The Marketization of English Higher Education and The Financing of Tuition Fees

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 9

London Review of Education

Volume 14, Number 1, April 2016

DOI: 10.18546/LRE.14.1.06

The marketization of English higher education and the


financing of tuition fees
David Palfreyman and Ted Tapper*
Oxford Centre for Higher Education Policy Studies (OxCHEPS)
This article explores the marketization of English higher education with particular reference
to the introduction of undergraduate student tuition fees. It argues that the breakdown of
the political consensus that underwrote the public funding of undergraduate student funding
was the consequence of ideological and economic changes that, following the threat of some
universities to impose top-up fees, resulted in the appointment of the Dearing Committee
and thereafter the steady introduction of variable fees up to a ceiling of 9,000 per annum,
repayable through income-contingent loans. It reviews the contemporary breaking of the
political consensus on this issue, as evidenced by the Labour Partys promise in the 2015
general election campaign to lower the maximum annual fee to 6,000, with the further
possibility of replacing income-contingent loans with a graduate tax. It concludes by putting
forward the policy options that are likely to emerge in the context of the publication of the
current governments Green Paper on higher education.
Keywords: public funding; student loans; market; ideological change; economic pressure;
graduate tax

Introduction
The increasing marketization of English higher education can be analysed with respect to a
number of dimensions, but at its heart the payment of tuition fees by home-based undergraduates
looms large (so bringing English higher education closer to both the long-established US model
and the recently reformed Australian system). It is the introduction of variable tuition fees that is
widely seen as the vital step in the marketization of English higher education (Farrell and Tapper,
1992; Brown and Carasso, 2013; McGettigan, 2013; Palfreyman and Tapper, 2014). While the
interpretations of the wider marketization of higher education are best described as ambivalent,
the imposition of variable tuition fees has been widely condemned and the issue is still far from
resolved note the decision of the Labour Party to include in its 2015 general election manifesto
a promise to reduce the current fee ceiling of 9,000 per annum to 6,000 (coupled with the
possibility that had it formed the next government, it would have sought to replace funding via
income-contingent loans with a graduate tax). This article is an opinion/discussion piece written
in part to point out the pitfalls of such a move (now very remote for the next five years), and to
argue for the continuation, albeit with some accompanying reforms, of student tuition fees repaid
through a scheme of income-contingent loans.

* Corresponding author email: kmtapper@aol.com


Copyright 2016 Palfreyman and Tapper.This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the
Creative Commons Attribution Licence, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction
in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

48 David Palfreyman and Ted Tapper


The coming of variable fees: The interaction of ideological and economic
variables
For much of the history of the English universities, higher education policy has been driven by a
combination of ideological and economic pressures. Throughout most of the twentieth century,
education was perceived as a positive social good, the expansion of which also allegedly enhanced
the progress of the economy. However, much of the political support for such claims focused upon
the state provision of free primary and secondary schooling, reaching its zenith in the passage
of the 1944 Education Act. For higher education the political focus was truncated the need to
augment the representation of students from working-class families and for a system that would
be open to all talented individuals regardless of their socio-economic circumstances. To this
end, from 1918 onwards a patchwork-quilt pattern of support for prospective undergraduates
was initiated by the local education authorities, which started to pay tuition fees and provide
maintenance grants, although the costs were reimbursed by the Treasury. However, following the
Anderson Report (Ministry of Education, 1960) the system was centralized and rationalized as
the national government assumed direct responsibility for making these payments.
While it may have been feasible to have imposed upon the Treasury a growing burden of
public expenditure, this became increasingly problematic when the expansion of higher education
considerably increased that burden. It should be noted that even Lord Robbins (1980), who can
be regarded as the ideological architect of that expansion of higher education, came to recognize
that continuing expansion should be funded at least in part out of a student loans scheme rather
than the public purse. In fact so as not to increase unduly the burden of public expenditure,
governments became increasingly parsimonious in their funding of higher education expansion,
and hence (although the overall burden may have continued to rise) expenditure per student
declined sharply (Greenaway and Haynes, 2000).Thus in the 1970s and 1980s universities turned
increasingly to the recruitment of overseas students (for whom they were required to charge
an economic fee) to balance the books. Consequently, the universities themselves were thinking
increasingly of alternative ways of funding tuition costs, while operating a lucrative market in
international students an experience they could draw upon when it came to charging fees from
the home student market.
These pragmatic economic considerations were steadily reinforced by the growing
ideological consensus that the pursuit of higher education enhanced what was essentially a
private rather than a public good, and thus it should be paid for by the individual recipient
rather than from the public purse. Not surprisingly, such claims gained increasing strength in
the years of successive Conservative Governments under Margaret Thatcher, although ironically,
thanks to internal party divisions, not one of her governments succeeded in bringing a student
loans scheme to fruition (Farrell and Tapper, 1992: 27484). But the soil had been thoroughly
tilled politically for the Dearing Report (1997) to lay the grounds for the subsequent Labour
Government, under the auspices of the Secretary of State, David Blunkett, to take the vital
step of introducing a flat-rate income-contingent loans scheme, and subsequently to underwrite
variable fees. There was an initial ceiling of 1,000 per annum. This was raised to 9,000 in the
early years of the Coalition Government, a development supported by the findings of another
official review of higher education, the Browne Review, Securing a Sustainable Future for Higher
Education (Browne, 2010). However, this review did not recommend a fees ceiling. As noted,
there has been much discussion of the fees ceiling being lowered to 6,000 per annum, with the
possibility of income-contingent loans being replaced by a graduate tax to secure the necessary
funding (Gill, 2015: 5). The danger of removing the ceiling on tuition fees is that, without a viable
accompanying policy on student loans, the most expensive universities would possibly be out

