c) retributive justice, which refers to the perceived appropriateness of sanctions in the case of
norm-breaking.
With regard to distributive justice, comparisons are made on the individual, the group,
and the societal level. On the individual level, taxpayers are concerned about the fairness
of their outcomes, and they want to be treated relative to their merits, eorts, and needs. If
an individuals tax burden is heavier than that of comparable other individuals, tax compliance is likely to decrease. On the group level, taxpayers are concerned about the fairness
of outcomes of the group and want a fair treatment of their group relative to other
(income) groups (e.g., Spicer & Lundstedt, 1976). If a specic group perceives its tax burden as heavier than that of another group, tax non-compliance is likely to increase within
this group (e.g., Juan, Lasheras, & Mayo, 1994; Spicer & Becker, 1980). On the societal
level, taxpayers are concerned about the fairness of the outcomes of the whole nation.
If the tax system is perceived as unfair, tax non-compliance is likely to increase (e.g., Baldry, 1987; Cowell, 1992), whereas a system experienced as fair might increase trust and consequently increase voluntary compliance.
With regard to procedural justice, the components essential for perceived fairness are
neutrality of the procedure, trustworthiness of the tax authorities, and polite, dignied,
and respectful treatment (Tyler & Lind, 1992). Comparisons again are made on the individual, group, and societal level. On the individual level, taxpayers consider the treatment
by the tax authorities, information provided, costs regarding compliance and administration, and the dynamics of allocation of revenues. It is argued that increased information
related to tax law and explanations for changes can increase fairness perceptions (Carnes
& Cuccia, 1996; Wartick, 1994). Perceived procedural justice on the individual level and a
culture of interaction are important for building up trust (Job, Stout, & Smith, 2007). On
the group and societal level, taxpayers consider the neutrality of tax ocers regarding
_subgroups, such as vocational groups, income groups, or cohorts. If tax authorities
and ocers treat taxpayers equally, in a respectful and responsible way, trust in the
government and thus voluntary tax compliance is likely to increase on the individual,
group, and societal level.
With regard to retributive justice, unreasonable and intrusive audits and unfair penalties lead to negative attitudes toward the tax oce and taxes in general (e.g., Spicer &
Lundstedt, 1976; Strumpel, 1969; Wenzel & Thielmann, 2006). Thus, unfavorable retributive justice perceptions could lead to increased distrust and consequently to increased tax
non-compliance. Although justice research has not always yielded consistent evidence for
the impact of justice perceptions on tax compliance, perceived justice might increase voluntary tax compliance.
In the current framework, perceived fairness is connected to the trust dimension
because a just treatment of taxpayers (i.e., distributive and procedural fairness) helps to
build and maintain trust. Retributive justice is connected to the power dimension as well,
because it depends also on detecting and ning wrongdoers. In turn, an inconsiderate exertion of power that is perceived as intrusive can reduce trust.
To summarize, some of the major factors discussed in previous research on tax compliance would gain from considering them within the slippery slope framework and its
interaction of the power and trust dimension. In Section 4 we discuss the contribution
of the framework for regulatory strategies.
220
221
222
To conclude, the slippery slope framework promises a better understanding of taxpaying behavior and of regulatory practices by highlighting the necessity to consider the
power of authorities, the trust in authorities, and their dynamic interaction. Considering
distinctions between enforced and voluntary compliance calls for rethinking the role of
tax authorities and suggests that taxpaying can be perceived not exclusively as an onerous
duty, but also as a well-accepted duty.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Henk Elers and the participants of the conference on Managing
and maintaining compliance (Leiden, The Netherlands, 1011 April 2006) for valuable
inputs.
References
Ajzen, I. (1991). The theory of planned behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 50(2),
179211.
Allingham, M., & Sandmo, A. (1972). Income tax evasion: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 1,
323338.
Alm, J., Jackson, B. R., & McKee, M. (1992). Estimating the determinants of taxpayer compliance with
experimental data. National Tax Journal, 45(1), 107114.
Alm, J., McClelland, G. H., & Schulze, W. D. (1999). Changing the social norm of tax compliance by voting.
Kyklos, 52(2), 141171.
