Ucalgary 2013 Kano Liena
Ucalgary 2013 Kano Liena
Ucalgary 2013 Kano Liena
by
Liena Kano
A THESIS
CALGARY, ALBERTA
JULY, 2013
in internalization and transaction cost economics (TCE) theories, for firm-level strategic
family firm, the multidivisional corporation, and the multinational enterprise. Further, I
CIA to the above subject matter. More specifically, the eight studies address: 1) the
CIA provides a valuable conceptual lens to explicate the essence of strategic governance;
I hope that this dissertation has laid a foundation for a unified CIA approach that brings
together various streams of literature, namely work in the realm of international business,
! ii
!
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
My deepest gratitude goes to all those who helped me fulfill my academic dream.
I would like to thank my family, starting with my husband Grant Huszti, who has
patiently supported me through many years of graduate school and acted as a single
parent too many times over the past four and a half years. I wish to thank my daughters
Miriam and Naomi for being my cheerleaders, and a daily source of joy. Finally, I would
like to thank my parents Dita and Lev Kano for teaching me how to learn at a very young
age, encouraging my intellectual curiosity, and supporting me unconditionally in
everything I do. My parents looked after my kids, walked my dog, and cooked dinner for
my family while I studied; their help allowed me to fulfil the requirements of the PhD
program without the rest of my world falling apart.
On the academic side, I would like to sincerely thank my research supervisor, Dr.
Alain Verbeke, for his generous support and exceptional level of involvement throughout
my PhD studies. Alain helped me find my research path, motivated and inspired me,
challenged me intellectually, and ultimately made my time in the program enjoyable and
productive. Everything that I have achieved in my short academic career I owe to Alain’s
clear guidance and wise council. I am looking forward to being his research colleague
for many years to come. Many thanks go to Dr. Loren Falkenberg, our Associate Dean
Research, for her enduring and vocal support of my work, as well as for her monumental
(and successful!) effort to enhance the PhD program experience for our entire cohort. I
am grateful to the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada, the
Faculty of Graduate Studies and Haskayne School of Business for generous financial
support. I would like to thank my supervisory committee members Dr. Birgitte Grøgaard
and Dr. Teri Bryant, my external-internal examiner Dr. Hetty Roessingh, and my external
examiner Dr. Bernard Wolf for the time and effort devoted to the process, and for their
helpful guidance and feedback. I would also like to thank Birgitte for her enormous
support during my first teaching term (including answering panicked phone calls). Last
but not least, I would like to thank Dr. Daphne Taras and Dr. Nicole Coviello, my role
models and mentors of many years. Nicole in particular inspired me to become an
academic, and has been coaching and encouraging me, unwaveringly, since we first met
fourteen years ago. I would not be writing this thesis if it were not for Nicole.
! iii
!
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ABSTRACT ii
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS iii
LIST OF TABLES viii
LIST OF FIGURES ix
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS x
INTRODUCTION 1
ESSAY 1. INTERNALIZATION THEORY AS THE GENERAL THEORY OF 13
INTERNATIONAL STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT: PAST, PRESENT AND FUTURE
INTRODUCTION 13
INTERNALIATION THEORY: ESSENTIAL ARGUMENT, ANTCEDENTS AND HISTORY 15
EVOLUTION OF INTERNALIATION THEORY 21
Entry mode choice 21
MNE’s international expansion strategy: The four dimensions of distance 26
MNE internal governance: Differentiated network MNE 27
MNE internal governance: M-form versus metanational solution 29
Theory of regional strategy and structure 30
Internalization theory and evolutionary view of the MNE 32
Multinationality-performance relationship 35
A note on the changing nature of FSAs 36
Section conclusion: Internalization theory in four types of international strategic 38
management research
THE FUTURE OF INTERNALIZATION THEORY: A FEW EXTENSIONS 40
International entrepreneurship and ‘born-globals’ 40
Emerging economy MNEs 43
CONCLUSION 49
ESSAY 2. AN INTERNALIZATION THEORY RATIONALE FOR MNE REGIONAL 52
STRATEGY
INTRODUCTION 52
ALTERNATIVE INTERPRETATION OF REGIONALIZATION PROPOSITIONS 55
H1 (based on the theory of new regionalism) 55
H2 (based on the theory of new economic geography) 57
H3a and 3b (based on the theory of the knowledge economy) 60
H4a, 4b and 4c (based on psychic distance theory) 63
H5 (based on escalating-commitment theory) 68
H6 (based on population ecology) 70
H7a and 7b (based on neo-institutional theory) 71
! iv
!
EXISTING EMPIRICAL SUPPORT AND POTENTIAL EMPIRICAL TESTS 74
CONCLUSION 76
ESSAY 3. NO NEW THEORY NEEDED TO STUDY MNEs FROM EMERGING ECONOMIES 79
INTRODUCTION 79
INTERNALIZATION THEORY: PAST AND PRESENT 81
A QUEST FOR NEW THEORIES TO STUDY EMNEs 87
INTERNALIZATION THEORY AS A GENERAL THEORY OF THE MNE: DEBUNKING 89
THE MYTHS
Internalization theory ≠ Static focus on transaction costs in established MNEs 89
Institutional differences are reflected in transaction costs 90
EMNEs do possess FSAs 91
Motivations for internationalization are addressed in the context of matching FSAs with 95
CSAs
ILLUSTRATION: ‘WORLD CLASS EMERGING MULTINATIONALS’ 96
FSAs 97
Recombination capabilities 100
Internationalization drivers 101
AN IMPORTANT NUANCE: STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES 102
CONCLUSION 105
ESSAY 4. TRANSACTION COST ECONOMIZING AND THE RISE OF THE MODERN 108
CORPORATION: REVISITING THE NATURE OF MAN IN ALFRED CHANDLER’S
OEUVRE
INTRODUCTION 108
TCE AND CHANDLER 112
THE ENVELOPE-CONCEPT OF BOUNDED RELIABILITY (BREL) 116
METHODOLOGY 118
Data 118
Theory building 119
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION 121
BRel in the making of the modern corporation: Extant categories 121
The extended model: New categories of benevolent preference reversal 127
IMPLICATONS 138
CONTRIBUTIONS, LIMITATIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH 140
ESSAY 5. TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS AND THE FAMILY FIRM 146
INTRODUCTION 146
TCE AND THE FAMILY FIRM 147
BEHAVIOURAL ASSUMPTIONS OF TCE: INTRODUCING BOUNDED RELIABILITY 150
BOUNDED RATIONALITY, BOUNDED RELIABILITY AND THE FAMILY FIRM 152
!v
!
CONCLUSION 160
ESSAY 6. THE TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS THEORY OF THE FAMILY FIRM: 162
FAMILY-BASED HUMAN ASSET SPECIFICITY AND THE BIFURCATION BIAS
INTRODUCTION 162
BEHAVIOURAL ASSUMPTIONS OF TCE 167
TCE AND THE FAMILY FIRM 170
BIFURCATION BIAS 173
Bifurcation bias as an effect of family firm professionalization 173
Bifurcation bias and the agency/stewardship paradox 174
Psychological origins of bifurcation bias 178
Bifurcation bias and transaction cost economics behavioural assumptions 179
Bifurcation bias in managerial practice 181
When is the bifurcation bias important? 189
CONCLUSION 193
LIMITATIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH 195
ESSAY 7. THE TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS THEORY OF TRADING FAVOURS 198
INTRODUCTION 198
TRANSACTION COST ECONOMICS’ FOUNDATIONAL CONCEPTS 202
Main tenets 202
Core assumptions 203
Extending behavioural assumptions of TCE: Bounded reliability 204
TRADING FAVOURS: ORIGINS, FOUNDATIONS, AND MANIFESTATIONS 206
Anthropological, economic and cultural foundations 206
Manifestations of trading favours in Russia and China: Blat and guanxi 209
TCE-BASED THEORY OF TRADING FAVOURS 212
Working definition and key questions 212
When is trading favours efficient 214
What enforcement mechanisms facilitate trading favours? 222
Types and impacts of trading favours 224
CONCLUSION 229
ESSAY 8. STRATEGIC GOVERNANCE FOR SUSTAINABILITY: EXPLORING THE 235
NATURE OF SUSTAINABILITY CRISES
INTRODUCTION 236
STRATEGIC GOVERNANCE FOR SUSTAINABILITY 238
RESEARCH SETTING: SUSTAINABILITY CRISES 240
RESEARCH QUESTIONS 242
RQ1: Why do sustainability crises occur? 242
! vi
!
RQ2: How do the three pillars of sustainability interact in a crisis situation? 243
RQ3: How does entrepreneurial action affect sustainability crises and their mitigation? 243
METHODOLOGY 244
Data 244
Theory building 247
WHY DO CRISES OCCUR? THREE BROAD THEMES 249
THE ROLE OF ENTREPRENEURIAL CONTEXT: THE ENTREPRENEURSHIP-CRISIS 250
MODEL
Directly unproductive profit-seeking crisis (DUP) 252
Unintended negative spillovers (UNS) 255
Entrepreneurship-sustainability crisis cycle 259
THE ROLE OF THE ECONOMIC PILLAR AND INTER-PILLAR SPILLOVERS 262
Economic pillar as a crisis catalyst 262
Inter-pillar spillovers 263
BENEVOLENT CONFLICT AMONG STAKEHOLDERS 264
A NOTE ON STRATEGIC GOVERNANCE 266
IMPLICATIONS AND CONTRIBUTIONS 267
LIMITATIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH 271
CONCLUSION 272
THESIS CONCLUSION 282
REFERENCES 288
APPENDIX 3.1. Cases analyzed on the ten EMNEs 320
APPENDIX 3.2. Inventory of EMNE FSAs, home country LAs, host country CSAs, and 323
internationalization drivers
APPENDIX 4.1. Corporate backgrounds: Du Pont and General Motors 330
APPENDIX 8.1. Cases analyzed on the twelve MNEs involved in sustainability crises 333
!
! vii
!
LIST OF TABLES
3.1 EMNE motivation for international expansion versus existing motivation 107
framework
4.1 Commitment continuum for the extended model of bounded reliability 143
!viii
!
LIST OF FIGURES
7.1 Trading favours U-curve hypothesis for the macro level 233
! ix
!
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
AC Air conditioning
EU European Union
HP Hewlett-Packard Company
HQ Headquarters
HR Human resources
!x
!
IB International business
LA Location advantage
! xi
!
UNS Unintended negative spillovers
! xii
!
INTRODUCTION
on the premise that economic actors will select and retain the most efficient governance
select economic institutions (markets versus firms versus clans), as well as coordination
and control methods (the price system versus hierarchy versus normative integration) that
are the most efficient for organizing a given transaction or set of transactions (Hennart,
1993).
CIA therefore offers an explanation for the existence of firms: Firms are
purposefully created when able to organize production more efficiently than other
management is the view of the firm as not only a nexus of contractual relationships
linking various resource owners, but also as a governance form specialized in value
from choosing the appropriate, economizing mix of internal contracts and contracts with
actors outside of the firm’s boundaries. This mix of contracts may need adjustments over
uncertainty, etc. and/or economic actors’ decisions, such as an intentional shift towards
which economic exchange takes place, including the processes associated with the
exchange (Zaheer & Venkatraman, 1995). At the macro level, firms that populate
1
!
industries and national economic systems can be considered mechanisms of governance,
as discussed above. At the micro level, an important distinction must be made between
structural governance and strategic governance. The former refers to the actual
economic actors’ routines or other managerial practices being deployed within a given
type of organizational structure (Zaheer & Venkatraman, 1995; Schmidt & Brauer, 2006).
In other words, strategic governance is largely about orchestrating the usage of a firm’s
resources through routines and other processes in relation to strategic decisions that have
long-term implications for the firm. This manuscript is mainly concerned with strategic
governance, which unfolds within certain types of organizational structures but can also
economics (TCE) theory (Williamson, 1975, 1981a, 1981b, 1985, 1991, 1996) and its
international business (IB) version – internalization theory (Buckley and Casson, 1976),
internalization theory share the same economic essence of CIA, namely that economic
actors will select and retain the most efficient governance mechanisms to conduct
transactions, but differ slightly in their emphasis and applications, as well as their units of
analysis, as discussed in detail in this thesis. With the main concern of both theories (and
of the CIA approach to the study of the firm) being the selection and retention of the most
2
!
efficient forms of governance, the most critical decisions related to selection and
1. Establishing boundaries of the firm – that is, the ‘make or buy’ decisions (Grøgaard &
the firm, and which should be conducted outside of the firm in the external market;
2. Organizing the interface with the external environment for the ‘buy’ activities, i.e.,
activities transacted in the external market; this may involve choosing among short
3. Organizing ‘make’ activities, i.e., activities performed inside the firm; this involves
Given the three sets of decisions defined above, the comparatively more efficient
rational, but only limitedly so” (Simon, 1961: xxiv), meaning that human actors have
choices;
reliable, but only limitedly so (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009) and explains instances of
3
!
commitment non-fulfillment and failure to make good on open-ended promises in an
organizational setting;
As such, strategic governance choices, in the context of the CIA approach, could
be presented in the form of a 3x3 matrix, distinguishing among three key components of
strategic governance and three main objectives pursued through strategic governance, as
strategic governance context in each cell of Figure I.1. More specifically, my research
organizational settings, from family firms to large multinational enterprises (MNEs), and
conceptual and empirical applications of CIA to the above types of subject matter. As a
set, the eight essays cover all cells of the strategic governance matrix, as outlined below:
4
!
Essay 1. Internalization theory as the general theory of international strategic
management
theory’s impact on IB research. In particular, this essay lays out essential arguments of
internalization theory, reviews its history and intellectual foundations, and discusses its
key applications in the field of international business, such as, inter alia, analysis of the
MNE’s entry mode choice, international expansion strategy, internal governance, and
1 sets the stage for the matrix and covers all cells (cells 1 – 9 in Figure I.1).
theory of the firm, is particularly well equipped to analyze MNE regional strategies,
which are seen as the most efficient strategic governance responses to economizing
challenges that exist outside of a firm’s home region. The argument is built upon recent
work by Wolf, Egelhoff, and Dunemann (2012) to show that internalization theory’s
predictions on MNE regional strategy are superior to those suggested by several other
conceptual frameworks. In terms of the strategic governance matrix, the essay focuses on
5
!
Essay 3. No new theory needed to study MNEs from emerging economies
on MNEs’ strategic governance choices hold in the emerging economy setting, I analyze
ten successful large EMNEs. In the strategic governance matrix, Essay 3 focuses on
establishing firm boundaries (the first row: 1, 4, 7), but with interactions with internal and
Essay 4. Transaction cost economizing and the rise of the modern corporation:
reliability (BRel) in the historical context of the rise of the modern corporation,
elaborating on Verbeke and Greidanus’ (2009) original framework. The model augments
explain failed human commitments. I revisit Alfred Chandler’s classic history of the Du
Pont and General Motors corporations (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971) to investigate
whether opportunism was a key factor in the making of the modern corporation. The
essential argument is that BRel corresponds more accurately to Chandler’s view of the
6
!
BRel as a central concept for the study of the firm may increase the legitimacy of TCE.
In terms of the strategic governance matrix, Essay 4 focuses on interactions between firm
boundaries and internal organization (the first and second rows: 1, 4, 7 and 2, 5, 8), with
In this essay I further explore the concept of BRel developed in Essay 4, this time
in the context of the family firm. The objective of this essay is to investigate how the
nature of BRel challenges in a family firm may differ from that in a traditional
Chandlerian hierarchy (such as the Du Pont and General Motors corporations analyzed in
Essay 4). The essay uses Gedajlovic and Carney’s (2010) application of TCE to family
business as a starting point, and lays a foundation for developing a unified TCE-based
theory of the family firm by introducing the concept of family-based human asset
Essay 6. The TCE theory of the family firm: Family-based human asset specificity and
This essay continues the foray into family business theory. Here, the objective is
to build upon the concept of family-based human asset specificity developed in the
previous essay to arrive at a full-fledged TCE-based theory of the family firm in an effort
from failing ones, in strategic governance terms. The central concept developed in this
7
!
examination of real-life family business cases, this conceptual study suggests that
matrix, Essay 5 focuses on internal organization (the second row: 2, 5, 8), but with
implications for decisions related to the boundaries of the firm (the first row: 1, 4, 7), as
well as for interfaces with external actors (the third row: 3, 6, 9).
study blends EMNE analysis and BRel development conducted in the previous essays to
efficiency purposes. Micro and macro level implications and spillovers of trading favours
are also discussed. This essay focuses mainly on interactions with external environment
crises
studies, amplified by a host of corporate governance scandals that have occurred over the
past decade. In this empirical essay, I analyze twelve high profile cases of corporate
sustainability crises in large MNEs. In each case a crisis linked to either social,
8
!
actors, the environment and the firm involved (in terms of performance and negative
reputation effects). Specifically, I look at (1) the role of BRel and BRat in the origination
of the crises; (2) spillovers of both causes and consequences of the crises among the three
pillars of sustainability (economic, social and environmental); and (3) the role of
entrepreneurial context in the crises. I find that various concepts developed and explored
in the prior essays, such as conditions exacerbating BRel and BRat, bifurcation bias (in
cases of family ownership) and favour-trading, play a role in the origination and
focuses on internal and external organization (the second and third rows: 2, 5, 8 and 3, 6,
9), with possible implications for firm boundary changes (the first row: 1, 4, 7).
As can be seen from the above synopses, all eight essays touch upon all three
objectives of strategic governance (that is, the two economizing objectives and the
higher-order capability in managing the innovation process in its entirety in the columns
of the matrix) to a certain extent. However, each essay has a specific starting point of
capability. Figure I.2 depicts how the eight essays fit within the matrix (here, the numbers
refer to the essays’ order in the dissertation, and not to matrix cells as in Figure I.1). As
most of the concepts and issues are interrelated, the boundaries between the cells become
somewhat blurred – hence the lack of visible borders in the matrix. In other words, the
essays are placed in the matrix according to the starting point and the main focus of the
analysis, but the reader should remember that sets of implications and interactions likely
9
!
It should be noted that the only section of the matrix not covered (other than by
the foundational first essay) is the top right corner, which focuses on firm boundary
changes decisions with the objective of managing innovation in its entirety. Work that
would fit in this section includes, for example, strategic governance analysis of mergers
and acquisitions, and strategic alliances. Research on this topic is abundant and falls
To date, five of the eight essays have been published. Essay 1 is forthcoming as a
Press. Essay 2 was published in Multinational Business Review in 2012. Essays 5 and 6
were published in Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice in 2010 and 2012, respectively.
Essay 7 was published in the Asia Pacific Journal of Management in 2013. Essay 3 was
(USA), and was included in the conference proceedings, while Essay 4 is scheduled for
Arguments developed in all eight essays build upon key tenets of CIA, embodied
different academic outlets (albeit united by the common strategic governance matrix), the
eight papers include brief reviews of theory and key concepts in order to facilitate a
logical flow from assumptions to conclusions, and therefore, some necessary overlap
exists among the eight essays, especially between the introductory Essay 1 and Essay 3
10
!
on EMNEs (see footnote on the overlapping section, in Essay 1). I have retained the
individual essay.
The following sections of the dissertation contain the eight essays introduced
above, followed by an overall conclusion and suggested potential research avenues that
logically stem from the analysis conducted and the concepts developed in this thesis.
11
!
Figure I.1. Strategic governance matrix
of firm boundary 1 4 7
changes
components
Strategic governance
2 5 8
inside the firm
Strategic governance
3 6 9
of external interfaces
8:SC
Strategic governance
of external interfaces
7: TF
!
1. Internalization theory as the general theory of international strategic management (IT)
2. An internalization theory rationale for MNE regional strategies (R)
3. No new theory needed to study MNEs form emerging economies (EM)
4. Transaction cost economizing and the rise of the modern corporation: Revisiting the
nature of man in Alfred Chandler’s oeuvre (AC)
Essays
12
!
Essay 1
research. The essay lays out essential arguments of internalization theory, reviews its
history and intellectual foundations, and discusses its key applications in the field of
international business, such as, inter alia, analysis of the multinational enterprise’s
(MNE’s) entry mode choice, international expansion strategy, internal governance, and
stimulating firms’ cross-border activity and entry mode choices, and ‘new’ or
internalization theory can enrich scholars’ understanding of a wide range of new and
emerging issues, both in IB and in the broader field of strategic management. The essay
management research.
INTRODUCTION
functioning of MNEs during the past four decades (Buckley & Strange, 2011).
13
!
Internalization theory’s key point, as a positive theory of the firm, is that exploiting and
determine the ‘optimal’ mode to be selected and retained. International activities are
foundations, and first formulated in Buckley and Casson’s (1976) classic work, the
internalization approach has strongly influenced the international business (IB) literature
since its inception (Safarian, 2003). The theory has been the subject of substantial
scholarly dialogue, and various refinements and extensions have made it the analytical
tool par excellence for the study of international strategic management decisions, more
specifically in the context of three types of governance choices: (1) the choice of the
firm’s boundaries; (2) the structuring of the interfaces with the external environment; and
(3) the firm’s internal organization (see Casson, 1979, 1986, 1987; Rugman, 1981;
internalization theory, exemplified by the work of Buckley and Casson (1976), Hennart
(1982) and Rugman (1981), focused primarily on the parameters stimulating firms to
expand across borders and on MNE entry mode choices. It largely ignored internal
governance issues and the selection of organizational structures within the MNE.
Verbeke’s work (1992, 2003, 2004), constitute what can be called the ‘new’
internalization theory, with the focus shifting to the MNE’s internal organization and
14
!
network capabilities. This expanded focus was achieved by infusing a ‘dynamic
those related to knowledge-based assets (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008b). This integration of
powerful as a general theory of the firm. The new internalization theory can explain the
choice of MNE boundaries, as well as the firm’s internal governance and its interactions
review its intellectual foundations and key applications, and conclude with a projection of
AND HISTORY
Internalization theory was first conceptualized by Buckley and Casson (1976) and
has its origins in a number of studies, including the work of Coase (1937), Hymer (1968,
1976) and McManus (1972). Coase (1937), who sought to explain the existence of
Coase’s view, a hierarchy supersedes the market if the costs of organizing exchanges
15
!
within a firm are lower than the market transaction costs; internalization theory extends
these arguments developed for the domestic context to the MNE. To ‘internalize’ means
to perform a transaction within the firm, and internalization theory essentially describes
the MNE as an internal market that operates across national boundaries (Verbeke &
Greidanus, 2009). The theory focuses on the relative costs and benefits of coordinating
cross-border economic activities internally, through managerial fiat, rather than externally
through the market (Buckley & Strange, 2011). The core argument is that profit-
maximizing firms internalize markets for intermediate goods (especially various types of
know-how, patents, brand reputation, etc.) across national borders in the face of various
market imperfections. These imperfections can take the form of information asymmetries
patent systems, the lack of future markets for knowledge generation, imperfect
knowledge pricing, etc. (DeGennaro, 2005; Rugman, Verbeke & Nguyen, 2011). Market
and control; if these activities are located in different countries, then an MNE will result
(Buckley & Strange, 2011). Further, the MNE will organize bundles of activities
The proprietary ownership and internal deployment of these FSAs serves to overcome the
external markets, with the pricing outcome being influenced by expected future value
creation and value capture by the parties involved. Internalization becomes a governance
mechanism for managing the FSA development and exploitation process in its entirety
16
!
(Rugman & Verbeke, 2008b).
embedded in Buckley and Casson’s (1976) work and is often viewed as the starting point
for internalization decisions (Safarian, 2003). Hymer’s insight was that foreign direct
investment (FDI) only takes place when the benefits of exploiting FSAs through
internalization are higher than the additional costs of conducting business across borders.
These additional costs may include, inter alia, information costs facing MNEs vis-à-vis
host country rivals, discriminatory treatment by governments and foreign exchange risks.
Zaheer (1995) later coined the phrase ‘liability of foreignness’ to describe these costs of
nations and the resulting hazards facing foreign MNEs (Eden & Miller, 2004). However,
Hymer did not really develop a complete theory of optimal operating mode choice.
Internalization theory, in contrast, explicitly addresses this issue. Assuming that the MNE
commands FSAs sufficient to compensate for the additional costs of doing business
abroad, internalization theory seeks to explain how the MNE overcomes market
imperfections (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Casson, 1979). Here, Hymer’s concept of FSAs
FDI and the MNE’s existence (Rugman, 1981; Rugman et al., 2011a).
differentials across nations (Dunning & Rugman, 1985). The latter perspective
17
!
Hymer essentially pioneered a firm-level industrial organization approach, as opposed to
paradigm, termed so for its comprehensive melding of several theory streams on FDI
explain foreign entry mode choices and their economic efficiency implications. Location
advantages capture differences among countries and regions, whereas ownership and
internalization advantages reflect firm-level strategy decisions and their outcomes. While
representing a comprehensive framework to explain foreign entry mode choices and the
economic efficiency implications thereof, the eclectic paradigm suffers from a relative
lack of parsimony when compared with internalization theory (Rugman et al., 2011a). As
explained above, a critical challenge for MNEs is to select the governance structure (e.g.,
internalization versus usage of the external market) that will be the most effective one
among feasible, real world alternatives to exploit and further develop FSAs. Here, the (O)
advantage is closely intertwined with the (I) advantage, because to ‘internalize’ means to
perform a transaction within the firm, which is often a necessary condition for profitable
FSA exploitation to occur. (O) is also inseparable from the (L) advantage, as costs and
benefits derived from FSA ownership are unavoidably influenced by location factors
(Itaki, 1991).
FSAs, which gives it a competitive advantage over rivals. These FSAs relate to special
18
!
cost and in the long run. This line of reasoning invites a comparison with the
contemporary resource-based view (RBV) of the firm pioneered by Barney (1991). While
the FSA concept predates the RBV by a full decade, it does have its origins in the
pioneering work of Edith Penrose (1959), whose view of the firm as an evolving
collection of resources was incorporated in modern RBV thinking (Rugman & Verbeke,
2002). Similar to Penrose’s view that economic value creation stems from effective and
departure from its Penrosean roots, however, is manifested in its view of the
environment: While Penrose believed that constraints to the firm’s growth resided with
more active role to the environment and sees it as a constraining or enabling force, as
(e.g., natural resources, low-cost labor available in a particular location, etc.) reflect the
MNE and essentially determine, along with the firm’s FSAs, whether or not internal
organization of the MNE’s international activities is the most effective governance mode.
transaction without the loss of economic value (i.e., managing ‘the transaction in its
19
!
developing and exploiting FSAs across borders (i.e., managing the ‘innovation process in
Pisano & Shuen, 1997). Fittingly, the unit of analysis shifts from TCE’s focus on the
individual transaction to internalization theory’s focus on the firm. Interestingly, the core
idea that the MNE is an internal market operating across national boundaries was
developed by so-called ‘Reading School’ scholars (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Rugman,
1981) independently of the foundational TCE work of Oliver Williamson (1975, 1981a,
1981b). The two streams developed in parallel (Rugman, 1986), and the obvious link
between both only became apparent as a result of two influential publications. First,
Francois Hennart published his 1977 doctoral dissertation on internalization theory and
Beyond its role in marrying the two transatlantic streams of thought on MNE
theory (Rugman, 1986), Hennart’s work can be seen as the beginning of a shift toward
the ‘new’ internalization theory, as he was the first scholar to address internal
various sets of geographically dispersed resources within the MNE (Hennart, 1982).
20
!
Hennart’s significant contribution is his drawing attention to the role of complementary
resources of foreign actors that the MNE may require for exploiting its own FSAs.
complementary resources. This line of thinking was further developed in Hennart’s most
recent work, where he argues that boundaries between FSAs and CSAs are blurrier than
commonly assumed, and that host country CSAs are not necessarily readily accessible to
the expanding MNE. In this context, the MNE’s international expansion is seen as an
economic actors who own or control host nation CSAs (Hennart, 2009).
The central concerns of early internalization theory (Buckley & Casson, 1976;
international expansion, and entry mode choice. While respecting the above concerns, the
focus of more recent extensions of internalization theory (Hennart, 1982, 2009; Rugman
& Verbeke, 1992, 2003) has shifted to internal organization, alternative governance
choices within the MNE, and MNE network analysis. Broadly speaking, new
The term ‘foreign operation mode’ is generally accepted to mean the MNE’s way
activities” (Benito, Petersen & Welch, 2009: 1458). The mode of entry into a foreign
21
!
market has long been a frontier issue in international management research (Madhok,
1997), and has predominantly been conducted from the internalization viewpoint
(Buckley & Casson, 1976; Rugman, 1980). According to this perspective, FDI will result
when internalizing transactions within the MNE is more efficient than performing
transactions with an external market partner (Madhok, 1997). Hennart’s (1992) treatment
of entry mode choice postulates that the FDI decision depends on the nature of the
the transaction as the risk of proprietary knowledge dissipation, the risk of adverse effects
on brand name reputation, the relative ease (or lack thereof) of accessing requisite
complementary knowledge held by third parties, and the possibility (or lack thereof) of
Rugman (1980, 1981) expanded the analysis of entry mode choice by contrasting
FDI with alternative entry mode choices such as licensing, franchising, and joint venture
formation. Further, Rugman offered a dynamic extension by showing that the mode of
entry may change over time as the relative costs and benefits associated with each entry
mode strategy change, and by constructing potential switchover points for each possible
entry mode over time. Specifically, switchover points depend on the relative costs of
servicing foreign markets and the potential to avoid dissipation of the rents derived from
FSAs: Typically, exporting to foreign markets with the FSAs embodied in final products
is the first step, followed by engaging in FDI and, finally, licensing a foreign producer
when the technology licensed reaches the point of no longer determining the firm’s
22
!
the internationalization process, developed by a group of Scandinavian researchers and
frequently referred to as the Uppsala model. Internationalization theory draws upon the
behavioural theory of the firm (Cyert & March, 1963) and proposes that international
expansion is a function of the MNE’s past international experience and knowledge base
(Johanson & Wiedersheim, 1975; Johanson & Vahlne, 1977, 1990; Luostarinen, 1979).
The model postulates that firms undertake international expansion in an incremental and
to establish a sales subsidiary, to invest in local assembly and packaging, to form a joint
venture, and finally to move to full scale local production and marketing by a wholly
owned subsidiary once enough experiential market knowledge is gained (Aharoni, 1966).
From the internalization theory perspective, this model neglects two critical elements:
First, it is the nature of the MNE’s FSAs that determines potential internalization
benefits, and second, the presence or absence of market imperfections affects the
possibility of external market transactions (Rugman et al., 2011a). Further, the Uppsala
model has been criticized for its lack of serious conceptual grounding and
internalization theory. Benito et al. (2009) propose a dynamic model of the choice and
evolution of foreign operation modes, whereby firms do not necessarily choose among
well-specified discrete alternatives, but rather select mode packages, and engage in
frequent within-mode adjustments and mode role changes. The model allows for the
23
!
recognizes that the choice of mode is as likely to be an emergent response to
model, the mode choice and change framework draws on the behavioural theory of the
firm and acknowledges path dependency of entry mode decisions, but here experiences
with an operation mode can in themselves be seen as the firm’s FSAs to be drawn upon
for international operations. Further, CSAs are recognized as influencing entry mode
internalization theory, and offers a richer, more dynamic, and, importantly, more realistic
comarketing, and original equipment manufacturing (OEM). The core argument is that
the choice of an optimal entry mode depends on the relative costs and benefits of both the
market for technology and the market for manufacture; while technology transfer across
borders, and the related choice between, inter alia, licensing and FDI, has been addressed
by internalization theory, other value chain activities have been largely neglected. Chen’s
model positions technology transfer in the broader context of the entire value chain,
including the manufacturing/marketing linkages with the final products market. The
model specifically recognizes the role of strategic assets controlled by host country-based
entry mode choice can be found in Hennart (2009), who, as mentioned above, focuses on
24
!
transactional characteristics of complementary local assets and models foreign market
entry as the assignment of equity between MNEs and owners of complementary local
FSAs. At the core of Hennart’s argument is the recognition that CSAs have owners, and
that the optimal mode of entry will maximize the welfare of those owners as well as that
of the MNE (Chen, 2005; Hennart, 1988, 1989, 2000; Yeung & Mirus ,1988). Traditional
internalization theory, while acknowledging the role of CSAs in internalization, does not
Teece’s (1986) insight that owners of specialized complementary assets play a greater
role than generally understood. He argues that entry mode choice is essentially a choice
of an assignment of residual rights between the MNE and host country CSA owners, and
that the selected configuration will typically maximize total potential rents by assigning
residual rights to the party whose behaviour is the most difficult to constrain—that is,
equity will be held by the MNE or by local firms or shared between them. This will
determine whether the MNE will enter a foreign market through greenfields, brownfields,
difficult to constrain, an equity joint venture (EJV) will result. Hennart uses his bundling
model to predict how entry modes will evolve over time, showing that the deepening of
the MNE’s commitment in a host country (e.g., from licensing to FDI) depends largely on
the efficiency of the markets for complementary local assets and for the MNE’s own
approach, and by explaining the evolution of the MNEs’ entry modes in foreign
countries.
25
!
MNE’s international expansion strategy: The four dimensions of distance
Critical to understanding CSAs is the notion of distance between the home and
administrative (or institutional), geographic (or spatial), and economic—and argues that
information and communications technologies that are supposed to make the world a
challenges (Simon, 1959) by making it more difficult for head office managers to
understand the subsidiary environment, and bounded reliability problems (Verbeke &
Greidanus, 2009) by limiting the extent to which the head office can engage in proper
are not independent of each other, but rather intertwined and mutually influencing each
which in turn may contribute to decreasing cultural distance through improved mobility
of labor and managerial best practices. It is then the compounded distance, defined as the
need to manage various distance dimensions simultaneously, that has the most substantial
effect on the firm’s ability to deploy successfully and efficiently its FSAs abroad
26
!
(Rugman et al., 2011a). The internalization perspective suggests that the level of the
MNE’s multinationality and its geographic scope will be determined by the extent to
which the MNE is able to deploy and recombine its FSAs to cope with compounded
Rugman and Verbeke (1992) have provided what is perhaps the most important
bound and non-location-bound (LB and NLB) FSAs. NLB FSAs are those FSAs that are
easily transferable across borders and are available to the entire MNE network. Typically,
such FSAs are developed at headquarters (HQ) and include technological, marketing, or
administrative knowledge. LB FSAs, on the other hand, are available only to certain
countries. One of the most interesting strategic aspects of LB FSAs is that some of them
can become ‘best practices’, and can be transformed into NLB FSAs and transferred to
thinking: From the view of the MNE as a monolithic organization fully controlled
through hierarchical decisions about FDI from the head office (Rugman & Verbeke,
2001) toward an analysis of the MNE as a differentiated network. The point here is that
each MNE affiliate commands idiosyncratic FSA bundles. The content, development, and
exploitation trajectory of these FSA bundles over time determine each affiliate’s role in
27
!
the MNE and drive interactions with other affiliates (Rugman & Verbeke, 2003, 2008).
What follows is recognition that the MNE can have multiple patterns of FSA
deployability across the MNE network, and the level of head office control. The MNE’s
key role is then to master this variety of FSA development patterns through recombining
resources and establishing linkages with CSAs and complementary resources of external
actors. The recombination capability in itself becomes the MNE’s highest-order FSA
This notion of multiple potential patterns of FSA development gave rise to the
subsidiary level (Rugman & Verbeke, 2001)—which are embedded in subsidiaries and
cannot be simply transferred to the rest of the MNE work, although they do have
has this kind of special expertise, it may be wisest to let that subsidiary expand beyond its
initially assigned charter, and to stimulate the exploitation of its SSAs internationally
(Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1986). Further, each subsidiary can be simultaneously associated
with multiple roles and FSA development patterns within the MNE.
advantages that are embedded in alliances and cannot be simply transferred to the
28
!
individual partner firms (Verbeke, 2009). Like SSAs, ASAs have international
exploitation potential, but cannot be simply diffused within the partner firms because of
within the alliance. The introduction of the concept of ASA represents an important
With its greater focus on internal MNE governance, the new internalization theory
has been instrumental in analyzing the efficacy of specific organizational forms, such as
the multidivisional, or M-form (Chandler, 1962), versus the metanational form (Doz,
Santos & Williamson, 2001). In their highly influential book, Doz et al. proposed a new
MNE, whereby the company is organized around three distinct activity levels: sensing,
the MNE utilizes sensing and magnet units, which work outside the realm of the MNE’s
operating divisions. Sensors identify and seek out geographically dispersed, unique
bodies of valuable knowledge, while magnets recombine the various unique pieces of
divisions then implement the new solutions put forward by the sensors and magnets.
internalization theory perspective, the sensor, magnet, and operating division units should
be assessed in terms of their capacity to recombine novel resources to turn them into
29
!
actual NLB FSAs (Verbeke & Kenworthy, 2008). Internalization theory looks at
consistent with Buckley’s (2009) concept of the global factory, this means that R&D and
other efforts to develop and access new knowledge cannot be structurally divorced from
production, marketing, and sales. To achieve innovation, the MNE must engage in
integrative resource recombination practices throughout its value chain. It follows, then,
that structural separation of innovation activities in sensor and magnet units, from the rest
of the organization—i.e., the operating divisions—is unlikely to help the MNE innovate,
al., 2011a). Empirical evidence will, of course, be the ultimate judge of the metanational
governance form’s validity; current reality, however, suggests that most MNEs still fit
argue that consumer needs are becoming increasingly homogenized, largely due to
means that the MNE must design ‘global strategies’ (Levitt, 1983; Yip, 2002).
Specifically, the MNE should standardize its products and services worldwide in order to
achieve economies of scale, and should implement uniform strategies throughout the
Yet, very few MNEs are truly global. A global company can be defined as having
30
!
less than 50% of sales (or assets) in its home region, and at least 20% of sales (or assets)
in each of the triad regions, the triad being defined as consisting of NAFTA, the
expanded European Union, and Asia, with these three regions representing the bulk of
innovations (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004). Empirical evidence suggests that increases in
international sales occur predominantly within the MNE’s home region of the triad, and
that substantial barriers to trade and FDI among regions of the triad still exist (Rugman,
2000). In a study of intraregional sales of the world’s 500 largest companies, 380 firms
had available geographic segment data; these firms accounted for 79.2% of the total
revenue of the 500 largest firms and had an average sales volume of $29.2 billion in
2001. The study showed that the average intraregional sales across these 380 firms
represented 71.9%; further, only 9 of the 380 firms (2.4%) were in fact global (Rugman
& Verbeke, 2004). There is no trend toward globalization, and the world’s largest MNEs
remain highly intraregional in their sales and assets (Oh & Rugman, 2007; Rugman &
Verbeke, 2008b).
processes, and marketing routines, can easily overcome distance. In reality, the non-
foreignness, which remain at both regional and national levels, lead to challenges in
transferring, deploying, and profitably exploiting FSAs across borders (Rugman &
31
!
of doing business abroad, which rises with the increase of cultural, economic, geographic,
and institutional distance across regional boundaries. In the end, adaptation costs may
turn out to be so high that home region expansion is preferred over global expansion. It
follows, then, that it may be appropriate for the MNE to tailor its strategy to fit a specific
role in each triad region, rather than to impose an integrated strategy throughout its
network (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004, 2007). The key strategic challenge is to achieve the
right balance between NLB and LB FSAs in each region where the MNE has a presence
In terms of striking such balance, the internalization theory lens can also be
assumes that the focus on socialization (‘normative integration’) inside the MNE is
sufficient to make the differentiated network MNE function effectively, and to achieve
both national responsiveness and global integration. In reality, however, internal MNE
coordination of affiliates based on their FSA bundles, and the subsequent coordination of
these affiliates in a network through normative integration, may become too complex,
and may therefore be replaced by a regional solution (Rugman & Verbeke, 1992).
In their milestone JIBS article, Kogut and Zander (1993) develop a new view of
the MNE, informed by the behavioural (Cyert & March, 1963) and evolutionary (Nelson
& Winter, 1982) theories of the firm. They suggest that the MNE represents a superior
32
!
governance mechanism for transferring tacit knowledge across borders because it
internal routines allow for effective knowledge transfer. The knowledge transfer process
itself is a platform for future knowledge generation and transfer, grounded in a social
context. Kogut and Zander argue that internalization theory focuses on the minimization
opportunism (“self-interest seeking with guile”, Williamson, 1981b: 1545), and that it
across borders, without considering the broader context that should include the MNE’s
While the above criticisms usefully suggest that it is beneficial to adopt a more
assessed from the ‘new’ internalization theory perspective. First, while conventional
parameters to explain MNE expansion patterns and technology transfer choices, new
concerned not merely with single-transaction economizing, but also with strategizing for
value creation purposes. Second, Kogut and Zander’s questioning of the opportunism
assumption is useful, as the concept of opportunism has indeed been the subject of much
academic debate. Opportunism has been criticized for its narrow conceptual focus,
inaccurate portrayal of human nature and the lack of sufficient empirical support (Tsang,
33
!
2006), and it has even been argued that concerns surrounding the behavioural assumption
of opportunism reduce the legitimacy of TCE as a general theory of the firm (Verbeke &
Greidanus, 2009). Yet, in this particular case, the criticism is perhaps misdirected. While
a focus of internalization theory, which is much more concerned with the behavioural
relevant than opportunism and has had a larger role in internalization theory (Rugman &
Verbeke, 2008b). Third, internalization theory does not divorce specific transactions from
of managing the MNE’s network, whereby it is prior investments that permit the
(Verbeke, 2003). In other words, it is rather naive to assume that combinative capabilities
held by a firm simply appear and make the firm superior to external markets: Investments
are required to create the combinative capability, and these investments are driven by
sufficient condition for internalization: The benefits and costs of alternative governance
forms must be assessed simultaneously. For example, external actors such as key
do not fit with the MNE’s core businesses, de-internalization may still be comparatively
34
!
more efficient (Rugman & D’Cruz, 2001).
Multinationality-performance relationship
Over the past fifty years, the IB literature has suggested various linkages between
multinationality and performance, and a number of authors have tried to find a systematic
relationship between the increase in the degree of the firm’s multinationality and its
bottom line. These studies have been published in credible outlets, yet their results are
performance, allegedly the outcome of three distinct stages during the MNE’s
decline in performance as the firm learns how to operate in foreign markets and
overcome the liability of foreignness and newness; in the second stage, performance
starts to rise with the increase in multinationality; in the third stage, large foreign
operations become too difficult to manage, and the firm’s performance again declines as
the firm overextends itself. On the surface, this research has important normative
implications for managers, suggesting that higher multinationality is likely to yield higher
the most basic principles of internalization theory—as, in fact, does the mere notion that a
perspective, the MNE will select entry modes and geographic configurations to best
match its FSAs, with the environment acting as a constraining or facilitating force.
