Fforde Economic Strategy
Fforde Economic Strategy
Fforde Economic Strategy
Published by
GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies, Institute of Asian Studies and
Hamburg University Press.
The Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs is an Open Access publication.
It may be read, copied and distributed free of charge according to the conditions of the
Creative Commons Attribution-No Derivative Works 3.0 License.
To subscribe to the print edition: <ias@giga-hamburg.de>
For an e-mail alert please register at: <www.CurrentSoutheastAsianAffairs.org>
The Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs is part of the GIGA Journal Family, which
also includes Africa Spectrum, Journal of Current Chinese Affairs and Journal of Politics
in Latin America: <www.giga-journal-family.org>.
Keywords: Vietnam, economic growth, politics, political economy, industrialisation, development policy
Prof. Adam Fforde is a professorial fellow at Victoria Institute of Strategic Economic Studies, Victoria University, Melbourne, Australia. He
was a full-time teaching member of staff at the SEA Program NUS in
20002001 and has supervised in a range of areas. Prof. Fforde is a
member of the Editorial Board of JCSAA. Personal website: <www.vu.
edu.au/contact-us/adam-fforde>
E-mail: <adam@aduki.com.au>
Adam Fforde
Introduction
Between its VIIth and XIIth Party Congresses (1991 and 2016), Vietnam
clearly experienced some major changes. Whether the country really
changed is the stuff of poetry and a familiar part of the discussions of
any political community about what has happened and so what might
happen. A core part of this, again in a quite familiar way, are arguments
about causality to what or whom can authorship of these changes be
ascribed and which arguments are deemed good and which are not.
This paper1 engages with such deliberations by contrasting an examination of some empirics with how the Communist Party of Vietnam (CPV)
has publicly characterised change, and its role within change as a central
author. The former uses the standard measures of economic growth, as
presented in the National Income Accounts, based on standard methods
that were introduced in the early 1990s as Soviet methods of measuring
levels of economic activity were discarded. The latter uses two core slogans: industrialisation and modernisation, or IM (Cng nghip ha - hin
i ha); and a socialist-oriented market economy, or SOME (Kinh t th
trng nh h ng x h
i ch ngha). I tend to agree with Gainsboroughs
seminal 2007 article, which argued that, by that time, CPV politics had
little to do with policy because discussions posed in those terms were the
clothes of factional rivalries. 2 However, this is an academic study and
whilst Pew surveys suggests that the Vietnamese people greatly like their
market economy, this tells us rather little about what they think has
caused change over the past generation.3 Given the lack of political reform, it is difficult to solve this issue in any effective or efficient way, as
disempowered populations cannot easily show what they really want. My
2
3
This paper draws upon a paper given at the Vietnam Forum 2016, entitled
Vietnam: Thirty Years Of Doi Moi And Beyond, held April 2016 at the
ISEAS-Yusof Ishak Institute, Republic of Singapore, as well as presentations
and discussions subsequently in May 2016 in Hanoi. I am grateful to everyone
who commented on the paper, and to an anonymous referee.
[] politicians in Vietnam generally do not distinguish themselves from each
other on policy lines, although struggles for control over resources are sometimes dressed up in policy terms (Gainsborough 2007: 20).
Goertzel reports, based upon the Pew Global Attitudes Project, that: Brazilians are divided in their opinions about the market economy, with 56% in the
Pew survey agreeing that most people are better off in a free market economy,
even though some people are rich and some are poor. Only 26.7% of the Argentines shared this sentiment in the midst of their economic crisis, as compared to 72.1% in the United States and a remarkable 95.4% in Vietnam, 43.6%
in India, 54.2% in Bolivia and 62.8% in Venezuela (Goertzel 2006: 45).
