MiFID e Version
MiFID e Version
MiFID e Version
0
CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES
CAPITAL MARKETS
KAREL LANNOO
Chief Executive Officer and Senior Research Fellow
CEPS & ECMI
Disclaimer
The views expressed in this report do not necessarily reflect the views and
positions of all members involved in the Task Force. The members do not
necessarily agree with all positions put forward and do not necessarily endorse
any reference to academic and independent studies. A sound and clear set of
principles has guided the drafting process, in order to preserve a neutral approach
to divergent views. All members were given ample opportunity to express their
views and if well-grounded they are reflected in the final text. Wherever
fundamental disagreement arose, the rapporteurs have made sure that all views
have been explained in a clear and fair manner. The content of the report, however,
can be only attributed to the rapporteurs. Data included in the text have been
generally considered as material and relevant.
ISBN 978-94-6138-081-4
Copyright 2011, ECMI and CEPS.
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system
or transmitted in any form or by any means electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording
or otherwise without the prior permission of the Centre for European Policy Studies and the
European Capital Markets Institute.
The Task Force aimed to shed new light on the main aspects of the Markets
in Financial Instruments Directive (MiFID), drawing on the vast practical
experience of the Task Force members, the timely input given by regulators
and the European Commission and the benefit of a substantial body of
academic research and analysis.
It was acknowledged at the outset of the Task Forces work that the
revision of MiFID was to be more than an ordinary assessment conducted a
few years after the introduction of a new directive, and that it was
important to take into account the lessons of the financial crisis in a context
of growing uncertainty about the future of Europe's capital markets. It was
believed that the review represented a significant opportunity to
strengthen the role of the internal market and to regain investors'
confidence, which had been badly damaged by the recent financial crisis.
As noted in the G20 context, MiFID is part of the process of strengthening
the effectiveness of regulation, especially in areas that had previously been
unregulated. Greater transparency, investor protection and market stability
are some of the main steps that will give financial markets sounder, safer
and more resilient foundations.
MiFID is one piece in a broader legislative and regulatory framework
regarding the financial markets and it is important to ensure that the
revised MiFID maintains appropriate coherence with other current and
forthcoming laws and regulations, whose interplay in the implementation
process should preserve legal certainty and a properly harmonised regime
for investment services.
The work of the Task Force and the final report, independently
drafted by the rapporteurs, come at a crucial moment for the MiFID review.
Through the Task Force, the industry has sought to make a contribution
that can play a major role in supporting the work of public authorities to
disentangle the effects of the crisis from the issues raised by separate
market failures or regulatory and supervisory gaps. The report is therefore
an attempt to make a thoughtful qualitative and quantitative analysis of the
|i
ii | PREFACE
major problems at stake and where feasible, to put forward proposals that
take into account market developments and reflect the latest findings in the
academic literature.
The Task Force was composed of market participants from practically
all relevant segments of the securities industry, whose interests and
sensitivities clearly did not always coincide. Therefore a consensus could
not realistically be reached on a number of important issues, but it did
create a unique opportunity for the Task Force to lay out the issues in a fair
and balanced way and to articulate the arguments of the different views of
these industry segments, providing legislators, regulators and supervisors
with a deeper insight into market views and the state-of-art literature. The
issues at stake are often arcane and highly technical, but the way in which
they are tackled by the public authorities in the coming months will have a
major impact not only on the functioning of the financial markets and on
the competitive position of the various players involved in the chain
between investors and issuers, but also, most importantly, on the well-
being of large and small investors and business units in Europe.
This is why the Task Force felt that it was more important to
articulate the issues and the different views that prevail than to purport to
submit elusive and vague consensus positions or high-level conclusions to
which each and all members of the Task Force could agree. The latter
approach would mask the real issues at stake and be an ineffective basis on
which public authorities could make their own policy decisions.
This objective guided the discussions in the five intense meetings
held in the second half of 2010. A key factor of success was going to be that
all segments of the industry would be able to express their views in an
open and constructive way, that the rationale for the various views would
be fully articulated and understood, and that reliable supporting data
would be provided to allow for a neutral and balanced assessment. It is to
the credit of all Task Force members that, notwithstanding the complexity
and sensitivity of the issues, they have successfully met this challenge. And
it is to the credit of the rapporteurs that they have produced a report that
sums up these issues in a lucid and balanced way. While this report will
not make the task of the public authorities seeking to define the future path
of MiFID altogether easy, it should at least allow it to be placed on a
stronger factual and conceptual basis. If one considers the complexity of the
task, this is a worthwhile outcome.
Pierre Francotte
Chairman of the Task Force
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
changes foreseen, this Task Force has chosen to focus on three core areas:
1) Transparency
2) Market structure
3) Provision of investment services
While the review has identified some regulatory gaps, it mainly seeks
to improve the way in which the Directive is implemented and enforced by
national authorities. The European Commission and ESMA should
minimise the risk of adding layers of regulation where failures are the
result of inadequate supervision or enforcement. Clarifying intended
scopes of current regulation may help to create a more harmonised
framework of supervisory practices. Most importantly, the review should
clarify ambiguities in the legal text when the application of the law is
inconsistent.
Investors should benefit from the new MiFID. The revision of the
legal text should aim at solving legal and market divergences across
Europe, and make sure that the benefits of the new competitive
environment are spread along the value chain and passed on to final users,
retail and wholesale investors, as appropriate.
When it comes to assessing the effects of MiFID, it is difficult to
disentangle the impact of regulation from the effects of the recent financial
crisis. Nevertheless, the creation of a harmonised regulatory framework for
the provision of investment services in Europe is a paramount achievement
of the Directive.
MiFID has changed European capital markets in many ways. It has
brought greater competition between trading venues and between
investment firms both on trading costs and execution services. It has also
contributed to substantial investments in technology for trading and
platforms. The growth of dark trading venues, such as MTF (multilateral
trading facility) dark pools and broker-dealer crossing networks (BCNs),
has been another interesting consequence of the new environment. Finally,
the Directive has widened the scope of transparency requirements,
harmonised the framework of business conduct rules and improved the
protection for investors.
Still, there is scope to bring more clarity to some definitions and
further harmonise rules and supervisory practices. In other areas, such as
market quality (price formation) and integrity, the impact of the Directive is
not yet apparent, since evidence remains fairly controversial and
inconclusive.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 3
Transparency
Transparency plays a crucial role in the smooth functioning of financial
markets and the monitoring of systemic risk. It also ensures that the
process of price formation works well, through efficient price discovery
mechanisms. Regulatory action is needed in some respects, however, not
only to take stock of the recent financial crisis but also to assess the
experience gained since the transposition of the Directive.
Transparency is no panacea for market failures, however. Ill-defined
transparency requirements would harm efficiency in less-liquid markets
with no increase of investor protection or reduction of systemic risk.
Conversely, markets could become less-liquid and thus more volatile.
Hence, regulatory intervention should be proportional to the structure of
each market and take into account the dynamics through which orders find
their market-clearing price.
Retail and wholesale markets are intrinsically different due to their
divergent market structures. Yet, the design of transparency requirements
should not only look at the nature of investors, but also at the
characteristics of the market itself. The Commission may need to launch a
public consultation in order to request data that would constitute a
technical basis on which to better distinguish retail and wholesale actors for
each financial instrument.
Equity markets
Pre-trade transparency supports the smooth functioning of venues trading
mechanisms, as well as efficient price discovery and implementation of best
execution policies.
Under certain conditions, pre-trade transparency may impair market
liquidity. Hence, MiFID introduced waivers, which should be retained. A
move towards a more rule-based approach should be balanced with
flexible application and ongoing supervision in order to meet market
needs. However, conflicting views between members emerge when
discussing the breadth of these exemptions.
Turning to post-trade disclosure, the financial crisis called for a
further layer of market transparency. A new regime should include the
disclosure of aggregate data on capital markets to monitor systemic risk
and increase market integrity and efficiency. The extension of trade
reporting to both shares admitted to trading only on MTFs or organised
4 | EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Bond markets
A strong push towards pre-trade public disclosure for non-equity financial
instruments would require a rethink of the current market structure for
less-liquid asset classes, and consequently a shift in the intermediation
towards auction markets and from a mainly institutional demand to a more
retail and small professional one to ensure a constant and sufficient
demand over time. Pre-trade transparency is, therefore, strictly needed in
6 | EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Market structure
Competition among trading venues on execution services and among
investment firms on the provision of other investment services have
generated positive effects, such as lower trading costs. Competition needs,
however, to be fair and based on a level playing field among MiFID official
trading venues. Markets benefit today from the interaction of various
groups of users and platforms.
Being a vital part of the network, competition appears where markets
are contestable, not only from a technological standpoint but also in terms
of fair market practices. This implies the need to lower barriers to entry and
exit for users and platforms (contestability), including sunk costs, as well as
to monitor market practices in a dynamic way.
This report also acknowledges the importance of ensuring a
harmonised approach in the application of MiFID requirements for official
trading venues. Regulated markets and multilateral trading facilities
should be subject to convergent legal obligations and supervisory oversight
across member states. This convergence already exists in some European
countries such as the UK.
On the classification of broker-dealer crossing networks (BCNs), the Task
Force discussed two different views.
On the one side, it is argued that some OTC trading escapes MiFID
rules on pre-trade transparency for trading platforms and systematic
internalisers, and does not provide sufficient post-trade information. It also
alleged that it escapes MTFs rules on access, discretion and surveillance. In
this view, some of the BCNs would perform the same function as RMs and
MTFs, while others may be more akin to systematic internalisers. BCNs
would operate as multilateral trading mechanisms by matching trades as
riskless counterparty. BCNs that do not meet the definition of OTC
trading would rather be classified either as multilateral trading platforms
or systematic internalisers (SIs). Otherwise, pre-trade transparency
obligations would be circumvented to the detriment of price discovery,
investor protection and market integrity.
Conversely, other market participants believe that advanced
brokerage, offered to wholesale counterparties through BCNs, meets the
MiFID definition of OTC trading. They note that trades may fall below the
standard market size only after splitting them to reduce market impact.
These child orders would then be internally matched, but mostly routed
10 | EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
to external trading venues, such as RMs and MTFs. The Directive, in their
view, would actually refer to parent orders, since fiduciary duties and
conduct of business rules apply to them as a whole. Finally, a Broker-dealer
Crossing System (BCS) should not be considered multilateral since the
dealers assume risks when providing best execution and other conduct of
business arrangements, which neutral platforms do not provide.
OTC equity trading plays an important role in financial markets, in
particular when it comes to the best execution of complex institutional
orders. Therefore, the review of MiFID should not ban these trading
activities. The review should rather clarify the criteria that define OTC
trades with proper flexibility, in particular what kinds of trades are subject
to OTC requirements under MiFID (e.g. child or parent orders). In
addition, it should foster the availability of data in order to allow the full
assessment and enforcement of best execution rules. Finally, it should
ensure that price formation processes and market quality are preserved
and, if possible, improved.
The data employed in the run-up to the MiFID review by the
Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR) to ascertain the size
of OTC equity trading are not sufficiently accurate. Analysis based on this
data cannot be considered conclusive and has probably led to an
overestimation of the size of this market. More effort needs to be made to
assess market quality in Europe with accuracy and to clarify the actual size
of OTC equity trading, its origin and its impact on price formation
processes. There is a compelling need to improve the quality of market data
by reducing inconsistencies and increasing granularity through the use of
harmonised flags.
The G20 called for derivatives to be further standardised and traded
on electronic platforms, where appropriate. A greater push towards
standardisation and organised trading should balance the benefits of a
more transparent and orderly setting with the costs incurred by a
potentially lower availability of customised derivatives, which would mean
a greater possibility to leave some risk in the system not properly hedged.
These proposals raise challenges for regulators and market participants
with regard to investor choice, market liquidity and efficiency, and
potential overlaps with the MTF regime. The MiFID review needs to
address them in a way that is proportional and consistent with the
European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR) and other relevant EU
directives.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 11
T
his report deals with the regulatory and economic challenges faced
by European regulators in the process of reviewing the Markets in
Financial Instruments Directive (MiFID). It does not attempt to cover
all issues and details raised by the MiFID review. Rather, it focuses on three
fundamental areas of the regulation of financial markets and instruments:
1) transparency, 2) market structure and 3) provision of investment
services. Within these three areas, the report examines the major trade-offs
faced by regulators, industry representatives and investors in the review
process. The summary of recommendations merges the findings of this
report with an objective and analytical contribution to the regulatory and
policy-making process
See Table 1.
18 | INTRODUCTION
1 Directive 2003/6/EC.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 19
UCITS
MAD PRIPs
MiFID
CRD EMIR
Source: Author
Some outstanding issues regarding MiFID, however, are not related
to regulatory gaps, but to the way in which the Directive was implemented
and enforced by national authorities. The European Commission and the
new European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA)2 need to look into
the nature of these problems when considering changes to MiFID.
Regulators should minimise the risk of adding layers of regulation where
failures are rather the result of inadequate supervision or enforcement.
Clarifying the intended scope of current regulation may help to create a
more harmonised framework of supervisory actions. The revision will
affect not only the rules of the business conducted by those providing
intermediation as well as trading venue services, but also the interests of
investors (both institutional and retail) and issuers.
MiFID came into force in November 2007 (see Figure 2).3 As
cornerstone legislation, it had broad implications for many institutions
across sectors, including investment firms, trading venues and regulatory
authorities. On the one side, the Directive has unequivocally promoted the
| 21
22 | THE MARKETS IN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS DIRECTIVE
7 Named after the Chairman of the Committee of Wise Men, Alexandre Lamfalussy, who
contributed to defining the terms of this procedure in the Final report of the Committee of Wise
Men on the Regulation of European Securities Markets, Brussels, 15 February 2001.
8Art. 294 (ex Art. 251, ECT) Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (2010
Consolidated Version; hereinafter, TFEU), Official Journal of the European Union, C83/47, 30
March.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 23
Singlemarketfor
wholesalefinancial
services
Highlevel
principles
Integratedsecurities
andderivatives
market
European
passport
Source: Authors.
MiFID pursues these goals via a set of rules, covering four main
areas:
1) European passport (freedom of action across the EEA once received
the authorisation in one of the member states);
2) Organisational requirements (compliance officer, outsourcing,
internal control systems, record-keeping, conflicts of interests);
3) Conduct of business rules (clients classification, best execution, know-
your-customer rules, marketing, information to clients, handling
orders rules); and
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 25
10Before MiFID, countries applied the concentration rule (Art. 14(3) of the 1993 Investment
Services Directive). This rule stated that member states had the right to concentrate all
orders on a regulated market. In practice, some member states exercised this right either by
restricting all trading or all but the largest orders to be executed on the primary exchanges.
Some member states did not exercise this right.
11A contrasting approach to regulation is the institutional one, which tends to regulate
market operators directly, by virtue of their status as institution or legal entity (as defined
by the legal text).
26 | THE MARKETS IN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS DIRECTIVE
opt out of these safeguards (appropriateness test), asking for execution-only service. For a
definition of non-complex instruments, see Art. 38, Implementing Directive, or Casey &
Lannoo (2009, p. 51). CESR is looking into the definition of complex vs non-complex
financial instruments. For instance, they might exclude from the group of non-complex
financial instruments all the instruments that embed a derivative and shares in non-UCITS.
UCITS may also be split into two groups consistent with their trading strategies, but the
proposal may come back at a later stage. See CESR (2010c, pp. 25-26).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 27
3.1 Introduction
MiFID is widely recognised as a major regulatory initiative of the European
Union in the financial services sector. It is an overhaul of the European
securities market, aimed at introducing a new, harmonised and competitive
design for the industry. Under the two high-level principles mentioned
above and diagrammed in Figure 3, the main objectives of the Directive
were market efficiency and investor protection.
It is difficult to disentangle the effects (positive or negative) of the
implementation from the impact of the recent financial crisis, which next
to the competitive pressure from newcomers has shrunk the business
volumes of the incumbent provider of execution services (see Figure 4).
Most notably, the reduction of frictional costs for trading and the following
increase in volumes may have been masked by the general cyclical
downturn brought about by the financial crisis. The crisis makes the overall
long-run effects of the Directive on the EU GDP difficult to grasp, but they
are estimated at 0.7% and 0.8% (London Economics, 2010).
However, the number of trades has been increasing, and volumes
seem to be moving to pre-crisis levels in 2010.
In terms of regulation, more needs to be done to fine-tune the current
legal texts with recent market developments and to avoid regulatory gaps.
Hitherto, MiFID has promoted a number of key changes:
1) Greater competition and market fragmentation,
2) Very significant investments in technology for trading and platforms,
3) Growth of dark pools and broker-dealer crossing systems (in line
28 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT
I ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARK
KETS | 29
F
Figure 4. Impacct of the crisis on EEA equity turnover
t and voolumes
(lit & dark)
14,562,761,413,782
-46.03%
7,860,089,362,2600
%
13.38%
1,6344,397,496,235 1,415,669,3556,321
838,628,584
+5.66%
8886,100,990
2008
2009
Turnover Volume
V Trad
des
Source: Th
homson Reuters, FESE.
F
1
17Explicit costs ofo trading are th
hose costs fully disclosed,
d such ass trading fees, which
w are
usually known before the investor enters into a deeal. Implicit costss of trading are th
u hose that
m not be fully
may y visible to invesstors before the transaction,
t such
h as opportunity costs of
e
executing an ord der on another platform
p that maay offer higher explicit costs, buut lower
i
implicit costs in terms of market immpact.
30 | THE IMPACT OF MIFID ON EUROPEAN MARKETS
18 Official MiFID trading venues are: regulated markets (RMs), multilateral trading facilities
Figure 5. Registered trading venues in the European Economic Area (EEA) and
breakdown for equities
Equity LitMarkets
MultilateralTradingFacilities
RegulatedMarkets
SystematicInternalisers 27
12 45
92 RMs MTFs
23
DarkMTFs BrokerDealerCrossingNetworks
Sources: Authors from CESR and Gomber & Pierron (2010).
As the report illustrates, dark trading may be only damaging when it becomes
such a relevant part of the market that it de facto impedes the smooth functioning
of price discovery and formation processes on lit markets.
As used in this report, dark liquidity usually refers to all trading executed
in financial markets done with no pre-trade transparency, either under the MiFID
exemptions (waivers) or under the MiFID definition of over-the-counter trade.24
Dark trading venues or dark markets, however, refer to a sub-category of dark
liquidity, which includes dark pools and broker-dealer crossing systems (see
section 5.4). Dark pools are trading venues classified as MTFs (so-called dark
MTFs). Those venues refer to neutral trading platforms where trades find their
market-clearing price with no obligation of pre-trade disclosure of investors
trading interests.
24As explained in section 5.4.1, OTC trades may not qualify as dark trade if they meet the
requirements set in Recital 53, MiFID.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 33
Sources: Credit Suisse AES Analysis, 1 Nov 2007 to 30 Dec 2010; Credit Suisse (2011).
On the other side, the growing number of trading venues has boosted
market fragmentation,25 thus increasing the search costs to source liquidity
and potentially also the market impact. Nevertheless, new technologies
seem to counterbalance this negative effect, delivering better order
management strategies with lower market impact. New technologies and
consolidated data solutions have drastically reduced the influence of depth
in the market of reference on trading decisions. In effect, estimates show
that the impact of market depth and volatility on implicit trading costs, and
therefore on trading decisions, is very low post-MiFID (London Economics,
2010). This result can be generally ascribed to the offer of multiple trading
venues to source liquidity on secondary markets for the same stock at a
reasonable price and cost.
Pan-European platforms. Fiercer competition, moreover, resulted in a
loss of market shares for national regulated markets and in the emergence
of new pan-European trading platforms (see Figure 7).
Figure 7. EEA equity markets 2010 pan-European market shares
Oslo Brs,
Turquoise, 2.868% 2.099% Other, 2.376%
Dark Pools, 2.06%
BATS Europe,
5.276%
LSE Group, London 13.293%
SIX Swiss 21.092% Milan 7.767%
Exchange, 6.082%
BME, 6.518%
Nasdaq OMX
NYSE Euronext,
Nordic, 6.679%
16.564%
Sources: BATS Europe, Thomson Reuters, FESE (Jan-Dec 2010; % total turnover, lit, auction,
and dark order books and hidden orders). For an overview of the main financial indicators
for equity and non-equity markets, please see Annex I.
Note: This graph includes the two most liquid shares (as ranked by CESR, by average daily
turnover) for the six biggest European equity markets.
Sources: CESR database and Fidessas Fragulator (% of volumes, YTD, 30 November 2010).