London Review of Education 49


of the reach of students from poorer families, which would risk creating a division in higher
education to parallel the one that marks the private secondary sector, with its stratum of a small
number of very expensive schools.
Politics and a possible guiding principle for the financing of tuition fees
In view of the strength of the underlying ideological values and the healthy size of their parliamentary
majorities, it is perhaps surprising that a Thatcher government did not succeed in introducing a
student loans scheme. Already Bahram Bekhradnia, current President of the influential Higher
Education Policy Institute, has reportedly called Labours 6,000 fees announcement terribly
disappointing and a mouse produced for electoral reasons (Morgan, 2015: 5). In an elaboration
of his attack, Bekhradnia is reported to have said: This would have been the perfect opportunity
for Labour to take a principled stand in favour of direct and substantial taxpayer funding of
higher education, balanced by a much-reduced student fee and reduced government subsidy
[for fee loans] (Morgan, 2015: 5). This appears to be a plea for a return to the proposals of the
Anderson Report, which for many within the Labour Party would be the most appropriate way
forward. Thus we face the possibility of internal party machinations parallel to those that the
parliamentary Conservative Party experienced in the 1980s.
Moreover, before attempting to enunciate a key guiding principle, it is important to note that
the context within which a future funding policy will evolve is critically different from that which
prevailed when the current policy unfolded; it will be strongly influenced by the fact that a loans
scheme, in various guises, has now been in operation for over ten years. For all its limitations it
has stood the test of time and now there are many who would argue that it is more important
to focus on the provision of maintenance grants than tuition fees.There is a wealth of established
policy knowledge to draw upon. Firstly, and perhaps most surprisingly, is the relatively limited
impact that the loans schemes have had upon student participation levels. These have recovered
from the reduction that occurred following the imposition of variable fees (especially when they
were raised from a maximum of 3,000 to a maximum of 9,000 per annum). Furthermore, it
now also appears that access from the more socially deprived sector of society has increased
rather than declined, although there is still some way to go before there is anything approaching
parity of access across all social groups. How is this significant change to be accounted for?
It was always likely that there would be a period of time before prospective students
absorbed the shock of the change in policy direction. Moreover, in a period of economic recession
for many, it may make more sense to continue in full-time education rather than to look for a
job, especially as a degree is still a necessary resource for accessing professional employment.
Finally, and most critically, under the auspices of the Office for Fair Access (OFFA) it was
expected that the universities would use some (25 to 35 per cent) of their fee income (between
6,000 and the amount charged) to promote wider access. Consequently, the universities
started to compete with one another to offer fee reductions and/or bursaries to applicants
from economically poorer families. It meant that all students, or their well-to-do parents, were
providing the resources to secure the fee reductions or bursaries for some, an arrangement
that was administered by the universities, with OFFA approving the terms in the form of access
agreements. It may sound like a very byzantine set of arrangements, but it appears to have had
the desired effect of balancing somewhat the social intake of student access to higher education.
It is almost as if we have returned to the nineteenth century, when access to higher education
by students from poorer families was invariably dependent upon financial support provided by
the university, albeit with either endowment income or those students who paid full-cost fees

