Interstate System
Interstate System
Interstate System
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
The International Studies Association, Wiley are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,
preserve and extend access to International Studies Quarterly
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Interstate System and
Capitalist World-Economy
One Logic or Two?
CHRISTOPHER CHASE-DUNN
Department of Social Relations
Johns Hopkins University
This essay argues that capitalism is best conceived as a peculiar combination of economic
and political processes which operate at the level of the world economy as a whole. Thus
the interstate system is the political side of capitalism, not an analytically autonomous
system, and its survival is dependent on the operation of the institutions which are
associated with the capital-accumulation process. The argument for this approach is made
as a prelude to further discussion, theoretical clarity, and empirical research. The point of
this project is to distinguish between theories which conceptualize the modern world in
terms of economic and political subsystems and those which regard capitalism as a system
in which political and economic processes can be understood to have a single, integrated
logic.
1. Core areas are those where core production is concentrated, while peripheral areas
contain mostly peripheral production. Core production is capital-intensive and uses
skilled, high-wage labor. Peripheral production is labor-intensive and utilizes low-wage
labor which is often subject to extra-economic coercion. Cotton textile production, a
leading core industry of the early nineteenth century, has become a peripheral industry in
the twentieth century relative to the much higher levels of capital intensivity and skilled
labor employed in contemporary core industries. Semi-peripheral areas are those states
which include a balance of core and peripheral types of production.
19
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
20 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
2. Marxian theory has usually disdained the seemingly artificial distinctions between
economics and politics which have become enshrined in the academic disciplines. Marx
asserted a holism of the underlying processes operating in a mode of production. But the
use of a deterministic logic to justify alleged necessity by Soviet ideologues added fuel to
the revolt against "economism" which had begun with Luxemburg, Gramsci, and Lukacs.
Poulantzas (1973) and Anderson (1974) seem to take this theoretical tendency to its most
extreme point within Marxism. Barker (1978) and von Braunmuehl (1979) and the other
German "state derivation" theorists are attempting to reintegrate the new theories of the
state by utilizing Marx's basic theoretical concepts to account for the operation of
capitalist states. Von Braunmuehl has done the most interesting work at the conceptual
level to integrate specifically the role of the larger state system with the operation of the
world market within a framework of basic Marxian concepts. McGowan and Walker
(1980) have written a useful review and synthesis of Marxian and non-Marxian
approaches to "international political economy." Rapkin (1980) has also suggested a
synthesis of "materialist and security-oriented approaches."
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 21
the world market play an integrated role. This article will raise a number
of methodological and metatheoretical issues, argue for a redefinition of
the capitalist mode of production, and discuss evidence for the
interdependence of the interstate system and the capital accumulation
process.
The world-system perspective has not been formalized as a theory of
capitalist development, and indeed some of its proponents seem hesitant
to move in this direction. My own work (Chase-Dunn and Rubinson,
1977, 1979) has attempted to move toward formalization so that the
empirical implications of the world-system perspective can be clarified
and research on specifically theoretical issues can begin. This article
develops theoretical implications with regard to the relationship
between the interstate system and the capitalist accumulation process,
and much of what follows may appear ex cathedra to those not familiar
with world-system studies. Many questions raised by this perspective
have not been asked in quite the same way by students of international
relations. I hope to begin an interdisciplinary dialogue which can
identify the important theoretical issues and the differentiating empiri-
cal implications.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
22 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 23
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
24 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
But a different perspective is adopted here, one which holds that nation-
states are, more fundamentally, organizations geared to maintain control
of home territories and populations and to undertake actual or potential
military competition with other states in the international system. The
international states system as a transnational structure of military
competition was not originally created by capitalism. Throughout
modern world history, it represents an analytically autonomous level of
transnational reality-interdependent in its structure and dynamics with
world capitalism, but not reducible to it.