26 HFT is a form of high-speed automated trading that it is often use by arbitrageurs and by
(e.g. increased use of HFT and automated trading) with implementation of RegNMS in the
US.
40 | THE IMPACT OF MIFID ON EUROPEAN MARKETS
35 BCNs represent linked groups of broker-dealer crossing systems (or BCSs) designed to
form one pool of liquidity and reach a critical mass to cross orders. Matching of orders
typically takes place with no pre-trade transparency and supported by best execution duties.
For the sake of simplicity, we will use these two terms (BCN and BCS) interchangeably in
the present text, as we are interested in the function they serve more than in the modality by
which they perform those services.
36 For a more detailed discussion of the economic and regulatory implications of BCNs,
37 See chapter 1.
38 See Arts 27-30, 44 and 45, MiFID.
39 But not all kinds of investors (e.g. eligible counterparties).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 43
quality (e.g. lemons and good cars; junk and good bonds and so on) are sold at a single price
because of asymmetric information (inability of the buyer to understand the actual
quality/risk of the cars/financial product or borrower), so that too much of the low-quality
product and too little of the high-quality product are sold. The equilibrium will result in a
market price (due to this inability of the buyer to understand ex ante the quality of the
product) a bit higher than the real value of low-quality products and consistently lower than
the real value of high-quality products. Hence, the market equilibrium, in the mid-term, will
determine that only low-quality products are sold in the market. This fundamental issue can
freeze markets, thereby justifying mechanisms for quality signals, such as neutral third-
party informational tools (rating agencies, etc.) or regulatory actions to increase
transparency or simply pre-sale services. See, in general, Akerlof (1970) and Kraakman
(1986). Moral hazard is an informational problem created by the opportunistic behaviour of
the more informed party, who tries to exploit the informational advantage and the scarce
ability of the less informed party to monitor his/her activity. See, in general, Holmstrom
(1979) and Milgrom & Roberts (1992).
44 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 45
41 The main empirical literature on market transparency comes from research and empirical
43 Transparency is something that everyone benefits from but very few would be willing to
provide information about their trades without explicit requirements. Therefore, the level of
transparency with no regulatory intervention may be sub-optimal. See also ESME (2009b).
44 The report distinguishes between trade reporting public disclosure pre-trade or post-
trade requirements from transaction reporting, which is a publication system for trade
reports to regulators.
45 OLOBs is a system in which submitted limit orders continuously receive immediate
execution against the book. Orders are submitted by public investors and dealers. It
operates as an auction because the price is formed through a continuous multilateral
matching of orders. A quote-driven continuous dealer market is a market in which investors
immediately execute their orders against the quotes provided by competing market-makers.
Bid/ask quotations typically depend on the size of orders. See, in particular, Madhavan
(1992).
46 Quote-driven markets are trading systems whose public quotes are the result of
fit all dimensions of securities trading. A market is liquid when it is almost infinitely tight,
which is not infinitely deep, and [] resilient enough so that prices eventually tend to their
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 47
underlying value (Kyle, 1985, p. 1317). Three aspects emerge from this definition: i)
tightness (which is the possibility to turn over a position at the fastest speed technically
possible, when needed); ii) depth (which refers to the ability of the market to absorb
quantities without having a large effect on price; it is usually not constant over time in some
asset classes); and iii) resiliency (which is the speed at which prices return to their
fundamental value after a move due to regular trading or with more intensity to external
shocks).
49 See chapter 1.
48 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
50 Market depth is a measure of liquidity that represents the ability to absorb order flows
without large changes in prices (Glosten, 1994); it represents the volume required to
generate a market unit price change (Kyle, 1985).
51 This report will generally refer to non-equity markets as markets that are not primary or
Conclusion # 1
Transparency plays a crucial role for the smooth functioning of financial markets and the
monitoring of systemic risk. It also ensures the correct functioning of the price formation
process through efficient price discovery mechanisms. However, regulatory actions in
certain areas are needed, not only as a result of the recent financial crisis but also from the
experience gained since the transposition of the Directive. Interventions should be
proportional to the market structure through which investors orders find the market-
clearing price. Disproportionate transparency requirements would harm market efficiency
in some illiquid markets with no increase of investor protection or reduction of systemic
risk, as the market would become less-liquid and more subject to manipulation and
eventually to market crashes.
52 For an overview of literature on market transparency, see Sabatini & Tarola (2002).
53 Spread and relative spread; market depth (bid/ask spreads and limit orders size);
transitory volatility (from liquidity provision); market-to-limit order ratio; full information
trade cost (FITC); and 2 components of the trade execution costs, implied spread (adverse
selection and transitory cost). Eom & Park (2007, p. 323).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 51
Market Quality
Pre-Trade transparency
Source: Author from EOM & Park (2007).
This pattern has also been suggested by recent studies on OTC equity
trading. There is no strong evidence of a positive relation between the size
of OTC trading and market depth (Gresse, 2010). However, Buti et al.
(2010b) find on a sample of US stocks that dark markets54 (non pre-trade
transparent venues) are not detrimental to market quality, although their
introduction pushed quoted spreads down until those venues reached a
certain market share.55 This intuition seems to be confirmed by an ongoing
study (Degryse, 2010), which tries to find hard evidence of a positive
relationship between market depth and size of over-the-counter trading.56
54 In the EU, the terms may only include MTFs or RMs applying pre-trade transparency
waivers. In this specific case, authors refer to all trading venues with no pre-trade
transparency (including broker-dealer matching systems).
55Authors identify this share at between 8% and 10%. However, they doubt the validity of
this threshold and warn that the causal relationship between dark pool and market quality
needs to be further investigated.
56Over-the-counter trading in these studies reflects a number that may be altered by double
counting and does not include all dark liquidity, as the report describes in the next sections
in more detail. However, it may include useful information on the impact of non pre-trade
transparent liquidity on market quality.
52 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY
R REG
GIME
Figu
ure 10. Market depth
d and OTC
C activity
57Thhis exercise showed that the threshold of actual tra ading that seemss tolerable is betw ween
12% and 27%. Also in n this case, authoors (such as Buti et al., 2010), warrn that this thresh
hold
may not be accurate anda that more an nd better data sho
ould be made av vailable to the maarket
in orrder to further inv
vestigate these isssues.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 53
58 Parasitic traders are a category of reactive traders (Harris, 1997), i.e. those who reply with
other traders (with some risk for the last ones, though). In addition,
decreasing tick sizes may have led more orders to be hidden due to higher
exposure risk, since orders may be more easily subject to legal front-
running through smaller price unit changes.
In conclusion, pre-trade disclosure of information on highly illiquid
products may affect the price formation process of other related financial
instruments, or disclose private information that parties do not want to
disclose as part of private negotiations.
Conclusion # 2
Pre-trade transparency is fundamental for trading venues and their trading structure, as
well as for an efficient price discovery and a better implementation of best execution
policies. It is also important to exempt some trading interests (e.g. block trades) from pre-
trade transparency requirements, because as mentioned above this situation may
otherwise have a negative impact on the market. The breadth of these exemptions is under
debate and conflicting views emerge on several aspects, as explained in the following
sections.
60 An indication of interest (IoI) is the name commonly used to refer to a message sent
between investment firms to convey information about available trading interest. IOIs are
also used by dark pools to attract order flow and to maximise trading opportunities by
enabling investors to find the contra-side of orders. The information provided in an IOI can
include the symbol of the security, the side (i.e. buy or sell) and volume/price of trading
interest (CESR, 2010b).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 55
he/she tries to execute, ii) trading on a related market in order to divert market
attention, iii) introducing and cancelling orders in order to create uncertainty
around their trading interest or iv) introducing orders with lower size in order to
create different expectations and get better terms.
Finally, traders may reduce their exposure by adopting offensive strategies to
attack front-runners, by trading in the opposite direction and then removing the
interest.
picked-off),
4) avoiding also hidden orders as they may be sniffed out by
sophisticated software,
5) taking advantage of a price improvement and
6) minimising transaction costs.
The size of non-pre-trade transparent liquidity is constantly growing
across Europe (see Table 3) and currently represents 6.76% of total EEA
trading (off and on-order book; see Table 4) and 10.86% of EEA trading on
RMs, MTFs and broker-dealer crossing systems (BCSs).
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1
Dark pools and hidden
orders** 4.71% 5.68% 5.6% 6.11% 5.26%^
Broker-dealer crossing
0.9% 0.9% 0.9% 1.4% 1.5%
systems
5.61% 6.58% 6.5% 7.51% 6.76%
* Trading under waivers, % of EEA total trading.
** Estimated market share as % of EEA total trading, assuming a constant average market
share of OTC trading of 38% in 2009 and Q1 2010 (CESR 2010b).
^ Does not include Poland.
Source: Authors calculation from CESR (2010b).
Table 5. Dark liquidity in the EU (% of EEA RMs, MTFs and BCNs trading)*
2009 2010
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1
Broker-dealer crossing
1.43% 1.43% 1.43% 2.21% 2.36%
systems**
9.03% 10.63% 10.43% 12.01% 10.86%
monitor these liquidity pools to learn when their size begins to undermine
market quality (mainly price formation and discovery processes).
IoIs. In order to increase the market quality of the liquidity pool, dark
trading venues (dark MTFs/RMs) may adopt a non-binding indication of
interest (IoI) messaging system. This system is typically designed to attract
liquidity, by giving access to privileged private information on trading
interests, including size, price (or a targeted weighted average price), buy
or sell, and often the symbol of the security. IoIs are typically sent to some
traders on a discriminatory basis. Therefore, those investors may benefit
from the network of dark pools without competing for liquidity with other
traders.
Some market operators argue that this might be an elegant way to
circumvent the public pre-trade disclosure of quotes, discriminating
against potential investors who might be interested. At the same time,
disclosure of IoIs does not bind the counterparty to conclude the trade. On
the one hand, a non-binding IoI messaging system may increase legal
uncertainty by stimulating expectations (inefficient commitment) about the
stipulation of the contract (trade). On the other hand, MiFID recognises the
importance of non-discriminatory access to order information on trading
venues (RMs/MTFs) in addition to the overarching objective for organised
trading venues (as defined by CESR, 2010g) to comply with pre-trade
transparency requirements. Therefore, CESR (2010b) considers the
provision of private valuable order information on a discriminatory basis
as a violation of MiFID principles (unfair), in conformity with the SEC
policy (2009). However, the Committee did recognise the role of IoIs in
OTC trading if finalised to find selected counterparties to a large order
waiting for execution. This practice was already widely in use before the
implementation of MiFID.
OTC trading. Dark liquidity can sit on official trading venues, both
MiFID-compliant and over-the counter. MiFID recognises the importance
of OTC trading (Recital 5364) as part of the general freedom of investors
64It is not the intention of this Directive to require the application of pre-trade transparency
rules to transactions carried out on an OTC basis, the characteristics of which include that
they are ad-hoc and irregular and are carried out with wholesale counterparties and are part
of a business relationship which is itself characterised by dealings above standard market
size, and where the deals are carried out outside the systems usually used by the firm
concerned for its business as a systematic internaliser., Recital 53, MiFID. For more details
about OTC trading venues, see section 5.4.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 59
For a detailed overview of the MiFID waivers (with examples), see CESR (2010e) and
68
price generated by another trading venue. In this case, the trading venue uses prices of more
liquid pools of liquidity in order to avoid the risk of not reaching the critical mass of
liquidity. See CESR (2010e, p. 3).
70 Art. 20, Implementing Regulation. The waiver applies to orders equal to or above a
minimum size specified in Table 2, Annex 2, Implementing Regulation. The calculation of
the normal market size should be made using the average daily turnover, which shall be
calculated as defined by Art. 33, Implementing Regulation. CESR (2010e, p. 17).
71 Art. 18.1 (b), Implementing Regulation. Specific conditions apply to negotiated trades that
avoid pre-trade market transparency as they are subject to different conditions than those
currently offered on public markets. CESR (2010e, p. 11).
72 Art. 18.2, Implementing Regulation. This waiver applies to orders held in an order
management facility (or Reserve) run by regulated markets or MTFs, which have the
potential to be introduced in the order book to be executed for instance against incoming
aggressive orders. See CESR (2010e, p. 14).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 61
in the same period of 2009, but only accounting for 1% of total trading on
RMs and MTFs (see Figure 11). As mentioned above, the presence of
alternative dark venues can improve market quality and stimulates new
flows of liquidity with a beneficial impact on investors choice and
competitiveness of trading venues. This waiver is designed for venues
willing to offer lower trading costs and potentially price improvements in
relation to the referenced venue. Orders should be executed at mid-point
of the bid/ask spread of the primary market or at mid-point or best bid or
best ask of the European Best Bid and Offer (EBBO), as currently
established by CESR (2010e). However, market participants have
conflicting views on this issue. They are split between those who would set
a specific threshold (individual/aggregated) for the size of orders that use
this waiver or capping the volumes regarding trading under waivers), and
those who would leave the decision to the market on how many trading
venues should use this waiver with the obligation for these venues to
provide price improvements in exchange for the waiver.
Market views. The former group, in effect, implicitly proposes to set a
threshold (e.g. a percentage of Large-In-Scale Orders;73 see Fleuriot, 2010)
that de facto makes this waiver available only to a type of order (large ones)
disregarding the type of trading system (as also pointed out by some CESR
members; CESR, 2010b). In their view, MiFID foresaw waivers to limit the
market impact of large orders and price hence should be limited to the mid-
point as only at that point of the spread would it be justifiable for those
orders not to contribute to the price formation process. Against this view,
other market participants argued that this waiver was originally designed
to favour competition on explicit and implicit trading costs between dark
and lit books. In their view, therefore, these venues should be allowed to
match orders within the spread of primary markets or EBBO, with the
guarantee of a price improvement. It is important to ensure a price
improvement when the price comes from another system. A limitation
based on size of orders in their view would harm the market, as no
longer will small or child orders (of large parent orders74) be traded
dark, with no protection from information leakage and so exposure risks.
73As defined by Table 2, Annex II, MiFID Implementing Regulation; for the purpose of
determining the size of large-in-scale orders, the average daily turnover is defined by Art.
33, Implementing Regulation.
74 As part of slice and dice defensive trading strategies in order to reduce market impact.
62 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
160
5.0%
140
120 4.0%
100
3.0%
80
60 2.0%
40
1.0%
20
0 0.0%
Q1/08 Q2/08 Q3/08 Q4/08 Q1/09 Q2/09 Q3/09 Q4/09 Q1/10*
LISO. The large-in-scale order waiver applies to orders that are bigger
than special thresholds set by MiFID for each defined liquidity band
(average daily order book turnover, ADT).75 It tries to soften the exposure
risk of large orders, which may generate market impact. It is largely used
by MTFs and RMs (for their hidden orders pools). As suggested by the
literature review above, hidden orders increase the quality of lit books as
they attract liquidity from large traders and informed traders, who try to
act more aggressively in order to capture this new liquidity flow. Therefore,
in order to ensure high market quality, the LISO waiver should work
properly and be able to capture fundamental liquidity in capital markets.
Market participants views are here again conflicting, and include
those that would reduce the threshold given that the average size of orders
is constantly dropping76 and those that fear inflating dark markets to the
benefit of a small part of the market that makes large use of this waiver,
while eventually deteriorating market quality. The former group claims the
importance of applying the waiver in a consistent and efficient manner. As
recently estimated in the UK market (LSE Group, 2010), the difference
between the standard market size (SMS)77 and the LISO thresholds is on
average 44 times larger (with high volatility within the basket of most
liquid stocks). In addition, it emerges from these calculations that by
reducing the LISO size on the FTSE 100 by 75% instead of the 25%
proposed by CESR, the capacity of the value of orders that may qualify for
the LISO waiver would reach almost 2% (circa 17% for the small and mid
cap index). Data show how the high variability of the LIS threshold
generally depends on the trading venue characteristics and size. This
would suggest that deciding the LIS size by liquidity bands may be correct
but the current thresholds set by each band may not reflect the changes in
the standard market size, which has been gradually going down in recent
years (in particular, with the introduction of MiFID). Therefore, this part of
the market is asking for a review of the LIS thresholds and a consistent
reduction in order to allow lit order books (in particular, those using
hidden orders facilities) to compete more efficiently especially with dark
MTFs.
The latter group, instead, believes that current thresholds are
sufficient and that a reduction would increase the size of non-displayed
trading and liquidity fragmentation, ultimately hampering the price
discovery process. Small investors claim that the reduction of the average
size of orders has been mainly caused by trading methodologies of
intermediaries, so a reduction of the LIS may only benefit them, with
unclear effects on end investors. In their view, the size of small end
investors orders has not decreased; therefore the way in which
intermediaries handle them should not affect in any case the way in which
end investors decide their investments.
78 For instance, in the UK, MiFID gives the possibility to investment firms to report OTC
trades either as negotiated or as OTC.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 65
continuous trading.
Turning onto the order management facility waiver, there is
widespread agreement that this waiver should be kept without major
changes. It allows better management of orders kept in reserves (e.g.
iceberg orders) in order to be used whenever the market would be under
stress due to several aggressive orders hitting the book at that moment. The
waiver therefore allows a more efficient execution service, attracting more
liquidity through brokers. CESR (2010b) clarified that differences between
RMs/MTFs and brokers applying this waiver should remain, as they
perform two different functions in financial markets.
Conclusion # 3
Under certain conditions, pre-trade transparency may impair market liquidity. Hence,
MiFID introduced waivers, which should be retained. A move towards a more rule-based
approach should be balanced with flexible application and ongoing supervision in order to
meet market needs. However, conflicting views between stakeholders emerge when
discussing the breadth of these exemptions. In effect, thresholds may need to be revised
regularly, in line with latest market developments. More specifically, regulators need to
carve out a new set of rules that promote the smooth functioning of capital markets and
meet investors needs with no adverse impact on market structure, which may ultimately
affect market liquidity, efficiency and investor confidence. Consistent and uniform
application across Europe should be ensured.
Conclusion # 4
Despite the importance of a consolidated quotation system, priority should be given to the
removal of relevant impediments to widespread use of consolidated post-trade data
solutions. In particular, it is important to improve investors access to both pre- and post-
trade data solutions, in order to transform fragmentation into beneficial competition for end
investors. Data accessibility to regulated and OTC venues is key for data consolidation.
structured finance products (Asset Backed Securities and Collateralised Debt Obligations);
c) Credit Default Swaps; d) Interest rate derivatives; e) Equity derivatives; f) Foreign
exchange derivatives; g) Commodity derivatives. Other non-equity financial instruments
that should be considered are sovereign and local authorities bonds, and equity-like
instruments.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 67
markets are hence designed to deal with less-liquid markets, only if this
low liquidity condition is verified. Dealer markets, in general, can:
1) Provide stronger protection against exposure risks (Pagano & Roll,
1993),
2) Reduce information leakage,
3) Reduce costs for uninformed traders (if they have contractual power
due to the market illiquidity or competition in the dealer market) and
4) Better price if dealers can exploit private information and investors
can control their fair use (Madhavan, 1995).
There are other two specific reasons why most non-equity products,
even less complex ones, are currently traded in quote-driven markets, with
a strong dealership:
i) Structure of the demand and
ii) Structure of the intermediation.
Firstly, demand for such products comes mainly from institutional
investors and other dealers, since retail participation remains highly costly
in terms of cost and lack of sufficient knowledge. The nature of clients, and
the complexity, heterogeneity and large size of non-equity financial
instruments affect market structure and thus the prices of financial
instruments. In dealer markets, institutional investors can exploit their
contractual power and customise their transactions more than in a non-
discriminatory and open market setting (Biais & Green, 2007). Moreover,
dealers can have more control of their risk positions when they deal with
few market operators and exposures.
Secondly, the structure of the intermediation favours certain market
developments. In effect, the amount of capital committed to intermediation
by dealers may affect per se the choice of a specific level of transparency. If
dealers act as a principal in the transaction, on the one hand, there is more
chance to create a market for illiquid products by selling them direct to
investors, but on the other hand financial products will sit on dealers
balance sheets, with inventory positions that need some protection from
market impact through less public disclosure, in order to be still able to act
as intermediary. Then, if dealers only act as broker-agents, on the one side,
there will be less capital committed and thus less need for protection from
market impact and more public disclosure. But, on the other side, illiquid
products may not receive execution due to insufficient demand. The
complex nature of modern financial markets and economies requires
intermediaries to provide clients with more tailored and sophisticated
68 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
products and services, which may often be traded only in specific market
settings and with limited public disclosure. The use of electronic multi-
dealer platforms has surely increased competition between dealers, who
compete with executable quotes, and extended market accessibility to a
wider set of investors who qualify as members (typically only brokers or
institutional investors). A strong push towards pre-trade public disclosure
may require a rethinking of current market structure and intermediation of
less-liquid asset classes (such as some categories of bonds, OTC derivatives
and structured products), which may anyway lack price transparency since
they are typically based on proprietary valuation models (CESR, 2009).