I have not surveyed the existing literature on the Vietnamese economy, partly
due to space limitations, partly because citations can be made to my own work,
and also because much of the literature exhibits strong belief in industrialisation
as an essential driver of growth, a view that the present paper challenges. Clearly, a literature survey is needed, and if this papers core observation is taken seriously, we also need more research on Vietnams economic growth since the
early 1990s. However, we may also be facing a paradigm shift, and experience
suggests that in such limbic states arguments often arise to ignore, in some way,
what appear as anomalies (Fforde 2016a) reports that there is evidence that this
may be occurring. Fforde (2005) reported an analogous rejection, by perhaps
three-quarters of the citations of it, of the conclusions from the application of
robustness- testing techniques that concluded that there are almost no robust
relationships between policy settings and growth performance globally. Similar
trends can likely be found in arguments that, in Vietnam, manufacturing exports have been important; these arguments ignore the lack of rapid growth in
value-added in such sectors, implying that they rely heavily upon imports of
materials that are then inputs to the factories. Fforde (2016c) discusses the issue of confirmation bias in empirical research.
Adam Fforde
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
1990
Source:
1996
2002
Years
2008
2014
This underpins a historical division of the period that I chose for analytical and expository purposes (another periodisation may offer better alternatives).
The question that then arises which is the focus of the present paper
is whether the foundational elements of development strategy, as expressed in IM and SOME, make sense.
Tables 1 and 2 show changes in the recorded pattern of employment, which is measured, as the NIA does, in terms of employment that
generates incomes for the three factors of production: land, labour and
capital.
Adam Fforde
Sector
Industry
Construction
Agriculture and forestry
Transport and communications
Trade and supply
Other material production
Housing, public services and
tourism
Science, education and culture
Health, social insurance and sport
Finance, etc.
State management
Other non-material
TOTAL
A. Numbers
3,394
820
22,483
526
1,719
30
B. %
11.0
2.6
72.6
1.7
5.5
0.1
296
1.0
899
310
118
240
139
30,974
2.9
1.0
0.4
0.8
0.4
100.0
Note:
Source:
GSO 1993.
5
6
In this paper, by services I mean tertiary sectors neither industry and mining, nor agriculture forestry and fisheries.
It appears that the Vietnamese GSO did not manage to sort out its employment data measured on the new basis until the end of the 1990s, later than the
production of NIA.
2000
Numbers
2014
Numbers
Change
Numbers
24,481
65.1
24,409
46.3
-72
256
3,550
0.7
9.4
253
7,415
0.5
14.1
-3
+3,865
83
0.2
248
0.5
+165
1,040
3,897
2.8
10.4
3,313
6,652
6.3
12.3
+2,273
+2,728
685
1.8
2,301
4.4
+2,755
1,174
3.1
1,953
3.5
+779
75
0.2
352
0.7
+277
19
0.05
251
0.5
+232
64
0.2
158
0.3
+124
376
1.0
n/i
n/i
262
0.5
995
226
2.7
0.6
1,860
493
3.5
0.9
+865
+267
132
0.4
286
0.5
+154
64
0.2
n/i
n/i
493
n/i
37,610
1.3
1,697
3.2
175
0.3
764
52,745
1.4
-318
+15,135
Note:
n/i = not included. (*) includes air conditioning. (**) In 2000, called Hotels
and restaurants; in 2014, the category is Accommodation and food service
activities. (***) In 2014, I have combined Transportation and Storage with Information and communication. (#) For 2014 I have given the entry for Professional, scientific and technical activities. (##) I am not sure how this data is
created. I thank an anonymous reviewer for arguing that many small private
household businesses in Vietnam may be involved in manufacturing; however,
like other arguments (such as those that seek to argue from rapid growth in
manufactures exports to rapid growth in manufactures value-added ignoring
the sectoral GDP data that suggests rapid growth of imports of inputs), this
appears as anomaly-attacking and an attempt to defend existing doctrine in
familiar ways. Table 3 clearly shows how developing countries have, on average, not been industrialising.
Source:
GSO 2008: Tables 17 and 18 and GSO 2015: Tables 53 and 54.
10
Adam Fforde
mining only generated about 3.9 million jobs. How is meaning given to
such data?