50 David Palfreyman and Ted Tapper


providing the financial resources. Moreover, there is a clear recognition that the terms governing
the repayment of loans are relatively generous: no repayment until income reaches 21,000 per
annum, suspension of repayment if income falls below that level, and cancellation of the debt 30
years after repayment commences. The inevitable consequence is that an increasing proportion
of the total debt will never be repaid, leaving the Treasury to meet the shortfall.The consequence
is that the payment of tuition fees remains a considerable burden upon public expenditure, which
should be welcomed by those who believe that higher education is a public good and thus its
costs should be underwritten by the public purse (although the inclination is to acknowledge the
irony of the situation rather than to welcome it).
The second contextual change is that, although there may be a broad acceptance that
higher education is a public good, this has much to do with its enhancement of knowledge and
promotion of high-status culture, and it does not mean that it is not also a private good and that
students as its beneficiaries should not meet at least some of its costs. Certainly, as seen in the
policy stance of Universities UK (UUK) there is considerable support for this view within the
universities (see the response of its Student Funding Panel to the new IFS report on student
funding Universities UK, 2015). Moreover, the current funding via income-contingent loans
with a high ceiling level gives considerable control to the universities to plan their financial
futures while distancing the prospect of bureaucratic state direction of their admissions policies.
Of course, there is some nostalgia in looking back to the immediate post-Anderson years, before
the post-Robbins expansion took off, and in imagining that the state will in future continuously
fund higher education generously on an agreed quinquennial basis. But political reality suggests
that this is not an area of public policy likely to be sheltered permanently because the demands
of other policy imperatives (for example, health care for the expanding elderly population)
have increasingly significant political appeal (for example, consider the 2015 general election
manifestos of all the major parties, in which concern for the funding of the National Health
Service takes precedence over every other policy). The ideological framework, within which
policy is partly shaped, has shifted in a direction that makes the demand for at least a partial
payment of fees by the student more acceptable. Moreover, it is important to point out that the
shift to funding teaching through student fees gives universities more control over their own
development. The universities are now functioning in the context of a state-regulated market
(Palfreyman and Tapper, 2014), for we have moved away from a centrally planned system of
higher education in which development was highly dependent upon the funding bodies first the
University Grants Committee and subsequently the funding councils.
The Labour Partys decision to commit itself to lowering the tuition fees ceiling from 9,000
to 6,000 per annum may be interpreted as simply an unsuccessful electoral manoeuvre to
enhance its prospects of securing more parliamentary seats. However, it has also added new
dimensions to the argument: firstly, that policy analysis does not inevitably have to be based on
the premise that tuition fees will automatically increase; secondly, that there is still a debate to be
had about the political relevance of higher education issues; and thirdly, that the future direction
of tuition fees policy still remains contentious.
The policy alternatives
In analysing these alternatives we have been guided by the principles implicit in the previous
section of this article that the universities should control their own fee levels, which rules
out the lowering of the maximum fee from 9,000 to 6,000 per annum, and that a graduate
tax should replace income-contingent loans. Either of these moves would leave the funding

