Kautilyas1 PDF
Kautilyas1 PDF
Kautilyas1 PDF
D. K. Srivastava*
Abstract
High tax-rates erode their own bases, and thereby adversely affect tax-revenues.
This general idea, which is referred to as the Laffer Curve, can be traced back to Kautilya's
famous treatise on Economics, Arthasastra, and even before that, to the ancient Indian book of
laws called the Manusmriti. This paper considers the basic tenets of taxation prescribed in these
texts and attempts to interpret the tax-rates proposed for different economic activities using Laffer
Curve analytics. In particular, an attempt is made to interpret the core rate of taxation proposed
in these works, viz., one-sixth of the tax-base. The implicit assumption in prescribing moderate
tax-rates appears to indicate the value judgement that in most economic activities, the negative
substitution effect of increasing taxation overpowers the positive income effect, if any, at rather
low tax-rates.
* The author is Professor at the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi.
ON THE MANU-KAUTILYA NORMS OF TAXATION: AN INTERPRETATION
USING LAFFER CURVE ANALYTICS
I. INTRODUCTION
The capacity of high tax-rates to erode their own tax-bases, leading to a parabolic
relationship between tax-rates and tax-revenues, has often been discussed in recent times in terms
of the Laffer Curve. The realization that an inverse relationship may exist between tax-rates and
tax-bases, and consequently between tax-rates and tax-revenues, beyond some critical levels of
tax-rates, is not entirely new. Specific passages in Adam Smith [1776] and Dupuit [1844] cited,
for example, in Fullerton [1982] indicate precisely these ideas. The fourteenth century Arabic
philosopher Ibn Khaldun, translated by Rosenthal [1967] and quoted extensively in Lipsey [1989]
had discussed these ideas at length. Much earlier to these sources, explicit references to the ideas
now summarily referred to under the rubric of the Laffer Curve are, in fact, obtained in Kautilya's
famous treatise on Economics, entitled Arthasastra1 (3rd Century B.C.) and even before that, in
the ancient Indian book of laws called the Manusmriti.2 Both works, keeping in perspective the
base-eroding capacity of high rates of taxes, emphatically stress moderate taxation. They had
prescribed, in great detail, relevant rates of taxes for specified economic activities. These tax-
rates, which are written as proportions or percentages, are specific numbers. Although one comes
across an array of tax-rates, there are only a few core tax-rates. Among these, the tax-rate of
one-sixth (16.667 per cent) is the key tax-rate applicable to domestic trade and economic
activities. While discussing the basic tenets of taxation prescribed in the Manu-Kautilya treatises,
it has been argued in this paper that it is possible to provide a specific interpretation to the core
tax-rate determined by them, which may be referred to as the Manu-Kautilya rate of taxation, by
using analytical tools appropriate for Laffer Curve analytics.
The outline of this paper is as follows. Section II discusses the ideas pertaining
to taxation in Arthasastra as well as Manusmriti by referring to the relevant slokas and Sutras in
the text. Section III identifies the tax-rates prescribed for different categories of tax-bases in the
two works. A methodology for a general specification of the Laffer Curve that may more
2
generally be called a rate-Revenue (rR) function is proposed in Section IV. Using this
methodology, an attempt is made to interpret the core Manu-Kautilya tax-rate in Section V. The
most attractive interpretation identifies it as a point of inflexion on the Laffer Curve. There is a
kind of universality in the proposed number which transcends both time and space. Section VI
concludes the paper.
Earlier, in Sloka 80 of the same Chapter [7], it has been said that the tax should be annual, and
that it should be collected by reliable functionaries. In collecting the tax, the King should be fair
between his subjects, as fair as a father, between his sons.
The King should never overtax. Taxation should never be detrimental to the
spontaneous growth of the tax base. Metaphors of a leech, bee and calf are used to bring this
point home.
3
"Just like a leech, calf and bee draw only small-but-very-small
quantities from their respective feeds (i.e., blood, milk and honey),
similarly a King should, by his orders, take from his subjects, very
small amounts of taxes" [7.129].
In the examples of leech, calf and bee, the amount drawn is always too small to be detrimental to
the growth of the base. Similarly, taxation should be moderate enough to be conducive to the
growth of the tax-base. Further on, in the same chapter, in Sloka 139, a warning is issued against
excessive `tax-greed' that will destroy the productive base of the system.
