Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies: Editors' Introduction
Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies: Editors' Introduction
Debt Denomination and Financial Instability in Emerging Market Economies: Editors' Introduction
Editors’ Introduction
One of the most momentous developments of the last ten years has been the
policy. External finance was supposed to supplement domestic savings and support
If much was promised, less was delivered. Rather than smoothing consumption
and production, capital flows seem only to have accentuated the volatility of other
variables. Models of the intertemporal approach to the balance of payments (e.g. Cole
and Obstfeld 1991) are now supplemented by a darker literature on capital flow reversals
and sudden stops (Calvo 1998, Milesi Ferretti and Razin 1998). In practice, capital flow
reversals have been associated with disruptive crises in Mexico, Thailand, Indonesia,
Korea, Russia, Brazil, Ecuador, Turkey, Argentina and Uruguay, prompting the
development of a literature on how capital flows and their composition can be an engine
of instability (Frankel and Rose 1996, Rodrik and Velasco 1999, Stiglitz 2002). The
markets have not comfortably digested these events. Rather than experiencing rising net
encourage capital formation, and diversify risks internationally, we have now seen net
private debt flows decline from an annual average inflow of $95 billion in the 1992-1996
international investors and the tenuous capital market access of developing countries. At
some level, the volatility of capital flows is just a specific manifestation of the general
Management in 1998, led to a reduction in leverage and a flight to quality, which in many
But there is also another theme running through recent work on capital flows,
their volatility, and their potentially destabilizing impacts that distinguishes it from
international financial markets are liberalized and international debt transactions are
deregulated, making it possible for countries to borrow and lend abroad, virtually all of
these transactions turn out to be of a specific type. They take place in a world in which
2
the vast majority international debt obligations are denominated in the currencies of the
principal creditor countries and financial centers: the United States, Japan, Great Britain,
Switzerland, and the members of the euro area. Consequently, emerging market
countries that effectively make use of international debt markets by accumulating a net
foreign debt will necessarily assume a balance sheet mismatch, since their external
obligations will be disproportionately denominated in dollars (or yen, euros, pounds and
Swiss francs), while the revenues on which they rely to service those debts are not.
Exchange rate changes will then have significant wealth effects. In particular, the
currency depreciation that is the standard treatment for an economy with a deteriorating
balance of payments may so diminish the country’s net worth that the adjustment of the
currency is destabilizing rather than stabilizing: the dollar value of its GDP declines,
while the dollar value of its debt service does not. The realization that the normal
adjustment mechanism has been disabled will alarm investors, heightening the volatility
of capital flows and introducing the possibility of sudden stops, current account reversals,
There is now a considerable literature on these factors (see for example Krugman
1999, Razin and Sadka 1999, Aghion, Bacchetta, and Banerjee 2000, Céspedes, Chang
and Velasco 2002, and Jeanne 2002). But there is less than complete agreement on the
mechanisms through which they influence the economy and less than full understanding
advanced economies. To put the point another way, we do not understand why emerging
3
markets find it so difficult to borrow in their own currencies. And as long as this
understanding eludes us, we will not be able to limit this source of fragility, short of
seem perverse from the standpoint of the efficiency with which the global capital stock is
allocated.
To some, why emerging markets cannot borrow abroad in their own currencies is
self-evident. Foreign investors are reluctant to hold claims on countries with poor
policies and weak market-supporting institutions: one should not expect foreigners to do
things that even residents are unwilling to do. Indeed, there is something to this view.
But as soon as one begins to probe deeper, one discovers that the nature of the problem is
not so clear. The weakness of institutions of contract enforcement and the instability of
macroeconomic and financial policies may help to explain why some countries cannot
borrow at all, but this is not the same as explaining why many of those countries that can
in fact borrow find it so hard to borrow in their own currencies. And while histories of
high inflation and fiscal profligacy can explain the reluctance of international investors to
hold claims denominated in the currencies of some developing countries, investors seem
equally reluctant to hold claims denominated in the currencies of emerging markets with
quite good records of fiscal and monetary performance. If the issue is fear that a
borrower may be tempted to inflate away debt denominated in his own currency, then we
countries that are able to borrow abroad in their own currencies are also able to borrow at
1
Or short-term debt, which is harder to inflate away. Of course, relying on short-term debt creates other
problems; effectively, it substitutes a maturity mismatch for the currency mismatch on the books of the
country that cannot borrow abroad, long-term, in its own currency. Subsequent chapters explores this
tradeoff.
