Investing in Ideas Business Innovation Policies
Investing in Ideas Business Innovation Policies
Investing in Ideas Business Innovation Policies
Since the pioneering work of Solow (1957), technological change has been credited with
explaining a substantial share of economic growth. Indeed, recent evidence for the United States
shows that investments in research and development (R&D)—a proxy for the innovation effort
of a nation—made up 40 percent of the productivity growth observed during the postwar era
(Reikard, 2011). Based on these findings, several Latin American and Caribbean countries have
established and implemented public policies aimed at enhancing innovation. In practice, the first
explicit interventions to encourage innovation by the private sector emerged even earlier, toward
the end of World War II. Although many of these policies were either abandoned or dramatically
downsized under the structural reforms inspired by the Washington Consensus, the disappointing
results in terms of productivity growth have led several countries in the region to reintroduce
Since the early 1990s, a new generation of public programs to encourage business
innovation has spread throughout the region. Policy experimentation is already generating new
evidence about the effectiveness of these interventions. This chapter assesses the main
person may have a very different understanding of how novel a device or a process is. For this
innovation process. Griliches (1979) suggests that similar to the production of goods, the
results from firm investments in R&D and the stock of knowledge. More recent innovation
research has expanded the set of inputs to include human capital, training, machinery, licenses,
software, and the like. Thus, it is possible to garner a glimpse of innovation by measuring some
of those inputs. On the outputs side, approximations for innovation outcomes include
productivity indexes, numbers of intellectual property rights, scientific publications, and self-
reported figures of innovations collected from innovation surveys (Smith, 2006). Each one of
these indicators by itself provides a partial view of the innovation process; however, together
Figure 3.1 assesses the performance of Latin America and the Caribbean vis-à-vis
developed countries with regard to innovation inputs. Panel (a) summarizes aggregate R&D
intensities for a sample of Latin American and Caribbean countries and compares them with a
sample of developed countries. This panel highlights several issues. First, R&D intensities in
Latin America and the Caribbean are systematically lower than in developed countries. Second,
according to this indicator, the world’s top performers are precisely those countries that have
managed to catch up with other developed countries over the last 20 or 30 years: Israel (4.3
percent), Finland (3.9 percent), and South Korea (3.7 percent). Third, in top-performing
countries, the private sector finances a large proportion of the R&D effort. While in developed
countries firms explain more than 60 percent of the national investment in R&D, this figure is
less than 35 percent in Latin America and the Caribbean. These findings suggest an important
including not only R&D but also training, purchasing of machinery and equipment, software
licenses and royalties for the use of patented technology for a sample of countries using
information from innovation surveys. Even within this broader definition of innovation
investment, a significant gap exists. While the average firm in a developed country spends
almost 4 percent of sales on innovation, the typical firm in Latin America and the Caribbean
spends around 2.5 percent. The gap is particularly large in intangible investments such as R&D.
The pattern that emerges is that technology embodied in machinery, mostly imported from
abroad, is the main force of innovation investment in the region. The evidence from developed
countries suggests that relying on imported technology is not necessarily bad if it leads to
domestic learning. However, in order for this to happen, technology must be combined with
absorptive capacities that allow for further improvements. Absorptive capacities depend on
research and development efforts and complementary human capital. According to panel (c),
there are on average only 1.1 researchers per 1000 workers in the region, eight times fewer than
in the typical OECD country—even though the average number of researchers in the region
Glance]
In summary, the Latin American and Caribbean innovation process is based on the
adoption and incremental improvement of existing technologies, rather than investment in R&D.
Has this pattern allowed the region to catch up to the rest of the world in terms of productivity?
The results in panel (d), which shows average productivity growth rates for each county from
1960 to 2010, suggest otherwise. In fact, long-term productivity growth rates in Latin American
and Caribbean countries are systematically lower than those in the OECD. Moreover, having a
productivity growth higher than the United States—depicted by the vertical line in panel (d)—is
Innovation is the result in large part of investment decisions made by firms; these
decisions are affected by the same conditions that affect investment in general. Indeed, the
quality of regulation, protection of property rights, tax code, macroeconomic regime, the
innovation—sometimes even more significantly than for fixed capital investments (OECD,
2013a). However, having the right framework conditions is a necessary but not sufficient
condition for innovation. Since most countries in the region have internalized the importance of
these conditions and made important progress with them, the focus of this chapter is on explicit
Although it is generally true that every modern economy needs an innovation policy, a
flaw in the design of innovation policy tends to be its focus on symptoms rather than on the
basis of gaps in R&D or technology adoption when compared with benchmark economies. This
focus on symptoms rather than constraints normally leads to poor policy design: low investment
in innovation or low levels of technology adoption could also be an optimum response to low
returns. In other cases, government justifies innovation policy based on socially desirable
objectives, such as job creation or social inclusion, without realizing that the relationship
Theory-based Justifications
The fundamental premise for innovation policies is that government intervention can be
2010). Broadly speaking, the rationale for public policy in this field can be based on the
following considerations:
Spillovers and the “Public Good” Nature of Knowledge
Since the seminal works by Nelson (1959) and Arrow (1962), knowledge has been
regarded as a nonrival 2 and nonexcludable 3 good. If knowledge does indeed have these
properties, then a firm’s rivals may be able to free-ride on its investments. These spillovers may
create a wedge between private and social returns and a disincentive against private investment
in knowledge production. However, spillovers are not automatic and should not be taken for
granted in every circumstance, as not all knowledge enjoys the properties of a public good with
the same intensity. Certainly, the “public good” rationale of knowledge applies more strongly to
generic or scientific knowledge than technological knowledge, which is more applicable and
specific to the firm. 4 Furthermore, in order for the public good rationale to be valid, there should
be some possibility of free-riding. If the originator can protect the results of the knowledge
generated (through entry barriers or the use of strategic mechanisms, for example), then the
potential for market failure declines. On the other hand, knowledge generated through
collaboration among different parties might be more difficult to protect and therefore more prone
(Hall and Lerner, 2010). First, the returns to innovation investments are more uncertain and
involve longer gestation lags. Second, innovators may be reluctant to disclose detailed
information about their projects because of spillovers. Third, innovation investments normally
include a large proportion of intangible assets (such as human capital) that have very limited use
as collateral. Although the problem of asymmetric information is always present whenever the
investor and financier are different entities, this problem may be worse in the case of knowledge
investments. This creates a wedge between the rate of return required by an innovator investing
his or her own funds and that required by external investors. Unless the innovator is particularly
wealthy, privately (and maybe socially) profitable innovation projects may not materialize due to
There may also be asymmetric information with respect to the knowledge about available
technologies. The most traditional diffusion model—in which technology adoption results from
the spread of information about the technology—highlights the fact that diffusion is not
monitoring exercises, and extension services that inform an industry of recent technology
advances.
Knowledge also has important tacit components that cannot be embodied in a set of
artifacts, such as machines, manuals, or blueprints. Thus, firms can benefit from networking with
one another and other actors because they need to learn from the knowledge bases of other
organizations. However, coordination failures can hinder the effectiveness of these knowledge
networks. Coordination failures emerge whenever private and public agents fail to coordinate
their knowledge investment plans in order to create mutual positive externalities (Aghion, David,
and Foray, 2009). Coordination failures also emerge in the process of accessing technological
infrastructure. Firms that alone cannot afford infrastructure can gain access to it if they
collaborate with others. Solving coordination problems requires paying special attention to those
institutional failures that can affect the linkages between the different actors in the innovation
system.
It is argued that one of the few advantages of a developing country is that it can simply
free-ride on the innovation investments of developed countries. As is clear from the preceding
discussion, the real world is far more complex than this. The returns of a given technology
depend on the context in which it is used. Key complementary inputs, such as human capital,
institutions, and natural resources, may vary greatly across different locations and affect the
performance of the same technology in different places. In order to successfully adopt a given
technology, firms must discover whether this technology is suitable for each particular context.
For that, local investment in learning and innovation is needed. These investments are affected
by the same problems of spillovers, asymmetric information, and coordination that affect
market failures coexist and feedback into each other. So, unfortunately for developing countries,
The evidence so far suggests that Latin America and the Caribbean seriously under-
invests in innovation. However, this statement lumps together countries that are very different.