Benefits and costs. Greater pre-trade transparency can indeed reduce
search costs and enhance price discovery processes as long as all relevant
investors can easily access these markets and dealers are not damaged by
information revelation. Flood et al. (1999) found that in a dealer market
opening spreads would be wider and trading volume lower, but price
discovery should be faster since traders would behave more aggressively in
order to find liquidity. Other authors therefore find a negative trade-off
between liquidity and price efficiency if transparency varies. Bloomfield
and OHara (1999) did not find any relevant impact of pre-trade
transparency requirements on dealer markets. Greater transparency, on the
one side, may reduce the informational advantage that dealers exploit in
exchange for the provision of liquidity and introduce uncertainty in
bilateral negotiations. The nature of the counterparty, for instance, is
usually included in the calculation of the price offered by dealers, which
cannot usually be estimated without an explicit request from the client. On
the other hand, however, the absence of pre-trade information may keep
the price discovery process for non-equity products very costly and
therefore inefficient, and it may promote a market setting with low
competition.
For all these reasons, a pre-trade transparency regime for non-equity
financial instruments should be designed in a different way from auction
order-driven markets or quote-driven dealer markets (duly adapted and
proportionate). In this regard, MiFID pre-trade transparency requirements
cannot be transposed as they now stand in order to prevent unintended
consequences on the incentives of dealers to provide liquidity through the
use of private information. In effect, pre-trade transparency may improve
search liquidity, since pre-trade information is asset-specific and helps to
reduce search costs and uncertainty around them, even in dealer markets
(Lagan et al., 2006). However, a pre-trade transparency regime could be
effective, depending on the number of potential counterparties that can
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 69
Conclusion # 5
A strong push towards more pre-trade public disclosure would require, in some
cases, a rethink of the current market structure for less-liquid asset classes, and a shift from
its mainly institutional demand to a more retail and smaller professional one. Conflicting
views in this area emerge around what should be the most efficient market structure for
these products. Liquidity in non-equity markets, such as markets for bonds, derivatives and
structured products, is currently handled through quote-driven auction markets, inter-
dealer platforms or bilateral negotiations led by dealers capital commitment.
For auction markets, whether led by dealers/market-makers (quote-driven) or
directly by demand (order-driven), pre-trade transparency is urgently needed. For inter-
dealer platforms (request-for-quotes model) or bilateral negotiations, where dealers commit
capital by being non-neutral counterparty, less pre-trade transparency than order-driven
ones (e.g. equity) is needed to function properly. Executable prices might thus not always
70 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
the close of business the following day. The competent authority may request
additional requirements in exceptional circumstances.84 Data on transactions
should be stored for at least five years and ongoing reporting should meet
specific criteria, including details on names, dates, times, quantity, prices and
codes to identify parties and venues.85 Reports should be sent to the competent
authority no later than the following working day after the execution of the
transaction. Transaction refers to any agreement concluded with a counterparty
to buy or sell one or more financial instruments (EU COM, 2010b, p. 47).
CESR has currently proposed amendments to the transaction reporting
regime.86 First, the Committee has proposed to add a third trading capacity to
transaction reports (in addition to principal on own account and agent), the so-
called risk-less principal, which consists of the investment firm acting on its own
account and on behalf of the client (client facilitator). This scenario would
simplify the harmonisation of current transaction reporting standards across
Europe.87 The immediate implementation of this proposal raises some concerns
since automated reporting systems would need to be changed accordingly.
Secondly, CESR advanced a proposal to mandate the collection of client
identifiers by competent authorities, increase their standardisation, and include
client IDs when investment firms transmit orders for execution.88
On the latter, the Directive requires reporting of executed transactions,
which may not necessarily require the disclosure of the clients ID if the order is
executed by an investment firm other than the one that received the order
execution.89
The Committee then suggested extending transaction reporting to
members of RMs, MTFs and OTFs that are not authorised as investment firms
(e.g. market-makers) since they fall outside MiFID (assuming they do not provide
investment services). Trading activities of non-members also contribute to price
formation, and leaving them out of the sight of regulators may undermine the
Conclusion # 6
Overall, post-trade transparency serves various important functions in financial markets,
such as improving price formation and market integrity. In effect, trade disclosure may
stimulate self-designed market surveillance and increase visibility at the same time as
market liquidity, thus increasing investors confidence and promoting price discovery.
However as illustrated in the following sections there is a need for regulatory actions in
certain areas, not only as a result of the recent financial crisis but also of the experience
gained since the transposition of the Directive. Transparency is not panacea for market
failure, though, and interventions should be proportional to the market structure and
dynamics through which investors orders find their market-clearing price. Ill-defined
transparency requirements would harm market efficiency in less-liquid markets with no
increase of investor protection or reduction of systemic risk, as the market would become
less-liquid and more volatile.
Finally in order to reduce the risk of manipulation on less-liquid thinner markets
and improve market integrity and surveillance it would be appropriate to extend the scope
of the transaction reporting regime run by regulators to all financial instruments admitted
to trading on MiFID-official venues, with no distinction between instruments listed on
regulated markets, multilateral trading facilities or organised trading facilities.
Nevertheless, this work needs to be coordinated with other initiatives at EU level, such as
the review of the Market Abuse Directive, and with a thorough cost-benefit analysis. In
effect, the extension would help the harmonisation of transaction reporting regimes and
supervisory practices across Europe.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 75
Conclusion # 7
The extension of public disclosure requirements (trade reporting) to equity-like instruments
and to shares admitted to trading only on MTFs or organised trading facilities would help
harmonise requirements among financial instruments that serve similar purposes. For
financial instruments other than shares and equity-like instruments, the mere extension
would most likely generate inconsistencies with the very nature of these financial
instruments (see following sections).
In terms of time limits for trade reporting, new technologies can help reduce delays.
The industry is working to make all market data that are not subject to delays freely
available after 15 minutes, in line with ESMAs recommendation. However, reducing the
maximum allowed delay from three minutes to one may prove immaterial since this delay
cannot be exploited by trading platforms in favour of their members. In addition, trades
may be affected by technical delays (latency issues) that ultimately affect all market
participants. In any case, the legal obligation is to report as close to real time as possible
and should be duly enforced. Delays should be allowed in specific circumstances, with
appropriate calibration for trades done at the end of the day. Current proposals should be
further evaluated since they may affect risk positions, with potential adverse consequences
on the market.94
94The LSE Group (2010) has calculated that for off-book securities admitted to trading in
their regulated market and traded under their rules reducing the deferred publication time
to the end of the day (with no exception) would mean that 27.2% of overall trade value in
that market (1.4% as number of trades) would be pushed to disclose positions by the end of
the day. This may create unforeseen consequences and push liquidity providers to reduce
the amount of capital committed to these markets.
95 A consolidated tape solution refers to the aggregation in one virtual basket of all post-
trade data of competing trading platforms in a specific market (in this case, the European
Economic Area, EEA). A consolidated quote solution should potentially offer pre-trade data
of all EEA trading platforms.
96 For an overview of the market for market data, please see ESME (2009a).
97 Market sources are regulated markets, MTFs and SIs that provide static pre- and post-
trade data of shares admitted to trading on their systems, or investment firms publishing
data with proprietary arrangements.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 77
98 Data vendors are providers of data that typically collect a vast amount of information
from several market sources and rearrange them in order to make them more easily
accessible to retail and professional final users.
99 There are in general two levels of granularity: level 1 (which only includes the touch
price) and level 2 (which gives a view over the order book, typically the first five best and
bid offers).
100Co-location services allow members of the trading platform to install their desks close to
the central data storage of the platform in order to reduce latency and receive data at the
lowest time physically possible.
101The fee for the last trade price charged by major exchanges (95% of EEA lit books
current volumes, but not as % of listed shares) is currently 75 per month. The full cost to
access a consolidated tape and quote solution in the US is roughly 70 per month. However,
the US data solution does not only offer last trade prices, but complete pre- and post-trade
data (levels 1 and 2), including the Best and Bid Offer (BBO), and covers 100% of listed
shares. To have only the level 1 pre- and post-trade data service in Europe for all EEA
markets, the price is around 409 per month (Atradia, 2010).
78 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
full cost (including data vendors fees and IT costs, where applicable) of
access to pre- and post-trade data (full level 1 data only) remains fairly high
(CESR, 2010b), in particular for small professional and retail investors.
However, regulated markets freely distribute post-trade data after 15
minutes. Moreover, CESR has also recommended the full unbundling of
pre- and post-trade data transparency information, which exchanges have
partially implemented in recent months by splitting post-trade from pre-
trade data.102 Revenues from market data are an important item of the total
revenues of exchanges (see Box 7). A drastic cut of fees might not be
manageable for them in the short term, since the collection and disclosure
of data is a service that normally comes at cost for market sources.
The second way to access consolidated post- or pre-trade data is
through data vendors, which pay distribution fees to exchanges and resell
data in a consolidated fashion. Since the costs of accessing several trading
venues are high, end investors may opt for one-stop-shop solution, even
though it may not offer the same depth and quality as the direct market
feed. However, the costs of one-stop data vending solution seem to be high
as well. Unbundling of services in this market may substantially reduce
costs for end users, however. In effect, a right to access single offered
services on a non-discriminatory basis may reduce costs for non-
sophisticated end users and allow data vendors to generate significant
economies of scale and scope by aggregating data from several asset
classes. This change would stimulate further competition103 and potentially
drive overall costs down further over the long term. In effect, concentration
is rather high in the current market setting. Two players, Bloomberg and
Thomson Reuters, capture two-thirds of the demand taking into account
the whole market, including data from asset classes other than equity (see
Figure 12). The market share of these two players is higher if only equity
market data is considered. The whole market for equity data sales and
trading is roughly $4.45 billion, of which $1.8 billion in Europe (Burton-
Taylor, 2010). Also in this market, the offer is typically done through cross-
selling practices (bundling or tying),104 which allow partial market
Other
Morningstar 21%
1%
Thomson Reuters
SIX Telecure 39%
4%
Dow Jones
1%
S&P/CaplQ
1%
Moody's
Analytics IDC
2% FactSet 2%
2% Bloomberg
27%
the end user would be able to buy the tied product alone, but not the tying product without
the tied one. Bundling occurs when none of the components of the package is sold
separately, and components are offered in fixed proportions. It is the simultaneous sale of
two or more products as a package, with no possibility to purchase both or one of them
individually. For a more detailed analysis, see CEPS and Van Djik Consultants (2009),
Tying and other potentially unfair commercial practices in the retail financial service
sector, a study submitted to the European Commission, 24 November
(http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/consultations/docs/2010/tying/report_en.pdf).
80 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
(ESME, 2009a):
1) Quotes should be executable and not indicative only,
2) Data should be delivered on real-time, with no delay (except where
waivers and calibration apply),
3) Data should refer to liquid markets and
4) Data formats and flags should be sufficiently standardised.
In particular, the use of diverse trade flags105 does not allow an easy
consolidation of data. The objective should be the reduction of flags to less
than 10 across all European trading venues. Moreover, on the one hand, the
insufficient granularity and monitoring of OTC reporting increases the risk
of misreporting and the uncertainty around quality of price formation and
of best execution (see section 5.4.1). On the other hand, trade reporting
obligations under MiFID create a serious issue of duplicative reporting (see
example in 0), which impedes an assessment of the actual size and shape of
the market.
APAs. In order to improve data accessibility and reliability, CESR
proposed to publish post-trade information through Approved Publication
Arrangements (APAs), which can be RMs, MTFs, organised trading
facilities (OTFs) or other operators (but not an investment firm itself). In
this way, trading venues would compete with data vendors for the
provision of market data to consolidators.106 In order to facilitate data
consolidation, APAs should define stricter requirements, approved and
monitored by competent authorities. However, it is fundamental that APAs
are designed around harmonised standards107 in order to reduce
105A flag is a code attached to the information on a trade that signals its status and/or the
venue where the trade has been executed. This report will refer to flags more simply as
codes for venue identification.
106NYSE Euronext has recently announced the intention to introduce a consolidated tape
with real-time post-trade data of all regulated markets, MTFs and OTC markets. See
http://www.euronext.com/news/press_release/press_release-1731-
FR.html?docid=929763.
107In order to reduce inconsistencies in trade and transaction reporting across asset classes,
free international open (i.e, non-proprietary) industry standards such as those developed
by the industry in line with the ISO 20022 standard (Universal financial industry message
scheme) may offer a high degree of reliability, transparency and standardisation to
ultimately enable data comparability and analysis by authorities with the possibility if
needed to adapt them to the characteristics of the market. Moreover, the introduction of
universal standards may reduce the risk of market segmentation and ensure a more
competitive and harmonised environment. CESR (2010g) has proposed the introduction of
ISO standards for post-trade publication fields.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 81
Market and Small Cap (Network C). Networks A and B are governed by the
Consolidated Tape Association Plan (CTA) and the Consolidated Quotation Plan
(CQ), while network C is governed by the OTC/UTP Plan. These plans collect fees
charged for the access to the consolidated tape and quotation and distribute them
across all primary markets, in line with a defined allocation formula.
Prior to 2007, at least half of the revenues from Networks A and B were
distributed in proportion to the number of reported trades, while Network C
redistributed half of its revenues in relation to the number of trades and half as a
proportion of the volume of trades in those shares. The allocation formula boosted
a widespread rebate programme through which exchanges pushed their members
to split their orders even though there was no risk of market impact. In effect, this
system created strong incentives to generate volumes, to print trades.
The implementation of RegNMS108 in April 2007 modified this allocation
formula by splitting revenues as follows: 25% depending on the number of shares,
25% on the number of trades, and 50% on quote aggressiveness, i.e. frequently
displaying better prices and thereby helping to narrow quoted spreads, while
distinguishing manually displayed quotation systems. The introduction of this
formula was followed by the SEC requesting the exchanges to adopt a rule against
tape shredding.109 Both these policies have helped to partially increase the average
trade size (Caglio & Mayhew, 2009), which proves that the allocation formula does
influence current trading activities and raises a trade-off between control over data
consolidation and indirect incentives on trading. Moreover, since the introduction
of this formula, the average number of quotes displayed every minute has
constantly increased (see figure below). Soaring trading volumes and algorithmic
trading (Angel et. al., 2010) may not be the only explanation for this later effect.
Hence, the impact of this new allocation rule deserves further investigation.
In addition to these networks, in March 2007 the SEC established Trade
Reporting Facilities (TRF), which report directly to the consolidated tape any
trades executed on venues other than national and regional exchanges.
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Release No. 34-51808; File No. S7-10-04,
108
500
400
300
200
100
0
2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
NASDAQlisted NYSElisted Russell2000 S&P500
Conclusion # 8
In the post-MiFID era, several aspects have reduced the quality of data and hindered
consolidation. In order to improve this situation, the MiFID review should look both at the
standardisation of data formats (code identifiers, etc.) and data granularity through flags.
The relevance of trade flags comes from the support they offer to liquidity discovery
mechanisms across trading venues. Market initiatives should reduce the number of trade
flags, currently around 50, to fewer than 10 across Europe. On the proliferation of data
formats, sources and vendors are working to reduce their number and bridge
inconsistencies. Achieving minimum consistency though industry cooperation would
probably be more efficient than strong regulatory intervention. In this regard, ESMA
should rather support current industry-led initiatives on standardisation. However, either
the Commission or ESMA should be able to impose consistency if commercial initiatives do
not lead to a satisfactory solution in a reasonable time frame.
Consolidated data solutions promote best execution and help to mitigate the
potentially negative effects of liquidity fragmentation. More accessible consolidated data
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 85
institutional investors.
Bond markets (corporate, sovereign and other public bonds)112 are
typically quote-driven markets or OTC bilateral negotiations, in which
intermediation plays a critical role. On the buy-side, the demand for these
financial instruments is overwhelmingly institutional, with very limited
retail participation (CESR, 2008). The vast majority of bonds are listed on
regulated markets, and, if traded there, they are typically pre- and post-
trade transparent, like shares. However, this situation refers to a very
limited number of securities; only those where there is enough liquidity to
allow trading on a regulated market. Typically, opacity prevails as
intermediaries are rewarded by their informational advantage in less-liquid
products. Portes et al. (2006) listed the characteristics of bond markets,
which explains their typical low liquidity. In effect, bonds (Biais & Declerk,
2007):
1) Attract long-term investors (hold and buy strategies),
2) Are difficult to short sell (at least in the same market) and so to
manage inventory risks,
3) Have few differences between each other (predictable returns) and
4) Are less concentrated than stocks (each issuer have several bond
issuances outstanding).
In addition, transaction costs for bonds usually decrease with high
ratings, short maturity and size (Edwards et al., 2007). Investing in short
maturity and bigger sizes may only provide incentives for a part of the
demand, which may ultimately affect liquidity in the market.
These characteristics have boosted institutional demand, which has
reciprocally influenced market microstructure. For instance, bond markets
in the US were typically order-driven markets with strong retail
participation in the 1920s. In a few years without relevant changes in the
role of bonds in financing the economy the weight of institutions reached
a turning point in which small trades were led towards a market
equilibrium designed for large investors (Biais & Green, 2007). Where
dealers commit capital on illiquid products, they will only do this in
exchange of less disclosure, since this is the equilibrium that rewards their
112This report considers sovereign bonds as part of the wider public bonds category, which
has been defined by CESR (2010f), p. 12. In particular, it includes bonds issued by
governments, governmental authorities and national/international organisations financed
by governments.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 87
probability that the exchange rate makes the value of the cash flow lower in
comparison to the original investment); and
Exogenous risks (the probability that external unforeseeable events would
delay payments of interests, principal, or lead to a debt restructuring).
However, where investors dispose of a bond before maturity the level of risk
dramatically increases. In this scenario, the final outcome of the transaction
(specifically, the bond price on the secondary market) can be affected by these
additional factors (Fabozzi, 2007):
Interest rate risk (the probability that the bondholder will bear opportunity
costs and expressed in the decline of the bond price when the official
market interest rate increases);
Floating rate risk (the probability that the interest rate paid to the
bondholder would be lower than the prevailing fixed interest rate paid for
bullet bonds);
Yield curve risk (the probability of a shift in the long-term yield curve due to
changes of the general market conditions);
Reinvestment risk (for bonds that periodically pay interest and principal,
which may need to be reinvested at least with the same return);
Downgrade risk (as mentioned above, the probability that the rating on the
issuers credit risk worsens, making the bond price decline);
Credit spread risk (the probability that the premium over a default-free
benchmark typically 10y US Treasury or 10y German Bund can increase
due to movements in related markets, as credit default swaps);
Liquidity risk (the probability that the market does not have enough
liquidity to price bonds at their theoretical level);
Volatility risk (the probability that the yield would follow an unexpected
and highly volatile pattern);
Call and prepayment risk (where the bond in exchange for a higher return
includes a provision that allows the issuer to call back the bond before the
maturity date by repurchasing it at market price or an pre-established one);
Sovereign risk (where the issuer is a government or government-funded
institution, the probability that the government exercises the sovereign
powers to unilaterally decide to default or restructure its debt).
As a result, investing in bonds may involve a high level of complexity,
which ultimately requires a carefully designed transparency regime. Ill-defined
transparency requirements may have unintended consequences for market
liquidity and investors participation in the bond market.
113Systemic liquidity is the market liquidity in stressed times, when liquidity is typically
driven by the homogeneous herd behaviours of investors (e.g. panic or euphoria). It is
specifically related to market participants behaviour. It is the opposite of search liquidity,
which is the liquidity in normal times when liquidity is typically driven by search costs for
end investors. See, Lagan et al. (2006).
114The prisoners dilemma is a situation in which parties behave opportunistically in order
to maximise their outcome. By acting uncooperatively, parties will end up in a worse
position than if they had coordinated their actions.
90 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
115The report does not consider information requested for transaction reporting purposes at
this stage, which is covered by current MiFID text and in the earlier section of the report.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 91
altogether. CESR did not consider the frequency of trades to set the
threshold but the possibility to delay publication by 15 minutes in
exceptional circumstances can eventually help where products are
infrequently traded. To give an example, on Xtrakter,116 almost 75% of the
43,000 corporate bond issuances are traded mainly wholesale and less than
10 times a month (orders can be up to 15% of all the bond issuance). In
October 2010, the highest average daily number of trades for a single bond
was 129 times. Moreover, while 80% of government bonds are traded
electronically (50-60% of volumes), only roughly 30% of corporate bonds is
traded on electronic platforms. This setting may drastically affect the level
of data that can be obtained in the 15 minutes buffer defined by CESR and
the Commission.