35
!
Domestic and international success will therefore be determined by the firm’s ability to
develop, transfer, deploy, and exploit its FSAs rather than by its geographic scope per se.
To illustrate this point, Verbeke and Brugman (2009) conducted a quality test of extant
uncovered serious conceptual and measurement challenges that essentially invalidate the
results of most past studies. Verbeke and Forootan’s (2012) subsequent study updated
and replicated the analysis. Kirca et al. (2011) conducted a meta-analysis of 120
theory in the context of the multinationality-performance relationship, and found that the
elements, including the type of FSA, industry characteristics, and the firm’s R&D and
advertising intensity. Essentially, the meta-analysis’ results confirm the key point that no
environments (Verbeke & Brugman, 2009; Verbeke & Forootan, 2012) — an insight
particularly relevant for practitioners, who might otherwise engage in a misguided quest
ones (e.g., brand names), with the strength of these FSAs approximated by the MNE’s
36
!
R&D and advertising spending, respectively. These imperfect proxies may have
represented an acceptable approximation for the MNE’s FSAs in the past, but certainly
did not capture the MNE’s uniqueness in qualitative terms. For example, such uniqueness
could reside in the MNE’s absorptive capacity to digest different cultures and to employ
embodies a dynamic capabilities-like view of the firm, recognizes the role of higher-order
FSAs beyond those associated with branding and technology — for example, FSAs in
managerial expertise, which are often at the heart of achieving superior performance, yet
are not easily measured in quantitative terms. In his plea to rethink IB research
methodology, Yair Aharoni (1993) argued it is very difficult, if not impossible, to capture
MNE success stories by using industry averages and statistical tests. Outlier stories
typically get buried in statistical databases, so that the uniqueness of MNEs is not truly
captured. Aharoni suggests that IB scholars would understand much more about
companies’ FSAs if they relied more on the tools of the business historian than those of
poignant in the context of emerging economy MNEs (EMNEs), whose key competitive
strengths are often not measurable by traditional proxies. EMNEs may have dramatically
different FSAs as compared to developed economy MNEs, and their trajectory of FSA
development may also be different—for example, many large EMNEs typically build
37
!
technological capacity by purchasing technology or entering into alliances to gain access
to existing technology instead of investing in R&D. The point here is that with the
comes an added challenge of capturing these FSAs empirically. Here, the RBV literature
may be useful: RBV scholars have been instrumental in developing a multitude of proxies
for empirically measuring a firm’s resource base (see Newbert, 2007, for a
undoubtedly aid in evaluating the unique FSAs of a range of unique MNEs (including
EMNEs).
management research
research questions in international strategic management fall within one of four general
categories, based on 1) their focus on the firm versus the environmental context; and 2)
with the following types of research questions relevant to each quadrant, as shown in
Figure 1.1.
variation constant. For example, how do firms from one particular domestic context
organize their activities in one specific foreign context (e.g., Japanese MNEs’ entry
38
!
2. Quadrant 2 includes the interactive analysis of firms, with contextual variation held
stable. In other words, how do relationships unfold between firms from context A and
firms from context B (e.g., how do joint ventures evolve between European and
differences affect supposedly ‘identical’ firms (e.g., what is the impact of country-
changes in these characteristics affect supposedly ‘identical firms’? (E.g., what is the
managerial impact of particular scores on a Kogut and Singh (1988) index of cultural
distance? What is the impact of trade agreements on FDI: Does increased trade
In the first type of studies, differences in FSAs among companies matter the most,
suggesting that these studies can be categorized as international RBV applications, but
choices. In the second type of studies, interactions between FSAs from firms with
different nationalities matter the most. Each company’s FSAs are believed to embody
home country CSAs. Here, higher distance typically leads to higher transaction costs and
higher complexity in making strategy choices. In the third type of IB research, only
differences in CSAs matter: The message is often that particular CSAs (such as a
properly enforced patent protection regime or high institutional quality) will reduce
39
!
transaction costs for MNEs at the macro level, thereby attracting and fostering the growth
of particular types of economic activities. The fourth type of studies deals with
interactions between CSAs of different countries, and the changes therein over time. This
in nature, with its key concern being the recombination of the MNE’s LB and NLB FSAs
with home and host countries’ CSAs, whereby access to the latter may actually be
controlled by host country actors. In one of the newest iterations of internalization theory,
namely Hennart’s (2009) bundling approach discussed above, quadrant 4 is collapsed into
quadrant 2: Here, CSAs are not exogenous macro parameters, but are controlled by
resource owners in a host country and not necessarily readily accessible by the MNE.
Accessing CSAs requires further recombination capabilities and FSA development on the
MNE’s part.
(Rugman & Verbeke, 2008b), internalization theory can be readily augmented to explain
a wide range of emerging issues in IB. In this section, we consider a few potential
application areas.
research, which has been argued to be a critical emerging area in IB (Dimitratos & Jones,
40
!
2005; Styles & Seymour, 2006; Young, Dimitratos & Dana, 2003; Zahra, 2005; Ellis,
2011), distinguishes itself from other IB theories by its emphasis on the entrepreneurial
firms that internationalize while still young and small (Knight & Cavusgil, 1996;
McDougall & Oviatt, 2000), and whose expansion is rapid and opportunity-driven
(Zahra, Korri & Yu, 2005) as opposed to incremental and inhibited by risk aversion.
driven by entrepreneurs’ ideas and knowledge which may have potential global
application; while small ideas may incubate local firms, big ideas will incubate MNEs
(Buckley & Casson, 2009). Born-globals are most frequently ‘market seekers’ in their
pattern is particularly prevalent among firms operating in small open economies (e.g.,
New Zealand, Israel, Denmark, etc.) where domestic demand is limited (Knight, Bell &
McNaughton, 2001).
globals’ international sales are achieved largely within their home regions. Research
found that Danish born-globals generated the vast majority of their international sales in
41
!
Europe (predominantly in Germany, which accounted for 50% of their sales), while
American born-globals generated 53% of their total sales domestically (Knight, Madsen
& Servais, 2004). Despite a vast amount of literature on born-globals, there is a paucity
of robust empirical evidence of any true born-global firms, in the sense of having an
equal presence in all regions of the triad, other than a few technology firms from India
and some small firms from Israel (Rugman & Almodovar, 2011). This suggests that born-
globalism may be no more than an illusion (Rugman et al., 2011), and that born-globals
can often be more accurately described as born-regionals (Rugman, 2000; Fisch &
economic, cultural, geographic, and institutional distance and liability of foreignness and
newness. Shortage of sufficiently developed FSAs to support FDI likely explains the fact
that born-globals’ opportunistic foreign sales usually take a form of exporting. It should
also be noted that the so-called globalization of markets that supposedly gave rise to the
conceivable that a big idea will breed global demand (e.g., imagine a pharmaceutical firm
that develops a cure for cancer), global implementation requires an expert recombination
of the company’s FSAs with multiple CSAs in diverse locations, which is extremely
challenging. Global governance will likely prove difficult for a young firm, presenting
multiple challenges throughout the firm’s value chain (i.e., finding reliable distribution
systems and local partners throughout the world), and leading to consequent bounded
42
!
reliability and bounded rationality challenges.
it should be noted the new internalization theory has long moved away from its MNE-
centric focus (see Hennart’s 2009 study, tellingly titled “Down with MNE-centric
available to the MNE, and is presently well equipped to explain the born-global
and government policies that favor economic liberalization, are assuming an increasingly
prominent position in the world economy (Wright, Filatotchev, Hoskisson & Peng, 2005),
as well as in MNE strategic activity (Verbeke, 2009). Hoskisson, Eden, Lau & Wright
growing developing countries, and thirteen were in transition from centrally planned to
separate essay included in this dissertation (Essay 3). However, EMNEs provide an
significant avenue for internalization theory’s future extension – and therefore must
not be amiss in this section on the future of internalization theory. This section
43
!
research on the topic over the past decade. The emerging economies phenomenon offers
three broad areas for consideration by IB scholars: situations where firms from developed
economies enter emerging economies, situations where firms from emerging economies
enter developed economies, and situations where firms from emerging economies enter
The last two areas of research have spurred a vivid debate among IB scholars
MNEs from the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, and China) and VISTA (Vietnam,
Indonesia, South Africa, Turkey, and Argentina) countries, as well as from Mexico and
significant adjustment to extant theory, or even an entirely new theory is required to study
EMNEs. To date, no consensus has emerged on the topic (Ramamurti, 2009). A sizeable
group of researchers (see Child & Rodrigues, 2005; Filatotchev, Strange, Piesse & Lien,
2007; Luo & Tung, 2007; Mathews, 2002a, 2002b, 2006a, and 2006b; Peng, Lu, Shenkar
& Wang, 2001) believe that EMNEs represent a new class of firms that pursues
therefore call for new theory development. Others (see Buckley et al., 2007; Dunning,
2006; Hennart, 2011; Narula, 2006; Rugman, 2009) suggest that EMNEs’
existing IB paradigms. Yet, a third group of authors (see Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008;
Guillen & Garcia-Canal, 2009; Ramamurti, 2009) posit that extant IB theories can be
44
!
Unfortunately, the rejection of existing IB theories, and especially internalization
theory as the general theory of the MNE (including the EMNE) appears to be associated
augmented theory issue three main charges against the internalization paradigm:
The first one relates to the fact that EMNEs operate in an institutional
al., 2001), and therefore require a new institution-based theory. However, internalization
theory has been successful in dealing with institutional distance, including institutional
transaction costs. Transaction costs are likely to rise due to economizing challenges
presented by institutional differences (Wright et al., 2005). For example, MNEs from
protection, weak legal and financial systems, etc. This is likely to create bounded
rationality and bounded reliability challenges (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009), potentially
increasing transaction costs. In contrast, local competitors and EMNEs from other
emerging economies will have a competitive advantage over their rivals from developed
countries due to the lower institutional distance (or a complete lack thereof) and will,
consequently, face lower transaction costs. In other words, from the internalization theory
perspective, institutions matter due to their potential to affect the additional costs of doing
business abroad.
The second charge against the use of internalization theory for EMNE research
45
!
Proponents of a new theory suggest that emerging economy multinationals do not in fact
possess FSAs and thus internationalize to acquire new FSAs rather than to exploit
existing ones. For example, Mathews (2002a, 2002b, 2006a, 2006b) suggests that Asian
EMNEs, which he terms Dragon multinationals, are essentially resource-poor, yet have
successfully expanded abroad without FSAs. This is argued to make EMNEs unsuitable
for theoretical analysis driven by the notion of FSAs—the very feature that EMNEs
supposedly lack. We believe that this misconception stems from the confusion
surrounding the notion of FSAs, and from the failure to differentiate between
previous section, conventional proxies for empirical measurement of FSAs — R&D and
EMNEs’ key competitive strengths are not necessarily related to technology and
branding, and second, even if EMNEs do cultivate technological and branding FSAs,
these FSAs may not be measurable by traditional proxies, as their development path may
not be associated with R&D and advertising spending. The point here is that EMNEs’
FSAs are different from those of developed economies’ MNEs, rather than absent
quality of management (as seen in India’s Tata Group’s innovative Nano product),
Many IB scholars have recognized the differential nature of EMNEs’ FSAs and
acknowledge that those FSAs can be exploited through FDI (see Cuervo-Cazzura &
Genc, 2008; Guillen & Garcia-Canal, 2009; Ramamurti, 2009; Zeng & Williamson,
46
!
2007). Some EMNE-specific FSAs mentioned in the literature include a better
products suited for special needs customers (relevant when expanding to other emerging
economies and competing with developed country MNEs), cost innovations and
networking skills, political know-how, etc. Still, we argue that internalization theory
predictions stand despite the idiosyncratic nature of EMNEs’ FSAs, which essentially
(higher-order ones versus technology-based ones) does not affect internalization theory’s
main prediction that the firm’s international success will depend on its ability to
successfully match its set of FSAs with host country CSAs. It is the generic
characteristics of these FSAs (e.g., transferability across borders and inimitability) and
CSAs (easily transacted in open markets or not), rather than the FSAs’ specific
mode choice and subsequent governance of developed country MNEs and EMNEs alike.
Related to the above point, the third proposed rationale for a new EMNE-based
Guillen and Garcia-Canal (2009) identify nine motivations for EMNEs’ FDI documented
in the literature: backward linkage into raw materials, forward linkage into foreign
47
!
markets, home-country government curbs, spreading of risk, movement of personal
FSAs, and exploitation of intangible FSAs. A closer look at the motivations listed above
will reveal that many could be found in developed country MNE expansions, as well. In
fact, all of those strategic goals fit neatly into an existing typology of internationalization
motivations: natural resource seeking, market seeking, strategic resource seeking, and
efficiency seeking (Dunning & Lundan, 2008; Verbeke, 2009), and as such hardly
All of this is not to say that the emerging economy context does not warrant a
FSAs and CSAs (Rugman, 1981, 1996) is particularly relevant to address this uniqueness.
Let us look, for example, at developed country MNEs entering emerging economies.
MNEs are required to engage in novel activities for new business creation in a foreign
country, rather than simply seek to sell a product or service (Yiu et al., 2007). FSA
development patterns for an MNE entering an emerging economy will be unique, with
extant NLB FSAs necessarily combined with substantial bundles of LB FSAs developed
in the host country (Verbeke, 2009). Developing LB FSAs in national responsiveness and
enlisting complementary FSAs of external actors. Such enlisting may be critical given
government agencies, various local organizations, and local and foreign firms that
48
!
To conclude, the new internalization theory, with its blend of TCE and RBV
components, its dynamic view on FSAs and its focus on finding an optimal combination
of FSAs and CSAs, is well equipped to handle additional complexities presented by the
and institutional theory—have been identified as leading theories in the field (Hoskisson
et al., 2000; Peng et al., 2001; Meyer & Peng, 2004). Internalization theory, which
effectively blends the transaction costs and RBV/dynamic capabilities perspectives, and
systematically takes into account institutional context, can significantly enhance our
understanding of both EMNEs and developed country MNEs’ expansion into emerging
economies.
CONCLUSION
“represents a quantum leap in our understanding of the MNE” (Hennart, 1986: 801).
Standing on the shoulders of such giants such as Coase and Penrose, internalization
theory has evolved considerably since its inception over forty years ago, from a relatively
also widened from the early focus on entry mode choices to explaining such
49
!
FSAs and attempting to economize on transaction costs so as to effect value creation and
offers a comprehensive view of the interactions between the firm and its environment,
much needed in strategic management theory (Hoskisson, Hitt, Wan & Yiu, 1999).
Internalization theory can assist in the efforts to blend TCE and RBV-thinking that
mainstream strategic management scholars have been undertaking during the past two
decades.
significant normative agenda. At the micro level, internalization theory is concerned with
identifying and correcting short- and medium-term inefficiencies, such as wrong entry
environmental conditions, etc. At the macro level, internalization theory has far-reaching
public policy implications: Only if public policy makers and regulators understood
correctly the drivers of MNE behaviour could the positive societal spillover effects of
1981). In line with Teece’s (1984) thinking on the benefits of blending theories and
work with practitioners and regulators so as to combine research findings with best
practices in business and public policy. Such blending will further increase internalization
management.
50
!
Figure 1. 1. Generic types of international strategic management studies
Source of variation
Analytical
approach Firm-level Location
51
!
Essay 2
REGIONAL STRATEGY
This essay demonstrates that internalization theory, as a ‘complete’ theory of the firm, is
particularly well equipped to analyze MNE regional strategies, thanks to its joint
transaction cost economics and resource-based foundations. The essay builds upon
recent work by Wolf, Egelhoff, and Dunemann (2012) to show that internalization
theory’s predictions on MNE regional strategy are superior to those suggested by several
other conceptual frameworks. For each of the eleven hypotheses formulated by Wolf and
simplicity and accuracy, allows in-depth analysis of MNE regional strategies. A broad
internalization theory as the general theory of the MNE, rather than looking for insight
from theories not intended – nor properly equipped – to study strategies of the world’s
INTRODUCTION
Multinational Business Review (MBR), have argued that the phenomenon of multinational
home region as opposed to a more balanced distribution across the globe, cannot be
explained fully through transaction cost economics reasoning. In their view, a broader
52
!
and more multi-faceted explanation is required of the regionalization phenomenon. The
authors utilize seven complementary theories from economics, psychology and sociology
We agree with Wolf et al. (2012) that the study of MNE internationalization
patterns, and regional strategy/structure choices in particular, requires more than a mere
phenomenon as advanced by Rugman (2005) and Rugman and Verbeke (2004, 2005).
1981a, 1981b, 1996), but rather on the theory’s ‘international version’, called transaction
innovation process in its entirety. This broad focus, as compared to Williamsonian TCE
choice of MNE boundaries, as well as the firm’s internal governance and its interactions
53
!
Second, Wolf’s and his colleagues’ description of the TCE foundational
assumptions is not entirely accurate. Contrary to the authors’ claim (see Table I in Wolf
et al., 2012), TCE explicitly rejects the conventional notion of ‘homo economicus’ in
favour of the bounded rationality behavioural assumption (Simon, 1959; see Williamson,
1996). The concept of bounded rationality is central to internalization theory and to the
across regional borders. Further, also contrary to what the authors imply, TCE
does not view international expansion decisions as choices among well-specified, discrete
alternatives even if much empirical work has been based on this assumption (Benito et
al., 2009). Nor does internalization theory assume hyper-rational, MNE-centric decision
actually able to explain MNE behaviour while encompassing the spatial, behavioural and
following section, we explore how the authors’ propositions can be reinterpreted through
54
!
ALTERNATIVE INTERPRETATION OF REGIONALIZATION
PROPOSITIONS
New regionalism refers to the politically induced process that started in the early
trade barriers (Hettne, Inotai & Sunkel, 1999). The authors argue, following the logic of
new regionalism, that MNEs are incentivized to concentrate the bulk of their business
activities within the boundaries of a regional integration agreement. They propose the
following (for purposes of consistency in the present paper, we will always use the words
themselves will not determine the scope of the MNE’s geographic expansion; rather, this
scope will be determined by the MNE’s ability to link its FSAs with CSAs of locations
within or outside of its host region. Regional integration agreements may influence this
ability: They promote intra-regional coherence and thereby reduce the MNE’s need to
develop new location-bound FSAs or adapt existing FSAs to host-country CSAs if a host
country is located within the home region (Rugman & Verbeke, 2005), thus indeed
also be noted that most region-based liberalization policies are reactions to a history of
55
!
cultural/economic/institutional similarities among countries in the region; they can be
Clegg, Forsans & Reilly, 2003) to further the ease of FSA adaptation, which was already
liberalization. In addition, this ‘incentive’ for home-region firms will not necessarily act
resource seeking, if these strategic resources cannot be obtained within their own home
region. Consider, for example, an emerging economy MNE expanding into a developed
economy (i.e. a host region), in order to access technological know-how (Guillen &
China – again, located in a host region) in search of cheap labour. The point here is that
region-based liberalization policies may indeed affect the regional scope of MNE
international activities, but will not determine such scope. The key determinant of the
MNE’s geographic scope is the firm’s ability to recombine FSAs with CSAs in order to
pattern will be determined mainly by micro level parameters, including the firm’s
56
!
Wolf et al.’s hypothesis is in fact disproved by Rugman and Verbeke’s (2004)
empirical data. Among the three regions of the Triad (defined as Europe, North America
and Asia-Pacific), Europe can be seen as the most integrated, as it is characterized by far-
whereas North America and Asia only benefit from the latter. Therefore, if Wolf et al.’s
prediction were true, European MNEs would be underrepresented in the group of truly
global and host-region oriented companies, and would account for the majority of home-
region oriented firms. The empirical data, however, show that the opposite is true:
European MNEs account for the lowest percentage of home-region firms and the highest
percentage of host-region ones, while the nine truly global MNEs are evenly distributed
consider the phenomenon of new regionalism, but it does so in the context of MNE
strategic positioning and its ability to link its FSAs with host country CSAs. Thus,
strategically and managerially relevant perspective than the theory of new regionalism,
while the latter considered in isolation yields an incorrect prediction that contradicts the
empirical evidence.
The theory of new economic geography stems from Marshall’s (1922) work on
the physical concentration of business firms, and attempts to explain the occurrence of
forces cause the spatial agglomeration of business. First is the force of agglomeration, fed
57
!
by market size effects, condensed labour market effects, and effects stemming from
location (Krugman, 1998). The authors adapt the theory of new economic geography,
particularly the agglomeration side of the argument, to the Triad region level, and suggest
the following:
H2. MNEs from regions with a greater level of relevant agglomeration will tend
to be more home-region oriented than MNEs from regions with a lower level of
relevant agglomeration.
We agree with the authors’ view that a Triad region is too broad a geographic
context within which to consider agglomeration, and that relevant clusters need to be
investigated within each Triad region. Industrial clusters, such as Silicon Valley or
Boston’s Route 128, would provide a better unit of analysis. From an internalization
theory viewpoint, such industrial clusters offer incumbent MNEs a variety of CSAs, or, in
this case, location- rather than country-specific advantages, such as easy access to a
highly skilled professional labour pool and state-of-the-art technical knowledge due to a
business schools), easy access to venture capital, and access to knowledge held by
industry leaders. If these location advantages (LAs) are relevant to MNEs from the home
region and these MNEs have comparatively easy access to them, a home-region
actors (e.g. existing supplier networks; partnership opportunities) may also encourage
expansion inside a cluster. However, whether or not the expansion in fact occurs (and is
58
!
successful) will be determined not by the MNE’s location near a particular innovation
cluster, but by its ability to gain access to the region’s LAs that may be held by local
actors (Hennart, 2009), and then to establish a match between its own FSAs and the
region’s LAs.
The dispersion side of the argument also needs to be considered: for example,
firms that possess FSAs superior to those of competitors and are vulnerable to
is an industry effect on the level of clustering: e.g. firms in industries where knowledge is
highly idiosyncratic (e.g. financial and professional service firms) may not have a great
need to learn from competitors (Nachum & Wymbs, 2007). It should also be noted that
relevant LAs are likely to attract investment not only from home region MNEs, but also
from MNEs outside of the region – consider, for example, inward FDI in Silicon Valley
by Japanese MNEs (Teece, 1992). The above leads to the following prediction:
itself attract investment from MNEs, whether from within or outside the region.
Nachum and Wymbs’s (2007) study on the location choices of financial and professional
services firms shows that LAs, including relevant agglomeration, do not determine MNE
59
!
location choices – rather, location choices are influenced by the interaction between LAs
The theory of the knowledge economy argues that contemporary firms rely on
intellectual capabilities to a greater extent than on physical inputs and natural resources
(Powell & Snellman, 2004), and therefore sourcing, processing and exploiting knowledge
are critical tasks for these firms (Dunning, 2000). The label ‘knowledge economy’ covers
a wide variety of research streams (Powell & Snellman, 2004). It includes literature on
knowledge networks, which argues that knowledge is rarely possessed by a single firm
and resides within networks of firms and institutions in a particular environment (Dicken,
1999), and literature on knowledge spillovers, which studies the effects of inter-firm,
intra-industry knowledge spillovers on R&D and innovation (Cohen & Levinthal, 1989).
hypothesize a strong linkage between low geographic distance and various types of
H3a. The more knowledge intensive an MNE is, the more it will pursue a home-
region orientation.
Even if only strategic asset seeking expansion is pursued, the above proposition
may hold solely in cases whereby the home region of the knowledge-intensive MNE
can occur inside the region. If not, the MNE may undertake an expansion into host
Valley (see the previous section). From an internalization theory perspective, this
60
!
expansion serves the purpose of accessing relevant LAs, either within or outside the
intensity could foster more globalization rather than regionalization, depending on the
innovative performance. The development of new economic theories, such as the new
economic geography and the theory of the knowledge economy, has led to a tendency to
overemphasize the importance of the region at the expense of the firm-level factors
(Dicken & Malmberg, 2001; Maskell, 2001). Empirical evidence in the strategic
management literature suggests that FSAs remain ultimately more important for an
MNE’s ability to produce innovations than the regional environment (Beugelsdijk, 2007).
Related to this point, different firms will benefit from LAs offered by knowledge clusters
to a different extent. Firms possessing the most advanced technologies may have
incentives to locate away from clusters in order to protect their core capabilities from
Seattle rather than in Silicon Valley is a case in point. Taking the above elements into
Wolf et al. (2012) further suggest that different activities within the MNE are
associated with different requirements for knowledge transfer, with the knowledge
generated in the upstream parts of the value chain (such as R&D) being more valuable
than knowledge generated in the downstream parts (such as sales and marketing).
61
!
Combined with the previous reasoning on intra-regional knowledge transfer, this led to
the following proposition (where upstream value chain activities are considered more
different for different value chain activities, namely downstream vs. upstream activities,
but offer a reverse prediction: globalization, when it does occur, happens predominantly
in the upstream end of the value chain, with the downstream activities maintaining a
stronger home region focus. This proposition is empirically supported by the data in
Rugman and Verbeke’s (2004) flagship study, which shows that many large MNEs do
have a strong geographic dispersion of their R&D, sourcing and production, but are not
capable of achieving a global distribution of sales. The reason is that FSAs required in
intermediate inputs, labour and capital, and production are very different from the FSAs
bundles that have to be accessed and deployed at the downstream end in a host region are
likely quite different from the knowledge combinations effective in the home region
(which does not necessarily hold for more upstream activities). Upstream activities, on
the other hand, provide the greatest potential for scale economies, whereby a
concentration of these activities often can be achieved in home regions (Verbeke, 2009).
62
!
Further, MNEs differ in their ability to adapt upstream and downstream activities
separately, i.e. in their decoupling flexibility (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008a). Strong
decoupling flexibility means that upstream and downstream activities can be easily
adapted separately; most brand-named goods fall into this category. Weak decoupling
Verbeke’s (2008a) empirical study, which shows that services MNEs’ decoupling
value chain activities will tend toward home region orientation more than
upstream activities.
Perhaps part of the problem with Wolf et al.’s (2012) proposition is that they
knowledge related, inter alia, to foreign cultures, customer preferences and institutions.
63
!
home and host countries (Brewer, 2007). Psychic distance is influenced by a variety of
H4a. The greater managers’ perception of the psychic distance between the home
region and other regions, the more the respective MNE will be home-region
oriented.
Observing that Asian countries are likely more psychically distant from European
and North American countries than the latter are from each other, they further predict
that:
H4b. When other factors are controlled for, Asian MNEs will tend to be more
dimensions between the home and host country – cultural, administrative (or
institutional), geographic (or spatial) and economic (Ghemawat, 2001) – that is central to
FSAs across borders. If any dimension of distance increases, so do the costs of doing
environment. Distance creates new bounded rationality challenges for managers who
reliability problems (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009) to the extent that it becomes difficult
for the head office to achieve proper monitoring and goal alignment with the subsidiary.
64
!
To add to the complexity of the notion of distance, the various distance
dimensions are not independent of each other, but rather intertwined and interdependent.
turn may contribute to decreasing cultural distance through improved mobility of labour
and managerial best practices. It is then the compounded distance, defined as the need to
manage various distance dimensions simultaneously, that has the most substantial effect
on the firm’s ability to deploy successfully and efficiently its FSAs abroad (Rugman et
distance.
The assumption that greater compounded distance between regions might lead to
a greater home-region orientation may seem plausible at first sight. However, a general
statement about a positive relationship between inter-regional distance and MNE home-
region orientation would appear somewhat simplistic. First, macro level distance may be
different in different parts of the value chains, e.g. upstream vs. downstream, as discussed
in the previous section. Consider North American Levi Strauss: its sales are strongly
home-region oriented, yet the entire bundle of upstream activities is located in Asia and
Latin America (Rugman, Verbeke & Yuan, 2011b). Second, the foreign entry motive
may also moderate the influence of distance on the MNE’s decision to make an
investment abroad. A strategic resource seeking MNE may find a high-distance market
locations (Verbeke, 2009). Similarly, a natural resource seeking MNE may expand into a
more proximate regions, as shown in Benito and Gripsrud’s (1992) analysis of FDI by
65
!
Norwegian MNEs. The internalization perspective suggests, again, that the level of the
MNE’s geographic scope will be determined by the extent to which the MNE is able to
deploy and recombine its FSAs to cope with compounded distance between the home and
Similarly, the influence of the home region itself on the propensity toward a
than macro level distance due to, for example, senior management’s extensive business
connections.
Rugman and Verbeke’s (2004) empirical results confirm the above reasoning.
Contrary to Wolf et al.’s prediction, Asian MNEs do not tend to be the most home-region
oriented – while they are more home-region oriented than their European counterparts,
they are significantly less home-region oriented than North American companies
(Rugman, 2005). Granted that ‘all other factors’ were not necessarily controlled for, this
the following:
orientation. Decisions on FDI into a high-distance host region are moderated by:
considered;
66
!
• the micro level distance between the firm and the host region; and
overcome distance.
Exploring psychic distance theory further, the authors combine it with the
Uppsala model, which focuses on the internationalization process. The Uppsala model
experience and knowledge base (Johanson & Wiedersheim, 1975; Johanson & Vahlne,
1977, 1990; Luostarinen, 1979), and postulates that firms undertake international
results:
H4c. The greater the international experience of an MNE, the more global will be
Here, the logical flow from theoretical assumptions to the proposition is not
entirely clear. First, host region expansion targets are not necessarily distant on all
dimensions (e.g. Spain and Mexico are located in different regions of the Triad but share
a common language and cultural heritage). Second, it is not clear how international
experience is defined (e.g. the number of countries where the MNE has a presence, the
The level of international experience alone would not necessarily lead to a greater ease in
entering a distant region, as the MNE ultimately needs to address incremental, or added,
distance (Hutzschenreuter, Voll & Verbeke, 2011). Even a higher level of diversification
of the MNE’s current locations does not necessarily imply a greater incentive for - and
ease of further expansion into - distant countries, as the ease of further expansion
67
!
(meaning really ease of FSA adaptation and recombination) depends on a particular
experience within the MNE’s current international portfolio. Further, empirical evidence
suggests that extant cultural diversity of the MNE’s subsidiary network will actually
subsidiaries increases complexity and ties up managerial resources that could otherwise
orientation.
reinvest in - certain actions (i.e. ‘escalate’ their commitment to these actions) even if
these actions have failed to achieve strategic goals in the past and are unlikely to do so in
the future (Brockner, 1992). The authors blend escalating-commitment theory with two
Administrative heritage describes the firms’ key routines and tacit knowledge that often
develop at the time of inception and are influenced by the vision of the founder and the
firm’s set of external circumstances. The literature distinguishes among four archetypes
68
!
multinationality-performance relationship suggests that a systematic, fixed relationship
exists between the MNE’s degree of multinationality and its performance. In this
context, Wolf et al. cite evidence that home-region oriented MNEs typically perform
worse than global, bi-regional or host-region oriented MNEs. The blending of the
should exist between the MNE’s geographic scope and its performance (Hennart, 2007;
Verbeke & Brugman, 2009; Verbeke et al., 2009; Verbeke & Forootan, 2012) and
international success will be determined by the firm’s ability to develop, transfer, deploy
and exploit its FSAs rather than by its geographic scope per se. As such, contrary to
Wolf et al.’s reasoning, performance factors are unlikely to drive the MNE’s commitment
view of MNE international expansion being a path-dependent process, with the path-
dependency being driven by the availability of resources and the need for new FSA
69
!
discussed in the previous section. Internalization theory thus yields the following
theory emphasizes the influence of selection pressures from the external environment on
a firm’s survival. The argument is that profit maximizers are selected, while the ability
environment. This explains persistence of organizational forms over time. Wolf et al.
decreases over time, this will rather be the consequence of a selection process
over time, in the sense that there is nothing deterministic about the international
expansion trajectory followed by individual MNEs (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004). The
70
!
calculus (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004). Alternatively, globalization may occur suddenly as
specific factors.
changes occurring at the level of the population of relevant firms, and adaptation at the
firm level. Koza and Lewin (1998) argue that new organizational forms resulting from
institutional environments, and firm intentionality. Rugman and Verbeke (2004) apply
this thinking to the regionalization phenomenon and argue that MNE regional strategies
are embedded in – and co-evolve with – the broader competitive, organizational and
institutional contexts at the regional level. This suggests the following proposition:
isomorphic pressures from the social and institutional environment in which the firm is
embedded (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Haveman, 1993; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Tolbert
& Zucker, 1983). While institutional theory pays little attention to firm-specific drivers
71
!
of behaviour, neo-institutional theory ascribes a more active role to the firm as an active
carrier of change and innovation (Dacin, Goodstein & Scott, 2002; Leblebici, Salancik,
Copay & King, 1991; Sherer & Lee, 2002). Applying neo-institutional theory to the
regionalization phenomenon, Wolf et al. argue that different industries are subject to
H7a. MNEs from different industries vary in terms of their degree of home-region
orientation.
The authors further suggest that competitors and suppliers are highly relevant to
H7b. If the competitors and suppliers of an MNE are home-region oriented, this
firm will also have a relatively strong tendency towards the home region.
specific factors, supports institutional theory’s key assumption of firms’ social and
etc. (Rugman & Verbeke, 2004), and therefore MNEs from different industries may
indeed vary in their regional strategies. Further, MNEs from different industries differ in
their inter-regional expansion potential, which depends largely on their ability to de-
couple upstream and downstream activities (as discussed under H3b above), and on the
extent of their supply-side autonomy of location choices (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008a).
72
!
H7a - internalization theory version. MNEs from different industries vary in terms
Much empirical support can be found for this proposition in extant literature.
levels by industry; studies conducted by Oh and Rugman (2006) and Rugman and Girod
(2003) explore regionalization in specific industry contexts, and Rugman and Verbeke
However, suppliers’ locations will not necessarily dictate MNE location choices.
with strong FSAs and significant purchasing size (Porter, 1980) may in fact be followed
by a supplier, rather than being a follower itself. In terms of competitors, MNEs may
indeed attempt to gain access to relevant knowledge spillovers and therefore locate close
to competitors; however, they may also choose to put some distance between themselves
knowledge. This, again, is particularly true for large MNEs with strong FSAs that are
vulnerable to appropriation by other firms due to their public goods’ nature (Grøgaard &
Verbeke, 2012). Whether or not the MNE follows its competitors geographically
depends on the extent to which the firm’s technological knowledge is critical to its
existence, and more generally on the nature of the firm’s FSAs as discussed under H2
above. Location choices depend on the interaction of LAs (in this case, availability of
73
!
supplier networks and proximity of relevant competitive knowledge) with the firm’s
FSAs. Wolf et al.’s H7b thus appears at odds with internalization theory:
the MNE’s home-region orientation and that of its suppliers and competitors.
proposition.
As noted above, some of our new propositions formulated from the internalization
theory perspective have already been empirically tested in extant research. For example,
Rugman’s (2005) book contains an analysis of intra-regional sales by region that supports
the lack of a relationship between the region’s level of economic liberalization and the
in H1. The same data support the lack of a higher degree of home-region orientation of
Asian MNEs suggested by H4b. A study by Nachum and Wymbs (2007) demonstrates
that MNE location choices are not determined solely by LAs, including the presence of
relevant agglomeration, but rather by an interaction of those LAs with the firm’s FSAs;
their results provide support for our H2 and H7b. H3b is supported by Rugman and
and Girod (2003) and Rugman and Verbeke (2008a) present empirical evidence of
H3a can be tested using Rugman and Verbeke’s (2004) data by assigning various
74
!
knowledge – industry R&D, skilled labour, and the size of the pool of basic science for a
relationship between MNE international experience and its home-region orientation could
be statistically tested using data from Rugman and Verbeke’s (2004) study, with the level
has a presence (a more sophisticated test would involve a measure of the MNE’s extant
diversity; extant diversity could be operationalized as the sum of the cultural distances
between the countries of every pair of subsidiaries, consistent with Hutzschenreuter et al.,
2011).
tests, and should keep in mind Yair Aharoni’s (1993) warning against relying solely on
According to Aharoni, statistical tests do not capture the MNE’s uniqueness, which could
reside, for example, in the MNE’s absorptive capacity to digest different cultures and to
entrepreneurial qualities. These higher-order FSAs are often at the heart of achieving
superior performance, yet are not easily measured in quantitative terms. In our case, this
is particularly true for H4, H5 and H6, which deal with such complex and
constructs are difficult to operationalize accurately, without losing valuable rich data that
are unique to each particular MNE. Here, in-depth case analyses would likely be more
75
!
helpful than quantitative methods in uncovering the linkages among the MNE
CONCLUSION
interdisciplinary approach can enrich our understanding of MNE regional strategy and
management, interdisciplinary reflection can add much value by facilitating the cross-
pollination of ideas, broadening the scope of available methodologies, and increasing the
pool of knowledge and experience on an important subject matter. This is precisely why
Internalization theory implicitly but powerfully blends key ingredients from paradigms
used in strategic management, such as TCE, RBV and the dynamic capabilities approach,
and is tied to broader concepts from disciplines beyond strategic management, such as
Even mainstream TCE, upon which the economic argument of internalization theory is
Wolf et al. appropriately recognize the need for a broad social focus when
explaining regionalization and offer much needed support for this phenomenon, but we
question the substantive value added beyond the extant internalization theory explanation.
They offer a list of hypotheses, but the question arises whether these hypotheses really
constitute theory (Sutton & Staw, 1995) – especially when considering that some
76
!
hypotheses contradict each other (e.g. H4a and H5), or offer essentially the same
conceptual lenses. It could be argued that enriching extant theory would require the
theory already achieves this goal: it relies on multiple ‘neighbouring’ concepts and in fact
embeds, in its own logic, all of the theories described by Wolf et al. (2011), as reflected
FSAs, CSAs, LAs, recombination, complementary resources and co-evolution (see Table
2.1). Internalization theory’s broader and more nuanced view of the MNE likely explains
contradictions that exist between the authors’ original hypotheses and the restated
does have such general applicability in that it covers a wide variety of aspects of MNE
(Rugman & Verbeke 2008b), and accuracy in that it yields managerially relevant
predictions that have been supported by empirical evidence. Wolf et al.’s set of
77
!
Table 2.1. Complementary social science theories embedded in internalization theory
concepts
78
!
Essay 3
ECONOMIES
The recent surge of emerging economy multinational enterprises (EMNEs) has prompted
theory, can accommodate this phenomenon, or whether new theory is required to study
EMNEs. Advocates for a new theory cite three alleged shortcomings of internalization
theory. First is its MNE-centric nature and related inability to account for institutional
differences between emerging and developed economies. Second is the EMNEs’ alleged
companies through a conceptual lens that assumes strong FSAs. Third is the EMNEs’
unique set of motivations for internationalization. Our view is that these flawed
demonstrate that EMNEs indeed possess FSAs, and that contemporary internalization
institutional specificities and the unique nature of EMNEs’ FSAs and FDI motivations.
We illustrate our argument with examples of ten large successful EMNEs from Asia and
the Americas.
INTRODUCTION
prominent position in the world economy (Wright et al., 2005), in MNE strategic activity
79
!
al. (2000) identified sixty four emerging economies, of which fifty one were rapidly
growing developing countries, and thirteen were in transition from centrally planned to
research on the topic, offering three broad areas for consideration by IB scholars:
situations where firms from developed economies enter emerging economies, situations
where firms from emerging economies enter developed economies, and situations where
firms from emerging economies enter other emerging economies. The last two areas of
research have been of particular interest to IB scholars over the past two decades, since
many MNEs from the BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India and China) and VISTA (Vietnam,
Indonesia, South Africa, Turkey and Argentina) countries, as well as from Mexico and
extant theory, or even an entirely new theory is required to explain EMNEs’ patterns of
consensus has emerged on the topic (Ramamurti, 2009). A number of authors (see Child
& Rodrigues, 2005; Filatotchev et al., 2007; Luo & Tung, 2007; Mathews, 2002a, 2002b,
2006a and 2006b; Peng et al., 2001) argue that EMNEs represent a new class of firms
that follow patterns of international expansion completely different from those of MNEs
from developed countries, and therefore call for a new theory. Others (see Buckley et al.,
2007; Dunning, 2006; Hennart, 2011, 2012; Narula, 2006, 2012; Rugman, 2009) suggest
80
!
equipped to describe and explain EMNE internationalization patterns. Yet, a third group
of authors (see Cuervo-Cazurra & Genc, 2008; Cuervo-Cazurra, 2012; Guillen & Garcia-
Canal, 2009; Ramamurti, 2009) subscribe to a mid-point view that existing core IB
theories can be applied to the EMNE phenomenon provided that they are substantially
dynamic view of firm-specific advantages (FSAs) and views the MNE as a network
organization. In this paper, we argue that internalization theory is sufficient to address the
reality and complexity of MNEs from emerging economies. In the following sections, we
provide a brief history and overview of internalization theory, follow up with a review of
the debate on the theory’s capacity to address the EMNE phenomenon in terms of
logic to ten large EMNEs and show that main internalization theory tenets still hold in the
Internalization theory provides a credible rationale for the existence of the MNE,
and has guided much IB research during the past thirty five years (Buckley & Strange,
2011). It has been characterized as a general theory of the MNE (Rugman, 1981). First
conceptualized by Buckley and Casson (1976), internalization theory has its roots in the
work of Coase (1937), Hymer (1968, 1976) and McManus (1972). The Coasean
81
!
transaction cost approach, according to which a hierarchy supersedes the market if it can
organize transactions more efficiently, provides perhaps the most critical antecedent of
market operating across national borders (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009). Here, the focus is
activities internally by the firm’s management with the cost of managing transactions
externally through the market (Buckley & Strange, 2011). The core argument of
assets across national boundaries is often more efficiently undertaken internally, within
the MNE hierarchy, than through the use of market mechanisms. Firms aim to maximize
profits by internalizing their intermediate markets for knowledge and experience across
with national patent systems, the lack of future markets, imperfect pricing of knowledge
etc. (De Gennaro, 2005; Rugman et al., 2011a). MNE internal organization is aimed to
proprietary ownership helps MNEs overcome the externality of knowledge being a public
good. MNE resulting from the internalization process can thus be seen as a governance
mechanism for developing and exploiting FSAs (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008b). However,
about considering alternative governance modes such as contracts and alliances when
82
!