Indeed, the Vietnamese for services dich vu may be glossed as those activities that enable or embody transactions (thus giao dich transactions generally, mau
dich trade transactions, phien dich translations). I find the semantics confusing. Comments on this would be welcome, not least because equivalent Chinese terminology appears to be different and stresses the subordinate nature of
services, seeming to prefer the term that in Vietnamese appears as phuc vu. All
of these Vietnamese words are of Chinese origin.
11
Adam Fforde
12
25%
+2.1%
+0.6%
48%
+6.5%
+1.4%
15%
+7.5%
-0.7%
10%
+10.8%
+0.1%
+6.2%
+0.5%
Note:
Source:
For Vietnam, the service GDP share rose from 38 per cent in 1992 to 43
per cent in 2013. In addition, whilst the share of the broad category
industry over the same period rose from 23 per cent to 29 per cent, this
growth was largely due to increased mining output. In 2013 mining
included in the industry statistical definition was 12 per cent of GDP
yet below 5 per cent in the early 1990s; this means that the non-mining
industry share of GDP fell from around 18 per cent in the early 1990s
to around 17 per cent in 2013 (GSO 1993: Table 18 and GSO 2014:
Tables 66 and 68). If one cares not to believe this data then the point to
bear in mind is that it is the public face of quantified economic change.
If someone makes a speech implying that successful industrialisation
was the core, central driver of change, then that person must either argue
that the fall in agricultures share and the rise of services share were
dependent upon industry, likely avoiding the issue that industry only
grows as a share of GDP if you include mining, or find some other way
to argue the point.
Table 4 shows data on added value (sum of wages, profits and rents)
provided by the GSO for the same classification.8 Further analysis is ongoing, but if we think of this as a snap-shot of a disequilibrium, with
factors of production guided by market and other signals, then this does
not suggest that manufacturing is a low point into which resources will
flood. Rather, it is rather similar to sectors such as trade and minor repairs, construction and hotels, in which large employment gains are
8
I have not yet attempted to match the value-added data with data on average
wages in these various sectors.
13
occurring and where the amount of value added per capita is well above
that of agriculture. The significant low points (leaving aside mining) are
electricity, gas and water (which includes air conditioning), financial
intermediation and real estate. Note that the mass public services (education and health) are poor, but keeping up, and that as labour pours out
of farming per capita, value-added there has kept up quite well to the
national average.
Table 4. Value-Added (Productivity) of Employed Work Force, 2000 and
2014 (prelim) (in million VND ng per person)
Sector
Agriculture, forestry and
fishing
Mining
Manufacturing
Electricity, gas and water (*)
Construction
Trade and minor repairs
Hotels and restaurants (**)
Transport, storage and
communications (***)
Financial intermediation
Science and technology (#)
Real estate, etc.
Public administration and
defence (2000)
Administration and support
services (2014)
Education and training
Health and social work
Recreation, culture and sport
Party, mass organisations
and associations (2000)
Party, mass organisations,
defence and security
Community, social and
private household (##)
Other service activities
TOTAL (whole economy)
2000
VND
2014
VND
Change
A. Ratio
B. Rank
4.4
28.6
x 6.5
166.6
23.1
169.2
22.7
16.1
20.9
1,683.3
70.0
652.2
60.7
58.3
64.2
x 10.1
x 3.0
x 3.8
x 2.7
x 3.6
x 3.1
1
10
6
11
7
9
14.8
75.2
x 5.1
3=
108.4
124.7
300.0
352.1
204.2
1,278.6
x 3.3
x 1.6
x 4.3
8
12
4=
32.1
n/i
n/i
262.1
14.9
26.6
19.4
64.9
134.4
80.7
x 4.3
x 5.1
x 4.2
4=
3=
5
9.6
n/i
n/i
62.5
21.9
32.9
x 1.5
13
n/i
11.7
85.6
74.7
x 6.4
Note:
n/i = not included. (*) includes air conditioning. (**) In 2000, called Hotels
and restaurants; in 2014, category is Accommodation and food service activities. (***) In 2014, I have combined Transportation and storage with Information and communication. (#) For 2014 I have given the entry for Professional, scientific and technical activities. (##) I am not sure how this data was
created.