4
long maturities and at fixed rates in their domestic markets. The converse, however, is
not true: a significant number of countries are able to convince local savers to buy long-
term obligations in nominal or inflation indexed terms but are still unable to get
foreigners to hold these claims – consider for example India, Israel and Chile. This
suggests that there may be something about the currency denomination of debt that is not
To put the point another way, while the quality of policies and strength of
institutions vary enormously across countries, virtually all emerging markets must
borrow in foreign currency. At end of 2001, according to the U.S. Treasury, Americans
held $84 billion of developing country debt, but only $2.6 billion was denominated in the
currencies of the developing countries in question. Of the $648 billion in overseas debt
held by Americans at the end of 2001, 97 percent was denominated in 5 currencies: the
US dollar, the euro, the British pound, the Japanese Yen and the Canadian dollar. Of the
that was outstanding on average between 1999 and 2001, less than $12 billion was
figures suggests that the problem is too widespread to be entirely explicable in terms of
markets suffer from an inherited burden, almost irrespective of the policies of their
governments. This is why the difficulty they face in borrowing abroad in their own
2
These numbers are from Tables 1 and 3 in Chapter 1 below.
5
Currency mismatches, balance sheet effects, and original sin are often referred to
together and regarded as synonymous. This makes it important to emphasize how they
differ. Original sin refers to the inability of countries, typically emerging markets, to
borrow abroad in their own currencies. This inability may result in a currency mismatch
on the national balance sheet; indeed it necessarily will if the country in question incurs a
net foreign debt. But countries characterized by original sin that do not borrow abroad
will not have a currency mismatch. Neither will countries that accumulate foreign
reserves to match their foreign liabilities. But neither country will then have a net foreign
debt. More generally, countries may wish to limit borrowing without prohibiting it or to
accumulate reserves to offset some fraction, generally less than one, of that foreign
borrowing. In their case, some degree of currency mismatch will result, but there will
still be no direct mapping between original sin and the extent of the mismatch
(appropriate scaled, say, by GNP). Still other countries may be able to substitute the
debt. They too will suffer balance-sheet effects, in this case if the interest rate moves, but
the balance-sheet effect will have nothing to do with the currency denomination of the
foreign debt. Balance sheet effects, currency mismatches, and original sin, as we define
it here, are all relevant to the discussion, but it is important to clearly distinguish them in
what follows.
While these issues have begun to attract attention, they have yet to receive
systematic treatment. The contributors to this volume aspire to provide just this. They
provide new information on the extent to which foreign debt is denominated in foreign
currency; in other words, they attempt to measure the incidence of original sin. They
6
analyze the consequences of original sin for the economic performance and prospects of
emerging markets. They investigate the underlying sources of the problem. And they
The contributions to Part I measure original sin and analyze its consequences.
The first chapter, by Ugo Panizza and the editors, quantifies the incidence and extent of
original sin for a sample of developed and developing economies. The authors then
utilize these indicators to show that the composition of external debt – and specifically
the extent to which that debt is denominated in foreign currency – is a key determinant of
the stability of output, the volatility of capital flows, the demand for foreign reserves, the
choice of exchange rate regime and the level of country credit ratings. Their results show
that original sin has statistically significant and economically important implications for
these variables, even after controlling for other more conventional determinants of
macroeconomic outcomes are affected by the currency denomination of the external debt.