However, bonds infrequently traded may need some protection from
full or partial post-trade transparency, especially when traded in big
wholesale sizes. In effect, full disclosure of these trades may stimulate
actions against the holder in other related markets (as CDS market), in
order to exploit the private information. Nevertheless, this issue may be
tackled with a specific scheme of delays (as done for equities). This scheme
could also take into account the frequency of trades. Delays calibrated by
the initial issuance, the frequency of transactions and their size may be
indispensable for these markets to function well. It would also play a key
role in winding up and unwinding big inventory positions.
Finally, it is fundamental to make sure that standards of publication
(e.g. identifiers, condition codes, transaction definition, etc) are clearly
defined and implemented across trading venues. This would eventually
stimulate data consolidation, which may be difficult to implement where
publicly available quotes are not executable. In any case, even partial
coverage would increase the attractiveness of these markets and,
116As mentioned above, Xtrakter publishes some information about bonds, available on
www.bondmarketprices.com. Xtrakter runs an approved reporting mechanism to the FSA in
London, which has processed 578 million transactions in 2009. It offers bid/offer quotations
and transaction reporting (through TRAX) for equities, fixed income securities (a vast
majority) and OTC derivatives. Xtrakter produces bond liquidity data on a monthly basis
that includes 28,000 to 35,000 securities per month; its database contains nearly 400,000
documents. Published data is only on fixed income securities. Overall, Xtrakter already
captures at least one leg of 60-70% of all fixed income market (at least one leg transacted in
London).
92 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
Conclusion # 9
A transparency regime for bond markets should provide meaningful information to
stimulate price discovery. The speed, breadth, and depth of information should be designed
around dynamic liquidity measures. Since there is not a single measure of liquidity
readily available, transparency requirements should be developed on an instrument-by-
instrument basis. This task should rather be left to secondary legislation, such as Level 2
implementing measures or binding technical standards.
Liquidity is a dynamic aspect, which may take different forms according to the
characteristics of the financial instrument and the trading mechanism. This reality should
be taken into account where allowing exemptions or deferred publication in order to
preserve an efficient and sound price formation process. Dynamic measures of liquidity can
be designed around aspects such as frequency of trades, overall turnover or prospective
liquidity, product standardisation, or transaction size. Finally, since data is fragmented,
data formats and flags may need to be further standardised for the purpose of pre-trade
transparency.
Promoting structural market changes in non-equity markets to give easier access to
retail investors may raise conflicting issues. For some market participants, the market for
fixed income securities should remain wholesale dealer-driven. In their view even though
a commendable objective direct retail access to non-equity instruments may destabilise
dealer-driven markets, as it may generate higher volatility with no liquidity enhancements.
These effects would ultimately heighten risks for retail investors, given the
increasing complexity of fixed income securities. Other stakeholders, however, firmly
support the opening of bond markets to retail investors. Greater transparency may be a
liquidity driver for these markets. Under proper delays and exemptions, the impact of retail
trading activities would be fairly limited.
4
4.4.5 Over-thhe-counter derivvatives
OTC Derivativves. Derivativees are financial instrumentss whose valuee (price
O
o the contracct) is derived
of d from the va alue of an un nderlying asseet (e.g.
e
equity, bond, or commoditty) or market variable (e.g.. interest rate,, credit
r
risk, exchange rate, or sto ock index) (V Valiante, 20100, p. 1). Alm most all
t
transactions (aaround 84%) are executed
11
17 d OTC, i.e. bilaaterally negotiiated or
t
through inter--dealer platfo
orms that disp play to their m members execcutable
q
quotes collecteed from a gro oup of dealerss with a limiteed role for reg gulated
m
markets and official
o alternaative trading platforms.
p 118 Th
hese instrumeents are
r
regularly useed for hedgin ng, funding, speculation and arbitrag ge. The
f
frequency of trades
t is very low. The figu ure below show ws the daily number
n
o trades per currency and maturity thatt are executed
of d in the OTC interest
i
r
rate swap (IR RS) market, wh hich represennts almost 75% % of the globaal OTC
d
derivatives maarkets (measured in notiona al value).119
F
Figure 14. Averrage daily numbber of IRS tradees by currency
1
117Updated figurre from BIS, by comparing notio onal amount of aaverage daily turnover of
OTC and exchange-traded derivatives;
O d seee http://www.b bis.org/publ/rpffx10.pdf?
n
noframes=1, and http://www.biss.org/statistics/ottcder/dt1920a.pd
df.
1
118For a more detailed
d discussio
on on the naturee of these produ
ucts and marketss, see in
general Valiante (2010).
g
1
119The notional value
v (or simply notional)
consistts of the face valu
ue of the OTC derivatives
ccontracts.
96 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY
R REG
GIME
Sourcce: TriOptima.
Figu
ure 15. Averagee daily number of
o new IRS trad
des by maturity
Sourcce: TriOptima.
Credit default swaps. Ano other importan nt class of OTTC derivatives is
creddit default swwaps (CDSs). These
T contractts allow a cou
unterparty to get
full protection ov ver an exposurre held by thee subscriber w with a third paarty.
The protection seller
s periodiccally receives a premium in exchange for
paying the diffeerence betweeen the face value v of the obligation (e.g.
(
secuurities) covered d by the CDS contract and thet current maarket value, wh hen
a crredit event occcurs. Alternattively, the insu
urer can pay thhe face value and
a
takee the obligatio on in exchang ge. The CDS is triggered when a speccific
creddit event occurs. In addition to a defau ult, a CDS con ntract can be also
a
trigggered by other events, such as a debt restructuring g or moratoriium
(ISD
DA, 2003).
Credit deriv
vatives have played
p a crucia
al role by provviding a sourcee of
priccing for some corporate bon nds. They also o offer protectiion for inventtory
posiitions in bond d markets sincce CDS markeets allow goin ng long on bon nds
withh no need to provide high h cash paymen nts as collaterral. Furthermoore,
bonnds covered by CDS con ntracts are regularly
r acccepted for reepo
tran
nsactions, whicch give a stro ong incentive to deal with iilliquid produ ucts.
Receent evidences (Shim & Zhu,, 2010) supporrt this statemeent and show that t
CDS S trading actu ually has boossted liquidity in Asian bon nd markets. This
T
self--reinforcing reelationship beetween CDS and bond markets has fosteered
creddit derivatives markets in n the last deecade. Despitee quick grow wth,
howwever, CDS sin ngle-name con ntracts are still very illiquid, with over 99%
% of
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 97
trades occurring fewer than 10 times a day from December 2009 to June
2010 (DTCC, CDS Data Warehouse). CDS index contracts, however, have a
more liquid market but only 20% of trades are actually traded more than 10
times a day and 10% more than 50 times a day from March 2010 to
September 2010 according to DTCC CDS Data Warehouse. CDS indexed
contracts are also highly standardised (ISDA, 2003) and electronically
traded. Aggregated data are periodically published by DTCC Deriv/Serv,
although no data are provided on net exposures of systemically important
financial institutions.
Trade disclosure. A post-trade transparency regime for SFPs and OTC
derivatives may be designed around requirements similar to the ones
adopted for bonds. However, since transactions are mainly OTC bilateral
negotiations with very low frequency and high size, information may be
not only meaningless but eventually harmful, especially if the financial
instrument acts as a benchmark for evaluating similar products. Therefore,
exemptions and delays for these financial instruments should be on
average wider than for bonds and primarily based on the size and
frequency of trades. Nevertheless, SFPs and OTC derivatives typically lack
price transparency, given the use of proprietary valuation models to price
complex products (CESR, 2009b). In this case, aggregate price indexes
should be publicly available in real time, whenever possible. In effect, given
the low number of transactions in these products, a continuous flow of
information may not necessarily be available to support the pricing of these
products by competing binding indication of interests from end investors
(as OLOBs). Therefore, proprietary pricing models become indispensable
tools.
Aggregate data. Securitisation and OTC derivatives may be formidable
tools to free capital back to the real economy and promote better allocation
of risk and resources. They contribute to transfer credit risk and spread it in
the markets to those who are more able to bear it. However, the experience
of the financial crisis has taught us that spreading risk among many
counterparties through complex financial instruments does not ultimately
cancel it. Information about the underlying assets and net exposures should
always be publicly available in order to monitor systemic risk. Competent
regulators should have access to data via reporting, especially through trade
repositories. During stress time, aggregated information on net exposures
could help contain herd behaviours set off by market opacity. It is thought
that this form of transparency can improve systemic liquidity (Lagana et
98 | A RENEWED TRANSPARENCY REGIME
al., 2006). Investment firms would have to provide this information, which
would subsequently be aggregated by trade repositories (TRs), with
sufficient skills and capabilities to collect and aggregate this information
(European Commission, 2010b, p. 13). However, aggregated information on
net exposures might not be readily available; hence financial institutions
could explore the possibility to modify their data management system in
order to collect information on net exposures in a way that does not
compromise the confidentiality of sensitive information. Trade repositories
would then be able to aggregate this information and offer a global picture.
Trade repositories would therefore play a double function: a) disclosing
aggregate data on net exposures (trade reporting); and b) providing specific
data on transactions to regulators on a confidential basis (transaction
reporting). The transparency regime should cover all derivatives centrally
cleared and those reported to trade repositories (Art. 6.1, EMIR).
Conclusion # 10
A post-trade transparency regime for derivatives and structured products should be more
detailed and tailored to the nature of these products. Where listed on RMs and/or MTFs,
the regime could be designed with the same methodology employed for bonds, but its
implementation should follow a phased approach.
Exemptions and due calibrations should be allowed in order to preserve efficient
price formation and guarantee the effective monitoring of systemic risk. Calibrations should
take into account the nature of these markets and of each financial instrument, rather than
a division into broader categories (e.g. by asset classes). A mere application of post-trade
transparency to a general list of instruments would definitely hamper market liquidity. As
for bond markets, measurements of liquidity should be taken into account with due care to
avoid adverse consequences in terms of liquidity for wholesale participants.
The extension of trade and transaction reporting to non-equity markets can be
facilitated by current infrastructures, thereby reducing costs.
Finally, harmonising the scope of eligibility for clearing purposes with the legal
duty to be pre- and post-trade transparent would leave big gaps in the actual
implementation of the transparency regime. In addition, it may also distort trading
activities and redirect them towards non-centrally cleared products, since on top of the
costs of centralised clearing firms would bear the risk coming from pre- and post-trade
transparency with no assessment of size and frequency of transactions. Extension of post-
trade and transaction reporting to non-equity markets can be facilitated by current
infrastructures (reducing costs) but it is critical that transparency requirements remain
independent from trading and clearing eligibility requirements. In effect, the requirements
to access a central counterparty clearing (CCP) are not only based on liquidity itself but
also on the standardisation of technical and legal aspects, and therefore the mere eligibility
for clearing of an instrument should not be considered to be a proper test of liquidity and
frequency of trading for transparency purposes.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 99
For instance, as shown above, CDS contracts are quite standardised and over 75%
of trades are confirmed on the same day. Dealers expect as much as 90% of these contracts
to be cleared on CCPs.120 While expectation about eligibility to central clearing are high,
this choice does not necessarily consider market liquidity, which remains still very low with
less than 20% of CDS contracts traded more than 10 times a day and less than once for the
vast majority of them. Potential delays and issues affecting the process of centralisation of
clearing on CCPs may ultimately affect the implementation of disclosure requirements in
these markets.
5.1 Introduction
The structure of financial markets changed dramatically over the last
decade. New trading technologies and growing volumes have generated
important network externalities, which have ultimately reshaped the
original market design based on natural monopolies. These developments,
together with innovative policy decisions, have also favoured changes in
three areas: competition and market fragmentation micro-structure and
infrastructure. In this framework, MiFID has managed to provide a
comprehensive regulatory framework that boosted the aforementioned
developments and minimised potential unintended consequences for
market quality and investor protection. This report does not address the
issue of what market structure works best. For this question, there is, in
principle, no final answer. The best market structure is the one in which a
market-clearing price can always be found (OHara, 1995, p. 269).
121A and B are two complementary products when an increase in the price of A also reduces
the quantity of B.
| 100
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 101
122The videogame industry (e.g. Microsoft Xbox 360, Sony Playstation, etc.) epitomises a
good example of a two-sided market, in which the value of the network will increase by
stimulating the interaction between users of the platform (gamers) and developers of game
software. The platform will therefore charge a more modest fee to developers (typically free
access or sometimes even paying them) in order to attract more users and generate size
externalities. The balance between the two fees (price distortions) will change as the
platform gains more users and increases its value or from the potential intensity of network
externalities that attracting a group of user may generate.
123B2B exchanges (e.g. Alibaba.com, etc.) are platforms that link business buyers and sellers.
Sellers are charged for posting their products, while buyers typically access those platforms
for free. The possibility to offer the content in multi-homing i.e. on multiple platforms
increases the value of the overall network as it increases the potential reach of sellers
proposals, whether or not both sides of users are both multi-home. Users wish to reap the
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 103
Source: Authors.
Membership
/AccessFee Intermediaries
DMA/SA
Trading Trading
PlatformB PlatformE Trading
Trading PlatformH
PlatformA
Execution
Fee Trading Trading
PlatformC PlatformG
Trading Trading Trading
PlatformD PlatformF PlatformI
DMA/SA
Membership Intermediaries
/AccessFee
Investorsbids
125The non-neutrality of access fees is the primary condition of two-sided markets (Rochet
& Tirole, 2004). This means that the overall volume of transactions depends on the allocation
of fees between groups of users. The platform can influence the overall number of
transactions by modifying the membership for a group of users, keeping the other fees
constant. In effect, members acting in different capacities may get (in relative terms) a lower
fee (as they bring uninformed and low-risk investors to the market) than a firm requesting
membership in its own capacity only.
126 The role of economies of scale and scope in the post-trading infrastructure have been
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 107
of the network derives not only from its size externality and its ability to
reach a critical mass of liquidity as originally perceived by markets and
policy-makers. It also comes from the interaction of competing trading
venues with different market designs to meet multi-faceted investors
needs. In effect, today an investor can pursue different strategies (e.g. price
improvements and speed) by executing simultaneously two different
orders on multiple platforms.
Conclusion # 11
Todays markets benefit from the interaction of groups of users and platforms, as well as
competition/interaction between platforms (including dealers networks). As a vital part of
the network, competition strives if markets are contestable, not only from a technological
standpoint (sunk costs), but also in terms of fair market practices and an evenly applied
market regulation (dynamic view). This implies the need to abate barriers to entry and exit
and monitor adopted market practices. Competition authorities should play an increasingly
important role in this regard.
discussed at length, in particular for settlement services. Some recent studies (Schmiedel,
2002; Schmiedel et al., 2006; Van Cayseele & Wuyts, 2006) suggest that there are potentially
strong economies of scale in the EU post-trading landscape, which may lead to further
alliances and mergers between incumbents. Divergent views arise around the policy
implications that these authors suggest. On the one hand, some authors (Schmiedel et al.,
2006) argue that to fully exploit the economies of scale of network infrastructures, mergers
and further integration in the post-trade industry should be promoted. On these theoretical
rationales, for instance, the ECB decided to go ahead with Target2Securities (T2S), which is a
project to create a pan-European platform for securities settlement accounts in central bank
money. On the other side, others (Van Cayseele & Wuyts, 2007; Van Cayseele & Reynaerts,
2010) noted that economies of scale are limited and are typically exhausted before the pan-
European scale is achieved. In addition, bridges and multi-homing services suggest that
economies of scope may be significant. Hence, they suggest that regulators should carry on
further investigation before unbundling services or creating monopolies in any part of the
value chain.
108 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
127 The marginal cost is the cost of producing one additional unit of the final output.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 109
Figure 18. Cost structures with (A) and without (B) size externalities
A B
Price Price
MC
ATC
ATC
MC
Quantity Quantity
128A perfectly contestable market is a market in which barriers to entry and exit are low
enough to give newcomers enough incentives to enter the market and compete with the
incumbents (Baumol, 1982).
110 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
129Market fragmentation concerns the co-existence of several trading platforms in the same
marketplace. This does not necessarily mean that this market setting favours the
fragmentation of liquidity by reducing interconnection and thus hampering price discovery
processes and market quality. This report uses the terms fragmentation and market
fragmentation interchangeably.
130 Art. 4, MiFID.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 111
1) Order creation
2) Order diversion.
The interaction between these forces determine the impact of co-
existing trading systems and the optimal degree of transparency, in
particular for a dealer market setting with low probabilities of trade
execution and experiencing the potential entry of a competing venue
(Degryse et al., 2009).
On the one hand, fragmentation fosters competition between trading
venues on access and execution fees (or bid/ask spreads), as well as
competition on execution services between brokers/dealers. Competing
trading venues also provide competing execution and matching services
(e.g. dark order books, crossing systems, internalisation, etc.). As long as
investors can access consolidated data (through mandatory disclosure) and
use technologies to split up orders (Madhavan, 1995), trading venues may
be able to offer diversified services to meet multi-faceted investors needs
and to produce strong economies of scope (interaction of many users and
liquidity pools and between pools). Those needs are very diverse (Harris,
2002) but can be perhaps summarised as:
Handling big size orders (hedging, inventory, etc.),
Investing in information (arbitrageurs, informed traders, etc.),
Closing a position as fast as technically possible (close to real-time)
and
Minimising costs.
For all these reasons, the market will most likely not coalesce in a
single pool of liquidity. The provision of new services and competitive fees
may then increase volumes even further (order creation). Several empirical
studies have shown so far that competition/fragmentation has produced
beneficial effects on market structure by reducing spreads, fees and
attracting new liquidity in some markets (Glosten, 1994; McInish & Wood,
1996; Battalio et al., 1997; Boehmer, 2005; Foucault & Menkveld, 2008; for a
review, see OHara & Ye, 2009; Riordan et al., 2009; Angel et al., 2010;
Gresse, 2010).
Cream-skimming. On the other hand, market fragmentation may have
some drawbacks for liquidity as it reduces beneficial liquidity externalities
(economies of scale). Orders will be diverted on other venues and not
consolidated in a single order book, with implications for the likelihood of
execution and potential unintended consequences on liquidity (Mendelson,
1987). Furthermore, orders will stop competing on the same order book
112 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
No-return point
Surplus
Y
a
Technological (mid-90s/early 2000)
and regulatory breakthroughs
(Abolition Rule 390 - MiFID)
Box 7. A case study of national stock exchanges: Next steps after the
demutualisation
In the last two decades, national stock exchanges have undergone evolutionary
changes in their governance and business models. Three major trends happened
to be part of these changes:
1) Demutualisation
2) Consolidation
3) Diversification
The demutualisation of European national stock exchanges started in the
early 1990s and had been ongoing for more than a decade (for a review, see
Levin, 2003). Nowadays, the once nationalised and user-governed stock
exchanges are for-profit entities facing fierce competition from new trading
platforms, but they still keep part of their institutional role in financial markets
(Lee, 1998). For instance, they still provide primary markets (listings) and junior
markets for small and medium enterprises (SMEs).
National stock exchanges have been leading the process of consolidation,
since the process of demutualisation started, and in reaction to the prospects of
abolishing the concentration rule and opening up execution services to
competition. Exchanges have been working to increase their economies of scale
in order to compensate the drop in trading revenues. This situation brought a
period of intense talks around potential mergers and some important ones
eventually took place. For instance, the merger in 2000 between Paris,
Amsterdam and Brussels (Euronext), followed then by Lisbon (2003). The
merger between the London Stock Exchange and Borsa Italiana was part of this
process too. In addition, a final act (for the moment) was the merger between the
NYSE and Euronext in 2007 that created the worlds biggest exchange.
Currently, exchanges are important players that are redesigning their
business models to keep pace with changes in market structure. In effect,
consolidation is also driven by the importance of acquiring sufficient know-how
and economies of scale to develop their business model in other parts of the value
chain or to reinforce their original vertical (silo) models (see Figure 20.).