Source:
GSO 2008: Tables 17 and 23 and GSO 2015: Tables 53, 54 and 62.
14
Adam Fforde
It is striking that the industrialisation story has had a long life. World
Bank teaching texts that are currently valid (that is, on their website),
such as World Bank and Soubbbotina (2000), argue that:
Everything that grows also changes its structure. Just as a growing
tree constantly changes the shape, size, and configuration of its
branches, a growing economy changes the proportions and interrelations among its basic sectorsagriculture, industry, and services and between other sectorsrural and urban, public and private, domestic- and export-oriented. [] Are there common patterns in how growing economies change?
As income per capita rises, agriculture loses its primacy, giving
way first to a rise in the industrial sector, then to a rise in the service sector. These two consecutive shifts are called industrialization and postindustrialization (or deindustrialization). All growing
economies are likely to go through these stages. (5051; emphasis added)
15
Explanatory Narratives
The economic history of Vietnam since the growth acceleration of the
early 1990s is still to be written. A key issue is the role of policy, as a
number of economic studies have argued that, despite heavy rhetoric
from the CPV asserting the importance of their policy choices, the pattern of change in the Vietnamese economy appears relatively uninfluenced by policy. Pham et al. (2008) concluded:
The result from three national IO tables [give] strong support for
the evolutionary movement of Vietnamese economy, or in our
terminology, a bottom-up process, in which Doi Moi is a critical
point [sic] marks the shift of Vietnamese economy from planned
economy to marker oriented one. Hence, we could say integration
in to [sic] the international market is inevitable and domestic final
demand, through its impact of [sic] consumption, investment and
export, play a vital role not only in the wealth of [sic] nation (gross
output) but also in improvement of welfare (GDP). (Pham et al.
2008: 33; Emphasis as in original)
Giesecke and Tran (2008) studied the period from 1996 to 2003 and
concluded:
In our story, we find rapid growth in GDP to be due to productivity and labour force growth. [] Our results downplay policy
reforms (such as the introduction of the VAT and reductions in
trade taxes) as important explicators of rapid growth in trade and
GDP. (Giesecke and Tran 2008: 2627; emphasis added)
Political scientists looking at the value to businesses of political connections have reached similar conclusions:10
10
16
Adam Fforde
These issues require that policy matters; that, contrary to Gainsboroughs analysis, national sovereignty be deployed into the devising and
implementation of policy. Gainsborough remarked that there is always
someone who can potentially stand in your way (2007: 179). If we view
the CPV as a ruling party very much influenced by Soviet thinking, then
it was made quite clear in the USSR during the political reconstruction
after the death of Stalin, as it was before, that national sovereignty lies
with the Party. If there are severe problems with making policy matter,
then, as Hinsley argued, this amounts to a classic instance of a situation
where relations between rulers and ruled will be under pressure to
change. As I have argued elsewhere, the central issue is the Land without a King phenomenon: the Party can rule hegemonically but it cannot
govern, and policy cannot be deployed to the advantage of rulers and
ruled alike (Fforde 2011, 2013). This comes down to a matter of domestic sovereignty, which, as Hinsley (1986) argued some time ago, is better
seen as a political concept rather than one deployed by political scientists:
If we wish to explain why men have thought of power in terms of
sovereignty we have but to explain why they have assumed that
there was a final and absolute authority in their society and why
instead switched, dissipated through various channels. Corrupt state officials
continue to manage organisations that receive state support, SOEs are protected and uncompetitive, public health and education are weak, etc. To make policy matter, political change is needed (as Leung argued).
17
they have not always done so []. (Hinsley 1986: 1, and quoted in
Fforde 2013: 8)
The concept has been formulated when conditions have been
emphasizing the interdependence between the political society and
the more precise phenomenon of its government. It has been the
source of greatest preoccupation and contention when conditions
have been producing rapid changes in the scope of government or
in the nature of society or in both. It has been resisted or reviled
it could not be overlooked when conditions, by producing a
close integration between society and government or else by producing a gap between society and government, have inclined men
to assume that government and community are identical or else to
insist that they ought to be. In a word, the origin and history of
the concept of sovereignty are closely linked with the nature, the
origin and the history of the state. (Hinsley 1986: 2, and quoted in
Fforde 2013: 16)
This raises the question of what can be said usefully about such matters
of preoccupation and contention, when the data suggests that Vietnamese economic change a major part of the countrys development
process is associated with a major contribution from services, and not
that much from manufacturing industry.