First proposed by Hymer (1960, published in 1976; 1968) and consequently
developed in Buckley and Casson’s (1976) work, the concept of FSA yields the core
insight that foreign direct investment (FDI) only takes place when the benefits of
exploiting FSAs through internalization can help overcome the additional costs and risks
of doing business abroad, i.e., the liability of foreignness (Zaheer, 1995). International
expansion thus becomes a firm-level strategy decision rather than simply a financial
capability unavailable to competitors (Rugman, 1981) and give the MNE the potential to
VRIO (valuable, rare, inimitable and organized in such a way as to allow a firm to
achieve competitive advantage) resources (Barney, 1991), and had its origins in the
pioneering work of Edith Penrose (1959). Yet, unlike Penrose who believed that
constraints to the firm’s growth resided entirely with the entrepreneur, internalization
theory ascribes a more active role to the firm’s environment, seeing it as a constraining or
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
2
Hymer pioneered a firm-level, industrial organization approach to FDI that was later
MNE foreign entry mode choices. Dunning’s OLI paradigm is frequently referred to as
FDI.
83
!
enabling force. This perspective is reflected in the concept of country-specific advantages
(CSAs) (Rugman, 1981). CSAs (e.g. natural resources, low cost labour, etc.) refer to the
of CSAs and the firm’s FSAs that determines whether internal organization of the MNE’s
capabilities-like perspective. The focus is not only on exploiting existing FSA bundles in
foreign markets, but also on managing the international FSA development and transfer
processes in their entirety, i.e., from early creation to subsequent usage across the MNE
network. Internalization theory in its current, most modern, iteration took a long time to
develop. Almost immediately after its inception (Buckley & Casson, 1976),
(see Buckley, 1983, 1998a, 1998b; Casson, 1979, 1986, 1987; Rugman, 1981; Teece,
1983). Still, early internalization theory, exemplified by the work of Buckley and Casson,
and Rugman, focused primarily on explaining which parameters would stimulate firms to
expand across borders and on investigating entry mode choice, and largely ignored
internal governance issues and organizational structures within the MNE. Subsequent
Rugman and Verbeke (1992, 2003), among others, led to what can be called the ‘new’
internalization theory, with the emphasis shifting to the MNE’s internal organization and
attention to the role of complementary resources of foreign actors that the MNE may
84
!
require in order to enable the exploitation of its own FSAs, can be seen as a beginning of
a shift toward the ‘new’ internalization theory. This line of thinking is further developed
in Hennart’s subsequent research, where he argues that host country CSAs are not
the MNE and other ones by owners of local CSAs (Hennart, 2009). In his most recent
work, Hennart (2011, 2012) uses his bundling model, which gives equal importance to
FSAs and CSAs, to analyze EMNE behaviour, predicting that EMNEs will make FDI
investments to access not only generally available CSAs, but also FSAs embedded in
foreign firms. Such FSAs may be accessible, inter alia, through employment contracts
with personnel located abroad and that can be ‘poached away’ from local rivals, or
through service contracts, e.g., to use local distribution networks, or through acquisitions
if the coveted FSAs are embedded in local firms and cannot be isolated from other assets.
The shift from the early internalization theory’s focus on economic efficiency and
choices within the MNE is evident in the work of Benito et al. (2009) and Chen (2005,
2010). Benito et al. propose that the choice of foreign entry mode is not necessarily a
choice among well-specified discrete alternatives, but rather reflects a messier reality
where mode packages, within-mode adjustments and mode role changes frequently take
place, and the simultaneous presence of multiple modes in various types of combinations
85
!
manufacturing (OEM), arguing that the choice of an optimal entry mode depends on the
relative costs and benefits of both the market for technology and the market for
manufacture. Like Hennart and Benito and colleagues, Chen specifically recognizes the
significantly augment the early MNE-centric thinking, which indeed neglected the roles
NLB) FSAs. NLB FSAs are typically developed at headquarters (HQ) and are easily
transferable across borders to the entire MNE network. Examples of NLB FSAs include
quality control capabilities can be considered NLB FSAs. Conversely, LB FSAs are tied
to select affiliates within the MNE, whether the HQ or subsidiaries, and can include
privileged retail locations), resources which may lose value when transferred across
borders (e.g. reputational resources), local best practices and routines, capabilities in local
NLB FSAs has invited an important shift in internalization theory thinking: from the view
2001), toward a more realistic analysis of the MNE as a differentiated network. Further,
this extension of internalization theory has led to the concepts of subsidiary-specific and
86
!
subsidiary or alliance level (Rugman & Verbeke, 2001; Verbeke, 2009), and embedded in
cannot necessarily be automatically dispersed throughout the rest of the MNE network.
Similarly, ASAs are embedded in the network and are lost when the MNE leaves the
network, as is the case with international airline alliances. The concepts of SSA and ASA
capabilities and internal governance, and its extension to MNE alliance networks.
During the past decade, the growth of emerging economies has invited an
increasing number of research studies on the topic, which has led to a vivid debate in the
international expansion patterns, and can it be used to predict their profitability and
survival (Hennart, 2011)? A sizable group of IB scholars believes that EMNEs represent
an entirely new phenomenon and follow a pattern of expansion completely different from
2005), which are often at the heart of the EMNE’s international expansion decisions. In
this context, internalization theory has also been accused of tending toward one-sided,
exclusion of a role of formal and informal institutional underpinnings that largely shape
MNEs’ business environment, strategies and performance (Hoskisson et al., 2000; Peng,
87
!
Wang & Jiang, 2008; Wright et al., 2005). The fact that EMNEs operate in an
2008).
and the very nature of EMNEs. While internalization theory, in particular, focuses on
FSA exploitation by MNEs, emerging economy multinationals are argued de facto not to
possess FSAs; according to this logic, they internationalize to acquire new FSAs rather
than to exploit existing ones (Mathews, 2002a, 2002b, 2006a and 2006b). These new
FSAs acquired through international expansion are then used as a springboard for further
internationalization (Luo & Tung, 2007). The fact that EMNEs essentially lack the very
rationale for new theory development (Child & Rodrigues, 2005). In some cases, non-
economic objectives for expansion are argued to produce completely different patterns of
national interests (Vernon, 1984), in addition to economic goals, are often cited as
examples.
88
!
Unfortunately, the above contentions appear to have been associated with a lack
theory by IB scholars working within the emerging economy context. Currently, four
separate, conceptual perspectives – TCE, agency theory, RBV and institutional theory –
have been proposed as leading theoretical frameworks for studying emerging economies
(Hoskisson et al, 2000; Meyer & Peng, 2004; Peng et al, 2001). However, internalization
theory, with its blending of TCE and RBV elements, and with its simultaneous focus on
analyzing transaction costs and effectively matching the firm’s FSAs to its environment,
MNE, including the emerging economy MNE, stems largely from poor or incomplete
Since its first iteration in Buckley and Casson’s classic work, internalization
extensions (see Ellis, 2011; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Madhok; 1997). It is important to
89
!
recognize that contemporary internalization theory actually does focus on managing
innovation processes in their entirety, and is therefore concerned not merely with
economizing, but also with strategizing for value creation purposes, including in the
In response to the charge that internalization theory has been derived primarily
to the exclusion of the role of external actors, countries and institutions, it should be
noted that the new internalization theory has long moved away from its MNE-centric
focus and has fully recognized the complex and multilateral nature of international
internalization thinking, takes into account interactions among MNEs, local firms and
host governments. Hennart successfully uses his bundling model to analyze EMNEs’
FDI. He predicts that EMNEs will expand abroad to access FSAs that are embedded in
foreign firms and accessible through employment contracts with overseas personnel.
Here, monopoly control of CSAs allows EMNEs to capture value from the joint
economy MNEs), with FDI as one possible vehicle to generate bundling of these CSAs
90
!
within internalization theory and is reflected in differential transaction costs. Institutional
differences between developed and emerging economies are likely to give rise to
different levels of transaction costs associated with alternative entry modes, and to
present new economizing challenges (Wright et al., 2005). For example, MNEs from
rationality and bounded reliability problems (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009), thus bearing
when compared to indigenous firms and EMNEs from other emerging economies. In
other words, institutions do matter in internalization theory because they can affect the
As noted above, some scholars posit that EMNEs do not possess FSAs, and thus
their behaviour cannot be explained within the traditional FSA-centric framework.3 One
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
3
Some internalization theory scholars also subscribe to the position that EMNEs lack
FSAs (Rugman, 2009; Lessard and Lucea, 2009). According to this mistaken viewpoint,
EMNEs rely entirely on their access to CSAs (e.g. oil and gas in Russia, cheap labour in
China, etc.) – a strategy that is not sustainable in the long run. Unlike proponents of
EMNEs will not be successful abroad due to their lack of FSAs. In response to this line
of reasoning, it can be argued, in accordance with Hennart’s (2009, 2011, 2012) bundling
perspective, that even domestic CSAs are not readily accessible to all home country
91
!
of the most well-known advocates of this viewpoint, Mathews (2002a, 2002b, 2006a,
2006b) argues that Asian EMNEs, which he terms Dragon multinationals, are essentially
resource-poor, yet have successfully expanded abroad without FSAs. Mathews’ LLL
framework, based on the premises of resource Linkage, Leverage, and Learning, suggests
This misconception potentially stems from the confusion surrounding the notion
of FSAs, and from the failure to let go of conventional internalization theory in its earliest
spending; and 2) the value of the company’s brand, as measured by its advertising
expenditures. These very imperfect proxies for the firm’s true technological and
marketing capabilities may, in the past, have provided a reasonable approximation for an
MNE’s FSAs, but are largely inapplicable in the emerging economy context, where firms
technology purchases and early alliance formation), and may lack a history of advertising
branding may indeed not be EMNE’s critical competitive strengths. Yet, this does not
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
MNEs. Access to these resources and the ability to utilize them in a profitable way should
be seen as distinct FSAs. In the emerging economy context, this access may imply an
idiosyncratic resources that form a critical part of the firm’s bundle of FSAs, in addition
92
!
mean that EMNEs do not possess FSAs – only that their FSAs may be dramatically
different from those of developed economies’ MNEs. Here, the quality of management
plays a crucial role. Teece (2007) has convincingly argued that entrepreneurial
evolutionary fitness. This FSA in entrepreneurial quality largely accounts for the success
of the Indian Tata Group’s innovative Nano product (the world’s cheapest car), and for
the competitive worldwide presence of Taiwanese Acer Inc. Mexico’s Cemex, in turn,
owes its past international success to another complex managerial capability – its superior
system for managing international merger and acquisition processes. A Chinese ‘dragon’
technology and knowledge assets, was able to do so largely due to its highly
organizational structure.
Garcia-Canal, 2009; Ramamurti, 2009; Zeng & Williamson, 2007) have acknowledged
that EMNEs do possess FSAs, which can be exploited through FDI, though those FSAs
differ from traditional ones described in the IB literature on developed country MNEs.
FSAs mentioned include a better understanding of emerging market customers and ability
to adapt technology to develop products suited for special needs customers (relevant
when expanding to other emerging economies and competing with developed country
93
!
function in difficult conditions), fewer core rigidities and greater entrepreneurial freedom
Yet, the argument that the dramatically different nature of FSAs requires a new
theory to study EMNEs is deeply flawed. All the EMNE FSAs listed above are examples
across borders in a way that creates value for the MNE (Verbeke, 2009). The fact that
EMNE strengths reside primarily in such higher-order FSAs rather than in more
still holds: The firm’s international success will depend on its ability to match
successfully its set of FSAs with host country CSAs. It is the generic characteristics of
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
4
Some of the FSAs frequently ascribed to EMNEs, such as greater flexibility to respond
& Garcia-Canal, 2009), are obviously not EMNE-specific but can typically be found with
94
!
these FSAs (e.g., transferability across borders and inimitability) and CSAs (easily
transacted in open markets or not) that will determine optimal entry mode choice and
subsequent governance. In its parsimony, internalization theory can explain the particular
with CSAs
strategic goals or motivations, which then lead to particular desired FSA - CSA
combinations, and subsequent location choices and operating mode selections. In this
context, Guillen and Garcia-Canal (2009) summarize nine motivations for EMNEs’ FDI
documented in the literature: backward linkage into raw materials, forward linkage into
‘unique’ motivations for international expansion do not necessitate a new theory either.
Many of the motivations identified for EMNEs can be found in developed economy
MNEs, as well, and, generally speaking, fit as subcategories into the four main FDI
market seeking, strategic resource seeking, and efficiency seeking (Dunning & Lundan,
2008; Verbeke, 2009), as shown in Table 3.1. Whether or not EMNEs need to upgrade
95
!
their capabilities while achieving their international expansion objectives is an issue of
matching FSAs with CSAs (Rugman, 2009), and is addressed fully by internalization
theory.
above, we now turn to the analysis of the expansion trajectories of real-world EMNEs, in
an effort to investigate whether EMNEs indeed possess FSAs, whether these FSAs are
similar to or different from FSAs of developed country MNEs, and whether EMNEs’
emerging multinationals” described in Van Agtmael’s (2007: 59) classic book. We then
assessed which MNEs out of this group of twenty five companies had been the subject of
detailed business school cases, addressing their international expansion trajectories. This
led to inclusion of ten MNEs in our analysis, including five Asian-based ones, with the
other five being headquartered in the Americas. We then analyzed a total of fifty three
description of the sample companies. Table 3.2 and Appendix 3.1 present a list of the
96
!
EMNEs studied, and corresponding lists of teaching cases5. Appendix 3.2 offers a
summary of vignettes taken directly from our data to illustrate our argument.
FSAs
Our reading of the data clearly showed that all ten EMNEs studied possessed
FSAs beyond access to home-country LAs. Some FSAs were indeed based on
preferential access to home CSAs – for example, Infosys’ and Tata Group’s access to top
engineering talent and to cheap skilled labour in India, or Concha Y Toro’s proximity to
Chile’s unique terroir (ideal conditions for wine-making). Yet, the EMNEs in our sample
relied on complex bundles of FSAs, both LB and NLB. Staring with LB FSAs, we
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
5!It should be noted that the use of teaching cases as secondary research data has
sometimes been criticized for unreported data bias (Kieser, 1994; Liang & Wang, 2004),
and two levels of abstraction (Miller & Friesen, 1977). However, teaching cases are
provided that they are used properly (Ambrosini, Bowman & Collier, 2010), which
means that cases should be selected through purposive sampling and drawn from
recognized case producers to ensure sufficient quality of information, and that multiple
cases and/or supplemental information should be used for each company to triangulate
the data. We followed this recommended protocol and, as a result, gained access to rich
97
!
• Embeddedness in local networks, including extensive distribution and sales networks:
extensive benefits from local government connections. Embraer and Petrobras had
• Knowledge of local markets: Evident in particular at Haier, Tata, Cemex, and Lenovo,
needs more effectively and efficiently than rival MNEs from emerging economies.
Haier’s superior capability to identify and quickly fill vacant market niches, as well as
of management.
• Commitment to innovation: Embraer is known across the globe for its technological
expertise and engineering prowess. Tenaris invests heavily into R&D. Cemex’ has a
long history of nurturing innovation, both in products and processes; its management
markets, as companies that possess this FSA have processes and routines in place to
countries. Tata Group routinely adapts its products and services to serve a particular
client group. Haier translates its market research capabilities into product
98
!
modifications in various markets. Cemex has successfully combined a global
business model of standardized processes and systems to serve specific needs of local
customer groups. Lenovo quickly responds to local market demands with product
customization. Petrobras stands out against other state-owned oil companies in Latin
management capabilities.
So far, all FSAs outlined above differ from ‘traditional’ NLB FSAs typically
ascribed to developed economy MNEs, such as brand and technological strength. Yet,
Tata’s, Cemex’ and Samsung’s strong brands are a powerful expression of this point, as
99
!
from traditionally assumed paths of advertising and R&D investment. Lenovo’s brand,
exclusive result of proprietary R&D. In its early years, Samsung licensed much of its
technological know-how. On the other hand, Embraer owes much of its technology
contention holds: EMNEs do possess FSAs, both LB and NLB; some of these FSAs can
be dramatically different from those found in their developed country counterparts, and
some are very similar; yet, paths of developing FSAs may diverge from traditionally
assumed advertising and R&D investments, and therefore cannot always be measured by
traditional proxies.
Recombination capabilities
In line with internalization theory logic, the EMNEs in our sample did not owe
their international success exclusively to home country CSAs – Haier in fact had an
unsustainable proposition. Rather, the ability to compete was determined by the EMNEs’
abilities to effectively bundle and recombine their FSAs with CSAs of home and host
countries to transform their LB FSAS into NLB ones, and to develop new LB FSAs in
host countries. Infosys, for example, built its entire strategic approach on recombination.
Its “Global Delivery Model” means sourcing capital from where it is cheapest, producing
where it is most cost effective, and selling where it is most profitable. Likewise,
100
!
Samsung was able to take advantage of its flexible manufacturing processes to establish a
through navigating alliance relationships, and later used this capability to manage its
international network of subsidiaries. Haier was able to increase its host country
in host countries, and entering into alliances to access host country knowledge-based
CSAs. In all cases, in line with internalization theory predictions, recombination became
international markets.
Internationalization drivers
seeking, efficiency seeking, and natural resource seeking. Strategic resource seeking was
perhaps the most prominent motivation, lending some limited credence to the claim that
Haier’s stated objective of expansion into developed markets was to “observe, digest,
imitate” technology and processes in the developed world. Similarly, one of Samsung’s
major goals for internationalization is to tap into top global talent. However, creating
disadvantage through FSA acquisition are not mutually exclusive. For example,
Samsung was able to take advantage of global talent due to its NLB FSA in innovative
101
!
Market seeking was a prominent internationalization driver among the EMNEs
studied. Lenovo’s international expansion was a response to the maturation of the local
PC market and increased competition from international retailers, while Concha Y Toro
sought to escape from a small and unsophisticated domestic market for wine.
Efficiency seeking was one of the primary internationalization drivers for Infosys,
serve them more efficiently. For Cemex, internalization served as a way of managing the
Finally, natural resource seeking was a primary expansion driver for Petrobras,
who sought to reach promising exploration areas in South America. We have thus
demonstrated that EMNEs’ internationalization drivers fit within the existing paradigm,
motives.
The sharp rise of EMNEs brought the phenomenon of state owned enterprises
emerging economies: SOEs are major economic players in many industrialized nations,
accounting for large shares of gross domestic product (GDP) (particularly in Europe),
and competing with leading corporations in various industries (Hafsi, Kiggundu, &
Jorgensen, 1987; MacCarthaigh, 2011). That being said, SOEs are possibly more
common in emerging markets, namely when the state plays an active interventionist role
in economic transformation from central planning to the market economy (Hu & Lin,
102
!
2013). With internationalization processes of SOE EMNEs being driven, at least partly,
We argue that, from the internalization theory perspective, SOEs may indeed
possess a set of unique FSAs, such as access to cheap capital, increased latitude for risk,
and ready access to decision-making bodies in the government and consequent ability in
influence, potentially, national policy. Further, SOEs from emerging economies may be
exempt from stringent regulations and policies to which their private counterparts are
subjected – e.g., human rights codes or environmental regulations. This latter point has
become a strongly debated topic in the West following increasing inward investment by
foreign SOEs, such as the Chinese National Oversees Oil Corporation’s (CNOOC)
purchase of Nexen Inc. (Canada), the Petronas (Malaysian state-owned oil company)
purchase of Progress Energy Resources (Canada) (Boothe, 2013), and the Aluminum
These FSAs, however, are only advantageous if the EMNE’s goals are consistent with
home government goals (Rugman & Verbeke, 1998) – as is the case of Chinese oil
companies, whose cross-border expansion (e.g. into Africa and Canada) advances
China’s energy security strategy. If the goals of the enterprise and the government are in
conflict, the EMNE will either be privatized, or its FSAs will turn into serious strategic
those of the MNE’s. Consider Embraer’s near-collapse in the 80’s, when the company’s
dependency on its relationship with the Brazilian military became destructive following
the fall of military dictatorship and a consequent sharp decline in military contracts
103
!
(Embraer was finally privatized in 1994 and went through a remarkable turnaround over
It is important to remember that all SOEs were not created equal and range greatly
in the degree of government ownership and involvement, the type of involvement, the
level of government involved, and, most importantly, in the SOEs’ strategy, objectives
and competitive characteristics. It has in fact been argued that the line between SOEs and
SOE assets are sold in the open market, and SOEs strive to become leaner, more
China, for example, the policy of separating government functions from business
operations is becoming increasingly applied, and SOEs’ access to capital at below market
With this in mind, we argue that it is not the ownership, but rather the
international market. The conditions faced by SOEs and private firms in international
markets are similar; yet SOEs’ FSAs related to government ownership are more likely to
be LB. SOEs’ challenge is therefore to effectively transfer and recombine their FSAs
with host country CSAs. Lenovo and Haier (where the Chinese government is a
Electric, a Chinese government-owned consumer electronic giant, failed its entry into the
104
!
public monopolies. The benefits of shelter-based behaviour break down if it fails in the
waste. As such, internalization theory holds for SOEs, whether emerging or developed
country-based.
CONCLUSION
Advocates for a brand new theory to study EMNEs typically cite three alleged
context: 1) its MNE-centric nature and related inability to take into account drastic
FSAs, which makes them unsuitable for analysis through a lens whose core foundation is
based on exploiting existing FSAs abroad; and 3) EMNEs’ unique set of motivations for
FDI. Our view is that these contentions are flawed and caused by an incomplete
understanding of internalization theory, or by the lack of familiarity with its most recent
transaction costs and MNE functioning; (b) can handle EMNEs’ idiosyncratic FSAs,
though we do agree that these FSAs can be significantly different from those of
developed country MNEs; and (c) does make predictions that are not fundamentally
ten successful, large EMNEs, showing that internalization theory predictions hold in the
emerging economy context – not surprisingly, as a ‘good theory’ should explain firm
behaviour in general, and not just under particular circumstances (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2012).
As such, we do not need a new theory to study EMNEs – rather, we need a new set of
105
!
proxies to measure EMNEs’ FSAs, as our examples clearly demonstrate that traditional
proxies are not necessarily applicable to EMNEs, even when FSAs are in fact traditional.
to the complex and intangible nature of many EMNEs’ FSAs. Here, IB scholars could
benefit from turning to the modern RBV literature: While little predictive work has been
done within this theoretical framework, RBV scholars have been instrumental in
based empirical studies have demonstrated that it is very difficult to capture the messy
and complex reality of international business by industry averages and statistical tests
(Aharoni, 1993). These difficulties are amplified in the emerging economy context,
where research subjects are fewer and many constructs are new, unique and poorly
understand much more about companies’ FSAs if we relied more on the tools of the
business historian than those of the mainstream economist. Extending this logic to
studying EMNEs, we are likely to advance our knowledge further and faster by
supplementing conventional statistical approaches of large samples with case studies and
longitudinal research. This type of work would likely validate our main point that
internalization theory indeed remains the general theory of the MNE, irrespective of this
106
!
Table 3.1. EMNE motivation for international expansion versus existing motivation
framework
107
!
Essay 4
Alfred Chandler, the greatest business historian of our time, is often regarded as an
antecedent. TCE has invited much criticism for its key behavioural assumption of
opportunism – a concept that Chandler, despite his close ties with TCE, does not appear
to endorse. We revisit Chandler’s classic history of the Du Pont and General Motors
corporations to investigate whether opportunism was indeed a key factor in the making of
the modern corporation, and propose an alternative framework to explain failed human
existing theory and create a new set of behavioural assumptions to complement and
augment the current assumptions of TCE. We argue that the proposed model of bounded
reliability (BRel) corresponds more accurately to Chandler’s view of the nature of man
central concept of the study of the firm may increase the legitimacy of TCE, and lay the
INTRODUCTION
discipline of business history in particular, is profound and lasting. Chandler has been
108
!
called “the most influential business historian of the twentieth century” (John, 2011: 185)
and has been lauded for “almost inventing the field of strategic management” (Winter &
Teece, 2010: 365). His monumental works, such as “Strategy and Structure” (1962),
“Pierre S. Du Pont and the Making of the Modern Corporation” (1971), “The Visible
Hand” (1977) and “Scale and Scope” (1990), set the standards for business and economic
consideration of future business trends (Curtean, 2010). Of particular interest for the
purpose of this paper is Chandler’s complex relationship with transaction cost economics
(TCE), a core theory of management science into whose development Chandler was de-
facto co-opted by Oliver Williamson – TCE’s creator who earned the 2009 Nobel Prize in
field (David & Han, 2004), TCE has received much attention from a broad range of
audiences (Rindfliesch & Heide, 1997), but has also invited much criticism, mainly for its
agents that populate firms and markets have an inherent proclivity toward opportunism,
109
!
A key behavioural assumption of a core paradigm in the organization studies
field, opportunism has come to occupy a significant place in management research; yet,
its legitimacy has been continually questioned in the academic literature (Conner &
Prahalad, 1991; Ghoshal, 2005; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Hodgson, 2004). This
effectively reduces the legitimacy of TCE as a general theory of the firm, as realistic
As Simon famously pointed out, “nothing is more fundamental in setting our research
agenda and informing our research methods than our view of the nature of the human
beings, whose behaviour we are studying. It makes a difference, a very large difference,
assumptions that form the basis of theory be appropriately tested, at least if this theory is
to be relevant to the practice of strategy. Unfortunately, Tsang (2006) argues that tests on
behavioural assumptions at the core of TCE – bounded rationality, risk neutrality and
opportunism – are largely absent in empirical research. To illustrate his point, Tsang cites
David and Han’s (2004) systematic assessment of the empirical support for TCE. David
and Han examined 308 statistical tests of TCE constructs from 63 articles and found that
only 19 tests involved opportunism as a variable, while most of the tests invoked the
empirical support, opportunism has been criticized for its narrow conceptual focus and,
broadly speaking, for inaccurate portrayal of the human nature (Verbeke & Greidanus,
2009). Jolls, Sunstein and Thaler (1998) argue that the assumption of unbounded self-
by TCE scholars in favour of the bounded rationality (Simon, 1961) construct. The
110
!
objective of this paper is to explore alternative factors that may, in addition to or in place
literature, but have not as of yet made major inroads into management science. In their
pioneering article on a behavioural approach to law and economics, Jolls et al. (1998)
assumption of bounded rationality, yet these constructs do not fully explain non-
behavioural assumptions was offered by Verbeke and Greidanus (2009), who proposed
intentional deceit. In this paper, we extend Verbeke and Greidanus’ model by suggesting
history of the Du Pont and General Motors corporations (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971), in
substantial organizational transformation. Chandler’s work offers fertile ground for our
TCE: Our prediction is that Chandler’s view of the human nature is much different from
111
!
In the remainder of the paper, we discuss the behavioural assumption of opportunism as it
bounded reliability, show how this concept is reflected in the ‘making of the modern
corporation’ (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971) and finally extend this concept by suggesting
is evident in the fact that the multidivisional enterprise theory has often been referred to
as “the Chandler-Williamson M-form hypothesis” (Rumelt, Schendel & Teece, 1991: 14).
Williamson uses Chandler’s work as an antecedent that has a bearing on the TCE
approach to the study of economic institutions in general and, in particular, to the study of
the modern corporation, especially when it comes to the changing structure of the
corporation over the past 150 years (Williamson, 1981, 1985). !Williamson has
essentially formulated Chandler’s analysis of the two prototype structures (McGee &
enterprise (Williamson 1981, 1996). The key reason for the existence of M-form is
Williamson is correct in that Chandler was mainly concerned with the description
rather than explanation of organizational change (Williamson, 1981b), and that his
detailed account of events that led to the formation of a modern corporation was therefore
112
!
open to interpretation. Chandler’s concern is mainly with the interaction between the
well as with the virtuous paths of learning (John, 1997), which the M-form is better able
Chandler’s and Williamson’s take on the origins of the M-form structure. Yet, while
strategic factors that are central to Chandler’s oeuvre undoubtedly depend on personal
action (Barnard, 1968; Ghemawat, 2002), Chandler did not pay explicit attention to
best explanation for the behaviour of characters that populate Chandlers’ business
Chandler, it seems, has a broader perspective of human nature, and may be sending a
different message through his careful and rich descriptions. During their transition from
loosely run family businesses to giant modern enterprises, growing firms such as Du Pont
and General Motors are bound to encounter challenges and conflicts, and many of these
challenges are bound to have a human dimension. Conflicts between personal and
impersonal values, business’ intrusion on kinship, a need to cope with change, a capacity
to process new information and absorb new ways of doing business are but a few
their journey toward a modern corporation. Many of these problems are related to
bounded rationality and, indeed, opportunism, which triggered failed commitments, i.e.,
113
!
universal explanation of such failures; Chandler indeed described other important
behavioural drivers.!
that Chandler, despite some of his reservations about TCE’s treatment of R&D, HR, and
growth through diversification (Chandler, 1982), was pleased and flattered by being co-
opted into its creation by the “leading figure of this approach” (Chandler, 1992: 85).
Stating that he had been enlightened by Williamson (Chandler, 1982), Chandler agrees
that the TCE approach is particularly relevant when studying the evolution of the large
industrial corporation, and that it “provides one of the sharpest, most precise means yet
devised to analyze the impact of technological and market changes on the structure of the
enterprises and the industries” (Chandler, 1982: 128). Chandler further cultivated his
connection to TCE and its author by thanking Williamson “for his imperialistic efforts to
join transaction cost economics with business history” (Chandler, 1982: 129). Chandler
operates with TCE concepts in his discussions of managerial capitalism (visible hand of
managerial direction vs. invisible hand of market mechanism – Chandler, 1981), and
attempts to embrace TCE in The Visible Hand (Chandler, 1977), although his use of TCE
as a conceptual lens did not extend much past the beginning of the book and did not
appear to have illuminated the story (Winter & Teece, 2010). In his later writings,
Chandler seems to turn away from TCE; he articulated his reservations with it as a theory
of the firm in his 1992 Journal of Economic Perspectives article (Chandler, 1992).
Unlike Williamson, who views the individual transaction as the basic unit of analysis
secondary concern (John, 2011) and focuses instead on the firm and its specific physical
114
!
and human assets, with the emphasis placed on production rather than exchange, and
learning and knowledge creation rather than boundaries between the firm and the market
(John, 1997). Convinced that the unit of analysis in a theory of the firm must be the firm,
Chandler writes that “only by focusing on the firm can theory predict the firm’s
observable at the level of an individual transaction than at the level of the firm – this is
perhaps why Chandler does not seem to share Williamson’s concern with opportunism.
We argue that the most relevant unit of analysis of economic actors’ imperfect
transactions. Strategies and processes are not created at the transaction level, and thus
economizing mechanisms will not be developed for each individual transaction. At the
firm level, on the other hand, observability is limited because the existence of the firm,
where critical change processes take place, and this is also where economizing
mechanisms reside, as routines inherently leave less room for imperfect effort than an
individual transaction due to built-in correction mechanisms. This level offers a great
115
!
vantage point from which to observe and understand complex intra-firm processes and
extent than at the too-narrow level of the individual transaction, or at the too-broad level
of the firm.
Chandler’s classic book, “Pierre S. Du Pont and the Making of the Modern Corporation”
– a renowned detailed account of the functioning of various parts and sections of the Du
Pont and General Motors corporation, written from the point of view of Pierre S. Du
Pont, a prominent business figure of his time and a critical force behind both
corporations’ unprecedented growth and success observed during the years the book
employees, managers, directors and business partners that may explain failed
commitments for reasons other than intentional deceit. We approach this search from the
level of a class of transactions, and, in doing so rely on the bounded reliability (BRel)
construct and extends the assumption of opportunism by including the many situations
where parties may fail to deliver on commitments while not intentionally engaging in
self-interest seeking with guile. Bounded reliability reflects the often-observed reality of
failed commitments caused by a variety of factors including but not limited to intentional
116
!
deceit (but excluding technical error, human incompetence or exogenous circumstances),
ante commitments in good faith (with benevolent intent), but the importance of those
commitments diminishes over time (preferences are reordered). Time discounting bias
(placing a lower value on future events than more proximate events) can also cause
the point that such commitments can no longer be fulfilled. Scaling back on
also be attributed to the planning fallacy, whereby planners rely on best-case scenarios
identify a large number of mechanisms for economizing on the three facets of bounded
reliability. In practical terms, these mechanisms may include realistic goal-setting, regular
reviews and imposition of limits on the size and scope of new activities.
117
!
While this framework was developed in the context of the multinational enterprise
multidivisional companies. In Williamson’s words, the MNE uses “the M-form structure
to extend asset management from a domestic base to include foreign operations. Thus the
domestic M-form strategy for decomposing complex business structures into semi-
Verbeke and Greidanus for MNEs are likely also to be observable in the multidivisional
METHODOLOGY
Data
Our analysis of the content of Chandler’s book, “Pierre S. Du Pont and the
writing, characterized by rich and detailed descriptions, offers ample opportunities for
foundational business history piece allowed identifying the context and reasons for
insight into which elements composing the ‘nature of man’ truly affect organizational
118
!
Theory building
The purpose of this paper is to elaborate on existing theory, TCE (Pratt, 2009), by
closing the critical gap created by the insufficiency of present behavioural assumptions,
and creating a new set of new behavioural assumptions to complement and augment the
existing ones. We adopted elements of the grounded theory approach (Strauss, 1987),
and followed procedures outlined by Glaser and Strauss (1967) and subsequently
modified and extended by other researchers espousing qualitative methods (Corbin &
Strauss, 1990; Glaser, 1978; Martin & Turner, 1986; Strauss & Corbin, 1990; Turner,
1981, 1983). Our analysis involved two broad stages. We started our data analysis with
reliability (the observed three facets of bounded reliability), and built additional insights
through the iterative analysis process. That is, in the first stage, we analyzed the book to
coding the text according to the three categories pertaining to the above dimensions. In
the second stage, we searched for emerging themes and patterns of managerial behaviour
that may extend the existing BRel framework by offering additional insights into reasons
followed the principles of the constant comparative method (Shah & Corley, 2006). As
compared the examples to clarify the themes. At the same time, emerging themes
directed us to other potentially relevant examples in the text. Finally we grouped each set
119
!
(Corbin & Strauss, 1990; Strauss & Corbin, 1996). For example, executives’ reluctance
to accept new roles following Du Pont’s Executive Committee in 1903 and Du Pont
refine its properties and relationships through continuous text analysis (Locke & Golden-
Biddle, 1997).
and their relationship to each other, all the while continuing to refer to the text in an
attempt to gain a deep understanding of the nuances of the data (Locke & Golden-Biddle,
1997). Our objective was to tell a cohesive story (Pratt, 2009) of how different categories
of BRel fit together and with the previously suggested model, how they fix the current
gap in TCE behavioural assumptions, and the role they played in the making of the
modern corporation. To put our story into its proper context, we included backgrounds of
120
!
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
commitments, including (but not limited to) the three existing categories of BRel. We
embezzlement, when, in 1904, one of the Du Pont company’s most trusted and respected
West Coast managers attempted to deliberately cheat the company out of $47,000 (p.
169). Other examples occurred at the time of a financial crisis. During a severe
economic downturn of 1907, Du Pont’s long-standing supplier of one of the most critical
contract on very short notice (p. 219). The supplier requested deposit of collateral, which
had not been a part of the previous arrangement. After the request was granted, the
Du Pont’s transactions and imposing additional requirements for the deposit of collateral.
While it is plausible that the supplier broke the existing arrangements to fulfill new
internal requirements in light of extraordinary circumstances (in which case this event
self-interest, as the supplier attempted to use the circumstances – a severe financial crisis
and the business partner’s high dependence on the supplied product – to achieve financial
121
!
gain. This example concerns Du Pont’s entire relationship with its supplier and therefore
represents a set of transactions, rather than an individual transaction or the entire firm,
confirming our earlier statement that a class of transactions may well be the most
A notorious antitrust lawsuit against Du Pont (observed from the point of view of
(pp. 259-300). The lawsuit was first brought about by a former employee, who could not
adapt to new ways of doing business after Du Pont’s restructuring in the early 1900s, and
resigned to start his own company. Bitter from losing his privileged position, Robert
monopolizing the market and using unfair competitive tactics to drive smaller industry
players out of business. The motivation for Waddell’s behaviour was probably twofold:
First, it was partly personal vendetta; second, he was hoping to collect damages by
proving that his own company was a victim of unfair competitive practices. In
implementing his attack, Waddell did not shy away from distorting facts and using false
premises (e.g. stating that Du Pont was selling at a loss for the purpose of destroying
extortion upon the government, etc.) – as such, this was another example of intentional
122
!
made initially in 1911 (p. 326). Although representing Coleman’s private commitment,
reprioritization (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009). Coleman planned to finance the road
construction himself, and to donate the highway to the people. The commitment was
likely a political move aimed at enhancing Coleman’s reputation, as at the time he had
construction was suspended due to difficulties encountered with downstate farmers who
were asked to sell land for a right of way, and for a while, Coleman focused on other
public: the commitment was postponed (as is often the case with benevolent
reprioritization), and construction resumed in 1926 and was brought to a close one bit at a
time.
be found in the way General Motors Corporation was managed prior to Pierre Du Pont’s
becoming involved with the company in 1915. General Motors’ President and founder,
William C. Durant, ran the company in a “fast-moving, free-wheeling manner” (p. 456),
involved in all intricacies of the company’s operations and must have greatly
much method or system, without an adequate decision-making body and without active
123
!
crisis and was unable to meet its obligations to shareholders. Some of the problem is
related to bounded rationality (i.e. the natural limits of both Durant’s knowledge on
various functional aspects of the business, and his intellectual capabilities), but the
functional areas must have been at the heart of the issue. It must be noted that, despite
the broad nature of the issue, this example deals not with the firm in its entirety, but
rather with a set of transactions pertaining to general management issues – and more
engine program in 1922 is likely related to the BRel challenge of overcommitment (pp.
544-546). Substantial resources and time had been committed to the development of this
important innovation. Pierre Du Pont, who was inspired by this innovation and foresaw a
great future for it in the automobile industry, actively pushed the production of the new
engine. However, Pierre must have overestimated the company’s ability to develop, test
and refine the engine in time to meet production deadlines. His overcommitment was
further fuelled by unrealistic promises of R&D and production managers, who were
overcommitment at different levels in the organization led to the engine’s market failure:
the newly engineered engine performed poorly, and the market’s reception of copper-
cooled cars was unfavourable. The Executive Committee decided to reprioritize, focusing
on an expansion program for Chevrolet instead of the further development of the copper-
cooled engine, to the great disappointment of Pierre Du Pont and Charles Kettering,
124
!
General Motors’ engineer in charge of R&D. Kettering attributed this preference reversal
to “an organized resistance within the Corporation” (p. 544); however, it was more likely
a rational decision driven by the poor performance of the prototype copper-cooled engine,
which, in turn, was due to management’s and R&D’s initial overestimation of the
company’s ability to produce the innovation. Here again, we are dealing with a class of
whole.
against the Du Pont company (pp. 259-300), already discussed above in the
‘opportunism’ section. At the onset, Du Pont’s management did not take the attack
and perhaps over-relying on the government’s and the court’s good will, management did
not believe in the possibility of a negative ruling, and as a result did not adopt strategies
and tactics aggressive enough to fight off the assault. Bounded rationality played a role
in the critical lack of attention to Waddell’s attack. However, BRel is at the heart of the
matter: Protests against concentration of economic power in the hands of large American
corporations were wide-spread at the time, and a negative public reaction was predicted
by Arthur Moxham, one of Pierre’s original mentors and a key member of Du Pont’s
executive team, at the time of the formation of the company. Limited knowledge and
inability to foresee the negative outcome are therefore not the only issues – rather,
overestimation of the company’s power led to the neglect of the critical information
which, at least partially, was at the company’s disposal. Most critically, the Du Pont
125
!
management neglected an urgent need to finalize the merging of all properties and
interests and to once and for all do away with “tricky” (p. 271) business practices of the
separate firms and indeed used unfair competitive practices and agreements to restrain
trade. Despite insistence on the part of some executives (Arthur Moxham, James
Townsend and Pierre Du Pont), the Executive Committee overestimated the company’s
political and market stance and was in no hurry to completely eliminate “embarrassing
vestigial remains” (p. 271) of the past trade deceit. This failure to complete the merger
made it difficult for management to demonstrate that the modern firm bore little
resemblance to the past trade association. Whether the outcome of the lawsuit would have
been different had the Du Ponts correctly estimated their position is unclear; however, at
least some of the devastating effects of the suit could perhaps have been avoided. The
antitrust decree resulted in broken promises to shareholders and partners, and at least part
type of mistakes in the future. Following the court’s dissolution decree, the company’s
President wrote to his chief counsel: “It is our desire to carry out not only the letter, but
the spirit of the Decree to the utmost and rather than have our people do anything that
could be considered in any way stretching the Decree in a way that would favour us, they
should be instructed to lean the other way and even give up trade or lose business rather
than put themselves in a position where their smallest act would be open to criticism” (p.
126
!
terms of maintaining a crystal-clear public image as far as antitrust dealings are
concerned.
The above analysis shows that benevolent preference reversal, and not just
benevolent conflict (Figure 4.1). In the following sections, we discuss these new
dimensions and their expressions, as identified in Chandler’s work. As with the initial
commitments are revised in favour of a conflicting set of goals, leading to the complete
simply swap) the moral circle whose interests matter in a particular issue (Jordan &
Audia, 2012); the issue then becomes reframed so as to serve a new set of interests.
associated with reframing of reality. “Pierre and his five associates conducted their
negotiations with Coleman and their final purchase of his stock with great speed and in
absolute secrecy” (p. 335) from his cousins Alfred and William Du Pont, as well as from
other members of the Executive Committee which would certainly not have permitted the
127
!
transaction had they had any knowledge of it. From Alfred and William’s viewpoint, the
move was “a breach of faith” (p. 336) which marked the beginning of a serious family
conflict that eventually split the family, and therefore, could be classified as an act of
angle. “If Pierre was to stay in,” – he writes, – “if he was to be responsible for the future
of the Powder Company, he wanted the necessary authority to carry out this
responsibility” (p. 337). Further, Pierre wanted to give key executives a substantial claim
on the profits, following his belief that “the success of a modern large corporation
consider themselves owners as well as managers” (p. 136) – a move that, in Pierre’s
view, would only be possible through his purchase of Coleman’s stock. We have,
therefore, a situation whereby conflicting goals prompted an action that can be considered
opportunistic in relation to some goals, but well intended in relation to other ones.