Diversification is the word that better identifies current market
developments in the business of exchanges. These firms have massively invested
in strategic mergers and new trading platforms, in particular by successfully
acquiring new MTFs (such as Turquoise, Smartpool and NYFIX Euro-
Millennium) or running their own (see Table 6) in order to build know-how on
new trading mechanisms (e.g. automated dark order books or HFT). Investing in
technologies to increase speed and capacity of infrastructures is key for their
future. For instance, NYSE Euronext recently launched its new universal trading
platform (for all markets) and LSE Group will soon launch the new Millennium
platform for the main UK markets (after the start of Turquoise with this system).
116 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
SIXGroup
NYSEEuronext
DeutscheBrse
NASDAQOMX
LSEGroup
BMEGroup
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%
Information Trading Listing SettlementandCustody IT Other
Source: FESE.
133 For more details about the merger proposal, see http://www.nyse.com/
press/1297768048707.html.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 117
134 For an interesting view on the role of exchanges, see Harris (2010).
135 Recital (6), MiFID. By contrast, Dealing on own account means trading against
proprietary capital resulting in the conclusion of transactions in one or more financial
instruments; Art. 4, MiFID.
136 For a review of potential trading mechanisms, see next section.
118 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
Trading Platforms
Neutral Non-Neutral
Source: Authors.
A non-neutral trading platform brings together buyers and sellers
orders that are already on its own books (own account) or are part of
dealings carried out by wholesale counterparties (e.g. asset management
companies). Therefore, execution services are provided as part of activities
to handle in-house orders (internalisation) or to cross them on internal
crossing networks (over-the-counter, OTC). Both activities can be
considered preferencing activities (Lee, 2002) developed by banks and
brokers/dealers in order to promote best execution outside MiFID official
venues (RMs, MTFs and SIs), as well as to increase competition on pricing
with main markets. These forms of trading present a trade-off between the
risks of market fragmentation and cream skimming on the one side, and
better prices and lower dealing costs (in particular, for the institutional
demand) on the other. A discriminating platform (Glosten, 1994), finally,
makes markets:
1) Less likely to breakdown (it selects liquidity) and
2) Unresponsive to competitive reactions (liquidity is typically locked-
in by switching costs and competition may not be profitable as
liquidity is limited.137
However, technologies have brought down switching costs and introduced new trading
137
methodologies. This is actually increasing competitive reactions also on these platforms for
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 119
Conclusion # 12
Competition between trading venues on prices and execution services and between
investment firms on the provision of other investment services has generated some positive
effects, in terms of promoting investments in trading platforms and reducing trading costs
for shares. Competition needs, however, to be fair and based on a level playing field between
MiFID-official trading venues and their structural characteristics.
In this respect, this report acknowledges the importance of ensuring a harmonised
approach across national supervisory authorities in the application of MiFID requirements
for official trading venues. This may require a further alignment of the remaining
differences in the legal obligations (and supervisory practices) applied to regulated markets
(RMs) and multilateral trading facilities (MTFs). This alignment of legal obligations
already exists in some European countries (e.g. the UK).
140Art. 27, MiFID; Arts. 21-25, Implementing Regulation. The Standard Market Size (SMS) is
defined in Annex II, Table 3 of the Implementing Regulation, which changes in relation to
the average value of transactions.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 121
basis have been evolving with time and are currently offered through
sophisticated internal crossing engines. These engines utilise complex
algorithms to achieve best execution, by either matching internally or
executing on MiFID official venues (RMs and MTFs). These internal
crossing systems are also more commonly defined as broker-dealer
crossing systems (BCSs, or broker-dealer crossing networks BCNs if several
BCSs interact in one or more pools of liquidity). In addition, crossing
activities are also subject to fiduciary duties and conduct of business rules
(Arts. 19, 20, 21, MiFID; OTC) as well as arrangements to disclose conflicts
of interests. While post-trade transparency obligations apply to them, they
are not affected by pre-trade transparency or organisational requirements
(CESR, 2010b).
MiFID captures internal matching activities offered by
brokers/dealers through the definition of transactions carried out on an
OTC basis. Three conditions should be met for trades to fall under the
definition of OTC equity trade (Recital 53, MiFID):
i) Transactions must be ad hoc and irregular;
ii) Dealings take place with a wholesale counterparty; and
iii) Dealings must be above the standard market size (SMS).
The interpretation around the implementation of these conditions is
currently different across the industry. Market views consistently diverge
around the business nature of BCNs, which for some perform the same
business as RMs and MTFs and therefore should be classified as such.
Market views. One side of the market believes that there is part of OTC
trading that should be traded on RMs/MTFs and SIs and are therefore
subject to strict pre-trade transparency requirements and more effective
post-trade reporting, while they acknowledge the importance of OTC
trading in the MiFID text. Most will agree that all trading happening in
Europe, including the one taking place under the OTC label, should be
properly classified in order to preserve market quality and prevent any
significant part of the market from escaping pre-trade transparency
without any economic justification (see below) and other MTFs rules on
access, discretion and surveillance. This part of the market argues that OTC
performs the same function as RMs and MTFs, and if not properly
classified, could increase liquidity fragmentation and weaken investor
protection.
Moving from the assumption that the OTC trade reports used were
meaningful and mostly accurate, a recent study tries to shed more light on
OTC trading (Gomber & Pierron, 2010). Using current data on OTC trades,
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 123
the authors show that about 39% of OTC trades are below retail size, 48%
are below standard market size, 87% are below large-in-scale and 73% are
too small to have a market impact according to their proprietary
methodology. According to them, this should be enough to clarify that
these networks deal with trades below the standard market size, even
though orders are partially sent to regulated markets and MTFs. In
addition, crossing systems are designed as multilateral trading
mechanisms that match trades, acting as riskless counterparties. Hence,
87% of trades could potentially escape the size-related pre-trade
transparency waiver imposed on RM and MTF trades (Gomber & Pierron,
2010). These findings imply that the MiFID conditions to be considered
OTC trading are not met and therefore there should be a proper
classification for these trades under current MiFID-official trading venues
(see below).
This first position concludes that, even if OTC trades would be
considered bilateral, 52% of them seem to be escaping MiFID rules of pre-
trade transparency for SIs. In any case, they see BCSs as multilateral
trading systems, that are systems managed by firms not operating on own
account or taking any risk in the transaction (recital 44, MiFID). As a result
multilateral trading systems should be classified as RMs and MTFs.
A countering view contests the abovementioned interpretation of
recital 53. In their view, broker-dealer crossing systems (BCSs) are fully
compliant with MiFID, which recognised their role in financial markets.
However, those platforms should be better classified in the new MiFID text.
124 | RESHAPING MARKET
A STRUCTUREE
Figu
ure 22. Transpaarency obligation
ns for venues under MiFID
mechanism
Execution
Multilateeral trading B
Bilateral trading
Classification
identification identificatio
on
Post-trade
Post-trade
P transparency y
Post-trade
trransparency (Anonymous SI S
transparency
w venue
with or OTC)
with venue
id
dentification identification
Limit orderr
display rulee
According to t this secondd position (seee graph below w), the advannced
brokkerage servicees offered to cllients (wholesaale counterparrties) through the
use of BCNs meeet the MiFID conditions
c for trades carried
d out on an OTC
O
basiis, since they are:
a
Dealings with
w wholesalle counterparrties (e.g. assset managem ment
companies),,
Dealings (pparent orders)) above the sta
andard markett size and
Dealings irrregularly transsacted with brokers/dealerss.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 125
Broker/Dealer Clients
External liquidity pools
(AM, etc)
Parent
Orders
Broker/Dealer
Split and
Front Desk Diced
(algorithmic
trading)
Internal
Open Markets
Crossing System
Child
Orders
External
Lit Markets Dark Markets Crossing
Systems
BCN
Source: Authors.
They note that trades may be below the standard market size only
after the broker/dealer has accepted to execute the trade and split the
parent order into child orders, eventually routing them to several trading
venues to minimise market impact (including internal crossing systems, as
BCSs or BCNs, but also RMs and MTFs). They argue that the Directive
refers to parent orders since fiduciary duties and business conduct rules
apply to the parent order as a whole and not separately to each child
order. Nevertheless, in their view, most trades are sent to regulated
markets and MTFs for execution, while usually less than 1/3 is internally
crossed. They argue that advanced brokerage services need to interact with
126 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
report the daily number, value and volume of transactions. It will also add
an identifier to transaction reports, to show when the transaction is
executed on the system.
Figure 24. Proposal for broker dealer crossing system (BCSs)
Broker-dealer crossing
systems
become
141 In particular, G 20, Declaration on strengthening the financial system, London Summit,
2 April 2009 (http://www.londonsummit.gov.uk/resources/en/PDF/annex-strengthening
-fin-sysm) and G 20, Leaders Statement: The Pittsburgh Summit, Pittsburgh Summit, 24-
25 September 2009.
142 Standardisation is a multifaceted concept. It refers to specific technical processes,
economic and legal terms of a financial product that allow a straight-through processing
(STP) of a derivative transaction (Valiante, 2010, p. 11). A product is standardised when the
interaction between those aspects does allow an STP of the transaction. The use of electronic
means is only one aspect of standardisation. Other relevant aspects are uniform contractual
agreements and the use of plain vanilla terms, where possible.
143 For a definition, please see Section 4.4.5.
128 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
The Commission suggests that OTFs should meet the following conditions:
1) Non-discriminatory144 multilateral access;
2) Support pre- and post-trade transparency obligations;
3) Report transactions to trade repositories; and
4) Have a dedicated facility for execution of trades.
For the consultation document, ESMA would set requirements to
determine when a derivative is sufficiently liquid to be traded exclusively on
OTFs or other organised venues. The decision could be based on liquidity
measures such as frequency of trades and average size of transactions, as well as
additional criteria such as the degree of investors participation. Ideally,
requirements may need to coordinate with rules proposed for swap execution
facilities (SEFs) in the US. Since the market for OTC derivatives is global,
uncoordinated responses could create regulatory arbitrages.
Furthermore, rule-making should take into account that non-equity
products (in particular, OTC derivatives) usually have a different market
structure than equity markets (limit order books), with dealers posting executable
quotes at investors request (Request For Quotes model; RFQ) or through
bilateral transactions. The RFQ model is required by the nature of the transaction
that is essentially bilateral, and by the nature of the demand that is mostly
institutional and require a certain degree of customisation. A greater push
towards standardisation and organised trading should balance benefits of a more
transparent and orderly setting with costs entailed by lower availability of
customised derivatives and so greater possibility to leave in the system some risk
not properly hedged (Valiante, 2010, p. 45).145
Trading in bonds and structured products is already partially done on
organised trading venues like MTFs, but transparency obligations do not
necessarily apply to them, due to the exemption in MiFID (Recital 46). In effect,
there is a risk that the requirements for OTFs may overlap with those for MTFs,
as they provide a execution service. The border between being qualified as a MTF
rather than an OTF should be clearly spelled out.
In order to promote more organised and transparent trading for non-
equity asset classes, the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) has
proposed146 that those systems should have robust risk controls and should
display either indicative or executable quotes from members. In order to avoid
144 The Commission does not clarify if non-discriminatory should have the same meaning
as non-discretionary, as currently defined by MiFID for RMs and MTFs (recital 44).
145 CESR (2010g) believes that trading of standardised derivative products on organised
trading venues is to be encouraged by regulators, even though not mandated at this stage.
146 Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), Core Principles and Other
publicly reported OTC may not be the same as what is actually traded
OTC. Secondly, and even more importantly from the perspective of either
of the two positions outlined above, CESRs data only include the market
share of OTC as reported through Markit BOAT or national exchanges. In
effect, these data do not permit a trade-by-trade analysis or break down the
overall 38% figure without assuming any double-counting or misreporting
(see Box 10). These issues contribute to increasing uncertainty and
opaqueness in the market. Without such an analysis, it is impossible to
draw from the market share of the OTC alone any definitive conclusions
about whether the OTC classification is being correct and whether, as a
consequence, there is sufficient transparency and market quality in the
market.
OTC breakdown. In this respect, a recent study (Nomura, 2010) reports
an earlier investigation made by the UK Financial Services Authority (FSA)
that estimates the share of reported OTC trades affected by double
counting.
Since some trading venues are not officially recognised by MiFID and
divergences exist between the regulatory and economic definition of trade,
what the Directive considers as trade to be made transparent does not
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 131
147 Give-up trades are orders executed by a broker (A) on behalf of another one (B), who is
officially executing it on behalf of a client. Since the order should be made by the broker B
on behalf of the client, broker A should give up the trade (once executed) to broker B. In this
way, the trade is printed when broker A buy shares on behalf of broker B and when the
trades are given up and bought/sold by broker B in order to justify his/her execution to the
client.
148 To amend Arts. 3 and 27(1)(b), Implementing Regulation.
149When a broker brings together clients orders to buy and sell, both transactions
conducted as one transaction.
150 Technical trades is a generic category that includes non-addressable liquidity or
exchange of shares [] determined by factors other than the current market valuation of
the share (CESR, 2010g, p. 11). This category should include back-to-back transactions to
ensure the proper functioning of the financial system.
132 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
Conclusion # 13
It is within the scope of this report to clarify the different views around the classification of
trading venues and OTC trading (BCNs). However, this report does not challenge the role
that OTC equity trading plays in financial markets, but rather acknowledges it, in
particular where it comes to guaranteeing effective best execution for complex institutional
orders. Therefore, the review of MiFID should not ban these trading activities but rather
recognise their relevance by properly classifying them.
This report also acknowledges the importance of ensuring a harmonised approach
across national supervisory authorities in the application of MiFID requirements to official
trading venues. This may require a further alignment of the legal provisions and
supervisory practices applied to regulated markets (RMs) and multilateral trading facilities
(MTFs). This alignment already does exist in some European countries, such as the UK
where the remaining differences have been levelled.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 133
Data employed in the run-up to the MiFID review by the Committee of European
Securities Regulators (CESR) to ascertain the size of OTC equity trading are inadequate.
Analysis based on this data cannot be considered conclusive and has probably led to
overestimates of the size of this market. More effort needs to be made to accurately assess
market quality in Europe and clarify the actual size of OTC equity trading, its origin and
its impact on price formation processes. There is a compelling need to improve the quality of
market data by reducing inconsistencies and increasing granularity through the use of
harmonised flags.
their shares should traded, however, has been historically challenged by both
market and policy-makers (e.g. the SEC151).
It is also relevant, in particular, to ensure that the interconnection among venues
is effective and does not permit the formation of inferior prices or market abuses
due to potential arbitrages with main markets or proper supervision cannot occur
(extreme case). Finally, the possibility to trade instruments freely across trading
venues is a crucial aspect for market liquidity; it broadens both the appetite of
investors and competition between trading venues, although venues may
ultimately suffer from any competitive constraint set by the issuer. For SMEs,
finally, the Commission (2010b, p. 20) proposed a special regime in order to
facilitate a cheaper access to capital, as well as to enhance inter-linkages between
markets.152 A set of requirements would apply to firms with market capitalisation
below 35% of the average market capitalisation. In this respect, the regime
proposed does not seem necessarily to rely on a set of lighter requirements but
rather on adapting current rules applying to trading venues and their members to
SMEs size and nature. The framework of rules will be defined in the framework
Directive, which will leave space to member states to tighten or loosen the regime
in line with the specific market conditions. This set of principles may boost a race
among member states to increase the level of standards, as long as the market
recognises these aspects as a further incentive to provide capital to SMEs.
Otherwise, as it seems to be in this case, the incentive for member states would be
to lower regulatory barriers in order to further reduce costs of access for SMEs
and end investors, as long as appropriate protection for both parties will still be
in place.
151The Unlisted Trading Privileges Act of 1994 made official that no approval from the SEC
was needed to trade securities (not only shares) in other markets than the market where
they were issued. See, Pub. L. No. 103-389, 108 Stat. 4081 (1994) (codified as amended at 15
U.S.C. 78l (f) (1994)). The US Congress has always expressed its favour towards multimarket
trading and that an issuer does not have the right to veto exchange trading of its
securities; Release Discussing Exchanges' and NASD's Proposed Rule Changes, Exchange
Act Release No. 34-22,026, 50 Fed. Reg. 20,310, 23,313-14 (1985).
152 For a more accurate proposal, see Demarigny (2010).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 135
153Investors must receive proper reward from their investment in information (which can
assume different forms; on fundamentals, rumours, etc.). The order flow, therefore, should
contain private and public information. Traders who act on the belief that they own private
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 137
information which in the end is already public and embedded into prices are called
noise traders.
154 They will base the decision on their beliefs about other traders future choices.
155 The report generally uses limit orders and unconditional limit orders interchangeably.
138 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
Source: Authors.
trading system) but it does not interpose itself to counterparties and the
transaction between the buyers and the seller is based on a bilateral RFQ
model. Therefore, quotes are only indicative and may vary in a pre-defined
range. The trading platform remains a neutral (and multilateral, as Recital
6, MiFID) trading system if non-discretionary rules to submit quotes by
dealers (inter-dealer platform) and orders by clients and dealers (dealer to
client) apply.
PureRFQmodel
Bilateral(OTC)
Private
negotiation
Continuous
DealerMarkets
auctions
Quotedriven
auctionmarkets
Batchauctions
Multilateral
Interdealer
Facilitator
(RFQmodel)
Dealertoclient
Source: Authors.
Benefits and costs. On the one hand, dealer markets may be beneficial
for some asset classes. In particular, these markets can ensure order
execution with minimal exposure risk (market impact; Pagano & Rell,
1993). This effect is achieved through a system of competing dealers that
exploit their informational advantage; namely, the possibility to see the
order size and price before it is executed, which does not necessarily
happen in order-driven markets (Malinova and Park, 2008). This
informational advantage comes as a reward for their investments into
capital commitments and advanced technologies. The use of capital on own
account also ensures that investors can trade highly-customised and
142 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
60,000
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Q1
2010
AverageTradeSize()
Figure 28. Average value of orders executed for most liquid European shares
80,000
70,000
60,000 BP
HSBC
50,000 Unicredit
ENI
Siemens
40,000
DeutscheBank
TOTAL
30,000
BNPParibas
ArcelorMittal
20,000 RoyalDutchShell
Telefonica
10,000 Santander
0
Aug07
Aug08
Aug09
Oct07
Dec07
Feb08
Oct08
Dec08
Feb09
Oct09
Dec09
Feb10
Jun07
Apr08
Jun08
Apr09
Jun09
Apr10
The figures above show the trend in the average size of orders
respectively for the London Stock Exchange SETS and for some of the most
liquid EU shares. The decline should reflect a substantial increase in the use
of split and dice strategies, which are based on trading algorithms that
route orders across markets after the big parent order has been split into
small child orders. The average size of retail orders has not followed the
same pattern. Nevertheless, the figure above suggests that MiFID has also
contributed to this decline by perhaps increasing competition in execution
services, thereby pushing investment firms to invest in new technologies
and diffuse them at a faster pace. In effect, besides the decline in the
average value of executed orders from 2007, the second figure also shows
that the difference between average values of orders among liquid shares is
drastically reducing to a tiny range (except for Telefonica and Santander).
This may be the result of a wider use of new trading technologies, which
typically treat orders and split them in a similar way. On average the
market seems to deal only with retail orders. Hence, this situation should
146 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
create more liquidity for small retail trades and less liquidity for
institutional orders that do not use split and dice strategies (explaining in
part the growth of dark pools of liquidity; see Section 4.2.1).
Algorithmic trading (AT) gives more speed and strategic thinking to
the investment decision. This trading activity, however, may also generate
costs. Firstly, it raises the asymmetric information between fast and slow
traders, which may discourage slow traders from investing and create
disequilibrium, thus volatility. No evidence that AT raises volatility has
been found so far (Hendershott & Riordan, 2009). Secondly, the increased
number of messages and potential human errors in defining the most
appropriate algorithm during the trading day may generate operational
risks and ultimately cause market crashes (see next Box), with potential
spiral effects due to the interconnection between orders on the order flow.
This situation would irremediably harm the investor confidence that keeps
global financial markets together (in particular OLOBs).
AT can be:
1) Directional (market trend) or market neutral (HFT),
2) Short or long,
3) Fully or partially hedged and
4) Short-term or overnight.
Algorithmic trading solutions are typically embedded in proprietary
software made in-house or outsourced to external IT companies.
Finally, investing in algorithmic trading presents high fixed costs,
mitigated by relevant economies of scale. Network effects and the risk for
slow traders to be easily picked off bring market participants to run to get
the best algorithmic trading technologies. However, on the one hand,
overinvestment may not be socially useful but, on the other, trading
platforms may need to have harmonised monitoring practices to avoid
downside spiral effects (Biais, 2010).