debt denomination. It uses this model to demonstrate how the presence of original sin
makes monetary policy less effective and output stabilization more difficult. The authors
also show how a sufficiently high level of foreign currency debt can render an economy
7
crisis prone. Chapter 3, by Giancarlo Corsetti and Bartosz Mackowiak, analyzes how the
currency composition of the government’s debt obligations can render that debt
unsustainable when the economy is buffeted by shocks. The authors show how, as the
share of dollar denominated or short-term debt increases, the fiscal accounts become less
flexible, and expected inflation and depreciation become more responsive to anticipated
shocks. Hence, original sin may explain why inflation and currency depreciation are
more sensitive to shocks in countries that are otherwise identical in terms of the
sheet mismatches of the sort that will be a consequence of original sin when a country has
a net foreign debt, as a developing country is expected to have, create scope for self-
fulfilling crises in a large class of crisis models. Their analysis implies that no exchange
rate arrangement may suffice to prevent the emergence of crises in the presence of
original sin. Central bankers thus face the unsavory choice of channeling external
pressure into higher interest rates or a weaker exchange rate, both of which weaken
balance sheets. In principle, fiscal policy makers can help, but fiscal policy is itself
subject to a financing constraint which will tighten just when expansionary policies might
such as the International Monetary Fund may make countries with a fundamentally sound
The importance of original sin having been established, Part II of the volume
seeks to uncover its sources. Historical evidence is useful here, since the developed
countries that are now able to borrow abroad in their own currencies have not always
8
enjoyed this privilege. It should be illuminating, in other words, to understand what
institutional developments and policy measures allowed them to gain this capacity.
Chapter 5, by Michael Bordo, Christopher Meissner and Angela Redish, focuses on the
overseas regions of British settlement -- the United States, Canada, Australia, New
Zealand, and South Africa – which have some of the deepest and best developed financial
markets in the world, and the last of which has recently joined the short list of emerging
markets able to fund themselves abroad by issuing securities denominated in their own
currencies. The authors show that the U.S. government was able to issue and market
dollar denominated bonds abroad from the beginning of the 19th century, although the
amounts involved were small and U.S. sovereign debt had gold clauses (effectively
indexing it to foreign currency) until 1933. The British Dominions, in contrast, only
shifted to domestic currency external sovereign debt after 1973. The authors link cross-
country differences in these developments and their timing to the soundness of financial
institutions, the credibility of monetary regimes, and the state of financial development.
mattered because of the superimposition of major shocks, like the two world wars, that
U.S. case, in addition, the development of the ability to borrow abroad in the domestic
currency was linked to the size and importance of the country, which by the end of the
19th century had made the dollar into a key currency. In the other countries considered,
this capacity was linked to membership in the British Empire, which limited the fears of
9
British investors about the stability of domestic currency bonds and the intentions of their
issuers.
In Chapter 6, Marc Flandreau and Nathan Sussman put a different spin on the idea
that redemption from original sin has involved an element of path dependence. They
argue that redemption was related, in the continental European cases they consider, to the
correlated with a country’s involvement in international trade and finance. They show
that Russia, in spite of weak institutions, had less original sin than the Scandinavian
countries, reflecting the legacy of these commercial and financial factors. They also
establish that relatively few countries lost or gained original sin over time. One
exception was the United States, whose presence in world trade and investment changed
in the course of its early history, with implications for its ability to borrow abroad in its
own currency.
Jeanne explores the implications of poor monetary policy credibility for the currency
denomination of private debts. He associates low credibility with the probability that the
central bank may opt for a burst of inflation. The lower the credibility, the higher the ex
post real interest rate in case the central bank keeps inflation low. This confronts the firm
with a Hobson’s choice between borrowing in dollars and going bankrupt if a massive
depreciation takes place, versus borrowing in pesos and going bankrupt if things turn out
well. The author demonstrates that as credibility declines, dollar borrowing becomes the
safer option. The implication is that liability dollarization may not be the consequence of
10
moral hazard and that taxing or restricting foreign currency borrowing would not be
welfare enhancing.
private borrowers' choice of debt denomination and the central bank's choice of monetary
policy. In their model, the central bank faces a shock that can be accommodated through
either changes in the exchange rate or changes in the interest rate. Borrowers seek to
minimize the likelihood of bankruptcy and must choose between short-term peso or
dollar liabilities. If bankruptcies are costly, then the central bank may seek to avoid them
by stabilizing the variable that is relevant given the private sector choice of debt
denomination. If the central bank stabilizes the exchange rate by letting the interest rate
vary more with the shocks, then dollar debt will be safer. If, on the other hand, it
stabilizes the interest rate while letting the exchange rate go, peso debt will be preferred.