Chandler suggests the lack of a malevolent intent. Pierre felt that “he had to choose
between the needs of the enterprise and the continuance of family solidarity” (p. 358); in
order to remain committed to his vision of the company and to the task of carrying out
this vision, he had to knowingly and consciously breach his cousins’ trust and therefore
break his prior commitment to preserving harmony and peace among family clans. He
traded off his commitment to Alfred and William for a commitment that he deemed more
important – the commitment to “the future of the Powder Company” (p. 338) and to its
key executives. The reality was therefore reframed: The moral circle of the family was
traded for an expanded moral circle of those affected by the future of the corporation,
deemed more relevant and important. Here, we are once again dealing with sets of
128
!
commitments within a particular and identifiable range of transactions, rather than at the
Pont’s transformation from a family firm to a modern enterprise, and can be traced
through other instances where the goals of the enterprise (as seen by Pierre) clashed with
the goals of the family. In Chandler’s words, “the most critical period in the history of
any modern large impersonal corporation comes when the founder or his family have to
make terms with the requirements of large-scale enterprise” (p. 357). Pierre was acutely
aware of this conflict between kinship and business and worked to mitigate it – mostly,
by means of negotiations, arbitration, sensitivity “to other people’s feelings” (p. 283) and
“care and diplomacy in making changes” (p. 499). In some instances, this effort served
in reframing of reality; yet, for the company to “continue long as a force in its industry,
the needs of the enterprise must come before those of the family” (p. 357) -- hence the
hypothesize that benevolent preference reversal associated with reframing of reality may
The difference between reprioritization and reframing of reality is that the former
delays the original commitment, making it less cognitively and/or temporally proximate,
while the latter invalidates the original commitment, swapping it for an alternative set of
objectives which are mutually exclusive with the original. Scaling back on
with the recognition of the impossibility of its achievement. Table 4.1 illustrates a
129
!
temporal continuum of the relationship between various facets of the extended model of
oeuvre. After all, it addresses the making of the modern corporation, describing nothing
less than two examples of massive change: 1) the metamorphosis of the Du Pont
company – first from a family partnership to a national business enterprise, and then from
disjointed, loosely run company to one of the largest and the most successful enterprises
of its time. In the course of these transformations, tensions often arose and commitments
failed due to people’s resistance to change. In his critique of the design school of
new facets of BRel associated with resistance to change, we are particularly interested in
the first and last categories: narrow-mindedness, which can also be described as genuine
difficulties in unlearning (Tsang, 1997) the old methods because of a mere “force of old
habit” (p. 126), and right-mindedness, or a genuine belief that the old ways were better.
130
!
In those instances, initial commitments to a new course could perhaps be described as
that, in analyzing benevolent resistance to change, we essentially deal with replacing (or
failing to replace) one set of routines with another; again, the appropriate unit of analysis
“The extent that this is now done on the part of [Harry Haskell and Hamilton
Barksdale – Du Pont’s senior executives], it is not with intent but from force of old habit,
and it will be some time before the two of them get straightened out,” (p. 126) – wrote
were to keep their attention on broad overall policy and leave operational details to
Committee, accepted the new arrangement and professed to comply, but in reality could
not abandon their old ways, continuing to attend to minute matters in their departments
and failing to focus on more important duties. This was not opportunism, as no self-
interest was sought through these actions. They simply could not unlearn their old
behaviour. Their outdated knowledge and routines prevented them from obtaining new
knowledge (Hedberg, 1981; Nystrom and Starbuck, 1984), and discarding the outdated
routines proved challenging. This clearly is behaviour not associated with malevolent
intent, but representing more than just a case of bounded rationality: Vocal acceptance of
the new arrangements signals full understanding, while the absence of malevolent intent
131
!
is unambiguous. Yet, commitment to the new arrangements remained unfulfilled, due to
Coleman and Pierre attempted to explicitly separate long-range policy making from
routine administration (pp. 314-321). The objective was to train a new generation of
leaders by allowing young executives to rise into key operational jobs while limiting the
Executive Committee’s role to raising funds, planning future capital expenditures and
evaluating existing operations. Yet, the Executive Committee members found it hard to
remove themselves from their former roles, continuing to micromanage operations and
interfering with succession planning by preventing the new generation of executives from
acquiring skills necessary to run the business in the future. After three years of
unsuccessful struggle with the new structure, it became apparent that “the solution lay in
a change of men rather than of organization” (p. 319), as “the traditions that had been
established for years were so strong that simply drawing an organization chart could not
change the company’s administration” (p. 319). The company’s succession planning
It is not quite clear from Chandler’s description how the issues with the 1903
reorganization were resolved, but it was most likely through Pierre Du Pont’s sensitivity
to others’ feelings and diplomacy in implementing new practices. Chandler believes that
the reason of Pierre Du Pont’s success at both Du Pont and General Motors was his
understanding of the demands of the new and changing situation, combined with his
desire to retain old values. Pierre recognized the needs of a new enterprise and promoted
132
!
employment of professional managers, adoption of new technologies and utilization of
new management techniques, while keeping the loyalties, commitments and incentives
that existed in a small family partnership. This personal relationship building must have
been Pierre’s way of economizing on bounded reliability that was associated with change.
Yet, Pierre Du Pont’s above approach did not always work. The reorganization of
1911-1914 resulted in a massive family squabble, at the end of which Pierre and his
siblings obtained full control of the company, thus achieving the “change of men” (p.
319) that allowed Pierre to move forward with the change of structure. The lesson to be
learned here is that, hard as it is, replacing old blood with new may sometimes be the
General Motors, when Durant had to resign in order for the reorganization to take place
under Pierre Du Pont’s guidance (pp. 475-491). Finally, this change of men economizing
strategy is evident in Pierre Du Pont’s own reaction to the swift and deep economic and
political changes of the 1930s (p. 590). Unable to grasp the meaning of the change he
was facing, Pierre responded by removing himself from the business world. Having
embraced change for his entire life, and having seen others destroyed by change, he
perhaps recognized a point where unlearning would be difficult, and chose to withdraw.
Sometimes resistance to change occurs when there is a genuine belief that the old
ways are better and more beneficial for the company than the new, and when there is a
scepticism and distrust of the new order. This type of behavioural response is most
evident in Alfred Du Pont’s, one of the company’s executives prior to the 1914
reorganization, reaction to the proposal by Coleman and Pierre: “... [the company] during
its existence, thrived under the old plan of organization to a remarkable extent; and ... this
133
!
success has been due largely to past methods, and not in spite of them.” (p. 307). This
lack of acceptance of the new methods led to a bitter family fight, a lawsuit and Alfred’s
and relationship building, and, in Chandler’s words, “care and diplomacy in making
changes” (p. 499). An excellent example of such economizing mechanism can be seen in
Pierre’s efforts to recover and regenerate General Motors when he took over Durant as
the company’s President (pp. 509-510). Pierre worked diligently to win the confidence of
managers who had looked up to Durant with respect and affection, and to restore
employees’ faith in the company’s future. He visited plants, had face-to-face meetings
with managers and made a point of personally meeting local businessmen and civic
leaders in cities and towns where General Motors’ plants and offices were located. By
doing this, Pierre was able to reassure General Motors’ staff, executives, suppliers and
stakeholders that the company would remain solvent and become prosperous, and that the
new management was competent, concerned about employees’ well being and willing to
learn.
Pierre Du Pont: “In business maters he never favoured maintaining the status quo. His
achievements resulted from an accommodation, not a resistance, to change” (p. 604). For
Pierre, understanding and acceptance of change became an enabler for creating two of the
most successful corporations of his time and for meeting these corporations’ obligations
134
!
to their stakeholders. He also realized that resistance to change and inability to unlearn
whereby conflicting commitments occur at one point in time among various actors in the
organization, due largely to poor coordination; actors then start working against each
Benevolent conflict deals with classes of transactions within two or more functional units
– more specifically, routines and practices that, due to the lack of proper, coordination-
focused organizational routines, come in conflict with each other. Our analysis brought
different parties was due to these parties’ diverging interests. This was not opportunism,
as all parties were acting with the corporation’s best interest in mind; however, the
objectives of the various parties were not properly aligned with each other, nor with the
existed between Powder Company departments during the financial panic of the early
1900s. (pp. 222-225) A study of the company’s inventory demonstrated that Du Pont’s
favourable prices for essential materials during the time of the crisis, which resulted in a
large increase in working capital at the exact time when consumption was dropping,
Essential Materials Department was aiming to reduce inventory cost, while the
135
!
Purchasing Department’s goal was to reduce long-term cost of supplies. Conventional
TCE would explain this issue simply by pointing to alleged opportunistic behaviour of
the two managers, who were engaging in subgoal pursuit in order to advance their
that they were acting in the best financial interest of the firm. The problem was that
neither of the managers was aware of the firm’s overall financial position. Pierre Du
Pont, who at the time was the company’s treasurer and thus possessed the best knowledge
of the firm’s financial requirements, had to act as an arbitrator between the conflicting
achieve the advantages of large-scale, long-term buying and minimum inventories. This
review eventually led to a decision to integrate vertically. From the BRel perspective, the
point of this incident is that both departments failed to help the company achieve its
traditionally operated independently and with very little cooperation and coordination.
between “line and staff men” (p. 528) and, eventually, non-achievement of financial
goals. The problem was remedied by creation of interdivisional committees. The first
interdivisional committee, called a “General Technical Committee” (p. 547), was struck
to bridge the gap between engineering and product development as a response to the
copper-cooled engine fiasco. The General Technical Committee proved successful, and
the company followed by setting up similar General Sales, Works Managers and Power
136
!
their own staff and funds strengthened the corporation considerably by harmonizing the
interests and activities of different departments without impairing their autonomy. These
consequences for the firm. At the time, Pierre Du Pont was establishing new costing and
pricing policies, which stipulated that interdepartmental billing, should be based on costs
rather than market prices. Thus, if intra-company prices were higher than suggested by
the market, the buying units ended up penalized by having to purchase supplies at greater
expense. As the company integrated vertically, it began to control a larger portion of its
charging within the company at cost in order to adhere to proper accounting procedures;
departments could not be easily assessed under the cost system, as it was not immediately
apparent which selling units’ costs were too high to match current, external market prices.
transfers. Much later, during his tenure at General Motors, Pierre accepted the market
negotiations (this practice, termed internal markets (Reger, 1999; Ouchi, 1979), has been
137
!
IMPLICATIONS
negative consequences for the firm. These dimensions include behaviour caused by
This extension of BRel theory advances the thinking that good faith preference
why non-fulfillment of commitment is likely to occur, and how companies can safeguard
additional dimensions is quite important. For instance, there is a widespread belief that
organizational change is inevitable and continuous (Mirza, 2009), and academics and
practitioners alike have dedicated much effort to understanding how businesses can
embrace change. The specific facets of BRel associated with change offer new ways of
the organization often serve as important sources of competitive advantage for M-form
enterprises (Ingham, 1992). Formal and informal coordination mechanisms have been
regarded in the literature as fundamental structural elements, or the glue that keeps the
138
!
organization together (Mintzberg, 1991). It is, therefore, important to understand how
enterprises, for example, face a set of multiple realities associated with home versus host
for large family firms, whereby effective management requires embracing the needs of
the family as well as the needs of the enterprise, which may sometimes be at odds. Again,
our findings illuminate reframing of reality as a source of BRel, and suggest safeguarding
tactics.
Related to the above point, each new dimension of BRel is tied to distinct
strategies aim at meshing conflicting commitments before they occur, and include
diplomacy, negotiations and arbitration. For BRel associated with benevolent resistance
Motors, this was achieved through personal leadership, relationship building and
communication and, in extreme cases, through change of men, whereby those who were
unable to learn the new practices either withdrew or were forced to withdraw from the
139
!
(Reger, 1999). Du Pont and General Motors adopted such mechanisms in the form of
this case, took a form of arbitration and relationship building through personal contacts.
Table 4.2 summarizes economising mechanisms for the newly identified BRel
dimensions.
mechanisms is the use of communication and relationship building. While the three
building are present to some extent in all three types of organizational routines aimed at
reducing BRel. This further emphasizes the role of interpersonal dynamics in the
relational, or implicit, portion of contracting – but our research highlights that this
RESEARCH
Our analysis has confirmed that Chandler’s historical accounts can hardly be
140
!
describes multifaceted and complex actors, whose decisions are driven by a variety of
factors among which opportunism is often not of critical importance. Chandler’s oeuvre
is really a story of change; it is therefore not surprising that factors related to change are
shown to underlie many decisions, including those that led to failed commitments. It is
interesting to observe that those failed commitments originate not only within divisions,
as Williamson’s interpretation of the M-form structure suggests, but in all corners of the
members, government officials and company Presidents have taken turns reprioritizing,
immune to breaking promises. Yet, Chandler would not attribute to Pierre any sort of
sufficient behavioural assumption upon which to build a theory; the true behavioural
By introducing BRel as a new central concept in the study of the firm, our paper
augments the deficient assumption of opportunism and thus increases the legitimacy of
TCE as a general theory of the firm. Importantly, the adoption of BRel as a key
vision” (Ghoshal, 2005: 82) by refuting the claim that all commitment non-fulfillment has
a malevolent nature. Our paper establishes the foundation for theorizing on BRel and, in
should develop tools for economizing not only on potential opportunistic behaviour, but
141
!
The present study has focused on one – albeit rich and abundant – source of data,
in one particular organizational context. Consequently, the proposed new facets of BRel
were developed in the context of a single multidivisional corporation. Yet, the first two
imagine how resistance to change, for example, can plague relationships between
suppliers and buyers, arms-length business partners or firms and governments, and can
thus lead to broken promises and unfulfilled obligations. However, the third dimension –
benevolent conflict due to poor coordination of interests – is more suitable for explaining
different parts of the firm in order to achieve a common goal or deliver on common
commitments. This dimension could be also applicable to hybrid organizations that have
strong structural interdependencies and common incentives and thus operate much like
important dimensions of BRel could be uncovered. For now, this paper straddles the
142
!
Table 4.1. Commitment continuum for the extended model of bounded reliability
commitments over time. E.g., with ex ante opportunism, the commitment was never
viewed as important, whereas with ex post opportunism, the commitment lost importance
commitment becomes less proximate while maintaining its ultimate importance. With
longer achievable starting at t1 time period. With benevolent reframing of reality, the
original commitment loses its importance in favour of an alternative commitment that fits
the new reality. With the benevolent resistance to change, the commitment remains
143
!
important throughout, but impossible to achieve without overcoming the resistance. With
the benevolent conflict, the ultimate importance of commitment remains, but, at time t1,
depends on a view point of a particular economic actor: that is, the commitment may be
144
!
Figure 4.1. Extended model of bounded reliability
Bounded'Reliability'
Reprioritization! Overcommitment!
New'categories'of'BRel'
Essay 5
thinking to the family business builds on TCE’s concept of asset specificity. Our analysis
drivers of failed human commitments. We show that both the exposure and response to
bounded rationality and bounded reliability challenges may be different in family firms
versus Chandlerian hierarchies, and introduce the new concept of family-based human
asset specificity.
INTRODUCTION
Oliver Williamson earned the 2009 Nobel Prize in Economics, largely based on
his contributions to transaction cost economics (TCE) theory. TCE has emerged as a core
paradigm in the management and organizational studies literature (Hill, 1990). Quickly
becoming one of the leading perspectives in the field (David & Han, 2004), it has
received much attention from a broad range of audiences (Rindfleisch & Heide, 1997)
and has been subject to numerous empirical tests (Tsang, 2006). It is therefore
transaction cost theory of the family firm” (Gedajlovic & Carney, 2010) use TCE
and performance of family firms. As family business research expands and matures, an
increasing range of theories is being applied to the context of this particular governance
form (Wiklund, 2006). Agency theory has frequently been used to explain family firm
performance; stewardship and resource-based view theories have also been applied in
! 146
analyses of the family firm (see Chua, Chrisman & Sharma, 2003; Dyer, 2006; Westhead
& Howorth, 2006). Gedajlovic and Carney’s article represents a welcome addition to the
family firm.
Gedajlovic and Carney argue that the family firm as an economic institution has
been largely ignored by TCE. They portray the family firm as a discrete structural
Williamson’s asset specificity concept, and argue that family firms are characterized by a
distinct class of assets, which are firm specific but at the same time generic in application,
termed generic nontradeables (GNTs). The authors identify four key types of GNTs:
bonding of social capital, bridging of social capital, reputational assets, and tacit
knowledge. Although the authors do not insist that these GNTs are unique to family
firms, it is important to make it clear that they can also be found in nonfamily firms.
because professional managers can be fired and only have their reputation when applying
for a job elsewhere. Furthermore, in certain cases, family firms may possess
consequences. For example, close social ties may promote unreliability, as the case of the
fallen Wall Street money manager Bernard Madoff, and his family business, Madoff
! 147
Investment Securities LLC, clearly illustrates.
The analysis of GNTs is also actually common in the more general, non-
argues that firms exist because they command a set of idiosyncratic resource bundles,
called firm-specific advantages (FSAs), which can be more efficiently exploited and
rejuvenated inside the firm than through the use of alternative governance forms.
Internalization theory suggests that some FSAs can be deployed and augmented across a
variety of related markets, whether product markets or geographic markets, i.e., they are
generic (within limits) in application. This holds especially for the company’s higher-
order FSAs, such as routines and recombination capabilities (Verbeke, 2009). In other
words, any firm, whether a venture capital firm, a family firm, or a Chandlerian
hierarchy, commands a mix of FSAs, some of which can be deployed solely in extant
activity domains or for specific transactions and other ones that have a much wider
applicability (e.g., General Electric’s capacity to absorb new acquisitions very rapidly in
its existing operations). In addition, each firm coordinates a mix of tradable and
reputational assets, etc.) representing the essence of the company. Here, what counts is
not so much governing single transactions or narrow transaction classes in their entirety
in a Williamsonian sense, but rather governing innovation processes (and related FSAs)
in their entirety, i.e., from sustained idea generation to the continued profitable selling of
Family firms are therefore not the governance form of choice in external
! 148
efficiency than transaction-specific or product-domain-specific assets. Nor do family
firms’ relative strengths and weaknesses vis-à-vis other governance forms derive largely
from the extent to which the former can economize (and generate value) by combining
GNTs with other asset classes (with other governance forms assumed comparatively
weak in this area). However, family firms may well represent the most efficient
governance alternative to exploit particular types of GNTs, but this requires credible,
Is the family firm indeed a discrete structural alternative? While different from a
monitored by arm’s length shareholders (Walsh & Seward, 1990), the family firm is still
supported by a distinct form of private ordering, different from that supporting markets
and hybrids (Williamson, 1996), and exhibits all characteristics of any other type of firm,
considered the particularities of family businesses and the phenomena Gedajlovic and
Carney describe as GNTs. Williamson (1996: 78–79) explicitly acknowledges the family
firm, with its comparative strengths and weaknesses, in terms of economizing properties,
and discusses how firms use private ordering systems of networks, profession-related
punishment routines, and contract enforcement through societal culture, reputation bonds,
These economizing mechanisms represent little else than the bonding of social capital,
! 149
bridging of social capital, reputational assets, and tacit knowledge, and are utilized by
family firms and managerial hierarchies alike (e.g., all firms rely on informal
legal enforceability (Zhou & Poppo, 2010). These mechanisms are not dedicated to
Williamson views them as economizing mechanisms rather than ‘assets’ (GNTs). Here,
some types of firms may be better equipped than other ones to access and efficiently
Assuming, fully in accordance with mainstream TCE logic, that Gedajlovic and
Carney’s GNTs as economizing mechanisms are useable not only by family firms but by
all firms, the important question becomes whether family firms are better or more poorly
equipped to use some of these mechanisms for economizing and value-creating purposes.
To answer this question, we briefly review and extend TCE’s core behavioural
assumptions.
RELIABILITY
Bounded rationality refers to economic actors’ behaviour that is “intendedly rational, but
only limitedly so” (Simon, 1961: xxiv). In other words, human actors have a limited
capacity to process information, address complexity, and make optimal choices. In the
view, human agents who populate firms and markets also have an inherent proclivity
! 150
disguise, obfuscate or otherwise confuse” (Williamson, 1985: 47). Opportunism has been
leading management theories are arguably built on assumptions that do not represent
reality in a complete and accurate way (Tsang, 2006). In particular, the concept of
opportunism has been the subject of significant controversy (Conner & Prahalad, 1996;
Ghoshal, 2005; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Hodgson, 2004). It has invited much criticism,
both for its narrow conceptual focus and for the lack of sufficient empirical support
(Tsang, 2006). It has been argued that concerns surrounding the behavioural assumption
of opportunism reduce the legitimacy of TCE as a general theory of the firm (Verbeke &
Greidanus, 2009). Yet alternative explanations of failed human commitments are scarce.
Until recently, scholars have largely addressed the deficient nature of the opportunism
assumption by ignoring or rejecting it (see Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Ghoshal & Moran,
1996). However, Verbeke and Greidanus (2009) have proposed the new envelope concept
extends the assumption of opportunism by including the many situations where parties
seeking with guile. Bounded reliability reflects the often-observed reality of failed
commitments caused by a variety of factors including but not limited to intentional deceit.
In other words, bounded reliability includes two broad classes of failed commitment:
! 151
can be associated with good faith reprioritization or with scaling back on
overcommitment; the preliminary model proposed by Verbeke & Greidanus thus contains
overcommitment.
good faith but become reordered because their importance diminishes over time, or
because more proximate (spatially or temporally) events take higher priority. Scaling
planned (but benevolently intended) ex ante commitments that then need to be scaled
back ex post. As part of their conceptual development, Verbeke and Greidanus identify a
number of safeguarding mechanisms for the three facets of bounded reliability, e.g.,
realistic and clear goal setting, regular reviews of targets and budgets, development of
informal connections among actors, joint strategic planning, and imposition of limits on
FIRM
concepts. If we start from observing a particular family firm, the question could be asked
as to the likelihood that family firm governance will be sustained, rather than shift toward
! 152
few key parameters likely to affect (in a testable fashion) the occurrence of such a shift,
growing family firms that use complex technologies are more likely to suffer from
a liability in recruitment and utilization of skilled and professional talent, as well as in the
promote employees on the basis of particularistic criteria rather than their skills and
available to the firm, thus exacerbating the managerial team’s inherent scarcity of mind
challenges imposed by the external environment. This is a liability especially in firms that
holds for large, diversified firms that are organizationally complex and need sophisticated
routines to determine the firm’s boundaries, its allocation of resources for purposes of
innovation, and more generally, its internal organization (Dyer, 2006; Verbeke &
Kenworthy, 2008). Here, the bounded rationality issue faced by the family firm is
twofold: The family firm suffers from a restricted quantity of mind, and the quality of
mind available to the firm may also be inferior. The prediction is therefore a governance
! 153
Second, the impact of investments in management professionalization. Assuming
again a complex technology and a high-growth environment, the question arises whether
managers (Chua et al., 2003; Gedajlovic, Lubatkin, & Schulze, 2004) can be effective in
addressing the above bounded rationality challenge and sustaining family firm
governance. Here, it is important to recognize that this course of action can itself create
with evaluation and compensation systems, whereby asymmetric treatment of family and
nonfamily managers creates severe bounded rationality and bounded reliability problems
and may ultimately lead to inferior economic performance (Chua, Chrisman, & Bergiel,
2009). Gedajlovic and Carney (2010) correctly point out that insider-oriented hiring and
promotion policies can alienate nonfamily workers and lead to perfunctory contributions,
policies commonly practiced by family firms, such as withholding stock options from
nonfamily managers to avoid dilution of family control and uncertainty of incentive pay
(Park, 2002), can have the same effect. Empirical evidence suggests that nonfamily
managers in family firms are often dissatisfied with the relative lack of equity in
compensation and potential for upward mobility (Poza, Alfred, & Maheshawi, 1997),
which can again trigger bounded reliability problems, in terms of reduced commitment.
asymmetric altruism (Chrisman, Chua, Kellermanns & Chang 2007; Chrisman, Chua &
Litz, 2004; Chua et al., 2009; Corbetta & Salvato, 2004; Lubatkin, Schulze, Ling & Dino,
! 154
2005)—a phenomenon whereby firm owners tend to be altruistic (generous) toward
family employees in the firm even when the latter “free ride and lack the competence
and/or intention to sustain the wealth creation potential of the firm” (Chrisman et al.,
2004: 338). Asymmetric altruism makes it difficult to enforce the explicit and implicit
contracts between family owners and family members working in the firm and promotes
reluctance to monitor, evaluate, and discipline each other can be a source of significant
and evaluation of employees can lead to shirking (an expression of opportunism), as was
pointed out by Weber (1946), and more generally to imperfect efforts to make good on
will only serve economizing purposes and prevent a shift away from family firm
dysfunctional particularism.
Third, the impact of complementary asset requirements. Let us assume again the
environmental context of complex technology and high growth. But let us add the
complexity that the family firm can only keep up with competitors if it secures access to
the complementary FSAs of outside partners. The problem of particularism is that family
objectives may gain priority over business objectives (Westhead & Howorth, 2006),
creating what Chandler and Salsbury (1971) described as a conflict between kinship and
business, between the family ways and the requirements of the environment, and between
! 155
personal and impersonal values. An additional complexity is that conflicting goals,
themselves from their parents, marital discord, and identity conflict (Kellermanns &
especially when debating the role that complex contractual agreements with third parties
could play in sustaining the business. Strong familial bonds can be a source of
2006). This distrust can interfere with utilizing any GNTs in bonding and bridging of
social capital and is likely to lead to a vicious cycle of increased bounded reliability
amoral familism is likely to make a family business less sustainable and to facilitate a
Given the above potential sources of bounded rationality and bounded reliability
unique to family firms, it is important to recognize that not all family firms are created
equal. Family firms differ vastly in their characteristics, and these differences have given
rise to multiple family firm typologies developed by family business researchers (see
Dyer, 1986, 2006; Gersick, Davis, Hampton, & Landsberg, 1997; Landsberg, 1999).
Family firms’ unique characteristics—such as the nature of family assets and liabilities in
! 156
determine the firms’ performance (Dyer, 2006) and, naturally, affect bounded rationality
and bounded reliability issues faced by these firms. When analyzing family firms’ unique
bounded rationality and bounded reliability challenges, it is therefore important not only
to compare family firms with Chandlerian hierarchies in generic terms, but also to look at
how a particular family firm type may affect both the exposure and potential responses to
reliability in generic terms are likely to differ from those in nonfamily firms. The typical
‘contract’ between the family firm as a governance structure and the family members
contracts with outsiders because of the presence of family-based human asset specificity:
1. Involvement in the business arises out of the family context, rather than out of
experiences; in other words, the ‘contracting’ typically begins long before the
moment that the family member actually takes on a job in the firm or signs a formal
employment contract.
2. The early involvement of family members in the business, possibly long before a
bounded reliability, e.g., as a result of shared knowledge, used inter alia to prevent
over long periods of time, on each other’s range of capabilities that can reduce
! 157
individual evaluation bias and thereby overcommitment.
position in the firm are higher for nonfamily members. Higher entry barriers result
from a particular form of time compression diseconomies, meaning there are limits
to the extent that socialization can be accelerated. In contrast, exit barriers are
higher for family members as compared with those facing nonfamily members,
because exit typically has further-reaching implications for the exiting manager’s
4. Family firms are less able to hire and fire managers to adjust to new external
circumstances; in other words, they cannot adjust their human resources base as
5. Family firms can rely to a higher extent on the loyalty of family member managers
and vice versa, than is the case with nonfamily firms and nonfamily managers.
Dysfunctionality arises when such loyalty leads to an absence of across the board,
asymmetric altruism), and the presence of amoral familism. This holds especially in
The paradox of family firms is thus that they have unique access to a stable and
loyal human resource base, leading to family-based human asset specificity and
Williamsonian bilateral dependency in this context, but at the same time, both the
quantity and quality of this resource base may be suboptimal. A prediction is therefore,
! 158
ceteris paribus, that families that are larger (leading to more options in quantitative terms
as to which family members can perform specific activities for the family business) and
higher quality resources, which become the subject of family-based, human asset
specificity), are likely to be the most successful in the long run. Such families are the least
likely to experience the disappearance of their family firm, especially if the professional
both bounded rationality and bounded reliability. Training reduces bounded rationality
challenges by developing the skills and competencies of family members (Westhead &
Howorth, 2006), but it can also signal the founders’ commitment to employees and
outsiders that any family members active in the firm will be held to the same professional
standards as nonfamily members, thus strengthening loyalty from the latter, and
bounded reliability. Here, functionally incompetent family members will not operate in
the firm, nor will they be rewarded because of kinship, thereby eliminating the
important. Chandler and Salsbury (1971) describe how the DuPont Corporation became
the first American company to allow outsiders to purchase stock in the family business,
out of a belief that the success of a modern corporation depended on making key
! 159
employees partners in the business. Ownership-based compensation practices can help
curb bounded reliability challenges by aligning employees’ interests with those of the
founders, even when the founding family remains largely in control of the business.
the family firm in cases where survival and growth depend on access to complementary
CONCLUSION
transaction cost theory of the family firm” applies TCE to the important, ubiquitous, and
arguably under-researched governance form of family firms. The authors focused their
analysis on Williamson’s asset-specificity concept, which was the starting point for
assessing family firms’ strengths and weaknesses vis-à-vis other governance forms. Our
view, however, is that reflecting on TCE’s behavioural assumptions in the context of the
rationality and the new envelope concept of bounded reliability could apply to the family
firm, and how family firms can best economize on bounded rationality and bounded
reliability. It appears that some bounded rationality and bounded reliability challenges,
especially those related to family-based human asset specificity, are indeed unique to
family businesses. However, many bounded rationality and bounded reliability issues
more so than by their family versus nonfamily status. A useful direction for future
research would be to take an in-depth look at what type of family firm may be better
! 160
equipped than other types of family firms to economize on bounded rationality and
business firms.
! 161
Essay 6
BIFURCATION BIAS
We develop a transaction cost economics theory of the family firm, building upon the
We argue that the prosperity and survival of family firms depend on the absence of a
assets (especially human assets). We propose that absence of bifurcation bias is critical
to fostering reliability in family business functioning. Our study ends the unproductive
divide between the agency and stewardship perspectives of the family firm, which offer
conflicting accounts of this firm type’s functioning. We show that the predictions of the
agency and stewardship perspectives can be usefully reconciled when focusing on how
INTRODUCTION
Family firms are of critical importance to their local and national economies
represent a dominant type of listed corporations around the world (Shim & Okamuro,
2011) and 35% of the Fortune 500 companies (Perman, 2006). Family firms are major
(Westhead & Cowling, 1998). The long-term trajectory of the individual family firm,
! 162
however, is not always a ‘happily ever after’ storyline. Extant research suggests that only
one third of family firms survive the second generation (Ward, 2004), and for the
remaining two thirds, the life span is reduced with each successive generation (Jivraj &
Woods, 2002), with the average life expectancy of U.S. family firms estimated to be 24
years (Lee, Lim & Lim, 2003)—a number roughly equivalent to the average tenure of the
founder (Beckhard & Dyer, 1983). Some of these firms cease to exist as family firms,
Yet, other family-owned businesses survive and prosper for centuries, passing
ownership from generation to generation, living through world wars and natural disasters,
and staying in business during periods of extreme financial turmoil. The Henokiens, an
association of centuries old family firms formed in 1981, represents financially sound
family businesses that are at least 200 years old (Bennedsen, Van der Heyden & MBA
and LVMH, to name but a few—have expanded across borders (Banalieva & Eddleston,
2011) and have made their way into the ranks of the most admired, internationally
firms from failing ones? What factors affect their continuity and success as family
businesses? In this paper, we answer these questions by applying the conceptual lens of
Despite the significance of the family firm in the world economy, family firm
research has not yet achieved full maturity, nor has it been fully integrated into
Family firms have been analyzed from a range of theoretical perspectives (Wiklund,
! 163
2006). Agency and stewardship theories, as well as the resource-based view (RBV) of the
firm, have been utilized most frequently in conceptual and empirical studies on family
firms (see Chua et al., 2003; Dyer, 2006; Gedajlovic et al., 2012; Westhead & Howorth,
2006). There have been a few worthwhile attempts to advance a TCE-based theory of the
family firm (see Gedajlovic & Carney, 2010; Lee et al., 2003; Memili, Chrisman & Chua,
2011a; Memili, Chrisman, Chua, Chang & Kellermanns, 2011b; Pollak, 1985), but no
unified TCE-based theory of the family firm has been developed yet. We expand on past
scholarly efforts with a view to develop a general TCE theory of the family firm.
TCE has unique potential to explain the existence and survival of family-type
characteristics of a family firm’s employee base, as well as other foundational assets held
by the firm. It could be argued that the RBV in strategy is even more powerful than TCE
the RBV misses is ex-ante guidance (rather than ex-post rationalization) on how best to
‘govern’ particular resources and resource bundles, including the specific types of human
assets employed by the family firm. In other words, the RBV may be able to provide an
organizational deployment, but lacks the analytical apparatus to assess the types of
‘contracts’ to be used for governing particular types of resources, whereas the asset
Second, TCE incorporates explicit behavioural assumptions, which allow for the
! 164
study of intentionality, but with the possibility of biases, predictably occurring in specific
rationality of economic actors than TCE, which builds upon the bounded rationality
in various governance contexts, including family firms. The presence of explicit and
realistic behavioural assumptions is also an advantage of applying TCE to the family firm
domain as compared to the RBV. The RBV has little predictive or prescriptive capacity,
maximizing assumption and the quest for superior profits attributed to the firm itself. In
fact, given the content of a firm’s resources reservoir, which can be described in detail
through a RBV lens, TCE provides guidance on how to govern efficiently that reservoir
and how to protect and augment it further through bounded rationality and bounded
reliability economizing.
Third, TCE was specifically designed to explain firm boundaries as well as the
interface with actors outside of these boundaries. TCE is therefore particularly well
equipped to theorize about the relationship between family firm owners and the firm’s
full range of stakeholders (employees, external service suppliers, etc.) with whom
! 165
other words, TCE with its focus on the governance of transactions is by its very nature
the firm and one of its stakeholders can be assessed in terms of ‘economizing’ properties
Fourth, agency and stewardship theories build upon diverging assumptions and
yield conflicting predictions (Banalieva & Eddleston, 2011), making the family business
scholarly literature somewhat dispersed and divided (Le Breton-Miller & Miller, 2009),
while TCE can contribute to resolving existing tensions between these competing
defining the family firm as one where a family controls enough votes to influence
significantly corporate conduct. In doing so, we do not discount the importance of family
involvement in operational matters, nor in higher-level governance, but rather argue that
family control will strongly affect both daily management and strategic decision-making
goals and vision but suggest that these express how the controlling family intends to
exercise control, for example, in terms of substantive decisions on the choice of products
and markets, and as regards organizational design. In other words, we treat these aspects
as design variables that family firms can influence endogenously, rather than as criteria to
! 166
BEHAVIOURAL ASSUMPTIONS OF TCE
(David & Han, 2004; Hill, 1990), regards the transaction as the basic unit of analysis and
cost economizing,’ ways (Riordan & Williamson, 1985). Oliver Williamson, the leading
figure of TCE, built his version of the theory upon three core assumptions: asset
means that particular assets, involved in a transaction (or class of transactions), cannot be
easily redeployed elsewhere without significant loss of economic value. Asset specificity
encompasses physical, organizational, and human assets, and is considered the most
transaction costs. Greater asset specificity increases transaction costs associated with
partners, and therefore to more complex, longer term contracting schemes, including
economic actors’ behaviour that is “intendedly rational, but only limitedly so” (Simon,
1961: xxiv), meaning that human actors have a limited capacity to process information,
address complexity, and make optimal choices. In the presence of bounded rationality, all
contracts are necessarily incomplete, which creates problems especially when asset
! 167
guile” (Williamson, 1981b: 1545). It manifests itself in “calculated efforts to mislead,
Williamson’s version of TCE, human agents who populate firms and markets have an
driver of both market failure and the rise of hierarchy (Williamson, 1993). It is important
cannot simply walk away from a transaction without incurring high costs from trying to
salvage and redeploy the assets committed. The latter behavioural assumption has been
the subject of significant controversy in the organizational sciences field (Conner &
Prahalad, 1991; Ghoshal, 2005; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Hodgson, 2004) and a reason
for much criticism directed at TCE. The opportunism assumption has been criticized for
its narrow conceptual focus and an inadequate portrayal of reality, as well as for the lack
of sufficient empirical support (Tsang, 2006). In the absence of convincing evidence that
predictions on the evolution of governance may actually be correct, but driven at least in
To address this issue, Verbeke and Greidanus (2009) have proposed the new
the many situations in which parties’ failure to deliver on commitments is not explained
! 168
of failed commitments caused by a variety of factors including but not limited to
Good faith reprioritization captures instances whereby economic actors make ex-
ante commitments in good faith, but the importance of those commitments diminishes
over time. Preferences may become reordered due to more spatially proximate
commitments taking precedence (e.g. local projects trump global projects at an MNE
subsidiary), or due to time discounting bias, i.e. placing a lower value on future events
than on more proximate events. Scaling back on overcommitment results from the
scaled back ex post. In both cases, initial commitments can no longer be fulfilled.
planning by participating parties, frequent budgetary reviews, and imposing limits on the
size and scope of new activities, obviously taking into account that such management
practices have costs as well as benefits. The main insight is that individuals engaged in
economic transactions may fail to make good on open-ended commitments for a variety
bounded rationality problem, because the information on the likely occurrence and the
effects of unreliability is fully known in advance. Correcting for such failures can then be
behaviour.’
! 169
TCE AND THE FAMILY FIRM
to the family firm that then triggers unusual contracting as compared to typical
employment contracts between the family firm and ‘outsiders,’ or between a nonfamily
firm and its employees. Unusual contracting appears for a number of reasons. Family
members typically become involved in the business early on in life, or even at birth—
before any formal contracting takes place. This early involvement, which often has
hereditary rather than professional roots, continues through adolescence (e.g., in the form
of summer jobs) and extends through actual employment with the firm in different
capacities (Le Breton-Miller, Miller & Steier, 2004; Memili et al., 2011a). Socialization
thus becomes a primary coordination mechanism in the family firm, which invests
heavily in family members for very long periods of time, so as to prepare them for future
leadership roles. As a result, nonfamily managers, who have not been socialized into the
company since birth and therefore do not possess the highly idiosyncratic knowledge
specific to family insiders (Lee et al., 2003), face higher entry barriers when it comes to
assuming key roles within the company. The pursuit of family-centered, noneconomic
goals (Chrisman et al., 2007; Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007), such as family harmony, family
status, family dynasty, socio-emotional value, ability to exercise family influence, etc.,
further raises entry barriers for nonfamily managers, as achieving these goals requires
very specific skills and behaviour that can be expected from family members, but would
be difficult to obtain from a nonfamily employee (Memili et al., 2011a). Exit barriers, on
the other hand, are significantly higher for family managers, because economic
relationships in the family firm are entwined with significant personal ones. Exit may
! 170
mean disruption of family dynamics, and in certain cases sanctions ranging from conflict
least in part related to the family’s noneconomic goals (though it may serve economizing
purposes, too), applies not just to human assets, but also to other types of assets
controlled by the family firm. Such assets may include the initial head office estate where
the company started, product lines introduced by the founders, original locations of
manufacturing operations, etc. Family firms’ ‘connections’ to such assets typically arise
from their noneconomic goals (Memili et al., 2011a), such as the desire to keep alive and
even reinforce family history/legacy and the values of the founders. Here, family-based
unwillingness to shed unprofitable product lines and business activities that have
historically defined the firm (Sharma & Manikutty, 2005), or in the attachment to a
particular location, a building, or any other asset that is no longer strategically relevant.
While beyond the scope of this paper’s analysis, family-based ‘other’ (i.e., nonhuman)
What results is, on the one hand, a uniquely stable and loyal human resource base
with limited danger of adverse selection (absent cognitive biases), because each family
member’s strengths and weaknesses are known to the fullest (Pollak, 1985). On the other
hand, both the quantity and quality of this resource base may be suboptimal. Family-
based bilateral dependency creates both high exit barriers to eliminate unproductive
human assets, and high entry barriers to acquire potentially much more productive
‘professional’ assets. In other words, the main problem here is not so much the absence of
! 171
external opportunities to redeploy without economic loss highly valuable assets uniquely
linked to the family firm, but rather the letting go or reallocation of individuals who
contribute little to economic value, but whose high human asset specificity may be
of family firms (Carney, 2005) further reduce the family firm’s capacity to adjust its
have three options that can be used individually or in combination to address the above
challenges:
1. Focus on growing the family, as a larger family will lead to more options in
quantitative terms as to which family members can perform specific activities for
the family business. This course of action (also seen in the context of ‘royal
monarch Henry VIII, who was consumed with the goal of fathering a male
successor), however, can hardly qualify as a business strategy. Growing the family
is usually outside of the family firm’s control, even though suitability criteria,
applied when selecting a partner for marriage with the family firm’s (future) owner,
members’ skills and competencies (Westhead & Howorth, 2006), and further
! 172
safeguards against bounded reliability by strengthening the loyalty of family and
education signals the owners’ commitment to employees and outsiders that any
family members active in the firm will be held to the same professional standards
quality and quantity of firm resources. Here, employment contracts with ‘external’
BIFURCATION BIAS
We focus our analysis on the third course of action above, as it leads to unique,
internal bounded reliability problems. Professionalization may create two distinct classes
of employees (family vs. nonfamily) within the firm that may result in potential
family firms as standard practice apply asymmetric treatment, whereby family employees
are treated by default as highly valuable, firm-specific assets, being ‘on the inside for the
long run,’ and as loyal stewards with a long-term commitment to the firm, while
! 173
used/internalized temporarily by the firm. When uncorrected in the long run, such
treatment of the family firm, as both agency and stewardship thinking feed directly into
the bifurcation bias concept. Agency and stewardship theorists form two distinct camps
that provide competing perspectives on the family business (Banalieva & Eddleston,
2011). Both theories focus on goal alignment (or the lack thereof) between the firm’s
owners and its managers (Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003), but fundamentally diverge on
whether family and nonfamily managers in family firms behave as agents or stewards
economics. It assumes that owners (principals) and managers (agents) have conflicting
goals, whereby managers may pursue their own goals to the detriment of the owners.