The SEC report (2010b) split the crash into two major events: i) a liquidity crisis in
the E-Mini (and SPY) future contracts156 market; and ii) a liquidity crisis in the
main stock index market (S&P 500). The general market trend on that day was
already affected by downward pressures from the morning due to the European
debt crisis, with high volatility (S&P volatility index was above 22%) and an
overall sentiment of uncertainty concerning the global economic outlook. The e-
Mini future contract market was very thin (the traded value was around $2.65
billion, 55% less than the early morning).
The market crash propagated from a liquidity crisis in the e-Mini future
contracts. In effect, against this background of low liquidity, an investment fund
trader submitted an aggressive selling algorithmic programme for a big position in
e-Mini contracts (75,000, for a value of $4.1 billion 157), which was a hedge for an
existing position in equity. Only two other sell programs of that size were executed
in the previous 12 months in that market. In addition, those other sell programs
took 5 hours to complete the execution, while in this case the same number of
contracts was executed in 20 minutes. The strong sell pressure, according to SEC
findings, was initially absorbed by high-frequency traders (HFTs), which support
previous evidence on the supply of liquidity offered by algo-HFT when the market
is volatile and fairly thin (Hendershott & Riordan, 2009; Chaboud et al., 2009),
together with fundamental buyers and cross-market arbitrages, which transferred
the selling pressure to equity markets. However, HFTs do not hold big positions
for a long time so they started to sell aggressively in e-Minis, causing an increase of
HFT trading, increasing volumes (HFT generally trade high volumes but do not
hold more than 4,000-5,000 contracts). The artificially high volumes made the
initial sell algorithm feed the market with more sell orders. The trader had set this
algorithm at 9% of total volumes in the previous minute, without considering price
and time, which ended up generating 75,000 contracts that could not be absorbed
at once. The human error of the trader was the assumption that higher volumes
meant higher liquidity. HFTs began to sell and buy contracts among each other,
while the market was going down and the buy-side demand dropped to less than
1% of the mornings levels. In short, the market actually dried up because of the
uninformed use of advanced trading technologies (see graph below).
156 The E-Mini is a stock index instrument traded in electronic future and equity markets. It
is a derivative product designed to replicate the S&P 500 Index. The number of outstanding
contracts is not fixed at any given time. This type of product was introduced by CME in the
1997 and trades exclusively on the CME Globex electronic trading platform 24h a day (SEC,
2010b). The first liquidity crisis also concerns the S&P 500 SPDR exchange-traded fund
(SPY), which replicates the S&P 500 index as well. For simplicity, the report only mentions
the e-Mini market since both markets were affected by the same kind of events.
157 The value of contracts traded was down from the morning to $2.65 billion.
148 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
To sum up, the crash was the combination of human error with the use of stop-
market orders by main US exchanges, which pushed prices to behave irrationally,
so generating heavy losses not only for the traders that run the algorithm but also
for markets. The SEC also concluded that pausing trading systems was beneficial
and that there should be clear and sound procedures to break erroneous trades to
ensure certainty and strengthen investors confidence. In the aftermath of the flash
crash, the authority introduced circuit breakers, which are procedures to halt
trading across markets when prices swing in the previous 5 minutes of a value
higher than 10%. According to these rules, systems should be paused for 5
minutes. Finally, it is thought unlikely that the same phenomenon would occur in
Europe, given that, on this side of the Atlantic, there is a more limited use of stop-
market orders and much less-liquid ETFs markets (low interconnection). However,
it would be beneficial for Europe to also adopt a set of rules to interrupt price
volatility in extreme circumstances, taking the solution in the US as a benchmark.
158Latency is the time/delay that occurs for a package of data to be sent/received from one
point to another. It is the technical delay caused by the inability of the physical
network/infrastructure to act/react in real time. Latency can be split in round trip and
proprietary (AFM, 2010). Roundtrip latency is the technical delay caused by the structure of
the trading platform, which may take a minimum amount of time to accept, execute and
confirm orders, besides time taken by the security check done by the firewall. Proprietary
latency is the technical delay caused by the hardware, software, IT infrastructure, and access
arrangements of brokers/dealers, or investment firms or investors (direct access) that
transmit orders to the platform for execution.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 151
159Co-location services have de facto substituted the role played by the floor trading in the
past. Instead of bringing together specialists and investment companies traders on the floor
to get information and execute orders faster, todays main equity markets put together in
the same room, close to the central data server the servers of trading specialists, brokers,
dealers, market-makers, and investment firms.
160To which apply also rules on regulatory capital, Capital Requirements Directive,
Directive 2006/49/EC (Art. 12, MiFID).
152 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
their own technology, without intermediaries. In both DMA and SA, the
intermediary is responsible for the customers conduct161 and transactions
are flagged with the ID code of the intermediary. Moreover, the
intermediary monitors customers activities (and eventually reports
anomalies to authorities; FSA, 2008) and typically applies specific
requirements to get DEA to the trading platform. In addition, trading
venues may unilaterally decide to restrict access only to certain type of
customer. DMA permits the intermediary to apply pre-trade filters and
post-trade controls, since orders are directed to markets through
intermediaries infrastructure. The proportion of trading value done
through Direct Market Access is expected to grow up to 15% by 2011
(Celent, 2008).
For SA services, intermediaries typically receive a drop copy of the
order at the same time when it is sent to the market (AFM, 2010). This
situation makes it difficult to apply pre-trade controls, even though it
allows faster execution because only pre-trade filters set by the trading
venue are actually applied. Pre-trade filters are particularly important to
detect erroneous trades or human errors (fat fingers), rather than for
detecting market abuses. Ex ante and ex post controls are applied to SA
services by the trading venue or by third parties on behalf of the
intermediary as well. SA is a typical service for a small number of highly
sophisticated intermediaries and their clients. IOSCO (2010b) suggests
applying:
1) Specific requirements to DEA customers, such as limits to
transactions notional value,
2) Pre-trade controls and
3) Post-trade controls.
In the case of Direct Access (DA), firms that are not investment firms
under MiFID may be granted membership to the trading platform. In such
cases, they would apply both their own internal controls and the controls of
the platform by executing orders directly on the trading venue, using their
own ID code. As a consequence, in order to avoid credit risk, members
should apply sound financial requirements and become clearing members
of the CCP for the purpose of balancing their trading activities with
161 Even though IOSCO (2009a and 2010b) recognises that it may be difficult in certain
jurisdictions to act against a non-member for violation of market rules or it may be difficult
to show an intermediarys lack of supervision.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 153
162It is worth noting how the regulatory approach is changing in comparison to the current
MiFID text, in which regulation imposes obligations on market participants as a result of
being the provider of a specific service rather than being identified with a specific status
(such as, high-frequency trader).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 155
163This section builds upon Barbara Matthewss presentation at the Task Force meeting on
15 October 2010 (Matthews, 2010).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 157
National G20?
Informal IMF?
Intl
Informal
EU Intl
EU +
national
Conclusion # 14
The systemic importance of modern capital markets highlights the inner tensions among
financial stability, market efficiency and technological innovation. A well-functioning
market must balance efficiency and safety, since inefficiencies will sooner rather than later
raise problems of safety and vice versa. Technology plays a central role in the configuration
of market infrastructure. In short, speed and volumes will likely continue to grow but
trading venues may have to deal with more frequent crises and outages.
158 | RESHAPING MARKET STRUCTURE
Overall, technological innovation, combined with new trading techniques, has brought
revolutionary changes to trading platforms. Among these changes, there are major benefits,
such as better order management and control of market impact; or more efficient and faster
feed of information into prices, which generate diffused gains in terms of lower spreads and
better price discovery.
However, modern trading also presents a number of challenges, such as an increase
in fundamental market volatility, which in turn has brought speed and volumes to critical
levels. Advanced execution services like direct-market or sponsored access have radically
increased speed and volumes for transactions, in an attempt to cope with increasing
volatility. Yet, limits to infrastructure capacity mean that higher speed and volumes risk
generating market disorder and financial instability. To overcome these challenges,
intermediaries and trading venues need to strengthen their own monitoring. A coherent set
of emergency procedures in case of market disruptions should be designed in consultation
with market participants (e.g. circuit breakers). There are a several efficient monitoring
systems already in place, which could serve as model systems. Finally, trading rules should
be harmonised across markets to avoid instability arising from arbitrage.
164 See Case No. COMP/M2220 General Electric/Honeywell, Regulation (EEC) No. 4064/89
166 The essential facility doctrine is a theory that was originally elaborated in the US
antitrust case law; see, U.S. v. Terminal Railroad Association, 244 U.S. 383, 1912. An extension
of this doctrine was elaborated in Europe too in several cases, in particular, European
Commission, Magill TV guide/ITP, BBC and RTE, in GUCE 1989, L 78/43; Court of Justice,
Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG vs Mediaprint Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co. KG,
Mediaprint Zeitungsvertriebsgesellschaft mbH & Co. KG and Mediaprint Anzeigengesellschaft mbH
& Co. KG, C-7/97, p. I-7791. Amongst the most important literature, see in general Areeda
(1990).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 161
Figure 31. Equity landscape before and after MiFID and the Code of Conduct
Before...
2
Clearing
SIS Eurex
CC&G LCH
xclear
LinkUpMarkets
NCSD VPSS
Settlement
Euronext Arca Turquoise BIT Group Equiduct Chix OMX2 OMX BATS DB BME
Europe
3 2 3 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2
Codeofconduct INTEROPERABILITYAGREEMENTS
EuroCCP EMCF
Clearing
Eurex
LCH1 SISxclear
Citi
LinkUpMarkets
Settlement
Euroclear
SE/FI
VPSS
EuropeanCSDs
Source: FESE.
Note (from the presentation): In green the interoperability agreements in place and in yellow
those on hold due to review by the regulators or to discussions between the parties. For a
complete overview of the status of the requested links between post-trading infrastructures,
As shown above, after the Code came into force, many requests for
interoperability and access were sent to incumbent infrastructures but only
two were actually put in place. In addition, MiFID also stimulated the entry
of new competing infrastructures in the clearing space.
Despite conflicting findings, costs of trading and clearing services
went down by 60% between 2007 and 2009, while costs of settlement
services seem to have gone down only in some markets, also due to the
competitive pressures coming from the upstream trading market thanks to
the introduction of MiFID (Oxera, 2009; EU COM, 2009b, p. 3). The
fragmentation of European financial markets infrastructure, in particular
for equities, is still led by geographical aspects (i.e. national markets; see
figures above).
In the aftermath of to the financial crisis, risk reduction seems to
prevail over cost reduction, which was a main objective of the Code. As a
result, interoperability agreements are being more deeply scrutinised for
potential threats to infrastructure integrity, while important guidelines are
still in the implementation phase (Sections 3.5.3 and 3.8.3, FESE et al., 2007).
In particular, the crisis drew attention to potential risks, such as
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 163
Conclusion # 15
Academic literature has consistently suggested that market infrastructures, particularly for
equity markets, are network structures that should operate in a competitive environment.
MiFID should therefore take action to keep barriers of entry and exit low, but with due
attention to economies of scope and potential efficiencies. The Code of Conduct succeeded in
improving price transparency and stimulated interoperability. More remains to be done,
however, to solve existent commercial and technical challenges in terms of access,
interoperability and unbundling. Ultimately, MiFID will favour freedom of access by
investment firms to competing market infrastructures. In effect, while the original MiFID
Directive (Article 34) envisaged a level playing field in terms of non-discriminatory access
to competing infrastructures, the transposition of this provision into national law and its
enforcement has been inconsistent across EU member states. As such, greater efforts need
to be made to ensure consistency in the enforcement of the regulatory framework. For this
purpose, not only the revision of MiFID will play a role, but also concurrent legislations
such as European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR), Securities Law Directive
(SLD) and Central Securities Depository Regulation (CSDR).
6. PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
167The definition of investment services and ancillary services can be found in Annex I, Sec.
A and B, MiFID. The latter are typically provided in combination with the former. However,
no authorisation to operate as MiFID investment firm should be granted if only ancillary
services are provided (Art. 6.1, MiFID). Ancillary services can only be provided in
combination with investment services to benefit from the European passport. The definition
of investment service under MiFID should be read in combination with the exemptions set
by Art. 2.1.
168See, in particular Art. 2.1, MiFID. Amongst others, MiFID most notably set exemptions
for insurance companies, energy firms, and UCITS and pension funds (Art. 2.1(a)(h)(i)(k)).
164 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 165
169Generic advices are not included in the definition, see Recital 81, Implementing
Directive.
170 Products and services can be classified in three categories: search goods; experience
goods; and credence goods. A search good consists of a product or service for which it is
possible to assess the quality before the purchase. Search elements include those attributes
of the relationship that are easily detected and understood by customers. An experience
good, however, is a product or service for which the buyer can evaluate the quality only
after the purchase and its use. Finally, a credence good is a product or service whose value
and quality cannot be assessed even after its use, as features cannot be easily compared with
other products or services. See Nelson (1970).
171For a general discussion of investor protection and competition policy issues in financial
services, see Renda & Valiante (2010).
166 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
172Sunk costs are irreversible costs paid once to produce or to consume a specific service or
product. They represent a barrier to entry for producers and a barrier to switch for
consumers. Sunk costs linked to investment services are usually higher for retail investors,
who cannot benefit from scale economies.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 167
173For an overall analysis of potential cognitive biases resulting from these cognitive limits,
see Renda & Valiante (2010), pp. 51-55. For instance, the overconfidence bias means that
people tend to overestimate (to be overconfident about) the probability of an outcome if an
example of the event has recently occurred (linked to the prospect theory and the precedent
behaviour). Therefore, consumers are generally overconfident in their abilities and in their
168 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
future fortunes. For example, many people invest, believing that they can beat the stock
market, or they underestimate the risk that illness or unemployment may cause difficulty in
repaying a loan (p. 54).
It represents the situation in which the investor is not able to or finds it inconvenient to
174
The former has broad implications for how services are offered and
disclosed to clients. MiFID organisational requirements play a primary role
in containing adverse effects by promoting a more effective monitoring and
discouraging moral hazard. Adverse selection, in particular, may drive
good quality services out of business with consequences for the stability of
the market. In this regard, MiFID business conduct rules ensure that
investors are aware and able to understand the risks they take and, ideally,
evaluate prices against actual product quality.
The introduction of stricter pre-trade and post-trade transparency has
also increased the flow of pre-contractual and post-contractual information,
which contributes to reduce adverse selection and moral hazard for end
investors (besides any test of suitability and appropriateness foreseen by
MiFID). It follows that MiFID organisational, conduct of business and
transparency rules have been more consistently applied, with positive
effects also on market structure and its long-term efficiency.
However, they may come at high cost, since they include tasks such as investigation,
measurement, documentation and monitoring (Hermalin et al., 2007).
176Default rules are those rules that apply to a legally binding agreement if not decided by
parties otherwise. They are effective in reducing transaction costs setting the ground for a
contractual agreement and they may encourage parties that enjoy an informational
advantage to reveal their type. Default rules have the role to balance the contractual power
between structurally strong and weak counterparties in terms of private information.
However, default rules need to be carefully drafted as they may increase transaction costs if
parties need too often to contract around them because they are or ineffective or too costly.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 171
177Civil Law countries are those countries in which law is primarily codified or designed
with other written regulations, while the role of the judges is to verify their application with
low space for interpretation. By contrast, Common Law countries are those where law is
developed through court decisions. However, since the last century these two systems have
been getting closer. For instance, a typically common law country such as the US has
recently approved an enormous package of financial reforms (Dodd-Frank bill) that will
need to be implemented primarily through detailed regulation.
172 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
178Civil Law countries are those countries were law is primarily codified or designed with
written regulation, while the role of the judges is to verify their application with low space
for interpretation. By contrast, Common Law countries are those where law takes shape
through court decisions. However, since the last century these two systems are getting
closer. For instance, a typically common law country as the US has recently approved an
enormous package of financial reforms (Dodd-Frank bill) that will need to be implemented
primarily through detailed regulation.
174 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
Organisational Requirements
Conduct-of-business rules
Source: Authors.
179 Plus Art. 5-25, Implementing Directive and Art. 7-8, Implementing Regulation.
180 See Casey & Lannoo (2009), pp. 141-143, footnote 3.
181 Art. 6, Implementing Directive.
182 Art. 6, Implementing Directive.
183 Art. 13.6, MiFID; Art. 16, 17, 51, Implementing Directive; and Art. 7-8, Implementing
176 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
Regulation.
184 Art. 5, 7, and 8 Implementing Directive.
185 Art. 13-14, Implementing Directive.
186 Art. 47, 48 and 49, Implementing Directive. Art. 31-32, Implementing Regulation.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 177
187 Art. 19, 20, 42, 43, 48, and 49, Implementing Directive.
188The Commission proposes to give an option to member states to exclude title transfer
collateral arrangements in case of professional clients and eligible counterparties.
178 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
193Dealing on own account means trading against proprietary capital resulting in the
conclusion of transactions in one or more financial instruments, Art. 4.1(6), MiFID.
194 Back-to-back transactions consist of a chain of securities transactions among multiple
counterparties (typically investment firms) involving the purchase and sale of a security, for
settlement on a single date. It may refer, for instance, to the case in which the investment
firm C buys a security from investment firm A and, at the same time, it sells the same
security to investor B during the same day. These are transactions perfectly matched with
very limited risk for the investment firm C.
180 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
Conclusion # 16
Organisational requirements play a crucial role in ensuring business continuity, market
integrity and investor protection. A proper implementation of the Directive should be
ensured by harmonising ORs and supervisory practices across Europe and removing
ambiguities in the legal text. Moreover, strengthening consistency with other upcoming
regulations would avoid inefficiencies and promote a uniform regime of investor protection
and market integrity within Europe, which would increase legal certainty and the
attractiveness of investment services.
195In this respect, the retail financial services sector can be said to differ noticeably from
other economic sectors. For example, in the telecommunications or energy sectors
consumers are less likely to suffer from an information asymmetry, provided that they have
visibility of the quality of service and relative price of the offer. At the same time, the
elements of trust, transaction specific investments and bounded rationality are much
less important in these fields. Finally, especially in the telecommunications sector,
consumers are more likely to shop around for better offers.
182 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
196For a more comprehensive analysis of the interaction between switching costs and
cognitive biases, see Renda & Valiante (2010).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 183
Box 15. A new regime for investment advice: the FSAs proposal
The UK Financial Services Authority (FSA, 2010a) proposed the introduction of a
new system of adviser charging for retail investment products. If investment
advice is to be disclosed as independent, it would need to have its own charges
either upfront or taken from the investment returns. Furthermore, charges should
not be supplemented with other commissions given by product providers, even in
form of non-monetary benefits (inducements). The purpose is to ensure the
independence of advice for retail clients and avoid the rules being circumvented
through the use of soft commissions. Fees should be contracted and fully
disclosed upfront (even potentially ongoing charges)197. In addition, only advisers
who provide a fair and independent analysis on a wide range of retail investment
products would be considered independent under the FSA proposal. The adviser
would have to demonstrate that he/she conducted a fair and independent analysis
of the relevant market for investment products. The relevant market would
include all retail investment products that are capable of meeting investors needs.
Since the range of products is potentially very wide, it would be preferable to
elaborate this definition in order to fully implement it. Investment advice that does
197 For instance, the periodic review of the performance (FSA, 2010a, p. 27).
184 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
company owned by a group that also offers the sale of other investment
products. In this case, the conflict of interest may also be high, since even
though the investment firm does not receive any monetary or non-
monetary benefit for the advice the whole group benefits from the activity
of the adviser.
Conclusion # 17
Some market participants claim that besides the importance of improving disclosure and
the role of the suitability test there should be a thorough review of the mechanisms of
incentives, which prevent advice from being independent. In particular, they argue that to
be considered independent, investment advice should be based on an independent system
of remuneration, by receiving only fees from the clients. No commission should be set by
product providers. Other market participants argue that obliging investors to pay for the
advice would increase the access costs to these services and dramatically reduce the use of
advisory services, with potential long-term costs for end investors. They suggest keeping
the possibility to remunerate distribution through commissions, but with the requirement
to improve disclosure on the nature of the services, in particular disclosing if the advisor is
solely remunerated by the client or whether he is remunerated by a product provider. Full
disclosure of all costs items and remuneration arrangements should be made before signing
the contract. This would improve the ability of investors to choose the service that best suits
their own interest. In the area of pre-contractual information, changes in MiFID will need
to be reconciled with other regulatory initiatives at European level (such as PRIPs, IMD
review, and Prospectus Directive).
