Business School Research Paper
Business School Research Paper
Business School Research Paper
Jonathan Z. Zhang*
Oded Netzer
Asim Ansari
February 2011
Jonathan Zhang is an Assistant Professor at the Michael G. Foster School of Business, University
of Washington (email: zaozao@uw.edu). Oded Netzer is the Phillip H. Geier Jr. Associate
Professor of Business at Columbia Business School (email: on2110@columbia.edu). Asim
Ansari is the William T. Dillard Professor of Business at Columbia Business School (email:
maa48@columbia.edu).
We model the multifaceted impact of pricing decisions in B2B contexts and show
capture the short and long-term dynamics of B2B customer purchasing, our
data from an aluminum retailer. We find that customers in our dataset can be best
sensitivity and a cautious approach to ordering, and a more “relaxed” state. The
seller’s pricing decisions can transition customers between these two states. An
optimal dynamic and targeted pricing strategy based on our model suggests a 52%
commodity prices reveals that the seller should pass much of the costs to customers
when commodity prices increase, but hoard most of the profit when commodity
marketing modelers have paid scant attention to B2B issues. While the B2B sector commands
more than 50% market share of all commerce in the U.S. (U.S. Department of Commerce 2007),
only a small fraction (approximately 3.4%) of the articles in the top four marketing journals deal
with B2B contexts (LaPlaca and Katrichis 2009). Among the different marketing decisions,
pricing in B2B environments is particularly under-researched (Reid and Plank 2004). In this
paper, we address this imbalance by developing an integrated framework for modeling the
multiple impacts of pricing in B2B contexts. We then illustrate how our framework can aid
profitability.
Pricing decisions in B2B contexts are different from those within business-to-consumer
(B2C) environments on multiple facets. First, B2B settings are often characterized by highly
variable costs of goods and order sizes, the prevalence of product and service customization, and
the reliance on personal selling to cement transactions. These factors create a fertile environment
for implementing first degree and inter-temporal price discrimination. Sellers in many B2B
situations can easily vary prices across buyers and can even change prices between subsequent
purchases of the same buyer. This flexibility generates significant opportunities for sellers to
pursue long-term profitability. In contrast, B2C retailers rely on a restricted set of targeted price
Second, the B2B environment involves evolving long-term relationships between buyers
and sellers (Morgan and Hunt 1994). The development of trust in such relationships can impact
price sensitivities over time. Pricing decisions, in turn, can play a vital role in developing and
sustaining such relationships (Kalwani and Narayandas 1995). Third, transactions in B2B
markets exhibit greater complexity as the business customer typically makes several inter-related
2
decisions. Specifically, B2B buyers not only choose what, when, and how much to buy, but also
decide on how to buy. In B2B settings, buyers often choose whether to ask for a price quote
(offering the seller the opportunity to provide a price quote) or whether to order directly from the
seller without asking for a price. Such requests for a price quote allow sellers to observe demand
and price sensitivity even when a sale is not made (i.e., when a bid is made and the buyer rejects
the bid). Such data are rarely observed in B2C settings (Khan et al. 2009). Similarly, the buyer’s
decision to order directly from the seller (without observing the price) indicates the strength of
relationship. Our modeling approach accommodates this unique aspect of the buying process.
Finally, decision makers (buyers and sellers) in B2B settings are often assumed to behave
rationally (Reid and Plank 2004). Thus, while behavioral pricing theory suggests that internally
constructed reference prices play an important role in customer purchase decisions, and that loss
aversion should be considered in modeling reference price effects (Kalyanaram and Winer
1995), it is not clear whether such behavioral effects are operant in the B2B domain.
aspects of the B2B environment. Our framework models customer decisions on each potential
hierarchical Bayesian copulas (Nelsen 2006; Pitt et al. 2006; Trivedi and Zimmer 2007) to
flexibly model the four decisions (purchase timing, purchase amount, quote request, and quote
facilitate targeting, incorporates asymmetric reference price effects and other behavioral effects,
handles price endogeneity using a Bayesian analog of control functions (Park and Gupta 2009;
Petrin and Train 2010), and accommodates purchase dynamics and the short and long-term
effects of pricing using a multivariate non-homogeneous hidden Markov model (Montoya et al.