Owners can minimize agency costs by imposing internal controls to restrain managers’
self-serving behaviour, and by aligning the interests of managers with those of owners
through incentives, though always facing some level of dead loss (Fama & Jensen, 1983;
Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Early agency theory work (e.g., Fama & Jensen, 1983; Jensen
& Meckling, 1976) assumed that family firms are immune to agency issues: Conflicts
between owners and managers are minimized due to ownership and control overlapping,
and the entwining of economic and personal relationships offers monitoring advantages
(Pollak, 1985). However, more recent applications of agency theory thinking to family
! 174
business suggest that family involvement creates unique agency challenges, such as
(Chrisman et al., 2004, 2007; Chua et al., 2009; Lubatkin et al., 2005; Schulze, Lubatkin,
Unlike agency theory, stewardship theory has its roots in theology (Thompson,
1960) and relies extensively on concepts from psychology and sociology, such as self-
suggests that organizational leaders are motivated to act in the organization’s best
interest, serve its mission, and behave as loyal stewards of their firm and its owners
(Davis, Schoorman & Donaldson, 1997). Family business scholars have adopted
stewardship thinking (Pearson & Marler, 2010) as a way to explore family firms’
proclivity toward stewardship behaviour (see Corbetta & Salvato, 2004; Davis, Allen &
Hayes, 2010; Eddleston & Kellermanns, 2007; Miller, Le Breton-Miller & Scholnick,
2008; Zahra, Hayton, Neubaum, Dibrell & Craig, 2008). It has been argued that kinship,
a single family name, and a common history promote a shared identity in family firms
and contribute to building enduring social capital that can be relied upon through
generations (Arregle, Hitt, Sirmon & Very, 2007; Banalieva & Eddleston, 2011; Sirmon
assumptions about the motivation and behaviour of economic actors, yet they coexist in
the field of family business research, and each has a strong following. Family business
! 175
theorists have attempted to reconcile this duality, providing some empirical support for
either theory (see Chrisman et al., 2007; Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007; Schulze, Lubatkin &
Dino, 2003; Schulze et al., 2001, for empirical studies supporting agency theory;
Eddleston & Kellermanns, 2007; Eddleston, Kellermanns & Sarathy, 2008, for empirical
studies in support of stewardship theory). The evidence to date suggests that each theory
may hold under specific contingencies/in specific circumstances, e.g., depending on the
extent of economic actors’ embeddedness in the family (Le Breton-Miller & Miller,
2009), the extent of separation of ownership and management (Corbetta & Salvato,
2004), the geographic focus of internationalization (Banalieva & Eddleston, 2011), the
family’s perception of the management team’s reliability and the context of the agency
contract (Cruz, Gomez-Mejia & Becerra, 2010), the firm’s position in its life cycle, etc.
proposing that both theories can be correct at the same time, and within a single firm.
Given the range of possible motivations and effort levels of various employees/managers,
both agency and stewardship-type behaviour can indeed be expected to occur inside the
family firm. The insight drawn from studying the bifurcation bias in family firms is that
stewardship thinking is applied by default to all family employees who are treated as
loyal stewards with a long-term commitment to the firm, while agency thinking is applied
Let us assume that the family firm hires professional, nonfamily managers (and
highly specialized employees). Bifurcation bias then refers to the default asymmetric
treatment of family and nonfamily managers. Family members are automatically assumed
to be more desirable than a mere agent (Lee et al., 2003) and expected to remain ‘on the
! 176
inside for the long run.’ They are ascribed stewardship traits such as loyalty, maximum
commitment and effort, as well a potentially high, long-term contribution to value in the
firm, regardless of their actual levels of skill, commitment, and effort. In contrast,
and potentially disloyal (self-serving) resources, who will not be committed to the firm
and will exert minimum effort, again regardless of their actual levels of skill,
epitomized in the words of Giovanni Agnelli, Jr. of the Fiat Group, who famously
declared that managers came and went but the Agnellis stayed (Toninato & Tapies,
2005).
It should be noted that in practice, the presence or absence of bifurcation bias may
not be absolute, but rather a matter of degree. However, the prevalence of noneconomic
goals, e.g., the preservation of family values, harmony, and social capital, maintaining
family control of the business, engagement of future generations in the business, etc.,
may make some level of biased treatment inevitable. Therefore, most family firms likely
find themselves at some point on a continuum from biased to bias-free. As one example,
at Magid Glove, a world leader in industrial safety equipment, family employees are
permitted flex time while nonfamily employees are not, yet family members are
evaluated according to a higher set of expectations, and are required to gain outside
experience prior to joining the business (Ward & Pericelli, 2005). For the purposes of our
applied systematically and by default. An example is the documented and systematic pay
! 177
discrepancies between family and nonfamily employees at the advisory investment bank
Lazard LLC, see Subramanian and Sherman (2007). A firm is seen as unbiased if it exerts
a visible and consistent effort toward unbiased practices throughout the organization.
programs implemented at the Finnish forest industry company Ahlstrom (Magretta, 1998)
recruitment criteria adopted at the chemical and pharmaceutical firm Merck KGaA
(Neumann & Tapies, 2006a, 2006b) and the company-wide profit sharing practiced at the
science-based products and services firm Du Pont (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971).
in the applied psychology literature (Gilovich, Griffin & Kahneman, 2002; Slovic,
Finucane, Peters & MacGregor, 2002, 2007). The affect heuristic represents a rule of
thumb, whereby decision makers experience ‘good feelings,’ i.e., a positive affect, when
considering one choice alternative, thereby attributing higher expected overall benefits to
it than warranted by the objective attributes of this choice alternative. In contrast, when
decision makers experience ‘bad feelings’ toward another alternative, this leads to lower
expected overall benefits than warranted by the objective attributes of that alternative. In
other words, when the affect heuristic is in play, the ‘affect-rich attributes’ of choice
alternatives dominate selection. In the case of family firms, the attribute of being a
‘family- insider’ in the context of hiring and promotion decisions triggers an automatic
type’ expectation. When the affect heuristic becomes embedded in managerial practices,
! 178
bifurcation bias results.
Theoretical relationship. The affect heuristic and the resulting bifurcation bias
nonfamily-based ones. The bifurcation bias thus means that the family firm’s modus
operandi is to keep for too long and at an excessive cost a set of unproductive family-
elsewhere, while at the same time systematically short changing highly valuable
of anchoring them inside the company. Rather than crafting contracts properly aligned
with the competences, expected professional services, and uniqueness desired from its
managers and employees, bifurcation bias leads to a division of a firm’s human assets
into two groups based on family status, and the ‘affect-rich’ attributes associated with this
status.
This modus operandi serves as a unique trigger of bounded reliability, in the sense
that the resulting portfolio of human assets in place may not serve efficiency purposes but
economic wealth creation. Importantly, the bifurcation bias may even be detrimental to
biased governance increases bounded reliability in the system, in the sense that less
! 179
competent, less skilled, and less performing managers will now be responsible for
achieving both sets of goals. An interesting situation may arise when noneconomic goals
are in conflict with economic goals. Here, the bifurcation bias will typically favor the
noneconomic goals of family members who govern the firm over economic goals. In
other words, decision makers are less likely to fulfill their most important fiduciary duty,
growth—of the firm. However, if family managers are less qualified than nonfamily ones,
with the latter driven out of the firm or becoming more unreliable owing to the family’s
as well.
performance: Main proposition. We argue that family firms subject to bifurcation bias
are susceptible to a bounded reliability squeeze from both ends, that is, from unreliable
family members wrongly qualified as ‘stewards,’ as well as from potentially reliable and
free to exhibit all possible facets of bounded reliability. Lax monitoring structures leave
family managers open to benevolent preference reversal (in terms of not making good on
their commitments to the firm), while the promise of a default lifetime tenure may
stimulate intentional opportunism in the form of shirking and free riding. On the other
influencing the controlling family’s decisions, may themselves become responsible for
! 180
new bounded reliability problems, namely when withdrawing or reducing their efforts
and commitment to the firm. Reduced effort and commitment can have very real
economic consequences for the family firm, as empirical evidence suggests that
profitability, survival, and continuity of family firms (Vallejo, 2009). Additional bounded
staffs a biased firm with archaic, improperly skilled, unproductive assets with limited
economic value.
We therefore propose that the bifurcation bias affects the firm’s ability to
economize on bounded rationality and bounded reliability and, consequently, reduces its
overall performance and weakens its ability to compete. Our main proposition is that
firms free of bifurcation bias will be more able to grow and prosper while sustaining
their family governance structure over the long haul. Conversely, those family firms that
suffer from bifurcation bias will face severe performance issues potentially leading either
to their demise, or to the shift of their family governance toward another governance
It should be noted again that bifurcation bias can affect not only human resources
management, but also decision making on many other types of assets such as businesses
bifurcation bias are well documented in the family firm literature. Asymmetric altruism
(Chua et al., 2009; Chrisman et al., 2004, 2007; Corbetta & Salvato, 2004; Lubatkin et
! 181
al., 2005) describes firm owners’ tendency to be altruistic (generous) toward family
employees in the firm, even when the latter “free ride and lack the competence and/or
intention to sustain the wealth creation potential of the firm” (Chrisman et al., 2004: 338).
While altruism in general serves to limit opportunistic behaviour within the family
(Pollak, 1985), asymmetric altruism interferes with properly designing and enforcing the
explicit and implicit contracts between family owners and family employees, and makes
family members’ reluctance to monitor, evaluate, and discipline themselves and each
other can invite significant bounded reliability challenges (Dyer, 2006), ranging from
deceit and shirking (Weber, 1946), to more general imperfect effort to make good on
open-ended commitments inside the firm. Here, the bifurcation bias takes the form of
outsiders (Dyer, 2006) and stemming from strong familial bonds, amoral familism can
damage relationships with outside partners and nonfamily employees alike and lead to the
access requisite, complementary assets held by other firms. In the context of intra-firm
relationships, amoral familism expresses itself as the distrust of people who work in the
firm but are not members of the owning family, e.g., the family board’s distrust of
! 182
poor operational and strategic decisions, and significant losses in the late 1970s
(Magretta, 1998).
In managerial practice, bifurcation bias can manifest itself in (1) recruitment and
below.
particularistic selection criteria with the default adjudication of key roles to family
members regardless of their level of competence. Gedajlovic and Carney (2010) point out
that such hiring and promotion policies can alienate nonfamily workers and lead to
promotion systems can be found both in the academic literature and through casual
entails appointing an outsider to run the firm temporarily until suitably qualified family
offspring becomes available to take the outside manager’s place (Lee et al., 2003), is one
example of bifurcation bias in recruitment. In his classic corporate culture text, Edward
Schein (1999) discussed bifurcation-biased practices at Jones Food, where only family
members were allowed to occupy key managerial positions; having skilled professional
managers working under them masked their incompetence. Predictably, the company
experienced severe bounded reliability problems, with incompetent family members free
riding and shirking, and competent but disgruntled nonfamily employees engaging in
‘underground’ antifamily behaviour. One of the key nonfamily managers branched out to
start a competitive business. Eventually, the family was forced to sell off the company
due to financial problems and leaders’ inability to bridge the gap between the family and
! 183
nonfamily employee camps.
economizing strategy rather than an expression of bias: Lee et al. (2003), for example,
factors, among these the professional qualities of the candidates in question, the nature of
the firm’s legal environment—in particular, the quality of available legal protection
(Burkart, Panunzi & Shleifer, 2003), culture, industry, and the ease of metering
analysis, whereby decision makers design optimal ‘contracts,’ including features of ex-
post governance, for all managers employed by the firm (and more generally for all
specialized skills).
! 184
rationality problems as well as bounded reliability challenges: Those family employees
inherently prone to shirking may abuse lax monitoring structures by engaging in free-
riding behaviour, which would not be possible if proper performance evaluation were in
place, while nonfamily employees may withdraw their effort as a result of perceived
employees—and employees in general—who are not prone to shirking and indeed behave
as loyal stewards while possessing all the competencies necessary to perform their tasks.
Still, effective monitoring systems are necessary even in the absence of obvious agency
behaviour. First, bounded rationality in the face of unexpected contingencies means that
does not imply malevolent intent: That is, even well-meaning ‘stewards’ may veer from
the path most beneficial to the firm due to benevolent preference reversal. As such, lax
stock option rewards to nonfamily managers are fairly common in family firms, as
families strive to avoid dilution of family control and uncertainty of incentive pay (Park,
2002). Empirical evidence suggests that nonfamily managers in family firms are typically
dissatisfied with the relative lack of equity in compensation (Poza et al., 1997), which can
the near collapse of Mondavi Wineries, where B shares were held only by family
members (Miller & Doyle, 2004). Salary discrepancies among family and nonfamily
! 185
employees at the same hierarchical level have an even sharper negative effect, as was the
case at Lazard LLC: ‘Secret’ compensation practices and unequal pay led to a severe
talent drain and consequent drop in profitability in the early 2000s (Subramanian &
Sherman, 2007).
Economizing on the bifurcation bias. Micro level economizing: In line with our
main proposition, family firms’ performance and survival is contingent upon their ability
bifurcation bias. On the micro level, this means addressing the presence of family-based
human asset specificity by (1) capturing the benefits from the unique human assets at the
firm’s disposal, while (2) avoiding or mitigating dysfunctional effects arising from this
human asset specificity. This can be done, first, by investing heavily in training programs
with particularistic selection criteria. Targeted investments in family education can take
various forms, from special in-house programs aimed at family members, as observed in
in the business must follow, as observed in the financial securities’ firm LG Investments
(Hess, 2009), Du Pont Corporation, food retailer Loblaw (Papyrina & Hardy, 2007), and
Johnson Family Enterprises (Ward & Zsolnay, 2004). Training and education are
managerial complexity, where absence of requisite skill levels can lead to—or amplify—
family members will be held to the same level of professional standards. This is
! 186
important particularly because proper signaling can allow the company to attract high-
quality nonfamily employees and improve the quantity and quality of its resource base,
resource practices. Specifically, this may mean instituting explicit equal opportunity
programs for family and outsiders as observed at Ireka Construction Berhad (Francesco,
2004), and appointing professional managers to key positions as practiced at the Hong
2006). Good practices in this area also include offering compatible compensation and
benefits packages to family and nonfamily alike, e.g., implementing company-wide profit
sharing, as is the case at the media giant Bertelsmann (Neumann & Tapies, 2006c), Du
Pont, and the publication firm Spiegel-Verlag (Villalonga, Beyersdorfer & Dessain,
2009). In general terms, what matters most is crafting managerial practices that embody
unbiased family values, including justice and equality among owners, managers, and
employees. Many successful family businesses (e.g., Johnson & Johnson, Ahlstrom
Corporation) make their core value of unbiasedness explicit in the form of codified
unbiased practices be adopted in order for a firm to shift on the bifurcation bias
continuum, which ranges from fully biased to unbiased governance. The conclusion is
therefore that for a family firm to economize effectively on bounded rationality and
bounded reliability, the entire bundle of human resources management practices must be
! 187
important for this professionalization to take place at all organizational levels, and to
Rigorous selection policies that take into account the education and training of
family members, and require significant outside work experience, may point to an actual
‘reversal’ of bifurcation bias in some unbiased firms. Such reversal reflects an extreme
economizing mechanism aimed at creating reliable role models and signaling the values
of fairness and equality to family outsiders. In this case, family members wishing to join
the business are held to a higher standard, and their professional and personal
employees (Cadbury, 2000; International Financial Corporation, 2007; Peter Leach &
Partners, 2008; Steen, 2006; Ward, 2004). Reversed bifurcation bias has been observed in
the context of family business daughters, struggling to make their way in the family firm
(Day, 2008).
unbiased firm. The transition was evident in the formal training of family members, the
join the business, the formal monitoring practices, and the appointment of professional
fortunes, from losing money in the main line of business to growing the business by $2
ownership and control of family firms can serve as mechanisms to economize on the
! 188
bifurcation bias. Legal systems in The Netherlands, France, and Germany, unlike the
Anglo-American system, dictate a strict division of powers among the firm’s top
management, its management board, and its supervisory board (Klein, 2000). In practical
terms, this means that a family member who sits on the company’s board cannot
originated as measures to protect minority shareholders (Burkart et al., 2003), but their
usage may have affected the evolutionary paths of family firms in different parts of the
specificity and therefore a feature of family firms, it does not affect all family firms
equally. The extent of its damaging consequences depends on a number of factors, most
notably technological complexity, firm size, organizational structure, the ease of metering
performance, the involvement of the family firm in joint innovation, the firm’s cultural
community. Here, family-based human asset specificity is not an issue, as the skills
required for successful business operations are not highly specialized and are easily found
! 189
environments where specialized knowledge and talent are required (Pollak, 1985), but
external talent.
Similarly, the sheer size of a family firm amplifies the damaging effect of
bifurcation bias. Larger firms typically have greater potential to exploit scale economies
in segments of the value chain, as well as scope economies across product lines or
geographic markets, but earning such scale and scope economies often depends on the
presence and ability of professional nonfamily managers in these value chain segments
motivate/reward, and retain professional managers, which will therefore undermine its
A similar point holds for diversified and multinational firms that are
evolving boundaries, its allocation of resources for purposes of innovation, and, more
generally, its internal organization (Dyer, 2006; Verbeke & Kenworthy, 2008). Here,
bifurcation bias is particularly deadly: It impairs the firm’s ability to control for the
makers, and putting the firm at a disadvantage when having to address challenges
imposed by new business environments in which the firm has expanded. Internal lack of
actors. Here again, the bifurcation bias creates a liability when it breeds amoral familism
! 190
interfering with efficient access to necessary resources, especially specialized knowledge
The ease of metering behaviour and performance will influence the consequences
of bifurcation bias. When monitoring is costly and difficult to implement, slack behaviour
or poor performance of family members is more likely to persist (Pollak, 1985), leading
to a vicious cycle of unreliability. Here, shirking by unreliable family managers will not
be corrected, and resentment will breed among nonfamily employees, leading to further
The nature of the exchanges in which a family firm is involved has a further
with the same partners that entail swift adaptation to changes in these partners’ needs,
increase the requisite specificity of assets involved in these transactions. Bifurcation bias
family-based human asset specificity and will therefore inflict more damage as
assets and demotivated professional managers are unlikely to be the family firm’s best bet
We predict that the impact of bifurcation bias will vary across societies and will
be significantly affected by national culture. Bifurcation bias will likely have a less
damaging effect in relational contracting cultures where family and nonfamily members
alike are expected to act loyally, as is the case in Japan (see Williamson, 1996). Here,
national culture can serve as an informal monitoring tool to reinforce loyalty at the
! 191
expense of exit, thereby curbing unreliability from nonfamily employees. In cultures that
focus less on relational contracting and more on formal contracts, with loyalty having less
value, as is the case in North America and Western European countries, bounded
reliability from nonfamily employees driven by the bifurcation bias represents a stronger
bifurcation bias, also affects the impact of that bias, especially at the macro level. In
contracting with external actors, bifurcation bias can exacerbate the mistrust of outsiders,
and retard the development of institutions and property right protections which lead to
practices with negative societal spillovers such as political rent seeking or tunneling
Finally, the extent to which a family firm pursues noneconomic goals, and the
determining the impact of the bifurcation bias on firm performance. It has been
demonstrated that noneconomic goals may conflict with financial goals: Family firms
may strive to preserve their socio-emotional wealth, even at the expense of performance
(Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007), and business goals such as wealth generation may be
subservient to family goals such as family control, ability to exercise influence over
When economic and noneconomic goals of a company are congruent (e.g., when
noneconomic goals include preservation of the business for future generations), the effect
! 192
economic performance, bifurcation bias impedes noneconomic goal achievement as well.
conflict with economic goals, e.g., when noneconomic goals include the continued
concentration of power in the hands of the family, job creation for incompetent family
members, and other objectives that may interfere with wealth creation. Here, the
CONCLUSION
human asset specificity, bounded rationality, and bounded reliability, we have argued that
the survival and prosperity of family firms depend on the absence of a dysfunctional
the asymmetric treatment of all ‘assets’ viewed as being on the ‘inside for the long run’
(especially family members) versus on the ‘outside’ and having mere ‘commodity status.’
Here, the default position is to treat family members as long-term stewards, while
nonfamily employees are considered de facto as agents, with ‘commodity status’ and an
We have suggested that the bifurcation bias manifests itself in the family firm’s
governance and (human resources) management practices. The main reason for the
bifurcation bias’ critical influence on the family firm’s destiny is its further impact on the
! 193
its particularistic selection criteria, its inability to attract ‘outside’ professional talent, and
the attrition of any such talent it was able to hire. This firm also faces further bounded
reliability problems associated with the unwillingness of the family members who control
unreliable family members. In addition, reduced effort can be expected from ‘commodity
contracts, including relational contracting features, do not fit their actual ‘asset
characteristics.’
Our paper proposes a TCE-based theory of the family firm with the presence or
have proposed specific contingencies explaining which types of family firms are likely to
firms and multinational firms; firms characterized by frequent, recurring exchange with
voids; and finally firms characterized by sharp conflicts between economic and
noneconomic goals.
bias at both micro and macro levels. Finally, we have advanced theory to close the long-
debated gap between the agency and stewardship views of the family firm, by showing
! 194
that both perspectives are actually correct, in terms of their description of real-world
phenomena in the family firm. The observation that both theoretical perspectives can be
bifurcation bias.
governance’s comparative efficiency, but does not address the full complexity of family
firm behaviour in the presence of noneconomic goals. This is perhaps the key limitation
of TCE as a general theory of the family firm. TCE assumes that family firms surviving
and thriving in the long run have economizing capabilities equal or superior to alternative
governance forms, and that they will fine-tune contracts and internal organizational
design where efficiency considerations dictate such changes. TCE views noneconomic
goals as a potentially dangerous deviation from the economizing script, unless these goals
‘non- economic’ would be wrong. We have briefly explored the relationship between
economic and noneconomic goals as a possible contingency factor to assess the presence
and impact of the bifurcation bias, but future research, preferably in the form of in-depth
case studies, could provide more thorough analysis of noneconomic goals’ influence on
Various contingency factors that we have not addressed may influence the
presence or absence of a bifurcation bias in the family firm. The founders’ and early
owner-managers’ personalities and leadership styles are likely to shape the firm’s values
! 195
and routines in terms of nonfamily employee treatment. For example, Johnson Family
owner-managers from the early 1900s (Ward & Zsolnay, 2004). Oscar de la Renta’s
personal democratic views became the driving force behind the company’s collaborative
and inclusive culture (Anad, Carpenter & Jayati, 2004). Harold Jones’s assumptions
about the role of the family shaped Jones Foods’ ideology and culture (Schein, 1999).
The Du Pont corporation, which was the first North American firm to allow nonfamily
employees to purchase stock in the company, owes this legacy to the personal views of
Pierre S. Du Pont, who believed that “the success of a modern large corporation depends
The extent and outcomes of bifurcation bias are further contingent on industry-
specific factors, e.g., the presence or absence of tight professional networks, complexity/
etc. Individual firms’ strategic choices, ownership structures (sibling partnerships, cousin
consortium, controlling owner, etc.), and the nature of family assets and liabilities (Dyer,
2006) may also affect the extent of a firm’s bifurcation bias, as may and macro and meso-
level factors such as legislative environments, the broader institutional context, and
cultural settings. Our study has sketched the overarching role and main drivers of
bifurcation bias in family firm governance, but has not systematically addressed the
avenue for future exploration is the role of bifurcation bias in the treatment of ‘non-
human’ family firm assets, especially ‘foundational’ assets, such as the original head
! 196
office location and real estate, the firm’s original production facilities and organizational
apparatus, and all assets associated with the firm’s initial product lines. Finally, more
large-scale empirical research is needed to test the main proposition developed here that
! 197
Essay 7
FAVOURS
date, a range of theories has been utilized to explore trading favours, but most extant
studies focus especially on negative aspects of favours, e.g. corruption and bribery. We
economizing practice serving efficiency purposes. From the TCE perspective, trading
hypothesize that trading favours will be more prevalent in (a) macro contexts
cultural contexts where in-group membership is highly valued; (c) high bounded
need to be made by the supplier of the favour. Enforcement mechanisms such as in-group
scoring and incentive compatibility can function as critical components of the trading
link to formal contracting and rate of recurrence, and describe a range of likely impacts.
INTRODUCTION
! 198
practice. Trading favours is found especially in emerging economies, where formal
market institutions are typically less developed (Myrdal, 1970), and weak contractual
the utilization of informal modes of exchange within the formal sector (Li, 2007;
Mudambi, Navarra & Delios, 2011). This practice can occur in any part of a value chain
and at any organizational level, but also at the macro level and in the public sphere;
favours can range from gifts, commissions and financial inducements, to granting
emerging economies, where trading favours is not just a commonly observed business
practice, but often also a necessary one, has brought this long-lived phenomenon to the
forefront of international business research during the past two decades. A number of
theoretical frameworks from a range of social science disciplines have been utilized to
explore trading favours, including economic rent-seeking theory (Besley & McLaren,
1993; Murphy, Shleifer & Vishny, 1993), institutional theory (Collier, 2002; Puffer,
McCarthy & Boisot, 2009), property rights theory (Jagannathan, 1986), game theory
(Macrae, 1982; Von Hippel, 1987; Yamagishi, Mifune, Liu & Pauling, 2008), the risk-
taking paradigm (Lee, Qian, Yu & Ho, 2005), sociocultural perspectives (Armstrong,
1992; Davis & Ruhe, 2003; Husted, 1999; Treisman, 2000) and transaction cost
economics (TCE) (Husted, 1994). Most of these studies have focused on the negative
aspects of favours, especially in the context of corruption and bribery, and on the public
governments.
! 199
TCE has been largely underutilized as a conceptual lens to study trading favours,
in spite of its analytical power (Husted, 1994). First, TCE’s economizing orientation
enables analysis of trading favours’ economizing properties (if any). Second, its focus on
trading favours against the costs and benefits of other real world alternatives for
governing transactions. Third, TCE recognizes that outcomes at the micro level can be
fundamentally affected by macro level shift parameters. Macro level shift parameters do
not simply refer to institutional changes over time in one jurisdiction or well-defined
geographic area. Macro level shift parameters refer to all the variables that could
reasonably affect the adoption, the specific governance features and the outcomes of a
practice, and that may differ from one jurisdiction or geographic space to the other. One
example is the property rights protection regime, which can differ substantially between
countries. As a result, TCE can easily accommodate variables that are the main focus of
a business practice. Such variables include, inter alia, government regulation of business,
theory, which is essentially the international business extension of TCE (and is for that
capabilities view of the firm, thereby providing a robust and integrated conceptual
platform from which to analyze multinational activities with all their complexities,
including network aspects (Rugman, D’Cruz & Verbeke, 1995; Grøgaard &Verbeke,
2012).
! 200
The above suggests that TCE can provide a valuable conceptual lens to analyze
the trading favours phenomenon. A small number of researchers has considered the TCE
implications of trading favours (see Fisman & Wang, 2010; Kalla, 2010; Mudambi et al.,
2013; Von Hippel, 1987), but Husted’s 1994 article remains the only published piece to
date to use TCE as an analytical tool for exploring the trading favours phenomenon in a
systematic way. Still, Husted’s pioneering piece focused rather narrowly on one
particular negative aspect associated with some transactions ruled by trading favours,
terms, with the purpose of designing strategies to safeguard against it. While providing
an insightful perspective of corruption, analyzed in TCE terms, Husted’s study did not
practice serving efficiency purposes in a particular institutional and broader macro level
context, without assuming that negative spillovers will necessarily occur (in contrast to,
e.g., the case of corruption). We assume on the contrary that, subject to a number of
conditions being fulfilled, trading favours represents a business practice consistent with
farsighted contracting and/or managing the innovation process in its entirety, and can
have positive consequences both for the firm and for society at large by enabling
transactions that otherwise may not take place (e.g. political connections enabling
corporate diversification in China as described in Li, He, Lan & Yiu, 2012). We adopt
favours, and formulate a number of unambiguous and testable predictions related to this
business practice. In the next two sections, we briefly review TCE and offer some history
! 201
and context for the trading favours phenomenon. In the fourth section, we explore the
applicability of TCE to trading favours, conceptualize trading favours in TCE terms and
Main tenets
organizational studies literature (Hill, 1990; David & Han, 2004). Rooted in the
pioneering work of Coase (1937), TCE in its current form largely owes its existence to
Oliver Williamson – the leading figure of TCE, whose contribution to the field was
rewarded with the 2009 Nobel Prize in Economics. Coase sought to explain the existence
exchanges, positing that a hierarchy supersedes the market if the costs of organizing
exchanges within a firm are lower than the transaction costs of performing the same
exchange in the market. Williamson’s version of TCE builds upon Coasean thinking by
intersecting the theory’s economic foundations with law and organization, and by posing
20). The transaction, which “occurs when a good or service is transferred across a
! 202
Core assumptions
Three core assumptions about the nature of the ‘assets’ involved in a transaction
and about economic actors’ behaviour underlie TCE: asset specificity, bounded
rationality, and opportunism (Williamson, 1996). Asset specificity means that particular
value. Differences in degree of asset specificity are largely responsible for observable
differences in transaction costs: The more specific the assets, the costlier the transaction,
because more safeguards must be introduced in contract content and process to protect
the owner of the specific asset against economic loss. Over the long run, greater asset
specificity not only increases transaction costs associated with simple, short term market
contracting, but also leads to bilateral dependency between exchange partners. This
bilateral dependency translates into more complex, longer term contracting schemes,
1996).
refers to economic actors’ behaviour that is “intendedly rational, but only limitedly so”
(Simon, 1961: xxiv), meaning that human actors are limited in their capacity to process
information, address complexity, and make optimal choices, both because of the natural
available information. In the presence of bounded rationality, all contracts are necessarily
! 203
Second, human agents who populate firms and markets are assumed to have an
interest seeking with guile” (1981b: 1545), which manifests itself in “calculated efforts to
mislead, distort, disguise, obfuscate or otherwise confuse” (1985: 47). Opportunism has a
because aggrieved parties cannot abandon a transaction without incurring high costs from
trying to salvage and redeploy the assets committed. Here, opportunism is the ultimate
behavioural driver of both market failure and the rise of hierarchy (Williamson, 1993).
The normative, short and medium term implications of the combined three assumptions
are thus that governance mechanisms (including labour contracts and human resources
It should be noted that the behavioural assumption of opportunism has been the
Prahalad, 1991; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Hodgson, 2004; Ghoshal, 2005; Tsang, 2006).
It has been criticized for its narrow conceptual focus, an inadequate portrayal of reality,
and the lack of sufficient empirical support. In the absence of convincing evidence that
Greidanus (2009) filled this void by proposing the envelope concept of bounded
! 204
reliability as an alternative explanation of failed human commitments. Bounded
form of self-interest, but is caused by a variety of factors including but not limited to
benevolent preference reversal associated with (1) reprioritization, meaning that ex ante
commitments made in good faith are reversed due to their importance diminishing over
time, or due to more proximate commitments taking urgent precedence; and with (2)
scaling back on overcommitment, meaning that ex ante unrealistic (albeit good faith)
bounded rationality; while bounded rationality reflects the scarcity of mind, bounded
opportunism: Human actors engaged in economic transactions may fail to make good on
rationality problem, but may at the same time be unrelated to self-interest seeking with
In the remainder of the paper, we will use the extended behavioural assumptions
systemic tendency for transactions to suffer from benevolent preference reversal, ranging
from breaking a specific and explicit promise at the project level, to not respecting a
broader and more implicit promise, such as working towards shareholder utility
! 205
maximization. Optimal governance choices (e.g. the choice of markets vs. hierarchies or
mechanisms with their distinct economizing properties) are thus driven by the asset
governance mechanism, to be compared with other ones, will consider the specificity of
assets involved in trading favours, and trading favours’ economizing properties in terms
According to Nobel laureate Vernon Smith, “all humans, of all cultures, engage in
the trading of favours” (Smith, 1998: 4). The practice of trading favours can be described
rooted in humans’ universal propensity “to truck, barter, and exchange” (Smith, 1998: 4),
which dates back at least two million years, i.e., a time period when our hominid
ancestors lived as hunter-gatherers in extended families and tribes (Klein, 1989; Semaw
et al., 1997). Trade in the conventional economic sense has likely grown directly out of
social exchange among kin and out of gift exchange common in hunter-gatherer societies,
see Freuchen (1961) for an account of the Greenland Eskimos’ gift exchange. The
transformation of social exchange into formal trading relationships allowed the gains
from an exchange to be extended beyond the reach of one’s family or tribe and ultimately
became the root cause for the allocation of property rights. When our ancestors broke out
! 206
of local exchange patterns and started to engage in more long-distance exchange (Smith,
2005), impersonal formal markets gradually replaced the informal social exchange of
goods and various types of favours. In Europe, for example, the dissolution of feudal
bonds and greater labour mobility led to the expansion of trading relationships - and the
consequent weakening of local networks - at the beginning of the 16th century (Puffer et
al., 2009), marking what Sir Henry Sumner Maine famously termed the movement “from
This is not to say that social exchange disintegrated – only that it was now mainly
applied in the domain of a small grouping of one’s kin, whereas the world of markets had
become separate and distinct. Frederick Hayek’s famous quote summarizes the conflict
between intimate and formalized relationships inherent in the transition to markets: “Part
of our present difficulty is that we must constantly adjust our lives, our thoughts and our
different rules. If we were to apply the unmodified, uncurbed rules (of caring
sentimental yearnings often make us wish to do, we would destroy it. Yet if we were
always to apply the rules of the extended order to our more intimate groupings, we would
crush them. So we must learn to live in two sorts of world at once” (Hayek, 1988: 18).
further the two worlds of impersonal and personal exchange. Obviously, greater
emerging markets, where the growth of formal institutions was slower (Puffer et al.,
! 207
2009), and the evolution from informal to formal institutions commenced later (Peng,
institutions” (Peng, Lee & Wang, 2005: 623). Lesser population mobility in developing
countries (due to lesser wealth) serves to tie individuals to local communities, further
strengthening the importance of local networks. Yet, historic and present differences in
socioeconomic characteristics of different societies are not solely responsible for these
Let us reiterate that formal trade and informal exchange share the same
foundation: humans’ universal capacity for reciprocity (Smith, 1998). While reciprocity
is believed to have universal functionality, its specific norms guiding exchange are a
product of culture, which makes forms of reciprocity “endlessly variable” (Smith, 1998:
p. 4). The variability of trading favours practices across societies exists because “actors
do not respond directly to situations, but respond to them through mediating orientations”
(Mudambi & Navarra, 2003: 39), rooted in the underlying culture(s) within which
individual actions are performed. Informal favours are thus significantly affected by
cultural factors (Lee et al., 2005): For instance, relational cultures that emphasize strong
favours practice (and will exhibit a higher tolerance to its negative spillovers) (Mudambi
et al., 2013). Such cultures are known for the pervasive intermingling of business
! 208
in Russia, protetzia6 in Israel, guanxi in China, wa in Japan, inhwa in Korea, cuna in
Chile, palanca in Mexico etc. To illustrate the practice of trading favours, we will take a
(Ledeneva, 1998: 37). Blat is often equated to corruption in the Western literature, yet it
is very distinct from illegal practices and open abuses (e.g. bribery) associated with
exchanges – “a favour one renders to someone else without any immediate personal profit
The noun ‘blat’ stems from the nineteenth-century adjective ‘blatnoi’, denoting a
person or object related to criminal activity, though the modern version of the word
carries no criminal connotations, nor moral opprobrium (Shalin, 1999). In its present
meaning, the term was established during the years of socialism, when consumer goods
were in short supply, and special privileges were required to gain access to desirable
goods or services. Blat did not imply payment for access, as goods were more valuable
than money in the absence of a free market system; gradually, blat developed into an
“alternative procurement system” (Shalin, 1999: 559) routinely activated to gain access to
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
6
Linguistically, protetzia is in fact a borrowing from the Russian “протекция”, literally
meaning “protection”. Both the word and the practice were likely influenced by
! 209
better housing, rare consumer goods, theatre tickets, jobs, hotel reservations, sought-after
doctor appointments, an injection of an anaesthetic in a dental office, etc. The idea is that
a recipient utilizes his or her network of friends and acquaintances to find an individual
with ties to the desired goods; this individual (the donor) does not expect payment
beyond perhaps a token gift of appreciation, but may require a reciprocation of the favour
at some point in the future. Failure to reciprocate may result in informal sanctions within
cases, ostracism.
With the collapse of the socialist economy in Russia and the onset of the free
market, blat has lost its importance as an alternative procurement enterprise; some believe
that the institution of blat is beginning to disintegrate, taking with it the fabled Russian
Shalin, 1999). Yet, in the current situation characterized by undeveloped legal and
offices, restrictive taxation, high interest rates, inflation and frail property rights (Puffer et
al., 2009), blat continues to act “as an oil in the wheels of Russian business” (Barnes,
Crook, Koybaeva & Stafford, 1997: 540) and to facilitate many business transactions.
Russian values of friendship and mutual help. With the transition to the market economy,
the role of blat as a redistribution system may indeed diminish, yet it is quite likely to
difficult to predict unambiguously the role that blat will continue to play in modern day
! 210
Russia; future empirical research should determine whether the practice’s importance has
people from the same native place, relatives, colleagues, people who served in the same
combat unit and so forth (Yang, 1988), and “involves a hierarchically structured network
of ‘face’, ‘renqing’ and related symbols” (Wong & Tam, 2000: 58). Face refers to one’s
reputation within the network; renqing refers to a set of social norms inherent in
unequal exchange (Luo, 2000). Unlike blat, which is an exchange among equals, guanxi
meaning than blat: While Guanxi can and does occasionally involve mutual ‘back-
individuals (Puffer et al, 2009). Guanxi’s relationship to trading favours is that it can
facilitate the latter if necessary by enforcing interpersonal obligations within the network.
Guanxi is deeply rooted in the Chinese culture with its strict Confucian codes of
ethics, filial piety and shame inculcation (Wong & Tam, 2000), as well as the high value
attached to family ties. Chinese socialist history has complemented the tradition of
guanxi (Wall, 1990): In an environment of controlled pricing and limited access to goods,
the utilization of private connections became a way to give and receive important
favours.
Like blat, guanxi is not synonymous with corruption, though it is easy to imagine
how “excessive guanxi” (Wall, 1990: 23) could take the form of corruption, especially
! 211
under current conditions of underdeveloped market and financial institutions and weak
legal enforceability. Today, the Chinese population’s increasing wealth and the general
alleviation of scarcity of goods and services is lowering the need for special favours and
thereby the scope of guanxi (Puffer et al., 2009). Still, being a deeply embedded practice,
both culturally and socially, guanxi is likely to remain a prominent informal institution in
The starting point of our analysis is to determine what trading favours actually is
from the TCE viewpoint. It is not a distinct, generic governance structure, and therefore
mechanism such as the price mechanism or hierarchy (i.e., decision making by fiat),
transferred across a technologically separate interface” (1985: 1). All transactions are
notion was developed by Karl Llewellyn, who argued that a contract between two parties
“almost never accurately indicates real working relations, but… affords a rough
indication around which such relations vary, an occasional guide in cases of doubt, and a
norm of ultimate appeal when the relations cease in fact to work” (1931: 737). All formal
! 212
contracting, referring to codified information (e.g. contract documents); and 2) relational
attitude of parties, sharing of goals, reliance on unwritten promises etc. The specific
socially derived norms and social ties between the contracting parties. The main
between parties enables easier ex post governance should any problems arise.
The interesting feature of trading favours is that it implies the presence of at least
based on socially derived norms and social ties. This reciprocation may or may not be
delayed, and does not necessarily reflect a direct response to the original favour. Given
with the roles of favour supplier and receiver being reversed in sequential
transactions. 7
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
7
Our viewpoint is different from Husted’s (1994), who looked solely at corruption
(associated with an extreme type of trading favours with substantial negative spillovers)
! 213
If trading favours is supposed to function as a relational contracting component
1. When is trading favours efficient (at the macro, group and micro levels) and when is
it not? In other words, if trading favours did not exist as part of relational contracting,
trading favours is observed at the macro, group and micro levels, we explore specific
Macro level. There is a consensus in the literature on trading favours that this
Institutional theory, which has been adopted as one of leading conceptual frameworks for
studying emerging economies (Hoskisson et al, 2000; Meyer & Peng, 2004; Peng et al.,
2001), explains the common occurrence of the practice by the fact that informal
fill voids in the realm of formal institutions such as private property rights protection,
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
as a distinct class of transactions, involving a private exchange between two parties, and
! 214
judicial and financial systems, contract-enforcing government institutions as well as local
intermediary firms supplying services through formal contracts. RBV researchers concur
institutional infrastructure, due to the fact that efficient institutions facilitate the securing
of strategic resources in the open market and thus reduce the need for favours as a
mechanism to access resources (Wan, 2005; Li et al., 2012). TCE offers a parallel
explanation, suggesting that trading favours will be the relational contracting component
challenges are strong, and formal rules and institutions represent an insufficient
governance response. For example, institutional voids in capital, labour and product
markets create bounded rationality challenges for firms trying to access potential partner
companies, employees and customers. The lack of enforceable accountability rules (e.g.,
between parties (Chen, Ding & Kim, 2010), thereby further contributing to bounded
providers, human resources management firms, etc., creates bounded rationality and
services, and an optimal employee reservoir (Khanna & Palepu, 1997). Bounded
mechanisms often found in emerging economies. In such situations, trading favours can
! 215
serve as a ‘bond’ to secure transactions, facilitating both information exchange and
voids. This line of thinking is to some extent supported by empirical evidence: Zhou and
Peng (2012) demonstrate on the basis of a large-cross-country sample of 2,686 firms that
1,280 Chinese public firms, that favours are more instrumental to firm growth when
and other institutions may also inhibit efficient transacting. For example, Mudambi et al.
(2013) demonstrate that higher levels of government regulation in an economy can lead
environment where firms face excessive legal obstacles to enter an industry or to operate
a business, or one that imposes excessive antitrust regulations on outsiders, can create
barriers to trade and investment. In addition, excessive formal rules and other institutions
can cause bounded rationality challenges through information overload, thereby also
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
8
Zhou and Peng’s study focused specifically (and more narrowly) on bribery. To the
extent that bribery can be interpreted as a specific (albeit potentially damaging) form of
favours, their study does provide partial evidence that favours are more prevalent in
! 216
inviting favours as a safeguard for firms to ease their way through a non-transparent and
regulations, will reduce incentives for trading favours (Mudambi et al., 2013) by
hypothesize that both an institutional vacuum and institutional overkill create bounded
rationality and bounded reliability challenges that can be usefully alleviated by trading
favours.
may include social norms, social interactions, common experiences, etc. An in-group
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
9
It should be noted that in real world situations a complete vacuum of formal rules is
some policy areas. However, these economies simultaneously suffer from the lack of
facilitate transactions and ensure their transparency, the information disclosure associated
! 217
exchange of favours (often to the detriment of those outside of the group) appears to be a
widely practiced phenomenon in both emerging and developed economies, with groups
ranging from ethnic minorities and castes to university alumni networks (Bramoulle &
Goyal, 2009; Chua, 2003; Pande, 2003; Kramarz & Thesmar, 2006) and informal trading
networks among individuals with common professional interests (von Hippel, 1987).