18
Adam Fforde
11
The focus of the Banks fundamental interests in lending rather than reform is
shown by the tactical decision, taken in I think 1991, to abandon as its main
counterpart the reformist Central Institute for Economic Management Research (CIEM) in favour of the highly conservative State Planning Commission.
At the time I was working in the Swedish development cooperation programme and key Bank staff were well aware of the politics involved.
19
Also:
Slow industrialization and urbanization cannot attract redundant
work forces. (GoV 2002: 15)
And:
The process of industrialization and urbanization has increased
the inflow of unregistered migrants from rural areas, mainly those
of working age and children. (GoV 2002: 20)
Such thinking committed the Party, and its main donor partners, to a
view of the nature of economic change that did not imply major changes
in sectoral priorities, and thus weakened the Partys ability to maintain
distance from the drivers of change in the 1980s, commercialising
SOEs.13
12
13
20
Adam Fforde
Through the 1990s, some limited research suggested that SOEs experienced a reduction in their autonomy compared with the trends of the
1980s (Fforde 2007). However, this change was not expressing any rational policy strategy because, as we know from some detailed reports to
the National Assembly in the late noughties, regulatory authorities actually knew very little, in terms of reliable data, about SOEs. Without reliable data, and the authority that can require it to be provided, the Partys
position appears, as Gainsborough described it, as a site for political
conflicts over the division of spoils, so that policy and its logic cannot be
deployed to deal with political issues.
A National Assembly Study Team reported end of the noughties
on the state of policy towards SOEs (Study Team 2009). To quote
Fforde (2009):
[] the opinion of the Study Team that the exercise of state sovereignty through the states formal ownership rights over these
businesses is essentially incoherent (the language is relatively
diplomatic):
The division of tasks and responsibilities that realise the
rights and duties of the state as owner, regarding Groups and
General Companies are scattered and divided (phan tan, cat
khuc). This leads to a situation where there is no organisation
that bears principal responsibility for the management of capital and assets at [these units ] and no organ that bears principal responsibility to monitor, analyse and evaluate deeply
and in reality on the meeting of targets and responsibilities of
regarding state ownership that are allocated to Groups and
General Companies. Ministries and People Committees pretty
much do not adequately grasp information on the activities of
these units. The Ministry of Finance carries out state financial
management but only participates indirectly in the management of capital and assets via the reports of the Ministries and
Peoples Committees and of the units themselves (Study
Team 2009: 20).
This supports the idea that, in any common-sense use of the term,
these units, despite being nominally state-owned, holding vast assets and being major contributors to the economy, are out of control. (Fforde 2009: 88)
21
holders) rather than their formal owners (Fforde 2004, 2007, 2014). The
trap for development policy in Vietnam, then, was that the state sector
poses, and posed, two main problems.
First, as such, the state sector was and is not an example of state
property; rather, it is a form of private property, controlled by interests
(not all interests) within the Party/State. As Greenfield wrote many years
ago:
There can be no doubt that the fiscal crisis of the state is important in this respect. But the reform of state sector enterprises
has intensified rather than resolved this crisis. It is characterized
by the private appropriation of public resources on a massive scale,
where the state acts as the instrument of this appropriation. The
dismantling of the bureaucratic centralism and subsidy system
has concentrated power in the hands of incumbent state enterprise managers and the most powerful segments of the party-state
bureaucracy []. (Greenfield 1994: 206)
Greenfield wrote from a hard Left perspective, but his sources are impeccable and dove-tail well with later studies such as Angie Tran (2013).