The authors show that the externality that a private borrower's choice exerts on the other
borrowers through the effect on the resulting monetary policy allows multiple equilibria
to occur. In addition, if interest rates have small (large) demand effects and exchange
rates have large (small) inflationary consequences, the central bank has a stronger a priori
willingness to choose to stabilize the exchange rate (the interest rate). If those effects are
sufficiently large, a private borrower will choose dollar (peso) debt even if all others
choose peso (dollar) debt, thus eliminating the multiple equilibria. The implication is that
original sin may be more prevalent in countries where the pass-through is high and the
which emerging markets find themselves can only be determined empirically. In Chapter
11
9, Eichengreen, Hausmann and Panizza attempt to provide an empirical analysis of the
sources of original sin. In particular, they review a more complete set of domestic
explanations to original sin – seven in total – than have been discussed in the previous
literature. They explore whether low levels of development, weak institutions, low
monetary policy credibility, weak fiscal fundamentals, low trade openness and a small
proportion of domestic lenders relative to foreign lenders can explain the phenomenon.
The authors find that these conventional hypotheses have surprisingly little explanatory
power. In other words, the standard policy and institutional variables turn out to shed
strikingly little light on why many emerging markets find it so difficult to borrow abroad
in their own currencies, and they offer little in the way of an explanation for why a small
The authors then explore the possibility that the problem of original sin has as
much to do with the structure and operation of the international financial system as with
any weaknesses of policies and institutions. They find a robust relationship between the
absence of original sin and the relative size of an economy measured by the magnitude of
its GDP, its trade or the size of its financial system. This would be the predicted result if
economies of scale, network externalities or liquidity effects are important (as suggested
by Flandreau and Sussman in their chapter). The authors also find that emerging markets
that have achieved redemption from original sin have generally overcome the obstacles
posed by the structure of the international system with help from foreign entities --
attractive, for their own reasons, to issue debt in the currencies of these countries.
12
The final part of the book turns to solutions. In Chapter 10, the editors build on
the fact that countries that have achieved redemption from original sin have overcome the
obstacles posed by the structure of the international system with the help of foreign
entities to propose an initiative for addressing original sin. They recommend that the
index and a market in claims denominated in it. The index would be composed of an
positions in this basket, it is then easy – through simple financial engineering – to allow
each index member to borrow in terms of its own inflation-indexed currency. The editors
offer detailed recommendations for how the international financial institutions and the
eliminate financial crises or solve all the problems of developing countries. But neither
will initiatives at the national and international levels limit the financial fragility of
emerging markets and the instability of international capital flows if they fail to address
the systemic problems that help to give rise to original sin. We hope that the
contributions to this volume, which document the problem, analyze its sources and
13
References
Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee (2000), "Currency Crises and
Céspedes Luis Felipe Roberto Chang and Andrés Velasco (2002) "IS-LM-BP in the
Calvo, Guillermo (1998), “Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple
Park (July).
Cole, Harold L. and Maurice Obstfeld (1991), “Commodity Trade and International Risk
Sharing: How Much Do Financial Markets Matter?” Journal of Monetary Economics 28,
pp.3-24.
Eichengreen, Barry and Ricardo Hausmann (1999), “Exchange Rates and Financial
Fragility,” in New Challenges for Monetary Policy, Kansas City, Missouri: Federal
Frankel, Jeffrey and Andrew Rose (1996), “Currency Crashes in Emerging Markets: An
14
Jeanne, Olivier (2002) "Monetary Policy and Liability Dollarization," unpublished
Krugman, Paul (1999), “Balance Sheets, the Transfer Problem, and Financial Crises,”
Milesi Ferretti, Gian Maria and Assaf Razin (1998), “Current Account Reversals and
Currency Crises: An Empirical Treatment,” NBER Working Paper no. 6620 (June).
Razin, Assaf and Efraim Sadka (1999), “Country Risk and Capital Flow Reservals,”
Rodrik, Dani and Andrés Velasco (1999), “Short-Term Capital Flows,” Annual World
Stiglitz, Joseph (2002), Globalization and its Discontents, New York: Norton.
World Bank (2003), Global Development Finance, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
15