We apply our framework using longitudinal transaction data from an aluminum retailer
selling to industrial buyers. We identify two latent buying behavior states: a vigilant state
characterized by high customer price sensitivity and a cautious approach towards ordering, and a
3
relaxed state that is characterized by more direct orders and lower price sensitivity. We also find
strong evidence for asymmetric reference price effects including loss aversion and gain seeking.
Consistent with the hedonic adaptation theory (Frederick and Lowenstein 1999), we find that
buyers not only weight price losses more than gains, but also take longer to adapt to losses than
to gains. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first empirical evidence for the hedonic
adaptation theory using secondary data. We also find that the proposed model exhibits superior
We illustrate how our model can be used for computing optimal individual targeted
prices that maximize long-term customer value. The optimal pricing policy balances between
short- and long-term perspectives. In the short-term, the price is determined by the tradeoff
between converting orders to sales and the desire to increase margins. In the long-term, the seller
balances the wish to reduce prices to retain customers in the relaxed state and the wish to keep
prices high to avoid reducing internal reference prices. The optimization indicates that the
optimal dynamic targeted pricing policy can increase the seller’s profitability by as much as 52%
compared to the status-quo. We also use a counterfactual analysis to examine the firm’s optimal
pricing policy in the presence of a volatile aluminum commodity market. Volatility in the
aluminum commodity market alters the cost structure for the seller while also changing the
external reference point for buyers. Consistent with the dual entitlement principle, our simulation
results indicate that when the commodity prices increase, the seller should pass to the buyers
much of the cost increase. However, it can “hoard” some of the benefits of a cost decrease when
In summary, our research pushes forward the pricing literature in several directions. On
and control functions to effectively capture relevant aspects of the B2B settings. More
importantly, on the substantive front, it yields insights about how the short- and long-term effects
of behavioral demand parameters such as loss aversion, reference price, and latent buying
4
behavior states shape customer demands in what is traditionally considered to be “rational”
purchasing activity. Furthermore, our findings provide strong evidence for the potential to
employ value-based pricing policies, even in a traditional B2B industry characterized by cost-
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 highlights the challenges and
opportunities in investigating pricing decisions in B2B settings. Section 3 describes the data
from an industrial metal retailer. Section 4 outlines the modeling framework. Section 5 illustrates
the application of our modeling framework to the data. Section 6 describes the dynamic targeted
pricing optimization based on the estimated model and Section 7 concludes by discussing
markets, targeted pricing, pricing dynamics and reference prices. In this section, we briefly
The majority of the research on B2B pricing is conceptual and survey based (Johnston and
Lewin 1996), and scant attention is given to quantitative pricing models. The overall neglect
could stem from conflicting views about the role and importance of pricing relative to other
attributes in B2B contexts (see Lehmann and O’Shaughnessy 1974; Wilson 1994 and
Hinterhuber 2004). In this paper, we empirically investigate the multifaceted impact of pricing
Targeting and customization are emerging topics in academic research and are immensely
relevant to the world of practice. The empirical literature on targeting, however, has primarily
focused on non-price marketing actions such as catalog mailing (Gönül and Shi 1998; Simester
et al. 2006), coupons (Rossi et al. 1996; Shaffer and Zhang 1995), digital marketing campaigns
5
(Ansari and Mela 2003), B2B communication contacts (Venkatesan and Kumar 2004) and
pharmaceutical detailing and sampling (Dong et al. 2009; Montoya et al. 2010) as these
marketing actions are viewed as being naturally customizable and targetable at the individual
level. In contrast, empirical research on individually targeted pricing has been relatively sparse,
possibly due to the logistical, ethical, and legal issues concerning price discrimination in
traditional (B2C) settings. Exceptions include Zhang and Krishnamurthi (2004) and Lewis
(2005) who study pricing and promotion targeted at the segments level. Khan et al. (2009)
demonstrate the importance of individually targeting consumers and the value of both inter-
temporal and cross-sectional targeting for a mix of promotional activities. The authors note that
one of the limitations of their study is the inability to observe purchase intents that did not result
in a purchase. They also highlight the logistical problem of individually targeted pricing in the
(1986) uses reference prices to capture dynamics. Greenleaf (1995) and Kopalle et al. (1996)
study the implications of reference prices for the firm's dynamic pricing policy, Lewis (2005)
incorporates customers' forward looking expectations about future prices, and Chan and
Seetharaman (2004) model the relationship between state-dependence and pricing decisions. We
differ from these studies on several aspects. First, we use a multivariate non-homogenous HMM
to allow for dynamic pricing and to capture the enduring impact of reference prices. Second, we
leverage these dynamics to target prices both at the individual level, as well as temporally, over
repeated transactions for the same customer. Finally, most pricing models investigate the effect
investigate the impact of the seller's pricing policy and the resulting reference prices on a
The notion that consumers use reference prices in assessing the attractiveness of offers is well
established within marketing (Hardie et al. 1993; Kalyanaram and Winer 1995; Kalwani et al.
6
1990; Krishnamurthi et al. 1992; Winer 1986). The literature distinguishes between “internal”
and “external” reference prices (Mayhew and Winer 1992). External reference prices (e.g.,
MSRP, and prices of other brands) are generally observable and common to all customers,
whereas internal reference prices are assumed to be individual-specific and are often constructed
based on the customer’s observed prices on previous purchase occasions. Briesch et al. (1997)
compares several external and internal reference price mechanisms and concludes that internal
underpinnings of reference price effects (Kalawani et al. 1990; Wedel and Leeflang 1998).
Erdem et al. (2010), in contrast, proposes a “rational” explanation for reference price effects
based on quality signaling and price expectations. In behavioral pricing, the observed price in
relation to a reference price is often encoded as either a loss or a gain and can thus have an
asymmetric impact on brand choice (Kalwani et al. 1990; Putler 1992), purchase timing (Bell
Despite the voluminous literature on reference prices, these have found little application
in B2B pricing models based on the presumed "rationality" of B2B decision makers
(Kalayanaram and Winer 1995). Internal reference prices, however, can play an important role in
B2B purchasing because transactions are formally recorded by most buyers and relationships are
typically long-term in nature. In addition, we know little about the impact of ignoring reference
prices on targeting policy and performance as they have not been studied in conjunction with
targeted pricing. We further the reference price literature along several dimensions by studying
the asymmetric impacts of internal reference prices in multi-decisional contexts which permit
first-degree and inter-temporal price discrimination. We also investigate the possible long-term
effects of reference prices in a B2B context. Next, we describe our dataset and the business
7
3. Data
Our data come from an East Coast local aluminum retailer that supplies to industrial clients such
as machine shops and fabricators operating in its geographical trading area. This dataset is
typical of what is found in B2B selling in commodity markets. The data contains customer-level
information on purchase events over a 21 month period from January 2007 to September 2008. A
purchase event begins with the need for a certain quantity at a given point in time. Given this
need, the buyer either places a direct order without asking for a price quote, or may request a
price quote (usually via the phone or fax). For example, a typical direct order may be received by
the morning via a fax saying: “Send me four aluminum sheets A inch by B inch and thickness of
C inch by tomorrow afternoon”. Direct orders are generally fulfilled immediately and the
customer is charged a price determined by the seller. Alternatively, if the customer requests a
quote (i.e., an “indirect order”) the firm bids for the customer’s business, and can only “win” the
business if the customer accepts the quoted price.1 Thus, in our setting, purchase events include
not only completed transactions but also lost transactions involving quotes that were not
The company has a large number of SKUs that are defined based on the shape, thickness
and customizable size of the aluminum. Furthermore, the wholesale cost of aluminum changes
on a daily basis following the London Metal Exchange (LME). Therefore, as is typical in this
industry, the company does not maintain a price list and determines the price to charge or quote
on a case by case basis. Because of the variation in order quantities and the large number of
SKUs, a common measure for prices in this industry is a “price per pound” measure that
incorporates the cutting costs and complexity of the order. As is typical of most customer
relationship management (CRM) datasets in B2B settings, our dataset does not include
1
Discussions with the management and sales personnel in the company that provided the data revealed that
negotiations, beyond the request for the price quote and the firm initial bid, are not common. Analysis of the price
and bid quantity relative to price and quantity on the order invoice confirmed that both price and quantity rarely
changed from the original bid to the final order. This provides empirical evidence for minimal negotiation beyond
the bid process.