Leung (2015), quoted above and with a radically different perspective,
agreed. The central issue here is the political and therefore developmental risks associated with a situation in which such elements of the Vietnamese economy are deemed to have a privileged role.
Second, the state sector and industrialisation was in many ways the
child of both Soviet and World Bank development doctrines that, for
quite different reasons, have lost their authority (the former due to the
collapse of the USSR, the latter due to the evident fact that industrialisation is no longer a dominant part of the aggregate picture of economic
change in developing countries). Therefore, under current doctrinal illumination, industrialisation as the development strategy appears anachronistic.
I now turn to the two slogans: IM and SOME.
22
Adam Fforde
Following the same line of research, what is clearly an on-line crib for
examinations replies to the question what is the theory (ly luan) of industrialisation and modernisation? as follows:16
The success of industrialisation and modernisation of the national
economy is the definitive factor in the success of the road to socialism that the Party and our people have chosen. Mainly because
of this, industrialisation and modernisation of the national economy is viewed as the central task of the entire period of transition
to socialism in our country [].
14
15
16
Thus the formal job descriptions of the members of the 2016 Politburo includes, at # 8, inh Th Huynh - Trng ban Tuyn gio Trung ng (Head of
the Central Propaganda and Education Department). Details of its responsibilities can be found online: <http://dangcongsan.vn/tu-lieu-van-kien/cac-bandang-tw/doc-492220153253656.html> (9 March 2016). These include examination and approval (tham dinh) of all projects and documents related to the
Partys position (Chu truong) of Party, Mass Organisations, etc. before they are
submitted to the Politburo [Section 2.2]. The same reference, from the VCP
website, provides the Departments internal structure.
See <www.nhandan.com.vn/giaoduc/dien-dan/item/27199202-cong-nghiep-h
oa-hien-dai-hoa-va-yeu-cau-doi-voi-giao-duc-dai-hoc-hien-nay.html> (9 March
2016).
See <www.wattpad.com/2927500-l%C3%BD-lu%E1%BA%ADn-v%E1%B
B%81-c%C3%B4ng-nghi%E1%BB%87p-h%C3%B3a-hi%E1%BB%87n-%C
4%91%E1%BA%A1i-h%C3%B3a-g%E1%BA%AFn-v%E1%BB%9Bi>
(9
March 2016).
23
Of course, the problem with this is that, taken to its logical conclusion, it
would have to be concluded that the apparent economic success has
been a failure, as industrys share of GDP has (as examined above) fallen
when mining is excluded; therefore, the economic growth processes
cannot fairly be called industrialisation. This is.
Nonetheless, what can be made of the concept of modernisation?
Early uses of the term in official documents seem to reflect a simple idea
17
18
19
Sic. The term derives from Marxs view that one hires out ones labour power,
not oneself, and is related to his view of the nature of commodities.
See <http://dangcongsan.vn/tu-lieu-van-kien/van-kien-dang/nghi-quyet-bchtrung-uong/khoa-vii/doc-2925201510081046.html> (9 March 2016).
That is, to produce Group A industrial goods; see above.
24
Adam Fforde
of matching what is found in developed countries, and the abovementioned Plenum Resolution offers no empirical referent beyond this.
20
That is, those directly under the bloc; they each in turn had their own constituent elements, usually SEs. Taken from <http://doanhnghieptrunguong.vn/>
June 2014 the Main Page of the site is entitled The Party Committee of the
Central Business Bloc (
ng y khi doanh nghi
p trung ng) (Fforde
2013: 3738).
25
It is not yet entirely a socialist-oriented economy. This is because our country is in the period of transition to socialism,
and there is still a mixture of, and a struggle between, the old
and the new, so there simultaneously are, and are not yet
sufficiently, socialist factors [1].
It is reasonably obvious from this that central tensions are those between
(1) the notion that it is market forces that should drive development, (2)
the goal of such development being industrialisation and modernisation,
and (3) the simple fact that after a generation of rapid and general popular use of a market economy and major economic change, the economy
has not industrialised. The evidence from analysis of the state sector suggests that the kernel of the matter is to be found there, and this is reflected in debates.