The observation that an investment gap in intangibles exists is not enough to suggest that an
economy faces an innovation problem. Low investment in R&D can also reflect systemic
problems that affect the accumulation of all sorts of assets, including physical and human capital
(Maloney and Rodríguez-Clare, 2007). A different explanation for an R&D intensity gap is
production specialization. The propensity of firms to invest in R&D varies across sectors (Pavitt,
relative productivities across sectors, clearly affecting the validity of the country comparison of
aggregate indicators. 5
mostly through their access to generic knowledge, human capital, and finance. The degree to
complementary inputs affects private investment in innovation. Table 3.1 shows how much these
variables explain the gap in innovation investment between Latin America and the Caribbean
and OECD countries. In the period 1995–2010, the business sector of the typical Latin American
and Caribbean country invested in R&D 1.18 percent of GDP less than the typical OECD
country, and this gap has increased since the period 1980–94, when it was 0.90 percent of GDP.
The factors underlying these gaps have changed. Prior to 1995, low access to generic
knowledge explained about 30 percent of the gap, while the absence of dynamic sectors in the
production structure explained just 10 percent. The lack of human capital and financial
development were in between those figures. After 1995, however, human capital increased
significantly in importance and, more strikingly, the role of the production structure increased
markedly to explain 26 percent of business investment gaps. On the other hand, financial
development, and to a lesser extent generic knowledge, have become less important. Clearly, the
Latin American and Caribbean business sector suffers from an innovation investment shortfall
beyond what would be expected given the financial development and human capital
accumulation of the region. Moreover, low public sector investment in the generation of generic
knowledge and the lack of sophistication of the production structure explain a significant part of
this gap. 6
[Insert Table 3.1 Explaining the Gaps in Business R&D: The OECD vs.
The evidence of investment gaps is not enough to justify intervention because they could
reflect a lack of innovation opportunities. Assessing this possibility requires looking at the social
returns rates (SRRs) to innovation investments. A review of more than 50 years of research
suggests that social returns to R&D are strongly positive (Hall, Mairesse, and Mohnen, 2010).
However, much of this research focuses on evidence from developed countries. Lederman and
Maloney (2003) find that the returns to R&D are not only higher for developing countries, but
also higher than the estimated return on physical capital. More specifically, for Latin American
and Caribbean countries, Maloney and Rodríguez-Clare (2007) find that social rates of return
calibrated using international data vary between 51 percent in the case of Peru and 16 percent in
Redding, and Van Reenen (2004) propose an approach in which productivity growth is the result
of innovation and technology transfer, and investments in R&D not only stimulate innovation but
also build absorptive capacities for technology transfer. The social return rates to R&D are the
expanded to include data on R&D investments from different sources. Figure 3.2 summarizes the
results of this method and suggests that SRRs for R&D investments are not only systematically
higher in Latin America and the Caribbean than in the OECD (56 percent vs. 32 percent in 2007)
but also that they have followed a divergent path over time. Indeed, while social returns have
declined in the OECD (mostly due to the lower returns from technology transfer as these
countries have moved closer to the technological frontier) in Latin America and the Caribbean,
social returns to R&D have tended to increase (mostly due to the greater scope for technology
transfer as these countries have systematically shifted away from the technological frontier). This
increasing trend in social returns, together with growing investment gaps, are consistent with the
finding that the Latin American and Caribbean region indeed faces an innovation shortfall.
[Insert Figure 3.2 Social Returns to R&D, Latin America and the
Innovation policy covers a broad set of issues that have been in the policy agenda for
decades. Although countries vary widely, the experience of successful catch-up economies
support and continuously updating innovation policies. Indeed, many of the best
performers not only boast high innovation investment rates today, but also sustained high
rates of effort over long periods of time, even above what was expected given their GDP
infrastructure and human capital 7 is coupled with support to applied research in key
openness, fiscal balance, competition, regulation, IPR protection, and the like) echoes
increasing support for investments in science and technology and business innovation,
allowing for a continuous shift of resources toward the most dynamic sectors.
grants, and tax incentives for business innovation, mission-oriented research funding and
public procurement were used extensively, and refocused continually on the generation of
spillovers (research collaboration and technologies that spread across different sectors,
such as biotechnology and information and communication technology) (see Box 3.1).
• A continuous focus on institutional capacity building, monitoring, and evaluation fed into
policy learning and gradually fostered a more complex and focused policy mix. South
Korea illustrates a typical example of this process of policy building (see Box 3.2).
designs. Based on the framework proposed in Chapter 2, these multiple policy designs can be
organized along two dimensions: scope, depending on whether the policy focuses on the
matrix that reclassifies innovation policies in four quadrants. Table 3.2 presents several examples
of scope-type combinations of policy instruments that are commonly found in successful catch-
up economies.
States]
[Insert Box 3.2 Innovation Policy Building through Catch-up: The Case of
South Korea]
The Latin American experience with innovation policy dates backs to the 1950s and since
then different policy approaches have been tried and abandoned over time. Although country
experiences are very idiosyncratic, three broad policy paradigms have been tried: the supply side
approach, which extended from the 1950s to the 1980s; the demand side approach, which
reigned from the 1980s through the 2000s; and the (emerging) systemic approach, which has
The supply side approach (1950s–1980s) was based on the idea of linearity from supply
capital and information—by public institutions (such as laboratories, research institutes, and
universities, mostly funded through entitlements) gave way to a series of instruments in the
councils—governed the system and were tasked with funding research, supporting human capital
complement support to research and technical and professional training. 9 Operating at the sector
level, these institutes fulfilled a dual role: carry out applied research, and transfer knowledge to
capacities and linkages between knowledge supply and demand were given far less importance.
The demand side approach (1980s–2000s) featured the structural reforms of the
Washington Consensus. The diagnosis blamed government failures and argued that keeping
intervention to a minimum was the best way to avoid them. This phase had important
implications for innovation policy. The majority of the public organizations and institutes
designed to promote innovation lost importance within the state bureaucracy. Public budgets
were severely curtailed. New incentive regimes were set up to introduce market discipline in
technological institutes that had to increase their funding by selling services to the private sector.
Human capital formation was deregulated and private universities entered the market while
intellectual property frameworks were gradually strengthened. All these changes occurred as
product market competition), support to the supply side of the equation was dismantled.
The pitfalls of the reforms became evident toward the end of this phase, when it became
clear that spillovers, lack of complementary assets, and financing were important obstacles for
firms to adapt to the new scenario. In response, some countries began experimenting with new
horizontal/market policy instruments, introducing grants for business R&D, R&D tax credits,
conditional loans, and vouchers for technology transfer in the second half of the 1990s. Most of
these programs were delivered through technology development funds, which initially worked
out of existing institutions such as development agencies or research councils, and later spun off
The systemic approach, which began in the early 2000s, emerged from a growing
consensus that business innovation support with a strong focus on the individual firm was not
enough to internalize spillovers and solve coordination failures. The diffusion of the idea of an
innovation system triggered renewed interest in investing on the supply side, but with increased
concern about generating the right incentives to favor closer coordination between supply and
demand. New institutions, such as technology liaison offices specialized in linking the different
actors, emerged. After many years of inaction, there was renewed interest in supporting
technology extension, but now with a focus on building absorptive capabilities in small and
medium enterprises (SMEs). Dissatisfaction with purely horizontal policies also grew. Thus,
since the early 2000s, the impetus has shifted to vertical programs. Some countries are
experimenting with funding schemes in areas where public procurement is important (such as
programs in health and energy) and are targeting subsidies to technologies (such as information
technologies) that can spread out across the production sector at large. This proliferation of
programs with very different designs and implementing agencies has heightened the stress on
institutions and highlights the need to improve policy coordination. Currently, the mix of
innovation policies in some countries is not very different from that in developed economies
The previous analysis offers different justifications for the implementation of innovation
policies based on the idea that profit-seeking agents will produce both a level and direction of
knowledge that fall short from a social welfare perspective. As David, Hall, and Toole (2000)
note, public policy has followed two main approaches: direct production of knowledge by public
institutions (universities, laboratories and public research institutes), most of them under the
category of public goods interventions; and fiscal incentives for private investment in knowledge
generation. 10
Issues of governance and funding incentives of public technological institutes are beyond
the scope of this chapter; in any case, their public funding is normally far less controversial than
market interventions. This section focuses on the second class of policy interventions, in
particular, two types of incentives: fiscal incentives for innovation, whose goal is to increase
private sector investment in innovation and whose focus is the firm as a knowledge producer;
and technology extension programs, whose goal is to stimulate firms to acquire or improve their
use of technology and whose focus is the firm as a knowledge user. Fiscal incentives mostly
occur in the form of direct subsidies or tax incentives, while technology extension programs
cover a wider set of interventions. Although other instruments exist, this discussion focuses on
these two because they are the most prone to moral hazard and rent-seeking problems, as they
Fiscal Incentives
Fiscal incentives come in two different forms: subsidies and tax incentives. Subsidies are
a type of direct support for business innovation that is project-specific. They transfer cash to
firms on the condition that firms execute a series of innovation activities. Subsidies are normally
delivered through two different mechanisms: nonreimbursable grants and conditional loans. 11 By
contrast, tax incentives are based on firm-level innovation activities and operate through a
Fiscal incentives not only reduce the marginal cost of capital to undertake innovation
investments, but can also encourage collaboration with other actors in the innovation system,
such as research centers, technological institutes, or firms. Table 3.3 summarizes the main
Two important differences between subsidies and tax incentives relate to their relative
effectiveness to internalize spillovers and their focus on those segments of the population of
firms most likely to be affected by market failures. Subsidies, given their project-based nature,
can not only target high spillover projects but can also direct funding toward firms more severely
affected by market failures, such as young firms and innovative SMEs. These features are less
clear in the case of tax incentives. In the first place, tax incentives are a fully market-friendly
mechanism; the firm decides which projects will be implemented. This might bias the incentives
toward projects with higher private appropriability. Moreover, tax incentives are not proportional
to the difference between social and private rates of return, as they should be, but instead to total
R&D costs (Maloney and Perry, 2005). Tax incentives also suffer from poor targeting as their
impacts depend on the fiscal position of each firm—an aspect that normally biases them toward
large firms. 12 In the case of subsidies, the fiscal cost is under control, since the resources
allocated to the programs are budgeted. On the other hand, in the case of tax incentives, fiscal
costs are less certain because the fiscal authority has no control over firms’ decisions. Both types
of fiscal incentives suffer from moral hazard problems; however, several good practice designs
are available to mitigate them (see the bottom panel of Table 3.3). Implementing these good
practices requires capacity building in both innovation agencies and tax authorities. The higher
administration and compliance costs of the direct subsidies must be compared with the higher
policing costs of the tax incentive. In summary, subsidies have a series of nice design features
that might make them a preferred choice compared to tax incentives for several Latin American
and Caribbean countries, in particular those with very weak tax authorities.