London Review of Education 51


of higher education to the vagaries of public expenditure and vulnerable to the shortfalls in
funding that occurred in the 1970s and 1980s. Such moves could also give the state potential
control over the admissions process, perhaps even impacting upon the academic profile of the
university by choosing to fund only those students who select to study certain academic options,
as was suggested by both Plaid Cymru and UKIP in their 2015 election manifestos. There are
also possible academic ramifications in replacing income-contingent loans with a graduate tax,
although the costs (and assumed benefits) are mainly political and have to be borne by the
government that enacts the pertinent legislation. Already we have an increase in applications to
overseas universities in response to the imposition of high fees and this could be intensified if
those who have graduated from an English university have to pay a graduate tax throughout their
working lives to finance future tuition fees. Also as an earmarked tax this would run into strong
opposition from the Treasury, which has always opposed such hypothecated taxation. When
variable tuition fees were first introduced there was considerable support (led in particular by
the LSE economist Nicholas Barr see Barr and Crawford, 2005: 10119) for the idea that they
should be underwritten by a government-financed scheme of income-contingent loans, which
was strongly favoured over proposals for a graduate tax: so why should an incoming government
go over the same territory again?
If there is no possibility that in the age of costly mass higher education we are ever likely
to see a return to the full and continuous public funding of higher education tuition fees (as
occurred when only around 15 per cent of the 1821 cohort were in higher education), and
given that financing through a graduate tax is likely to embroil any government in a protracted
period of political turmoil while threatening universities with a loss of control over how they
conduct their affairs, then the only reform package that seems to make sense is to change the
prevailing model of income-contingent loans. The overall purpose of the reform would be: (1) to
enable universities to exercise maximum control over their tuition fees policy; (2) to control the
burden that the scheme imposes upon public expenditure; and (3) to provide students with more
choice in the selection of their degree programmes and greater protection from lax university
standards once they have commenced a course. At the moment the one real constraint on the
level of fees that higher education institutions can impose for UK/EU undergraduates is the
ceiling of 9,000 per annum. As recommended by the Browne Review this should be removed,
and universities empowered to set their own fee levels.This would undoubtedly result in a wider
variation of fee levels, and help to keep higher education out of the political limelight by making
fee increases an institutional rather than a government responsibility. The financial obligations
incurred by the state through the current income-contingent loans scheme could be mitigated
in two different ways. Firstly, by tightening up the conditions of repayment: setting repayment
at a steeper rate, with positive incentives offered for early repayment, and repayment extended
over a longer period of time if necessary. Secondly, the Student Loans Company could limit the
amount that could be borrowed by each student, perhaps to 6,000 per annum.The hope would
be that such a move, combined with placing responsibility for fee increases upon the universities,
would persuade universities to moderate their fee levels. The universities themselves could be
responsible for finding the necessary resources to bridge the funding gap (between 6,000 and
the fee). This would entail the universities making deals with financial institutions, which should
prove to be relatively straightforward for universities that could demonstrate that their students
invariably graduated and found financially rewarding jobs. Where this was not possible, perhaps
the university should consider whether it should offer such a course, or whether it should
lower its fee level. Universities should also be required to provide more information on how
they determine their fee levels and should be more open to providing redress to students when