Finally, external controls may also help to limit the side effects of
CoIs. In particular, regulation in related areas, civil litigations, supervisory
powers and a highly competitive environment can increase the level of
prevention, identification, and management of CoIs. In effect, the way CoIs
manifest themselves may differ depending on the selling practices
involved. For instance, steering practices are frequently used in services
that offer advice on investment products, whenever the portfolio of options
presented to the client includes the advisers own products. Steering
consists of stressing to the investor the advantage of subscribing to a more
costly product because of the re-edit this generates for the advisor, which is
not clearly disclosed to the client. Sometimes this amounts to an intentional
misjudgement of the individuals risk by the financial intermediary to
extract a rent in a specific period, by imposing specific requirements or
additional fees. Other examples of CoIs arise with the provision of
corporate finance services, such as pricing the value of a company that is
also a borrower from the same intermediary. This situation may induce the
intermediary to overprice the value of the company to be able to raise
enough money in a future security offering (e.g. IPO).
New proposals. As mentioned above, the Commission (2010b) is
looking at the possibility of harmonising and strengthening the current
regime of sanction, if there is a violation of MiFID rules, as well as
introducing the principle of civil liability for investment services providers
in order to level investor protection across the EU. Managing conflicts and
structuring incentives for the distribution of financial products are major
concerns for the definition of new implementing measures for CoIs.
Conclusion # 18
MiFID rules on conflicts of interest represent a first step in the introduction of a common
approach across Europe for the prevention, identification, management, and disclosure of
such conflicts. Further initiatives to strengthen the current regime and align supervisory
practices would enhance the treatment of these conflicts and benefit financial markets. A
harmonised set of sanctions, however, should be combined with flexibility for member states
to adapt rules and procedures in line with their national contexts, in order to ultimately
guarantee the goal of a sound and safe environment of protection for investors.
206ECPs are investment firms, credit institutions, insurance companies, UCITS and their
management companies, pension funds and their management companies, other financial
institutions authorised or regulated under Community legislation or the national law of a
member state, undertakings exempted from the application of this Directive under Article
2.1(k) and (l), national governments and their corresponding offices including public bodies
that deal with public debt, central banks and supranational organisations., Art. 24, MiFID.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 191
Conclusion # 19
Although the crisis showed that some of the eligible counterparties (ECPs) were not able to
understand risk properly, the client categorisation regime should not be subject to a major
overhaul. Since portfolio managers are eligible counterparties under MiFID but manage
money on behalf of professional and retail clients and have the obligation to act in the best
interest, some market participants suggest that portfolio managers should be entitled to
unilaterally require the reclassification as retail clients. Others, however, advocate the
inappropriateness of this request since their role is more than execution on behalf of
investors, but they would directly gain (commissions on profits) from rules that should
theoretically only benefit retail investors.
208The suitability rule was originally defined in USA as an antifraud device (violation of the
Rule 10b-5 under section 10(b) SEC Act 1934, 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5, 2001). See Clark v. John
Lamula Investors, Inc., 583 F.2d 594 (2d Cir. 1978). In the EU, instead, the suitability rule was
created as a rule to protect investors confidence and to foster market integrity; see Art. 19.4,
MiFID and Art. 35-37, Impl. Dir.; Moloney (2008).
209US Courts consider unsuitable an investment that is incompatible with the investors
objectives and if the broker recommended it, even though she knew or reasonably believed
that the investment was inappropriate. See Kreenan v. D.H. Blair & Co., 838 F. Supp. 82, 87
(S.D.N.Y. 1993).
210 See Alton Box Bd. Co. v. Goldman, Sachs & Co., 560 F.2d 916, 922 (8th Cir. 1977).
194 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
that may push people to give less consideration to aspects related to the
performance (through risk profile assessment) than it was originally
thought. Hitherto, assessing other aspects than risk profiles would improve
the reliability of the suitability test. It is also worth noting that the
implementation of suitability requirements among member states may
have raised barriers to market products in some countries. It would be
worthwhile to explore the consequences of a fragmented implementation.
Benefits and costs. The introduction into the regulation of very specific
requirements to assess risk profile and suitability may become a mythical
search for a risk-free solution for consumers. The last pioneers who left for
this search never returned. Rather than focusing only on the appropriate
level of risk for investors, trying to mimic investors choice, a more
workable alternative would be to make sure investors are fairly informed
about the risks they decide to incur, which is one of the original objectives
of MiFID. Responsibility should ultimately fall on investors. However, a
loose definition of suitability that shifts the whole burden onto investors is
not desirable either. Above all, service providers need to assist investors in
their decisional process. Notably, an array of aspects (behavioural and
financial) should be considered in a suitability test. Most of all, firms
should look at the risk attitude and the decision style of consumers when
they create a personalised investment portfolio. Only the combination of
these aspects will allow a meaningful rating process of products and
clients, thereby leading firms to provide a more suitable service. Finally,
supervisors should make sure that the implementation of suitability
requirements is uniform since differences in national implementation can
create costly barriers to the cross-border provision of services, as well as
important fractures in the level of protection for end investors. The
suitability and appropriateness tests are among the main pillars of the CoB
rules introduced by MiFID, and are meant to strengthen the protection of
investors and the quality of the services provided to them. This protection
is particularly relevant where firms are providing cross-border services
through an EU passport. However, the roll-out of the infrastructure to
perform these two tests has required uniform implementation and has
come at a significant cost. One-off costs to upgrade systems and update
clients information are among the most important, next to the costs of
assessing the compliance of services and products with the MiFID
framework (FSA, 2006b, p. 18).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 195
Conclusion # 20
The suitability test is a crucial aspect of the provision of investment advice and portfolio
management services. Views diverge slightly on how to assess the knowledge, financial
situation and objectives of investors, and in particular, on how deeply the suitability test
should look into investors habits and their willingness to undertake risk. Some members
regret the lack of harmonisation in the implementation of suitability requirements for
discretionary portfolio management. These members would welcome action by ESMA to
improve legal certainty and reduce barriers to market investment products across the EU.
However, other members do not think any intervention is needed in this regard and are
satisfied with the current level of harmonisation.
Some market participants believe that certain UCITS might have become too complex to be
easily understood by investors and so to skip the appropriateness test, at least for retail
clients. Others, instead, argue that classification, in particular for UCITS, should remain
as such, since a change in classification could damage the UCITS brand outside the EU.
MiFID has had widespread implications for several areas of financial markets, in
particular for the asset management business. Besides the application of MiFID to
portfolio management services, it is the interaction between MiFID and UCITS that
raises concerns. In particular, MiFID sets a formal exemption (Art. 2.1 (h)) that has
not been de facto applied. In effect, UCITS are currently exempted from the
appropriateness test as non-complex financial instruments, which means that they
are part of the Directive. UCITS management companies are then classified as
ECPs under MiFID, therefore best execution or suitability tests are not applied,
unless agreed otherwise. Besides these formal exemptions, there are several aspects
that put UCITS under the MiFID spotlight. UCITS typically apply and get the
status of professional investor, but they also ask to be treated as retail investors,
since the investment product is mainly designed for retail investors. The UCITS
Directive also provides for similar organisational requirements as those in MiFID
(Recital 1, UCITS Implementing Directive 2010/43/EU) to create a level playing
field between UCITS managers and MiFID investment firms undertaking portfolio
management services.
Overall, there are other aspects that emerge with the revision of MiFID as
points of discussion that may affect the debate on UCITS. Among others, the
following aspects would have an impact on the asset management industry:
Unilaterally granting retail best execution to managers of retail funds
(without the need for the agreement of dealers);
Modifying current definitions of complex versus non-complex financial
instruments;
Investigating the status of the implementation of suitability requirements for
investment advice and discretionary portfolio services; and
Changing the charging structure for investment advice and its basic
requirements, and promoting greater inducement disclosure.
The interaction between these areas may have important implications for the
future of the industry, in particular for the convergence between alternative and
traditional investments (if no differential status would be granted to traditional
investments) and on the traditional distribution channels (by changing the role and
nature of investment advice).
198 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
they can assume different forms according to multiple factors, such as the
nature of the client.
In this regard, the criteria to be considered by investment firms when
performing best execution of an order are the following (Art. 44.1, Impl.
Dir.):
i) Specific instructions given by the client,
ii) Nature of the client (retail or professional),
iii) Nature of the financial instruments and
iv) Nature of the execution venues.
What should be considered as best execution for retail clients
(typically price and costs) may not be the same for professionals (Art. 44.3,
Impl. Dir.). The difficulty of drawing up a precise definition of what is best
execution is obvious in todays financial markets. Accordingly, the
Directive does not give an easy-to-enforce definition of best execution
either. The legal text tries to grasp all factors influencing a financial
transaction, but does so in a general manner. However, this situation is not
necessarily a detriment to final investors for two reasons, which should
always be verified. On the one hand, general clauses are typically set to
define a fiduciary duty, which should by definition fill gaps in incomplete
contracts, i.e. when it is too costly and difficult for the contracting parties to
specify all relevant terms. This situation does not call for detailed
provisions in the law, but rather requires stronger enforcement tools and
judicial review and the flexible application of best execution requirements
(Macey & OHara, 1997 & 2005). On the other hand, when transaction costs
are sufficiently low, a broad definition allows counterparties to bargain and
contract around the duty of best execution or customise it (even opt out)
. In addition, technological developments (Smart Order Routers, SORs)
support the customisation of best execution policies, even in a context of
great market fragmentation where best execution cannot be easily verified.
Nevertheless, a strict regulatory definition can increase verifiability
but the quality of the execution (investment) service would be potentially
lower, with ultimately potential negative effects on demand. A too precise
definition of best execution may exacerbate ex ante commitment and so
inefficient investments. Current legal text sets the boundaries in which
competing investment firms tailor execution policies in line with clients
interests. More should be done to increase verifiability by improving the
content of execution policies and the quality and depth of market data.
200 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
214 This list must be reviewed periodically, taking into account execution venue fees,
clearing and settlement fees and any other fees paid to third parties involved in the
execution of the order (Art. 44.3, Impl. Dir.). Effective barriers to add new venues can be
(among others, CESR, 2010h, p.5): (1) The lack of interoperability between clearing houses,
so the inability to choose a clearer of choice; (2) Local rules which prevent remote
membership of exchanges or complex re-registration processes; (3) Different regulatory
regimes and clearing and settlement requirements in several countries, creating obstacles to
competition between venues; (4) Absence of a central counterparty continues to be a
clearing problem for some venues; (5) Distance speed (or latency), mitigated by new
facilities, e.g. hosting facilities, IT developments etc.; and (6) System costs, integration to
back office and settlement systems.
215 See, in particular, FSA (2006), p.12.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 201
216For instance, the US case law recognises as industry practice - therefore not considered
violation of the best execution duty - accepting a rebate for directing order flow to a
particular broker or trading venue; see Macey & OHara (1997), pp.195-196.
217CESR is also looking to define an appropriate execution metric in order to measure
execution (on a quarterly basis) in shares (for other financial instruments it has been
postponed to a future discussion) and it may ask execution venues to produce reports on
execution quality using metrics set by CESR. CESR (2010), Investor Protection and
Intermediaries, op. cit., pp. 18-26.
202 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
Conclusion # 22
Best execution duties lie at the foundation of the fiduciary relationship between service
providers and clients. Execution policies and data are essential aspects of the effectiveness of
these legal requirements. MiFID tries to grasp all factors influencing the best execution of a
financial transaction, and does so in a very general manner. A strict legal definition (price-
only) would assume that other services needed to achieve best execution (such as speed,
transaction cost analysis, etc) would be efficiently provided by the market itself under
competition, with no need of a formal legal protection. A broad definition, however, is not
necessarily detrimental for final investors as long as execution policies are properly
implemented and data allows sufficient verifiability of execution. Conflicting views emerge
between those who argue that execution policies should be designed around a dynamic
obligation of result, i.e. complying with the minimum legal requirements is not enough in
their view to achieve best execution. Other participants however challenge the view that
issues with best execution come from execution policies, which are MiFID-compliant.
Investors themselves receive full information about their execution policies. Both recognise
that those issues emerge from a consistent lack of data on execution quality from trading
platforms, which are under discussion within the debate on the new transparency regime.
204 | PROVISION OF INVESTMENT SERVICES
Overall, MiFID requires firms to act in their clients best interest (Art. 19.1), which
constitutes a good-faith clause that should allow judges the necessary discretion to decide
whether best execution has effectively taken place. However, since MiFID also defines what
constitutes the clients best interests, it impairs judiciary discretion and rather favours the
principle of caveat emptor. This principle is not satisfactory either, due to the lack of
verifiability, which means investors have to choose among execution policies that may not
always be implemented properly. Observability and verifiability are considered minimal
informational requirements for an event to define a contractual contingency.
Best execution also impacts on market structure. Best execution de facto is
synonymous of low transaction costs and is achieved when the fewest resources are lost in
intermediation. Best execution policies must ensure that, when the abovementioned
conditions are met, the investment firm screens the whole market, in particular those
execution venues that can offer best execution to clients. Hitherto, the duty of best
execution sustains a competitive environment between trading venues, as incumbents are
indirectly forced to deliver better quality of execution, due to the investment firms
commitment to deliver it.
7. A NEW REGIME FOR COMMODITY
DERIVATIVES
| 205
206 | A NEW REGIME FOR COMMODITY DERIVATIVES
The financial crisis. The recent increase in market prices and volatility
of such goods has diverted attention away from a potential link between
prices on spot markets and volumes and prices of transactions done on
underlying future markets. The alleged financialisation of commodities
and their prices formation process has put many derivatives transactions
under the regulatory spotlight, in an attempt to address the historical high
price volatility in commodity markets. It needs to be said that derivative
markets (in particular, future markets) are just one of the variables that
may affect the price formation processes of commodities. Amongst other
variables, there are fundamental aspects such as: demand (e.g. the GDP is a
valid measure); supply constraints; transportation costs; storage costs; and
other exogenous factors (weather, political stability, etc). Uncertainty about
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 207
218This approach does not seem to be in line with the legal text proposed for central
counterparty (CCP) clearing of over-the-counter derivatives in the recent proposal of
European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR; COM (2010), 484/5). In that proposal,
non-financial counterparties are not in principle covered by the scope of the regulation if
they do not breach a certain clearing threshold.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 209
219The joint advice of the Committee of European Banking Supervisors (CEBS) to the EU
Commission (CEBS-Advice) in 2008 clearly states that systemic risk concerns [of
commodities business firms] appear significantly smaller relative to the systemic risks
posed by banks and ISD financial investment firms. In the commodities case studies
examined in this report, systemic concerns were limited and contained. See, joint CESR-
CEBS Advice (ref. CESR/08-752), 15 October 2008, see ref. 12, ref. 38 et seq., 213 et seq., 282
et seq., (http://www.c-ebs.org/getdoc/ee9b85fa-4d64-48dc-9f45-a7350881ddac/2008-15-10-
CESR-CEBS-advice-on-Commodities.aspx).
210 | A NEW REGIME FOR COMMODITY DERIVATIVES
220In line also with the US Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act,
P.L. 111-203, H.R. 4173.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 211
221 The border between private legal information and inside information is often so
unclear that regulators may be willing to ban trading a product rather than monitoring
activities on an ongoing basis. See Art. 1, Market Abuse Directive 2003/124/EC.
212 | A NEW REGIME FOR COMMODITY DERIVATIVES
OTC. On the other side, position limits for OTC contracts may increase the
number of trades and eventually the costs that the requesting
counterparty should pay, since it could not benefit from the freedom to
privately negotiate an important risk exposure. However, it greatly
depends on how the position limit would be formulated, whether or not it
would be an obligation to reduce size of the position below the limit, or
whether it would only require disclosure to regulators. Position limits
generally impose on commodity traders a cap on the size of transactions
based on broader indicators. Some argue that these measures may be easily
circumvented by trading more frequently with smaller sizes, which makes
supervision a more complex and costly activity. By contrast, the use of
position limits may be indispensable in markets where the single
transaction can directly manipulate prices, such as physical markets or
markets for non-storable commodities (e.g. electricity exchanges).
Position management allows the detection of dominant net positions
at the end of the trading day and a more accurate monitoring of systemic
risk. If positions create unreasonable upward or downward pressures on
prices, market operators can require traders, at the beginning of the next
trading day, to reduce their positions. Position management may thus be a
more effective tool for tackling this issue, since manipulation in commodity
markets does not usually come from the impact on prices of the availability
of investors to transact a security at a specific price, but from the
availability of counterparties to bargain a future position. Since the
availability of settlement dates is actually quite limited, it would be more
meaningful to collect all trading reports and calculate the total net position
of an investor in that specific market. In securities markets, however, the
availability of securities is typically wider and manipulation comes
frequently from the misuse of a single or multiple transactions by
exploiting inside information or the accumulated size (trading with
knowledge). Some have also cast doubt on the improper use of leverage.
These worries also concern securities markets, but the issue itself should be
confined to the reforms on capital requirements for financial institutions
(Basel III), as it may be more appropriate to tackle them in that context.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 213
Conclusion # 23
Narrowing exemptions for commodity derivatives under MiFID may have a substantial
impact on the business of non-financial companies. Some market participants advocate the
need for a level playing field between financial and non-financial firms when they come to
trade financial instruments. In their view, it would represent an important step towards
greater transparency and investor protection, while others ask for further investigation of
the unintended consequences in terms of higher costs of hedging relevant exposures in the
market, as well as lower competitiveness, liquidity, and competition. The need for
consistency across several regulations in the commodity business may need a more fully
articulated answer and coordination with initiatives to define capital requirements for
investment firms.
Curbing speculation is a vague objective, since how someone can actually
distinguish between hedging and speculative trading remains highly controversial.
Regulators instead should shed light on the risks of price manipulation potentially arising
from the accumulation of dominant net positions in derivatives markets (futures).
Strengthening supervisory powers may in principle be effective to control price
manipulation, but its role in controlling systemic risk may be doubtful, in particular
through position limits. The use of position management tools to monitor the size of net
positions would be more effective.
8. CONCLUSIONS
214 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 215
nature of each market, whether auction or bilateral, and take into account
the dynamics through which orders find their market clearing price.
Pre-trade transparency supports the functioning of venues trading
mechanisms, as well as efficient price discovery and the implementation of
best execution policies. Under certain conditions, however, pre-trade
transparency may impair market liquidity.
For equity financial instruments, waivers of pre-trade transparency
should be retained. A move towards a sounder rule-based approach,
however, should be balanced with flexible application and ongoing
supervision in order to meet market needs. Conflicting views in the market
emerge when discussing the breadth of these exemptions. Regulators need
to devise a new set of rules that promotes the efficient and stability of
Europes capital markets and meets investors needs with no adverse
impact on market structure, market liquidity, efficiency, or investor
confidence. In addition, the consistent and uniform application across
Europe should be ensured.
For non-equity financial instruments, a strong push towards more
pre-trade public disclosure would require, in some cases, a rethink of the
current market structure for less-liquid asset classes, and a shift from its
mainly institutional demand to a more retail and smaller professional one.
Clashing positions in this area emerge as a result of different views around
the most efficient market structure for these products.
Liquidity in non-equity markets, such as markets for bonds,
derivatives and structured products, is mostly handled through quote-
driven auction markets, inter-dealer platforms or purely bilateral
negotiations through the direct commitment of dealers capital. For auction
markets, whether led by dealers/market-makers (quote-driven) or directly
by demand (order-driven), pre-trade transparency is strictly needed. For
inter-dealer platforms (request-for-quotes model) or bilateral negotiations,
where dealers commit capital by being non-neutral counterparties, less pre-
trade transparency than in order-driven ones (e.g. equity) could enable
them to function properly. Executable prices might thus not always be
consistently available. Current market structure, however, does not impede
future market developments in the years to arrive at a different structure of
intermediation and nature of the demand.
The alternative to a shift in market structure and demand, which may
not necessarily occur, is to design a different transparency regime from the
one applied to equities. However, an appropriate level of pre-trade
216 | CONCLUSIONS
AFM (Authority for the Financial Markets) (2010), High frequency trading.
The application of advanced trading technology in the European
marketplace, Report, December (http://www.afm.nl/en/
professionals/afm-actueel/rapporten/2010/hft-rapport.aspx).
Akerlof, G.A. (1970), The market for lemons. Qualitative uncertainty and
the market mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3,
August, pp. 488-500.
Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson (1996), A New Approach to the
Regulation of Trading across Securities Markets, New York University
Law Review, Vol. 71, No. 6, December.
Amihud, Yakov, Haim Mendelson and Beni Lauterbach (1997), Market
microstructure and securities values: Evidence from the Tel Aviv
Stock Exchange, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 45, No. 3,
September, pp. 365-390.