Alm, J., Sanchez, I., & deJuan, A. (1995). Economic and noneconomic factors in tax compliance. Kyklos, 48(1),
318.
Andreoni, J., Erard, B., & Feinstein, J. S. (1998). Tax compliance. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(2), 818860.
Ayres, I., & Braithwaite, J. (1992). Responsive regulation: Transcending the deregulation debate. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Baldry, J. C. (1987). Income tax evasion and the tax schedule: Some experimental results. Public Finance, 43(3),
357383.
Bergman, M. S. (2003). Tax reforms and tax compliance: The divergent paths of Chile and Argentina. Journal of
Latin American Studies, 35, 593624.
Bogardus, E. S. (1928). Immigration and race attitudes. Boston: D.C. Heath and Company.
Braithwaite, V. (2003a). Dancing with tax authorities: Motivational postures and non-compliant actions. In V.
Braithwaite (Ed.), Taxing democracy. Understanding tax avoidance and tax evasion (pp. 1539). Aldershot:
Ashgate.
Braithwaite, V. (2003b). A new approach to tax compliance. In V. Braithwaite (Ed.), Taxing democracy.
Understanding tax avoidance and tax evasion (pp. 111). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Braithwaite, V. (2003c). Perceptions of whos not paying their fair share. Australian Journal of Social Issues, 38(3),
335362.
Braithwaite, V. (2007). Responsive regulation and taxation: Introduction. Law and Policy, 29(1), 311 (Special
issue on responsive regulation and taxation).
Braithwaite, V., & Job, J. (2003). The theoretical base for the ATO compliance model. Technical Report Research
Note 5. CTSI, RSSS, ANU. Retrieved 12 July 2006, from http://ctsi.anu.edu.au/publications/research%20notes/RN5.pdf.
Carnes, G. A., & Cuccia, A. D. (1996). An analysis of the eect of tax complexity and its perceived justication on
equity judgments. Journal of the American Taxation Association, 18, 4056.
Cialdini, R. B. (1996). The triple tumor structure of organizational behavior. In D. M. Messick & A. E.
Tenbrunsel (Eds.), Codes of conduct (pp. 4458). New York: Sage.
Clotfelter, C. (1983). Tax evasion and tax rates: An analysis of individual returns. The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 65(3), 363373.
Collins, J. H., & Plumlee, R. D. (1991). The taxpayers labor and reporting decision The eect of audit schemes.
Accounting Review, 66(3), 559576.
223
Cowell, F. A. (1992). Tax evasion and inequity. Journal of Economic Psychology, 13(4), 521543.
Cullis, J., & Lewis, A. (1997). Why people pay taxes: From a conventional economic model to a model of social
convention. Journal of Economic Psychology, 18(23), 305321.
Eberl, D. (2003). Vertrauen und Management. Stuttgart: SchaeerPoeschel.
Eriksen, K., & Fallan, L. (1996). Tax knowledge and attitudes towards taxation: A report on a quasi-experiment.
Journal of Economic Psychology, 17(3), 387402.
Feld, L., & Frey, B. (2005). Illegal, immoral, fattening or what?: How deterrence and responsive regulation shape
tax morale. In C. Bajada & F. Schneider (Eds.), Size. causes, and consequences of underground economy. An
international perspective (pp. 1637). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Feld, L., & Kirchgassner, G. (2000). Direct democracy, political culture, and the outcome of economic policy: A
report on the Swiss experience. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(2), 287306.
Fischer, C. M., Wartick, M., & Mark, M. M. (1992). Detection probability and taxpayer compliance: A review of
the literature. Journal of Accounting Literature, 11(1), 146.
Fishbein, M., & Ajzen, I. (1975). Belief, attitude, intention and behavior: An introduction to theory and research.
Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Fjeldstad, O. H. (2004). Whats trust got to do with it? Non-payment of service charges in local authorities in
South Africa. Journal of Modern African Studies, 42(4), 539562.
Frey, B. (1992). Tertium datur Pricing, regulating and intrinsic motivation. Kyklos, 45(2), 161184.
Frey, B. (2003). Deterrence and tax morale in the European Union. European Review, 11(3), 385406.
Frey, B., & Kirchgassner, G. (2002). Demokratische Wirtschaftspolitik. Munich: Vahlen, Vol. 3.