Research shows that operation of the group heuristic is stronger in some cultures
than in others (Yamagishi et al., 2008). In cultures and regions that downplay belonging
to a network, firms will tend to rely more on arm’s-length relationships and formal
contracting (Cai, Jun & Yang, 2010). In contrast, in cultural contexts where in-group
membership is highly valued, reputation and social bonds can act as a system of private
1985). The ‘close-knittedness’ of any group is likely to facilitate frequent and recurrent
group members, which is evident even in groups sharing the seemingly most trivial,
result of long-term discrimination by outsiders, and entry is restrictive. The size of the
in-group vis-à-vis the overall reference population is likely to affect the in-group to out-
group distance. Olson’s (1965) theory of groups suggests that the size of a group is
! 218
inversely related to individual information levels. Membership of smaller groups is
asymmetries (Mudambi, Navarra & Nicosia, 1996). The end result is a more ‘exclusive’
group with a larger, common distance to out-group members. Such distance can be
reinforced through a system of extra-legal rules (e.g., rules emanating from religion or
geography, or community-based ones) that govern the group but do not apply to out-
group members. In ‘exclusive’ groups, trading favours will prevail as a mechanism that
can economize on bounded reliability more cost-effectively than alternative (i.e., legal or
occurs between two actors with no (or limited) ex ante information dissemination to third
parties. Williamson (1996) describes the breakdown of a farmer’s hay baler with the
prospect that the crop would be ruined by rain. The farmer is saved by a neighbour’s offer
to help bale the hay without charge except to reimburse for the gasoline. Williamson
but a similar act of (emergency) assistance is expected in the future should another
member of the small community need it, thus creating a circle of recurrent, calculative
support (making this situation somewhat analogous to the one described above for the
! 219
group level). This type of perpetual good news, however, is only possible if the relevant
community is able to apply sanctions effectively for failure to reciprocate, with sanctions
ranging from moral suasion to ostracism. In the presence of such safeguards and
Bounded rationality, on the other hand, may be high, with tacit information carried in the
mind of each transacting party, and with a general lack of knowledge as to when a
reciprocal transaction might occur, and what its substance would be. However, it is
precisely because the timing, scope and scale of the private exchange of favours, and
even the identity of the contracting parties may be unknown ex ante, that trading favours
micro level exchange, the cost of each favour as perceived by the supplier must
systematically be lower than the benefits perceived by the recipient; this situation is likely
to occur when the demand for a favour results from a ‘crisis event’ in the life of the
favour recipient, but ultimately requires only an incremental effort from the supplier to
favours will be more prevalent in contexts (1) with severe bounded rationality
problems, but only minor bounded reliability challenges; (2) where frequent
opportunities exist for indirect reciprocity; and (3) where c<b, with c as the cost
! 220
of each favour perceived by the supplier, and b as the benefit of each favour as
Let us clarify that the above severe bounded rationality problems refer to high
levels of uncertainty about future transactions, e.g. in terms of their actual occurrence,
severe reliability problems is usually observed when formal and informal sanctions are
readily available to enforce transactions, and/or when the loyalty of actors involved in
families). In the business context, this extends to family firms that are characterized by
family-based human asset specificity, meaning that such companies may suffer from a
shortage in terms of both the quantity and quality of required human resources. At the
same time, family-based human asset specificity implies unique access to a stable and
loyal human resources base with limited adverse selection (Pollak, 1985), meaning low
bounded reliability within the firm and frequent opportunities for both direct and indirect
reciprocity. Our prediction, therefore, is that trading favours will be more prevalent
high and technological systems are complex, will find it challenging and costly to engage
! 221
know-how inside the firm is involved (and even outside of it, in the presence of co-
located companies operating in the same pre-competitive cluster), can facilitate cost-
in the favour should not exceed the perceived benefit to the recipient at any level of
favours trading, in order for the transactions to occur. Assuming that asset specificity -
drives transaction costs associated with transactions, greater asset specificity over time
will lead to more bilateral dependency between contracting parties. While trading
favours may then still operate as a relational component of contracting, it may no longer
dependent transactions, and will either move to a substitute role, or will be completely
supplanted by longer term and more complex forms of contracting. This leads to
hypothesis 4.
favour. This also holds for the supply of the reciprocal favour.
governing how favours are extended and honoured, enforcement mechanisms represent a
critical part of the practice in order to guarantee the reciprocal transaction. These
! 222
1. In-group sanctions can be utilized in tight-knit communities to enforce reciprocation.
In-group punishments can be facilitated by close social ties, and can range from mild
reprimand to ostracism (consider blat and guanxi networks discussed above). Easy
functioning institutional checks and balances (and thus may not be available to
3. Possibility of image scoring refers to situations whereby granting a favour may raise
of the favour therefore benefits from indirect reciprocity, which compensates for
potential loss of value should the favour not be reciprocated by the original recipient.
4. In cases of indirect reciprocity (as in the above situation of image scoring), each party
involved in the practice becomes a residual claimant (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972) of
benefits arising from the system of favours. In this case, incentive compatibility
among all actors involved must be established for the indirect reciprocity incentive to
! 223
Types and impacts of trading favours
that the practice of trading favours can come either as a complement to formal
contracting (as is often the case at the macro level, especially in developed economies
frequency, trading favours ranges from unique, two-way reciprocity between two
Based on the above classification, we can distinguish among four generic types of
trading favours, as identified in Figure 7.2. In the first quadrant are unique two-way
trading favours practices that complement rather than replace formal contracting, e.g.,
large scale one-time infrastructure projects that are impossible to implement without a
(e.g. building a pipeline in Russia requires a formal contract with government, as well as
deployment of favours in order to gain land access and building permits). In the second
quadrant are unique two-way favours that substitute for formal contracting, perhaps best
exemplified by Don Corleone’s famous quote in The Godfather: “Some day, and that day
may never come, I’ll call upon you to do a service for me. But until that day – accept this
justice as a gift on my daughter’s wedding day”. This type of trading favours need not
have mafia connotations; the literature and cinematography are teeming with examples of
great life-saving and life-changing stories that fall within this category of transactions. In
! 224
the third quadrant are recurrent multi-way favours that complement formal contracting,
such as favour trading within formal business networks, e.g. know-how trading in
hay baler example also belongs in this quadrant, assuming that all farmers engage in
some formal joint purchasing of inputs, joint marketing and distribution, etc. The fourth
contracting – examples include blat and guanxi, as well as exchanges of favours within
any informal network (e.g. informal know-how sharing among engineers not belonging to
(related to corruption and unethical business practices) has been well documented in the
literature (see, inter alia, Chan & Unger, 1982; Chen et al., 2010; Cockcroft, 1996;
Groseclose, 1996; Husted, 1994; Jensen, Li & Rahman, 2010; Lee et al., 2005; Mudambi
et al., 2013; Volkema, 1999). Its positive impacts, in terms of enabling transactions and
economizing on bounded rationality and bounded reliability has garnered less attention to
date. We take a separate look at the micro and macro level impacts of favours trading.
At the micro level, we distinguish between trading favours practices that serve an
economizing versus an exclusion purpose. At the macro level, we look at the societal
impacts of micro level behaviour, whereby we distinguish between the impacts filling
discourage prevailing micro level approaches to trading favours and their impacts.
! 225
In the first quadrant, micro-economizing practices reflect efficiency-oriented
behaviour that unfortunately leads to negative societal spillovers, for example when
of illegal favour-trading between banks and financial analysts on Wall Street that is
outside the West (e.g. China, India and other emerging economies), whereby a few
corporate governance problems (i.e. resource misallocation) at the micro level, while
resource allocation and economic growth (Morck, Wolfenzon & Yeung, 2005). Profit
tunnelling in Indian business groups is yet another example: here, owners of business
groups (single shareholders who completely control several independently traded firms
but have significant cash flow rights in only a few of them) expropriate minority
shareholders by tunnelling resources from firms where they have low cash flow rights to
firms where they have high cash flow rights. This practice can have disastrous societal
! 226
clouding accounting and essentially reducing the transparency of the entire economy
filling – quadrant of Figure 7.3 tell a conventional TCE story. For example, trading
favours can be used at the micro level to increase efficiency of transactions in situations
where requisite macro level, efficiency-enhancing (formal) institutions are absent. The
cumulative effect of micro level trading favours practices may then de facto fill an
institutional void. Indian business groups (collections of publicly traded firms in a wide
variety of industries, with a significant presence of common ownership and control, also
emerging markets10. These services that in advanced economies are delivered by a variety
markets, as well as some forms of contract and property rights enforcement, etc. – are
costly for individual firms to produce themselves. However, large diversified business
groups fill the void by investing in internal structures and processes to perform the
intermediation function. In the best-case scenario, the payoff comes in terms of higher
the macro level (Khanna & Palepu, 2000). Social welfare may also be enhanced by
business group-government liaisons should that relationship support taxation and fiscal
!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!!
10
Here, we assume that business groups do not engage in questionable practices such as
profit tunneling discussed in a previous example, and we use business group governance
! 227
Finally, the fourth quadrant of Figure 7.3 pertains to micro-exclusion practices
that have a void-filling impact at the macro level. This storyline is characteristic of non-
democratic societies, where private interests are sacrificed for the so-called greater good,
connections (e.g. imposing a 95% tax on oil revenues greater than $100 per barrel on
foreign oil and gas multinationals in Venezuela, which creates an unfair advantage for the
dominant state oil company). In such cases, substantial favour-trading between the ruling
government and the micro level beneficiaries of government favours occurs in parallel
with discriminatory measures against other micro level actors. This is a complex issue
with mixed evidence as regards outcomes. Khanna and Yafeh tap into the grey area with
parasites” (2007: 331). They find that business groups, while serving to fill institutional
voids, can engage in rent-seeking through exercising power over incumbent businesses,
can conclude that trading favours practices that serve efficiency purposes at the micro
level without negative spillovers at the macro level (quadrant 3) – that is, purely
economizing trading favours practices – are likely to be sustainable in the long run.
Entrenchment and exclusion practices, in contrast, lead to costs associated with negative
spillovers, such as corruption costs, welfare losses from monopolies and rent-seeking
behaviour etc. From a purely transaction cost-economizing perspective, these costs will
in the long run lead to changes in the macro level shift parameters to eliminate this type
of inefficiency and reduction of societal welfare, leaving room only for efficiency-
! 228
oriented favours trading. Unfortunately, a range of considerations beyond economics –
psychological, sociological, cultural etc. – may interfere with the realism of this
prediction. In other words, we would like to conclude with the prediction that negative
spillovers of favours trading are likely to be eliminated in the long run and that only
economizing expressions of the practice will survive; however, at this point, it may be
more reasonable simply to echo Lee and colleagues’ (2005) view that such spillovers do
negatively affect the long-term effectiveness and efficiency of how business is conducted
CONCLUSION
provides a credible conceptual lens for evaluating trading favours’ economizing features
have defined trading favours as a component of the relational contracting portion of how
would render trading favours efficient, and have formulated testable hypotheses to
investigate trading favours’ efficiency features at various levels (micro, group, macro and
multiple levels). We have described enforcement mechanisms necessary for the effective
this practice in terms of the conditions for their occurrence and their micro and macro-
sustainable over the long run when serving efficiency purposes at both the micro and
macro levels.
! 229
By virtue of its parsimony and predictive capacity, TCE provides a road map to
reflect on the practice of trading favours. It allows for an analysis of various complex
contexts in which trading favours occurs, and allows for a realistic analysis of the
phenomenon through the concepts of bounded rationality and bounded reliability, while
assuming economizing properties of this practice. Yet, the TCE-based analysis of trading
properties, TCE does not address fully complex ethical and moral questions related to this
practice, nor its anthropological roots and social embeddedness. Further, though TCE
acknowledges the possibility of power asymmetries and can actually address the related
governance challenges when these asymmetries are endogenous (e.g. resulting from
exogenously imposed power asymmetries. The latter include, inter alia, cases of giving
is that this lens can easily accommodate complementary perspectives. Other theoretical
predictions. For example, the internalization theory version of TCE, which blends the
Coasean transaction cost economizing perspective with the resource-based and dynamic
capabilities views of the firm, can add value by analysing the linkages between trading
favours and firm-specific advantage (FSA) development patterns. As one example, in the
emerging economy and a local partner with strengths in national responsiveness, one
would expect trading favours to occur for: (1) MNE products involving ‘old
! 230
technologies’, rather than those embodying the MNE’s newest technologies and related
firm-specific advantages (FSAs), and (2) local services that may be difficult to access by
the MNE but can easily be deployed by the local partner through economies of scope, and
without having to dedicate ‘production capacity’ in an exclusive and costly fashion to the
economies, frequently associated in the literature with trading favours, offer a particularly
interesting situational context for trading favours analysis. First, emerging economies are
elements of both institutional vacuum and overkill (e.g., in terms of protectionist local
policies). These conditions facilitate testing the trading favours U-curve hypothesis at the
macro level. Second, trading favours practices are comparatively more visible in
favours in emerging economies may have substantial, and again very visible,
Fourth, both institutional and cultural specificities, as macro level shift parameters,
influence the application and impacts of trading favours in each emerging economy.
Such specificities should allow for useful comparisons among these nations, and in our
As a closing note, our study has important practical implications for managers and
policy-makers alike: Trading favours is not synonymous with unethical business practices
and therefore does not necessarily need to be fought as a societal evil. Its often deep
! 231
societal roots would make fighting it difficult, if not futile. The managerial challenge is
not to chase trading favours from governance design and from conducting transactions,
but rather to understand how to use it efficiently, and to focus on appropriate enforcement
negative spillovers.
! 232
Figure 7.1. Trading favours U-curve hypothesis for the macro level
! 233
Figure 7.2. A classification of trading favours types
SCOPE
Q1 Q3
Complements Large scale Formal business
LINK WITH infrastructure projects networks
FORMAL
CONTRACTING
Q2 Q4
Substitutes The Godfather, Part 1 Blat, guanxi, protetzia,
palanca, cuna etc.
! 234
Essay 8
by a host of corporate governance scandals that have occurred over the past decade. We
analyze twelve high profile cases of corporate sustainability crises. In each case, a
(in terms of impacts on performance and negative reputation effects) for the firm
involved, in addition to obvious negative impacts on the environment and/or society. The
objectives of our study are to investigate why sustainability crises happen, to explore
spillover interactions of both causes and consequences of the crises among the three
pillars of sustainability (economic, social and environmental), and to analyze the role of
entrepreneurial action (or the lack thereof) inside the firm in both the origination of and
those where negative societal and environmental impacts were unintended spillovers of
otherwise productive entrepreneurial activities; we argue that these two types of crisis
! 235
occur in different pillars of the sustainability tripod. We further discover that economic
pressures are at the core of all crises, regardless of the visible loci of sustainability
INTRODUCTION.
present generation without compromising the ability of the future generations to meet
their own needs (WCED, 1987). Corporate sustainability, more specifically, means
(Epstein, 2008). Together, these three areas of impacts form the so called three pillars of
sustainability (World Summit United Nations General Assembly, 2005) and give rise to
the term ‘triple bottom line’ – implying that the three pillars are not mutually exclusive
With the business world’s growing realization that corporations must address
sustainability (Searcy, 2012), the issue has moved to the forefront of academic research in
management, and has found its way into business school curricula around the world
(Stead & Stead, 2010). Yet, the idea of sustainability and social responsibility is perhaps
as old as business itself (Lolescu, 2009), and has been explored by such prominent
administrative scientists as Barnard (1938) and Bowen (1953) long before it became a
relatively new field within the broader discipline of management studies, and is naturally
! 236
an appropriate sustainability angle. Current governance practices and, significantly,
research direction (at least in management theory) are for the most part focused rather
narrowly on internal control and compliance with existing regulations (Clarke, 2007); yet,
narrow focus is no longer appropriate. Practitioners and researchers alike are facing a
challenge of “bridging the great divide” (Clarke, 2007: 267) between governance and
sustainability. This paper represents a move toward closing this gap, with a particular
focus on strategic governance aspects. More specifically, we explore how different types
related crises – a particularly relevant research setting given the wave of corporate ethics
scandals that has swept the business world since the Enron collapse in 2001 (Fombrun &
Foss, 2004).
methodology, and present results. We conclude with implications for practice and future
research.
employ the constant comparative method (Glaser & Strauss, 1967; Strauss & Corbin,
1990), whereby data is collected and analyzed simultaneously. A pure form of iterative
research presentation would involve a mixed discussion of data collection, analysis and
more traditional sequence, with at least some of the theory preceding data collection and
analysis, and results sections (consistent with Nag, Corley, & Gioia, 2007). This
! 237
presentation form does not directly reflect the temporal sequence of our research,
whereby data was collected and analyzed simultaneously and theoretical insights
emerged directly from the data (though guided by relevant extant theory), but it offers
exchange takes place, including the processes associated with the exchange (Zaheer &
they are purposefully created when they are able to organize production more efficiently
than other governance forms, i.e. external markets (Williamson, 1996). At a micro level,
strategic governance. The former refers to the actual organizational structure governing
economic activities, e.g., the usage of the multidivisional form (M-form) versus the
managerial practices (Zaheer & Venkatraman, 1995) and refers to “dynamics of actual
behaviour in respect to strategic decision making” (Schmidt & Brauer, 2006: 14).
through routines and other processes, with the focus on allowing for two types of
involved in activities;
! 238
2. Superior economizing on bounded reliability (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009) of
managing innovation in its entirety, namely for managing the entire process of
most efficient governance mechanisms will be those that, on balance, allow for superior
contributions to the two economizing objectives, and for superiority in managing the
innovation process in its entirety. This last element can be viewed as the dynamic
entirety. In Williamson’s oeuvre such superiority arises mainly from addressing properly
the level of asset specificity at hand in transactions. In our work, superiority arises mainly
from addressing properly the extent to which innovation is needed by the firm, with a
special focus on the entrepreneurial context for value creation and capture from
innovation.
reliability, and (2) creating an entrepreneurial context for managing the innovation
process in its entirety, through selecting and retaining specific governance mechanisms
1. Establishing the boundaries of the firm – that is, the ‘make or buy’ decisions
! 239
performed inside the firm, and which should be conducted outside of the firm in the
external market;
2. Organizing the interface with the external environment for the ‘buy’ activities, i.e.,
activities conducted by actors external to the firm; this may involve choosing among
3. Organizing ‘make’ activities, i.e., activities performed internally, within the firm; this
Each of the above three focal points of comparative institutional analysis applied
to three categories of decisions, combines strategic and structural elements. However, our
study is concerned mainly with strategic governance in a sustainability context – that is,
we explore how managerial behaviour, as expressed in routines and other processes, lead
involved in establishing sustainable business practices, and how they facilitate or hinder a
decisions analyzed, our study addresses mainly the internal routines and other processes,
and the interactions with multiple external stakeholder organizations. We do not seek to
address firm boundary choices directly, though recognizing possible implications for firm
boundary changes.
consequences for stakeholders. In our case, these negative impacts cause disruption in
! 240
one or more sustainability pillars – that is, they are linked to social,
We investigate crises that occur in each of the three pillars of sustainability, which
is significant given the current scholarly debate surrounding a win-win paradigm for
sustainability. The win-win paradigm reflects the general consensus that sustainability
(Bansal, 2005), and that the three pillars of sustainability may coexist in relative harmony
(Hahn, Figge, Pinkse & Preuss, 2010). Consequently, a ‘business case’ argument for
undertakings to achieve economic benefit (Yuan, Bao & Verbeke, 2011). The win-win
paradigm has been criticized from a philosophical perspective for subordinating social
equity and environmental integrity under economic prosperity (Hahn & Figge, 2011), and
management and performance (Hahn et al., 2010). While several scholars have attempted
to address trade-offs and spillovers among the three sustainability pillars (see Dyllick &
Hockerts, 2002; Walley & Whitehead, 1994; Young & Tilley, 2006; Holt & Watson,
2008; Kaptein & Wempe, 2001; Margolis & Walsh, 2003; Hahn et al., 2010; Hahn &
environmental, social, and economic well-being (Bansal, 2005). What is missing in both
and/or how spillovers and trade-offs shape organizational, environmental and societal
! 241
outcomes. Our study takes an in-depth look at the interdependencies, spillovers, and
trade-offs among the three pillars of corporate sustainability. By using crisis situations as
a starting point of the analysis, we create a particularly favourable context for exploring
pillars.
RESEARCH QUESTIONS
following a wave of highly visible corporate scandals in the USA and Europe over the
last decade (Fombrun & Foss, 2004), the mainstream academic literature on this topic
tends to be either too general – and, as a result, not applicable in specific situational
contexts – or, at the other end of the spectrum, too issue-specific and lacking normative
conclusions that would hold in a broader context. On the broad side, sustainability crisis
is viewed from a global or macro perspective, e.g. in the context of global warming and
crisis (Morck & Yeung, 2009), etc. While this macro level view is undeniably valuable
for policy-making purposes, it does not offer actionable micro level insights. At the
handling crises, e.g. effective communication (Sosa, Eppinger, & Rowles, 2007),
stakeholder trust (Pirson & Malhotra, 2008), managing employees’ inappropriate self-
interest (Finkelstein, Whitehead, & Campbell, 2009), etc. These studies are often
published in managerially oriented outlets and may have some practical implications.
! 242
However, due to their situational context, they do not lead to a broad understanding of the
nature of sustainability crises. The purpose of our study is to advance this understanding
As mentioned above, few studies have addressed trade-offs and spillovers among
the three dimensions of sustainability, especially at the organizational level, where the
dominant ‘business case’ paradigm implies search for conflict-free situations. It must be
noted that it is not our intention to criticize the win-win paradigm – on the contrary, our
results, as will become evident later, support the business case logic. Rather, our
objective is to investigate how the three pillars interact at the time of a crisis, and whether
there are any patterns of negative outcome spillovers from one dimension of
sustainability to another.
RQ3. How does entrepreneurial action affect sustainability crises and their
mitigation?
capitalism” (2007: 1346), which involves recognizing trends, redirecting resources, and
! 243
METHODOLOGY
Yin, 2003; Nag et al., 2007) and interpretive methodology with elements of grounded
theory (Strauss, 1987). Yin (2003) and Maxwell (1996) suggest that ‘how’ and ‘why’
questions (which precisely describe our research questions) lend themselves particularly
well to inductive and qualitative methods. Further, grounded theory-like (Strauss, 1987)
research design is useful for capturing unanticipated phenomena, common in areas that
lack prior research (Maxwell, 1996), which is the case for research related to
discern, through careful data analysis, motivations and sense-making of actors involved
in events analyzed. We, as researchers, fulfill the task of further interpreting actors’
behaviour (Nag et al., 2007) and elevating our interpretations to a conceptual level; in
developing our conceptual model, we are guided by both the research context and prior
Data
Our data set includes sixty one teaching cases of high-profile sustainability-
The cases were selected through purposive sampling, which, according to Yin
(2003), is a suitable sampling method for inductive research design. The companies
1. High profile of a crisis, as evidenced by the number of teaching cases written about
the crisis, and by the amount of media and scholarly attention to the crisis.
! 244
2. Availability of supplemental information. To triangulate and verify our research data,
• News articles
• Journal articles
• Press releases
• Annual reports
• Corporate websites
Availability of such documents for a corporation was one of our criteria for including
objectives of our study is to explore drivers for crises with different sustainability
loci, we needed a case sample that would allow us to search for within-group
by linking their negative impacts to one of the three pillars, e.g. accounting and
four sets of cases in each sustainability pillar. Figure 8.1 illustrates how our research
! 245
(Figure 8.1 about here)
recognized case producers only, and looked for sufficient quality and detail describing
allow us to interpret nuances of both micro and macro-environments within which the
Table 8.1 and Appendix 8.1 present a summary of our research data and a list of
The use of teaching cases as research data is sometimes criticized for potentially
incomplete description of the situation and lack of precision (Kieser, 1994), possible
subjectivity (Liang & Wang, 2004), and the presence of two levels of abstraction (Miller
& Friesen, 1977). We argue that, if used properly, teaching cases present a legitimate,
reliable and practical secondary data source for management research. We followed
Ambrosini et al.’s (2010) protocol for using teaching cases in research in order to address
potential concerns with the methodology. First, to overcome potential bias, we used
multiple teaching cases for each company and extensive supplemental information to
triangulate the data; using court documents whenever available helped us increase
producers only, which reduced the probability of information distortion due to the
rigorous process associated with writing and publishing cases. Cases produced by such
top case publishers as Harvard Business Publishing, Darden Business Publishing and
Ivey Publishing are typically written by experienced faculty members, include the
! 246
minimum of two interviews with companies’ key decision makers in addition to
extensive base information, and are tested in the classroom prior to publication. In terms
of criticisms related to the second level of interpretation, it should be noted that case
writers are specifically encouraged not to interpret data, and to “act as a reporter,
describing as closely as possible what has occurred” (Naumes & Naumes, 1999: 15). It
however, due to the nature of the requirement to convey rather than to interpret
‘leading’ students to a solution, teaching cases might in fact be among the less biased
secondary data sources available to researchers. Second, purposive sampling dealt with
the issue of incompleteness and potential emphasis on certain teaching points at the
expense of other relevant information. Further, it should be noted that the selected cases
were specifically written to highlight crisis situations, which exactly matched our
research questions. Third, teaching cases are argued to be written on organizations that
portray extreme examples of a situation or an issue (Ambrosini et al., 2010) – this may
indeed be true, but did not hinder our research agenda, as crises exemplify extreme
situations of governance breakdown. With the limitations of our data duly addressed, our
sample presented us with unique research opportunities. Through using teaching cases,
we gained access to longitudinal data (Miller & Friesen, 1977) spanning generations,
which would be very difficult, if not impossible, to obtain in the field. We were also able
to work with rich and nuanced micro level information while maintaining sample breadth,
which allowed us to discern patterns at the macro level without sacrificing idiosyncratic
micro level detail. Related to the above point, our data enabled us to combine micro and
! 247
macro levels of analysis in order to satisfy our research agenda. At the micro level,
managerial action became a unit of analysis, while at the macro level, we were able to
Theory building
framework, we adopted modified grounded theory approach (Strauss, 1987), and adhered
to procedures outlined by Glaser and Strauss (1967) and subsequently modified and
extended by other qualitative researchers (Corbin & Strauss, 1990; Glaser, 1978; Martin
& Turner, 1986; Strauss & Corbin, 1990; Turner, 1981, 1983). We used emergent coding
and constant comparison techniques (Shah & Corley, 2006) to analyze our data, which
meant that data and theory were compared constantly and continually throughout the data
In the initial stage of our analysis, we coded each case separately, paying
particular attention to circumstances and behaviours that may have led to the crises.
After analyzing multiple cases, we began discerning patterns across the data, which
provisional themes were formulated, we compared the examples to clarify the themes,
and searched the data for other potentially relevant examples. We collapsed each set of
related codes forming an emerging theme into broad categories (Corbin & Strauss, 1990;
Strauss & Corbin, 1995), for example: evidence of entrepreneurial context, unmitigated
! 248
Finally, coding categories were elevated to the broad conceptual level, leading us to three
main themes related to crisis origination: 1) entrepreneurial context; 2) the role of crisis
locus; and 3) the role of benevolent conflict among stakeholders’ needs. As such, our
three research questions collapsed into one, whereby the role of entrepreneurial context
and the role of crisis locus became two of the three themes that explained sustainability
crisis. Table 8.2 provides example of themes and categories used to code the data.
based on the locus of crisis, and searched for within-group similarities and inter-group
additional categories related to the interaction between the locus of crisis and managerial
behaviour, and to the directions of spillovers among the three loci. Table 8.3 provides
Once the first read of the cases and supplemental information was completed, the
data were systematically re-examined to ensure they fit into the formulated themes and
categories. To ensure accuracy of coding, we extracted text vignettes that represented the
core of our themes and recorded them separately, consistent with a procedure followed by
Isabella (1990). Table 8.4 shows representative examples of verbatim vignettes and
corresponding codes.
emerging categories and their relationships to each other, which directed us back to the
! 249
data (Locke & Golden-Biddle, 1997) and helped augment evolving theory (Isabella,
1990). The final conceptualization presented in the remaining sections arose from a
“fluid movement between theory and data” (Isabella, 1990: 12), combined with continual
Our analysis disclosed that the twelve organizations (and their macro
crises:
2. Presence of internal and/or external financial pressures (i.e., crisis drivers related to
As such, the second and third research questions, as mentioned above, became
subsumed under the first one – that is, the role of entrepreneurship (RQ2) and the role of
crisis locus (RQ3) became two of the three broad themes explaining the occurrence of
crises (RQ1). In the following sections, we discuss our findings related to the three broad
themes.
ENTREPRENEURSHIP-CRISIS MODEL
Our analysis revealed that each of the twelve companies was characterized by a
! 250
“These guys were entrepreneurs…. It was a very exciting place to be. We were
Table 8.5 offers several other examples of entrepreneurial context evidence in our
data set.
both a dominant and a pervasive force in organizations (Cyert & March, 1963; Miller &
Mintzberg, 1974; Miller & Friesen, 1980). Miller and Friesen (1980) argue that any
with momentum. This is true of entrepreneurial orientation, that is, entrepreneurial firms
1982; 2), and mitigating mechanisms may be required to ward off these dangers. Miller
bounded rationality and bounded reliability; these conditions included, inter alia, high
! 251
geographic, cultural, economic and institutional distance (Ghemawat, 2001) between
information (e.g. Enron, Goldman Sachs, WorldCom, Adelphia, Merck, BP, Talisman),
and high turnover and/or lack of continuity among key decision makers (e.g. HP, Enron).
reliability were absent or insufficient – in other words, prime conditions existed for
bounded reliability challenges. However, our data led us to distinguish between two
or, simply speaking, fraud; and (2) crises characterized by managers’ failure to prevent
activities. We suggest that the two types of crises have different behavioural drivers and
occur in different pillars of the sustainability tripod, as shown in Figure 8.2 and discussed
below.
! 252
Directly unproductive profit-seeking crisis (DUP)
Enron’s former vice president and whistleblower Sherron Watkins, “the dark side of
innovation is fraud” (2003: 11). The four DUP cases in our sample, namely Enron,
WorldCom, Goldman & Sachs and Adelphia, were affected by this unfortunate reversal.
Like all cases analyzed, the DUP cases exhibited entrepreneurial context, the presence of
conditions exacerbating bounded rationality and bounded reliability, and the lack of
DUP cases from the rest of the sample – there was abundant evidence of opportunism
practiced at the time of the crisis, with the purpose of self-enrichment by those involved
evident in long histories of ethical lapses by top managers and general embeddedness of
travel agency owned by the CEO’s sister for all Enron’s and Arthur Andersen’s corporate
travel, or WorldCom’s CEO’s systemic view of any form of a corporate code of conduct
company’s entrepreneurial roots shaped its culture, which encouraged aggressive risk-
taking and pushing the limits of convention (and, as it eventually turned out, law). This
and bounded reliability risks. The organization was complex and decentralized, having
grown through acquisitions that were not systematically integrated. The conditions of
bounded reliability and bounded rationality were further exacerbated by the founding
! 253
family’s extreme bifurcation bias – a unique expression of bounded rationality and
bounded reliability found in some family firms, characterized, inter alia, by family
members’ full control of the company and unwillingness and/or inability to monitor each
other. As Fortune magazine mused after Adelphia’s demise, the company’s CFO “ran the
financial side of the business like a Saudi prince” (Fortune, 2002: 144), with no external
or internal controls, and no accountability to either the board or the audit committee. The
Adelphia’s leaders’ history of ethical transgressions from the company’s inception to its
demise. From the early days of Adelphia’s existence, the CEO’s secretary “was forever
going to the bank and moving funds from account to account so that her boss could stay
business: Subscriber numbers were inflated, the family’s additional businesses were
providing services for Adelphia, shareholders’ funds were used to fund the family’s
luxurious lifestyle. Adelphia’s former VP of Finance testified that lying was an integral
and bounded reliability, and the lack of economizing mechanisms, created conditions that
enabled sustainability crisis, while the company’s history of opportunism has primarily
meaning that cultures that discourage opportunism decrease economic actors’ propensity
toward opportunistic behaviour. Our data suggest that the opposite may also be true:
! 254
cultures (in our case, corporate cultures) that have accepted or institutionalized
Locus of DUP crises. All four DUP crises where behaviour of economic actors
sustainability triangle – that is, the only crises that took a DUP form were those with the
visible financial locus, i.e. accounting and investment frauds. It is indeed easy to see how
material gains are involved, and how it would lead to breakdowns in strategic
governance. The important point here is that we did not find strong evidence of
opportunism in cases pertaining to the remaining two pillars (social and environmental);
crises whose visible loci were environmental and social are better described as
find evidence of a strong form of self-interest in economic actors involved in UNS cases.
and bounded reliability, and the lack of sufficient economizing mechanisms. However, in
terms of main mechanisms underlying managerial behaviour, three distinct but related
! 255
1. Bounded awareness, or “cognitive blinders” (Bazerman & Chugh, 2005: 3) that
promote a myopic focus on a certain goal while at the same time limiting awareness
commencing drilling may have limited safety awareness and allowed critical
mistakes.
in the quality of its own and its partner’s product (bred by a long-term productive
partnership with Firestone) that multiple and readily available warning signs of the
result of some rather rash decision-making on the part of the board in response to an
urgent and panicky perception that ‘something has to be done about a major
information leak’.
Interestingly, all three of the above traits have been commonly associated with
overconfidence (Kahneman & Lovallo, 1993; Busenitz & Barney, 1997; Zahra, Yavuz &
firms (Miller & Friesen, 1978). This connection justifies the presence of these underlying
! 256
of the facets of bounded reliability (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009), which further confirms
impulsivity were not present in DUP cases. On the contrary, multiple examples
demonstrate that these traits can coexist with opportunism. Consider Enron, where elitist
culture was promoted, and where employees were so confident in the company’s
revolutionary business model that they continued to believe they were making the world a
better place long after evidence of the contrary was revealed. What separates UNS cases
behaviour by managers may indeed have led to/been motivated by direct and indirect
argument is that in UNS cases, self-enrichment was not the predominant, institutionalized
motivation that led to crises, even though we cannot state that none of the actors involved
exhibited any degree of opportunism at any point in time. This conclusion was prompted
awareness, overconfidence and impulsivity that became the key psychological drivers.
bounded reliability, and the lack of economizing mechanisms, these drivers appear to
! 257
Merck’s Vioxx recall can serve as a classic illustration of an environmental UNS
commitment to organic growth through R&D (somewhat atypical in the industry that
tended to grow largely through diversification), and perhaps in the total of five Nobel
prizes won by Merck’s scientists. Yet, the environment in which Merck’s product launch
took place was rather challenging from the bounded rationality and bounded reliability
standpoint. The research on Vioxx safety was incredibly complex, and the results were
conflicting and ambiguous. Time pressure to get the product to market inhibited the
company’s ability to implement thorough checks and balances, and insufficient scrutiny
In examining our data, we were able to find abundant – and, in our view,
convincing – evidence of the company’s overall ethical stance. For decades, Merck has
been regarded as one of the best employers in Europe, and has been known for its firm
adherence to the founding principles that patients come first. Many respected public
figures have vouched for the ethics of the company’s former CEO in charge of the Vioxx
launch (Bazerman & Chugh, 2005); it seems safe to conclude that opportunism was
indeed not the key reason for the crisis. Other, more complex dynamics were at play as
far as managerial behaviour was concerned. First, a competitive race to get Vioxx to
market ahead of a major rival, amplified by significant investment into the drug and
pending expiry of key patents, created a single-minded focus on launching the drug, and
limited management’s awareness of critical evidence of the drug’s potential side effects;
! 258
the drug was evident in their reaction to controversial research data: that of shock and
disbelief. Indeed, the first impulse seemed to be to doubt accuracy of the Vioxx test
results. So it seems that rather than intentional breach of ethics, it was the quality of
strategic decision making that led to the Vioxx crisis. The combination of bounded
and severe time pressures may have facilitated the negative health and safety
Locus of UNS crises. We identified the eight cases with visible social and
Packard, Chiquita and Talisman) as UNS crises – that is, crises where damaging
sustainability scandals of the past decade. Public trust in corporate ‘big guys’ seems to
be eroding quite rapidly; large MNEs, for example, earned a negative trust rating by a
majority of respondents to the World Economic Forum’s 2006 survey (Coursey, 2006).
Corporations have responded with urgent efforts to restore public trust – and thus, the
questions of ethics and morality have become the focus of much corporate activity around
the world. Chief Ethics Officers have been appointed, codes of conduct drafted, and
attempts made to infuse ethical values into corporate cultures (Fombrun & Foss, 2004).
While there is certainly nothing wrong with designing and promoting ethical guidelines
(although we would like to point out that Enron had an elaborate sixty four page Code of
! 259
Ethics), it is important to realize that promoting corporate morality will not necessarily
safeguard against UNS crises situations, where negative consequences are not caused by
reliability. However, our analysis suggests that crisis itself can stimulate entrepreneurial
activity and innovation, both at micro and macro levels. We observed a recurring
entrepreneurial context, in the absence of proper checks and balances, facilitates crisis.
Here, two outcomes are possible: Depending on the severity of the crisis, the firm may
either cease to exist (as was the case with Enron, Adelphia and WorldCom), or it may
engage in a new round of innovation to respond to the crisis and to prevent future
occurrences (e.g. advanced safety features of 2002 Ford Explorer following the massive
Multiple stakeholders at the micro, group and macro levels engage in post-crisis
implemented to prevent future crises). In this sense, macro level entrepreneurship may
! 260
occur regardless of whether the firm survived its crisis – e.g., the Sarbanes-Oxley Act
Enron, Adelphia and WorldCom. Figure 8.3 graphically represents the entrepreneurship-
crisis cycle.
As an illustration, let us review the case of Mattel. Mattel’s toy recall due to high
lead content and critical design flaws led to a number of design and testing innovations at
the company level, e.g. new methods for securing previously easily detachable magnets,
and portable lead detectors to test paint content during production. Macro level
help local manufacturers innovate, create their own designs, and build their own brands to
the first Chinese system for recall of unsafe products, as well as a four-month nation-wide
food and drug safety campaign. In North America and Europe, regulators engaged in
players pushed for mandatory global safety standards for toys. Mattel’s crisis also gave
and societally beneficial results, is always a second best solution – and is usually not
perfect. The jury is still out, for example, on whether SOX benefits outweigh its multiple
! 261
tangible and intangible costs, which include increased audit and legal fees, decreased
risk taking and entrepreneurial activity on behalf of managers. Companies now receive
higher-priced, more conservative audits from a smaller number of providers, while true
integrity “cannot be legislated” (Sayther, 2003: 6) and is still not guaranteed. Consistent
with Williamson’s (1996) view of firm-level governance being bracketed by macro and
of complex interactions among the firm, its economic actors, and its macro-environment
(including all relevant stakeholders). Where crises are involved, this interaction often
are therefore not to wait for a crisis to happen before devising entrepreneurial solutions,
but rather to economize on bounded rationality and bounded reliability in order to protect
all those stakeholders who give the firm its so-called social license to operate. In
practical terms, it could be useful to identify potential areas of conflict where multiple
necessarily bad: Freeman reportedly believed that “where there is a conflict, innovation
kicks in and more value gets created” (Laplume, Sonpar & Litz, 2008: 1179).
It is our view, based on the analysis of the cases, that all crises, regardless of their
visible loci, originated in the economic pillar – that is, all companies we researched
experienced severe financial pressures that led managers to seek shortcuts, take
unjustifiable risks, and make costly mistakes. These pressures could be external (e.g.
! 262
rising material costs, downward pressure on prices, industry saturation, trade restrictions)
declining share prices). Table 8.7 provides evidence of economic pressures in all of the
cases we studied.
The significance of this finding is in that it provides support and context for the
business case argument for sustainability. The business case argument has been criticized
for its “bounded instrumentality” (Hahn & Figge, 2011: 325) and unjustified dominance
of the economic aspect of sustainability over the social and environmental ones; yet, our
data show that problems at the economic end are likely to bring on breakdowns in social
and environmental pillars. In other words, economic realities of business must be tended
to before positive societal and environmental impacts can be realistically achieved – not
instruction to always secure one’s own oxygen mask before assisting others. This may
seem self-serving and immoral; yet, the simple fact remains that one is not in a position to
help another (even more vulnerable) being unless one is in fact breathing.
Williamson (1991) claimed that economizing is the best strategy. More than 20
years later, this controversial claim appears to receive validation in the context of
economizing respect (Williamson, 1991), the firm will be hard pressed to make positive
contributions to society and the environment, no matter how honourable its social and
! 263
Inter-pillar spillovers
Our analysis showed that not only did all crises originate in the economic pillar,
but most inter-pillar impact spillovers also cycled through the economic pillar: That is,
economic pressures may have given rise to a crisis of a social or environmental nature,
which in turn worsened the economic condition further, creating a vicious cycle of
environmental and social effects, and the cycle continued until either the firm collapsed,
Economic pressures promoted a subcontracting system designed to push down costs and
total cost of recall to Mattel amounted to $68.4 million; share price fell dramatically
(further economic breakdown). Mattel withdrew its license to export from Lee Der – its
Chinese contractor responsible for manufacturing toys with high lead content – leaving
Lee Der with large inventory and no business prospects (economic breakdown). Lee Der,
known as one of the better employers in the industry, was forced to close the factory;
2,500 workers lost their jobs, and Lee Der’s director Cheung killed himself (social
environmental crises where environmental and social impacts are difficult to separate:
For example, the BP Deepwater Horizon rig blowout created environmental damage and
! 264
simultaneously deeply affected coastal industries, such as fishing and tourism, whose
continuity and survival depended solely on the state of the environment. The practical
implication here is that managers should consider both social and environmental risks
inferred, to ethical and sustainable practices (refer to Table 8.8 for examples). It is easy
to cynically assume, in light of the major sustainability crises that occurred, that those
espoused sustainability values were simply window-dressing – and perhaps they were in
some cases, particularly where opportunism and DUP activities were involved. However,
our view, based on analysis of detailed case data, is that in the remaining cases the
commitment to sustainability was real, and the dramatic diversion of corporate reality
from the firms’ stated values was due to the poor quality of strategic governance rather
than greenwashing.
The challenge was that issues central to the crises tended to span organizational
boundaries and affected multiple stakeholders with diverging needs. Some companies
Shrempp, Daimler Benz CEO and the principal architect of the DaimlerChrysler merger,
was revered by shareholders around the world and earned the nickname of ‘Mr.
Shareholder Value’; at the same time, his second nickname, ‘The Rambo of Europe’,
reflected his ruthless attitude towards the workforce, which he continued to methodically
slash in an effort to increase shareholder value, even in the face of European labour
! 265
unions’ exceptional strength. Other companies were able to develop stakeholder
management capabilities in their home countries, but failed to transfer them to host
countries where crises occurred: Talisman, for example, appeared to have a solid
sustainability record and showed evidence of good intentions in Sudan, but must have
overestimated its ability to transfer its stakeholder management capability to Sudan, and
underestimated the impacts of others’ actions (e.g., the Sudanese government and
military, as well as various NGOs) related to the company’s operations on the local
community.
strong incentives to maximize shareholder value (Pirson & Malhotra, 2008). However,
our data show that it is not necessarily so. At DaimlerChrysler, employees’ interests
were indeed subsumed under shareholder value. Yet, at Chiquita, employees’ wellbeing
was the reason behind protection payments to Colombian paramilitary groups, which,
community was showered with benefits – as it turned out later, at the expense of
shareholders. And at Merck, a conflict existed within the same stakeholder group – while
some patients suffered from dangerous side effects of Vioxx, others were vying for the
particular stakeholder group – rather, the common thread here is that the conflict was
either not managed, or was managed partially, to the exclusion of one or more
stakeholder groups.