Sometimes subsidies coexist with credit programs that focus on funding the adoption of
equipment). The rationale for the credit lines differs from that normally used for subsidies. In the
case of the adoption of technology embodied in machinery and equipment, the returns are more
likely to be appropriated by the investors, so policy should focus on solving a liquidity constraint
problem only through the provision of credit. However, if the purchased technology generates
spillovers to the rest of the sector—for example, through demonstration effects by the pioneer
dissemination. The implementing agency must carefully define what should or should not be
considered an innovative technology and the potential for spillovers (see Box 3.3).
[Insert Box 3.3 FONTAR’s Toolkit: Basic Rules for Allocating Subsidies
vs. Credit]
So far in the region, following the trends from developed countries, subsidies have
increasingly focused on fostering research collaboration and linkages among the different actors
in the innovation system. Indeed, countries are gradually moving from supporting single projects
that involve university-industry interaction to more integral programs that involve full sectors by
efforts of different firms and to increase their collaboration with universities and research
centers, which has been a historical problem in Latin America and the Caribbean. The basic
assumption is that these consortia could help internalize spillovers, coordinate complementary
private investments and reduce duplication of competitive research agendas. By solving these
multiple failures, consortia should trigger higher returns to R&D investment. 13 Although still too
early to make a final judgment on the performance results of these collaborative interventions,
early evidence suggests that the results critically depend on correctly aligning the incentives of
firms and universities, the absorptive capacities of participating firms, the proximity among
participants and the experience and conflict solving capabilities by the group’s manager. On the
public sector side, these large-scale interventions also demand coordination among different
institutions and flexibility as the research agenda emerges from the interaction among the
Figure 3.4 summarizes the amount of public resources spent on business innovation for
the countries with the largest support systems in the region. Brazil tops the ranking, with
transfers to the private sector amounting to 0.14 percent of GDP in 2008. About 70 percent of
these resources were delivered through subsidies, and 30 percent through tax incentives. Chile
and Colombia came next (0.04 percent of GDP). Figure 3.4 also shows that the typical OECD
country spends 0.11 percent of GDP on R&D fiscal incentives, around four times more than the
typical Latin American and Caribbean country. The experience of developed countries suggests
that scaling up the system strongly depends on the generosity of the tax incentive component of
the policy (the same is true in Latin America and the Caribbean).
[Insert Figure 3.4 Direct Government Funding and Tax Incentives for
Technology Extension
extension program (TEP). TEPs are designed to facilitate the adoption of existing technologies to
improve the efficiency of a production unit. What differentiates a TEP from other innovation
policy tools is that the new technology is mostly developed outside the adopting unit. 14 These
programs typically have a dual focus. On the one hand, they provide services to reduce the costs
of searching for information about new technologies, sometimes matching user needs with
appropriate suppliers. They also provide support to enhance firms’ ability to absorb new
technologies, through hands-on training, pilot production demonstration, and assistance when
negotiating with the technology supplier (De Ferranti et al., 2003). In some cases, TEPs are
combined with support for incremental innovation (in terms of adaptation to local conditions).
Different models and approaches to TEPs have been developed and implemented over
time. 15 The approach in the United States and the United Kingdom—spearheaded by the U.S.
(MAS)—has traditionally focused on intervening at the firm level by providing field services to
enhance the ability of SMEs to adopt new technologies or organizational models. The continental
European approach, typified by Austria, Germany, and some Scandinavian countries, focuses
more on supporting not only the SME’s adoption of existing external technologies, but also on
improving these technologies through sector-specific research consortia. The Japanese and
extension services to SMEs through national technology institutes (NTIs), both in manufacturing
and agriculture, some of them established during the early 1950s. Problems related to funding
and incentives have compromised the effectiveness of these institutions. Most of the NTIs have
been reformed, and funding through entitlements is gradually being replaced with performance
agreements and sales of services. Moreover, the traditional NTI model has been complemented
with various programs aimed at creating a market for technological services. Most Latin
American and Caribbean governments have introduced programs based on public-private cost
sharing, sometimes with vouchers for producers to purchase services from publicly certified
private providers and NTIs. These changes have gradually led to the generation of a private
supply of technological services for SMEs. Finally, TEPs in Latin America and the Caribbean
have progressively moved from targeting individual firms to groups of firms. This change
technological infrastructure. To help overcome potential coordination failures, new TEPs have
been developed to promote firm collaboration and networking. Although assessments suggest
that these changes are steps in the right direction, as TEPs have effectively improved the
performance of their target population, they have also revealed structural limitations in reaching
firms that suffer severe financial and technological constraints. For this reason, fully publicly
operated services may still be required to satisfy demand for extension services at the base of
productivity pyramid. Another limitation of TEPs in the region is that despite the reforms,
coverage—in terms of the proportion of assisted firms over target population—seems to be very
Although fiscal incentives for innovation and TEPs are conceptually different
instruments, their performance can be improved by targeting the synergies that might emerge by
combining features of both types of instruments. For example, although innovation support
programs correct market failures by providing a financial reward to the pioneers, the diffusion of
the new discoveries could be further enhanced by linking part of the reward that the pioneers
receive to dissemination activities that give followers access to technology (for example, through
product discoveries, pioneers’ rewards could be at least partially linked to followers’ sales of the
same product. 16
In terms of the volume of resources invested and number of firms covered, business
innovation support in Latin America is still in its infancy, as many of the programs are more in
the nature of pilots than full-fledged interventions. However, the good news is that the best
practice designs outlined in Table 3.3 are gradually being incorporated in their deployment. Of
course, the situation is far from ideal, but the trend at least in terms of instrument design seems to
be in the right direction. However, before deciding whether to expand the fiscal resources and
the coverage of these programs, the effectiveness of the existing ones in solving the
One of the first issues to be defined in impact evaluation is the set of outcomes of
interest. A distinction should be made between input and output indicators. Input indicators are
more directly affected by the intervention: for example, total investment in innovation. To the
extent that innovation policy reduces the capital cost of firms, it could be possible to identify
which innovation policies generate an increase in innovation investment at the firm level (input
policies increase firms’ investment in innovation, and the overall contribution of the private
sector to this effort: the so-called crowding-in effect. However, just assessing whether innovation
efforts increase as a consequence of a subsidy is not enough for evaluation purposes. It is also
the impact of these programs on direct beneficiaries. However, direct beneficiaries are just one
component of the social returns, and perhaps the least interesting one. A key rationale for these
programs should be the extent to which they generate spillovers. This can be done by tracing the
impact of the programs on indirect beneficiaries (such as through labor mobility or geographical
colocation). Although very few impact evaluations to date have explored the relevance of
spillovers, some of them have been done specially for this report. 17
As in other regions, evaluating the effects on investment has been the most common
approach to impact evaluation for Latin America and the Caribbean. 18 Table 3.4 summarizes the
results of 16 impact evaluations done in the region. The evidence across the different studies is
that fiscal incentives clearly stimulate innovation or R&D investments. In almost all cases, the
seven evaluations, where the main impact indicator is private investment in innovation or R&D,
the results for this variable are also positive and significant, suggesting crowding-in. Fiscal
support may be having a signaling effect on the quality of the projects, allowing firms to
leverage additional resources from financial markets (see Benavente, Crespi, and Maffioli,
2007). Comparing across the different instruments, matching grants schemes were not found to
have a significantly different multiplier effect on investment than loans or tax incentives.
However, matching grants schemes clearly dominate when they provide funding conditioned on
collaboration (see cases with “Firms & UNIV” as beneficiaries in Table 3.4 cases) or when they
target new innovators. 19 Apparently, matching grants programs are particularly well-suited for
building linkages among the different actors of the innovation system, addressing both market
The majority of the studies summarized in Table 3.4 use techniques that construct
characteristics of the firms. 20 This provides for an accurate assessment of the programs’ selection
process, which per se provides valuable information on the programs’ targeting. The results
show that firms with high levels of human capital or previous experience in managing innovation
programs are more likely to be selected. This is not surprising, considering the weight normally
given to quality when selecting proposals. However, a system based on past accomplishments
might overlook new innovators, which may be more prone to suffer market failures. Ceilings of
maximum support per firm could be considered, given the trade-off between fostering
excellence, which may require multiple interventions for certain beneficiaries, and variety. The
also important to improve the coordination between innovation support and technology extension
programs, given the focus in TEPs on building innovation management capacities in firms.
At the international level, fewer studies analyze the effect of public support on firm
performance; the results are mixed. The main difficulty in this type of study is that a longer time
horizon is required to detect these effects. While investment effects can be detected almost in
conjunction with the receipt of public financing, other effects are detectable only after the
innovation has taken place. Thus, rigorous impact evaluations of these effects may require
following firms for a minimum of five years after receipt of public financing. In order to fill this
knowledge gap, the Inter-American Development Bank reassessed some of the programs in
Table 3.4 over a longer period and looked at impacts on productivity. Table 3.5 summarizes the
results for the five evaluated programs. All the programs were evaluated using the same
approach, with the main output indicator being labor productivity. The results suggest significant
increases in labor productivity: from 9–12 percent when only individual firms are targeted, and
from 10–24 percent when joint firm-university projects are supported. Additional evidence
shows that strong complementarities could be achieved when the support of different programs is
the combined effects of Chile’s FONTEC, supporting individual firms, and FONDEF,
innovation support programs are combined with other PDP programs. 21 Complementarities also
exist between innovation policies and policies that normally form part of the framework
Impacts]
The IDB has also evaluated a series of TEPs. Castillo et al. (2014a) evaluate the effect of
Argentina’s Support Program for Organizational Change (PRE) on employment and wages. 22
The program cofinanced technical assistance to support process and product innovation
activities. Using a unique dataset with information for the population of firms in Argentina, the
study finds large effects on employment attributable to the program’s support, with increases of
around 20 percent. For the median firm, participation in the program generated five additional
jobs. The program support for process innovation increased real wages by 2 percent, while
support for product innovation increased real wages by 4 percent. The evaluation also provided
evidence of the program’s positive effect on both firm survival and export.
Benavente and Crespi (2003) analyze the impact of the Chilean Productive Development
Program (Programa Asociativo de Fomento, PROFO), which promotes joint projects among
groups of SMEs to improve access to markets and help them innovate, which sparked
productivity improvements of 11 percent vis-à-vis the control group. 23 In addition, the social
return rate of the program was at least 20 percent. TEPs oriented to the diffusion of agricultural
technology demonstrated qualitatively similar results (see Table 3.5). 24 Overall, the results
confirm that TEPs are effective in achieving their expected results and that different approaches
work when applied in the proper contexts. Obviously, evidence on effectiveness should also be
Case of Chile]
Although knowledge spillovers are at the core of the theoretical justification for
innovation policy, very few impact evaluations measure these potential effects. This omission
probably reflects the difficulty of identifying the mechanisms through which spillovers occur. In
the context of impact evaluation, measuring spillovers implies identifying the impact of the
program not just on direct beneficiaries (firms that received program support) but also on indirect
beneficiaries (firms that received benefits from the program through their relation with direct
To fill this gap, the IDB has recently undertaken studies in Argentina (Castillo et al.,
2014b) and Brazil (Ingtec and USP Research Group, 2013). The two studies focus on fiscal
incentive programs, and define labor mobility as the main mechanism through which knowledge
spillovers occur. Because much of this new knowledge is “captured” by the human resources
operating in the beneficiary firm during the execution of the project, relevant spillovers may
occur when one of these workers moves to a different firm, carrying part of the knowledge
To track and measure the effect of spillovers, both studies use administrative employer-
employee longitudinal datasets that track the mobility of qualified workers from direct
beneficiary firms to other firms (indirect beneficiaries). Once both direct and indirect
beneficiaries were identified, the causal effects—direct and indirect—of the programs were
estimated.
Findings are summarized in Table 3.6. Because of data limitations, effects on innovation
investments are available for the Brazilian programs only. The findings for Brazil show positive
spillover effects in terms of human resources devoted to innovation activities, with increases
ranging from 6–17 percent, depending on the programs. Interestingly, the program promoting
cooperation between firms and universities produces the largest spillover effects (17 percent),
providing evidence that spillovers could be larger when the knowledge generated is more
“generic.” In terms of spillovers on firm performance, the studies on Brazil and Argentina
confirm that the programs positively affected firm growth (measured in terms of employment),
with effects ranging from 7–20 percent, and exporting by boosting export probability in
Argentina by 4 percent and the ratio of exports/employees in Brazil between 17 and 23 percent.
Overall, these results strongly support the “lack of appropriability” rationale at the basis
of innovation policies. They also provide an extremely valuable input for the future social cost-
benefit analysis of these policies, providing ranges for the potential magnitude of the spillovers.
In summary, the evidence is that fiscal incentives for innovation are effective in stimulating
business innovation investments and productivity growth. This implies that the programs in
general are targeting firms that might be facing some sort of market or coordination failure;
when these constraints are relaxed, firms react favorably by increasing their innovation
investments. The evidence also shows that the spillovers generated by these programs can be
substantial, suggesting that they are effectively correcting for market failures. However, impact
evaluation results also suggest that effectiveness can be enhanced by a better focus on market
failures (for example, by targeting investments in intangibles rather than tangibles, hiring
researchers by firms or focusing on university-industry collaboration) or on those firms more
prone to suffer market failures (such as innovative SMEs and young innovators). Impacts could
competition, among innovation programs and other PDPs (such as those for export promotion, as
Keys to Success
Innovation policies are complex. They require the resolution of complicated market and
coordination failures; they involve multiple stakeholders, and require long gestation periods. For
the ability to engage with the private sector, coordinate across public agencies and guarantee the
continuity of policies. The experience from developed countries and successful catch-up
economies suggests that successful implementation of innovation policies requires building four
organization that sets a long-term national innovation strategy with clear and measurable
objectives and binding recommendations about the policy mix, financing, instruments,
jurisdictions, and mandates. Ideally, the institution that assumes this role should not be tied to the
political cycle, in order to assure the continuity of innovation policies, and be well-staffed with
technical resources to make strategic studies and foresight exercises. Several developed countries
have established public-private councils that fulfill this function, including Canada, Finland,
Germany, Ireland, and South Korea. In Latin America, high-level innovation councils are in
place in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Costa Rica, Mexico, and Uruguay. However, in many cases,
these organizations are not fully institutionalized, multi-stakeholder representation is weak, they
lack operational resources and their power depends on the interest of the current administration
in power; this violates some of the key principles of these organizations. In many cases, these
institutions only play an advisory role, while line ministries still handle the strategic decisions.