"The King should not destroy his own roots, and the roots of his
subjects by excessive greed, because the King, destroying his own
roots, and the roots of his subjects, makes himself and his people
suffer" [7.139].
"He (the King) should take from the kingdom, fruits as they ripen,
as from a garden, avoiding taking unripe fruits, for that will be
self-destructive, and cause an uprising against him" [5.2.70].
4
The rates are usually in terms of proportions (percentages). Important Slokas wherein Manu has
indicated the tax-rates, that are often different for different categories of tax-bases, and also
contain some elements of progressivity, are given below. Chapter 7 of the Smriti, in Slokas 130,
131 and 132, contain the prescribed tax-rates.
"The tax of the King for animals and gold (in excess of the initial
amount) shall be 1/50th part, and for grains it will be 1/6th, 1/8th
or 1/12th part (the latter ones for less fertile lands)" [7.130].
Here, the general rate prescribed for agricultural produce is 1/6th. Lower rates
(1/8th and 1/12th) are for less fertile land. The same rate has been specified for a host of other
goods. Thus,
In Slokas 137 and 138, several categories of people are indicated, where
concessional rates are to be applied or exemptions are to be given. It is clear that with some
exceptions (1/8th or 1/12th for less fertile lands, and 1/50th for animals and gold), the general rate
of taxation prescribed by Manu is 1/6th of the tax-base.
The entitlement to the King of one-sixth share of the activities of his subjects,
appears to have a `divine' sanction in Manusmriti. It transcends mere taxation of economic
activities, and characterises even the sharing of the fruits of `dharma' and `adharma' of his
subjects, i.e., the (intangible) fruits of the good and prescribed deeds, as also the fruits
(punishments) of bad and proscribed deeds of his subjects. Thus,
5
deeds (adharma) of his subjects" [8.304].
And "From among the subjects residing in his kingdom, the King who
protects his subjects well, obtains one-sixth of the fruits of good
deeds performed by his subjects, like the reading of Vedas,
performing of Yajnas, giving of donations and worship of devas"
[8.305].
In the Kautilya Arthasastra, the general principles of taxation and the rates of
taxation are given in Part 2 Chapter 22 and additional principles for the `replenishment of treasury'
(in times of emergency, war, etc., which may have caused an excessive outflow from the treasury)
are given in Part 5 Chapter 2.
In Part 2, Chapter 22, Sutras 3-8 prescribe these tax-rates. Sutra 3 states:
"On goods coming in (the duty shall be) one-fifth of the price" [2.22.3].
This is the highest duty prescribed in the Arthasastra and applies to `imports' from
outside the kingdom. It is an ad-valorem duty. For goods produced within the kingdom, a slight
edge is provided with lower rates. Thus, Sutra 4, gives the rate as 1/6th. It states:
6
[2.22.7].
In the Arthasastra, thus, the following rates have been proposed: 1/5th for
imports, and 1/6th for domestic production, with the lower rates of 1/10th, 1/15th, 1/20th and
1/25th for specified categories of goods. In Book 1, Chapter 13 of Arthasastra, there is a
reference to 1/6th as being a general rate. It is said "Therefore, even forest-dwellers offer a sixth
part of their gleaned grains (saying, `This is the share for him who protects us')" [1.13.9].
In Manusmriti, quite clearly, the preferred rate of tax is 1/6th. This is also the core
rate of taxation in Kautilya's Arthasastra. But imports have to pay a rate higher than this, and for
certain preferred categories of goods, the tax-bases of which are to be encouraged, lower rates
are prescribed. There is some provision for variation within the same category, e.g., those
covered in Sutras 6 and 7.
The relationship between tax-rates, and the tax-revenues that they generate over
the entire range from zero to hundred per cent, can be summarised in terms of rate-Revenue (rR)
functions. An example of such a relationship in the context of an income or wage tax is the Laffer
Curve which describes a parabolic relationship between tax-rates and tax-revenues. In principle,
it is possible to visualise the existence of a rate-Revenue function for each tax, whether direct or
indirect, although various alternative shapes of the function may be derived for different taxes.
7
Assuming that a single rate (r) pertains to a tax-base (B), revenue from the concerned tax may be
written as
R = rB (1)
The tax-base, may be considered to be a function of a number of variables (Xj ) including the tax-
rate itself. All the other variables are assumed to be independent of r and R, and their values are
taken to be given. Thus,
The rate-revenue function would thus describe how revenues would change as the concerned tax-
rate changes from zero to its maximum possible value, treating other determinants of the tax-base
as exogenous. Should any of these change, the entire rate-Revenue function would need to be
shifted appropriately.