! 266
We argue that except for the DUP/fraud cases, the stakeholder conflict was
pursued personal gains at the expense of various stakeholder groups, which was not the
trading practices with select stakeholders. BP, like many other oil companies,
being in charge of their own industry’s oversight. Enron, as is widely known, engaged in
illegal favour trading with its auditor Arthur Andersen. While the intent of favour trading
was not necessarily malevolent, the resulting impact, in our cases, was almost certainly
entrenchment at the macro level, and exclusion of stakeholder groups at the micro level.
governance in a crisis situation, that is, crises can occur regardless of the type of micro-
structure for decision making adopted in an organization. Let us look at the level of
decision-making centralization, for example. Much has been written about comparative
Chandler’s (1962) and Williamson’s (1971) M-form hypothesis, where the M-form
efficiency. While all of the companies we analyzed are large M-form MNEs, they do in
! 267
however, were at the opposite end of the spectrum, with decision-making highly
effects (Aoki, 1986; Zabojnik, 2002), and it would be logical to assume that it could play
a role in coordinating stakeholder needs to manage benevolent conflict. Yet, our data
clearly demonstrate that crises can happen in both centralized and decentralized
present in both centralized and decentralized decision-making processes, and the lack of
governance for bounded rationality and bounded reliability that arose from those
processes and routines, rather than the structures and administrative relationships guiding
A key revelation of our study is the link between entrepreneurship and crisis.
While the concept of dark entrepreneurship is certainly not new and has been previously
explored in various academic contexts, including, inter alia, small business and
entrepreneurship (Beaver & Jennings, 2005; Zahra et al., 2006), political economy
(Bhagwati, 1982; Baumol, 1990), and criminology and terrorism (Lockwood, Teasley,
Carland & Carland, 2006; Abdukadirov, 2010), no explicit link has, to the best of our
knowledge, been made between dark entrepreneurship and sustainability crises. While
we cannot generalize the cause and effect relationship between entrepreneurship and
crises to the entire population due to the nature of our qualitative data, we were able to
show the process by which entrepreneurial context facilitated a crisis in the firms we
! 268
studied. Most importantly, we distinguish between true dark entrepreneurship, which we
term DUP following Bhagwati (1982), and unintended negative spillovers (UNS) of
productive entrepreneurship, and show that these two types of entrepreneurship are linked
a positive light and fostered in any organization with an innovation imperative, should
safeguards are necessary along the way to keep bounded rationality and bounded
opportunism as a crisis trigger, our nuanced data analysis shows that opportunism is
actually not the only, nor a key behavioural driver of crises in cases where
entrepreneurship is not truly dark, and where negative societal and environmental
spillovers are unintended. Safeguarding against opportunism alone would lead managers
Related to the above point, we have found that environmental and social crises,
unlike economic ones, were of the unintended variety. This is particularly significant
considering a current trend, both in the academe and in the broader society, of blaming
and shaming big corporations (Wickert & Schaefer, 2011) for their moral
misdemeanours. Yet, our data lead us to conclude that it was not BP executives’ intent to
damage flora and fauna along the Gulf of Mexico coast, nor was it Mattel’s managers’
purpose to poison children with lead paint. While responsibility for costly breakdowns in
! 269
that infusing morality into business will not necessarily address these breakdowns, nor
prevent negative consequences. For management scholars, this means that we should
perhaps extend our sustainability research agenda to study real causes of sustainability
failures at the micro level, with an emphasis on developing actionable solutions. For
practitioners, the key implication of our study is that developing a code of ethics alone
may not prevent negative sustainability impacts on society and environment; rather,
We have also shown that the link between entrepreneurship and sustainability
crisis is not linear, but rather cyclical, and multilevel in that multiple stakeholders at both
micro and macro levels engage in post-crisis entrepreneurship (see Figure 8.3).
Practically, this does not mean, however, that managers should wait for a crisis to happen
Our second significant insight deals with the role of the economic pillar in
sustainability crisis. We found that all sustainability crises, regardless of the loci of their
visible impacts, resulted from economic pressures on the firms involved. At the risk of
venturing into the dangerous territory of the business case paradigm argument, we think
that our findings back up the logic of the business case model for sustainability.
! 270
While the business case paradigm is typically criticized for being restricted to
conflict-free solutions (Hahn at al., 2010), we have actually approached the issue of
sustainability from the conflict end, and discovered that the conflict was in fact ignited by
business case (economic) deficiencies. To put aside the philosophical question of which
pillar of sustainability should come first, our research shows that, in a practical sense,
economic realities of the business must be taken care of before sustainable business
practices can be implemented. Failure to do so may result not only in the lack of positive
societal and economic impacts, but also, potentially, in significant negative impacts
should a crisis erupt. The somewhat evident but nowadays muted implication for
managers is that only an economically healthy business can have positive impacts on its
multiple stakeholders.
current state of the field. To date, stakeholder theory has been the most widely applied
Stakeholder theory’s main tenet is that corporations have obligations to individuals and
groups both inside and outside the organization (Freeman, 1984) – therefore, there is an
obvious natural fit between stakeholder theory and the issue of sustainability. Yet,
stakeholder theory is not explicitly concerned with assumptions about human nature,
a crisis context (Watkins, 2003). Nor does stakeholder theory explain governance
choices made by firms in addressing sustainability issues. From this angle, our study
! 271
behavioural perspectives. Going forward, our understanding of sustainability could be
institutional approach.
Every empirical study has its limitations, and ours is no exception. First, we have
investigated and described root causes of sustainability crises and processes that
essentially led to the crises, but we were not able to study solutions and preventative
measures that companies employ to mitigate crises. In other words, we know why a
crisis may happen, but we can only speculate, rather broadly, what the solution should be.
Further research (of firms that have successfully avoided or recovered from crises) is
Second, our data set of teaching cases has allowed us to link micro and macro-
perspectives and to conduct temporal analysis of internal and external processes, but we
have not had personal access to economic actors involved in these processes in a way that
primary data from interviews and observations would have afforded. Essentially, our
study is subject to all typical limitations of secondary data research, e.g. unreported data
bias, potential incompleteness (Jennings, 1997) and two levels of abstraction (Miller and
Friesen, 1977). We do think that we have minimized the impact of these limitations
through our careful case selection, the use of multiple cases, and the addition of
supplemental information, thus turning our data set into a reliable proxy for fieldwork.
Still, future primary field research could complement this study – possibly through an in-
depth analysis of one of the firms in our data sample (one that has survived its crisis).
! 272
Our study highlighted some interesting instances of governance breakdowns and
multi-actor achievement barrier, but this study extended the concept of benevolent
CONCLUSION
resources, through routines and other processes, to economize on bounded rationality and
shown that failure to economize on bounded rationality and bounded reliability can result
impacts for various stakeholders). Further, we have shown that simply fostering
results provide context for comparative institutional analysis logic, according to which
the most efficient governance mechanisms (including governance for sustainability) will
be those that, on balance, allow for superior achievement of the above economizing and
innovation objectives.
! 273
In terms of strategic governance components, we dealt mostly with internal
strategic governance and strategic governance of external interfaces, i.e., the relationships
with the macro environment and the multiple stakeholders involved in - or affected by - a
corporation’s activities. Even though we did not focus on the selection of firm
boundaries, our study does have implications for that particular governance challenge:
Governing for sustainability may require firms to redirect resources, to reshape routines
and other processes, and to engage in new activities. Whichever level of strategic
governance decisions the firm is engaged in, and whichever stakeholders are involved,
we should follow Sherron Watkins’ (2003) advice to recognize human nature. Simon has
famously stated that the issue of human nature “makes a difference, a very large
! 274
Table 8.1. Data sample
! 275
Table 8.3. Examples of coding categories – inter-group analysis of crisis locus
! 276
Table 8.5. Evidence of entrepreneurial context
! 277
Table 8.7. Economic pillar as crisis catalyst: Evidence from data
! 278
Table 8.8. Stated/acted commitments to ethical and sustainable practices
! 279
Company Evidence of espoused or acted commitments
Mattel Compared to peers, manufactured a high proportion of toys in house to have more
control over safety
The first global consumer products company to apply Global Manufacturing
Principles to its facilities and core contractors on a worldwide basis
Pioneered collaboration with the Consumer Product Safety Commission to develop
industry safety and testing standards
Sterling reputation in the industry for being a good corporate citizen (especially in
regards to Chinese operations)
Merck Reputation as one of the best employers in Europe
Universal recognition of the founding principle: “We try to never forget tat
medicine is for the people. It is not for the profits. The profits follow, and if we
have remembered that, they have never failed to appear. The better we have
remembered it, the larger they have been.” (George W. Merck)
“Whatever decision we make… is going to be based on the science and what’s in
the best interest of the patients” (Ray Gilmartin, CEO)
Ray Gilmartin (CEO) widely known for his uncompromising ethics
! 280
Figure 8.1. Cases analyzed and the three pillars of sustainability
Financial/Economic+
1. Enron+
2. WorldCom+
3. Goldman+&+Sachs+
4. Adelphia+
Environmental+ Social+
Financial/Economic+
• Enron+
• WorldCom+
Opportunism+ • Goldman+&+Sachs+
• Adelphia+
Benevolent+
preference+
reversal+
• Ford/Firestone+ • DaimlerChrysler+
• Ma;el+ • Hewle;BPackard+
• Merck+ • Chiquita+
• BP+ • Talisman+
HS&E+ Social+
! 281
Figure 8.3. Entrepreneurship-sustainability crisis cycle
Economizing%on%
Mul2ple)levels)) The)End.)
BRat%and%BRel%
Mul2ple)stakeholders)
Severity%
Economizing%on%
BRat%and%BRel%
Firm%level)
entrepreneurship) Crisis)
Lack%of%proper%
checks%and%balances%
Economic'
!
!
Environmental' Social'
! 282
THESIS CONCLUSION
has broad applicability), simple and accurate (Weick, 1979). As shown in this
manuscript, both TCE and contemporary internalization theory are general, i.e.,
simple in terms of their parsimonious approach (Rugman & Verbeke, 2008b), and
accurate in that their predictions have been largely supported by empirical evidence
found in scores of studies over the past three decades (see Rindfleisch & Heide, 1997;
Gibbons, 2010). Most recently, Crook and colleagues’ meta-analysis of 143 TCE-based
studies showed that TCE’s core predictions are strongly supported by empirical evidence,
and concluded that the theory’s “enormous influence” (Crook, Combs, Ketchen &
Aguinis, 2013: 73) is therefore justified. TCE and internalization are thus, according to
Weick’s quality standards, good theories; their prominence in the strategic management
That being said, both theories (naturally) have their predictive boundaries, and the
impact and reach of each could be further enhanced through exploring those boundaries.
argued that economizing should be at the core of any business strategy theory
! 283
entrepreneurship, resource allocation and technical progress simply asks too much.
Several workable theories that uncover and explicate the operative mechanisms for each
of these four classes of activity taken separately… is, I think, a more promising way to
Interestingly, this viewpoint has not resonated with strategy researchers, who have
been pursuing a quest for “a coherent theory of effective internal coordination and
resource allocation, of entrepreneurship and technical progress” (Rumelt et al., 1991: 19)
for decades. TCE supporters in particular have been concerned with infusing resource-
based perspective into transaction cost economizing. Almost thirty years ago, Teece
issued a call to bring “together the theories and various findings of research” (1984: 107),
(Teece, 2009). Synergies between TCE and the RBV have also been explored
empirically (Combs & Ketchen, 1999; Zhou & Poppo, 2009), with a view that infusing
RBV into transaction cost economizing can better explain managers’ organizing
decisions – i.e., such infusion can at the same time isolate and take into account the
impact of asset specificity and the impact of the assets’ strategic value on managerial
decision-making (Crook et al., 2013). It has also been argued that RBV can offer
(Masten, Meehan & Snyder, 1991; Masten, 1996; Monteverde, 1995a, 1995b), which
! 284
further suggests potential complementarity between the RBV and TCE approaches
stand-alone status in relation to ‘strategy research’ and other scholars’ urgent plea to
blend TCE and RBV thinking, such synergistic combination already exists in
internalization theory, which has its roots both in resource-based and transaction cost
traditions. As discussed in the first essay, internalization theory has not ‘taken off’ in the
broader field of strategic management, despite its coveted balanced view of internal
could be a first way in which to push the current boundaries of the theory.
shows how CIA, exemplified by TCE and internalization theory, explains strategic
by “governance inseparability” (Argyres & Liebeskind, 1999: 49), meaning that a firm’s
Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1998; Dyer & Singh, 1998). The challenge, therefore, is to
incorporate relational, social and historical aspects of decision-making into the CIA
! 285
The second way in which the influence and relevance of TCE and internalization
explain managerial behaviour could be the first step, followed by further developing and
My hope is that this dissertation has laid a foundation for such a realistic
approach, as I have applied CIA to a wide range of strategic governance decisions, and
have utilized the concept of bounded reliability in each instance of strategic governance
analysis. I think that this work could serve as a starting point for further exploration.
Below are a few key ideas for academic research projects I intend to pursue and that
this thesis, namely work in the realm of IB, EMNEs, regionalization, favours,
overview of the subject matter of strategic governance and a rich, coherent set of
business at the base of the pyramid (Hammond, Kramer, Katz, Tran & Walker, 2007)
and the global factory (Buckley, 2009, see Essay 1) are new IB concepts that by
across various dimensions of distance, and would therefore present a fertile and
interesting context for the CIA approach. Work on EMNEs, favours and
! 286
sustainability (Essays 3, 7 and 8) included in this thesis, as well as Essay 4 dedicated
to the development of BRel, would serve as antecedents for the base of the pyramid
study. The study of strategic governance within a global factory setting would stem
from Essay 1, while also relying on the BRel concept developed in Essay 4, and
management textbook that does not include either the BCG growth-share matrix, or
this manuscript, vastly complex strategic management decisions may not always
and their economizing properties with the traditional portfolio management approach
would present a fascinating avenue for applying CIA. One result of such a study –
4. Further development of BRel. This thesis has merely scratched the surface of BRel’s
potential. Full development of the BRel concept, if taken seriously by the scholarly
community, is likely to become the subject of much future research and several
academic careers. For now, this thesis is offering some additional avenues to explore
and refine BRel. For example, bounded awareness – a psychological source of UNS
! 287
crises observed in entrepreneurial managers, see Essay 8 – could be conceptualized as
an additional facet of BRel (note that bounded awareness is distinct from bounded
managers subject to bounded awareness have access to all required information, yet
Similarly, Essay 8 provides a context for extending the benevolent conflict facet of
5. Testing the BRel model. Once the concept of BRel is sufficiently developed, it could
be operationalized and tested empirically. Finding empirical support for BRel (and
thus ‘rehabilitating’ TCE’s flawed behavioural assumptions) would be the final link
required for making TCE/internalization theory the ‘complete’ theory of the firm.
! 288
REFERENCES
Aharoni, Y. 1993. In search for the unique: Can firm-specific advantages be evaluated?
Journal of Management Studies, 30: 31–49.
Alchian, A.A. & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, information costs, and economic
organization. American Economic Review, 62: 777-795.
Ambrosini, V., Bowman, C., & Bollier, N. 2010. Using teaching case studies for
management research. Strategic Organization, 8: 206-229.
Anad, B., Carpenter, E., & Jayati, S. 2004. Oscar de la Renta. Boston, MA: Harvard
Business School Publishing.
Aoki, M. 1986. Horizontal vs. vertical information structure of the firm. The American
Economic Review, 76(5): 971-983.
Arregle, J.L., Hitt, M.S., Sirmon, D.G., & Very, P. 2007. The development of
organizational social capital: Attributes of family firms. Journal of Management Studies,
44: 73–95.
Arthurs, J. & Busenitz, L. 2003. The boundaries and limitations of agency theory and
stewardship theory in the venture capitalist/entrepreneur relationship. Entrepreneurship
Theory and Practice, 28: 339–358.
Audretsch, D.B. & Feldman, M.P. 1996. R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation
and production. The American Economic Review, 86(3): 630-640.
Autio, E. 2005. Creative tension: The significance of Ben Oviatt’s & Patricia
McDougall’s article ‘Toward a Theory of International New Ventures.’ Journal of
International Business Studies, 36 (1): 9–19.
! 289
Banfield, E.C. 1958. The moral basis of a backward society. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
Barnard, C. 1968. The Functions of the executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.
Barnes, J.W., Crook, M.H., Koybaea, T., & Stafford, E. 1997. Why our Russian alliances
fail. Long Range Planning, 30(4): 540-550.
Barney, J.B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of
Management, 17: 99–120.
Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. 1986. Tap your subsidiaries for global reach. Harvard
Business Review, 64: 87–94.
Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing across borders — the transnational solution.
Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Bazerman, M. H., & Chugh, D. 2006. Decisions without blinders. Harvard Business
Review, 84(1): 88-97.
Beaver, G., & Jennings, P. 2005. Competitive advantage and entrepreneurial power: The
dark side of entrepreneurship. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development,
12(1): 9-23.
Beckhard, R. & Dyer, W.G., Jr. 1983. Managing continuity in the family-owned business.
Organizational Dynamics, 12: 5–12.
Benito, G.R.G. & Gripsrud, G. 1992. The expansion of foreign direct investments:
Discrete rational location choices or a cultural learning process? Journal of International
Business Studies, 23(3): 461-476.
Benito, G. R., Petersen, G. B., & Welch, L. 2009. Towards more realistic
conceptualisations of foreign operation modes. Journal of International Business Studies,
40: 1455–1470.
Bennedsen, M., Van der Heyden, L., & MBA Students of Family Business Management.
2010. When MBAs meet Henokiens: What can we learn from long-lived family firms?
Fontainebleau, France: INSEAD workshop.
Bernstein, L. 1990. The Choice between public and private law. Discussion paper no 70,
Program in Law and Economics, Harvard Law School, Harvard.
! 290
Bertrand, M., Mehta, P., & Mullainathan, S. 2002. Ferreting out tunneling: An
application to Indian business groups. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 121–
148.
Bertrand, M. & Schoar, A. 2006. The role of family in family firms. The Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 20: 73–96.
Besley, T. & McLaren, J. 1993. Taxes and bribery: The role of wage incentives.
Economic Journal, 103(416): 119-141.
Binda, V. 2012. Strategy and structure in large Italian and Spanish firms, 1950-2002.
Business History Review, 86: 503-525.
Bowen, H. R. 1953. Social responsibilities of the businessman. New York: Harper and
Row.
Brewer, P. 2007. Psychic distance and Australian export market selection. Australian
Journal of Management, 32(1): 73-94.
! 291
Buckley, P. J. 2009. Internalization thinking—from the multinational enterprise to the
global factory. International Business Review, 18 (3): 224–235.
Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise.
Basingstoke and London: Macmillan.
Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. 2009. The internalization theory of the multinational
enterprise: A review of the progress of a research agenda after 30 years. Journal of
International Business Studies, 40 (9): 1563–1580.
Buckley, P. J., Clegg, J., Cross, A. R., Liu, X., Voss, H., & Zheng, P. 2007. The
determinants of Chinese outward foreign direct investment. Journal of International
Business Studies, 38: 499–518.
Buckley, P.J., Clegg J., Forsans, N., & Reilly, K.T. 2003. Evolution of FDI in the United
States in the context of trade liberalization and regionalization. Journal of Business
Research, 56(10): 853-857.
Buckley, P. J., & Strange. R. 2011. The governance of the multinational enterprise:
Insights from internalization theory. Journal of Management Studies, 48(2): 460–470.
Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., & Shleifer, A. 2003. Family firms. Journal of Finance, 58:
2167–2201.
Busenitz, L. W., & Barney, J. B. 1997. Differences between entrepreneurs and managers
in large organizations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision-making. Journal of
Business Venturing, 12(1): 9-30.
Cadbury, A. 2000. Family firms and their governance: Creating tomorrow’s company
from today’s. London: Egon Zender International.
Cai, S., Jun, M., & Yang, Z. 2010. Implementing supply chain information integration in
China: The role of institutional forces and trust. Journal of Operations Management, 28:
257-268.
Carter, R., & Hodgson, G. M. 2006. The impact of empirical tests of transaction cost
economics on the debate on the nature of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 27(5):
461-476.
Casson, M. 1979. Alternatives to the multinational enterprise. New York: Holmes &
Meier.
! 292
Casson, M. 1987. The firm and the market. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Chan, A. & Unger, J. 1982. Grey and black: The hidden economy of rural China. Pacific
Affairs, 55(3): 452-471.
Chandler, A. D. 1962. Strategy & structure: Chapters in the history of the American
industrial enterprise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Chandler, Alfred D. 1990. Scale and scope. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press.
Chandler, A. D. & Salsbury, S. 1971. Pierre S. Su Pont and the making of the modern
corporation. New York: Harper & Row.
Chen, C.J.P, Ding, Y., & Kim, S. 2010. High-level politically connected firms,
corruption, and analyst forecast accuracy around the world. Journal of International
Business Studies, 41: 1505-1524.
Chen, S-F. 2010. A general TCE model of international business institutions: Market
failure and reciprocity. Journal of International Business Studies, 41: 935–959.
Child, J., & Rodrigues, S. B. 2005. The internationalization of Chinese firms: A case for
theoretical extension. Management and Organization Review, 1: 381–410.
Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., Kellermanns, F.W., & Chang, E.P., 2007. Are family
managers agents or stewards? An exploratory study in privately-held family firms.
Journal of Business Research, 60: 1030–1038.
Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., & Litz, R. 2004. Comparing the agency costs of family and
nonfamily firms: Conceptual issues and exploratory evidence. Entrepreneurship Theory
and Practice, 28(4): 335–354.
! 293
Chua, A. 2003. Globalization and ethnic hatred. Phi Kappa Phi Forum, 83(4): 13-16.
Chua, J.H., Chrisman, J.J., & Bergiel, E.B. 2009. An agency theoretic analysis of the
professionalized family firm. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 33(2): 355–372.
Chua, J.H., Chrisman, J.J., & Sharma, P. 2003. Succession and nonsuccession concerns
of family firms and agency relationship with nonfamily managers. Family Business
Review, XVI(2): 89–107.
Cohen, W.M. & Levinthal, D.A. 1989. Innovation and learning: the two faces of R&D.
The Economic Journal, 99(379): 569-596.
Collier, M.W. 2002. Explaining corruption: An institutional choice approach. Crime, Law
and Social Change, 38(1): 1-32.
Combs, J. G., & Ketchen, D. J. 1999. Explaining interfirm cooperation and performance:
Toward a reconciliation of predictions from the resource-based view and organizational
economics. Strategic Management Journal, 20(9): 867-888.
Conner, K. & Prahalad, C. 1991. A resource-based theory of the firm: Knowledge versus
opportunism. Organization Science, 7(5): 477-501.
Corbin, J., & Strauss, A.I. 1990. Grounded theory research: Procedures, canons, and
evaluative criteria. Qualitative Sociology, 13: 3-20.
Crook, R., Combs, J., Ketchen, D., & Aguinis, H. 2013. Organizing around transaction
costs: What have we learned and where do we go from here? The Academy of
Management Perspectives, 27(1): 63-79.
Cruz, C.C., Gomez-Mejia, L.R., & Becerra, M. 2010. Perceptions of benevolence and the
design of agency contracts: CEO-TMT relationships in family firms. Academy of
Management Journal, 53: 69–89.
! 294
Cuervo-Cazurra, A. 2012. Extending theory by analyzing developing country
multinational companies: solving the goldilocks debate. Global Strategy Journal, 2(3):
153-167.
Curtean, D. 2010. Alfred Du Pont Chandler, Jr. – Contributions to the business history.
Review of Management & Economic Engineering, 9(1): 229-216.
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. 1963. A behavioural theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice Hall.
Dacin, M.T., Goodstein, J., & Scott, W.R. 2002. Institutional theory and institutional
change: Introduction to the special research forum. The Academy of Management
Journal, 45(1): 43-56.
David, R.J. & Han, S.K. 2004. A systematic assessment of the empirical support for
transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 25(1): 39-58.
Davis, J., Allen, M., & Hayes, H. 2010. Is blood thicker than water? A study of
stewardship perceptions in family business. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34:
339–358.
Davis, J. & Ruhe, J.A. 2003. Perceptions of country corruption: Antecedents and
outcomes. Journal of Business Ethics, 43(4): 275-288.
Davis, J., Schoorman, D.L., & Donaldson, L. 1997. Toward a stewardship theory of
management. Academy of Management Review, 22: 339–358.
Day, A.M. 2008. Family business daughters: The ties that bind and divide. Theses and
Dissertations. Paper 203. Scholar Commons@USF.
Deebe, F. 1996. How GM got to the top. Ward’s Auto World, 32: 58-60.
! 295
Dicken, P. & Malmberg, A. 2001. Firms in territories: A relational perspective. Economic
Geography, 77(4): 345-363.
DiMaggio, P.J. & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism
and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2):
147-160.
Dimitratos, P., & Jones, M. V. 2005. Future directions for international entrepreneurship
research. International Business Review, 14 (2): 119–128.
Doz, Y., Santos, J., & Williamson, P. 2001. From global to metanational: How
companies win in the knowledge economy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Dunning, J.H. 2000. Regions, globalization, and the knowledge economy. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Dunning, J. H. 2006. Comment on dragon multinationals: New players in the 21st century
globalization. Asia-Pacific Journal of Management, 23:139–141.
Dunning, J. H., & Lundan, S.M. 2008. Multinational enterprises and the global economy.
Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Dunning, J. H., & Rugman, A. M. 1985. The influence of Hymer’s dissertation on the
theory of foreign direct investment. American Economic Review: Papers and
Proceedings, 75 (2): 228–260.
Dyer, J.H., & Singh, H. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of
interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4): 660-
679.
Dyer, W.G., Jr. 1986. Cultural change in family firms. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
Dyer, W.G., Jr. 2006. Examining the “family effect” of firm performance. Family
Business Review, XIX(4): 253–273.
Dyllick, T., & Hockerts, K. 2002. Beyond the business case for corporate sustainability.
Business Strategy and The Environment, 11(2): 130-141.
Eddleston, K., Kellermanns, F., & Sarathy, R. 2008. Resource configuration in family
! 296
firms: Linking resources, strategic planning and technological opportunities to
performance. Journal of Management Studies, 45: 26–50.
Eden, L., & Miller, S. R. 2004. Distance matters: Liability of foreignness, institutional
distance and ownership strategy. Volume Advances in International Management, 16:
187–221.
Ehrhardt, O., Nowak, E., & Weber, F.M. 2006. Running in the family: The evolution of
ownership, control and performance in German family-owned firms 1903–2003. National
central of competence in research financial valuation and risk management. Swiss
Finance Institute Research Paper No. 06-13. Available at:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=891255 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.891255.
Fama, E. & Jensen, M. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of Law &
Economics, 26: 327–349.
Filatotchev, I., Strange, R, Piesse, J., & Lien, Y.-C. 2007. FDI by firms from newly
industrialized economies in emerging markets: Corporate governance, entry mode and
location. Journal of International Business Studies, 38: 556–572.
Fina, E., & Rugman, A. M. 1996. A test of internalization theory and internationalization
theory: The Upjohn Company. Management International Review, 36 (3): 199–213.
Finkelstein, S., Whitehead, J., & Campbell, A. 2009. Think again: Why good leaders
make bad decisions. Business Strategy Review, 20(2): 62-66.
Fisman, R. & Wang, Y. 2010. Trading favours within Chinese business groups. American
Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 100: 429-433.
Fisch, J. H., & Oesterle, M.-J. 2003. Exploring the globalization of German MNCs with
the complex spread and diversity measure. Schmalenbach Business Review, 55 (1): 2–21.
Fombrun, C., & Foss, C. 2004. Business ethics: corporate responses to scandal.
Corporate Reputation Review, 7(3): 284-288.
Francesco, A.M. 2004. Ireka Construction Berhad: A Chinese family business goes
public. London, ON: Ivey Publishing.
! 297
Freeland, R.F. 2007. Alfred D. Chandler review. Industrial and Corporate Change,
16(5): 977-981.
Gedajlovic, E., Carney, M., Chrisman, J., & Kellermanns, F.W. 2012. The adolescence of
family firm research: Taking stock and planning for the future. Journal of Management,
38(4): 1010–1037.
Gedajlovic, E., Lubatkin, M.H., & Schulze, W.S. 2004. Crossing the threshold from
founder management to professional management: A governance perspective. Journal of
Management Studies, 41: 899–912.
Gersick, K.E., Davis, J.A., Hampton, M.M., & Landsberg, I. 1997. Generation to
generation: Life cycles of the family business. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Ghemawat, P. 2001. Distance still matters: The hard reality of global expansion. Harvard
Business Review, 79 (8): 137–147.
Ghoshal, S. 2005. Bad management theories are destroying good management practices.
The Academy of Management Learning and Education, 4(1): 75-91.
Ghoshal, S. & Moran, P. 1996. Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory.
The Academy of Management Review, 21(1): 37-74.
Gilovich, T., Griffin, D.W., & Kahneman, D. 2002. Heuristics and biases: The
psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Glaser, B.G., & Straus, A.L. 1967. The discovery of grounded theory: Strategies for
qualitative research. Chicago: Aldine.
Gomez-Mejia, L.R., Haynes, K.T., Nunez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K.J.L., & Moyano-
! 298
Fuentes, J. 2007. Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family-controlled firms:
Evidence from Spanish olive oil mills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52: 106–137.
Grøgaard, B. & Verbeke, A. 2012. Twenty key hypotheses that make internalization
theory the general theory of international strategic management. In A. Verbeke and H.
Merchant (Eds), Handbook of Research in International Strategic Management: 7-30.
Cheltenham: Elgar.
Groseclose, T. 1996. An examination of the market for favours and votes in congress.
Economic Inquiry, 34: 320-340.
Guillen, M., & Garcia-Canal, E. 2009. The American model of the multinational firm and
the ‘new’ multinationals from emerging economies. Academy of Management
Perspectives, 23: 23–35.
Hafsi, T., Kiggundu, M. N., & Jorgensen, J. J. 1987. Strategic apex configurations in
state-owned enterprises. Academy of Management Review, 12(4): 714-730.
Hahn, T., & Figge, F. 2011. Beyond the bounded instrumentality in current corporate
sustainability research: Toward an inclusive notion of profitability. Journal of Business
Ethics, 104(3): 325-345.
Hahn, T., Figge, F., Pinkse, J., & Preuss, L. 2010. Trade-offs in corporate sustainability:
You can't have your cake and eat it. Business Strategy and the Environment, 19(4): 217-
229.
Hammond, A. L., Kramer, W. J., Katz, R. S., Tran, J. T., & Walker, C. 2007. The next 4
billion: Market size and business strategy at the base of the pyramid. Washington, DC:
World Resources Institute, International Finance Corporation.
Hannan, M.T. & Freeman, J.H. 1977. The population ecology of organizations. American
Journal of Sociology, 82(5): 929-964.
Hayek, F.A. 1988. The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Haveman, H.A. 1993. Follow the leader: Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new
markets. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38(4): 593-627.
Hedberg, B. 1981. How organizations learn and unlearn. In P.C. Nystrom & W.H.
Starbuck (Eds), Handbook of organizational design (Vol.1). Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
! 299
Hennart, J. F. 1986. What is internalization? Review of World Economics 122: 791–804.
Hennart, J. F. 1989. Can the ‘new forms of investment’ substitute for the ‘old forms’? A
transaction costs perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 20 (2): 211–233.
Hennart, J. F. 1993. Explaining the swollen middle: Why most transactions are a mix of
“market” and “hierarchy”. Organization Science, 4(4): 529-547.
Hennart, J. F. 1994. The ‘comparative institutional’ theory of the firm: Some implications
for corporate strategy. Journal of Management Studies, 31(2): 193-208.
Hennart, J. F. 2000. Transaction costs theory and the multinational enterprise. In C Pitelis
& R. Sugden (Eds), The Nature of the Transnational, 2nd ed.: 72–118. London:
Routledge.
Hennart, J. F. 2009. Down with MNE centric theories! Market entry and expansion as the
bundling of MNE and local assets. Journal of International Business Studies, 40:1432–
1454.
Hennart, J.F. 2011. Don’t cry for Argentina! Emerging market multinationals and the
theory of the multinational enterprise. In European International Business Academy
(EIBA) conference, Bucharest, Romania.
Hennart, J. F. 2012. Emerging market multinationals and the theory of the multinational
enterprise. Global Strategy Journal, 2(3): 168-187.
Hettne, B., Inotai, A., & Sunkel, O. (Eds.) 1999. Globalism and the new regionalism.
New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Hill, C.W.L. 1990. Cooperation, opportunism, and invisible hand: Implications for
transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 15: 500–513.
Hodgson, G.M. 2004. Opportunism is not the only reason why firms exist: Why an
explanatory emphasis on opportunism may mislead management strategy. Industrial and
Corporate Change, 13: 401-418.
Holt, D., & Watson, A. 2008. Exploring the dilemma of local sourcing versus
international development – the case of the flower industry. Business Strategy and the
Environment, 17(5), 318-329.
! 300
Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C.-M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging
economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 249–267.
Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Wan, W. P., & Yiu, D. 1999. Theory and research in
strategic management: Swings of a pendulum. Journal of Management, 25(3): 417–455.
Hu, F. Z., & Lin, G. C. 2013. Placing the transformation of state-owned enterprises in
North-East China: The state, region and firm in a transitional economy. Regional Studies,
47(4): 563-579.
Husted, B.W. 1999. Wealth, culture, and corruption. Journal of International Business
Studies, 30(2): 339-360.
Hutzschenreuter, T., Voll, J.C., & Verbeke, A. 2011. The impact of added cultural
distance and cultural diversity on international expansion patterns: A Penrosean
perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 48(2): 305-329.
Ingham, H. 1992. Organizational structure and the internal economy of the firm: The UK
insurance industry. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13(6): 463-474.
Itaki, M. 1991. A critical assessment of the eclectic theory of the multinational enterprise.
Journal of International Business Studies, 22: 445–460.
Jennings, D. 1997. Researching and writing strategic management cases: A systems view.
Management Decision, 35: 100-105.
Jensen, .M., Li, Q., & Rahman, A. 2010. Understanding corruption and firm responses in
cross-national firm-level surveys. Journal of International Business Studies, 41: 1481-
1504.
! 301
Jensen, M. & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency
costs and ownership structure. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3: 305–360.
Jivraj, J.S. & Woods, A. 2002. Successional issues within Asian family firms: Learning
from the Kenyan experience. International Small Business Journal, 20: 77–94.
Johanson, J. & Vahlne, J.-E. 1977. The internationalization process of the firm: A model
of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of
International Business Studies, 8(1): 23–32.
John, R.R. 1997. Elaborations, revisions dissents: Alfred D. Chandler, Jr.’s The Visible
Hand after twenty years. Business History Review, 71: 151-200.
John, R.R. 2011. Business historians and the challenge of innovation. Business History
Review, 85: 185-201.
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C.R., & Thaler, R. 1998. A Behavioural approach to law and
economics. Faculty Scholarship Series, Paper 1765, Yale Law School: New Haven, CT.
Jordan, A., & Audia, P. (2012). Self-enhancement and learning from performance
feedback. Academy of Management Review, 37, 211–231.
Kahneman, D., & Lovallo, D. 1993. Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive
perspective on risk taking. Management Science, 39(1), 17-31.
Kellermanns, F.W. & Eddleston, K.A. 2004. Feuding families: When conflict does a
family firm good. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 28(3): 209–228.
Khanna, T. & Palepu, K. 1997. Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging
markets. Harvard Business Review, 75: 41-51.
! 302
Khanna, T. & Yafeh, Y. 2007. Business groups in emerging markets: Paragons or
parasites? Journal of Economic Literature, XLV: 331-372.
Kieser, A. 1994. Why organization theory needs historical analyzes – and how this
should be performed? Organization Science, 5: 608-620.
Kirca, A. H., Hult, G. T., Roth, K., Cavusgil, S. T., Perry, M. Z., Akdeniz, M. B.,
Deligonul, S. Z., Mena, J., Pollitte, W. A., Hoppner, J. J., Miller, J. C., & White, R. C.
2011. Firm-specific assets, multinationality, and financial performance: A meta-analytic
review and theoretical integration. Academy of Management Journal, 54(1): 47–72.
Klein, S.B. 2000. Family businesses in Germany: Significance and structure. Family
Business Review, 13: 157–181.
Knight, J., Bell, J., & McNaughton. R. 2001. Born globals: Old wine in new bottles?
ANZMAC Conference, Auckland, New Zealand.
Knight, G. A. & Cavusgil, S. T. 1996. The born global firms: A challenge to the
traditional international theory. In S. Cavusgil, S. Madsen, & T. Madsen (Eds), Advances
in international marketing: 11–26. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Knight, G. A, Madsen, T. K., & Servais, P. 2004. An inquiry into born global firms in
Europe and the USA. International Marketing Review, 21(6): 645–665.
Kogut, B. & Singh, H. 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode.
Journal of International Business Studies, 19(3): 411–432.
Kogut, B. & Zander, U. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the
multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 24(4): 625-645.
Koza, M. P. & Lewin, A.Y. 1998. The co-evolution of strategic alliances. Organization
Science, 9(3): 255-264.
Kramarz, F. & Thesmar, D. 2006. Social Networks in the Boardroom. Working Paper
5496, SSNR, Rochester, NY.
Krugman, P. 1998. What’s new about the new economic geography. Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 14(2): 7-17.
Laplume, A. O., Sonpar, K., & Litz, R. A. 2008. Stakeholder theory: Reviewing a theory
that moves us. Journal of Management, 34(6), 1152-1189.
! 303
Leblebici, H., Salancik, G.R., Copay, A., & King, T. 1991. Institutional change and the
transformation of interorganizational fields: An organizational history of the U.S. radio
broadcasting industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(3): 333-363.
Le Breton-Miller, I. & Miller, D. 2009. Agency vs. stewardship in public family firms: A
social embedded- ness reconciliation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 33: 1169–
1191.
Le Breton-Miller, I., Miller, D., & Steier, L. 2004. Toward an integrative model of
effective FOB succession. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 28: 305–328.
Ledeneva, A.V. 1998. Russian’s economy of favours: Blat, networking and informal
exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lee, I. H. 2010. The M curve: The performance of born-regional firms from Korea. The
Multinational Business Review, 18(4): 1–22.
Lee, K., Qian, G., Yu, J.H., & Ho, Y. 2005. Trading favours for marketing advantage:
Evidence from Hong Kong, China, and the Unites States. Journal of International
Marketing, 13(1): 1-35.
Lee, K.S., Lim, G.H., & Lim, W.S. 2003. Family business succession: Appropriation risk
and choice of successor. Academy of Management Review, 29: 657–666.
Levitt, T. 1983. The globalization of markets. Harvard Business Review, 61(3): 92–102.
Li, P.P. 2007. Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour: Toward an integrative
model of informal exchange. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24(2): 227-246.
Li, W., He, A., Lan, H., & Yiu, D. 2012. Political connections and corporate
diversification in emerging economies: Evidence from China. Asia Pacific Journal of
Management. doi:10.1007/s10490-011-9265-5.
Liang, N. & Wang, J. 2004. Implicit mental models in teaching cases: An empirical study
of popular MBA cases in the Unites States and China. Academy of Management Learning
and Education, 3: 397-413.
Llewellyn, K.N. 1931. What price contract? An essay in perspective. Yale Law Journal,
40: 704-751.
! 304
Lockwood, F., Teasley, R., Carland, J. A. C., & Carland, J. W. 2006. An examination of
the power of the dark side of entrepreneurship. International Journal of Family Business,
3: 1-20.
Lolescu, R. 2009. The significance of CSR and the effects of the financial crisis. Revista
Tinerilor Economişti, 12: 105.
Lopez, L. E., Kundu, S. K., & Ciravegna, L. 2009. Born global vs. born regional:
Evidence from an exploratory study on the Costa Rican software industry. Journal of
International Business Studies, 40(7): 1228–1238.
Lovallo, D., & Kahneman, D. 2003. Delusions of success. Harvard Business Review,
81(7), 56-63.
Lubatkin, M.H., Schulze, W.S., Ling, Y., & Dino, R.N. 2005. The effects of parental
altruism on the governance of family-managed firms. Journal of Organizational
Behaviour, 26(3): 313–330.
Luo, Y., & Tung, R. 2007. International expansion of emerging market enterprises: A
springboard perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 38: 481–498.
Madhok, A. 1997. Cost, value and foreign market entry mode: The transaction and the
firm. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 39–61.
Mahto, R., Davis, P., Pearce, J.A. II, & Robinson, R., Jr. 2010. Satisfaction with firm
performance in family business. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34: 985–1001.
Margolis, J. D., & Walsh, J. P. 2003. Misery loves companies: Rethinking social
initiatives by business. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(2): 268-305.
! 305
Martin, P.Y., & Turner, B.A. 1986. Grounded theory and organizational research.
Journal of Applied Behavioural Sciences, 22: 141-157.
Maskell, P. 2001. The firm in economic geography. Economic Geography, 77(4): 329-
344.
Masten, S. E., Meehan, J. W., & Snyder, E. A. 1991. The costs of organization. Journal
of Law, Economics, & Organization, 7(1): 1-25.
Maxwell, J. 1996. Qualitative research design. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.
McGee, J. & Thomas, H. 1986. Strategic groups: Theory, research, and taxonomy.
Strategic Management Journal, 18:15–30.
McManus, J. C. 1972. The theory of the international firm. In G. Paquet (Ed.), The
multinational firm and the nation state: 66–93. Toronto: Collier-Macmillan.
Memili, E., Chrisman, J.J., & Chua, J.H. 2011a. Transaction costs and outsourcing
decisions in small- and medium-sized family firms. Family Business Review, 24: 47–61.
Memili, E., Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., Chang, E.P.C., & Kellermanns, F.W. 2011b. The
determinants of family firms’ subcontracting: A transaction cost perspective. Journal of
Family Business Strategy, 2: 26–33.
Meyer, K. E. & Peng, M. W. 2005. Probing theoretically into Central and Eastern
Europe: Transactions, resources, and institutions. Journal of International Business
Studies, 36(6), 600-621.