coordination capacities translate the long-term innovation strategy into specific policy designs
and allocate budgets to implementing agencies. Given the multiple ministries involved and
idiosyncratic organization of the public sector, two different models of policy coordination can
be identified in the region. Some countries have established “innovation cabinets,” where
different ministries discuss policy coordination and implementation (Chile and Uruguay). In
other cases, this policy coordination function is concentrated in a specific ministry that leads
cross-ministerial cabinets (Argentina and Brazil). Both models have pros and cons. An
innovation cabinet is likely to be more inclusive and have better horizontal coordination, but may
also suffer from higher transaction costs. A dominant coordinating player could be more efficient
at coordinating related agencies, but lack horizontal reach. Despite these advances, the countries
in the region still have a long way to go with regard to policy coordination, in particular
regarding the coordination of innovation policies and other PDP policies (Crespi and Tacsir,
2012) and also regarding policies implemented at different levels of government (such as federal,
Policy implementation capabilities: The best practice from developed countries suggests
that policy implementation should be carried out by a merit-based technically capable civil
service able to partner with the private sector (Devlin and Moguillansky, 2012). Given the
dimension is not an easy task. Evidence from successful cases suggests that this is sometimes
better attained by autonomous agencies, which tend to enjoy higher stability, are more open to
experimentation, and more responsive to client needs than centralized ministerial departments
(OECD, 2011 and Box 3.1). Autonomous agencies also could have more flexibility to manage
talent and hire the human capital required to run their operations. Consistent with this trend,
several Latin American and Caribbean countries, such as Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Uruguay,
have created implementing agencies with some of these characteristics, although the exact
agency traits vary by country. Whatever the actual institutional configuration of the agency, it
should be accountable for the efficiency of its operations at the policy and strategic levels and
should be clearly aligned to policy-level decisions. Policy implementation is more than just
managing private sector incentives for business innovation; it also encompasses policy
capabilities to align the incentives of public research centers and technological institutes to
respond to private sector needs and to simulate more pertinent technological research. 25
to function well. More specifically, monitoring and evaluation capacities are central not only in
order to abort wrong projects early, but also to avoid private sector capture of policy
implementation. For effective monitoring, every budgetary line should be linked to measurable
outputs so that both outputs and resources can be tracked over time, and deviations from goals
can be identified and discussed. Evidence form developed countries suggests that the whole
policy system should have an evaluation arm in charge of implementing impact evaluations of
the different programs. The evaluation unit should be external (or nested in a different
evaluation capacities are severely underdeveloped in the region to date. Although ministerial and
agency-level bodies are gradually building the capacity to conduct impact evaluations, they still
have a long way to go in order to develop program evaluation plans that incorporate state-of-the
art methodologies and, at the same time, set up the information technology systems to produce
bottlenecks. First, specialized human capital to manage innovation policy is scarce. Training is
sometimes done on an ad hoc basis. In some countries, low public sector salaries induce high
rotation of personnel, which hinders efficiency and favors capture. Second, public management
and financial systems are not adequately set up to manage programs that require regular financial
transfers from the public to the private sector and flexible, timely disbursements according to
private sector needs. Third, obsolete information systems hinder monitoring and evaluation.
Fourth, there is a shortage of external examiners who do not have conflicts of interest, especially
in contexts where the research community is small. Finally, low differentiation of functions
successful innovation policy implementation, government failures could be worse than market
failures. Countries in the region have only recently started to build up institutional capacities in
some of the above-mentioned dimensions. Not surprisingly, those countries where impact
evaluations show the most successful results are also those where at least some of the
institutional concerns have been tackled. However, this process of institutional capacity building
Although over the last 20 years, the region has made remarkable progress in improving
the framework conditions, this has not been enough to trigger a process of productivity catch-up.
Indeed, the market and coordination failures that hinder innovation investment and technology
adoption are still pervasive, and governments have notably failed to find a proper policy solution
for many of them. Nowadays, the private sector innovation investment gap between Latin
American and Caribbean and developed or successful emerging economies is larger than it was
20 or more years ago—despite the persistently high social returns to innovation investments. A
combination of investment gaps with increasing returns can only be interpreted as a sign of a
Despite this rather grim scenario, some glimmers of optimism are beginning to appear
throughout the region. First, after many years of inaction, several countries have started to invest
engineering. Some countries have complemented these efforts with additional investments in
research capacity and technological infrastructure. Although these efforts are relatively recent
and have been insufficient to induce an improvement in business innovation investment, they are
finds that the new emphasis on building research capacity and human capital needs to be
complemented by a consistent stimulus on the demand side (the firms) and on solving the
coordination failures that hinder the interaction between supply and demand. In other words,
neither a supply push nor a demand pull by themselves are enough; the most likely dividends
will come from working on both sides and their interaction. The focus should be on putting in
place those policy interventions that can jumpstart the region’s innovation systems by solving
However, in contrast with growing public support to the research base and human capital
formation, the fiscal budgets allocated to business innovation programs remain rather meager. To
some extent, business innovation policy in the region is still in its infancy. Yet as the evidence
presented in this chapter shows, when these programs are correctly designed, they are capable of
employment, and generating spillovers. Although the risks of moral hazard and capture are
always present, these problems can be minimized when several basic design principles are put
into place (such as program support with a sunset clause, private sector cofinancing, allocation
through competitive processes, ex ante evaluation through external peer-reviewers, and ex post
impact evaluation.)
Yet boosting the budgets of these programs will not be enough. In addition to basic
design principles, these programs must be specifically designed to maximize their social returns.
Issues such as increasing differentiation of the programs according to the basic innovation
capabilities of the beneficiaries need to be integrated within the policy mix. Special consideration
should be given to programs with clear incentives for collaboration among firms and universities,
since programs with such features yield a higher multiplier effect in terms of investment and
spillovers. Incentives should aim clearly toward those projects that generate spillovers and
technology diffusion.
In addition, many issues with regard to the policy mix are not being tackled properly and
need to be given serious consideration, including more experimentation. Among the key issues
that require further investigation are the effectiveness of the available instruments to diversify
the production structure by encouraging product innovation and enhancing the entry of new
innovative start-ups, the role of policy to stimulate innovation in the service sector, and the
importance of better aligning incentives with performance (not only by funding investment but
also by linking the generosity of fiscal incentives to the outcome of those investments). Finally,
and more important, far more consideration should be given to institutional arrangements that
bring about continuity, good governance, and productive public-private collaboration for
innovation. Arguably, reform of these institutional aspects lags the furthest behind in the policy
agenda. In particular, important institutional capacities, such as policy coordination, are still
weak, and others, such as strategy setting and impact evaluation, are mostly missing. This
cooperation.
Box 3.1 Fostering Innovation through Government-sponsored Mission-
oriented Research and Public Procurement: The Case of the United States
key feature of mission-oriented research is that policymakers, rather than scientists, choose the
fields in which large investments of public R&D funds are made. Allocation decisions are based
on assessments of the research needs of specific agency missions in fields ranging from national
defense to agriculture, health, energy, and other activities. The R&D investment budgets of most
OECD nations are dominated by programs that serve specific government missions. According
to a report by the U.S. National Science Foundation, mission-oriented research ranges from 50
percent of total government R&D spending in Germany to 90 percent in the United States, with
the budgets of Japan, France, the United Kingdom, Canada, and South Korea falling in between
A key feature of mission-oriented research is that projects being funded are normally of a
more applied nature. This has led to the argument that to the extent that research findings are
very specific, the scope for spillovers is narrower than in the case of other research. Empirical
evidence has shown, however, that this is not the case, as many of the technological
breakthroughs currently used by the private sector originated in mission- oriented research
programs (including such notable examples as semiconductors, the Internet, GPS, hybrid corn,
MRIs, and hydraulic fracturing). Moreover, private sector spillovers can be maximized when
mission-oriented research tilts toward funding new bodies of scientific or engineering knowledge
that support innovation across different sectors; when it focuses on developments in the early
phases of a new technology; when it funds new publicly available technological infrastructure
(such as research labs in universities or research centers); and when the procurement rules foster
both competition and collaboration among research teams, universities, publics labs; and firms.
technology from one or more public agencies. Placing large orders of early versions of a
technological device allows the producer to learn, improve quality, and reduce prices for other
private sector users. Procurement rules can also promote technology diffusion. For example, in
the U.S. defense sector, public procurement is sometimes accompanied by policies that require
the supplier to develop a “second source” for the product: that is, a different domestic producer
that could manufacture a functionally identical product in order to avoid supply interruptions.
Mission-oriented research and public procurement, however, are not without risks. Large
publicly funded research programs might increase the costs of R&D (such as the salaries of
researchers), crowding out private sector R&D investment. Mission-oriented research could also
bias the research agenda toward applications that are not easily transferred to the private sector.
The United States has solved this institutional challenge by managing mission-oriented research
programs through specialized agencies. An example is the Defense Advanced Research Projects
Agency (DARPA), set up in 1957 within the Department of Defense to invest in high-risk, high-
payoff research. DARPA is a small, flexible, and flat organization with about 140 technical
professionals. It is exempted from the normal federal regulations for civil personnel, providing it
with important flexibility for managing talent. DARPA’s technical staff are hired or assigned for
four to six years. All key staff (office directors and program managers) rotate to ensure a
constant infusion of fresh thinking and perspectives. This gives DARPA the flexibility to get into
and out of an area without the burden of sustaining staff. DARPA neither owns nor operates any
industry and universities. Project-based assignments are organized around competitions to solve
a specific technology challenge. Then the development and production are handed off to the
Box 3.2 Innovation Policy Building through Catch-up: The Case of South
Korea
South Korea has been one of the most successful latecomer economies in achieving rapid
economic growth and is approaching the ranks of advanced economies in terms of GDP per
capita. One element of Korea’s success has been its emphasis on capability and technological
development, which has led to the consolidation of private exporting and R&D capacity. During
the catch-up process, Korea went through four phases. In each phase, the government
In the 1960s, when Korea began its modernization process, the country faced two key
barriers: low technological capabilities of domestic firms and poor human capital (in particular,
imports with licensing, developing a new graduate school of engineering and applied sciences
(the Korean Institute of Science and Technology, KIST), and setting up key institutions for
science and technology infrastructure. These actions facilitated the absorption of imported
technologies and attracted technology-based FDI. In this stage, domestic firms participated only
in assembling and packaging processes, with very limited investment in innovation. For the
Korean firms, this was a learning-by-doing period without an explicit attempt to develop new
capabilities or technologies. During this period R&D investment was never higher than 0.5% of
the GDP.
In this second phase, Korean firms more actively adopted foreign technologies through
imitative innovation and reverse engineering. They invested more intensively in adapting foreign
funding private R&D through tax incentives, and by conducting R&D activities directly and
sharing the results with private firms. In the 1980s, a joint public-private R&D program was set
up to support higher-risk projects. Consequently, the R&D/GNP ratio increased from 0.42
percent in 1975 to 1.41 percent in 1985. During this stage, government investment in R&D still
This third phase was a period of rapid catch-up led by the major Korean businesses.
products. Realizing the limits of a strategy based on licensing and embodied technology transfer,
Korean firms established their own in-house R&D centers. To encourage this trend, the
government eased the accreditation process for setting up private R&D institutes, and a large
number of institutes were established. The R&D/GNP ratio increased from 1.41 percent in 1985
to 2.32 percent in 1994. Such active engagement of private R&D activities enabled Korea to
absorb the newly emerging technologies. From this period onward, private R&D investment has
been a key part of the Korean innovation and technology development process, accounting for
As South Korea approaches the technological frontier, the country is entering a new and
critical phase in its development. With the slower growth of labor and capital inputs and
increasing competition from new industrializing countries, South Korea faces new challenges.
The catch-up model is now under stress, and South Korea is shifting from a “catch-up” to a
“creative” innovation system. The creative model requires increased spending on R&D – by both
public and private sectors – and improved knowledge flows and technology transfer across the
system. This demands stronger support to innovative SMEs and Start-Ups; increasing the role of
longer-term, fundamental research; developing research capacity in the universities; and dealing
with lagging productivity in services. This transition towards a creative economy can already be
seen in some innovation indicators. Patents owned by Koreans increased from 7 in 1982 to 3,558
in 1999 according to a U.S. register. In 2006, the R&D/GNP ratio passed the 3 percent threshold.
Box 3.3 FONTAR’s Toolkit: Basic Rules for Allocating Subsidies vs. Credit
created in 1995 and has been one of the pillars of Argentina’s innovation policy. Although the
program has expanded its interventions over time, it has focused on providing support to
business innovation projects through two main instruments: reimbursable funding, through credit
for innovation; and nonreimbursable funding, through matching grants and tax credits.
The assessment of innovation projects usually requires very specific technical expertise.
The lack of such expertise can worsen the problem of asymmetric information between investors
and the innovator. Programs such as FONTAR, which assess innovation projects through
appropriate review processes, provide valuable signals to financial markets about the technical
and commercial sustainability of the investments. Moreover, innovation projects are riskier,
more intangible, and more prone to spillovers than technology adoption projects, which are
based on more easily collateralized physical investment (like machinery). For this reason,
external investors systematically require higher risk premiums to finance innovation activities, or
Because FONTAR’s lines of funding target different kinds of investments with different
degrees of risk and lack of tangibility, the instruments used for each line can be sharply
contrast, projects aimed at the adoption of existing knowledge embedded in tangible assets are
less risky and the returns are more likely to be appropriated by the innovator. Thus, the policy
table that follows shows how FONTAR’s officers allocate the different projects to the different
instruments.
The Chilean government has been experimenting with business innovation policies since
the early 1990s, mostly through different direct support (matching grants) programs to stimulate
business innovation and university-industry collaboration. Most of these programs have been
managed by the National Development Agency (CORFO) and the National Science and
Technology Council (CONICYT). More than 6,000 projects have been funded since 1991. This
experience has generated rich evidence to learn about a variety of impacts of innovation policies
and competition. It has been argued that innovation is at odds with competition because the need
to generate innovation rents to reward the innovators normally implies accepting some sort of
market distortion (for example, through the granting of intellectual property rights) as the price
to pay to obtain more innovation. Recent research on this subject has reevaluated this view,
finding that the relationship between these two variables is more complex than previously
thought. Aghion et al. (2012) argue that the effects of fiscal incentives to stimulate innovation in
a given sector vary depending on the degree of competition among firms: the more competitive
the sector is, the more these firms will be encouraged to innovate in order to escape competition.
In other words, a certain demand for innovation is necessary in order for fiscal incentives to be
effective, and competition is the trigger for this demand. Using data from China over the 1988–
2007 period, Aghion et al. (2012) report results consistent with this view.
In order to explore whether this argument applies to Chile, the Chilean data on the
beneficiaries of business innovation programs were linked to the manufacturing census over the
had any positive effect on firms’ total factor productivity. To see whether these effects vary
across sectors depending on the intensity of competition, the treatment variable was interacted
The results of these interactions are plotted in the figure below, where sectors are ranked
from a very low level of competition on the left to a very high level of competition on the right.
As the figure shows, the impacts of business innovation programs clearly grow with the degree
of competition in the sector. In fact, the impact may have been negative in sectors with very low
levels of competition. These results have strong implications for innovation policy design: the
impacts of the program could have doubled if the fiscal support focused only on those sectors
with a high intensity of competition. This also points to strong complementarities between
from Chile]
Figures
Figure 3.2 Social Returns to R&D, Latin America and the Caribbean vs. the OECD
0.6
Social return rate
0.5
0.4
0.3
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Source: Authors' calculations based on Griffith, Redding, and Van Reenen (2004).
𝑝
𝑅 𝑅 𝑅 𝑅
𝑖𝑡∆𝐴 1 =ƿ − +δ 𝑙𝑛 −
1 +∑3 δ −
ƿ=1 2𝑝 x 𝑙𝑛 −
Note: Estimates are based on the following model: 𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1 𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1 𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1 𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1, where A is total factor
productivity, R is research and development investment, and AF is the productivity frontier. In this model, the social return rate to
R&D has two sources: its contribution to innovation, which that pushes 𝑅
the technological
𝑅
𝑝 frontier; and the creation of absorptive
capacities for technology transfer. In other words, 𝑆𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑡 = ƿ1 + ∑3ƿ=1 δ2𝑝 − x 𝑙𝑛 − . The results are based of OLS estimates.
𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1 𝑌 𝑖𝑡 −1
Results using instrumental variables (with the Ginarte and Park IPR protection Index and the Productivity Frontier as instruments)
were qualitatively similar. OLS are more conservative than IV estimates.