B = o + 1 r + 2 r2 + ....... + n rn (3)
The influence of the exogenous variables, being held constant, is summarised in the constant term.
Without loss of generality, the terms used in (3) can be normalised with respect to o. Defining,
Y = /o and i = i /o (i = 1, ..., n)
Y = 1 + 1 r + .... + n rn (4)
This procedure enables one to use the output (tax-base) which would obtain when
8
the tax-rate is zero as a unit of measurement. Thus, in (4), when r = 0, Y = 1. Any change in Y,
is now brought about solely through changes in the tax-rates. Thus, for any given r, if Y = 1.5,
it would mean, that the tax-base is 1.5 times what it would be in the absence of taxation, given
a set of exogenous variables. Assuming that the tax-rate can vary in the range of (0, 1), we may
specify the rate-base relationship in a general way by using the following version of Rolle's
theorem:
This theorem is required to ensure that the tax-base does not continuously decline
as the tax-rate increases. Rather, at first the tax-base increases as the tax-rate increases, reaches
a peak and then continuously declines, becoming zero, at hundred per cent rate of taxation.
Because of the existence of a peak, there must exist a tax-rate at which Y would become equal
to its value at r = 0, i.e., the revenue initiating point, as depicted in Figure 1.
There are sound economic reasons why for direct as well as indirect taxes, the tax-
base may at first increase as the tax-rate increases, and subsequently decline, continuously.
In the construction of a Laffer Curve for an income tax, it has been recognised
that the imposition of a tax on income has both a substitution effect and an income effect. The
imposition of a tax on income induces people to substitute leisure for labour, thereby having a
negative impact on income. On the other hand, over some range, people are
FIGURE 1
9
induced to work harder in order to maintain their post-tax income, thereby generating an income
effect. Beyond a certain range, the substitution effect dominates the income effect, leading to a
continuous decline in the tax-base. But as long as the income effect is larger than the substitution
effect, which is expected over low rates of taxation, the tax-base function may rise.
A quadratic function in r is necessary and sufficient to ensure a single peak for the
tax-base function in the range of r = (0, 1). A special form for equation (4) may be defined as
Y = 1 + r (1 + ) r2, 0 (5)
10
its peak shifts to the right. To identify the maximum, we have
from which
Install Equation Editor and double- (6)
click here to view equation.
The revenue function corresponding to the base function given by (5) may be written as
R = r + r2 (1 + ) r3 (7)
This specification ensures that tax-revenues are zero when the tax-rate, r = 0.
Further, R = 0, also when r = 1, i.e., when hundred per cent of the tax-base is taxed. At this rate,
the base becomes zero.
From this,
This function may be interpreted as the marginal revenue function. R itself has a maximum, when
11
Install Equation Editor and double-
click here to view equation.
Beyond, r*, the marginal rate of Revenue, begins to decline. This means that beyond r*, tax-
revenue increases at a decreasing rate.
It is with the positive root in the above expression that the second order condition for a maximum
is satisfied.
Since the tax-base (Y), total tax-revenue (R) and marginal tax-revenue
Install Equation Editor and double-
click here to view equation. , are all functions of the tax-rate, they can be drawn in a vertical
sequence, as shown in Figure 2. In this figure, the tax-rates r*, r(Rmax) and r(Ymax) have been
indicated respectively as rR, rR and rY. The aggregate revenue function (Figure 2a) can be divided
into three distinct ranges. In part I, aggregate revenue increases at an increasing rate as the tax-
rate increases. In part II, aggregate revenue increases at a decreasing rate. Part III provides the
inefficient part of the revenue function where tax-revenues decline as tax-rates continue to
increase.
The core Manu-Kautilya rate is 1/6th of the value of the tax-base (income or value
of commodity), i.e., 16.667 per cent. Lower and higher rates are prescribed in exceptional cases.
12
Install Equation Editor and double- (12)
click here to view equation.
At this point the marginal revenue curve (R_) also reaches a maximum. Beyond this point
revenues continue to grow but at a decreasing rate.
Although other interpretations of this rate are possible, it is attractive to interpret the Manu-
Kautilya rate of taxation as the point of inflexion on the rate-revenue (rR) function. An alternative
is to interpret this rate as a base maximising rate. For a value of =0.5, r(Ymax)=/[2(1+)]=1/6.