52 David Palfreyman and Ted Tapper


they feel they have not been given the standard of education that they felt they were purchasing.
Universities should also be required to demonstrate their academic credibility and not simply
assert their control of the curriculum as their defence. The change strategy is to increase both
the power of the state and the power of the student market to create a state-regulated
market that is increasingly attuned to providing high-quality higher education in the context of a
university system that is increasingly differentiated internally with respect to the goals it pursues.
What is required is a competitive market, and to help establish that market the state not only
needs to regulate the way in which higher education providers make their services available, but
also must ensure that there is a steady increase in the number of universities offering high-quality
degree programmes, with regulation ensured by a combination of inspections by the Quality
Assurance Agency (QAA) and the publicizing of the findings of the National Student Surveys
(NSS), along with the creation of a new regulator an Office for Higher Education or Office for
Tertiary Education. And, as the state retreats from directly financing a students higher education,
it has to take on a greater burden of ensuring consumer protection for the student-customer
paying high fees.
So action is pursued on three fronts: (1) to introduce technical changes to the current
student loans scheme that will lessen its dependence upon the public purse (even possibly
making the universities assume the responsibility for raising financial support for at least part of
the costs of tuition fees); (2) to require the universities to assume greater responsibility for the
academic quality of the programmes they offer; and (3) to permit, through a regulated process
of access, more institutional providers to enter the market in order to increase institutional
competition and student choice. Although we are not going to return to a system of higher
education in which student access is overwhelmingly publicly financed, we can construct a model
in which there is a more equitable sharing of the costs of tuition and in which students can be
better assured that they receive quality higher education (while the universities retain more
control over their own affairs).
Post-2015 general election prognosis
Following the election of the Conservative Government at the 2015 general election, various
developments can be foreseen. The ceiling on fees may be removed and the higher education
institutions left to set their own fee levels, including potentially raising them above the current
ceiling of 9,000 per annum. There will be a tightening of the terms of loan repayments a
higher rate of repayment and an extension of the length of time during which repayment can be
claimed, combined with discounts for those who pay early. There will be no early move towards
curtailing the amount that the state is prepared to offer to support the payment of tuition fees,
but this will be set down as a medium-term policy objective, and universities will have to start
preparations for raising funding to enable their students to pay their tuition fees.The institutions
will offer more bursaries and fee reductions to students, which may be directed specifically at
students opting to study particular (perhaps undersubscribed) courses or who are deemed
to be potential high-flyers. Over time more providers will enter the higher education market,
and in this respect note the growth of massive open online courses (MOOCs), which may
offer productivity gains at lower cost to the student. Such providers may not be universities as
such, but institutions offering professional and/or trade courses, while some existing universities
will be increasingly devoted to the pursuit of research and will become more like specialized
research institutes than universities. There will be the creation of a student loans scheme for

London Review of Education 53


graduates to address the decline in state funding on this front. England will move steadily towards
a mass, highly differentiated model of higher education, of which the university as we have known
it will be a declining part.
Accompanying these policy changes, there should also be a significant shift in the direction
of academic debate. The focus on state funding and/or marketization should draw to a graceful
close. It should be followed by a phase in which there is thorough examination of how institutions
adjust to securing funding in a world where there is a parsimonious state and demanding market
conditions. How do higher education institutions respond to this context? How do managers
behave? Can costs be controlled, or even reduced, allowing greater price competition? How is the
role of the academic affected? How much institutional and system cohesion is likely to prevail?
What does this mean for the traditional role of the university, supposedly dedicated to enhancing
scholarship and expanding research while increasingly structured to provide differential forms of
professional and technical training?
Notes on the contributors
David Palfreyman isthe Bursar and a Fellow of New College, University of Oxford. He is also the Director
of the Oxford Centre for Higher Education Policy Studies (oxcheps.new.ox.ac.uk). His latest book (with Ted
Tapper) is Reshaping the University:The rise of the regulated market in higher education (Oxford University Press,
2014). David is the Honorary Treasurer and a Trustee of the Society for Research into Higher Education
(SRHE), and was a Trustee of theHarpurTrust (also known as the Bedford Charity) for twenty years.
Ted Tapper has spent nearly all his academic career at the University of Sussex (19682003). His research
has developed in two broad fields: the politics of secondary schooling, with a focus on the increasing
authority of the central state; and the politics of higher education, encompassing a reasonably large body
of work on the governance of higher education and the politics of policymaking. More recently, he has
examined the role of ideas in the process of change in higher education.

References
Barr, N., and Crawford, I. (2005) Financing Higher Education: Answers from the UK. Abingdon: Routledge.
Brown, R., and Carasso, H. (2013) Everything for Sale? The marketisation of UK higher education. Abingdon:
Society for Research into Higher Education and Routledge.
Browne, J. (2010) Securing a Sustainable Future for Higher Education: An independent review of higher education
funding and student finance. London: Department for Business, Innovation and Skills.
Farrell, S., and Tapper, E. (1992) Student loans: The failure to consolidate an emerging political consensus.
Higher Education Quarterly, 46 (3), 26985.
Gill, J. (2015) From the cradle to the ballot. Times Higher Education, 5 March. Online. www.
timeshighereducation.com/comment/leader/from-the-cradle-to-the-ballot/2018895.article (accessed
10 January 2016).
Greenaway, D., and Haynes, M. (2000) Funding Universities to meet National and International Challenges.
London: The Russell Group.
McGettigan, A. (2013) The Great University Gamble: Money, markets and the future of higher education. London:
Pluto Press.
Ministry of Education (1960) Grants to Students (Anderson Report). London: HMSO.
Morgan, J. (2015) Access would get a reboot under Labour, says Byrne. Times Higher Education, 5
March. Online. www.timeshighereducation.com/news/access-would-get-a-reboot-under-labour-saysbyrne/2018897.article (accessed 10 January 2016).
National Committee of Inquiry into Higher Education (1997) Higher Education in the Learning Society (Dearing
Report). Norwich: HMSO.