Table 3.1 Explaining the Gaps in Business R&D: The OECD vs. Latin America and
the Caribbean (percent of the total GAP)
Financial development
26.9 15.3
Production structure
10.7 26.0
Residual 9.5 9.2
Total 100 100
Source: Authors' calculations based on Lederman and Saenz (2005); OECD (2010); World Bank (2010b); IDB (2010);
RICYT (2013).
Note: The contribution to the gaps is based on a model, 𝑦𝑖𝑡 = 𝑋𝑖𝑡 β𝑡 + 𝐿𝐴𝐶𝐼 δ𝑡 + τ + ε𝑖𝑡 where Y is business
R&D as a percentage of GDP, X is a vector of variables described in the text, and LAC is a dummy variable
identifying Latin American and Caribbean countries, capturing a residual gap that is not explained by the above-
mentioned variables.
a. The main variables are measured as follows: (i) knowledge is built by accumulating publicly performed R&D per
worker; (ii) human capital is approximated by average years of schooling in the labor force (due to data constraints,
human capital is not corrected by quality); (iii) financial development is measured by the intensity of credit to the
private sector; and (iv) production structure is measured by using the proportion of high-tech manufacturing on
value added.
Table 3.2 Innovation Policies in Developed Countries: A Taxonomy
TYPE
Horizontal Vertical
Higher education/Training. Technological institutes
Support to scientific research. (agriculture, industry, energy,
Public good
Intellectual property rights. fishing, etc). Standardization.
Research infrastructure. Human Thematic funding. Signalling
capital inmigration. Labor training. strategies. Information diffusion
S
Competition policy. Regulation. policies (extension systems).
C
Technology transfer organization. Technological consortiums.
O Contests
P
R&D subsidies, R&D tax credits. Public procurement. General
Market intervention
Impacts Reduce marginal cost of R&D activities. Reduce marginal cost of R&D activities.
Collaboration Funding can be targeted toward collaboration. Deduction can also target collaboration.
Fully market friendly mechanism. The firm decides. It might be biased
Spillovers Funding can be targeted toward projects with high spillovers.
towards more privately appropriable projects.
Funding can provide partial cash advances (relaxing liquidity They operate fully ex post, and are less suitable to solve financial
Liquidity constraints
constraints). constraints.
Funding can provide "signalling" to external investors. No signalling.
High (funding can be targeted toward firms with innovation problems, Low (effectiveness depends on the general tax context of the country,
Focus
such as innovative SMEs or start-ups). other tax exemptions and loopholes) and biased toward larger firms.
Implementation costs High ex ante and ex post. Low ex ante but high ex post.
Institutional capacities High capabilities ain innovation agencies. Lower capabilities in innovation agencies, but higher in tax authority
Firm capacities High (to formulate a project) High (to identify an innovation program)
Uncontrolled, the fiscal costs depend on decisions taken by the firms.
Fiscal costs Controlled costs and transparent. Funding targets the marginal project. When based on volume, subsidies go to intra marginal projects as
well.They make the fiscal system more complex.
They create an incentive to artificially classify non R&D expenses as
Moral hazard Financing can go to firms that do not face market failures.
R&D which may not be easy to control for tax authorities.
Implementation of cofunding schemes (matching grants) with nominal Base the incentives on R&D growth rather than volume or establish a
limits and a list of elegible expenses. project-based decision making process similar to subsidies.
Subsidy rate proportional to the size of spillovers (e.g. higher in public
Good design practices goods, generic research or collaborative projects). Build monitoring and evaluation capacities in the tax authority
Include in the deduction a premium for externalities (e.g. collaboration or
Implementation of a competitive allocation process (call for proposals). the hiring of R&D personnel).
Transparent allocation by a public-private council based on evaluations
Inclusion of carry-forward provisions or cash conversions for new firms.
by external and independent peer reviewers.
Capacity building in firms for project formulation and setting of Predict the fiscal cost and inlude it in the budget, setting a transparent
milestones for funding. mechanism to allocate the credits when the demand is higher than supply.
Include a sunset clause with a careful monitoring and evaluation system. Include a sunset clause with a careful monitoring and evaluation system.
Source: Authors’compilation based on Lederman and Saenz (2005); OECD (2010); World Bank (2010b); IDB (2010); RICYT (2013).
Table 3.4 Effects on Innovation Investment (Input Additionality): Testing for Crowding-in/Crowding-out Effects
Country Evaluation Program Inte rve ntion Be ne ficiarie s Indicator Impact Crowding Me thod
pe riod name in/out
Argentinaa 1994-2001 FONT AR-T MP1 Subsidized loan Firms Ln (total R&D) 0.15** In FE-IV
Argentinab 1998-2006 FONT AR-ANR Matching grants Firms Ln (private innov exp) 0.18* In FE-CS
Panamac 2000-2003 FOMOT EC Matching grants Firms Ln (T otal R&D) 0.15** No evidence FE-CS
Uruguay d 2000-2006 PDT -I Matching grants Firms Ln (private innov exp) 0.84** In FE-CS
Mexico e 2004-2007 EFIDT R&D tax credit Firms Ln (private R&D) 0.25** In FE
Colombiaf 2000-2002 T ax Incentives R&D tax credit Firms Ln (private R&D) 0.06** In SM
Argentinag 1995-2001 FONT AR CFF R&D tax credit Firms Ln (private R&D) 0.13*** In FE
Brazilh 2005-2010 LEI-DO-BEM R&D tax deduction Firms Ln (R&D employment) 0.07*** in FE
Brazilh 2001-2008 LEI da Informatica R&D tax deduction Firms Ln (R&D employment) 0.01 out FE-CS
Argentinai 1994-2004 FONT AR CFF R&D tax credit Firms (T otal R&D $) 1.90** In SM
Argentinaj 2001-2004 FONT AR-ANR Matching grants Firms (T otal R&D intensity) % 0.18** No evidence DID-PSM
Brazilk 1996-2003 ADT N Subsidized loan Firms (Priv. R&D intensity) % 0.66** In PSM
Brazill 1999-2003 FNDCT Matching grants Firms & UNIV (Priv. R&D intensity) % 1.63** In PSM
Chilem 1998-2002 FONT EC Matching grants Firms (T otal R&D intensity) % 0.74* Partial out DID-PSM
Panaman 2006-2008 SENACYT Matching grants Firms (T otal R&D intensity) % 0.13** In PSM
Colombiao 2002-2003 COFINANCIACION Matching grants Firms & UNIV (T otal R&D Intensity) % 1.20* In PSM
Source: Authors’ compilations based on the studies noted. aChudnovsky et al. (2006). b López, Reynoso, and Rossi (2010). cMaffioli, Pusterla, and Ubfal
(2011). d CENIT and CPA Ferrere (2010). eCalderón-Madrid (2011). fMercer-Blackman (2008). g Binelli and Maffioli (2007). h Kannebley and Porto (2012).
i
Giuliodori and Giuliodori (2012). j Chudnovsky et al. (2006). k de Negri, Borges Lemos, and de Negri (2006a). l de Negri, Borges Lemos, and de Negri
(2006b). mBenavente, Crespi, and Maffioli (2007). n Crespi, Solís, and Tacsir (2011). o Crespi, Maffioli, and Meléndez (2011).
Note: FE-IV (Fixed Effects, instrumental variable), FE-CS (Fixed Effects and common support), FE (Fixed Effect), SM (Structural Modelling), DID-PSM
(Difference in Difference, Propensity Score Matching), PSM (Propensity Score Matching). In the case of the evaluation of SENACYT-Panama, total R&D
intensity is computed as R&D as a fraction of total innovation sales. UNIV stands for universities. *** 1% significance level, ** 5% significance level, *
10% significance level.