Friedland, N. (1982). A note on tax evasion as a function of the quality of information about the magnitude and
credibility of threatened nes: Some preliminary research. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 12(1),
5459.
Friedland, N., Maital, S., & Rutenberg, A. (1978). A simulation study of income tax evasion. Journal of Public
Economics, 10(1), 107116.
Groenland, E. A. G., & van Veldhoven, G. M. (1983). Tax evasion behavior: A psychological framework. Journal
of Economic Psychology, 3(2), 129144.
Jackson, B. R., & Milliron, V. (1986). Tax compliance research: Findings, problems, and prospects. Journal of
Accounting Literature, 5(1), 125165.
Job, J., Stout, A., & Smith, R. (2007). Culture change in three taxation administrations: From command-andcontrol to responsive regulation. Law and Policy, 29(1), 84101.
Juan, A., Lasheras, M. A., & Mayo, R. (1994). Voluntary tax compliant behavior of Spanish income tax payers.
Public Finance, 49, 90105.
Kinsey, K. A., & Grasmick, H. G. (1993). Did the tax reform act of 1986 improve compliance? Three studies of
pre- and post-TRA compliance attitudes. Law and Policy, 15(4), 239325.
Kirchgassner, G., Feld, L. P., & Savioz, M. R. (1999). Die direkte Demokratie. Munich: Vahlen.
Kirchler, E. (2007). The economic psychology of tax behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Kirchler, E., & Berger, M. M. (1998). Macht die Gelegenheit den Dieb? Jahrbuch der Absatz- und Verbrauchsforschung, 44, 439462.
Kirchler, E., & Maciejovsky, B. (2001). Tax compliance within the context of gain and loss situations, expected
and current asset position, and profession. Journal of Economic Psychology, 22(2), 173194.
Lewis, A. (1982). The psychology of taxation. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Mason, R., & Calvin, L. D. (1978). A study of admitted income tax evasion. Law and Society Review, 13(Fall),
7389.
Niemirowski, P., Wearing, A.J., Baldwin, S., Leonard, B., & Mobbs, C. (2002). The inuence of tax related
behaviours, beliefs, attitudes and values on Australian taxpayer compliance. Is tax avoidance intentional and
how serious an oence is it? Sydney: University of New South Wales.
Orviska, M., & Hudson, J. (2002). Tax evasion, civic duty and the law abiding citizen. European Journal of
Political Economy., 19(1), 83102.
Park, C. G., & Hyun, J. K. (2003). Examining the determinants of tax compliance by experimental data: A case of
Korea. Journal of Policy Modeling, 25(8), 673684.
Pommerehne, W., & Frey, B.S. (1992). The eects of tax administration on tax morale. (Series II, No. 191)
University of Konstanz.
Pommerehne, W., & Weck-Hannemann, H. (1996). Tax rates, tax administration and income tax evasion in
Switzerland. Public Choice, 88(1-2), 161170.
Porcano, T. M. (1988). Correlates of tax evasion. Journal of Economic Psychology, 9(1), 4767.
224
Rawlings, G. (2003). Cultural narratives of taxation and citizenship: Fairness, groups and globalisation.
Australian Journal of Social Issues, 38(3), 269306.
Schmolders, G. (1960). Das Irrationale in der oentlichen Finanzwirtschaft. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.
Schmolders, G. (1964). Finanzwissenschaft und Finanzpolitik. Tubingen: J. c. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Sigala, M., Burgoyne, C., & Webley, P. (1999). Tax communication and social inuence: Evidence from a British
sample. Journal of Community and Applied Social Psychology, 9(3), 237241.
Slemrod, J. (1985). An empirical test for tax evasion. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(2), 232238.
Slemrod, J., Blumenthal, M., & Christian, C. (2001). Taxpayer response to an increased probability of audit:
Evidence from a controlled experiment in Minnesota. Journal of Public Economics, 79(3), 455483.
Song, Y.-D., & Yarbrough, T. E. (1978). Tax ethics and taxpayer attitudes: A survey. Public Administration
Review, 38(5), 442452.