Angel, James J., Lawrence E. Harris and Chester Spatt (2010), Equity Trading
in the 21st Century, Working Paper (www.ssrn.com).
Areeda, Phillip (1990), Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting
Principles, 58 Antitrust L.J.
Armstrong, Mark (2006), Competition in two-sided markets, RAND
Journal of Economics, Vol. 37, No. 3, Autumn.
Atradia (2010), The cost of access to real time pre- and post-trade order book data
in Europe. A review of content fees within the wider context of data product,
delivery and infrastructure costs, Research Study, August.
Baruch, Shmuel (2005), Who Benefits from an Open Limit-Order Book?,
Journal of Business, Vol. 78, No. 4, July, pp. 1267-1306.
Battalio, Robert H. (1997), Third Market Broker-Dealers: Cost Competitors
or Cream Skimmers?, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 52, No. 1, March.
Battalio, Robert H., Jason Greene and Robert Jennings (1997), Do
Competing Specialists and Preferencing Dealers affect Market
Quality?, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 10, No. 4, October, pp.
969-993.
220 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 221
Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig (1982), Contestable
Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure, New York, NY: Harcourt
Brace Jovanovich, June.
Bessembinder, Hendrik, William Maxwell and Kumar Venkataraman
(2006), Market transparency, liquidity externalities, and institutional
trading costs in corporate bonds, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.
82, May, pp. 251-288.
Biais, Bruno (2010), Algorithmic Trading. Equilibrium, efficiency and
stability, presentation at Market Microstructure Conference, Institut
Louis Bachelier (ILB), Paris, 6 December.
Biais, Bruno and Fany Declerk (2007), Liquidity, Competition and Price
Discovery in the European Corporate Bond Market, IDEI Working Papers,
Institut dEconomie Industrielle, University of Toulouse
(http://idei.fr/doc/wp/2007/liquidity_competition.pdf).
Biais, Bruno, Fany Declerck, James Dow, Richard Portes and Ernst-Ludwig
von Thadden (2006), European Corporate Bond Markets: Transparency,
liquidity, efficiency, CEPR Working Paper for the City of London,
Centre for Economic Policy Research, London, May
(http://www.cepr.org/PRESS/TT_CorporateFULL.pdf).
Biais, Bruno and Richard C. Green (2007), The Microstructure of the Bond
Market in the 20th Century, IDEI Working Paper, Institut dEconomie
Industrielle, University of Toulouse, 29 August (http://neeo.univ-
tlse1.fr/502/1/bondmarket.pdf).
Bloomfield, Robert and Maureen O'Hara (1999), Market Transparency:
Who Wins and Who Loses?, The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 12,
No. 1, Spring, pp. 5-35.
Boehmer, Ekkehart, Gideon Saar and Lei Yu (2005), Lifting the Veil: An
Analysis of Pre-Trade Transparency at the NYSE, The Journal of
Finance, Vol. 60, No. 2, April, pp. 783-815.
Brogaard, Jonathan A. (2010), High-frequency Trading and Its Impact on
Market Quality, Working Paper, Northwestern University, July
(www.ssrn.com).
Buccirossi, Paolo (ed.) (2008), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, Cambridge,
MA: The MIT Press.
Burton-Taylor LLC (2010), Financial Market Data/Analysis Global Share
and Segment Sizing 2010 (http://www.burton-
taylor.com/samples/B-T_Global_Market_Data-
222 | REFERENCES
Analysis_3_Year_Segment_and_5_Year_Competitor_Analysis_2010-
Information_Kit.pdf).
Buti, Sabrina, Barbara Rindi and Ingrid M. Werner (2010a), Dynamic Dark
Pool Trading Strategies in Limit Order Markets, Dice Centre Working
Paper, 2010-6, Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial
Economics, Ohio State University, March.
(2010b), Diving into Dark Pools, Dice Centre Working Paper,
2010-10, Charles A. Dice Center for Research in Financial Economics,
Ohio State University, June.
Caglio, Cecilia and Stewart Mayhew (2009), Equity Trading and the
Allocation of Market Data Revenue, draft Working Paper
(http://business.rutgers.edu/files/caglio_mayhew_may272009.pdf).
Casey, Jean-Pierre (2006), Bond Market Transparency: To Regulate or not to
Regulate, ECMI Policy Brief, No. 4, December.
Casey, Jean-Pierre and Karel Lannoo (2009), The MiFID Revolution,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Celent (2008), The Evolution of Direct Market Access (DMA) Trading
Services in the US and Europe Report, March
(http://reports.celent.com/PressReleases/20080313/DMA.htm).
(2009), Demystifying and Evaluating High Frequency
Equities Trading, Report, December.
CESAME Group (Clearing and Settlement Advisory and Monitoring
Experts Group) (2008), Solving the industry Giovannini Barriers to Post-
Trading within the EU, Group Report, 28 November
(http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/financial-
markets/clearing/index_en.htm).
CESR (Committee of European Securities Regulators) (2007), Best
Execution under MiFID. Questions and Answers, Ref CEST/07-320.
(2008), Transparency of corporate bond, structured finance product
and credit derivatives markets, Consultation Paper CESR/08-1014, 19
December.
(2009a), Impact of MiFID on equity secondary markets functioning,
Report 09/355, 10 June.
(2009b), Transparency of corporate bond, structured finance product
and credit derivatives markets, Report CESR/09-348, 10 July.
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 223
Demarigny, Fabrice (2010), An EU-Listing Small Business Act, Report for the
French Ministry, March
(http://www.eurocapitalmarkets.org/node/455).
Demsetz, Harold (1968), The Cost of Transacting, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 82, No. 1, February, pp. 33-53.
Di Noia, Carmine (2001), Competition and Integration among Stock
Exchanges in Europe: Network Effects, Implicit Mergers and Remote
Access, European Financial Management, Vol. 7, No. 1, March, pp. 39-
72.
Domowitz, Ian (1990), The Mechanisms of Automated Trade Execution
Systems, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 1, pp. 167-194.
(1996), The Classification and Regulation of Automated
Trading Systems, in Andrew W. Lo (ed.), The Industrial Organisation
and Regulation of the Securities Industry, National Bureau of Economic
Research Conference Report, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago
Press.
Domowitz, Ian and Benn Steil (1999), Automation, Trading Costs, and the
Structure of the Securities Trading Industry, Brookings-Wharton Papers
on Financial Services (http://www.cfr.org/content/publications/
attachments/Brookings-Wharton.pdf).
Dow, James and Gary Gorton (2006), Noise Traders, NBER Working Paper,
No. W12256, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
MA, May.
DTCC Deriv/Serv, CDS Data warehouse (www.dtcc.com/products/
derivserv/data/index.php).
Easley, David, Nicholas M. Kiefer, Maureen OHara (1996), Cream-
Skimming or Profit-Sharing? The Curious Rule of Purchased Order
Flow, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 51, No. 3, July, pp. 811-833.
Easterbrook, Frank H. and Daniel R. Fischel (1993), Contract and
Fiduciary Duty, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XXXVI, April.
Economides, Nicholas (1993), Network Economics with Application to
Finance, Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments, Vol. 2, No. 5,
December, pp. 89-97.
(1996), The Economics of Networks, International Journal of
Industrial Organization, Vol. 14, pp. 673-699.
226 | REFERENCES
Valiante, Diego (2010), Shaping Reforms and Business Models for the OTC
Derivatives Market: Quo vadis?, ECMI Research Report No. 5, ECMI,
Brussels, April (www.eurocapitalmarkets.org).
Van Cayseele, Patrick and Jo Reynaerts (2010), Complementary
Platforms, under revision, Journal of Network Economies.
Van Cayseele, Patrick and Christophe Wuyts (2006), Measuring Scale
Economies in a Heterogeneous Industry: The case of European Settlement
Institutions, SUERF The European Money and Finance Forum,
Vienna.
(2007), Cost Efficiency in the European Securities Settlement
and Depository Industry, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 31.
Varian, Hal R. (2006), Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach, New
York, NY: W.W. Norton and Company Inc.
Walter, Ingo (2004), Conflicts of Interest and Market Discipline Among
Financial Services Firms, European Management Journal, Vol. 22, No.
4, pp. 361-376.
(2006), Reputational Risk and Conflicts of Interest in Banking and
Finance: The Evidence So Far, Working Paper, Stern School of Business,
NYU, New York, NY, 9 December.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust
Implications A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization, New
York, NY: Free Press.
ANNEX I. LIST OF ACRONYMS
No representatives of issuers associations were formally involved in the work of the Task
222
Force.
223 In particular, organised trading facilities, so-called OTFs (EU COM, 2010b).
240 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 241
242 |
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 243
BME Spanish
SIBE (Electronic) Order-driven Iberclear236 Iberclear237 Vertical
Exchanges
Borsa TradElect Monte Titoli
Order-driven CC&G Vertical
Italiana (Electronic) Euroclear Bank238
Euroclear
EMCF240
Nasdaq OMX INET Nordic Sweden and
Order-driven EuroCCP241 Vertical
Nordic239 (Electronic) Finland, VP
SIX X-clear242
Securities (DK)243
SIX X-clear SIS
SIX Swiss SIX Platform LCH. Clearnet SegaInterSettle246
Order-driven Vertical
Exchange (Electronic) Eurex Clearing244 Clearstream247
EMCF245 Euroclear Bank248
TradElect Oslo Clearing
Oslo Order-driven VPS250
(Electronic) LCH.Clearnet249
OASIS (Integrated
Automatic System Hellenic
Athens Order-driven ATHEXClear S.A. Vertical
for Electronic Exchanges S.A.251
Trading) (Electronic)
WARSET (WARsaw
National
Stock Exchange National Depository
Warsaw Order-driven Depository for Vertical
Trading System) for Securities
Securities
(Electronic)
Oesterreichische
Central
Kontrollbank AG
Vienna Xetra (Electronic) Order-driven Counterparty Vertical
(OeKB)252
Austria (CCP.A)
244 | ANNEXES
UTP (Universal
Banks and
Luxembourg Trading Platform Order-driven LCH.Clearnet Horizontal
ICSDs books
SM) (Electronic)
Central
EBOS (Electronic Central Securities
Securities
Stock Exchange Depositary of the
Bratislava Order-driven Depositary of the Vertical
Trading System) Slovak Republic
Slovak Republic
(Electronic) (CSD SR)
(CSD SR)
Malta Stock Malta Stock
Malta SE Horizon (Electronic) Order-driven Vertical
Exchange CSD Exchange CSD
Lit Pan-
Settlement
European Trading Services Clearing Services Market Model
Services
Venues255
EMCF
Chi-X Platform
Chi-X SIX X-clear National CSDs Horizontal
(Electronic)
LCH.Clearnet256
Millennium EuroCCP
National CSDs
Turquoise Exchange platform SIX X-clear257 Horizontal
Euroclear Bank259
(Electronic) LCH.Clearnet258
LCH.Clearnet260
BATS MTF
BATS Europe Order-driven EMCF National CSDs Horizontal
(Electronic)
SIX X-clear261
Universal Trading LCH.Clearnet262
NYSE Arca
Platform - NYSE Order-driven National CSDs Horizontal
Europe EuroCCP
Euronext systems
246 | ANNEXES
(Electronic)
National CSDs
Xetra Xetra 11.0
Order-driven Eurex Clearing Clearstream Vertical
International (Electronic)
Banking Frankfurt
Nomura NX
Nomura NX Order-driven Nomura NX Nomura NX Vertical
(Electronic)
LCH.Clearnet
Equiduct
Equiduct Order-driven Depending on National CSDs Horizontal
(Electronic)
home market263
Euroclear Sweden
BTP (Burgundy
and Finland, VP
Burgundy Trading Platform) Order-driven EMCF Horizontal
Securities
(Electronic)
Denmark
Six X-clear
UBS MTF UBS MTF Order-driven National CSDs Horizontal
EuroCCP264
224 For latest developments in access and interoperability for clearing and settlement of cash equities between trading platform and
CCPs/CSDs and between CCPs and/or CSDs, please see FESE, EACH & ECSDA, Joint Status Update of the Code of Conduct,
(http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/financial-markets/docs/code/mog/20100315_fese_each_ecsda_en.pdf). There are three types of
access to the infrastructure: standard access (SA); customized unilateral access (CUA or CA); and transaction feed access (TFA).
Interoperability between infrastructures means advanced forms of relationships amongst Organisations where an Organisation is not
generally connecting to existing standard service offerings of the other Organisations but where Organisations agree to establish
customised solutions. Amongst its objectives, Interoperability will aim to provide a service to the customers such that they have choice of
service provider. Such agreement will require Organisations to incur additional technical development. Please, see FESE, EACH and
ECSDA, European Code of Conduct for Clearing and Settlement, 23-24 (http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/financial-
markets/docs/code/code_en.pdf).
225 Firms that showed interest in entering the market (potential competitors) but have not yet been granted the link with incumbent
228 Includes Paris (CAC 40), Amsterdam (AEX), Brussels (BEL 20), and Lisbon (PSI 20).
229 NYSE Euronext has recently decided to terminate its contract with LCH.Clearnet and it will start soon clearing trades in-house;
(http://www.efinancialnews.com/story/2010-05-24/nyse-euronext-challenges-cme).
230 Requested a TFA to Euronext Lisbon, Paris, Amsterdam and Brussels and a TFA to Euroclear Belgium, France and Netherlands, and
Interbolsa.
231 Euroclear Group comprises International Central Securities Depository (ICSD) Euroclear Bank in Brussels and Central Securities
Depositories (CSDs) Euroclear Belgium, Euroclear Finland, Euroclear France, Euroclear Nederland, Euroclear Sweden and Euroclear UK &
Ireland.
232 TFA request from SIX x-clear not live.
233 Part of Link Up Markets, a joint venture by ten leading Central Securities Depositories (CSDs) Clearstream Banking AG Frankfurt
(Germany), Cyprus Stock Exchange (Cyprus), Hellenic Exchanges S.A. (Greece), IBERCLEAR (Spain), MCDR (Egypt), Oesterreichische
Kontrollbank AG (Austria), SIX SIS AG (Switzerland), STRATE (South Africa), VP SECURITIES (Denmark) and VPS (Norway). Its key
objective is to improve efficiency and reduce costs of post-trade processing of cross-border securities transactions by streamlined
interoperability on the CSD layer.
Launched on 30 March 2009, Link Up Markets has established a common infrastructure allowing for streamlined interoperability between
CSD markets and introducing efficient cross-border processing capabilities. The solution enables CSD customers to significantly reduce
the cost gap between settling and safekeeping domestic and foreign securities.
234 TFA with Eurex Clearing requested.
235 Requested TFA with FWB and Eurex, and SA or CA with Clearstream.
236 Iberclear provides risk management services. A project to set up a CCP is in progress, with a consultation open by the Spanish
Supervisor (CNMV).
237 Part of Link Up Markets. See footnote 233 above.
239 Includes Copenhagen (OMX Copenhagen 20, or OMXC20), Stockholm (OMX Stockholm 30 Index, or OMXS30), Helsinki (OMX
241 Not live yet. MoU with Nasdaq OMX to clear equities for Copenhagen, Stockholm and Helsinki.
242 Not live yet. Interoperability between CCPs dealing with trades executed on Nasdaq OMX Nordic (EMCF).
243 Part of Link Up Markets. See footnote 233 above.
244 It requested: TFA and Interoperability with SIX X-clear; interoperability with LCH.CLearnet; and TFA with SIX Platform and SIS
SegaInterSettle.
245 TFA requested.
254 Includes Tallinn (OMX Tallinn, or OMXT), Riga (OMX Riga, or OMXR), and Vilnius (OMX Vilnius, or OMXV).
255 The biggest 11 venues by turnover (Thomson Reuters data; January - May 2010).
264 To be activated when interoperability models have been approved by national authorities.
ANNEX IV. FIGURES AND TABLES
ILLUSTRATING EQUITY MARKETS
20,000,000
15,000,000
10,000,000
5,000,000
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Source: WFE.
| 249
250 | ANNEXES
Source: WFE.
Figure AIV.2 European (10 biggest trading venue) aggregate annual turnover
($ million)
14,000,000
12,000,000
10,000,000
8,000,000
6,000,000
4,000,000
2,000,000
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
MillionEURAnnualTurnover Average
London 22.385%
Frankfurt 16.474%
Paris 15.646%
Milan 9.652%
Zurich 8.443%
Madrid 6.752%
Amsterdam 6.318%
Stockholm 5.409%
Oslo 2.377%
Helsinki 2.065%
Copenhagen 1.128%
Brussels 1.119%
Lisbon 0.467%
Vienna 0.366%
Others 1.399%
Sources: BATS Europe, Thomson Reuters (Jan-Dec 2010, % turnover; lit and auction books).
London
Milan
ChiXEurope
BATSEurope
BolsadeMadrid
NasdaqOMXNordic
Paris
DeutscheBrse
Turquoise
OsloBrs
Amsterdam
Warsaw
SIXSwissExchange
Other
DarkPools
Sources: BATS Europe, Thomson Reuters (Volumes Lit, Auction, Dark Books).
252 | ANNEXES
1.468%
57.22% 34.277%
7.033%
16,000,000
14,000,000
12,000,000
10,000,000
8,000,000
6,000,000
4,000,000
2,000,000
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
GovernmentDebtSecuritiesMarket,Outstanding CorporateDebtSecuritiesMarket,Outstanding
FinancialInstitutionsDebtSecuritiesMaket,Outstanding Securitisedproducts,Outstanding
2,500,000
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
NetIssuanceofGovernmentDebtSecurities NetIssuanceofCorporateDebtSecurities
Securitisedproducts(issuance) NetIssuanceofFinancialInstitutionsDebtSecurities
AggregateSizeofDebt
SecuritiesMarket,
Outstanding
25,000,000
20,000,000
15,000,000
10,000,000 EquityDomestic
GDP
MarketCapitalisation
5,000,000
GlobalOTCDerivatives
EquityTotalValueof
Market,GrossMarket
ShareTrading
Values
20,000,000 AggregateSizeof
Exchangetraded
DebtSecurities
derivatives(th
15,000,000 Market,
contracts)
Outstanding
10,000,000
5,000,000
0
GlobalOTC
AggregateNet
Derivatives
IssuanceofDebt
Market,Gross
Securities
MarketValues
EquityDomestic
EquityTotalValue
Market
ofShareTrading
Capitalisation
2000 2005 2009
Sources: ECMI (2010) data from Eurostat, BIS, WFE,
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 257
450,000
400,000
350,000
300,000
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Exchangetradedderivatives,Outstanding OTCderivatives,Notionalamount
Sources: ECMI (2010), data from BIS, WFE (ETD are estimations by default).
258 | ANNEXES
80,000
70,000
60,000
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Exchangetradedderivatives,Outstanding OTCderivatives,Grossmarketvalue
Sources: ECMI (2010), data from BIS, WFE (ETD are estimations by default).
MIFID 2.0: CASTING NEW LIGHT ON EUROPES CAPITAL MARKETS | 259
Figure AIV.11 Global debt and derivatives markets vs world GDP ( billion)
35,000
30,000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Securitisedproducts,Outstanding GlobalOTCDerivativesMarket,GrossMarketValues(outstanding)
GovernmentDebtSecuritiesMarket,Outstanding CorporateDebtSecuritiesMarket,Outstanding
FinancialInstitutionsDebtSecuritiesMarket,Outstanding WorldGDP
Sourcse: ECMI (2010); data from BIS, Eurostat, World Economic Outlook, AFME.
ANNEX V. TASK FORCE PARTICIPANTS
Disclaimer
The views expressed in this report do not necessarily reflect the views and positions of all
members involved in the Task Force. Members do not necessarily agree with all relevant
undertaken positions and do not necessarily endorse any reference to academic and
independent studies. A sound and clear set of principles has guided the drafting process, in
order to preserve a neutral approach to divergent views. All members views have been
heard and if well-grounded incorporated in the final text. When fundamental
disagreement materialised, the Rapporteurs attempted to explain all views in a proper and
fair manner. Finally, members have received enough time to comment and to contribute to
each version of the Final Report, which can be only attributed to the Rapporteurs and no
one else within the Group. Data included in the text have been generally considered as
material and relevant.
Chair
Pierre Francotte
Former CEO, Euroclear
General Manager, PLF International
Rapporteurs
Members
Ludovic Aigrot Georg Baur
Head of EU Affairs Chair Securities Working Party
NASDAQ OMX European Banking Federation
Jack Vensel
Managing Director
Citi
Observers