21
26
Adam Fforde
Conclusions
It is useful to remember that the economic success of Vietnam since the
early 1990s has been a surprise to many. Structural change away from
agriculture but without industrialisation is even more unexpected. Also
unexpected was the transition of the state sector away from the largely
healthy processes of bottom-up commercialisation of the 1980s, which
created the supply capacity that allowed Vietnam to first avoid negative
output shock as Soviet aid was removed and then drive the first stages of
rapid growth in the 1990s.
Accommodation of foreign-invested businesses and an emergent
registered private sector in the noughties, with macroeconomic stability
until around 2007, suggests that the role of the widely unappreciated
Nong Duc Manh (Party general secretary, 20012011) is as contradictory
as that of the also widely unappreciated Le Duan (in office 19601986).
After the fall of Le Kha Phieu in 2001, the next six years under Nong
Duc Manh saw a consolidation of Vietnams service-oriented globalisation, fast growth of employment in manufacturing, and preparation for
transition to middle income status in 2009. Throughout this period the
Party required students and others, if they wanted high marks, to explain
the validity and correctness of SOME and IM, when the reality increasingly showed that poverty was falling quickly, the country was growing
quickly, that industrialisation was not occurring, and it was a misnomer
to call the state sector the state. If we take a step back, this is readily
27
2.
It does not seem to matter what you call the animal, so long as it
catches mice. The Vietnamese economy has been part of considerable progress in the 25 years since a market economy clearly emerged.
It is still not really clear why this happened, not least as services, and
the way in which they fitted into the wider economy has not been
studied to a great degree. Puzzlement never killed anybody. Now
what?
To feed, nurture and therefore catch more mice, perhaps at lower
cost, policy needs to be made to matter and must also to be located
within reasonably convincing narratives about what is happening,
why it matters and what might be done about it. IM does not seem
to be part of such narratives, but SOME does, especially if the old
MarxistLeninist references to relations of production and thus
the rather odd justification for the leading role of the state are
prevented from climbing in, making it harder for the CPV to get its
act together and preserve its regime through policies the population
like, such as reform of public health and public education. That
would appear to be a more clever way of staying in power than going after dissidents and pressuring free trade unions.
Finally, there is a clear need for further research into two areas. The first
is to generate plausible explanations of patterns of change in the Vietnamese economy since the early 1990s.The second is the sociology and
politics of what seem to have been strong and likely misplaced beliefs in
industrialisation, both in reality and normatively. For both, a decent
literature survey is sorely needed.
References
Fforde, Adam (2016a), Yes, But What about Services, (under review).
Fforde, Adam (2016b), Reinventing Development, The Sceptical Change Agent,
London: Palgrave, (forthcoming).
Fforde, Adam (2016c), Confirmation Bias: Methodological Causes and a
Palliative Response, in: Quality and Quantity, July, <DOI:10.1007/
s11135-016-0389-z>.
28
Adam Fforde
29
30
Adam Fforde
Study Team (2009), Bao cao ket qua giam sat Viec thuc hien chinh sach, tai
cac tap doan, tong cong ty nha nuoc (Report on the Study of the Implementation of Policies at Groups and General State Companies), Hanoi: National Assembly.
Tran, Angie Ngoc (2013), Ties That Bind: Cultural Identity, Class, and Law in
Vietnams Labor Resistance, Ithaca: Cornell University SEA Program
Publications.
Viet Ha (2015), Dinh nghia moi ve kinh te thi truong dinh huong
XHXN co gi khac biet? (Any Change in the New Definition of
Market Economy with a Socialist Direction?), in: RFA, 5 March.
WDR see World Bank, and T. S. Soubbbotina
World Bank (1993), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public
Policy, Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank (n.y.), online: <http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NV.I
ND.TOTL.ZS/countries> (24 November 2015).
World Bank, and T. S. Soubbbotina, with Katherine A. Sheram (2000),
Economic Growth Meeting the Challenges of Global Development, WBI
Learning Resources Series, Washington, DC: The World Bank.