In other words, for all commodities or tax-bases where lies between 0.5 and 1, the tax-rate of
1/6 will lie between the point where the marginal revenue curve has a maximum and the point
where the tax-base would be a maximum. The judgement that is involved in the prescription of
the Manu-Kautilya tax-rate for a given tax-base are thus the following:
i. that for most commodities (or tax-bases), the value of is likely to be low;
and
ii. that it is useful to remain in the range where, at one extreme, marginal tax-
revenue starts falling and, at the other, where the tax-base stops
increasing.
Figure
13
Manu-Kautilya have argued for a low-rate of taxation, which is far below the
revenue maximising tax-rate, synonymous with the "greed" of the taxing authority. Further, the
tax-rate should be low enough to lead to a growth in the tax-base. Thus, the relevant tax-rate
should not go beyond the base-maximising rate and should be less than the revenue-maximising
tax-rate. It can be established that the point of inflexion is to the left of both the base - and
revenue maximising tax-rates. In fact,
or if ( + 2)2 > 0
which is true.
Y = 1 + r - 2r2.
This is a highly symmetric function where at 50 per cent rate of taxation, the tax-base falls back
to the initial level achievable in the pre-tax situation. The base is maximised at r = 0.25. Beyond
14
this point, the tax-base starts falling, reaching the revenue initiation level (r = 0) at r = 0.5. Thus,
with = 1, a typical tax-base function is obtained, divided into three distinct parts over the ranges
of r from 0 to 0.25, 0.25 to 0.5, and 0.5 to 1.
It may be noted that the tax-rate of one-sixth is derived in a manner such that it
is independent of the specific circumstances of a country and time which are captured in the
constant term (`' in equation 3, which refers to what the output would be when no tax is levied).
All production and technological conditions are captured within this term. The only parameter
on which the tax-rate depends is `', which relates to the responsiveness of the tax-base to tax-
rate changes.4 Given a benchmark value of , the general rate of tax is prescribed.
While moderate taxation is not detrimental to the growth of the tax-base and may,
in fact, augment it, excessively high tax-rates are self-debilitating. They lead to a depletion of the
tax-base as well as tax-revenues. These ideas form the basis of the Laffer Curve. In this paper,
an attempt is made to trace back these ideas to the ancient Indian texts dated as far back as 1000
B.C. to 300 B.C. It is contended that not only the general principles of taxation enunciated by
Manu and Kautilya have relevance even today, the specific tax-rates which they prescribed,
especially for domestic economic activities, can be interpreted in terms of modern Laffer Curve
analytics.
15
* The author would like to thank Shri Satish Kamath and Shri R. S. Tyagi for adept
computational and secretarial assistance, respectively.
Notes
2. Most Smriti literature is considered to have been written during the period from 1000 B.C.
to 400 B.C. Manusmriti is acknowledged to be the oldest of them and most authentic.
Subsequent Smritis derive extensively from the Manusmriti.
qd = A Bp
qs = a + bp (1 r)
where r is the tax-rate and p is the tax inclusive price paid by the buyer. The quantity
traded and equilibrium price are given by:
Also,
16
if Ab(1 r) > B(A + 2a)
Thus, the tax-base would increase from 0 to r** as the tax-rate increases, provided r**
> 0.
4. It may be noted that as increases, the rate at which tax-base is maximised, shifts to the
right. When = 0, r(Ymax) = 0. As ~ , r(Ymax) = . As such parameter captures
the relative strength of the income effect vis-a-vis the substitution effect generated by
increase in tax-rates. The higher is the value of , the larger is the income effect. Beyond
the base-maximising tax-rate, the base-eroding capacity of increasing tax-rates becomes
overpowering. In concentrating on low values of in the range ( to 1), the implicit
assumption appears to be that in most economic activities, the negative substitution effect
of increasing taxation sets in quite early.
17
References
Dupuit, Jules, (1844), "On the Measurement of the Utility of Public Works", translated in K. J.
Arrow and T. Scitovsky (eds.), Readings in Welfare Economics, 1969.
Fullerton, Don, (1982), "On the Possibility of an Inverse Relationship Between Tax-Rates and
Government Revenues, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 3-22.
Kangle, R. P., (1972), "The Kautilya Arthasastra, Part II", University of Bombay (1st edition
1963).
Lipsey, R. G., (1989), "An Introduction to Positive Economics", 7th Edition, Weidenfeld and
Nicholson, London.
18
kautilya/15.3.99
19