54  David Palfreyman and Ted Tapper


Palfreyman,D.,andTapper,T.(2014)Reshaping the University:The rise of the regulated market in higher education.
Oxford:OxfordUniversityPress.
Robbins,L.(1980)Higher Education Revisited.London:Macmillan.
UniversitiesUK(2015)ResponsetonewIFSreportonstudentfunding.London:UniversitiesUK.


Related articles in London Review of Education
In the same issue
ThispaperwaspublishedinaspecialissueentitledHighereducationpolicy-makinginaneraof
increasingmarketization,editedbyOuraniaFilippakou.Theotherarticlesinthatissueareas
follows(linksunavailableattimeofpublication):
Ainley,P.(2016)TheBusinessStudiesUniversity:Turninghighereducationintofurthereducation.London
Review of Education,14(1).
Caruana,V. (2016)Researching the transnational higher education policy landscape: Exploring network
poweranddissensusinaglobalizingsystem. London Review of Education,14(1).
Dennis,C.A.(2016)Furthereducationcollegesandleadership:Checkingtheethicalpulse.London Review
of Education,14(1).
Filippakou,O.,andTapper,T.(2016)Policy-makingandthepoliticsofchangeinhighereducation:Thenew
1960suniversitiesintheUK,thenandnow.London Review of Education,14(1).
Marginson, S. (2016)Foreword:The partial shift from public to private goods in UK higher education.
London Review of Education,14(1).
Montgomery, C. (2016) Transnational partnerships in higher education in China: The diversity and
complexityofelitestrategicalliances. London Review of Education,14(1).
Parry,G.(2016)CollegehighereducationinEngland19441966and19972010.London Review of Education,
14(1).
Salter, B., Filippakou, O., andTapper,T. (2016) Expanding the English medical schools:The politics of
knowledgecontrol.London Review of Education,14(1).
Temple,P.,Callender,C.,Grove,L.,andKersh,N.(2016)ManagingthestudentexperienceinEnglishhigher
education:Differingresponsestomarketpressures.London Review of Education,14(1).
Temple,P.,andcolleagues(2016)DavidWatson19492015:Alifeinhighereducation. London Review of
Education,14(1).
Williams,G.(2016)Highereducation:Publicgoodorprivatecommodity?London Review of Education,14(1).

Elsewhere in the journal


Ainley, P. (2015)Reversal reversed?The new consensus on education and training. London Review of
Education,13(2),17985.
Carasso,H.,andGunn,A.(2015)Fees,fairnessandtheNationalScholarshipProgramme:Highereducation
policyinEnglandandtheCoalitionGovernment.London Review of Education,13(2),7083.
Carpentier,V.(2008)Theeconomicanalysisofuniversities:Strategicgroupsandpositioning. London Review
of Education, 6(3),29394.
Clark,P.(2012)Arenationalhighereducationpoliciesadequateforthenextdecade?.London Review of
Education,10(3), 24760.

London Review of Education 55


Gibbs, P. (2009) Adopting consumer time: Potential issues for higher education. London Review of Education,
7 (2), 11324.
Gunning, D., and Raffe, D. (2011) 1419 education across Great Britain convergence or divergence?.
London Review of Education, 9 (2), 24557.
Kennedy, K.J., Chan, J.K-S., and Fok, P.K. (2011) Holding policy-makers to account: exploring soft and hard
policy and the implications for curriculum reform. London Review of Education, 9 (1), 4154.
Shattock, M. (2010) The entrepreneurial university: An idea for its time. London Review of Education, 8 (3),
26371.
Temple, P. (2015) What has the Coalition Government done for higher education?. London Review of
Education, 13 (2), 1748.

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy