Group Project Draft 2 - v2
Group Project Draft 2 - v2
Group Project Draft 2 - v2
Introduction
The Global Financial Crisis (GFC) of 2007-2008, a period of severe stress in global
financial markets, is considered by economists as the worst financial crisis since the 1930s’ Great
Depression. There is still ongoing debate on what are the exact causes of the GFC although the
market features and conditions leading to the crisis were immediately known, prompting
authorities around the world to draft and implement regulations to prevent a repeat. This paper
investigates the primary causes of the GCF, the market conditions and features characterizing
GFC, the response of policymakers and regulators, descriptions of a consequent regulation and
A financial crisis became apparent after a series of events in early 2007. The following
are the series of events during the GFC based on timelines by Guillen (2009) and Giles (2011).
It started in the United States of America where there was a deepening housing crisis. As
foreclosure rates rose, banks and hedge funds are faced with useless assets after investing heavily
in subprime mortgages. It started in February 2007 when Freddie Mac, a big player in the
mortgage sector, announced it will stop buying subprime loans considered most risky. The
financial world was shaking with a series of troubles at New Century Financial in April, French
bank BNP Paribas in August and UK’s Northern Rock in September. By 2008, the US economy
was experiencing recession. In January, the US Federal Reserve stepped in to prop up the
2008, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taken over by the government while several other
banks in the US and the UK went down before US Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson used the
3
$700bn Troubled Asset Relief Program to purchase bad assets in the US. UK also bailed out
several banks in October. Recession followed in Ireland, the US and the UK (Guillen 2009, Giles
2011).
condition in the market. These include (1) a contagion across assets, (2) increase in counterparty
risk, (3) credit rationing, and (4) deleveraging through capital outflow (Blanchard 2009).
Contagion across Assets. During a financial crisis, there is a steady growth in volatility
across assets. High volatility in the price of the asset results from a sudden decrease in the price
of the asset relative to its past average value. High volatility is a signal of growing financial
doubt and associated with policy uncertainty leading to reduced investment, production and
investment. It also delays investment since high volatility increases the value to invest in real
Increase in Counterparty Risk. Counterparty risk between banks refers to a rise in the
perceived odds that a bank’s loan from another bank may not be repaid. This is indicated by an
increase in the average rate banks charge each other for loans and the rate at which government
can borrow. During a brewing financial crisis, banks tend to attempt to keep sufficient cash on
hand and limit their reliance on loans from other banks. Thus, along with the increased
counterparty risk perception, there is also a reduction in the maturity of loans that banks are
Credit Rationing. A worsening financial crisis is also affected by credit rationing or the
constriction of lending standards by banks. This is due to deleveraging by banks, another feature
4
of financial crises discussed below. In other words, credit rationing is a condition wherein
lenders are reluctant to forward extra funds to borrowers at the ongoing market interest rate.
the case of the GFC, credit rationing for firms and households occurred somewhere around mid-
sectors, via large capital outflows can cause a steep rise in indebtedness. Discrepancy in
exchange rate then exacerbates the condition, further burdening all types of debtors such as
The abovementioned market features and conditions during a financial crisis were also
present during the GFC. Causes that originate from excessive investments in subprime assets and
subsequent volatility led to these market features and conditions as described below.
Low to High Asset Volatility. Low volatility increases the likelihood of a financial crisis.
Since volatility is a factor in risk management practices, a period of low volatility encourages
financial institutions to bet on riskier positions, increasing their balance sheet leverage.
Therefore, during low volatility periods, financial agents who aim for higher gains tend to lend
more or place from safer to riskier assets. In other words, extended periods of low-volatility is
considered to cultivate optimism and excessive lending, thus, increasing the probability of a
financial crisis (Danielsson et al. 2018). Before the GFC, low volatility in the subprime
mortgages led to a sustained credit boom - the primary cause of the GFC - behind excessive
5
lending and move towards riskier assets. In the end, the large boom episode resulted in the high
Shrinking Assets and Counterparty Risk. During the GFC, banks were reluctant to lend
each other - because of the risks and uncertainties associated with the volatility in the marked -
which was observed from the middle of 2007 onwards, especially in the US and the UK. A spike
in 3-month Libor and the three-month Tbill rates was noted when the US government let the
large, systemic bank Lehman Brothers fail and file for bankruptcy in September 2008, an
Credit Spread and Credit Rationing. Due to the subprime volatility, there was a large
decrease in the values of the financial institution’s asset holdings during the GFC. As a result, a
drastic intensification of agency troubles in these financial institutions as well as, to a lesser
extent, nonfinancial firms. Consequently, there was widening of credit spreads and proliferation
of credit rationing. Huge cutbacks on all types of investments, thus, occurred (Hall 2010).
Domestic and Sovereign Deleveraging. Over the course of the GFC, deleveraging not
only occurred in domestic credit but also in sovereign credit which made the financial crisis of
2007-2008 a global crisis. In the said process, first-world country banks dramatically reduced
their exposure to emerging markets through closing of credit lines and repatriation of funds.
Selling exploded across the board resulting in the steep rise in the premium especially for
counties with extensive current account deficits (Blanchard 2009), considered one of the deeper
In response to the GFC, policymakers and regulators have attempted to repair the damage
done to financial systems and economies through the implementation of a range of reforms at the
6
international and domestic levels. Key reforms that have been completed through the Financial
1. Basel III Capital Requirements (discussed in detail below) as well as adoption of a capital
Basel III Capital Requirements. The Basel framework is comprised of three pillars; these
are Pillar 1 which establishes the computations of regulatory capital requirements for risk
involving credit, market and operation, Pillar 2 which establishes how a bank should assess its
capital adequacy and pursue actions based on assessments, and Pillar 3 which establishes the
bank disclosure requirements to foster market discipline (Achterberg & Heintz 2012). In 2010,
the main features of the Basel III included stipulations to increase capital level and quality,
improve risk capture, restrict bank leverage, enhance bank liquidity and restrain procyclicality. In
2017, revisions to risk capture feature to include standard approaches to computing risks and
bank leverage feature to include higher leverage ratio requirements for G-SIFIs were made
(BCBS 2018).
7
The above provisions of Basel III follow the general theme and rationale of financial
regulation by dealing with several failures in the existing pre-crisis regulatory structure and at the
same time introducing groundwork for a robust banking system that will ensure that build-up of
One of the downsides to the Basel III is a disruption to the credit supply to the economy
due to the implementation of the new regulations. Furthermore, long-term growth of the
economy will be adversely affected if small businesses do not have access to finance due to
reduced available loans and elevated credit risk premiums (Chan et al. 2012). Basel III is also
seen to negatively affect the liquidity management practices by banks thus restricting banks’
ability to freely control balance sheets soon and possibly dampening fund movement into new
Despite these unintended effects, there could be benefits in the long term since Basel III’s
aim is to ensure a stable economy. A stable economy could ease access to bank lending. An
economic environment with less fluctuation results in a reduced volatility in credit supply to
Policy and Regulatory Responses: Intended Effects, Features Needing Regulation and
Downsides of Implementation
As mentioned above, policies and regulations such as the Basel III were intended to build
a stable economy and prevent a repeat of the GFC. According to Blanchard (2009), generally, the
reforms are aimed at lowering the fragility of the financial system without severely hampering its
efficiency. The liquidity provisions and government interventions are put in place to dampen the
8
derivative securities more complex to ensure a better allocation of risk. Another objective is to
decrease leverage. Since leverage before the GFC was too high, regulation is therefore needed to
According to above assumptions, liquidity, derivative securities and leverage are features
of the financial market that need regulation. One other important feature is asset price and credit
booms, both are known to be controlled by proper, active monetary policy (Blanchard 2009).
A couple of downsides have already been described above regarding the Basel III. Other
unintended effects of financial regulations and policies include possible lessening of competition
as avoidance by firms of markets they would have entered without policies and regulations
(Garrona 2015).
Financial crisis is preceded by periods of low volatility in asset values and subsequent
underestimation of risks. In this scenario, asset bubbles and credit booms typically followed by
asset volatility and contagion, increased counterparty risk, credit rationing and deleveraging that
constitute a financial crisis. The GFC is not exempt in these indicators and market features. Thus,
policies and regulations such as the Basel III were put in place to prevent a repeat and foster a
stable economy. However, downsides and unintended effects are probable in the implementation
of reforms such as disruption of credit supply and long-term economic growth. Nonetheless, ease
of access could result from a stable economy brought about by policies and regulations.
9
Therefore, disruptions and slow economic growth in the short term are sacrifices that the
financial world should endure to reap the long-term benefits of the highly-needed reforms.
References
Achterberg, E., Hans Heintz. (2012). Basel III - An easy to understand summary. RiskQuest.com.
BCBS. (2018). Finalising Basel III: In brief. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Bank for
on 26 July 2018.
Blanchard, O. (2009). The crisis: Basic mechanisms and appropriate policies. CESifo Forum,
Chan, K., Allen, B., Milne, A. and Thomas, S. (2012). Basel III: Is the cure worse than the
Claessens, S. and Kodres, L. E. (2014). The regulatory responses to the global financial crisis:
Claessens, S., Dell’Ariccia, G., Igan, D., Laeven, L. (2010). Lessons and policy implications
from the global financial crisis. IMF Working Paper 10/44, Washington, DC.
Danielsson, J., Valenzuela, M., and I. Zer. (2018). Learning from history: Volatility and financial
crises. The Review of Financial Studies, Volume 31, Issue 7, 1 July 2018, Pages 2774–
2805, https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhy0494
10
Garonna, P. (ed). (2015). The costs and benefits of financial regulation: Towards a monitoring
Giles, M. (2011). A participatory teaching strategy: Developing a timeline of the global financial
Guillen, M.F. (2009). The global economic & financial crisis: A timeline. The Lauder Institute,
https://lauder.wharton.upenn.edu/wp.../Chronology_ Economic_Financial_Crisis.pdf on
25 July 2018.
Hall, R.E. (2010). Why does the economy fall to pieces after a financial crisis? The Journal of
König, P. & D. Pothier (2016). Design and pitfalls of basel’s new liquidity rules. DIW Economic
Bulletin, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research, vol. 6(21), pages 251-
259.
Reinhart, C.M. (2012). A series of unfortunate events: Common sequencing patterns in financial