Discussion Paper: Public Service Reforms: Trends, Challenges and Opportunities
Discussion Paper: Public Service Reforms: Trends, Challenges and Opportunities
Introduction
Need for reforms
Public service in both the developed and developing world plays a vital role in providing
public goods, such as defence, public order, property
Public service delivery has rights, macro-economic management, basic education,
acquired new dimensions as public health, disaster relief, protection of environment,
and coordinating private sector activity. A capable public
governments need to
service is essential for creating a favourable investment
respond not only to climate and facilitating people’s participation in economic
changes in the global life. As countries get more globalized governments face
environment but also to the increasingly complex and cross-cutting issues, such as
demands of an active economic volatility, climate change and migration. Wide
use of the internet has made citizens more aware and
impatient and that puts public servants under greater public scrutiny. Against this
backdrop, public service delivery has acquired new dimensions as governments need to
respond not only to changes in the global environment but also to the demands of an active
citizenry. Formulating integrated policies and their effective implementation would require
an adaptable and efficient public service that can anticipate emerging challenges and
ensure that potential strategies are informed by better understanding of future contexts. It
must also learn to empower people and be able to work with them, as traditional vertical
accountability systems can act as a major impediment to working across boundaries 1.
There is a widespread perception that public servants in many Governments have not
delivered what was expected from them. On the other hand, returns from improving
effectiveness of the government are immense. An efficient public service is necessary
(though not sufficient) for benefits to reach the socially and economically weaker sections
of the society who have fewer alternatives to services provided by government. Mere
allocation of funds for programmes that do not work effectively would be a waste of public
money unless extra efforts are spent on improving government efficiency, and also to
ensure that the poor are able to participate and put pressure on public administration to
deliver so that they receive the intended benefits.
The importance of good governance and having honest and competent public sector
institutions for a country’s economic and social development is now widely accepted.
Daniel Kaufmann, who worked as the World Bank’s Director for global governance, states
that countries that improve their governance effectiveness raise their standard of living, as
measured by per capita incomes, by about three times in the long run 2. Poorly functioning
public sector institutions and weak governance are major constraints to equitable
1 O'Flynn, Janine L., Blackman, Deborah Ann and Halligan, John, Working Across Boundaries: Barriers, Enablers,
Tensions and Puzzles (September 14, 2011). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1927666 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1927666
2 World Bank 2000: Top of Form Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank
Strategy. However growth may take place without following the route of traditional governance reforms, as in
Central Asian Republics where the growth pattern is based on export of natural resources (oil, gas) and labour-
intensive raw materials (cotton), commodities that allow high degrees of monopoly at the expense of broad-based
pro-poor economic development. See Jörn Grävingholt, 2011: The Political Economy of Governance Reforms in
Central Asia, German Development Institute
3 See module 5 of A New Synthesis of Public Administration: Serving in the 21st Century by Jocelyne Bourgon.
Kingston: School of Policy Studies and McGill-Queen's University Press , 2011 at http://www.nsworld.org/
4 Anita Karwal, Effective Public Service Delivery and e-Governance: Who Drives Whom?, at http://www.nsworld.org/
Merit-based recruitment
The concept of public service in the industrialized countries developed in the late
nineteenth century, often with the provision of municipal services of gas and water. Later,
other services such as electricity and healthcare got added. However, up to the 19th
century, there was extensive nepotism, favoritism, and political patronage attached with
the staffing and recruitment of public servants, which was often referred to as a "spoils
system". Though some of these characteristics are still prevalent in the first world
countries, things started changing with passage of time in some countries. Transition from
an oppressive to responsive bureaucracy even in these countries has not been smooth or
quick, and has taken almost a century to mature. As state functions and the number of
public servants started increasing rapidly in the post War scenario in Western Europe, the
need to make them more efficient and outcome focused was felt leading to reforms in many
developed countries, such as UK, New Zealand, and Australia. These countries, though not
many others, have aimed to make their bureaucracy have the following characteristics:
it is merit-based and politically neutral;
it is well-structured, “right-sized”, and well-paid;
it is accountable, professional, and generally free of corruption;
it is relatively autonomous, responsive, and representative; and
it is well-trained, performance-oriented, and relatively open.
5 Meredith Edwards, John Halligan, Bryan Horrigan, Geoffrey Nicoll 2012: Public Sector Governance in Australia,
ANU E Press Canberra; also Select Committee on Public Administration: Fourth Report at
http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200203/cmselect/cmpubadm/165/16505.htm
6 Shepherd Geoffrey 2003: Civil Service Reform in Developing Countries: Why Is It Going Badly? 11th International
Anti-Corruption Conference, 25-28 May, Seoul
7 This section draws heavily from Grindle Merilee S., 2010 ‘Constructing, Deconstructing, and Reconstructing
Career Civil Service Systems in Latin America’, Harvard University, March
Reforms in Brazil10
As opposed to other Latin American countries, reforms in Brazil initiated in 1995 have
been quite successful. These aimed at fiscal adjustment, making public administration more
efficient and focused on citizens’ needs and creating autonomous agencies controlled
through management performance contracts. Reforms faced political obstacles, resistance
from lower and middle civil servants, unions, leftist political and interest groups; a political
elite in fear of losing privileges; and opposition from the judiciary.
Luiz Carlos Bresser-Pereira, Minister of State Reform, was the main intellectual and
political architect of the reform. His intellectual leadership was crucial to push these
reforms into the spotlight, convince the government, shape public opinion, influence the
party members, and get the constitutional amendments approved. He was not only adept at
the technical issues but possessed political skills to sell the reforms. His proximity to the
President; and the fact that government had brought an end to a decade of unprecedented
high inflation and per capita income stagnation helped in making him succeed.
Key elements of Bresser‘s reforms included11:
gaining credibility by implementing reforms which did not depend on legislative approval
but would show immediate improvement such as information technology to manage the
payroll and tackling procurement;
de-emphasizing procedure in favour of accountability for outcomes, and greater autonomy
to managers for pursuing goals freely as opposed to close supervision and auditing at each
step;
reforming the entrance system for careers in public service by holding regular public
examinations open to university graduates;
8 Haque, M. S. (2004): Governance and bureaucracy in Singapore: Contemporary reforms and implications.
International Political Science Review, 25(2), 227-240.
9 Haque, M. S. (2003): New public management in Malaysia and Singapore. Journal of Comparative Asian
Development.
10 Simone Bunse and Verena Fritz 2012: Making Public Sector Reforms Work; Policy Research Working Paper 6174
The World Bank August
11 http://www.princeton.edu/successfulsocieties/policynotes/view.xml?id=150
12 Tom Christensen 2012: Welfare reform and ‘wicked issues’ – from coupling to de-coupling?, University of Oslo,
Rokkan Centre For Social Studies, Working paper, April
14 Tom Christensen 2012: Welfare reform and ‘wicked issues’ – from coupling to de-coupling?, University of Oslo,
Rokkan Centre For Social Studies, Working paper April; and Tom Christensen and Per Lægreid 2006: NPM and
Beyond: The Second Generation of Reforms, Paper presented at the NASPAA (National Association of Schools of
Public Affairs and Administration) annual conference October 19-21.
15 Tom Christensen and Per Lægreid 2006: NPM and Beyond: The Second Generation of Reforms, Paper presented
at the NASPAA (National Association of Schools of Public Affairs and Administration) annual conference October 19-
21
16 Halligan, J. and J. Adams (2004). “Security, capacity and post-market reforms: Public management change in
2003.” Australia Journal of Public Administration, 63(1): 85-93
18 Administrative Reforms Commission, 2008: ‘Performance Management System.’ X Report of the Second
Administrative Reforms Commission. New Delhi, Government of India.
19 The Power of Using the Right to Information Act in Bangladesh: Experiences from the Ground, World Bank, at
http://wbi.worldbank.org/wbi/Data/wbi/wbicms/files/drupal-acquia/wbi/Final%20version%20-%20The%20Benefits
%20of%20Using%20the%20RTI%20Act%20in%20Bangladesh.pdf
20 http://www.acdi-cida.gc.ca/rbm
21 GET Note: Center of Government Delivery Units, “Recently Asked Questions” Series November 2010 at
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTGOVANTICORR/Resources/3035863-1285601351606/NovemberGetNote.pdf
27 Saxena N.C. 2012, Administrative Reforms for Better Governance, National Social Watch, New Delhi
28 Saxena N.C., Nadine Speich, and Paul Steele (2005), Review of the Poverty - Environment Links Relevant to the
IUCN programme, April, IUCN, Geneva
29 Mansuri, Ghazala, and Vijayendra Rao. 2013. Localizing Development: Does Participation Work? Washington, DC:
World Bank
31 CHHIV Yiseang and Philippe LAFOSSE 2007, Deconcentration, Decentralization and Poverty Alleviation: The Case
of Cambodia, paper presented at the International Conference on "Public Administration and Governance at the
Forefront of Change: Dimensions, Dynamics, Dysfunctions and Solutions" December 5-7, Manila, Philippines
33 . There is an interesting IDS report, which asserts that “governments of countries that are administratively
decentralized (deconcentration) tend to spend a higher proportion of their revenues on pro-poor social spending
while politically decentralized states spend little on social sectors. The research concludes that “there is no
consistent, significant statistical association between the degree of fiscal decentralization and pro-poor public
spending. See Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex: www.id21.org/society/s8aas1g1.html
34 http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/decentralization/what.htm
35 http://www.ids.ac.uk/idsproject/the-political-economy-of-successful-governance-reforms
20 Public Service Reforms: Trends, Challenges and
Opportunities
isolation, causation is also in the other direction. Non-performing administration leaves
little choice to the politicians but to resort to populist rhetoric and sectarian strategies 36.
Harun37 argues that civil servants in Indonesia opposed reforms as it meant downsizing or
reduction in their wages or perks. More accurate monitoring and reporting of financial
operations were also seen as a direct threat to their income levels in Indonesia where the
dependence on non-salary, quasi-legal or illegal forms of remuneration of bureaucrats is
significant. In such countries therefore a short term goal could be ‘just enough
governance’38, where the initial focus is only on economic growth, with the aim of
addressing specific capacity and institutional constraints affecting growth, and not seeking
to address in one go all possible institutional constraints affecting delivery of government
programmes.
Conventional administrative reforms in the developing world have had a mixed record for
several reasons. A major problem is in mobilizing the kind of political and administrative
will necessary to implement them. Vested interests are able to block many reforms and
make it difficult to monitor the few that tend to get adopted. It could also be that people are
not certain about the final outcome of some of these reforms. As a result, many ambitious
reforms are proposed in official reports that are seldom acted on. Much time and money
are wasted on exercises that produce no impact on the ground.
However political pressures may also act in the positive direction if reforms result in better
outcomes for the masses. In India, for instance, lately there has been a growing realization
among some chief ministers (Bihar, Gujarat and Chhattisgarh are good examples) on the
need to improve governance, and this has paid political dividends as they have been able to
overcome anti-incumbency factors and have been able to get re-elected in the elections.
Even in these states reforms have not been to the liking of many politicians as giving up
patronage based administration in favour of building institutions has immediate costs and
gains are delayed. The successful Chief Ministers have had to keep legislative assembly
members and ministers under check, which is difficult when the state is under a coalition
regime or the ruling party is constrained by a thin margin in the assembly, or is divided
into factions. However the repeated electoral success of some chief ministers has certainly
put pressure on others to professionalise administration and deliver on their promises.
Conditions for success
The local context in both low-income and middle-income countries may favour as well as
oppose public sector reforms. Incentives for initiating public sector reforms include
globalization, regional integration, or aid dependency 39. Intensive economic growth (and
the shifts in interests and pressures accompanying it) appears to be a potentially powerful
driver for public sector reforms. Brazil, China, and India have all been undertaking a range
36 Saxena N.C. 2010, The IAS Officer – predator or victim?, Commonwealth & Comparative Politics, Vol. 48, No. 4,
November, 445–456
37 Harun 2007: Obstacles to Public Sector Accounting Reforms in Indonesia‘ Bulletin of Indonesian Economic
Studies Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 365-376
38 Brian Levy & Francis Fukuyama, 2010: Development Strategies: Integrating Governance and Growth; Policy
Research Working Paper 5196, The World Bank January
41 Jörn Grävingholt, 2011: The Political Economy of Governance Reforms in Central Asia, German Development
Institute
42 Blanca Heredia and Ben Ross Schneider 1998: The Political Economy of Administrative Reform: Building State
Capacity in Developing Countries, March, at http://lasa.international.pitt.edu/LASA98/Heredia-Schneider.pdf
43 Mansuri, Ghazala, and Vijayendra Rao. 2013. Localizing Development: Does Participation Work? Washington, DC:
World Bank
largely because of their strong civil service. Greater efficiency and effectiveness can
legitimately be demanded of public administrations in many East Asian countries. Clearly,
civil service systems in many East Asian countries cannot be considered a problem; they
are, rather, an important part of the solution to these countries’ other problems.
Though freedom of the media is limited in Malaysia, an alliance of business interests,
politicians and civil servants supported the need for efficiency and flexibility in public
services, in the interests of national development and economic growth. Mahatir, as Prime
Minister of Malaysia, explicitly rejected western style liberal democracy and yet pushed
through reforms of the civil service from early in his incumbency. China, a one-party state,
has implemented extensive public sector reforms, including reforms to recruitment,
performance pay, avoiding over-reliance on deference and hierarchy, etc. 44 Sometimes an
44 European Union, Public Sector Reform An Introduction March 2009
47 http://www.nsworld.org/findings/Why-is-a-New-Synthesis-of-Public-Administration-Needed%3F/Citizens-as-Value-
Creators
48
http://www.mckinsey.com/features/government_designed_for_new_times/leading_transformation_in_the_21st_centu
ry
49 Hybrid PPPs: Levering EU funds and private capital, January 2006, Report prepared by PricewaterhouseCoopers
LLP (“PwC”) for the World Bank
50 http://bit.ly/YrJmvK
51 http://www1.ifc.org/wps/wcm/connect/3f64d180498391a5856cd7336b93d75f/SuccessStories_MWSSweb.pdf?
MOD=AJPERES
52 Edgardo M. Favaro, 2010, USING REGIONAL INSTITUTIONS TO IMPROVE THE QUALITY OF PUBLIC SERVICES,
World Bank, Economic Policy and Debt Department, October 15
53 http://nsworld.org/findings/Building-New-Capacities-Resilience/Resilient-Public-Policies#!
prettyPhoto[examples2]/2/
55 http://wiki.dbast.com/images/4/4b/The_digital_media_and_the_reinvention_of_government.pdf
56 http://epress.anu.edu.au/narayanan/mobile_devices/ch07.html