Table 3.5 Output Additionality: Testing for Productivity Impacts
e
0.19***
Argentina 1996-2008 PRE T EP Firms Ln(employment) FE-CS
0.22***
0.02***
Argentinae 1996-2008 PRE T EP Firms Ln(wages) FE-CS
0.04***
f
Mexico Add PNAA T FP-Full subs. Firms Ln(wages) 0.05*** FE-CS
Mexico f Add CIMO T FP Firms Ls(sales) -0.05*** FE-CS
Perug Add BONOPYME T FP Firms Ln(sales) 0.16*** FE-CS
Perug Add CIT E-Calzado T FP Firms Ln(sales) No effect FE-CS
Colombiah Add FOMIPYME T FP Firms Exports 0.40*** FE-CS
Chilei Add FAT T FP Firms Ln(wages) 0.09*** FE-CS
Chilei Add PROFO-PDP T FP Firms Ln(wages) 0.08*** FE-CS
Argentinaj 2002-06 PROSAP T EP-Full subs. Grape producers Probability of adopting new variety 0.03** FE
k
14**
Uruguay 1999-2006 PREDEG T EP-Part subs. Fruit producers Adoption of new varieties FE-CS
9.3*
l
Uruguay 1999-2006 PREDEG T EP-Part subs. Fruit producers Density of plantation 108.5** FE-CS
Uruguay m 2001-03 LPP T EP-Part subs. Livestock producers Adoption of managerial practices 25.3**/18.74** FE-CS
Note: FE-CS (Fixed Effects and common support), FE (Fixed-Effects). UNIV stands for universities. Full subs stands for full subsidies. Part sub
stands for partial subsidies. *** 1% significance level, ** 5% significance level, * 10% significance level.
Source: Authors’ compilations based on the studies noted. aCrespi, Maffioli, and Meléndez (2011). b Parra Torrado (2011). cÁlvarez, Crespi, and
Cuevas (2012). d Maffioli, Pusterla, and Ubfal (2011). eCastillo et al. (2014a). fLópez-Acevedo and Tinajero-Bravo (2011). g Jaramillo and Díaz (2011).
h
Duque and Muñoz (2011). i Tan (2011). j Maffioli et al. (2011). k Maffioli et al. (2013). l Maffioli et al. (2013). mLópez and Maffioli (2008).
Table 3.6 The Search for Spillovers
Notes: FE-CS (Fixed Effects and common support), RE-DYN (Random Effects with dynamics). *** 1% significance level, ** 5% significance level, *
10% significance level.
Source: Authors’ compilations based on studies noted. aCastillo et al. (2014b). b Ingtec and USP Research Group (2013).
Table B3.3.1 Basic Rules to Allocate Funding to Innovation Projects: The Case of FONTAR
Risk
Characteristics
Tangibles
Intangibles
0.05
0.03
0.01
-0.01
1 2 3 4
Quartiles of the competition index based on Lerner index: 1-low to 4-high
1
This is an average figure. Not all countries report these figures for every year. So for some countries, data begin in
1999. In others, data end in 2008.
2
Once produced, new knowledge can be used simultaneously by many different firms because the new “blueprints”
are not normally associated with physical constraints. This characteristic is an extreme form of decreasing marginal
costs as the scale of use increases: although the costs of the first use of new knowledge may be large, in that it
includes the costs of its generation, further use can be done at negligible small incremental costs (Aghion, David,
and Foray, 2009).
3
The nonexcludable nature of knowledge refers to the difficulty and cost of trying to retain exclusive possession of
it while, at the same time, putting it to use.
4
Technological knowledge is also more likely to be protected by intellectual property rights (IPRs). IPRs provide
innovating firms the right to temporarily exclude others from using a new idea commercially so the originators can
appropriate the rents of their investments in innovation. In exchange for this, the owner must disclose the invention
so anyone can improve upon it. However, IPRs can also generate unintended consequences, as they cause a static
market distortion in the form of monopoly power and slower technology diffusion for producers that must pay a
higher cost to transfer protected technology. In other words, IPRs also create market distortions that might or might
not be compensated by the increased incentives to innovate (De Ferranti et al., 2003).
5
It has also been suggested that traditional R&D statistics do not capture the innovation effort carried out by natural
resource–intensive industries well. For example, investments in mining prospecting are not considered part of R&D,
so mining is an activity that is more knowledge-intensive than the official statistics suggest. Given that the bulk of
Latin American countries are very intensive in these activities, this measurement problem may overestimate the gap
between the typical Latin America country and say, South Korea. However, when the comparison is done with
developed countries well-endowed with natural resources, such Australia and Canada, the investment gaps remain
and are still significant. Accordingly, the natural resource curse is not the explanation for the gap.
6
In both periods there is a residual not explained by those variables included in the analysis. Several omitted factors
are included in this residual. For example, Katz (2001) puts forward the hypothesis that macroeconomic volatility
typical of the Latin American and Caribbean development process might have affected entrepreneurs’ “animal
spirits,” making them reluctant to spend on highly risky and sunk investments such as R&D. An alternative
hypothesis could be the differences in the size distribution of firms. Unfortunately, the authors lack detailed
comparable information of R&D by size of the firm, and thus could not include this factor in the analysis.
7
An early example of this is the U.S. decision to upgrade agricultural productivity through the land-grant
universities during the second half of the 19th century (with the passing of the Morrill Act of 1862 by Congress).
Another example is the establishment of Israel’s Institute of Technology (Technion) during the early 1920s.
8
Such as energy technologies, microelectronics, aerospace, health and, in some cases, the defense sector.
9
Such as the National Institute of Industrial Technology (INTI) and the National Institute for Agricultural
Technology (INTA) of Argentina, the Agricultural Research Corporation (EMBRAPA) of Brazil, the Technological
Institute (INTEC) of Chile, and the Institute for Industrial Technology and Technical Norms (ITINEC) of Peru.
10
The fact that knowledge is a public good does not necessarily mean that it needs to be provided by the public
sector, at least in its entirety.
11
Conditional loans are a risk-sharing financial instrument by which loans could be partially or even totally written
off on the basis of three criteria: the success of the investment, the technological risk, and spillovers of an innovation
project. In Israel, for example, the repayment of conditional loans is done through royalties of between 2 percent to
5 percent of the sales of the innovated product until the original grant is fully repaid.
12
A nice feature of subsidies is that they can also provide signaling on the quality of an externally assessed
innovation project. Tax incentives are normally ex post, so they are less suitable to alleviate financial constraints and
have no signaling power.
13
Several evaluations in developed countries suggested that indeed this could be the case (Irwin and Klenow, 1996;
Branstetter and Sakakibara, 1998; Czarnitzki and Fier, 2003).
14
In the OECD (2005b) framework, the concept of “fully developed outside” is close in spirit to the idea of
“innovation new to the firm.”
15
See Ezell and Atkinson (2011) for a review on this topic. The earliest examples of technology extension programs
are found in agriculture both in continental Europe and the United States (Steinmueller, 2010).
16
In a similar line, several developed countries have put in place fiscal incentives (mostly in the form of a tax
deduction) on those profits generated from IPRs royalties or sales (see, for example, the UK Patent Box act)
17
See, for example, Lach, Parizat, and Wasserteil (2008) and Mohnen and Lokshin (2010).
18
For evidence on the effectiveness of business innovation programs in developed countries, see the summaries by
David, Hall, and Toole (2000) and Westmore (2013).
19
Chudnovsky et al. (2006) found that crowding-in effects were particularly strong in the case of new innovators.
20
In particular, propensity score matching (PSM) techniques.
21
Chapter 8 discusses the potential benefit of combining and sequencing innovation and export promotion
programs.
22
This evaluation links beneficiary data with Argentina’s social protection dataset. This allows the beneficiaries and
controls to be tracked over a long period of time at low cost. The trade-off is that productivity as such cannot be
measured. In this chapter, productivity is approximated by the average wages paid by the firm.
23
For more on PROFO, see Chapter 7.
24
This is particularly true when measures of technology adoption such as the one reported in Table 3.5 are
considered. Less conclusive are the findings on yields. In many cases, yields seem not to be affected in the short run
(which, in some cases in the only time frame considered in the evaluations), but increased over longer periods. The
available evidence seems to confirm that also for agricultural TEPs, positive effects on productivity require a certain
period of gestation; in the short run, producers may experience some adjustment costs to the new technology and
practice, which may lead to null or even negative short-run effects on productivity.
25
Given that spillovers surround scientific and generic technological research, there is clearly a role for public
research and technology centers. However, without the right institutional arrangements, these organizations may end
up being captured by scientific elites and carry out their activities in complete isolation from societal needs
(Artopoulos and Navarro, forthcoming). There is some consensus that successful public research and technology
centers should have a funding mechanism that allows them to build capabilities over the long term but at the same
time also connect their research agenda to the needs and demand of the private sector. This can be achieved by
combining long-term core funding regulated by performance agreements negotiated every four to five years with
competitive finance though matching grants funds and authorizations to provide contract research to the private
sector. Researches should also be promoted based on performance and enjoy at least some of the benefits of the
intellectual property that they are generating. Finally, and most importantly, the private sector should be represented
on the boards that control these institutions (Maloney and Perry, 2005).