What Is Social Capital
What Is Social Capital
What Is Social Capital
brill.nl/ajss
Abstract
Social capital is an old concept but it entered into academic and policy debates only in 1990s. Its
importance in explaining economic and social phenomena have been increasingly felt in recent
years. Literature on theoretical and empirical aspects of social capital grew signicantly during
last decade. The whole notion of social capital is centred on social relationships and its major
elements include social networks, civic engagement, norms of reciprocity, and generalised trust.
Broadly speaking, it is dened as a collective asset in the form of shared norms, values, beliefs,
trust, networks, social relations, and institutions that facilitate cooperation and collective action
for mutual benets. It is a complex multidimensional concept having dierent dimensions,
types, and levels of measurement. Common types of social capital include: structure and cognitive; bonding, bridging, and linking; strong and weak; and horizontal and vertical. It can be
measured and analysed at individual- and collective-levels in terms of social perspective and
micro-, meso- and macro-levels in terms of geographic perspective. The properties of social
capital, such as capacity to appear in as an explanatory variable in the production function,
accumulation over time, capability of improving economic performance, investment with
expected future returns, convertibility, and the need of maintenance, make it qualify as a form of
capital, though there are some criticisms about the use of term capital in social capital. Research
on social capital remains in its initial stage and the concept is still elusive, prone to contextual
denition, decient in common measurement indicators, inability to explicitly quantify eects,
and subject to various criticisms. Conceptual and measurement imprecision has led the concept
prone to vague interpretation, less empirical application, and underestimation of its value. More
empirical studies and testing of the concept on the ground is needed to develop a commonly
accepted denition and measurement indicators that can explicitly disentangle and quantify its
eects on overall development processes. Better conceptualisation and operationalisation of
social capital theory is helpful to attract more investment on its development, design appropriate
social policies, and promote sustainable development.
Keywords
social capital, review, denition, types, controversies, economic development
DOI: 10.1163/156853109X436847
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
481
Introduction
Social scientists and development experts often puzzle to explain why economic growth and development dier signicantly across countries or regions
that enjoy virtually equal access to technology, resources, and market in a
modern global world. Explaining large economic disparities across countries
having otherwise identical production environments in terms of technology
and capital (natural, physical, and nancial) is a major challenge for researchers. In the past, economists employed dierent theories to address the variation in economic development, but satisfactory explanations still remain at
large. For many decades, the standard economic theories, such as Solow
growth model and Walrasian equilibrium model, were the dominant mode of
economic analysis. These rational choice models assumed that economic
variables account most, if not all, of variations in economic outcomes. These
theories focused primarily on economic variables and hardly recognise the
potential role of social and cultural factors on economic development. Essentially, socio-cultural factors were left unaccounted for in standard economic
theory (Bilig, 2000). Even now, mainstream economic theories pay little
attention to social values and are reluctant to rely on these values as potential
determinants of economic outcomes (Barro and McCleary, 2002; Guiso
et al., 2006).
Over time, economic theories have been criticised on various grounds.
First, they fail to explain economic growth and development outcomes fully.
The literature argues that standard factors of production (technology, physical
capital, and human capital) explain only part of the development story. There
are social and cultural factors (norms, values, beliefs, and institutions) that
play prominent roles in economic performance and we need to account those
cultural factors in explaining development (Easterly and Levine, 2001;
Christoforou, 2005). Second, they are unable to explain why unprecedented
economic growth is not sustainable and usually accompanies undesirable outcomes, such as income inequality, low improvement in quality of life, social
injustice, social conicts, adverse eects on environment, etc. Third, they fail
to account social values systems in economic development. Fukuyama (2001)
criticised that economists normally make simplifying assumptions that human
beings are rational and their utility maximising behaviour is invariant across
societies. As a result, they ignore the social value systems. All these criticisms
are interrelated and emphasized the importance of social and cultural factors
in economic theories. This seems to suggest that viewing development from a
one-dimensional (economic) perspective would be a conformist idea. Indeed,
economic activity is deeply embedded in social structure, where socio-cultural
values inuence personal traits of an individual that consequently aects the
482
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
483
duction. Later on, it was recognised that not only human capital, but also
cultural factors are important in economic and social outcomes. This reorganisation of social components on development led to the birth of social
capital in 1990s (see Lucas, 1976; Harrison and Huntington, 2000; OECD,
2001). Indeed, rising interest on the interconnection between social values
and development led to the birth of the development economics and institutional economics sub-disciplines. Now, development institutions, like the
United Nations and the World Bank, have recognised cultural diversity as an
important component of development process and have started incorporating
local cultural factors in their development programmes. Literature looking at
the relationship between culture and economic phenomena has been growing
substantially since then.
Prominent scholars, such as Max Weber, Amartya Sen, Samuel Huntington, etc., claim that culture interacts with economic development in many
ways and, hence, cultural dimensions are critical in understanding economic
behaviour (Sen, 1999; Landes, 2000). Empirical studies have established the
positive inuence of socio-cultural values and institutions on economic growth
and their critical role in the success of developed countries (Huntington,
1998; Inglehart and Baker, 2000; Hjerppe, 2003). Fukuyama (2001) contended that economic development is inuenced not just by the existence of
formal institutions, but also by certain norms and values that accelerate
exchange, savings, and investment. He outlined four means through which
culture aects economic behaviour impact on organisation and production, attitudes towards work and consumption, the ability to create and manage institutions, and the creation of social networks. The strong linkage
between culture and development has been well established now and social
scientists are now paying more attention as to how social values can shape the
overall development process (Inglehart, 1997; Beugelsdijk, 2003; Guiso et al.,
2006; Sabitini, 2006). The strand of literature looking at the relationship
between social values and development patterns is on rise (Putnam, 1993;
Fukuyama, 1995; Barro, 1997; Inglehart, 1997; Knack and Keefer, 1997; Zak
and Kanck, 2001; Gradstein and Justman, 2002; Beugelsdijk, 2003; Pryor,
2005; Guiso et al., 2006; Sabitini, 2006). Incorporation of cultural values in
economic models make economic discourse richer, more valuable, better able
to capture the nuances of the real world, and make them more useful (Guiso
et al., 2006).
Mainstream neo-classical growth models started with variables physical
capital and labour, then included human capital, subsequently incorporated
institutions, and has nally considered including culture. In the 1990s, a new
school of thought on the determinants of economic development emerged,
484
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
which embracing the concept of social capital (trust, social networks, and
institutions) to explicitly explain the eect of socio-cultural values in economic behaviour. This is essentially a reorientation of institutional economics.
Social capital embodies cultural traits of a society and is considered as source
of wealth (Putnam, 1993; Fukuyama, 1995). The dierential impact of norms,
values, and beliefs on trust, networks, and institutions is the basis of social
capital (Fukuyama, 2001). The appealing characteristic of social capital is that
it can be conceptualised and measures in specic forms and can be incorporated into standard economic models (Guiso et al., 2006; Sabitini, 2006).
Researchers have uncovered the role of social capital in economic progress
and sustainable development (Putnam, 1993; Knack and Keefer, 1997; Sabatini, 2006). Granovetter (1985) argues that most economic behaviours are
embedded in social networks. Social capital plays a signicant role in providing access to more information, increasing social cohesion, better civic engagement, reducing opportunistic behaviour, boosting political participation,
government responsiveness and eciency, reducing transaction costs, providing insurance against risk and uncertainties, and solving collective actions
problems (Coleman, 1990; Putnam, 1993; Fukuyama, 1995; Woolcock
and Narayan, 2000; Lin, 2001; Paxton, 2002; Welzel et al., 2005). Empirical
studies have established the positive eect of social capital on health, educational outcomes, social welfare, and reducing tax evasion (UNESCO, 2002;
Productivity Commission, 2003; Hombres et al., 2006). Social capital, thus,
has a potential to serve as powerful means of development. It can shape the
economic outcomes at both the micro and macro levels (Rodrik, 1998).
Recently, social scientists, including economists, have became increasingly
interested in social capital and have been using this concept as an explanatory
variable to explain economic behaviour (Knack and Keefer, 1997; Temple,
2001; Sabatini, 2006).
Large numbers of empirical studies have claimed the positive correlation
between social capital and development. Nevertheless, the social capital concept is plagued by theoretical vagueness and conceptual weakness (Ponthieux,
2004) and its practical value has been challenged on various grounds. Sabatini
(2006) claims that the relationship between social capital and economic development is still unconvincing and sometimes conicting. He outlined three
weaknesses of social capital no universal denition and measurement
method; no unanimous agreement on the positive relationship between social
capital and development; and even when a positive relationship is established,
doubts remain on the causal nexus between social capital and its outcomes.
Chen (2005) argues that despite actual and perceived positive inuence of
social capital, there is still some scepticism about whether and how much
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
485
486
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
487
488
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
489
490
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
491
The set of denitions representing dierent view broadly agree with the
view that the basic foundation of social capital is the social relations that
engenders individual and collective benets. Social capital is a multidimensional construct containing various forms and functions. Encompassing different view, social capital can be regarded as a collective asset in the form of
social relations, shared norms, and trust that facilitate cooperation and collective action for mutual benets. It is a capital asset produced through actors
investment, endowing investors to use as credits by virtue of connections.
Social relations are regarded as an asset of an individual a resource in the
form of information and trust that actors can draw dawn once accumulated.
Availability of the capital allows achieving certain goals that would otherwise
be impossible in the absence of capital. Social relations vanish if not maintained; reciprocity decline over time; and norms depend on regular communications (Coleman, 1990). This implies that the actors investment strengthens
and reinforces the capital while disinvestment leads to a decline of the capital.
Elements that are crucial to the denition and conceptualisation of social
capital can be grouped into three broad categories: social networks (of families, friends, communities, and voluntary associations), norms of reciprocity
(shared norms, values, and behaviours), and trust (in other people and institutions). Specically, social capital involves informal social relations, memberships in social networks and groups, civic engagements (volunteering),
community and organisational participation (volunteering), trust in the people and institutions, and norms of reciprocity. It is a collectively-owned resource
generated through individuals shared norms, values, attitudes, and behaviours that produces mainly a positive inuence on economic development.
492
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
assets, bonds, etc) that have the potential to produce goods and services. Classical capital, in this sense, is a surplus value or commodity that can be used as
a factor of production. The fundamental properties of classical capital goods
include it is a commodity that is tangible, can be owned, and can be traded in
the market. Besides, the capital stock is productive and can be used as investment for future production, generating as a result of investment, durability,
and depreciates from both use and non-use (Schmid, 2000; Castle, 2002;
Piazza-Georgi, 2002).
Social scientists, mainly sociologists, have redened the classical theory
of capital in terms of neo-capital theories (human capital, cultural capital,
institutional capital, and social capital). The neo-capital theories borrow the
original macro-level concept of capital from Marxist theory and apply it to
individual actors (Lin, 2001). The neo-capital theory argues that every individual can make choices to generate capital and keep it for their own benet.
Application at the individual level and recognition of the value of choice decision of each actor are the two critical elements of neo-capital theory (Lin,
2001). The neo-capital theories recognise the importance of intangible
resources embedded in individual actors (qualities of labour and social relations) that have the potential to produce goods and services. The capital metaphor of social capital has a base on neo-capital theory.
Prominent theorists, such as Pierre Bourdieu, James Coleman, and Robert
D. Putnam, claim that social capital has similar (although intangible) properties to traditional forms of capital; hence, the term capital in social capital has
analogous meanings with other forms of capital. Coleman (1990) contends
that, like other forms of capital, social capital is productive, making possible
the achievements of certain ends that in its absence would not be possible.
But, unlike other forms of capital, social capital inheres in the structures of
relations between and among actors. It is not lodged either in the actors themselves or in physical implements of production. Putnam (1993) argues that,
while physical capital refers to physical objects and human capital refers to
properties of individuals, social capital refers to connections among individuals their social networks, their norms of reciprocity, and the trust that arise
from them. OECD (2001) distinguishes social capital from human capital
based on three perspectives. First, social capital is embedded in relationships
and therefore cannot be considered the exclusive property of any specic individuals; second, it is the product of an investment of time and energy but its
benets can prot individuals that did not participate in its making; and third,
it has positive externalities that aect the wider community so that costs and
benets of social relations do not accrue only to the person building relationships, but to every individual that belongs to the group.
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
493
Not all social scientists accept the metaphor of capital to describe social
relationships. Several authors, primarily economists, have questioned and
criticised the capitalisation of social capital (see Baron and Hannon, 1994;
Portes, 1998; Arrow, 2000; Solow, 2000; Hoerth et al., 1999; Inkeles, 2000;
Schmid, 2000; Fine, 2001; Bowles and Gintis, 2002; Durlauf, 2002; Harriss,
2002; Smith and Kulynych, 2002; Quirbia, 2003; Roberts, 2004; Halpern,
2005). They have criticised the capitalisation of social capital on dierent
grounds. Smith and Kulynych (2002) believe that the meaning of capital is so
broad and pervasive that it obscures its distinction and consequently measurement. On the other hand, Inkeles (2000) thinks that use of term capital is
too narrow and proposes more broad term like social resources. The term
community would be more appropriate to social capital because it focuses
attention on what groups do rather than what people own (Bowles and Gintis,
2002). Social capital is not necessarily the best term, but might just be a social
fabric (Halpern, 2005). Some authors criticise that social capital is neither
social, nor capital (Robison et al., 2002; Roberts, 2004).
Several authors have clearly pointed out the weaknesses of the analogy
between physical capital and social capital. Arrow (2000) argues that physical
capital has three important characteristics: extension in time, deliberate sacrice in the present for future benets, and alienability (transfer of ownership
from one person to another). To him, social capital shares only the time
dimension aspect with physical capital (for example, trust or reputation take
some time to develop); but it does not necessarily require any material sacrice; in most cases, it is also dicult to transfer the ownership of social capital
from one person to another. Further, social networks are maintained to provide other than economic benets for actors. Conceptually social capital, thus,
fails to full the properties of classical capital goods. In this sense, Arrow questions the appropriateness of the term capital to represent social relations and
he discourages the use of social capital terminology. Solow (2000) raises some
measurement problems of social capital and notes that, . . . it is an attempt
to gain conviction from a bad analogy. He writes that while physical capital
can be measured and rate of return can be readily calculated by past investment net of depreciation, such measurement is not straightforward for social
capital. Besides, social capital appreciates with use and traditional models are
incapable of explaining the changes of social capital over time. Hoerth et al.
(1999) comments that social capital is the product of altruism and, hence, it
does not full the basic characteristics of capital resources built up through
investment and that can be drawn upon when needed. To qualify as capital
an entity must possess an opportunity cost, but this is lacking in social capital
(Baron and Hannon, 1994). Social capital is not equally available to all, in
494
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
much the same way that other forms of capital are dierently available. Geographic and social isolation limit access to this resource (Edwards and Foley,
1998).
Many authors criticise social capital in terms of its ownership. One major
dierence between social capital and other forms of capital is that social capital resides in a social relationship, whereas other forms of capital primarily
resides in the individual alone (Robison et al., 2002). Portes (1998) compares
features of dierent forms of capital and comments that while economic capital is in peoples bank accounts and human capital is insides their heads, social
capital inheres in the structure of their relationships. You can sell your privately-owned asset, such as land, but you cannot sell your social relations, in
which other individuals also have a stake. Social capital is the only form of
capital not under any individuals complete ownership (Yang, 2007). Moreover, unlike other forms of capital, actors cannot trade social capital in the
market but it is, instead, embedded within a group (Gant et al., 2002; Glaeser
et al., 2002). Social capital belongs to each member of a group and requires
the actions of all involved to sustain it (Wilson and Chiveralls, 2004). This
suggests that the properties of social capital are similar to those of neo-capital
theory but not to those of classical capital theory. Economists agree that social
capital inuences economic outcomes, but whether this inuence can be or
should be meaningfully coded into a capital metaphor of social capital is a
debatable issue (Quirbia, 2003). Given these conceptual and measurement
imprecisions, many economists feel reluctant to assign capital metaphor to
social capital.
On the other side of the coin, there are large numbers of prominent social
scientists who believe that social capital shares many commonalities with other
forms of capital and, hence, we can genuinely assign capital metaphor to social
capital. The mushrooming of social capital literature in past decade is a case in
point. Robison et al. (2002) mentions that physical capital posses properties
of transformation capacity, durability, exibility, substitutability, decay (maintenance), reliability, the ability to create other capital, capacity for investment
and disinvestment, and alienability. Social capital shares most, if not all, of
these capital-like properties. Castle (1998) describes that capital in any form
qualies as capital only if it makes humans more productive when they use it
in combination with other forms of capital. Hoerth et al. (1999) mentions
that the outcomes of social capital are capital in nature, because capital is
something that is durable; retains its identity even after repeated use; and can
be used up, destroyed, maintained and improved. Both structural and cognitive forms of social capital posses capital characteristics because they both
require investment of time and eort, not always of money (Grootaert and
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
495
496
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
available for future use. Holding social capital in an analogous form of decay
is misleading (Sobel, 2002). He argues that expanding social networks indirectly increases other members social capital by giving them access to a larger
network. Some scholars criticise social capital that investment in social capital
does not bring any opportunity costs. Woolcock (1998) responds this comment by saying that while individuals do not invest directly in a commodity
social capital, they do often make calculated decisions to join clubs, do favours,
and make and maintain relationships with an expectation of future benets.
Such deliberate decisions to increase their social capital bring certain opportunity costs.
Light and Gold (2000) identify two properties namely storability and
transformability that are common between social capital and other forms of
capital. To him, social capital is the only capital that can be accessed and
accumulated by rich and poor alike. This is because investing on it requires
only time and energy, but not money. Social capital facilitates transformation
of individual capitals into material wealth which is available for rich and poor
equally.
Svendsen and Svendsen (2005) believe that social capital shares some common properties of other forms of capital and, hence, it can be regarded as
capital. Their argument is that like physical, economic, or human capital,
social capital can provide immediate benets to the individuals (in the form of
information or help from friends). We can convert social capital into other
forms of capital (get a better job). We can also cultivate social capital in the
hope of future benets, applying strategies modied by cultural codes. However, it is dierent from other forms of capital in the sense that it cannot be
exclusively owned by single individual and it is prevailingly a non-excludable
good. Social capital can benet many actors at the same time (Schmid, 2002).
Lin (2001) denes social capital in relation to neo-capital theories, by
separating it from classical capital theory. Lin writes that premise behind
the notion of social capital is the investment in social relations with expected
returns. People engaged in social networks can derive certain benets. To
Lin, it is the members of the group who make maintenance and reproduction
of this social asset possible. Thus, it resembles the features of neo-capital
theory.
Above discussion revealed argument for and against the appropriateness
of the term capital in social capital. To what extent social capital shares properties of other forms of capital is crucial to consider it as capital. It appears that
social capital is dierent in some properties from other forms of capital, but it
shares many common properties of other forms of capital. It exhibits some
similar characteristics to other kinds of capital in the sense that it can be put
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
497
into economic production functions, it is accumulated over time, and it signicantly improves economic performance (Fafchamps and Minten, 2002).
Social capital is similar to other forms of capital in the sense that it can be
invested with expected future returns, is convertible, is appropriable, and
requires maintenance. The social relationships can be utilised as an economic
resource for the production of goods and services. Thus, social capital does
have many properties that qualify it as capital. The capitalisation of social
capital is based on sucient reasoning. It is worth noting that it is the term
capital that makes social capital attractive to such a wide range of people bringing together of sociology and economics (Adam and Roncevic, 2003).
498
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
499
500
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
501
502
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
503
the rule of law, and government (Hopkins, 2002; Bjornskov and Svendsen, 2003). This means, the micro-approach emphasises the nature and
forms of cooperative behaviour; the macro-approach focuses on the
conditions (favourable or unfavourable) for cooperation; and the mesoapproach highlights structures that enable cooperation to take place
(PRI, 2005). The Policy Research Initiative (PRI) argues that the microapproach focuses on the value of collective action, the meso-approach
focuses on the structure that enables cooperation, and the macroapproach focuses on the value of integration and social cohesion. This
implies that social capital can be measured and analysed at various levels. Basically, this hierarchical distinction of social capital is a combination of cognitive (micro), structural (meso), and institutional (macro)
aspects of social capital. Social capital, thus, operates, either individually or collectively, at various levels and each level produces dierent
outcomes and has dierent implications for public policy.
Conclusion
Social structures, cultural norms and values, and institutions aect economic
behaviour through multiple direct and indirect channels and, hence, they are
critical in understanding sustainable economic development. Successful explanation of economic development, thus, has to transcend beyond narrow measures of mere income growth to encompass social, cultural, and political
variables. In the past, mainstream economic models focused primarily on
standard factors of production and they largely ignored the socio-cultural
dimensions. As a result economic development ended up with low welfare
improvement and high social problems; economic models also proved to be
decient in explaining development outcomes fully. This led to re-orientation
of development approach placing emphasis on social norms, values, beliefs,
and institutions. As a result human capital, institutions, and currently social
capital became important elements of economic models. The role of social
capital in overall development process came into light in 1990s and its importance in explaining economic and social phenomena has been increasing felt
thereafter. Social scientists have been using the concept as an important determinant of economic behaviour. The interest on social capital is overwhelming
and the literature on theoretical and empirical aspects of social capital grew
signicantly during the last decade.
The idea of social capital can be traced long back but its entry into academic
and policy debates can be credited to the pioneering work of Pierre Bourdieu
(1986), James Coleman (1988) and Robert Putnam (1993). Broadly, social
504
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
capital can be dened as a collective asset in the form of shared norms, trust,
networks, social relations, and institution that facilitate cooperation and collective action for mutual benets. Social capital is a complex multidimensional concept having various dimensions, types, levels and determinants, and
varieties of denitions exist depending on the discipline and interest. Nevertheless, most denitions emphasise the role of social relations in generating
benets for individual and society as a whole. The critical elements of social
capital include social networks (families, friends, communities, and voluntary
associations), norms of reciprocity (shared norms, values, and behaviours),
and trust (people and institutions). It is collectively-owned capital generated
through individuals shared norms, values, attitudes, and behaviours that positively benets economic development. The most common forms of social
capital include structural and cognitive social capital; bridging, bonding, and
linking social capital; strong and weak ties; and horizontal and vertical social
capital. Social capital can be measured at individual and collective level as well
as at the micro-, meso-, and macro-levels. These dierent forms and level of
analysis suggest that social capital can be dened, operationalised, and measured in dierent ways.
The use of term capital in social capital is a highly controversial issue.
Some economists criticise the capitalisation of social capital in the sense that
it lacks many of the basic properties of classical capital and, hence, it does not
qualify as capital. On the other hand, many social scientists argue that although
social capital lacks some basic properties of classical capital, it shares many
important properties of classical capital and, hence, it qualies as capital. It
can be argued that the properties of social capital, such as it can be put into
production function, can accumulate over time, is capable of improving economic performance, can be invested with expected future returns, is convertible, is appropriable, and requires maintenance; this makes it qualify as one
form of capital. The social relationships can be used as an economic resource
for the production of goods and services. Given the high signicance of social
capital in explaining economic and social phenomena, it is of less value to
spend resources on capital debate.
References
Adam, F. and Roncevic, B. (2003) Social Capital: Recent Debates and Research Trends. Social
Science Information 42(2): 155183.
Adler, P. S. and Seok-Woo Kwon (2002) Social Capital: Prospects for a New Concept. Academy
of Management Review 27(1): 1740.
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
505
Aldridge, S., Halpern, D. and Fitzpatrick, S. (2002) Social Capital. Performance and Evaluation Unit Discussion Paper. London: Cabinet Oce. Available at: http://www.strategy.gov.
uk/ down- loads/seminars social-capital/ social capital.pdf.
Anheier, H. and Kendall, J. (2002) Interpersonal Trust and Voluntary Associations. British
Journal of Sociology 53: 343362.
Arrow, K. (2000) Observations on Social Capital in Dasgupta, P. and Serageldin, I. (eds.)
Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Baron, J. and Hannon, M. (1994) The Impact of Economics on Contemporary Sociology.
Journal of Economic Literature 32(3): 11111146.
Barro, R. J. (1997) Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Barro, R. J. and McCleary, R. M. (2002) Religion and Political Economy in an International
Panel. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. W8931. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract= 312644.
Becker, G. S. (1996) Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Ben-Ner, A. and Putterman, L. (1997) Values and Institutions in Economic Analysis. Department of Economics Working Paper No. 97/4. Providence, RI: Brown University.
Beugelsdijk, S. (2003) Culture and Economic Development in Europe. Ph.D. dissertation.
Tilburg University.
Bilig, M. S. (2000) Institutions and Culture: Neo-Weberian Economic Anthropology. Journal
of Economic Issues 34(4): 771778.
Bjornskov, C. and Svendsen, G. T. (2003) Measuring Social Capital: Is there a Single Underlying Explanation. Department of Economics Working Paper No. 03/05. Aarhus, Prismet:
Aarhus School of Business.
Bourdieu, P. (1986) The Forms of Capital in Richardson, J. G. (ed.) Handbook of theory and
research for the sociology of education. New York: Greenwood Press, Pp. 241258.
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2002) Social Capital and Community Governance. The Economic
Journal 112: 419436.
Burt, R. S. (1992) Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Carpenter, J. P., Daniere, A. G. and Takahashi, L. M. (2004) Cooperation, Trust, and Social
Capital in Southeast Asian Urban Slums. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 55
(4): 533551.
Castle, E. N. (1998) A Conceptual Framework for the Study of Rural Places. American Journal
of Agricultural Economics 80: 621631.
(2002) Social Capital: An Interdisciplinary Concept. Rural Sociology 67: 331349.
Chen, X. (2005) Magic Or Myth? Social Capital and its Consequences in the Asian, Chinese,
and Vietnamese Contexts, in Mutz, G. and Klump, R. (eds.) Modernization and Social Transformation in Vietnam: Social Capital Formation and Institutional Building. Hamburg: Institut
fr Asienkunde.
Christoforou, A. (2005) On the Determinants of Social Capital in Greece Compared to Countries of the European Union. Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM) Working Paper
No. 05/68. Milan: FEEM.
Chuah, S. H., Homann, R., Jones, M. and Williams, G. (2005) An Economic Anatomy of
Culture: Attitudes and Behavior in inter- and intra-National Ultimatum Game Experiments.
Centre for Decision Research and Experimental Economics (CeDEx) Discussion Paper
no. 2005/11. Nottingham: University of Nottingham.
Coleman, J. S. (1988) Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital. American Journal of
Sociology Supplementary 94: 95120.
506
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
507
Heron, J. M. (2000) Beyond Community and Society: The Externalities of Social Capital
Building. Policy Sciences 33: 477494.
Hitt, M. A., Ho-Uk Lee and Yucel, E. (2002) The Importance of Social Capital to the Management of Multinational Enterprises: Relational Networks among Asian and Western Firms.
Asia Pacic Journal of Management 19(23): 353372.
Hjerppe, R. (2003) Social Capital and Economic Growth Revisited. Valtion Taloudellinen
Tutkimuskeskus (VATT) Discussion Paper No. 307. Helsinki: Government Institute for Economic Research.
Hoerth, S. L., Boisjoly, J. and Duncan, G. J. (1999) The Development of Social Capital.
Rationality and Society 11: 79110.
Homans, G. (1961) Social Behavior: Its Elementary Forms. New York: Harcourt, Brace and
World.
Hombres, B., Rocco, L., Suhrcke, M. and McKee, M. (2006) Does Social Capital Determine
Health? Evidence from Eight Transition Countries. Rome: Institute for the Protection and Security of the Citizen.
Hopkins, L. (2002) What Is Social Capital? Institute for Social Research (ISR) Working Paper
No. 2. University of Michigan, Michigan: Institute of Social Research. Available at: http://
www.sisr.net/publications/workingpapers/No2_LH_nal.PDF.
Huntington, S. P. (1998) The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. Carmichael, CA: Touchstone Books.
Iisakka, L. and Alanen, A. (2006) Social Capital in Finland: Domestic and International Background in Iisakka, L. (ed.) Social Capital in Finland: Statistical Review. Helsinki: Statistics
Finland.
Inglehart, R. (1997) Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, Economic, and Political
Change in 43 Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Inglehart, R. and Baker, W. E. (2000) Modernization, Cultural Change, and the Persistence of
Traditional Values. American Sociological Review 65(1): 1921.
Inkeles, A. (2000) Measuring Social Capital and is Consequences. Policy Sciences 33: 245268.
Jacobs, J. (1961) The Life and Death of Great American Cities. New York: Random House.
Johari, M. Y. Hj (1989) Social Development, Social Change and Development Planning in
Sabah in Johari, M. Y. (ed.) Socio-Cultural Dimension Of Development Planning. Proceedings
of a seminar held at Kundasang, Ranau, Sabah. 30 March1 April 1987. Sabah, Kota
Kinabalu: Institute for Development Studies (SABAH), Pp. 2548.
Kilby, P. (2002) Social Capital and Civil Society. Canberra: ANU.
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1997) Does Social Capital Have An Economic Payo? A Cross-Country Investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4): 12511288.
Landes, D. S. (2000) Culture Makes all the Dierence in Harrison, L. E. and Huntington,
S. P. (eds.) Culture Matters. New York: Basic Books, Pp. 213.
Light, I. and Gold, S. J. (2000) Ethnic Economies. San Diego, CA: Academic Press.
Lin, N. (2001) Social Capital: A Theory of Social Structure and Action. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Loury, G. (1977) A Dynamic Theory of Racial Income Dierences in Wallace, P. A. and
LaMond, A. (ed.) Women, minorities, and employment discrimination. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Lucas, R. E. (1976) Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique in Brunner, K. M. (ed.) The
Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Vol. 1 of Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.
Newton, K. (2001) Trust, Social Capital, Civil Society, and Democracy. International Political
Science Review 22: 201214.
OECD (2001) The Well-Being of Nations: The Role of Human and Social Capital. Paris: Oce of
Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).
508
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
(2002) Social Capital: The Challenge of International Measurement. Paris (France): OECD.
Available at: http://www.oecd.org/ dataoecd/2/47/2380584.pdf.
Ostrom, E. (2000) Social Capital: A Fad or a Fundamental Concept? in Dasgupta, P. and
Serageldin, I. (eds.) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, D.C.: The World
Bank, Pp. 172215.
Paxton, P. (2002) Social Capital and Democracy: An Interdependent Relationship. American
Sociological Review 67(2): 254277.
Piazza-Georgi, B. (2002) The Role of Human and Social Capital in Growth: Extending Our
Understanding. Cambridge Journal of Economics 26: 461479.
Pichler, F. and Wallace, C. (2007) Patterns of Formal and Informal Social Capital in Europe.
European Sociological Review 23(4).
Ponthieux, S. (2004) The Concept of Social Capital: A Critical Review. Paper presented at the
10th Association de comptabilit nationale conference on National Accounting, Paris, 2123
January 2004.
Portes, A. (1998) Social Capital: Its Origin and Applications in Modern Sociology. Annual
Review of Sociology 24: 124.
PRI (2005) Social Capital as a Public Policy Tool. PRI Project report. Toronto: Policy Research
Initiative (PRI).
Productivity Commission (2003) Social Capital: Reviewing the Concept and its Policy Implications. Research Paper. Canberra: AusInfo.
Pryor, F. L. (2005) National Values and Economic Growth. American Journal of Economics and
Sociology 64(2): 451482.
Putnam, R. (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
(2000) Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon
and Schuster.
Quibria, M. G. (2003) The Puzzle of Social Capital: A Critical Review. ERD Working paper
No. 40. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Roberts, J. M. (2004) Whats Social about Social Capital? British Journal of Political and International Relations 6: 471493.
Robison, L. J., Schmid, A. A. and Siles, M. E. (2002) Is Social Capital Really Capital? Review
of Social Economy 601: 121.
Rodrik, D. (1998) Where Did All the Growth Go? External Shocks, Social Conicts, and
Growth Collapses. NBER Working Paper No. 6350. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Sabatini, F. (2006) The Empirics of Social Capital and Economic Development: A Critical
Perspective. Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei FEEM) Working Paper 2006/15. Milan: Eni
Enrico Mattei Foundation.
Sander, T. H. (2002) Social Capital and New Urbanism: Leading a Civic Horse to Water.
National Civic Review 91: 213221.
Schmid, A. A. (2000) Sources of Social Capital. Department of Agricultural Economics Sta
Paper No. 00/07. Michigan: Michigan State University.
(2002) Using Motive to Distinguish Social Capital from its Outputs. Journal of
Economic Issues 36: 747768.
Seely, J., Sim, A. and Loosely, E. (1956) Crestwood Heights: A Study of the Culture of Suburban
Life. New York: Basic Books.
Sen, A. (1999) Development as Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Slangen, L. H. G., van Kooten, G. C. and Suchanek, P. (2004) Institutions, Social Capital
and Agricultural Change in Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of Rural Studies 20(2):
245256.
Smith, M. K. (2007) Social capital, the encyclopedia of informal education. Available at: www.
infed.org/biblio/social_capital.htm.
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
509
Smith, S. S. and Kulynych, J. (2002) It may be Social but why is it Capital? The social construction of social capital and the politics of language. Politics and Society 30:149186.
Sobel, J. (2002) Can We Trust Social Capital? Journal of Economic Literature 40(1): 139154.
Solow, R. M. (2000) Notes on Social Capital and Economic Performance, in Dasgupta, P. and
Serageldin, I. (eds.) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, D.C.: The World
Bank.
Svendsen, G. L. H. and Svendsen, G. T. (2005) The Creation and Destruction of Social Capital:
Entrepreneurship, Cooperative Movements, and Institutions. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Tabellini, G. (2005) Culture and Institutions: Economic Development in the Regions of
Europe. Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute for Economic Research (CESifo)
Working Paper Series No. 1492. Munich: Bocconi University.
Temple, J. (2001) Growth Eects of Education and Social Capital in the OECD Countries in
Helliwell, J. F. (ed.) The Contribution of Human and Social Capital to Sustained Economic
Growth and Well-Being. Proceedings of OECD/HRDC Conference, Quebec, 1921 March
2000. Ottawa: HRDC.
Todaro, M. (2000) Economic Development. London (UK): Addison-Wisley Longman, Inc.
Tsai, W. and Ghoshal, S. (1998) Social Capital and Value Creation: The Role of Intra-Firm
Networks. Academy of Management Journal 41(4): 464476.
Turner, J. H. (2000) The Formation of Social Capital, in Dasgupta, P. and Serageldin, I.
(eds.) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank,
Pp. 94146.
UNESCO (United Nations Educational, Scientic and Cultural Organization) (2002) Social
Capital and Poverty Reduction. Which roles for the society organizations and the state? Paris
(France): UNESCO.
Upho, N. (2000) Understanding Social Capital: Learning from the Analysis and Experience
of Participation in Dasgupta, P. and Serageldin, I. (eds.) Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Upho, N. and Wijayaratna, C. M. (2000) Demonstrated Benets from Social Capital: The
Productivity of Farmer Organizations in Gal Oya, Sri Lanka. World Development 28: 1875
1890.
Van der Gaag, M. P. J. and Snijders, T. A. B. (2003) A Comparison of Measures for Individual
Social Capital. Paper presented at the conference on Creation and Returns Of Social Capital,
3031 October 2003, Amsterdam, The Netherlands.
Van Oorschot, W., Arts, W. and Gelissen, J. (2006) Social Capital in Europe. Measurement and
Social and Regional Distribution of a Multifaceted Phenomenon. Acta Sociologica: Journal
of the Nordic Sociological Association: Special Issue on Social Capital 49(2): 149166.
Van Schaik, T. (2002) Social Capital in the European Value Study Surveys. Country paper
prepared for the OECD-ONS international conference on Social Capital Measurement, London, 2527 September 2002. Tilburg: Tilburg University.
Ville, S. (2004) Social Capital: An Insight Revealed Or A Concept Too Many? Economics
Working Papers WP 04/05, School of Economics and Information Systems. Wollongong,
NSW: University of Wollongong.
Welzel, C., Inglehart, R. and Deutsch, F. (2005) Social Capital, Voluntary Associations, and
Collective Action: Which Aspects of Social Capital Have the Greatest Civic Payo? Journal
of Civil Society 1(2): 126.
Wilson, L. J. and Chiveralls, K. R. (2004) Labor and Social Capital: Disengaging From Social
Justice. Conference paper. Adelaide: The University of Adelaide. Available at: http://hdl.
handle.net/2440/28930.
Woolcock, M. (1998) Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework. Theory and Society 27(2): 151208.
(2001) The Place of Social Capital in Understanding Social and Economic Outcomes.
Canadian Journal of Policy Research 2(1): 117.
510
H. Bhandari, K. Yasunobu /
Asian Journal of Social Science 37 (2009) 480510
Woolcock, M. and Narayan, D. (2000) Social Capital: Implications for Development Theory,
Research, and Policy. The World Bank Research Observer 15(2): 225249.
World Bank (2007) Social Capital for Development. Available at: http://www1.worldbank.
org/prem/poverty/scapital/.
Yang, K. (2007) Individual Social Capital and Its Measurement in Social Surveys. Survey
Research Methods 1(1): 1927.
Zak, P. J. and Knack, S. (2001) Trust and Growth. The Economic Journal 111: 295321.