Modelski (1978) and Zolberg (1979) argue even more strongly for the
autonomy of the state system in opposition to what they see as
Wallerstein's economic reductionism. These authors raise the important
question about the extent to which it is theoretically valuable to
conceptualize economic and political processes as independent sub-
systems, but in so doing they oversimplify Wallerstein's perspective.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 25
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
26 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
4. This definition of the capitalist mode of production as including both core and
peripheral forms of labor control is, without doubt, a major revision of Marx's theory. It
has been opposed most forcefully by LeClau (1977), who characterizes peripheral areas as
participating in the world capitalist economy but not subject to the fully developed
capitalist mode of production. Wallerstein's approach implies that the core-periphery
relationship is much more than a transitional stage by which areas are reorganized into
core-type capitalism His argument implies that the reproduction of specifically peripheral
types of capitalism is a necessity for containing class struggle within the core. Exploitation
of the periphery enables core capitalists to reward core workers with income and political
rights, which creates a relative harmony of class relations in the core (see also Galtung,
1971). This is not a static situation, however, as the business cycles and uneven
development which characterize capitalist accumulation constantly shift the terms of class
and international regimes.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 27
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
28 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 29
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
30 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
successful core states have been those that combined a relatively strong
world-economy-oriented bourgeoisie with a relatively decentralized
state. Tardanico (1978) has argued that the extent to which a state is
supported during a military emergency by the class fractions6 which
form its "center coalition" ("power bloc" in Poulantzas's terms) should
be considered a dimension of state strength. This problem can best be
handled by observing that there is a certain differentiation among core
states in the type of development path followed. Some rely more on
geopolitical military advantage and centralized and effective fiscal
structures, while others-the more successful ones-rely on low over-
head decentralized states which act efficiently to protect and extend the
vital business interests of their national capitalists. Lane's (1979)
concept of "protection rent" is relevant here. Some states provide
effective protection at or near "cost" and allow the profitable operation
of the businesses under their protection. Others are less efficient and less
effective even though they may be better able to extract taxes from their
own citizens.
Thus, core states are strong relative to peripheral states, but some are
stronger vis-a-vis their own internal capitalist class fractions than
others. The most successful core nations have achieved their hegemony
by having strong and convergent business class interests which unified
state policy behind a drive for successful commodity production and
trade with the world market. Second-runners have often achieved some
centrality in the world economy by relying on a more state-organized
attempt to catch up with the "caretaker" states in terms of political and
economic hegemony. Skocpol's (1977) emphasis on the less autocratic
form of development in the most successful states does not lend support
to the contention that geopolitics and capital accumulation are
autonomous from one another, although success is perhaps not the best
criterion for determining the nature of capitalism as a system. For this
we need to focus on the dynamics and relationships operating in the
system as a whole, not in its parts, the national societies.
It may be argued that the existence of states which successfully follow
an exclusively political-military development path is evidence in favor
of the thesis that geopolitical and economic processes operate indepen-
dently. The existence of such a development path is unquestionable (for
example, Prussia, Sweden, Japan, U.S.S.R.), but the upward mobility
of these states was certainly conditioned by their context, a world
6. Class fractions are defined by Poulantzas (1973) as interest groups within classes.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 31
The competitive state system serves several functions which allow the
capitalist accumulation process to overcome temporarily the contra-
dictions it creates, and to expand. The balance of power in the interstate
system prevents any single state from controlling the world economy,
and from imposing a political monopoly over accumulation. This
means that "factors of production" cannot be constrained to the degree
that they could be if there were an overarching world state. Capital is
subjected to controls by states, but it can still flow from areas where
profits are low to areas where profits are higher. This allows capital to
escape the political claims which exploited classes attempt to impose on
it. If workers are successful in creating organizations which enable them
to demand higher wages, or if communities demand that corporations
spend more money on pollution controls, capital can usually escape
these demands by moving to areas where there is less opposition. This
process can also be seen to operate within federal nation-states. Class
struggles are most often oriented toward and constrained within
particular territorial state structures.
Thus the state system provides the political underpinning of the
mobility of capital, and also the institutional basis for the continuing
expansion of capitalist development. States which successfully prevent
capital from migrating do not necessarily solve this problem, because
capital from other sources may take advantage of the less costly
production opportunities outside the national boundaries, and push the
domestic products out of the world market.
This implies that capitalism is not possible in the context of a single
world state, or rather that such a system would eventually develop a
political regulation of resource allocation which would more regularly
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
32 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
7. On the prior origins of the state system Zolberg (1979) is ambiguous. At one point
he argues that the formation of the world economy contributed to the crystallization of the
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 33
state system, while at other points he refers to the prior existence of states and the logic of
military expansion. He is lumping together considerations of the balance of power
mechanism with the clearly more ancient state-building strategies of military conquest.
Skocpol waffles on the issue of the autonomy of the state system. In her text (quoted
above) she seems to assert that the state system and the logic of geopolitical domination
are substantially autonomous from the capital accumulation process, but in a footnote
(1979: 299) she approvingly quotes Otto Hintze, "the affairs of the state and of capitalism
are inextricably interrelated, . . . they are only two sides, or aspects, of one and the same
historical development." This is orthodox Wallersteinism.