! 306
Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. 1997. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth
and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340-363.
Miller, D., & Friesen, P. H. 1982. Innovation in conservative and entrepreneurial firms:
Two models of strategic momentum. Strategic Management Journal, 3(1): 1-25.
Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Scholnick, B. 2008. Stewardship vs. stagnation: An
empirical comparison of small family and non-family businesses. Journal of Management
Studies, 45: 51–78.
Miller, D., & Mintzberg, H. 1974. Strategy formulation in context: Some tentative
models. Unpublished manuscript, Faculty of Commerce, McGill University.
Miller, G.S. & Doyle, T. 2004. Mondavi winery. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School
Publishing.
Mintzberg, H. 1990. The design school: Reconsidering the basic premises of strategic
management. Strategic Management Journal, 11(3): 171-195.
Moore, D. A., Oesch, J. M., & Zietsma, C. 2007. What competition? Myopic self-focus in
market-entry decisions. Organization Science, 18(3): 440-454.
Morck, R., & Yeung, B. 2009. Never waste a good crisis: an historical perspective on
comparative corporate governance. Working paper w15042, National Bureau of
Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Morck, R., Wolfenzon, D., & Yeung, B. 2005. Corporate governance, economic
entrenchment, and growth. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII: 655-720.
! 307
Mudambi, R. & Navarra, P. 2003. Political culture and foreign direct investment: The
case of Italy. Economics of Governance, 4(1): 37-56.
Mudambi, R., Navarra, P., & Delios, A. 2013. Government regulation, corruption and
FDI. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 30(2): 487-511.
Mudambi, R., Navarra, P., & Nocosia, D. 1996. Plurality vs. proportional representation:
An analysis of Sicillian elections. Public Choice, 86(3-4): 341-357.
Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. 1993. Why is rent-seeking so costly to
growth? American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 83(2): 409-414.
Nachum, L. & Wymes, C. 2007. The location and performance of foreign affiliates in
global cities. In A.M. Rugman (Ed.), Regional Aspects of Multinationality and
Performance, Research in Global Strategic Management, Vol. 13: 221-259. Oxford:
Elsevier.
Nag, R., Corley, K. G., & Gioia, D. A. 2007. The intersection of organizational identity,
knowledge, and practice: Attempting strategic change via knowledge crafting. Academy
of Management Journal, 50(4): 821-847.
Narula, R. 2006. Globalization, new ecologies, new zoologies, and the purported death of
the eclectic paradigm. Asia-Pacific Journal of Management, 23: 143–151.
Naumes, W., & Naumes, M. J. 1999. The art & craft of case writing. London: Sage.
Neumann, F.A. & Tapies, J. 2006a. Succession at Merck KGaA. Barcelona, Spain: IESE
Publishing.
Neumann, F.A. & Tapies, J. 2006b. Balancing family and business needs at Merck
KGaA. Barcelona, Spain: IESE Publishing.
Neumann, F.A. & Tapies, J. 2006c. Bertelsmann: The ownership question. Barcelona,
Spain: IESE Publishing.
! 308
Nystrom, P.C. & Starbuck, W.H. 1984. To avoid organizational crises, unlearn.
Organizational Dynamics, Spring: 53-65.
Oh, C.H. & Rugman, A.M. 2006. Regional sales of multinationals in the world cosmetics
industry. European Management Journal, 24(2-3): 163-173.
Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action. Boston: Harvard University Press.
Ouchi, W.G. 1979. A conceptual framework for the design of organizational control
mechanisms. Management Science, 25: 833-848.
Pande, R. 2003. Can mandated political representation increase policy influence for
disadvantaged minorities? Theory and evidence from India. American Economic Review,
93(4): 1132-1151.
Papyrina, V. & Hardy, G. 2007. Loblaw Companies Limited: Preparing for Wal-Mart
supercenters. London, ON: Ivey Publishing.
Peng, M.W., Lee, S.-H., & Wang, D.Y.L. 2005. What determines the scope of the firm
over time? A focus on institutional relatedness. Academy of Management Review, 30(3):
622-633.
Peng, M. W., Lu, Y., Shenkar, O., & Wang, D. 2001. Treasures in the China shop: A
review of management and organizational research on Greater China. Journal of Business
Research, 52: 95–110.
Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Wiley.
Perman, S. 2006. Taking the pulse of family businesses. Business Week, February 13.
! 309
Peter Leach & Partners, LLP. 2008. Pay, benefits and incentives in family companies.
London: Peter Leach LLP.
Pirson, M., & Malhotra, D. 2008. Unconventional insights for managing stakeholder
trust. MIT Sloan Management Review, 49(4): 42-51.
Powell, W.W. & Snellman, K. 2004. The knowledge economy. Annual Review of
Sociology, 30: 199-220.
Poza, E.F., Alfred, T., & Maheshawi, A. 1997. Stakeholder perceptions of culture and
management practices in family and family firms—A preliminary report. Family
Business Review, 10(2): 135–155.
Pratt, M.G. 2009. For the lack of a boilerplate: Tips on writing up (and reviewing)
qualitative research. Academy of Management Journal, 52: 856-862.
Puffer, S.M., McCarthy, D.J., & Boisot, M. 2009. Entrepreneurship in Russia and China:
The impact of formal institutional voids. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34(3):
441-467.
Ramamurti, R. 2009. What have we learned about EMNEs. In R. Ramamurti & J. Singh
(Eds), Emerging multinationals from emerging markets: 399–426. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Rindfleisch, A. & Heide, J.B. 1997. Transaction cost analysis: Past, present, and future
applications. The Journal of Marketing, 61(4), 30-54.
! 310
Rugman, A. M. 1996. The theory of multinational enterprises. Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar.
Rugman, A. M. & Almodovar, P. 2011. The born global illusion and the regional nature
of international business. In R. Ramamurti & N. Hashai (Eds), The future of foreign
direct investment and the multinational enterprise. Research in Global Strategic
Management 15: 265–283. Bingley, UK: Emerald.
Rugman, A.M. & Girod, S. 2003. Retail multinationals and globalization: The evidence is
regional. European Management Journal, 21(1): 24-37.
Rugman, A. M. & Verbeke, A. 1992. A note on the transnational solution and the
transaction cost theory of multinational strategic management. Journal of International
Business Studies, 23(4): 761–771.
! 311
Rugman, A. M. & Verbeke, A. 2007. Liabilities of regional foreignness and the use of
firm-level versus country-level data: A response to Dunning et al. (2007). Journal of
International Business Studies, 38: 200–205.
Rugman, A.M. & Verbeke, A. 2008a. A new perspective on the regional and global
strategies of multinational services firms. Management International Review, 48(4): 397-
411.
Rugman, A. M. & Verbeke, A. 2008b. Internalization theory and its impact on the field of
international business. In J. J. Boddewyn (Ed.), International business scholarship: AIB
fellows on the first 50 years and beyond. Research in Global Strategic Management 14:
155–174. Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.
Rugman, A. M., Verbeke, A., & Nguyen, Q. T. K. 2011a. Fifty years of international
business theory and beyond. Management International Review, 51(6): 755–786.
Rugman, A.M., Verbeke, A., & Yuan, W. 2011b. Re-conceptualizing Bartlett and
Ghoshal's classification of national subsidiary roles in the multinational enterprise.
Journal of Management Studies, 48(2): 253-277.
Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. J. 1991. Strategic management and economics.
Strategic Management Journal, 12: 5-29.
Safarian, A. E. 2003. Internalization and the MNE: A note on the spread of ideas. Journal
of International Business Studies, 34: 116–124.
Sayther, C. 2003. Report card on Sarbanes-Oxley: One year later. Financial Executive,
19(7): 6.
Schein, E.H. (1999). The corporate culture survival guide. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-
Bass.
Schmidt, S. L., & Brauer, M. 2006. Strategic governance: How to assess board
effectiveness in guiding strategy execution. Corporate Governance: An International
Review, 14(1): 13-22.
Schulze, W.S., Lubatkin, M.H., & Dino, R.N. 2003. Exploring the agency consequences
of ownership dispersion among the directors of private family firms. Academy of
Management Journal, 46: 179–194.
Schulze, W.S., Lubatkin, M.H., Dino, R.N., & Buchholtz, A.K. 2001. Agency
relationship in family firms: Theory and evidence. Organization Science, 12: 99–116.
! 312
Semaw, S., Renna, P, Harris, J.W.K., Fiebel, C.S., Bernor, R.L., Fesseha, N.Y. &
Mowbray, K. 1997. 2.5 million-year-old stone tools from Gona, Ethiopia. Nature, 385:
333-336.
Shah, S. K., & Corley, K. G. 2006. Building better theory by bridging the quantitative–
qualitative divide. Journal of Management Studies, 43: 1821-1835.
Shalin, D.N. 1999. Review of “Russian’s Economy of Favours: Blat, Networking and
Informal Exchange”. Contemporary Psychology, 28(5): 558-560.
Sharma, P. & Manikutty, S. 2005. Strategic divestments in family firms: Role of family
structure and community culture. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 29: 293–311.
Sherer, P.D. & Lee, K. 2002. Institutional change in large law firms: A resource
dependency and institutional perspective. The Academy of Management Journal, 45(1):
102-119.
Shim, J. & Okamuro, H. 2011. Does ownership matter in mergers? A comparative study
of the causes and consequences of mergers by family and non-family firms. Journal of
Banking & Finance, 35: 193–203.
Simon, H.A. 1961. Administrative behaviour (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan.
Simon, H.A. 1985. Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political
science. American Political Science Review, 79: 293-304.
Sirmon, D.G. & Hitt, M.A. 2003. Managing resources: Linking unique resources,
management and wealth creation in family firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
27: 339–358.
Slovic, P., Finucane, M.L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D.G. 2002. Rational actors or
rational fools: Implications of the affect heuristic for behavioural economics. The Journal
of Socio-Economics, 31: 329–342.
Slovic, P., Finucane, M.L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D.G. 2007. The affect heuristic.
European Journal of Operational Research, 177: 1333–1352.
Smith, V.L. 1998. The two faces of Adam Smith. Southern Economic Journal, 65(1): 1-
19.
Smith, V.L. 2005. Hayek and experimental economics. The Review of Austrian
Economics, 18(2): 135-144.
! 313
Sosa, M. E., Eppinger, S. D., & Rowles, C. M. 2007. Are your engineers talking to one
another when they should? Harvard Business Review, 85(11): 133-143.
Stead, J. G., & Stead, W. E. 2010. Sustainability comes to management education and
research: a story of coevolution. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 9(3):
488-498.
Steen, M. 2006. The decision tree of family business. Stanford Business Magazine,
August.
Straus, A.L. 1987. Qualitative analysis for social scientists. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Straus, A.L, & Corbin, J. 1990. Basics of qualitative research: Grounded theory
procedures and techniques. Newbery Park, CA: Sage.
Subramanian, G. & Sherman, E. 2007. Lazard LLC. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
School Publishing.
Sutton, R.I. & Staw, B.M. 1996. What theory is not. Administrative Science Quarterly,
40(3): 371-384.
Teece, D. 1981. The multinational enterprise: Market failure and market power
considerations. Sloan Management Review, 22(3): 3–17.
! 314
Teece, D. J. 2009. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management: Organizing for
innovation and growth: Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Teece, D., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic
management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(8): 537–556.
Tolbert, P.S. & Zucker, L.G. 1983. Institutional sources of change in the formal structure
of organizations: The diffusion of civil service reform, 1880-1935. Administrative
Science Quarterly, 28(1): 22-39.
Toninato, F. & Tapies, J. 2005. The Agnellis and the Fiat Group: The story of a family
empire (A). Case DG-1475-E. Barcelona, Spain: IESE Publishing.
Trainer, F. E. 1997. The global sustainability crisis: The implications for community.
International Journal of Social Economics, 24(11): 1219-1240.
Tran, E., Sambamurthy, B., & Mansinghka, S. 2006. The Harilela Enterprises: An Indian
family business in Hong Kong. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Publishing.
Turner, B.A. 1981. Some practical aspects of qualitative data analysis: One way of
organizing the cognitive processes associated with the generation of grounded theory.
Quality and Quantity, 15: 225-247.
Turner, B.A. 1983. The use of grounded theory for the qualitative analysis of
organization behaviour. Journal of Management Studies, 20: 333-347.
! 315
Vallejo, M.C. 2009. The effect of commitment of non-family employees of family firms
from the perspective of stewardship theory. Journal of Business Ethics, 87: 379–390.
Van Agtmael, A. 2007. The emerging markets century: How a new breed of world-class
companies is overtaking the world. New York: Free Press.
Verbeke, A. 2003. The evolutionary view of the MNE and the future of internalization
theory. Journal of International Business Studies, 34: 498–504.
Verbeke, A., & Brugman, P. 2009. Triple testing the quality of multinationality—
performance research: An internalization theory perspective.” International Business
Review, 18: 265–275.
Verbeke, A., & Forootan, M. Z. 2012. How good are multinationality–performance (M-
P) empirical studies? Global Strategy Journal, 2(4): 332-344.
Verbeke, A. & Greidanus, N.S. 2009. The end of the opportunism vs. trust debate:
Bounded reliability as a new envelope concept in research on MNE governance. Journal
of International Business Studies, 40: 1471–1495.
Verbeke, A., Li, L., & Goerzen, A. 2009. Toward more effective research on the
multinationality and performance relationship. Management International Review, 49:
149–62.
Villalonga, B., Beyersdorfer, D., & Dessain, V. 2009. Spiegel-Verlag Rudolf Augstein
GmbH & Co. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Publishing.
Von Hippel, E. 1987. Cooperation between rivals: Informal know-how trading. Research
Policy, 16: 291-302.
Wall Jr., J.A. 1990. Managers in the People’s Republic of China. The Executive, 4(2): 19-
32.
Walley, N., & Whitehead, B. 1994. It's not easy being green. Harvard Business Review,
72(3): 46-52.
! 316
Walsh, J. & Seward, J. 1990. On the efficiency of internal and external corporate control
mechanisms. Academy of Management Review, 15(3): 421–458.
Wan, W.P. 2005. Country resource environments, firm capabilities, and corporate
diversification strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 42: 161-182.
Ward, J.L. 2004. Perpetuating the family business: 50 lessons learned from long-lasting
success. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Ward, J.L. & Pericelli, S.G. 2005. Magid Glove and Safety Manufacturing Co. Boston,
MA: Harvard Business School Publishing.
Ward, J.L. & Zsolnay, C.A. 2004. Succession and continuity for Johnson Family
Enterprises. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Publishing.
WCED. 1987. Our common future. Oxford: World Commission on Environment and
Development and Oxford University Press.
Weber, M. 1946. From Max Weber: Essays in sociology. H.H. Gerth & C.W. Mills (Eds).
New York: Oxford University Press.
Weick, K.E. 1979. The social psychology of organizing. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Westhead, P. & Howorth, C. 2006. Ownership and management issues associated with
family firm performance and company objectives. Family Business Review, XIX(4): 301–
316.
Westhead, P. & Cowling, M. 1998. Family firm research: The need for a methodological
rethink. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 23: 301–316.
! 317
of Economic Literature, 19: 1537-1568.
Winter, S.G. & Teece, D.J. 2010. A conversation with Sidney Winter on the contributions
of Alfred Chandler. Industrial and Corporate Change, 19(2): 363-376
Wolf, J., Egelhoff, W.G., & Dunemann, T. 2012. Why MNCs tend to concentrate their
activities in their home region. The Multinational Business Review, 20(1): 26-43.
Wong, Y.H. & Tam, J.L.M. 2000. Mapping relationships in China: Dynamic approach.
Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 15(1): 57-70.
World Summit United Nations General Assembly. 2005. 2005 World Summit Outcome,
Resolution A/60/1, adopted by the General Assembly, 15 September 2005.
Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R. E., & Peng, M. W. 2005. Guest editors’
introduction: Strategy research in emerging economies: Challenging the conventional
wisdom. Journal of Management Studies, 42: 1–33.
Yamagishi, T., Mifune, N., Liu, J.H., & Pauling, J. 2008. Exchanges of group-based
favours: Ingroup bias in the prisoner’s dilemma game with minimal groups in Japan and
New Zealand. Asian Journal of Social Psychology, 11: 196-207.
Yang, M. 1988. The modernity of power in the Chinese socialist order. Cultural
Anthropology, 3: 408-427.
Yeung, B. & Mirus, R. 1988. On the mode of international expansion: The role of agency
costs in an expanded framework. In Academy of International Business conference, San
Diego, CA.
Yin, R. K. 2003. Case study research: Design and methods. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
! 318
Yip, G. 2002. Total global strategy II. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Yiu, D. W., Lau, C., & Bruton, G. D. 2007. International venturing by emerging economy
firms: The effects of firm capabilities, home country networks, and corporate
entrepreneurship. Journal of International Business Studies, 38: 519–540.
Young, S., Dimitratos, P., & Dana, L.P. 2003. International entrepreneurship research:
What scope for international business theories? Journal of International
Entrepreneurship, 1(1): 31–42.
Young, W. & Tilley, F. 2006. Can businesses move beyond efficiency? The shift toward
effectiveness and equity in the corporate sustainability debate. Business Strategy and the
Environment, 15(6): 402-415.
Yuan, W., Bao, Y., & Verbeke, A. 2011. Integrating CSR initiatives in business: An
organizing framework. Journal of Business Ethics, 101(1): 75-92.
Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V. 1998. Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of
interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Science, 9(2):
141-159.
Zahra, S.A., Hayton, J.C., Neubaum, D.O., Dibrell, C., & Craig, J. 2008. Culture of
family commitment and strategic flexibility: The moderating effect of stewardship.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32: 1035–1054.
Zahra, S. A., Korri, J. S., & Yu, J.F. 2005. Cognition and international entrepreneurship:
Implications for research on international opportunity recognition and exploitation.
International Business Review, 14(2): 129–146.
Zahra, S. A., Yavuz, R. I., & Ucbasaran, D. 2006. How much do you trust me? The dark
side of relational trust in new business creation in established companies.
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 30(4): 541-559.
Zeng, M. & Williamson, P. J. 2007. Dragons at your door: How Chinese cost innovation
is disrupting global competition. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
! 319
Zekany, K.E., Braun, L.W., & Warder, Z.T. 2004. Behind closed doors at WorldCom:
2001. Issues in Accounting Education, 19(1): 101-117.
Zhou, J. Q., & Peng, M. W. 2012. Does bribery help or hurt firm growth around the
world? Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29(4): 907-921.
Zhou, J. Q., & Peng, M. W. 2012. Does bribery help or hurt firm growth around the
world? Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29(4): 907-921.
Zhou, K. Z. & Poppo, L. 2010. Exchange hazards, relational reliability, and contracts in
China: The contingent role of legal enforceability. Journal of International Business
Studies, 41: 861–881.
! 320
APPENDIX 3.1. Cases analyzed on the ten EMNEs
Company Cases
1 Lenovo Lenovo: Countering the Dell Challenge. (Pan & Sethi, 2075. Asia Case
Research Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
2 Infosys Infosys in India: Building a Software Giant in a Corrupt Environment.
(Abdelal, Di Tella, & Kothandaraman, 2007. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
Infosys Consulting in 2006: Leading the Next Generation of Business
and Information Technology Consulting. (Burgelman & Capur, 2006.
Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford, CA).
Infosys Consulting in 2011. (Burgelman & Schifrin, 2011. Stanford
Graduate School of Business, Stanford, CA).
Infosys: The Challenge of global Branding. (Saperstein, Murty, &
Desai, 2005. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Infosys Technologies: Powered by Intellect, Driven by Values.
(Velamuri & Mitchell, 2006. IESE Business School, Navarra, Spain).
Infosys Technologies. (Nanda & Delong, 2002. Harvard Business
School Publishing, Boston, MA).
3 Tata Tata Consultancy Services: Selling Certainty. (Ghemawat & Altman,
2011. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
NTT DOCOMO – Joint Venture with Tata in Indian Mobile Telecom.
(Chen & Chandrasekhar, 2010. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario,
Canada).
Tata Consultancy Services: Sustaining Growth Momentum in China
2010. (Geok, Gilbert & Buche, 2010. Nanyang Technological
University, Singapore).
Tata Consultancy Services: Globalization of Software Services.
(Roberts, Dheer, & Viard, 1995. Stanford Graduate School of
Business, Stanford, CA).
Tata Consultancy Services: Globalization of IT Services. (Roberts &
Mekikian, 2009. Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford, CA).
Tata Consultancy Services: A Systems Approach to Human Resource
Development. (Geok & Buche, 2012. Nanyang Technological
University, Singapore).
Tata Motors’ Acquisition of Daewoo Commercial Vehicle Company.
(Singh, Harish, & Singh, 2008. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario,
Canada).
Tata Motors’ Integration of Daewoo Commercial Vehicle Company.
(Singh, Harish, & Singh, 2008. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario,
Canada).
House of Tata: Acquiring a Global Footprint. (Khanna, Palepu, &
Bullock, 2009. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Tata Consultancy Services. (Deshpande & Schulman, 2009. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
! 321
Company Cases
House of Tata – 1995: The Next Generation (A). (Khanna, Palepu,
Conneely, & O’Neil-Massaro, 2006. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
House of Tata – 2000: The Next Generation (B). (Khanna, Palepu, &
Wu, 2006. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Tata Consultancy Services: High Technology in a Low-Income
Country. (Kennedy, 2001. Harvard Business School Publishing,
Boston, MA).
4 Haier Haier: Taking a Chinese Company Global. (Khanna, Palepu, &
Vargas, 2006. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Haier: Taking a Chinese Company Global in 2011. (Khanna, Palepu,
& Andrews, 2011. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Haier: Management Control on a Tactical Level. (Lau & Han, 2007.
Asia Case Research Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong
Kong).
Haier: How to Turn a Chinese Household Name into a Global Brand.
(Farhoomand, 2007. Asia Case Research Centre, The University of
Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
5 Samsung Samsung Electronics. (Siegel & Chang, 2009. Harvard Business
School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Maintaining the “Single Samsung” Spirit: New Challenges in a
Changing Environment. (Khilji, Oh, & Manikoth, 2011. Yvey
Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Design Strategy at Samsung Electronics: Becoming a Top-Tier
Company. (Freeze & Chung, 2008. Design Management Institute,
Boston, MA).
Samsung China: The Introduction of Color TV. (Choi, Beamish, &
Sharp, 2002. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung Electronics and LCD Technology (A). (Dhanaraj & Kim,
2004. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung Electronics and LCD Technology (B). (Dhanaraj & Kim,
2004. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung Electronics and LCD Technology (C). (Dhanaraj & Kim,
2005. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung Electronics (A): Entering India. (Chakraborty, Sharma, &
Ray, 2006. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung Electronics (B): In India. (Chakraborty, Sharma, & Ray,
2006. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Samsung International, Inc. (1986. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
Samsung Electronics Company: Global Marketing Operations.
(Quelch & Harrington, 2008. Harvard Business School Publishing,
Boston, MA).
6 Embraer Embraer: Shaking Up the Aircraft Manufacturing Market (Lopes,
Zimath, Maat, Silva, & Chen, 2007. Darden Business Publishing,
! 322
Company Cases
Charlettesville, VA).
Embraer: The Global Leader in Regional Jets. (Ghemawat, Herrero, &
Monteiro, 2009. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Bombardier Aerospace: The CSeries Dilemma (Taleb & Hebert, 2011.
Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
7 Petrobras Petrobras in Ecuador (A). (Musacchio, Goldberg, & De Pinho, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Petrobras in Ecuador (B). (Musacchio, Goldberg, & De Pinho, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Drilling South: Petrobras Evaluates Pecom. (Desai & De Pinho, 2004.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
8 Cemex CEMEX (A): Building the Global Framework (1985-2004). (Kanter,
Yatsko, & Raffaelli, 2009. Harvard Business School Publishing,
Boston, MA).
CEMEX (B): Cementing Relationships (2004-2007). (Kanter, Yatsko,
& Raffaelli, 2009. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
CEMEX’s Foundations for Sustainability. (Kanter, Yatsko, &
Raffaelli, 2009. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Cementing the Bottom of the Pyramid: A New Direction at CEMEX?
(Rodriguez, Monsegur, & Zagazeta, 2006. Darden Business
Publishing, Charlettesville, VA).
CEMEX in Mexico: Constructing the Path to Responsible
Competitiveness. (Serrano & Diaz-Saenz, 2006. SEKN – Social
Enterprise Knowledge Network, Harvard business School Publishing,
Boston, MA).
CEMEX: Transforming a Basic Industry Company. (Lee & Hoyt,
2005. Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford, CA).
CEMEX: Global Competition in a Local Business. (Podolny, Roberts,
Han, & Hodge, 2007. Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford,
CA).
CEMEX: Global Growth through Superior Information Capabilities.
(Chung, Paddack, & Marchand, 2003. International Institute for
Management Development, Lausanne, Switzerland).
The CEMEX Way: The Right Balance between Local Business
Flexibility and Global Standardization. (Chung, Marchand, &
Kettinger, 2005. International Institute for Management Development,
Lausanne, Switzerland).
The Globalization of CEMEX. (Ghemawat & Matthews, 2004. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
9 Tenaris Tenaris: Creating a Global Leader from an Emerging Market.
(Catalano & Roberts, 2004. Stanford Graduate School of Business,
Stanford, CA).
10 Concha Y Toro Concha y Toro. (Deshpande, Herrero, & Reficco, 2010. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
! 323
APPENDIX 3.2. Inventory of EMNE FSAs, home country LAs, host country CSAs, and internationalization
drivers
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Infosys Cheap skilled Engineering talent Entrepreneurial quality of Availability of Local responsiveness Market-seeking
India labour ‘Nearshoring’ management capital (nearshoring) Strategic resource-
locations: FSAs Innovation in the delivery Demand for Subscribing to norms seeking
in local of IT services services/ of good corporate
responsiveness Cost-effective global potential conduct in host
delivery model profitable sales countries
Management of Access to Long term
geographically dispersed knowledge re: relationships with
projects best clients (adopting
Strong brand management managerial practices)
Service quality practices
Data security
Intellectual property
protection
Culture of meritocracy
Tata Access to Local reputation Internal capabilities to Access to Synergistic blending Market seeking
Group foreign capital Brand strength manage/integrate M&As knowledge & of acquisitions into Strategic resource
India (requirement for Embeddedness in Entrepreneurial quality R&D existing businesses seeking
foreign MNEs to networks Umbrella operations to Access to Replicated business
tie up with a Government facilitate global business markets models in similar
domestic connections in a cohesive manner markets (global
company) while maintaining delivery model
Cheap skilled decentralization across emerging
labour Ability to adapt P&S to a markets)
Raw materials particular client group
security
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Haier Cost advantages Brand reputation Commitment to quality Access to Ability to capitalize Market seeking (fill
China Government Local (both products and after- technology on access to vacant niches e.g.
connections responsiveness sale service) Access to technology and compact computer in
DID NOT rely Knowledge of Entrepreneurial quality of powerful knowledge (‘observe, the USA)
extensively on local management (ability to distributors digest, imitate’; Strategic resource
local market/consumers identify and fulfill vacant licensing seeking
personnel/low (advantage over market niches) agreements)
cost as sources foreign MNEs) Market research Organization of
of competitive capabilities (translated overseas markets
advantage into product (overseas promotion
overseas (low modifications) division)
cost alone not Customer-centric business Established
seen as a Innovative organizational connections with
sustainable structure (ZZJYT – self- sought after
competitive managed teams) distributors (Wal-
advantage) Investment in logistics Mart) due to high
and distribution quality of products
Alliance formation
Local staffing
Local research =
responsiveness
! 325
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Cemex Access to Brand recognition Sophisticated managerial Access to Used learning from Market seeking
Mexico skilled/ educated Local distribution routines operations and Spanish companies Efficiency seeking
personnel network Technology (automated management to improve Strategic resource
Access to Expertise in sales, accounting, practices operations at home seeing
resources developing logistics; CEO’s Leveraged Synergistic
Fewer countries ‘technology fetish’ expertise integration of
institutional Employer of Sophisticated operating in acquired operations
pressure than in choice in Mexico methodology for developing Flexibility in
developed integrating acquisitions countries to set implementing the
markets (PMI – post merger up operations Cemex Way locally
integration) in Asia and the Right balance
Strong culture Middle East between local
Flexibility/local business flexibility
responsiveness and global
The Cemex Way – global standardization
business model of
standardized processes
and systems
Innovation (long history
of; nurturing)
Lenovo Access to Extensive sales Customization/quick Access to 20% increase in Market seeking
China technologies network response to market established marketing/promotion (maturation of local
developed by Government demands (value-added brand budget (leveraging market/increased
state R&D support development based on marketing strength) competition from
Knowledge about local requirements) Gradual transition direct sale retailers)
local market and from IBM to Lenovo
consumer needs brand
Strong brand
! 326
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Concha y Terroir– ideal Support of wine Reputation for ‘value for Demand Ability to adapt Market seeking:
Toro conditions for trade associations money’ brand strategy to Relatively small and
Chile wine making Ability to produce good local demands unsophisticated
quality wine Leveraged price domestic market
Sophisticated brand strategy to gain
strategy access to global
distribution
Embraer Access to highly Ties to the Technological Demand Ability to fill vacant Market seeking:
Brazil skilled government expertise/engineering Access to niches in foreign filling a niche in 70-
engineering (government’s prowess alliance markets to 120-seat market
talent (ITA) efforts to promote Entrepreneurial agility partners Responsiveness to Efficiency seeking:
aeronautics): Extensive global partner customer needs risk-sharing with
benefit of SOE network to outsource non- globally global network of
resources, core services Alliances to supplier-partners
funding, tax Customer streamline
advantages focus/responsiveness to operations, share risk
(before needs and gain access to
privatization) new markets
PROEX program
to help finance
exports
! 327
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Samsung Highly skilled Government Brand value/reputation Access to Early alliance Strategic resource
Korea human resources support (as part of Technology (licensed; market formation to develop seeking: team of
(National HR economic developed/invested in) Access to new technology Korean Americans
development; development Customization ability knowledge/ Responsiveness to with experience in
long term efforts) Innovative HR practices industry customer needs semiconductor
investment in Geographic Commitment to experience globally industry n California,
people) proximity of innovation Access to top Leveraged home top talent around the
Economic design and Reputation for design talent around reputation to become world
growth production Knowledge culture the world one of the most Market seeking
One of the most (facilitated ‘Single Samsung’ Access to recognized brands (demand for AC in
technologically interaction/ initiative cheap labour globally (global India due to
advanced enhanced user- Flexible manufacturing (increasing brand strategy) expanding middle
countries in the trend research) processes/advanced labour cost in Design research to class/higher
world Distribution manufacturing techniques Korea – understand local disposable incomes;
Culture of hard network (India) political needs increased
work reforms Used manufacturing competition in
abandoning flexibility to domestic market)
regulated establish global
wages) manufacturing
network/take
advantage of cheap
labour
! 328
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Petrobras Natural Partial Access to cheap capital Promising Processed excess of Natural resource
Brazil resources government Modernized governance exploration heavy crude oil seeking (promising
Access to heavy ownership/ model/managerial areas abroad exploration areas in
crude oil support; access to decision making process, Natural gas Gained access to Latin America)
Access to some senior decision flexible/responsive Processing natural gas Market seeking: in
of the largest makers in management structure capacity for Built a position in response to
pre-salt deposits government (stood out against SOE oil heavy crude energy market in privatization/opening
of light crude oil Dominant companies in Latin oil South America of country to foreign
in the world position in both America) Local management in ownership
upstream and host countries to Efficiency seeking:
downstream navigate diversification to
activities at home politics/secure access reduce risk
to public policy Strategic resource
decision makers seeking: help from
international oil
companies to handle
technical challenges
(high levels of
carbon dioxide in
offshore discoveries)
! 329
EMNE Nature of LAs LB FSAs NLB FSAs Host CSAs Recombination Internationalization
ability drivers
Tenaris Ample supply of Reputation for Direct global distribution Demand for Experience in Market seeking: lack
Argentina people to work quality network (Techint products, multicultural of domestic growth
in Strong industry Commercial Network) access to long relations through prospects, increased
manufacturing standing allowed European engineering term alliances international
to attract the most traditions/common customers Alliance to competition at home
qualified engineering language Access to coordinate export due to opening of
Argentine across cultures skills and sales globally/ market to imports
graduates Quality commitment expertise allocate production Efficiency seeking:
Customer responsiveness among mills procurement for steel
Adversity advantage pipe and other steel
(history of building plants businesses
in difficult environments)
JIT allowed to supply
customers with
comprehensive pipe
management services on a
continuous basis
Long term/on-going
customer relationships
Technology (investment
in R&D)
! 330
APPENDIX 4.1. Corporate backgrounds: Du Pont and General Motors
Du Pont was founded in 1802 by Eleuthere Irenee du Pont, who left France in
1800 to escape the French Revolution. The company was started at the Eleutherian Mills,
Army by the middle of the 19th century. In the early 1900s, Du Pont continued to expand,
moving into the production of dynamite and smokeless powder. Du Pont’s President,
Eugene du Pont, died in 1902, at which point the company was sold to the three great-
grandsons of the original founder: Alfred Du Pont, T.T. Coleman Du Pont and Pierre S.
Du Pont. Pierre handled finance; Alfred ran the black powder operations, and Coleman
became President, and remained in this position until Pierre bought Coleman’s shares of
In the decades leading up to the Second World War, Du Pont acquired ownership
in automotive, cellophane, and rayon segments, and introduced new technologies to the
market. Throughout the Second World War, Du Pont became a major producer of war
supplies, and played a major role in the Manhattan Project in 1943. After the war, the
the success of the Apollo Space program and to the development of modern body armour
(Datamonitor, 2012).
! 331
biosciences, nutrition & health, performance chemicals, performance materials, safety &
Reuters, 2013).
Oldsmobile, Cadillac, Elmore, Oakland and several other companies. In 1910, Durant
lost control of GM to a bankers’ trust due to the large amount of debt taken on to finance
the acquisitions (Deebe, 1996), but gained back control of the company after starting
Chevrolet Motor Car Company in 1911 and secretly purchasing a controlling interest in
GM (www.gm.com).
In 1914, Pierre Du Pont invested in GM’s stock, and the following year joined
GM’s board of directors, of which he was eventually appointed Chairman. The Du Pont
company assisted the struggling automobile firm with a further stock purchase. Shortly
thereafter, Durant again lost control of GM after the new vehicle market collapsed, and
Pierre Du Pont was elected President. Under his guidance, GM became the number one
automobile company in the world. After Pierre’s retirement, Alfred P. Sloan took charge
of the corporation and led it to its post-war global dominance. The company’s great
financial success of the 1920s was expunged by the Great Depression of the 1930s.
During World War II, GM was transformed into a prominent supplier of war materials,
providing $12.3 billion worth of defence product between 1940 and 1945 (Deebe, 1996).
In 1957, the Du Pont corporation was forced to divest itself of its GM shares
under Clayton Antitrust Act action. Still, the 1950s was marked by record sales and
! 332
innovations in styling and engineering. GM’s unprecedented growth lasted into the early
1980’s, when it employed 349,000 workers and operated 150 assembly plants around the
world. At that point, the company started losing market share to its successful offshore
competitors. In 2009, the global economic recession significantly reduced vehicle sales,
leaving GM critically short of operating income. The company was granted bankruptcy
This restructuring led to an initial public offering and the emergence of today’s GM – a
! 333
APPENDIX 8.1. Cases analyzed on the twelve MNEs involved in
sustainability crises
Company Cases
1 Enron The Enron Collapse. (Hamilton & Francis, 2004. International Institute
for Management Development, Lausanne, Switzerland).
The Fall of Enron. (Healy and Palepu, 2012. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
Innovation Corrupted: The Rise and Fall of Enron (A). (Salter,
Levesque, & Ciampa, 2005. Harvard Business School Publishing,
Boston, MA).
Consulting by Auditor (C): Aftermath of the Enron Collapse. (Nanda &
Prusiner, 2006. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
What Happened at Enron? (Moffett, 2004. The Garvin School of
International Management, Glendale, Arizona).
Broken Trust: Role of Professionals in the Enron Debacle. (Nanda,
2003. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
2 WorldCom Cynthia Cooper and WorldCom (A). (Werhane & Mead, 2009. Darden
Business Publishing, Charlettesville, VA).
Accounting Fraud at WorldCom. (Kaplan & Kiron, 2007. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
WorldCom Inc.: What Went Wrong? (Gollakota & Gupta, 2005. Yvey
Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Restoring Trust and WorldCom. (Lorsch & Robertson, 2004. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
3 Goldman Sachs Goldman Sachs and Its Reputation. (Baron, 2011. Harvard Business
School Publishing, Boston, MA).
SEC versus Goldman Sachs (A). (Li & Green, 2010. Darden Business
Publishing, Charlettesville, VA).
Goldman Sachs: A Bank for All Seasons (A). (Goldberg & Obenchain,
2010. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Goldman Sachs: A Bank for All Seasons (B). (Goldberg & Obenchain,
2010. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Goldman Sachs: A Bank for All Seasons (C). (Goldberg & Obenchain,
2010. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Internal Governance and Control at Goldman Sachs: Block Trading.
(Salter & Sarkar, 2004. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston,
MA).
4 Adelphia Adelphia Communications Corp.’s Bankruptcy. (Gilson, Villalonga &
Hartman, 2010. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
The Lessons of Adelphia’s Cash Fraud. (Johnson & Rudolph, 2007.
Wiley InterScience, New York, NY).
Restoring Trust in Auditing: Ethical Discernment and the Adelphia
Scandal. (Barlaup, Dronen, & Iris, 2009. Managerial Auditing Journal,
Emerald, Bingley, West Yorkshire, UK).
! 334
Company Cases
5 Ford/Firestone After Job 1: Actions and Reactions in the Ford/Firestone Recall (A).
(Sullivan, Lelyveld, & Geary, 2005. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
The Firestone/Ford Tire Controversy (A). (Narayanan & Nieves, 2001.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
The Firestone/Ford Tire Controversy (B). (Narayanan & Nieves, 2001.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
6 Mattel Mattel’s Strategy after Its Recall of Products Made in China.
(Jiangyong, Zhigang, Linhui, & Loo, 2009. Asia Case Research
Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
Mattel’s China Experience: A Crisis in Toyland. (Teagarden, 2008.
Thunderbird School of Global Management, Glendale, AZ).
Unsafe for Children: Mattel’s Toy Recalls and Supply Chain
Management. (Lee & Hoyt, 2008. Stanford Graduate School of
Business, Stanford, CA).
Mattel: Crisis Management or Management Crisis. (Baron, 2008.
Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford, CA).
Mattel’s Long Hot Summer. (Wei-Skillern, Marciano, & Passy, 2008.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Mattel Toys – Made in China (A). (Jackson & Xiubao, 2008. Asia Case
Research Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
Mattel Toys – Made in China (B). (Jackson & Xiubao, 2008. Asia Case
Research Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
Mattel Toys – Made in China (C). (Jackson & Xiubao, 2008. Asia Case
Research Centre, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong).
Mattel and the Toy Recalls (A) (Bapuji & Beamish, 2008. Yvey
Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Mattel and the Toy Recalls (B) (Bapuji & Beamish, 2008. Yvey
Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Mattel Toys (A): The Financial Realignment. (Moffett, 2008.
Thunderbird School of Global Management, Glendale, AZ).
7 Merck Merck: Managing Vioxx (A). (Simons, Rosenberg, & Kindred, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (B). (Simons, Rosenberg, & Kindred, 2010.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (C). (Simons, Rosenberg, & Kindred, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (D). (Simons, Rosenberg, & Kindred, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (E). (Simons, Rosenberg, & Kindred, 2009.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (F). (Simons & Kindred, 2010. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Merck: Managing Vioxx (G). (Simons & Kindred, 2009. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
! 335
Company Cases
Vioxx: Too Risky for Merck? (Petersen & Singhal, 2007. Kellogg
School of Management, Chicago, IL).
8 BP BP and the Gulf of Mexico Oil Spill. (Roberto, 2011. Yvey Publishing,
London, Ontario, Canada).
Accounting for Catastrophes: BP PLC and Union Carbide
Corporation (B). (Hawkins & Sesia, 2011. Harvard Business School
Publishing, Boston, MA).
BP: Beyond Petroleum. (Yemen, Lenox, & Harris, 2011. Darden
Business Publishing, Charlettesville, VA).
Drilling Safety at BP: The Deepwater Horizon Accident. (Kaufman &
Wing, 2012. Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
BP’s Macondo: spill and Response. (Rotemberg, 2012. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
9 DaimlerChrysler Crafting a Vision at Daimler-Chrysler. (Golden & Nolan, 2002. Yvey
Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
Daimler-Benz A.G.: Negotiations between Daimler and Chrysler.
(Bruner, Christmann, Spekman, Kannry, & Davies, 1998. Darden
Business Publishing, Charlettesville, VA).
Daimler-Chrysler: The Post-Merger Integration Phase. (Morosini &
Radler, 2003. International Institute for Management Development,
Lausanne, Switzerland).
Daimler-Chrysler: Post-Merger News. (Airey, Gepp, Harris, &
Menard, 2003. Yvey Publishing, London, Ontario, Canada).
10 HP Unauthorized Disclosure: Hewlett-Packard’s Secret Surveillance of
Directors and Journalists. (Lawrence, Harris, & Baack, 2008. Case
Research Journal, Keystone, CO).
Hewlett-Packard (A) (Deshpande & Schulman, 2006. Yvey Publishing,
London, Ontario, Canada).
Hewlett-Packard (B) (Deshpande & Schulman, 2011. Yvey Publishing,
London, Ontario, Canada).
11 Chiquita Blood Bananas: Chiquita in Colombia. (Schotter & Teagarden, 2010.
Thunderbird School of Global Management, Glendale, AZ).
Chiquita in Colombia. (Mead, Wicks, & White, 2010. Darden Business
Publishing, Charlottesville, VA).
Chiquita Brands International (A). (Spar & Mulligan, 2007. Harvard
Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
Chiquita Brands International (B). (Spar & Huntsberger, 2001.
Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA).
12 Talisman Talisman: An Unexpected War? (Verbeke, 2009. Cambridge
University Press, New York, NY).
Business Ethics and Development in Conflict (Zones): The Case of
Talisman Oil. (Idahosa, 2002. Journal of Business Ethics, 39: 227-246,
Springer, NY.).
Talisman Energy, Sudan, and Corporate Social Responsibility.
! 336
Company Cases
(Carmody, 2000. The Canadian Yearbook of International Law, 38:
237, UBC Press, Vancouver, Canada).
Oil and Politics: Talisman Energy and Sudan. (Kobrin, 2004.
International Law and Politics, 36: 425, NYU Law, NY.)
! 337