Spicer, M. W., & Becker, L. A. (1980). Fiscal inequity and tax evasion: An experimental approach. National Tax
Journal, 33(2), 171175.
Spicer, M. W., & Lundstedt, S. B. (1976). Understanding tax evasion. Public Finance, 21(2), 295305.
Spicer, M. W., & Thomas, J. E. (1982). Audit probabilities and tax evasion decision: An experimental approach.
Journal of Economic Psychology, 2(3), 241245.
Strumpel, B. (1969). The contribution of survey research to public nance. In A. T. Peacock (Ed.), Quantitative
analysis in public nance (pp. 1322). New York: Praeger.
Taylor, N. (2003). Understanding taxpayer attitudes through understanding taxpayer identities. In V. Braithwaite
(Ed.), Taxing Democracy. Understanding tax avoidance and tax evasion (pp. 7192). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Torgler, B. (2005). Tax morale and direct democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(2), 525531.
Trivedi, V.U., Shehata, M., & Mestelman, S. (2004). Attitudes, incentives, and tax compliance. Hamilton:
McMaster University, Department of Economics.
Trivedi, V. U., Shehata, M., & Lynn, B. (2003). Impact of personal and situational factors on taxpayer
compliance: An experimental analysis. Journal of Business Ethics, 47(3), 175197.
Turner, J. C. (2005). Explaining the nature of power: A three-process theory. European Journal of Social
Psychology, 35(1), 122.
Tyler, T. (2001a). Public trust and condence in legal authorities: What do majority and minority group members
want from the law and legal institutions? Behavioral Sciences and the Law, 19(2), 215235.
Tyler, T. (2001b). Trust and law abidingness: A proactive model of social regulation. Boston University Law
Review, 81(2), 361406.
Tyler, T. (2003). Trust within organisations. Personnel Review, 32(5), 556568.
Tyler, T. (2006). Psychological perspectives on legitimacy and legitimation. Annual Review of Psychology, 57,
375400.
Tyler, T., & Lind, E. (1992). A relational model of authority in groups. In M. P. Zanna (Ed.). Advances in
experimental social psychology (Vol. XXV, pp. 115191). San Diego, CA: Academic Press.
Vogel, J. (1974). Taxation and public opinion in Sweden: An interpretation of recent survey data. National Tax
Journal, 27(1), 499513.
Wahlund, R. (1992). Tax changes and economic behavior: The case of tax evasion. Journal of Economic
Psychology, 13(4), 657677.
Warneryd, K., & Walerud, B. (1982). Taxes and economic behaviour: Some interview data on tax evasion in
Sweden. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2(3), 187211.
Wartick, M. (1994). Legislative justication and the perceived fairness of tax law changes: A reference cognitions
theory approach. The Journal of the American Taxation Association, 16(2), 106123.
Webley, P., Robben, H. S. J., Elers, H., & Hessing, D. J. (1991). Tax evasion: An experimental approach.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Webley, P., Robben, H., & Morris, I. (1988). Social comparison, attitudes and tax evasion in a shop simulation.
Social Behaviour, 3(3), 219228.
Weck-Hannemann, H., & Pommerehne, W. (1989). Einkommenssteuerhinterziehung in der Schweiz: Eine
empirische Analyse. Schweizerische Zeitschrift fur Volkswirtschaft und Statistik, 125(4), 515556.
Weigel, R. H., Hessing, D. J., & Elers, H. (1987). Tax evasion research: A critical appraisal and theoretical
model. Journal of Economic Psychology, 8(2), 215235.
Wenzel, M. (2003). Tax compliance and the psychology of justice: Mapping the eld. In V. Braithwaite (Ed.),
Taxing Democracy. Understanding tax avoidance and tax evasion (pp. 4169). Aldershot: Ashgate.
Wenzel, M. (2004). An analysis of norm processes in tax compliance. Journal of Economic Psychology, 25(2),
213228.
225
Wenzel, M. (2005). Motivation or rationalisation? Causal relations between ethics, norms and tax compliance.
Journal of Economic Psychology, 26(4), 491508.
Wenzel, M., & Thielmann, I. (2006). Why we punish in the name of justice: Just desert versus value restoration
and the role of social identity. Social Justice Research, 19(4), 450470.