8. The exchange of preciosities involves exchanging goods which have little labor
value to their producers but great value to their consumers. Mandel (quoted in Ftank,
1979) refers to this as an exchange of "unequals" which occurs before social systems
interact substantially such that their divisions of labor come to be integrated sufficiently to
produce what Marx (1967) referred to as "abstract labor"-the equivalence of qualita-
tively different types of labor in terms of a single system of value. Of course, the formation
of abstract labor and the equivalence of labor values is a slow process which is never
complete, even within an integrated commodity economy. However, in a single interactive
commodity economy there is a tendency to the exchange of equal values which subjects the
division of labor itself to periodic reorganization. The exchange of preciosities tends to
become the exchange of labor value equivalents as merchant capital "acts as a solvent on
precapitalist relations of production" (Marx, 1967). This process occurs, not automati-
cally, but with the vicissitudes of the exercise of political coercion by which areas become
integrated into the capitalist world economy and subjected to the process through which
they are made peripheral.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
34 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
features which were only later fully articulated in the capitalist mode of
production that emerged in Europe and Latin America in the sixteenth
century. One of these was the state system, which as Zolberg (1979)
agrees, only became stabilized after its emergence in Europe.
Does the continuity of the Italian state system, its failure to develop
into a world empire, constitute a case for the independence of the state
system? No-its incorporation into the emerging capitalist world
economy allowed the Italian system to evade this fate.
Skocpol's contention about the prior emergence of the interstate
system also receives support from Anderson's (1974) interpretation of
the rise of absolutist states in Western and Eastern Europe, but this
contention rides on one's definition of capitalism. Anderson holds to the
school which sees the "fully formed capitalist mode of production" as
becoming dominant only in the eighteenth century. Wallerstein's
interpretation emphasizes the extent to which "agrarian" capitalism
became dominant in the long sixteenth century with the formation of a
hierarchical division of labor between the core, Northwest Europe, and
the peripheral areas of Eastern Europe and Latin America. Anderson's
interpretation of the absolutist states in formation downplays the
importance of capitalist production in the growing cities of feudal
Europe and the emergence of agricultural production for the market in
rural areas. Wallerstein's interpretation implies that the capitalist mode
of production became the most important stimulus for change well
before the bourgeois revolutions in which explicitly capitalist interests
came to state power. Anderson's account does not deny the importance,
especially in the West, of the emergence of bourgeois sources of power
and financial support, but he chooses to call the glass half empty instead
of half full. His discussion of state formation in Eastern Europe
correctly identifies the extent to which it was reactive to the competitive
and aggressive interstate system which emerged first in the West. He
ignores, however, the importance of the developing core-periphery
division of labor for the shifts in class structure which influenced state
formation in the East.
Skocpol's contention that nation-states predated the dominance of
capitalism is clearly correct. Medieval states were present in precapi-
talist England and France. However, the emergence of the interstate
system is another matter. The balance-of-power system defined above
emerged first among the Italian city-states and later in the Europe of the
long sixteenth century, contemporaneous with the emerging dominance
of capitalism as a world economy.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 35
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
36 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 37
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
38 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
11. Modelski's explanation of the rise of hegemonic core powers in terms of a "desire
to create a global order . . . an expression of the will to power, the urge to control and to
dominate, to imprint a pattern on events," (1978: 224) also seems an unlikely candidate for
explaining much of the variance. He does not explain clearly why this desire emerges in
1500 or how it is differentially distributed to explain which nation-states came to dominate
the world economy. Modelski's (1980) more recent paper acknowledges, in principle, the
interdependence of political and economic processes, but his account continues to proceed
in terms of a "great power" theory of history which ignores the division of labor between
the core and the periphery.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 39
12. It has also been suggested that the reason hegemonic core powers do not try to
impose imperium on the whole system is their enlightened view that the multistate system
is necessary for the survival of capitalism. Disraeli is suggested as an example. I would tend
to argue that this type of consciousness can be understood as a response to the actual
dispersion of investment capital which accompanies the apex of hegemony of the leading
core state. Liberal economic and political ideology is not randomly distributed.
13. 1 would argue, in agreement with Modelski (1978) and Thompson (1980), that the
predominantly land-oriented continental expansionism of the French monarchy was not a
strategy which could lead to hegemony in the capitalist world economy. It is notable that
the overhead costs of purely geopolitical expansionism (Cox's "Florentine model" of
domination, 1959) cannot effectively compete with the low overhead strategy of allowing
a more decentralized political system to bear the costs of administration while surplus
extraction is accomplished by trade. The "Venetian model" is the one followed by the
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
40 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
states which became hegemonic core powers (Netherlands, Britain, and the United States),
while the land-oriented political centralizers have been reduced to the role of second-
runners among the core states.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Chase-Dunn / INTERSTATE SYSTEM 41
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
42 INTERNATIONAL STUDIES QUARTERLY
only when competing theories have been formulated with enough clarity
to allow them to be systematically subjected to evidence. My goal has
been to present an alternative way of conceptualizing capitalist
development in order to stimulate further discussion and research. The
attempt to create a reintegrated interdisciplinary science of political
economy is a necessary step in the project to understand (and influence)
the directions and potentialities of our present collective history.
This content downloaded from 152.32.102.177 on Mon, 14 Oct 2019 13:42:35 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms