70ColumLRev PDF
70ColumLRev PDF
Citations:
Provided by:
LSE Library
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope of your license, please use:
Copyright Information
COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW
Vol. 70 NOVEMBER 1970 No. 7
This is an article about the remedies that our legal system provides when
men do not keep their promises. It sets out the principal options that were avail-
able as those remedies developed, describes the choices that were made, and
suggests some of the factors that influenced those choices. It will be seen that
there were seven critical choices, and that from these the reader who has the
patience to work through the analysis can deduce the bulk of the law of contract
remedies.
Why do men keep their promises? Surely for reasons as varied and com-
plex as men and promises themselves. Sometimes, like the father who promises
to take his son to the ball game, they do so because they "want" to. At other
times, like Frost's traveller on a snowy evening, they do so because they "have"
to-because they feel themselves under some compulsion.' Surprisingly, al-
though it might be supposed that at least one of the objectives of any system of
legal remedies for breach of contract would be to compel promisors to keep their
promises, our own system nevertheless purports to reject such compulsion as a
goal.
If a society were seriously concerned with compelling men to keep their
promises, it might be expected to treat a breach of contract as a crime and to
punish defaulting promisors. Ours has not done so, and in this we are representa-
* Professor of Law, Columbia Law School; B.S., 1948, Univ. of Mich.; M.A., 1949,
Yale Univ.; LL.B., 1952, Columbia Univ.; Visiting Professor of Law, Harvard Law
School, 1970-71.
1. For a discussion of "ethical," "social" and "jural" compulsions to perform promises,
see Wignore, The Scope of the Contract Concept, 43 COLUm. L. RFv. 569, 569-70 (1943).
See also Farnsworth, The Past of Promise: An Historical Introduction to Contract, 69
CoLum. L. REv. 576, 604-06 (1969).
1146 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
tive of mankind as a whole.2 Even in the communist countries, where the con-
tracts of state enterprises are designed to carry out an economic plan in which
there is the plainest public interest, breach of such a contract is not a crime.
And this is said to be true of Communist China too, although performance of
such contracts has there been declared to be a "political task" and party control
over the individual is used to assure it.s
If a society were seriously concerned with the compulsion of promisors, it
might at least be expected to impose civil penalties for breach of contract if it
chose not to impose criminal ones. The state, rather than exact the penalty itself,
might simply allow the promisee to claim a sum of money designed to punish
the defaulting promisor. The communist countries do just this in enforcing con-
tracts between state enterprises under an economic plan, by assessing a fine
against the defaulting promisor, payable to the injured promisee, as a "form of
social criticism." 4 In contrast, courts in this country, as in most of the rest of
the world, expressly reject the notion that remedies for breach of contract have
punishment as a goal, and with rare exceptions, refuse to grant "punitive dam-
ages" for breach of contract.5 In so refusing they confidently claim to be blind
to fault, and they purport not to distinguish between aggravated and innocent
breach.6 So Holmes said, "If a contract is broken the measure of damages gener-
ally is the same, whatever the cause of the breach." 7 The skeptical reader may
well ask whether even men of judicial temperament are immune from the
temptation to depart from a rule so oblivious of blame" and, indeed, some excep-
2. Criminal penalties are, however, available for some abuses of the bargaining process
itself. Thus the MODEL PENAL CODE § 223.3(a) (P.O.D. 1962? defines the crime of theft
to include deception by creation of a false impression as to 'intention or other state of
mind," but it specifically provides that "deception as to a person's intention to perform a
promise shall not be inferred from the fact alone that he did not subsequently perform
the promise."
3. Hsiao, The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China, 53 CALIF. L. REV.
1029, 1049 (1965).
4. Grossfeld, Money Sanctions for Breach of Contract in a Communist Economy, 72
YALE L.J. 1326, 1332 n.41 (1963). For other discussions of the role of such contracts, see
J.HAZARD, COMMUNISTS AND THEIR LAw ch. 13 (1969) ; Hsiao, supra note 3; Kiralfy,
A New Civil Code of the R.S.F.S.R.: A Western View, 15 INT'L & Comp. L.Q. 1116
(1966). Grossfeld discusses the shift in East German law from a system of fines added on to
compensatory damages to one of fines in lieu, at least in part, of damages, to prevent the
temptation to induce breach. Grossfeld, supra at 1340-41. Penalties under the Comecon
General Conditions, adopted for use in foreign trade by the Council for Mutual Economic
Assistance, are discussed in Hoya, The Comecon General Conditions-A Socialist Unifica-
tion of International Trade Law, 70 COLUm. L. REv. 253, 287-97 (1970). On the factors
that determine whether the aggrieved party will pursue these remedies, see Loeber, Plat
and ContractPerformance in Soviet Society, in LAw IN TH SoVIET Socm-= 128, 169-72
(W. LaFave ed. 1965).
5. Simpson, Punitive Damages for Breach of Contract, 20 OHIo ST. L.J. 284 (1959).
A leading case is Addis v. Gramophone Co., [1909] A.C. 488. A leading exception is
Welborn v. Dixon, 70 S.C. 108, 49 S.E. 232 (1904).
6. The .term "innocent breach" should not be confused with "excusable nonperfor-
mance," which involves no breach at all. Instances of "subjective impossibility," which
is not an excuse for nonperformance, are typical examples of "innocent breach." See E-
STATEMENT OF THE LAW OF CoNTaRcrs § 455 & Illustrations (1933) [hereinafter cited as
RESTATEMENT].
7. Globe Refining Co. v. Landa Cotton Oil Co., 190 U.S. 540, 544 (1903).
8. See Lagerloef Trading Co. v. American Paper Products Co., 291 F2d 947, 956
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1147
tions to the rule will be suggested in the pages that follow.9 In its essential
design, however, our system of remedies for breach of contract is one of strict
liability and not of liability based on fault, 10 and this would be a strange design
indeed if it were a system directed at the compulsion of promisorsi
Our system, then, is not directed at compulsion of promisors to prevent
breach; rather, it is aimed at relief to promisees to redress breach. It is not
much concerned with the question suggested by Frost's lines: How can men be
made to keep their promises? It is instead preoccupied with a different ques-
tion: How can men be encouraged to deal with those who make promises?
Perhaps it is more seemly for a system of free enterprise to promote the use of
contract by encouraging promisees to rely on the promises of others, rather
than by compelling promisors to perform their promises out of fear that the
law will punish their breaches. In any event, this at least adds to the celebrated
freedom to make contracts, a considerable freedom to break them as well.
How can men be encouraged to deal with those who make promises? The
answer given by our legal system is: By protecting their expectations in the
event of breach. The principal objective of the system, once breach has occurred,
is to put the promisee in the position in which he would have been had the prom-
ise been performed, i.e., had there been no breach." This is accomplished by
(7th Cir. 1923), in which the court said, "Repudiators of fair and solemn and binding
promises are commercial sinners." But our system of damages for breach of contract
ordinarily imposes no penalty for this sort of sin. This is not to say that there are no
areas of contract law in which account is taken of the character of the bieacb. There
is, for example, a substantial body of authority that makes distinctions based on the
character of the breach in determining whether to allow a party in default to recover for
what he has performed before default. In one seminal case the court said: "Nothing can be
more unreasonable than that a man, who deliberately and wantonly, violates an engage-
ment, should be permitted to seek in a court of justice an indemnity from the consequences
of his voluntary act... Wherever there is a reasonable dxcuse, however, the law allows
a recovery." Stark v. Parker, 19 Mass. (2 Pick.) 267, 273 (1824), discussed it Lee, The
Plaintiff in Default, 19 VAiN L. REv. 1023, 1028 (1966). Cases that take account of the
character of the breach in determining whether performance has been "substantial" afford
another example. E.g., Jacob and Youngs, Inc. v. Kent, 230 N.Y. 239, 244, 129 N.E. 889,
891 (1921) ("The transgressor whose default is unintentional and trivial may hope for
mercy if he will offer atonement for his wrong").
9. See the discussion of Flureau v. Thornhill, text accompanying notes 13-16 infra;
of the choice between cost and market price, text accompanying notes 98-117 infra; of
recovery based on reliance, text accompanying note 133 infra; of recovery based on
market price, text accompanying note 189 infra; of unforeseeable loss, text accompany-
ing note 274 infra; and of uncertain loss, text accompanying note 301 infra.
10. Grossfeld points out that in East German law, liability for breach is based
primarily on the "fault principle" rather than on strict liability so that the r sr is
not liable at all for a breach occasioned by circumstances that the promisorp "could not
avoid." Grossfeld, supra note 4, at 1332-35. Contract liability is therefore more narrowly
confined than in most legal systems including our own, and this narrows the applicability
of the system of fines for the most part to cases of "fault."
11. THE UNrFoRm CoMMxtccA. CODE § 1-106(1) [hereinafter cited as UCC] provides
that Code remedies "shall be liberally administered to the end that the aggrieved party
may be put in as good a position as if the other party had fully performed." Of course a
legal system that falls as far short as does ours of recognizing the costs of litigation when
awarding relief may, for that reason, fail to attain that goal in practice. This is not,
however, a problem peculiar to contracts.
1148 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
tive restitution or reliance interest upon breach of contract, the dominant theme
is one of relief based on the promisee's expectation interests.
The use of the expectation interest for measuring recovery leads to results
that may fall far short of compulsion. This may be seen from the following
illustration:
Illustration 1. Manufacturer contracts to sell goods for $100,000 to
jobber, who expects to resell them to dealers at a profit. For financial
reasons, Manufacturer decides that it will be to his advantage to dis-
continue manufacture of the line of goods and fails to deliver to Jobber,
who is unable to obtain such goods elsewhere. jobber sues Manufac-
turer for breach of contract. The evidence shows that because of a drop
in the market on which jobber sells, he would have realized only $101,-
000 on resale of the goods, which happens to be exactly equal to the
cost, $100,000, of the goods, plus the expenses, $1,000, that he would
have incurred in reselling them.
Had there been no breach, Jobber would have had to spend $101,000 to gain
$101,000; consequently, he requires no relief to put him in the position in which
he would have been had the contract been fully performed. Manufacturer is
liable for only nominal damages, trivial in amount, as the result of his decision
not to perform. 17 Clearly there is no compulsion here.
There may, of course, be circumstances in which the law's use of the ex-
pectation measure will afford some compulsion for a promisor to perform his
promise. He may well find it cheaper to perform than to give relief to the prom-
isee for his disappointed expectation. And the mere possibility of a controversy
that may lead to an adverse decision in court may reenforce the other compul-
sions that society exerts apart from law.'8 The extent to which the expectation
measure does, in fact, operate as a sanction to compel performance is a matter
worthy of study. 19 The point here is only that it is not designed to achieve that
end.
17. Nominal damages are given since in principle a breach of contract always gives
rise to a right of action; costs are not always awarded with the nominal damages, how-
ever, and in some jurisdictions a failure to award nominal damages is not grounds for
reversal. Even if the injured party is awarded costs along with nominal damages, this
will fall far short of reimbursing him for the actual expenses of litigation. See 5 CoRBni
§ 1001.
18. There is also the possibility that such compulsions will tend to dissuade the
promisee from seeking to hold the promisor to his promise, perhaps resulting in com-
promise. On the strong tendencies along these lines in Japan, see T. Kawashima, Dispute
Resolution in Contemporary Japan,in LAw Ix JAPAx: THE LEGAL ORDER IN A CHANGING
Socmry 41 (A. von Mehren ed. 1963). See also Lubman, Mao and Mediation: Politics
and Dispute Resolution in Communist China, 55 CAw. L. REv. 1284 (1967); Cohen,
Chinese Mediation on the Eve of Modernization, 54 CALIF. L. REV. 1201 (1966).
19. See Macaulay, Non-ContractualRelations in Business: A Preliminary Study, 28
Am. SoCoLOGIcAL REv. 55 (1963).
20. RESTAMMNT § 326 lists restitution as a third kind of relief. It is, however, better
1150 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:11.45
was-promised, as where the court confers the promised benefit on the injured.
party or orders the defaulting promisor to do so. It is said to be "substitutional"
when it is intended to provide him with something in substitution for that bene-
fit, as where the court awards the injured party money damages.2 '
Although damages will, in some cases, permit the injured party to arrange
an adequate substitute for the expected benefit, specific relief is clearly the form
better suited to the objective of putting the promisee in the position in which he
would have been had the promise been performed. Of course the passage of time
may reduce the effectiveness even of specific relief. The benefit will at best
usually be delayed since contract remedies are ordinarily not available until after
breach has occurred. 22 And there are some situations in which specific relief is
simply not possible at all. For example, the promise may have been one to
deliver particular goods which turn out to be defective, or to have been de-
stroyed, or to have been sold to a third person. But there remain many in-
stances in which specific relief will be both timely and feasible. They can be
put into two broad categories.
In one category of cases, specific relief does not require the cooperation of
the defaulting promisor. If the promise is to deliver goods, an officer of the court
may seize and deliver them; if it is to convey land, he may execute a binding
conveyance; if it is to pay money, he may seize and sell enough of the promisor's
assets to yield the required sum. In this category the practical impediments to
specific relief are at a minimum. In the other category of cases, however, specific
relief does require the cooperation of the promisor. Consider, for example, a
promise to act in a play, to paint a house, or to build a building. To assure
specific relief in each of these cases some form of coercion may be needed, so
that the practical impediments are substantial.
The civil law system, i.e., those descended from Roman law, have by and
to view restitution as an interest to be protected (where the attempt is to put the promisor
back in the position in which he would have been had the promise not been made), rather
than as a kind of relief. As § 326 itself points out, restitution may be either "specific" or
"substitutional."
21. Substitutional redress need not be limited to money, but may be in kind. Isaac
Schapera tells of a case among the Tswana in which a man who broke his promise to
deliver a cow-to another was obliged to deliver four cows, one in substitution for the cow
he should have given and three in substitution for its offspring. Schapera, Contract in
Tswana Case Law, 9 J. AFPCAN L. 142, 148 (1965). Charles Wright notes the incidence
of this in everyday dealing--"If I lose the ski poles I have borrowed from a friend, I
buy a new pair and return them to him"--and suggests that legal sanctions of this sort
might be considered. Wright, The Law of Remedies as a Social Institution, 18 U. DaT.
L.J. 376, 378 (1955). In a society with a market economy, however, the tendency is to
assume that the injured party can procure a substitute himself and need only be com-
pensated for the expense involved. In French law, for example, if the promisor fails to
perform his duty to do work, as where a landlord fails to repair the leased premises, the
court may authorize the promisee to have it done at the promisor's expense. P. HERZOG,
Civnx PROcEDURE Ix FRANcE 557 (1967). Cf. the buyer's remedy of "cover" under
UCC 2-712, discussed in text accompanying notes 166-73 infra.
22. In the exceptional case where a party repudiates his obligation in advance of the
time for performance, specific relief might be given without delay. And where a declara-
tory judgment is granted before the time for performance, it at least reinforces the extra-
legal compulsions to perform, although it adds no legal compulsion.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1151
large proceeded on the premise that specific redress should be ordered when-
ever possible, not only for cases in the first category, but even for those in the
second category as well, unless the disadvantages of the remedy outweigh its
advantages. As Dawson has said of the German law,
The main reservations are for cases where specific relief is impossible,
would involve disproportionate cost, would introduce compulsion into
close personal relationships or compel the expression of special forms
of artistic or intellectual creativity. Presumably German courts, like
French courts and our own, would 23 not affirmatively order
painters to
paint pictures or singers to sing.
The logic of the civil law is reenforced by practical considerations in communist
countries that lack markets on which aggrieved parties can arrange substitute
transactions. The task of manufacture imposed on a state enterprise by a gov-
ernment plan, for example, can only be accomplished if the enterprise receives
the specific raw materials that it has been promised for production; money
24
damages are not an adequate substitute.
The common law countries escape both the civil law's doctrinal logic and
communism's practical need for compulsion. The early common law courts did
know specific relief, for many of the first suits after the Norman Conquest were
proprietary in nature, designed to regain something of which the plaintiff had
been deprived.25 Even the action of debt was of this character, since it was
based on the notion of an unjust detention of something belonging to the plain-
tiff.2 6 But it became the' practice in these actions to allow money damages for
the detention in addition to specific relief, and with the development of new
forms of action, such as assumpsit, that were in no way proprietary, subsitu-
tional relief became the usual form.
The typical judgment at common law declared that the plaintiff recover
from the defendant a sum of money, which in effect imposed on him a new obli-
gation as redress for the breach of the old. The new obligation required no
cooperation on his part for its enforcement since, if the sum was not paid, a writ
23. Dawson, Specific Performance in France and Germany, 57 MIcrH. L. Rxv. 495,
530 (1959). In France, however, a distinction is made between promises "to give," and
those "to do or not to do." Id. at 506-25. As to the latter, the system for enforcement of
court orders of specific performance, known as the astreinte, is of questionable effective-
ness. "An outside observer will be excused, I hope, for describing such a principle [of
allowing specific performance] as almost wholly meaningless where the astreinte is the
only means employed for its realization." Id. at 524-25. Another writer, describing specific
performance and the astreinte in French law, reports that since a 1959 decision of the
Cour de Cassation, "French law professions no longer share this scepticism." P. HERzoG,
supranote 21, at 563.
24. See Grossfeld, supra note 4, at 1330-31. On the impact of "economic revisionism,"
see M. GAmARNiKov, EcoNo Ic REFORMs in EASTERN EUROPE (1968), where the author
describes how "communist economics began to emerge from the era of absolute scarcity
and strictly controlled production and distribution into a stage of a limited buyer's market,"
and points out that "the impact of the Western prosperity on economic thinking in the
Soviet bloc can be seen in various attempts to incorporate the principles of a market
economy into the framework of central planning." Id. at 12, 19.
25. See Washington, Damages in Contract at Common Law, 47 L.Q. REV. 345 (1931).
26. See Farnsworth, supra note 1, at 586-87.
1152 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
of execution would issue empowering the sheriff to seize and sell so much of the
defendant's property as was required to pay the plaintiff. The proprietary ac-
tions remained, so that there were a few instances where relief at common law
was specific; for example, in an action by a buyer for replevin of goods sold to
him but not delivered, the sheriff might first seize them from the seller and turn
them over to the buyer,27 and the judgment would then declare that the buyer
was entitled to them. And, of course, where the claim was to a sum of money
that the defendant had promised to pay, the effect, as in the original action for
debt, was to give the promisee specific relief; for example, in an action by the
seller for the price of goods delivered but not paid for, judgment would be given
against the buyer for the full amount of the price. 28 But these instances were the
exception rather than the rule, and even where the common law courts granted
specific redress, they were unwilling to exert pressure directly on the defendant
to compel him to perform. The judgment itself was seen as a mere declaration
of rights as between the parties, and the process for its execution was directed
not at the defendant but at the sheriff, ordering him to put the plaintiff in pos-
session of real or personal property or to seize the defendant's property and sell
29
such of it as was necessary to satisfy a money judgment.
The enforcement of promises in equity developed along very different lines.
Prior to the development of assumpsit by the common law courts in the six-
teenth century, most of the cases brought before the chancellor were based on
promises that would not have been enforceable at common law, and the question
was whether they would nevertheless be enforced in equity. After the develop-
ment of assumpsit, equity accepted the test for enforcement that had been
developed by the rival common law courts, and refused to enforce simple prom-
ises made without "consideration." To this extent its jurisdiction in contract
became concurrent with that of the common law courts, and its concern shifted
from the enforceability of the promise to the nature of its enforcement.3 0
Under the influence of the canon law (for the early chancellors were usu-
ally clerics), decrees in equity came to take the form of a personal command to
the defendant to do or not to do something. His cooperation was assumed, and
if he disobeyed he could be punished not only for criminal contempt, at the
instance of the court, but also for civil contempt, at the instance of the plaintiff.
This put into the plaintiffs hands the extreme sanction of imprisonment, which
might be supplemented by fines payable to the plaintiff and sequestration of the
27. Since replevin was generally available only to the owner of property, the
rationale was that the ownership of the goods in the seller's possession had passed to the
buyer. See UNIFORM SALEs Act § 66 (now replaced by the UCC).
28. On the enforcement in equity of decrees for payment of money, see W. WAI.su,
A TREATIsE ON EQUITY 62-63 (1930).
29. C.A. -usTON, THE ENFORCEMENT OF DEmcEs IN EQuiTy 7 (1915). On the
common law's use of imprisonment for debt, see 8 HoLDswoRTH, A HISTORY OF ENGLISH
LAw 231-33 (1926).
30. H. McCLINTOcK, HANDBOOK OF THE PRINrIPLES OF EQuITy 125-27 (2d ed.
1948) ; W. WALsH, supra note 28.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1153
defendant's goods. 3' So it was said that equity acted in personam, against the
32
person of the defendant, while the law acted in rem, against his property. But
it did not follow that the chancellor stood ready to order every defaulting
promisor to perform his promise. Equitable relief was confined to special cases
in light of both practical and historical limitations.
The practical limitations grew out of the problems inherent in coercion.
Our courts, like those of civil law countries, will not undertake to coerce a per-
formance that is personal in nature-to compel an artist to paint a picture or a
singer to sing a song. (They have, to be sure, been ingenious in framing orders
enjoining contracted parties from acting inconsistently with their promises as a
substitute for orders directing them to perform them-the court that will not
order the singer to sing may enjoin him from singing elsewhere.) 3 3 Our courts
have also been reluctant to order specific performance where difficulties of
supervision or enforcement are foreseen, e.g., to order a building contractor
specifically to perform his contract to repair a house. It has been suggested that
in their origins these ideas carried a load of snobbery, expressed in distaste for
menial tasks-'how can a Master judge of repairs in husbandry?' "4 Today
they are more often justified as a means of avoiding conflict and unfairness
where no clear standards can be framed in advance. The practical exigencies
of drafting decrees to guide future conduct under threat of contempt have also
moved courts to require that contract terms be expressed with somewhat
greater certainty if specific performance is to be granted than if damages are
to be awarded. 85 But these practical limitations are on the whole far less sig-
nificant than the historical ones.
31. The development of these supplementary sanctions is traced in C.A. HusTo,
supra note 29, at 76-83; W. WALSHr, supra note 28, at 47-48. Huston notes the measures
required "to coerce obedience from the stubborn seventeenth-century Englishman. Thus in
1598, after one Walter had been already subjected in vain to close imprisonment for some
time, the court ordered him to perform within a fortnight 'which if he shall not do ...
then his Lordship mindeth without further delay not only to shut the defendant close
prisoner but also to lay as many irons on him as he may bear.'" Id. at 79, citing Clerk
v. Walter, Monro 718.
32. See generally F. JAmEs, CIVIL PRocEDuRE 21-24 (1965). For a discussion of the
power of equity to act in rein, see C.A. HusToN, .supranote 29, at 71-86; H. McCLNrocic,
supra note 30, at 94-96; W. WALsH, supra note 28, at 45-50. Declaratory relief) in which
the court states the rights of the parties but does nothing further to enforce them, may
operate to secure performance of promises through non-jural sanctions that coerce per-
formance. F. Jsams, supra at 26-31.
33. Lumley v. Wagner, 1 De G.M. & G. 618, 42 Eng. Rep. 687 (Ch. App. 1852). A
more extreme example is that of a suit for specific performance of a contract to run
street cars to connect with the plaintiff's trains, in which the court enjoined the defendant
from operating any cars unless it performed its contract. Prospect Park & Coney Island
MR. v. Coney Island & Brooklyn R.R., 144 N.Y. 152, 39 N.E. 17 (1894).
34. Dawson, supra note 23, at 537, quoting from Rayner v. Stone, 2 Eden 128, 130, 28
Eng. Rep. 845, 846 (1762). Consider also the remark of Chancellor Walworth, in a suit
against an opera singer for specific performance: "I am not aware that any officer of this
court has that perfect knowledge of the Italian language, or possesses that exquisite
sensibility in the auricular nerve which is necessary to understand, and to enjoy with a
proper zest, the peculiar beauties of the Italian opera, so fascinating to the fashionable
world." DeRivafinoli v. Corsetti, 4 Paige 263, 270 (N.Y. 1833). See generally 5A CoRBIN
§§ 1171-72.
35. Bethlehem Eng'r Export Co. v. Christie, 105 F.2d 933, 934 (2d Cir. 1939) (per
1154 COLUMBIA LAW REVIE[7 [Vol. 70:1145
The most important of the historical limitations derives from the circum-
stance that, since the chancellor had first granted equitable relief in order to
supply the deficiencies of the common law, equitable remedies were readily char-
acterized as "extraordinary." When, during the long jurisdictional struggle be-
tween the two systems of courts, some means of accommodation were needed, an
"adequacy" test was developed to prevent encroachment by the chancellor on
the powers of the common law judges. Equity would stay its hand if the remedy
at law was "adequate."3 6 To this test was added the gloss that the money dam-
ages awarded by the common law courts were ordinarily "adequate"--a gloss
encouraged by the philosophy of free enterprise, since in a market economy
money ought to enable an aggrieved promisee to arrange a substitute trans-
action. As one writer put it:
The law, concerning itself more and more with merchandise bought
or sold for money, with things having a definite and calculable ex-
change value, came to conceive that the money compensation, which
was an entirely adequate remedy in the common case, and in many
cases the only possible one when once the wrong complained of had
been committed, was [generally] the only remedy available for their
37
use ....
So it came to be that, in sharp contrast to the civil law approach, money dam-
ages were regarded as the norm and specific relief as the deviation, even where
the law could easily have provided specific relief without any cooperation from
the defaulting promisor.
Land, which the common law viewed with particular esteem, was singled
out for special treatment. Each parcel, however ordinary, was considered to be
"unique," and from this it followed that if a vendor defaulted on his promise to
convey land, not even money would enable an injured purchaser to find a sub-
stitute. The remedy at law being in this sense "inadequate," a decree of specific
performance would 'ordinarily issue.38 Although the case for allowing the
vendor to have specific performance when the purchaser defaulted was less com-
Learned Hand, J.: "This contract is so obscure, and, strictly taken, so incoherent, that
nobody can be sure of its meaning.... Arguendo, we shall assume that these promises
created a valid contract which could be enforced at law like any other; but it does not
follow that equitable remedies would also be available ... "); Van Dyke v. Norfolk
Southern 1LR., 112 Va. 835, 72 S.E. 659 (1911). But cf. City Stores Co. v. Ammerman,
266 F. Supp. 766 (D.D.C. 1967).
36. According to Holdsworth, "It was not till the eighteenth century that it was
settled that equity would only grant specific relief if damages were not an adequate
remedy." 1 W. HoLDswoRTH, A HisTORy OF ENGLISHE LAW 457 (7th ed. 1956).
37. CA. HusToN, supra note 29, at 74. Holmes, with some overstatement, wrote that
"The duty to keep a contract at common law means a prediction that you must pay
damages if you do not keep it-and nothing else." Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10
HAv. L. Rnv. 457, 462 (1897).
38. E.g., Kitchen v. Herring, 42 N.C. 190 (1851) (principle in regard to land
adopted, not because it was fertile or rich in minerals, or valuable for timber, but simply
because it was land-a favorite and favored subject in England, and in every country of
Anglo-Saxon origin).
CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1155
pelling, equity also granted him relief.3 9 But no such reason applied to the
contract for the sale of goods, for in a market economy it was supposed that,
with rare exceptions for such "unique" items as heirlooms and objects of art,
substantially similar goods were available elsewhere. 40 Some attempts have been
made to liberalize this restriction. The draftsmen of the Uniform Commercial
Code state in its Comments that it introduces "a new concept of what are
'unique' goods," 4' and they assert that "where the unavailability of a market
price is caused by a scarcity of goods of the type involved, a good case is nor-
mally made for specific performance under this Article." 42 But specific perfor-
mance is still the exception, not the rule, and in contrast to the view held in
socialist countries, it is to be justified on the basis of the peculiar needs of the
aggrieved party and not the general welfare of society as a whole. Although a
court, in determining the adequacy of an award of damages, may take account
of such factors as the difficulty of their ascertainment (e.g., under a long-term
"output" or "requirements" contract 43 ) and the improbability of their collection
(e.g., against an insolvent defendant 44 ), the typical buyer of goods must still
content himself with money as a subsitute for the goods in the event of breach.
A second historical limitation, or group of limitations, is premised on the
notion that equitable relief is "discretionary." Since the chancellor was to act
according to "conscience" (a circumstance that prompted the famous charge
that his conscience might vary with the length of his foot 45), he might withhold
relief where considerations of "fairness" or "morality" dictated. Some of the
most renowned of these equitable restrictions are embodied in equity's colorful
maxims: "he who seeks equity must do equity" ;46 "he who comes into equity
39. E.g., Hopper v. Hopper, 16 N.J. Eq. 147 (1863). For discussion of the basis of
this rule, see 5A CoR~iw § 1145.
40. E.g., McCallister v. Patton, 214 Ark. 293, 215 S.W.2d 701 (1948) (specific per-
formance denied buyer of automobile in spite of short supply following World War II).
But see Morris v. Sparrow, 225 Ark. 1019, 287 S.W2d 583 (1956) (specific performance
granted cowboy who had been promised horse after he trained him).
41. UCC § 2-716, Comment 2, which goes on to say that
output and requirements contracts involving a particular or peculiarly available
source or market present today the typical commercial specific performance situa-
tion, as contrasted with contracts for the sale of heirlooms or priceless works of
art which were usually involved in the older cases.
See, e.g., Curtice Bros. v. Catts, 72 NJ. Eq. 831, 66 A. 935 (1907) (supply of tomatoes for
canning could not be replaced in time). See also UCC § 1-106 and note 11 supra.
42. UCC § 2-713, Comment 3.
43. E.g., Eastern Rolling Mill Co. v. Michlovitz, 157 Md. 51, 145 A. 378 (1929).
44. E.g., White Star Refining Co. v. Hansen, 251 Mich. 224, 231 N.W. 577 (1930).
But cf. Heilman v. Union Canal Co., 37 Pa. 100 (1860) (insolvency alone not sufficient).
Where the defendant is insolvent, the situation of his other creditors should not, however,
be overlooked. Cf. UCC § 2-502 on the buyer's right to the goods on the seller's insolvency.
45. "'Tis all one, as if they should make his foot the standard for the measure we
call a Chancellor's foot; what an uncertain measure this would be l One Chancellor has
a long foot, another a short foot, a third an indifferent foot; 'tis the same thing in the
Chancellor's conscience." SELDEN, TABLE TALx, quoted in Gee v. Pritchard, 2 Swanst.
402, 414, 36 Eng. Rep. 670, 679, (Ch. 1818).
46. E.g., Hazzard v. Westview Golf Club, - Me. -, 217 A2d 217, 225 (1966).
1156 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
must come with clean hands" ;47 and "equity aids the vigilant." 48 One of the
most troublesome is the now largely discredited "mutuality of remedy" rule,
under which specific performance would not be granted to the aggrieved party
unless it would have been available to the other party had the aggrieved
party been the one in breach.4 9 It is one of the curious inconsistencies to arise
out of the dual jurisdiction of law and equity that these restrictions operated to
bar only equitable relief and did not prevent the award of damages at law.50
The historical development of the parallel systems of law and equity may
afford an adequate explanation of the reluctance of our courts to grant specific
relief; it is scant justification for it. A more rational basis might be the severity
of the sanctions available under the contempt power for their enforcement.5 1 In
any event, the current trend is clearly in favor of the extension of specific relief.
The fusion of law and equity into a single court system at least facilitates a
major change in this direction, and commentators have urged such a change.
Why not, as in both French and German law, give specific perfor-
mance as to any physical object that can be found and is reachable by
direct execution? It is true that whenever speed is a factor and markets
reasonably organized, promisees will not often ask for it .... But
why not leave this to the promisee's choice ?52
Still, for the present, the promisee must ordinarily be content with money dam-
ages.
The award of money to one aggrieved by a civil wrong dates back to a
time when its primary purpose was to keep the peace. As one writer explained:
The root idea of primitive law is not compensation for injury but com-
position for revenge .... With the growth of the power of the state
and the consequent respect for the law which found its sanction in that
power, composition gradually became53 compensation. The idea of pen-
alty grew into that of reparation.
Ultimately, the remedies recognized for delicts by primitive law were extended
by the common law to give a remedy for breach of promise, and so the modern
47. New York Football Giants v. Los Angeles Chargers Football Club, 291 F.2d 471,
473 (5th Cir. 1961) (Giants denied injunction to prevent Charles Flowers from playing
with Chargers, in violation of his contract with Giants; Giants did not have "clean
hands" because they had kept contract secret so that Flowers would not be barred from
playing in Sugar Bowl). But cf. Washington Capitols Basketball Club v. Barry, 419 F2d
472 (9th Cir. 1969) (dispute between Washington "Caps" and San Francisco Warriors
over services of Rick Barry).
48. Swiss Oil Corp. v. Fyffe, 296 Ky. 178, 186, 176 S.W.2d 398, 402 (1943).
49. For a case invoking the rule to allow specific performance, see Hopper v. Hopper,
16 N.J. Eq. 147 (1863). For an extensive criticism of the rule, see 5A ComiN §§ 1178-1204.
50. An exception is the equitable rule against enforcement of an "unconscionable"
bargain, which has been made a rule of law for contracts of sale by UCC § 2-302.
51. See Dawson, supra note 23, at 537-38.
52. Dawson, supra note 23, at 532. See also 5A Coannr § 1136; Van Heeke, Changing
Emphases in Specific Performance,40 N.C. L. REv. 1 (1961).
53. C.A. HuSTON, supra note 29, at 39-40 (1915). This article does not deal with
remedies in tort for acts amounting to breach of contract, for example, action in conver-
sion for the seller's failure to deliver goods is not included within its scope.
CONTRACTUIL BREAC1 1157
from his prestige alone, that his instructions would be given proper weight.
And from this it was only a short step to direct control over the assessment of
damages by a specific instruction to the jury as to the amount to be allowed
should there be recovery. The trial court judge might also grant aLnew trial on
the ground that he had himself erred in ruling on the admissibility of evidence,
including evidence as to damages, or in his charge to the jury, including his
instructions as to damages. Most important, the ruling of the trial judge on a
motion for a new trial was a matter of "law" which could be considered on
appeal by a higher court. It was out of appeals from these rulings that the
courts, toward the end of the eighteenth century, finally began to limit the body
of principles that were to govern the award of damages for breach of contract. 7
To the general principle of recovery based on the promisee's expectation
interest there emerged three important limitations. They guard against the
possibility, suggested by the following illustration, that a crushing burden might
be imposed on the promisor.
Illustration2. Supplier contracts to sell Manufacturer a replacement
part for Manufacturer's broken machine for $100. Supplier fails to
deliver the part and the machine remains idle. Manufacturer sues Sup-
plier for $100,000 in damages based on the loss of anticipated profits
through the use of the machine in his business over the ten-year life of
the part.
Full protection of the expectation interest has been described by one commenta-
tor as "one of those generous aspirations which the law does well to put but
58
sparingly into practice.
One of the limitations that have emerged concerns the aggrieved party's
behavior after breach. The calculation of the damages that are required to put
him in the position in which he would have been had the promise been per-
formed takes, as its point of departure, his situation after breach. It is often
open to him to take steps to ameliorate, or at least to avoid aggravating, that
situation. Should he be expected to do so even though this will redound to the
benefit of the defaulting promisor by diminishing his liability? If, in Illustration
2, Manufacturer can obviate his loss of profits by purchasing a similar part in
substitution for the one promised by Supplier, should he be expected to do so?
Courts have commonly answered such questions in the affirmative and refused
to allow the injured party to recover for loss that was "avoidable."
A second limitation relates to the extent of the risk undertaken by the party
in breach. The classic, if apocryphal, case is that "where a man going to be mar-
ried to an heiress, his horse having cast a shoe on the journey, employed a
blacksmith to replace it, who did the work so unskillfully that the horse was
lamed, and, the rider not arriving in time, the lady married another; and the
57. Washington, Damages in Contract at Common Law II, 48 L.Q. Rm,. 90-93 (1932).
58. Id. at 107.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1159
blacksmith was held liable for the loss of the marriage." 5 How far can the
aggrieved party hold the other accountable for the loss of such expectations as
these? In Illustration 2, even assuming that no similar part could have been
obtained as a substitute, does it follow that Manufacturer can hold Supplier ac-
countable for all of his anticipated profits over a ten-year period? To answer
such questions courts developed a test of "foreseeability" as an outer limit, and
refused recovery for loss that was "unforeseeable."
A third limitation goes to the adequacy of proof. Generally it is the ag-
grieved party who has the burden of persuasion on this point. How convincingly
must he establish, for example, the position in which he would have been had
the promise been performed? If Manufacturer in Illustration 2 is to recover his
anticipated profits, how persuasive must be his evidence as to their amount?
Through the attempts during the eighteenth century to control the jury's assess-
ment of damages, there evolved a principle that "certainty" was required in the
proof of contract damages and that there could be no recovery for loss that was
"uncertain." As De Grey, C. J., said in 1774, "In contract the measure of dam-
ages is generally matter of account, and the damages given may be demonstrated
to be right or wrong. But in torts a greater latitude is allowed to the jury: and
the damages must be excessive and outrageous to require or warrant a new
trial.60 The operation of this requirement of "certainty" within the framework
of the procedure for new trial is said to have caused the body of rules for dam-
ages to develop more rapidly in contract than in tort. 61
The general principle as it has evolved, then, is that-subject to these
three limitations-the injured party's expectation interest will be protected by
subsitutional relief that will secure for him the "benefit of the bargain." The re-
mainder of this article will consider, in turn, (a) the operation of this general
principle and some of the problems that arise in calculating the amount of re-
covery appropriate for the protection of the injured party's expectation interest;
(b) two alternatives to this general principle, namely, the alternatives of basing
recovery on the injured party's restitution interest or on his reliance interest,
59. Willes, J., in British Columbia Saw Mill Co. v. Nettleship, L.R. 3 C.P. 499, 508
(1868). A similar illustration is that "where a Canon of the church, by reason of the non-
delivery of a horse pursuant to agreement, was prevented from arriving at his residence
in time to collect his tithes." Griffin v. Colver, 16 N.Y. 489 (1858). This is evidently taken
from that of Pothier quoted in note 235 infra.
60. Sharpe v. Brice, 2 Black, W. 942, 943, 96 Eng. Rep. 557 (K.B. 1774). Common
Pleas would not grant a new trial in tort unless the amount awarded was "monstrous
and enormous ... such as all mankind must be ready to exclaim against, at first blush."
Accord, Beardmore v. Carrington, 2 Wils. K.B. 244, 250, 95 Eng. Rep. 790, 793 (1764).
See Washington, supra note 25, at 363-66. A test of "reasonable certainty" is now said to
be applied in tort cases. See 2 F. HARPER & F. JAMEs, THE LAW OF TORTS § 25.3 (1956).
But it is often less strongly phrased than is the test for contract cases. Compare RESTATE-
MENT OF THE LAW OF TORTS § 912 (1938) ("such certainty as the nature of the tort and
the circumstances permit") and Comment d ("a fair degree of certainty") with RESTATE-
MENT § 331 (1) ("reasonable certainty") and Comment a ("a reasonable degree of
certainty"). See also McCoRmicK, § 32. But see 5 CoRirN § 1028.
61. Washington, supra note 57, at 92.
1160 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
and the situation in which these alternatives are appropriately put to use; and
(c) the operation of the three principal limitations that have been placed on the
principle of protecting the injured party's expectation interest with regard to
loss that is "avoidable," "unforeseeable," or "uncertain."
A system of damages for breach of contract which has as its general basis
the protection of expectations suffers from two handicaps. The first is that it
requires a hypothesis-a hypothesis of the position in which the injured party
would have found himself had both he and the party in breach performed. Some
of the problems involved in this hypothesis are discussed later in connection
with the requirement of foreseeability. The second handicap is that it requires
an estimate-an estimate of a sum of money considered adequate to put him in
that position. This estimate might be based on cost to complete, that is, the
additional financial sacrifice that the injured party would have had to incur in
order to obtain a substitute performance considered adequate to put him in the
desired hypothetical position. Or it might be based on diminution in value, that
is, on the loss of advantage to the injured party that resulted from his not
62
being in that position.
Basing the estimate on cost to complete has initial appeal, as seeming to
come closer to actually assuring the injured party's expectation. This assumes,
however, that a substitute performance will be generally available at some cost
to put the injured party in the desired hypothetical position. Yet in many
instances no substitute performance is available at any cost. The party in breach
may be uniquely capable of performing his promise, e.g., a promise to star in a
play or to disclose a secret process. Or the delay occasioned by his failure to
perform his promise may have made any performance impossible, e.g, a promise
to perform an emergency operation or to install a fire alarm. 3 And even in
those instances where an adequate substitute performance can be found, prob-
lems of valuation are not necessarily eliminated. The injured party ought to be
compensated for any delay that has occurred, and cost to complete is not a
suitable basis for this because no amount of money can turn the clock back. In
the face of such practical difficulties in basing the estimate on cost to complete,
it is not surprising that the preference in our legal system is for an estimate
based on diminution in value."
62. According to Bonbright "'value'... refers to the advantage that is expected to
result from the ownership of a given object of wealth (or to the market price that this
advantage will command), whereas ['cost'] refers to the sacrifice involved in acquiring
this object. This distinction is clearly in our minds when we ask whether any thing, or
any desirable human achievement, 'is worth what it costs."' 1 J.BONBRIGHT, THE VALUA-
TION OF PROPERTY 19 (1937).
63. Note 21 supra collects some examples where substitutional relief is in kind rather
than in money. But such relief is practicable in only a small proportion of cases.
64. It would still be possible to fashion a rule that based the estimate on cost to
complete to the extent that this was possible, and used diminution in value only where
19703 CONTRACTUAL BREACH
In principle the diminution in value sought is that to the injured party him-
self, quite without regard to the diminution in value to anyone else, and depends
on his own particular circumstances, including his personal needs and resources
or of those of his, enterprise. According to Bonbright, value in this sense "repre-
sents a state of mind, a favorable attitude of a particular person or group of
persons."65 Basing the estimate on diminution in value, therefore, requires the
sometimes questionable assumption that this loss of advantage to the injured
party can be expressed in terms of money. Still, where the injured party's ex-
pected advantage consists largely or exclusively of the realization of profit, as is
the case for most commercially significant exchanges, it can be so expressed with
some assurance, and our courts have been able to live with this assumption.
Two ingredients enter into this estimate of the difference between the value
to the injured party of the hypothetical situation in which he would have found
himself after full performance of the exchange, and his actual situation after
breach. The first ingredient is the injured party's loss on the bargain,which he
suffers because the exchange for which he originally bargained has been
frustrated. It may have two components. One component is the loss in value to
the injured party of the other party's performance, and is equal to the difference
between the value to the injured party of what the other party was to have done
under the contract and the value of what he in fact did. This component is
always present, regardless of whether the breach is partial or total. Where the
breach is total, the injured party may elect to rely on it as an excuse for not
rendering the balance of his own performance; if he does so elect, a second
component enters into the calculation of his loss on the bargain.This component
is the cost that he avoided as a result of being excused. His loss on the bargain
is then the difference obtained by subtracting this cost avoided from the loss in
value.66
cost to complete could not be used. In this connection, see the discussion of cost to
complete as a measure of diminution in value, at text accompanying notes 89-120 infra. For
a case holding that the estimate is to be based on diminution in value, see Guardian Trust
Co. v. Brothers, 59 S.W2d 343 (Tex. Civ. App. 1933), in which, however, the court
seems to have overlooked the point, made at note 89 infra, that cost of completion fixes the
upper limit of diminution in value.
65. 1 3. BONBRGHT, supra note 62, at 67. It therefore takes into account the value of
money itself to the injured party. Id. at 70.
66. Problems of allowing interest on the amounts in question, to take account of
differences in times of performance, will be ignored here for the sake of simplicity.
1162 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:114.5
Although the profit sought is the profit that this Builder, not some hypothetical
builder, would have realized, a court may well mistrust his own optimistic esti-
mates and rely on the testimony of experts.7 4
A more difficult and revealing example lies between these two extremes,
when Owner's breach occurs before completion but after Builder has begun
performance, or at least preparation for performance, and has incurred expenses
which either cannot be returned to him, such as materials affixed to Owner's
land, or cannot be put to other use, such as plans and drawings made to suit
Owner's needs.
Illustration3c. The facts being otherwise as stated in Illustration 3,
Owner breaches by repudiating the contract after Builder has begun
performance, at a time when it would have cost him $400,000, out of a
total cost of $900,000, to complete the factory. Builder sues Owner for
damages.
Here, again assuming no other loss, Builder's recovery under Formula A is
simply his loss on the bargain,which is equal to the loss in value, $1,000,000,
less cost avoided, $400,000, or $600,000. In practice, of course, it is no simple
matter to determine the cost avoided, the amount that it would have cost Builder
to finish performance.7 5 One way for Builder to meet his burden with respect
to this figure is to use the information usually available to him with regard to
the costs already incurred in reliance on the contract. The cost of reliance,which
in Illustration 3c would necessarily be $500,000, is then subtracted from the
estimated cost of complete performance, $900,000, to give $400,000.76
Cost avoided _ cost of complete performance - cost of reliance.
Therefore, a convenient alternative for calculation of the loss on the bargain is
simply to add the cost of reliance, here $500,000, to the estimated profit, here
$100,000, which again gives $600,000.
Loss on the bargain = cost of reliance + profit.
lem of overhead saved by a builder or manufacturer is discussed in Harris, A General
Theory for Measuring Seller's Damages for Total Breach of Contract, 60 MicH L. Rxv.
577, 588-92 (1962) ; Note, Seller's Recovery When Buyer Repudiates Before Completion
of Manufacture, 99 U. PA. L. REv. 229, 232-33 (1950). The Code gives litte help in this
area. See UCC §§ 2-704(2), 2-708(2). A leading case before the Code is Jessup & Moore
Paper Co. v. Bryant Paper Co., 297 Pa. 483, 147 A. 519 (1929).
The burden of persuasion as to cost avoided is generally on the injured party. E.g
Allen, Heaton & McDonald v. Castle Farm Amusement Co., 151 Ohio St. 522, 86 N.E2d
782 (1949) (suit by advertising agency on contract to provide services). In the "corre-
spondence school" cases, however, courts have been unusually willing to allow the school
to recover the full price of the course, at least unless the student in breach can show the
school's cost avoided. E.g., International Correspondence School, Inc. v. Crabtree, 162
Tenn. 70, 34 S.W.2d 447 (1931) ; La Salle Extension Univ. v. Ogburn, 174 N.C. 427, 93
S.E. 986 (1917). See notes 204-05 infra.
74. See Patterson, Builder's Measure of Recovery for Breach of Contract, 31 CoLum.
L. REv. 1286, 1292-94 (1931).
75. There is a thorough discussion of this in Harris, supra note 73.
76. To the extent that Builder has savings that result from salvage, for example,
through materials that can be put to other use, they should be excluded from cost of
reliance and included in cost avoided.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1165
77. Where Builder has been delayed by Owner's breach, prior to Builder's decision
to treat that breach as total, loss caused by that delay should be treated as other loss.
78. Under the rules relating to mitigation, however, Builder will be held to a standard
of reasonableness with respect to savings that might have resulted from salvage.
79. See Patterson, supra note 74, at 1289-91.
80. To the extent that the income is deferred income, it will have to be capitalized,
a problem that is ignored here for the sake of simplicity. See 1 J. BONBRIGHT, supra note
62, at 216-32.
81. The same is true where the breach consists of a delay in completion. Owner will
be allowed damages based on the difference between the income that the factory would
have produced had performance been timely and that which it will produce as a result of
the delay. He is not confined to the rental price of the premises during the delay, the price
that some hypothetical lessee would have paid on the market for their use during that
period.
82. As will be seen later, the ultimate user also poses the more difficult problems with
regard to unforeseeable loss, text accompanying notes 219-76 infra, and uncertain loss,
text accompanying notes 277-303 infra.
1166 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
83. Fuller & Perdue, supra note 12, at 78, use the terms "essential reliance" and "in-
cidental reliance" instead of direct reliance and collateral reliance. The latter terms are
used here as parallel to the commonly used terms direct profit and collateral profit.
84. Owner's profit on collateral transactions, or his collateral profit, would be cal-
culated with no deduction for the cost of complete direct performance and would be equal
to the collateral income lost less the cost of complete collateral performance.
85. The equivalence of the two formulas can be established by showing that:
collateral income lost - collateral cost avoided - direct cost avoided = cost of
direct reliance + cost of collateral reliance+ direct profit
Rearranging the terms gives:
collateral income lost = (cost of direct reliance + direct cost avoided) + (cost of
collateral reliance+ collateral cost avoided)+ direct profit
And substitution gives:
collateral income lost = cost of complete direct performance + cost of complete
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1167
specifications had been followed and that which it will bring as built
is $10,000. Owner sues Builder for $15,000 in damages.
Damages measured by the cost to Owner to complete performance are subject
to the objection that they may compensate him for more than the diminution in
value to which the laws says he is entitled. If the cost to complete performance,
here $15,000, exceeds the diminution in value to him, so that it would not be
"worth what it would cost" for him to complete, then damages measured by that
cost will leave him with a windfall in the amount of the excess. To allow this
windfall would be to go beyond protection of his expectation and, in effect,
penalize Builder, thereby departing from the principal objective of contract
remedies. Cost to complete is, however, useful in fixing an upper limit for re-
covery since, even if that cost is less than the diminution in value to him
making it advantageous for him to complete, the "principle of substitution"
operates so that damages measured by that cost will at least be sufficient to
enable him to obtain a substitute performance. 89
Damages measured by the diminution in the price that Owner could realize
on the market,90 here $10,000, avoid the above objection, but are subject to the
converse objection that they may undercompensate Owner. If Owner planned
to keep the building for his own use, the advantage that he expected may well
exceed that to those who would buy on the market. As Bonbright pointed out,
many properties, highly prized for the special purposes for which they
are designed, are of trivial value [on the market] because only the
present owner is in a position to exploit them.9 1
To this extent of this excess, damages measured by the decline in market price
will fail to compensate Owner for his loss in value. But if he anticipated selling
the building on completion, damages measured by the price that the building
would have brought him in a hypothetical sale on the market may closely ap-
proximate its value to him. Diminution in market price is, therefore, useful in
fixing a lower limit for recovery, since the value of property to its owner is
usually no less than the net price at which he could sell it.
When diminution in value is elusive, then, cost to complete is a useful mea-
sure in fixing an upper limit for recovery and diminution in market price is a
useful measure in fixing a lower limit.9 2 The diminution in value to Owner in
Illustration 4, for example, can be assumed to lie between $10,000 and $15,000,
89. According to Bonbright, the rule "that replacement costs sets the approximate
upper limit of ... value" is "one of the most useful rules of thumb" in appraisal theory.
1 J. BONBRIGHT, supra note 62, at 157. The "principle of substitution" is discussed in text
accompanying notes 166-69 infra.
90. Bonbright calls this "the highest price for which the owner could sell it, under
prevailing conditions of the market." 1 J. BONBRIGHT, supra note 62, at 56.
91. 1 3. BONBRIGn1T, supranote 62, at 66.
92. Disregarding the element of damage due to delay in completion, the cost to com-
plete operates as an upper limit on diminution in market price, so that damages measured
by cost to complete will not be less than damages measured by diminution in market price.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH J169
Which measure more closely approximates this diminution in value will depend
on the circumstances. When damages measured by cost to complete will not
greatly exceed those measured by diminution in market price, so that the error
will not be large whichever is chosen, courts generally favor the former as the
more generous of the two. 93 Owner can therefore expect to recover $15,000 in
Illustration 4. Where, however, they differ widely,: the preference may shift to
damages measured by diminution in market price.
In some cases the contract itself may suggest which measure gives the
better approximation of value to Owner.
Illustration4c. The facts being otherwise as stated in Illustration 4,
the contract states that of the $50,000 price, $40,000 is for the house
itself and $10,000 is for ornamental sculpture on its exterior. Builder's
departure from specifications consists of his failure to add the sculp-
ture. Although the cost to Owner to have another builder add the
sculpture would be $15,000, its addition would raise the market price
of the property by only $1,000.
Here the figures for cost to complete and diminution in market price show only
that the diminution in value to Owner, because of Builder's failure to add the
sculpture, lies between the disparate limits of $1,000 and $15,000, but the fact
that when the contract was made Owner was evidently willing to pay $10,000
for it, suggests that $15,000 is the more appropriate approximation of diminu-
tion in value to him at the time of breach. 94 This, in fact, will ordinarily be the
measure of his recovery in such a case. As one court put it:
A man may do what he will with his own....and if he chooses
to erect a monument to his caprice of folly on his premises, and em-
ploys and pays another to do it, it does not lie with a defendant who
has been so employed and paid for building it, to say that his own per-
formance would not be beneficial to the plaintiff. 5
Yet to the extent that Owner's expected advantage consists of the realization of
profit to the exclusion of matters of personal taste and welfare, diminution in
market price may be the better measure of that benefit.96 If, for example, Owner
is a developer who plans to place the house on the market, and if his earlier
willingness to pay $10,000 for the sculpture was due simply to his gross mis-
calculation, at the time the contract was made, of the eff6ct that it would have
93. RESTATEMENT § 346(1) (a) (i), for example, states a basic rule allowing damages
for "the reasonable cost of construction and completion in accordance with the contract."
See also Illustration 4 to that section.
94. The value of the sculpture on which damages are to be based, however, is its value
to the owner at the time of breach and not the value that he thought, at the time of con-
tracting, it would have. Bonbright discusses "real" and "esteemed" value in 1 J. BONBRIGHT,
supra note 62, at 82-84.
95. Chamberlain v. Parker, 45 N.Y. 569, 572 (1871) (Andrews, J.),
96. In Chamberlain v. Parker, id. at 572-73, the court continued: "The point to be
considered is, whether the plaintiff in any sense, actual or legal, has lost by the default of
the defendant a sum equal to the expense of digging the well," i.e., the cost of completion.
It held that he had not.
1170 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW[ [Vol. 70:1145
the probable value to Owner. Courts have been particularly baffled by such
situations in which the contract calls for more than one sort of performance with
no allocation of the return performance which would -suggest their relative
values to the injured party. I
Two leading decisions are the Minnesota case of Groves v. John Wunder
Co., 00° and the Oklahoma case of Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal Mining Co.1°- In
Groves, one party agreed to lease to the other, with the right -to excavate, a
twenty-four acre tract of industrial property. The lessee paid $105,000 and pro-
mised to leave the property at a uniform grade. Instead it left the grade uneven.
Had the lessee performed, the market price of the property upon termination of
the lease would have been $12,160; for th6 owner to have the grading done
would have cost upwards of $60,000. The owner sued for damages measured by
the latter figure, but recovered only damages measured by the $12,160. On ap-
peal, it was held that the trial court erred in limiting the owner to damages
measured by market price.10 2 In Peevjhouse,the owners of a farm leased -it to
a mining company for five years for strip-mining. The lessee paid a sum of
money and promised to do restorative and remedialwork on the land: It failed
to do the work. Had the lessee performed, the market price of the farm would
haGe been increased by only $300; for the owners to complete wotild have cbst
about $29,000. The owners sued for $25,000 and recovered $5000 in the trial
court. On appeal, it was held that the trial court erred in allowing damages
greater than those measured by market price and reduced the judgment
to $300.10.
In each case the party leasing for the- purpose of excavation was in a
position analogous to that of Builder. In each casethe lessee's performance was
to be of two sorts, paying money for the right to excavate and restoring the.land
after excavation. In each ca e the return performance was the lease 'ith thr
right to excavate which was not, of course, allocated as between the -"yment
and the restoration. 04 In each case the excavator paid the money, analogous to
Builder's construction of the house, and in each case he failed to restore the
land, analogous to Builder's failure to add the sculpture. In Groves the court
concluded that cost to complete was the proper measure of damages; iii Peevy-
house it concluded that diminution in market price was the proper measure.
In Groves the court stressed the "willful" character of the breach*'5:an4
remarked that the "objective of this contract.., was the improvement of real
construction and completion.., if this is possible and does not involved un-
reasonable economic waste."'112
Illustration 4c. The facts being otherwise as in Illustration 4b, the
sculpture is to be built into the foundation in such a way that its addi-
tion, once the house has been completed, will require considerable
demolition and reconstruction.
In this situation, Owner will usually be confined to damages measured by
diminution in market price. In Jacob & Youngs v. Kent,1 13 for example, a con-
tractor built a $70,000 country residence for the owner, but inadvertently
departed from the contract specifications by using the plumbing pipe of
Cohoes, rather than of Reading Manufacture. The two types of pipe were
identical in all characteristics except their origin, and to have replaced the
Cohoes pipe with Reading would have required demolition of substantial parts
of the structure. Judge Cardozo wrote for the New York Court of Appeals:
In the circumstances of this case, we think the measure of the
allowance is not the cost of replacement, which would be great, but the
difference in value, which would be either nominal or nothing ... The
owner is entitled to the money which will permit him to complete,
unless the cost of completion is greatly out of proportion to the good
to be attained. When this is true, the measure is the difference in
'value."i 4
The result seems not to have turned on the fact that the departure was in-
advertent rather than intentional."15 Presumably the court concluded that the
nominal diminution in market price was a closer approximation to the loss in
value to the owner than was the considerable cost of demolition and replacement.
This is a reasonable conclusion in any situation in which the cost to complete
has been substantially increased by the breach itself and consists in large part
of undoing work already done and then redoing it, and only in small part of
making improvements that directly affect the value to the owner. Loss in value
to the owner is likely to be only a small fraction of the cost to complete, and
damages measured by the diminution in market price are probably the better
approximation of this.
It is misleading, however, to suggest that the award of damages measured
by cost to complete would result in "economic waste" in such a situation. What
is meant by "economic waste" seems rather to be a use of assets in a way con-
sidered "wasteful" according to standards shared by society in general.
112. RESTATEMENT § 346(1) (a) (i).
113. 230 N.Y. 239, 129 N.E. 889 (1921).
114. 230 N.Y. at 244, 129 N.E. at 891. Accord, Hansen v. Anderson, 246 Iowa 1310,
'71 N.W2d 921 (1955).
115. Because suit was by the contractor against the owner, there was also a question
whether there had been .substantial performance on the contractor's part, in the light of
which the character of the owner's breach was regarded as significant. 230 N.Y. at 244,
129 N.E. at 891. Three judges dissented, arguing that-there had not been substantial
performance.
1174 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW[ [Vol. 70:1145
Certainly there would have been "economic waste" in this sense if the con-
tractor in Jacob & Youngs had been compelled to replace the Cohoes pipe with
Reading at a cost greatly in excess of what society in general, as evidenced by
the market, would regard as the resulting increase in value. But awarding
damages measured by cost to complete results in no such compulsion, for the
law does not supervise the injured party's disposition of the money that he
recovers as substitutional relief.11 If he recovers a sum measured by cost to
-complete, he is free to choose whether he will "waste" it on completion or put
it to other use. Even if he were limited to a lesser sum measured by diminution
,in market price, he will still be'free to waste it along with other assets, on
completion, and it is doubtful that recovery of the larger sum will appreciably
increase the likelihood that he will do so. 1 7 It is perhaps more likely that the
threat of, damages measured by cost to the owner to complete might coerce the
builder into correcting the defect himself, which he could probably do at some-
what lesser cost than could the owner; this course however, would probably
be less' attractive to' both parties than settlement at some figure short of the
cost to the builder but above the difference in market price.
Much of the talk of "economic waste" thus misses the mark. Usually the
only valid point to be made is that there is the probability of an excessive
windfall for the owner and a heavy penalty for the builder if cost to complete
rather than diminution in market price is adopted as the measure of loss in
value. This is so where, as in Jacob & Youngs, much of the cost to complete
results from the breach itself and consists of expenses in undoing and redoing
work that is not directly productive of value to the injured party, so that there
is' reason to suppose that theloss in value to him is much farther from cost to
complete and closer to diminution in market price than it would otherwise be.
But on this analysis the "economic waste" argument is a spurious one in both
Groves and Peevyhouse. There was no suggestion 'n either case that the cost
;to complete was increased by the breach and would have been less had restora-
tion been carried 'out during the regular course of the lessee's operations. Al-
though if is possible to imagine a situation in which restoration at the end of
the lease would involve undoing and redoing work to achieve an end that could
have been attained much more efficiently had it been done over the period of
the lease, it does not appear that this was so in either case.118 As far as can
116. As has aiready been pointed out, courts are particularly reluctant to give specific
relief-to-the owner ior breach of a construction contract. Text accompanying note 34
supra.
117. The subsequent history of Groves supports this. After the reported decision, the
lessee paid $55,000 to the owner to settle the claim. The land was left until 1951, when
some grading was done on a portion at a cost of $6,000 and in 1953 this portion was sold
for $45,000 to a buyer who planned to use it for a factory. J. DAWSON & W. HARWvEY,
CASES ON CONTRAcrs AND CoNTRAcr RExmDrEs 12 (2d ed. 1969).
118. It is sometimes suggested that, as the court said in Peevyhouse, "the 'economic
waste' referred'to consists of the destruction of a substantially completed building or other
structure." 382 P 2d at 112. See also RESTATEMNT § 346, Comment b. To the extent that
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1175
be seen, all of the cost of the restorative work included in the $60,000 and
$29,000 figures was that contemplated at the time of the contract.
All this does not suggest that the court should have measured damages by
cost rather than market price in Peevyhouse or by market price rather than
cost in Groves. It merely suggests that there was little reason in either case
to prefer the one to the other. If, in fact, the value to the owner in both cases
lay somewhere between the two extremes, the solution reached by the trial court
in Peevyhouse accords with common sense. Rather than accept the Draconian
choice between the Scylla of overcompensation through cost and the Charybdis
of undercompensation through market price, it gave judgment for an inter-
mediary amount, $5,000, roughly a sixth of the cost of completion, but over
fifteen times the diminution in market price." x9 It was reversed, but it is indeed
doubtful that the appellate court improved upon the compromise in the court
below. The "certainty" achieved by insisting on a choice between cost or mar-
ket price is plainly illusory if there is no reliable way of connecting either of
the two measures to the loss in value to the owner. Where the loss in value
to the owner is uncertainj and cost to complete and diminution in market price
differ widely, it would be better to give the trier of fact discretion to fix any
figure, not unreasonable under the circumstances, as long as it lies within
those two limits. On this basis, then, both Groves and Peevyhouse were wrongly
decided. 20
125. Dawson, Restit tion or Damages?, 20 OHIO ST. L.J. 175, 186-87 (1959).
126. Dawson, supra note 125, at 187. He cites Acme Mills & Elevator Co. v. Johnson,
141 Ky. 718, 133 S.W. 784 (1911), in which a seller failed to deliver wheat which he had
contracted to sell for $1.03 a bushel, sold it before the delivery date to another buyer for
$1.16 a bushel, and was held liable for nominal damages only when the market dropped
below the contract price by the delivery date. See also RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF
AGEcCY § 404 (1957), Illustration 2. But in Timko v. Useful Homes Corp., 114 N.J. Eq.
433, 168 A. 824 (1933), it was held that a vendor of lots, for which the purchaser had
tartly paid, held them in trust -for the purchaser and waS liable to him for damages
based on the price at which he wcongfully'sold them to a third party.
COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
27
lie would liave been had he not made the contract with Owner, no court
would allow him this larger sum. A court will not, as Fuller and Perdue stated
it, "knowingly put the plaintiff in a better position than he would have occupied
28
had the contract been fully performed."' Expectation here operates as an
upper limit on recovery, a defensible limit since one of the justifications for
the protection of the expectation interest in the first place is that it yields
rules that are superior, because of their certainty and ease of application, to
20
those derived from the reliance interest. Businessmen regularly rely on
contracts by foregoing other opportunities and adjusting their business to the
expected performance, and basing recovery on such reliance would pose grave
problems of measurement.
A second exceptional case, in which the injured party may prefer damages
based on reliance to those based on expectation, arises when the breach has
relieved him from finishing performance of what has turned out to be a losing
30
contract.'
127. To eliminate the possibility that Builder, might have repudiated the contract with
Owner and accepted the more profitable offer, remaining liable to Owner for damages,
assume that those damages would be at least $200,000, so that this course of action would
have been less desirable for Builder..
128. Fuller & Perdue, supra note 12, at 79. $ee also their discussion of the compen-
sability of gains prevented through reliance at 417-18.
129. Id. at 61-62. They also suggest that
in a hypothetical society in which all values were available on the market and
where all markets were "perfect" in the economic sense ... there would be no
difference between the reliance interest and the expectation interest. The plain-
tiff's loss in foregoing to enter another contract would be identical with the
expectation value of the contract he did make.
Id. at 62. They give the illustration of a "physician who by making one appointment
deprives himself of the opportunity of making a precisely similar appointment with another
patient . .." Id. at 74:
130. It may be that the injured party entered into the contract 'because of some
special advantage, such as the enhancement of his experience or reputation or good will,
with respect to which his proof fails to meet the standard of certainty, discussed in text
.accoinpanying notes 277-303 infra. What he then regarded as an advantageous contract
may thus appear as a 'losing" contract. Cf. note 68 supra.
131. See RFSTATEMEZiT § 333. This means that not only is the cost of reliance limited
by the contract price in an extreme case, but that a negative profit term must be included
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1179
The argument, of course, overlooks the fact that the measure of Owner's
actual benefit from Builder's performance may well be less than the cost to
13 8 ,
Builder of that performance.
The case for Builder is more appealing where it is unclear whether he
would have made a profit or sustained a loss had the contract been fully per-
formed. A court might limit him to nominal damages on the ground that he had
not proved damages. But most courts have been more generous to Builder, and
there is substantial authority that he may simply ignore the profit term in
Formula B 139 and recover on the contract itself for his cost of reliance,at least
so far as it is reasonable. 40 Thus in United States v. Behan 41 the Supreme
Court of the United States allowed a contractor to recover for his reasonable
expenditures, including unavoidable losses on materials on hand, incurred in
reliance on a contract which the government ordered stopped. The project was
an experimental one in which the contractor was to lay down an artificial cover-
ing of cane mats on the bed of the Mississippi River to keep the channel clear
for navigation. It did not appear from the evidence whether he would have
made a profit or sustained a loss had performance been permitted. According to
the Court:
It does not lie.., in the mouth of the party, who has voluntarily and
wrongfully put an end to the contract, to say that the party injured
has not been damaged at least to the amount of what he has been
induced fairly and in good faith to lay out and expend (including his
own services), after making allowance for the value of materials on
hand ... unless he can show that the expenses of the party injured
have been extravagant, and unnecessary for the purposes of carrying
out the contract. 142
The effect is to leave the burden of persuasion as to profit on Builder, if he
seeks to use profit to increase his recovery beyond the cost of reliance, but to
put the burden as to loss on Owner ifhe seeks to use loss to reduce Builder's
143
recovery below the cost of reliance.
138. See the discussion at note 78 supra. This may work a kind of rough justice
where the contract is a losing one for the reason suggested in note 125 spra.
139. Formula B is set out in text at note 77 supra.
140. Since the profit term is ignored, a limit of reasonableness must be imposed. See
note 135 supra. But see the criticism of this in Patterson, supra note 74, at 1298-99.
141. 110 U.S. 338 (1884).
142. 110 U.S. at 345-46. To the extent that this language suggests that the injured
party can recover in full his reasonable outlay, even though the party in breach proves
that he would have sustained a loss, it goes too far. See L. Hand in L. Albert & Son v.
Armstrong Rubber Co., 178 F2d 182, 189 (2d Cir. 1949).
143. A few courts have allowed pro rata recovery of the contract price, a result that
may be justified as a compromise. In Kehoe v. Rutherford, 56 N.J.L. 23, 25, 27 A. 912,
914 (1893), the court-allowed the builder "only such a proportion of the contract price
as the fair cost of that work bore to the fair cost of the whole work required" for ex-
cavation where the contract fixed the price by the cubic yard. In Shapiro Eng'r Corp.
v. Francis 0. Day Co., 215 Md. 373, 137 A.2d 695 (1958), the court allowed recovery
of that amount of the contract price apportioned for the purpose of payment to the part
of the contract that had been completed, on the ground that it was "divisible."
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1181
Although the Behan case was concerned with Builder's recovery under
Formula B of the cost of reliancewhere profit was in doubt, a similar question
arises with respect to Owner's recovery under Formula B' of the cost of direct
reliance and the cost of collateral reliance where direct profit is in doubt. 144
Judge Learned Hand concluded that recovery should be allowed in such a case.
the form of the travel and living expenses of its employees together with an
allowance for their salaries and wages, and the rental of the exhibition booth.
Here the recovery consisted of both the cost of direct reliance and the cost of
collateral reliance,there being no other loss and no proof of direct profit.
In L. Albert & Son v. Armstrong Rubber Co.,148 from which the earlier
statement by Learned Hand is taken, a manufacturer contracted to buy from a
seller, during the Second World War, four machines designed to recondition
old rubber. The manufacturer abandoned the venture when the seller failed
to deliver the machines in time to be of use. The court allowed the manufacturer
to recover the cost of collateral reliance, the amount it had expended to lay
the foundation for the machines. Again, recovery can be viewed as that under
Formula B' with no proof of direct profit. In this case, however, the court
allowed the seller the privilege of deducting from the recovery any losses that
it could prove the manufacturer would have sustained had the seller delivered
the machines on time.
The complexity of the problems that can arise out of such claims for the
cost of collateralreliance is well illustrated by a 1954 English case, Cullinane
v. British "Rema" Manufacturing Co.14 9 A seller sold to a manufacturer a
machine warranted capable of producing six tons of dry clay powder per hour.
When delivered and installed it produced only two tons per hour, a rate that
made it commercially useless. The manufacturer included in his claim for
damages against the seller the amount that he had paid on the purchase price
of the machine (the cost of direct reliance) and his expenses in the construction
of buildings to accommodate the machine (the cost of collateral reliance).150
To this he added the direct profit that he had already lost during the first three
years of the expected ten-year life of the machine, the period that had elapsed
between the delivery of the machine and the trial of the case. In effect, his
claim for damages had two parts. One was based on his expectation for the first
three years, the period that had passed at the time of the trial and for which
he was prepared to prove direct profit. He based his calculations of direct profit
on estimated collateral income lost during each year less estimated cost of
complete collateral performance for that year and less an appropriate amount
for depreciation of the machine and buildings for that year. The other part
was based on his cost of reliance over the remaining seven years of the expected
life of the machine, the period that still lay ahead at the time of the trial and
for which he was not prepared to prove profits. There is no reason why such a
claim should not be honored. Under Formula B', the manufacturer would be
entitled to damages based on the cost of direct relianceand the cost of collateral
reliance plus his entire direct profit over the machine's expected life of ten
148.'178 F.2d 182 (2d Cir. 1949).
149. [1954] 1 Q.B.D. 292.
150. To take account of salvage, the manufacturer directed a sum tor the "residual
value" of the machine and the "break up value" of the buildings. Id. at 293.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1183
years. His recovery of the cost of direct reliance and the cost of collateral
reliance should not be prejudiced merely because he limited his claim for
recovery based on his expectation of direct profit to the first three years of
that life, as long as proper account was taken for depreciation during that time.
In effect, the manufacturer quite rightly attempted to use Formula B' in its
entirety for the three-year period for which he was prepared to prove profits,
and Formula B' with the direct profit term disregarded for the remainder of
the ten years, using an appropriate figure for annual depreciation to allocate
the proper fraction of the cost of complete direct performance and the cost of
complete collateral performance to the first three years. Unfortunately, the
court rejected this attempt. Evershed, M.R., concluded that the manufacturer
had to choose between recovery based on "the capital cost he has incurred" and
recovery "on the basis of the profit which he has lost,"'151 and accepted the
seller's argument that the manufacturer's claim "really involves giving damages
twice over."' 1 2 The court limited the manufacturer to the larger of the two
items, the direct profit for the three-year period. The case appears to be one in
which the court would have benefited from a more careful analysis, along the
53
lines suggested here, of these complex damage problems.'
To the extent that his obstinacy reduced his cost avoided and thereby increased
his loss on the bargain,the contractor was denied recovery. The Uniform Com-
mercial Code does empower a manufacturer of goods that he has contracted
to sell to elect to complete their manufacture in spite of a repudiation by the
buyer if "in the exercise of reasonable commercial judgment" the manufacturer
concludes that less loss will result from completing the goods and then dis-
posing of them than from halting their manufacture and salvaging them while
in process. If he does so he may then base his recovery on the goods as com-
pleted, even if his "reasonable commercial judgment" turned out to be in
error.Y65 Ordinarily, however, the injured party is expected to stop work as a
means of maximizing the cost avoided, and if he proceeds he does so at his
own risk.
As to loss in value, the injured party is expected to minimize this com-
ponent in order to minimize his loss on the bargain and, therefore, his damages.
Here the "principle of substitution" limits the loss in value to him, due to a
performance that is not forthcoming, to the cost at which he could replace that
performance, with an allowance for any additional loss occasioned by delay in
replacement.' 66 This is the same principle that makes the cost to complete the
upper limit of recovery in the building contract cases, 167 and it is the source
of some of the most important of the rules used in calculation of damages.
According to this principle, the injured party, on learning of the breach, is
expected to take affirmative action to avoid loss by making such substitute
suffer it to be done in all events, would sometimes lead to great injustice. A man
may hire another to labor for a year, and within the year his situation may be
such as to render the work entirely useless to him. The party employed cannot
persist in working, though he is entitled to the damages consequent upon his
disappointment. So if one hires another to build a house, and subsequent events
put it out of his power to pay for it, it is commendable in him to stop the work,
and pay for what has been done and the damages sustained by the contractor.
He may be under a necessity to change his residence; but upon the [contrary
rule], he would be obliged to have a house which he did not need and could not
use.
165. UCC § 2-704(2). For a discussion of the seller's options under the Code, see
Harris, A Radical Restatement of the Law of Seller's Damages: Sales Act and Commer-
cial Code Results Compared, 18 STAr. L. Rxv. 66, 70-72, 100-09 (1965).
166. This, of course, assumes that the situation is among the exceptional ones in which
specific relief is available.
167. See text accompanying note 89 supra. Cost to complete in the building contract
cases is one instance of replacement cost, since completion of the building according to
specifications involves arranging a substitute transaction with another builder. Of the
principle of substitution, Bonbright says:
Having a house to live in may be so important to me that I would give my entire
fortune rather than go without it. But having this particular house is much less
important, since I could buy another, equally attractive house, say, for $10,000.
Recognition of this principle of substitution has led appraisal writers to lay down
the rule that the replacement cost of property ordinarily sets the approximate
upper limit of its value.... Yet this [principle] is not invariably valid, and its
universal acceptance would sometimes result in a gross undervaluation. Owners
and prospective buyers of property cannot secure substitutes instantaneously;
sometimes the delay is serious, not to say fatal. In consequence, property which
is now available may be worth much more than the cost of a substitute which
would be quite as satisfactory save for the fact that it cannot be 'secured until
a future date.
I J. BONBRiGHT, supra note 62, at 156-57.
1186 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW (Vol. 70:1145
Here the plaintiff had his money in his possession and he might have
purchased other bacon of the like quality the very day after the con-
tract was broken, and if he has sustained any loss, by neglecting to do
so, it is his own fault.17 2
Assuming that the buyer is able to find a fully equivalent substitute, the loss in
value (represented by the first bracketed term of Formula C) is zero and,
since the buyer's cost of performance equals the contract price and his cost of
substitute equals the cover price, Formula C becomes Formula C-B:
168. UCC § 2-713. In practice, however, it is unlikely that the injured party will be
compensated in full for the trouble and inconvenience he has been caused by having to
make substitute arrangements.
169. Any cost that he has incurred in making the arrangement and any loss that he
has sustained as a result of delay in replacement should be included in other loss.
170. Illustration 2 is set out in text following note 57 supra.
171. UCC § 2-715(2) (a) allows the buyer consequential damages only to the extent
that they "could not reasonably be prevented by cover [under UCC § 2-712] or other-
wise." See UCC § 2-715(1) on incidental damages.
172. Gainsford v. Carroll, 2 B. & C. 624, 625, 107 Eng. Rep. 516 (K.B. 1824).
173. It has been held, for example, that an advertising agency need not "cut its rates
for unsold space, with incidental disturbance of its business" to avoid loss. Barron G.
Collier, Inc. v. Kindy, 146 Minn. 279, 178 N.W. 584 (1920).
CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1187
substitute goods will require the buyer to finance a second transaction. 174 An-
other arises when a buyer has an opportunity to avoid loss by making a less
favorable contract with the repudiating seller himself, assuming of course that
the buyer is not asked to surrender his rights under the repudiated contract. 175
Rules similar to those governing recipients of goods apply to recipients of, for
10
example, services and land.. 7 7
Furthermore, supplier, on learning of breach by the recipient, is also
expected to arrange a substitute transaction. Thus a seller of goods, on learning
of breach by the buyer, is expected to arrange a resale to another buyer.'73
Since the seller is expected to dispose of all of the contract goods, for which he
will presumably receive a lower price, his cost avoided (represented by the
the second bracketed term of Formula C) is zero, and since seller's value of
performance equals the contract price and his value of substitute equals the
resale price, Formula C becomes Formula C-S:
(C-S) Seller's damages= contract price - resale price + other loss.
Analogous requirements apply to other suppliers, for example, those of ser-
vices' 70 and land. 8s0
That this limitation of recovery, spawned by the principle of substitution,
is not an inevitable one can be seen from the fact that at one time it was not
applied to the supplier of personal services. In Gandell v. Pontigny,'8' an 1816
174. RESTATEMENT § 336, Illustration 10 indicates that he is not expected to finance
a second purchase. See also T. SEDGWicsc, A TREATiSE ON THE MEAsURE OF DAMAGES
§ 744 (9th ed. 1912). But the Code makes no such exception to the general rule that
bases damages on the assumption that a substitute transaction is possible. UCC § 2-713.
Cf. UCC § 2-502. -_ ,
175. The possibility of personal humiliation may also be a factor. See Lawrence v.
Porter, 63 F. 62 (6th Cir. 1894), for a case in which the court concluded that the buyer
should have made the second contract where the seller had breached by refusing to
deliver on credit and insisted on cash. Contra, Coppola v. Marden, Orth & Hastings Co.,
282 Ill. 281, 118 N.E. 499 (1917). The problem is discussed in 5 ComIm § 1043 and, in
connection with the availability of replevin under UCC § 2-716(3), in Peters, supra note
131, at 234. An interesting variation occurs when a customer incurs substantial damage by
his refusal to pay the unjustified bill of a utility, such as a water company, which has a
monopoly on its services. Compare Schultz v. Town of Lakeport, 5 Cal. 2d 377, 54 P.2d
1110 (1936), viodified, 55 P2d 485 (1936), with Severini v. Sutter-Butte Canal Co., 59
Cal. App. 154, 210 P. 49 (1922).
176. See 5 Coann; § 1096. These rules based on the cost of a substitute transaction
apply not only to contracts for personal service but also to construction contracts to the
extent that cost of completion is the measure of recovery applied. See text accompanying
notes 89-120 supra.
177. See 5 Conn; § 1098. As was pointed out in text accompanying note 38 supra,
the purchaser of land usually can compel specific performance. See also the discussion of
Flureau v. Thornhill, text accompanying notes 13-16 mpra. The rule limiting the injured
party to recovery based on the cost of a substitute transaction may pinch especially where
the broken promise is one to lend money, since whatever the impact on the prospective
borrower, recovery is generally limited to the difference between interest at the market
rate and interest at the contract rate. See 5 CoRBiN § 1078.
178. UCC § 2-708.
179. See 5 CoRBiN § 1095. These rules apply to contracts for personal service. Dif-
ferent rules apply, for example, to construction contracts for the reasons indicated in text
accompanying note 208 infra.
180. See 5 Com § 1098A.
181. 4 Camp. 374, 171 Eng. Rep. 119 (1816).
1188 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEWl1 [Vol. 70:1145
English case, a merchant was sued by his clerk, whom he had wrongfully dis-
charged in the middle of a quarter. The clerk was allowed to recover the agreed
compensation for the entire quarter, including the part when he had not worked,
on Lord Ellenborough's reasoning that:
Having served a part of the quarter and being willing to serve the
residue, in1 8contemplation
2
of law he may be considered to have served
the whole.
In Howard v. Daly,'8 3 a leading American case decided in 1875, however, this
doctrine of "constructive service" was regarded as
so wholly irreconcilable to that great and-beneficient rule of law, that
a person discharged from service must not remain idle, but must
accept employment elsewhere if offered, that we cannot accept it ....
The doctrine of "constructive service" is not only at war with prin-
ciple but with the rules of political economy, as it encourages idleness
and gives compensation to men who fold their arms and decline ser-
vice, equal to those who perform with willing hands their stipulated
amount of labor184
The doctrine has now been replaced by a rule analogous to that applicable
to the seller of goods, under which the employee is expected to make reason-
able efforts to arrange a substitute transaction by finding similar employment
with another employer. His recovery is then determined by what he would
have earned under the contract with the party in breach less what he did or
could with reasonable efforts have earned elsewhere.185
Because ours is a free enterprise economy, there has been a natural ten-
dency to assume that the injured party has available to him a market on which
he can arrange a substitute transaction. It is supposed that through the
encouragement of substitute transactions on such markets society can avoid
waste without relying, as do the communist countries, on a system of generally
available specific redress. This supposition is reinforced by the fact that a
common purpose of contracting parties in a free enterprise economy is to shift
the risk of market fluctuations. In consequence, the substitution principle has
182. Id. at 375, 171 Eng. Rep. at 120.
183. 61 N.Y. 362 (1875).
184. Id. at 373.
185. Prima facie the measure of such damage is "the wage that would be payable
during the remainder of the term ;" but this is only the prima facie measure. The
actual damage is measured by the wage that would be payable during the re,
mainder of the term reduced by the income which the discharged employee has
earned, will earn, or could with reasonable diligence earn during the unexpired
term.
Lehman, J., In Holl-wedel v. Duffy-Mott Co., 263 N.Y. 95, 101, 188 N.E. 266, 268 (1933).
On the burden of persuasion, see text accompanying notes 203-05 infra. The employee need
not, however, take other employment that is not of the same general character. E.g.,
Hussey v. Holloway, 217 Mass. 100, 104 N.E. 471 (1914). Courts have disagreed over
whether the employee's recovery should be reduced by amounts received as unemployment
compensation or similar benefits. Compare Pennington v. Whiting Tubular Prod. Inc., 370
Mich. 590, 122 N.W.2d 692 (1963) (not reduced), witfl United Protective Workers v.
Ford Motor Co., 223 F2d 49 (7th Cir. 1955) (reduced).
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1189
been generalized to yield the familiar standardized damage formulas. Thus the
buyer's damages came to be calculated on the basis of
the difference between the contract price and the [market] price which
the article bore at or about the time
8s
when, by the terms of the contract,
it ought to have been delivered.'
Assuming, then, that the cover price is equal to the market price, Formula C-B
becomes Formula C-B':
(C-B') Buyer's damages= market price - contractprice + other loss.
Buyer's cost of entry into the market along with his loss due to any delay are
properly included under other loss, although there is a tendency to assume that
187
markets are frictionless and to neglect such additional items as these.
Illustration 5. Seller contracts with Buyer to deliver goods on a
specified date for $100,000. Seller fails to deliver on that date. The
market price of similar goods at and immediately after the delivery
date is $110,000.
Buyer's recovery under the standard damage formula is based on the $10,000
difference between market price and contract price. Since the objective is com-
pensation of Buyer and not punishment of Seller, this is so even though the
the damages that Seller must pay Buyer are compensated for by the enhanced
value of the goods to Seller as a result of the rise in their market price. Further-
more, assuming that there is a market on which he can arrange a substitute
transaction, Buyer is limited to this recovery even though he might have made
a larger profit on resale of the goods.
Illustration5a. The facts being otherwise as stated in Illustration 5,
Buyer, after making his contract with Seller but before Seller's breach,
makes a contract to resell the goods to another purchaser for $125,000.
Buyer's recovery is still based on the $10,000 difference between market price
and contractprice, and not on the $25,000 gross profit that he would have made
on the resale, since it is assumed that by spending only $10,000 more on the
market he could obtain goods to enable him to perform his resale contract and
18
realize a gain based on that same resale contract.
Buyer has been allowed damages based on the difference between market
price and contract price even when this gives him a larger recovery than that
based on his gross profit on resale.
186. Gainsford v. Carroll, 2 B. & C. 624, 107 Eng. Rep. 516 (1824).
187. UCC § 2-713(1) allows the buyer "any incidental . . . damages," which are
defined in UCC § 2-715(1) to include "any commercially reasonable charges, expenses
or commissions in connection with effecting cover," but it is not clear that such charges
would be available where the buyer based his recovery on a hypothetical rather than an
actual transaction. Any expenses saved by the buyer as a result of the seller's breach
should, of course, be included as a negative term in other loss. See UCC § 2-713(1).
188. Gross profit is cited as a base because of the ease of illustration. If profit is used
as a measure of recovery, of course, adjustment must be made so as to limit the injured
party to his net profit. See note 201 infra.
1190 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW[ [Vol. 70:1145
Comparable rules apply to the seller, on breach by the buyer. 194 In this
case Formula C-S reduces to Formula C-S':
(C-S') Seller's damages= contractprice - market price + other loss.
Under the Code a rule parallel to that on cover by the buyer also protects
the seller who arranges a substitute transaction after the buyer's breach, allow-
ing him recovery based on the difference 19 5
between the contract price and the
resale price if the resale was reasonable.
Permitting the injured party, as the Code does, to base his recovery on
terms of reasonable substitute arrangements that he has made may require
the court to police the injured party's choice of the substitute arrangements
on which he bases his damages. This will be so in any situation in which he
regularly makes contracts for similar goods on a fluctuating market, since his
tendency in such a situation will be to claim as the substitute that transaction
which will yield the largest recovery.19 6 The availability of a ready market has,
however, the substantial advantage for the injured party of relieving him of
the task of establishing market price, a task that may raise difficult problems
of proof.lor Therefore, although the injured buyer is not required to cover
nor the injured seller to resell, and either can instead claim damages based on
market price, the use of actual rather than hypothetical substitute arrangements
as the basis for recovery has an obvious practical advantage. Although For-
mulas C-B' and C-S' can be extended to transactions not involving goods, such
as those involving land or services, there are in these areas no counterparts to
the Code's rules allowing the injured party to base recovery on an actual as
opposed to a hypothetical substitute transaction.
The principle of substitution has some important restrictions, however,
for by its very nature, it applies only where an adequate substitute contract
could have been arranged by the injured party. Where no such transaction
was possible, the general measure of recovery applies. Thus, the availability of
an adequate substitute must be determined by the court and depends on two
circumstances.
The first and more obvious circumstance is the accessibility of reasonable
opportunities to enter into similar transactions or, in other words, the avail-
ability of a market. For when no actual substitute transaction has been arranged,
the principle of substitution operates only when there is a market, and in the
203. UCC § 2-713 says flatly that the buyer's "measure of damages ... is the differ-
ence between the market price... and the contract price... ." UCC § 2-708 says that the
seller's "measure of damages ... is the difference between market price ... and the unpaid
contract price ... ," but if this measure "is inadequate to put the seller in as good a position
as performance would have done then the measure of damages is the profit (including
reasonable overhead) which the seller would have made from full performance by the
buyer .... " Courts have been even readier to assume a market for money than for goods.
Recovery for breach of a promise to lend money is ordinarily limited to the difference be-
tween the contract rate of interest and the market rate of interest, i.e., that at which the
aggrieved borrower could get a substitute loan. "There is no other thing so generally dealt
in, and so universally prevalent, as money." New York Life Ins. Co. v. Pope, 139 Ky. 567,
571, 68 S.W. 851, 852-53 (1902).
204. Roth v. Speck, 126 A2d 153 (Mun. Ct. App. D.C. 1956) ("The measure of
damages for breach of an employment contract by an employee is the cost of obtaining
other services equivalent to that promised and not performed." Id. at 155) ; Triangle Waist
Co. v. Todd, 223 N.Y. 27, 119 N.E. 85 (1918) ; Fugua & Smith v. Massie & Sons, 18 Ky.
L. Rptr. 842, 37 S.W. 587 (1896) (burden is on employer to show that no replacement was
available).
205. E.g., Levy v. Tharrington, 178 Okla. 276, 62 P.2d 641 (1936). For a minority
view, see Abrams v. Jackson County Bd. of Educ., 230 Ky. 151, 18 S.W2d 1000 (1929).
The problem does not ordinarily arise where the injured party is a supplier of services that
are not personal, for the reasons indicated at note 209 infra. For the related problem of
allocating the burden of persuasion as to cost avoided in contracts for services that are not
personal, see note 68 supra.
206. Matthew 6:24.
207. See note 185 stupra.
1196 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
ever, the injured party is a supplier of services that are not personal, under a
contract for construction of a building for example, another comparable oppor-
tunity is not viewed as a substitute. Rather, it is assumed that the contractor
could have expanded his business to undertake additional jobs so that the
breach of the original contract resulted in "lost volume" that could not be
recaptured by a second similar contract.2 0 8 Even if it can be proved that there
was a market on which other similar opportunities were available, the principle
of substitution would not apply and the general measure of recovery would
obtain. And even if the contractor actually enters into another similar trans-
action after breach, it is assumed that he would have done so anyway and it is
20 9
not regarded as a substitute.
This second aspect is of particular importance in connection with contracts
for the sale of goods because of the assumption in such cases that there is a
market. Yet even if there is a market, where the injured party is a seller whose
supply exceeds his demand, a second sale of the same goods on that market will
not recapture his profits, for it will cost him a sale of other goods that he would
otherwise have sold.210 Where the injured party is a manufacturer who has
contracted to sell goods that he produces, this assumption is ordinarily made,
the manufacturer being treated like the building contractor and allowed to
recover under the general measure of recovery and without regard to the
principle of substitution. 21 1 In spite of the existence of a market, the manufac-
turer is thus allowed to recover for his lost volume, since the assumption is
that his supply is at least equal to his demand and that he has, therefore, lost
a sale if he is obliged to sell the same goods twice.
Illustration 6. Manufacturer contracts with Buyer to produce and
deliver goods to Buyer for $100,000, the market price of the goods at
208. E.g., Mount Pleasant Stable Co. v. Steinberg, 238 Mass. 567, 131 N.E. 295 (1921).
On the problem of overhead saved in such a case, see note 73 supra.
209. This is true even if the other transaction is one which would not have been avail-
able to him but for the breach. In Olds v. Mapes-Reeve Constr. Co., 177 Mass. 41, 58 N.E.
478 (1900), a subcontractor, after breach by the contractor, made a second contract directly
with the owner to do substantially the same work called for by the first contract, and the
court held that it was error to base the subcontractor's recovery against the contractor on
the difference between the price in the first contract with the contractor and the price in
the second contract with the owner. Accord, Kunkle v. Jeffe, 71 N.E.2d 298 (Ohio Ct.
App. 1946) (a real estate broker, after the vendor breached by failing to sell to a puchaser
procured by the broker, arranged the sale of other property to the same purchaser at an
even larger commission) ; Grinnell Co. v. Voorhies, 1 F.2d 693 (3d Cir.), ceri. denied, 266
U.S. 629 (1924) (a contractor who had agreed with the owner to install an automatic
sprinkler system, after the owner became insolvent and breached, made a similar contract
vith the firm that took over the insolvent owner's premises).
210. The same holds true where the injured party is a buyer whose demand exceeds his
supply, a circumstance that may be occasioned by wartime shortages, for example. Cover
will not recapture the buyer's profits, for it will require him to purchase goods that he
would otherwise have purchased anyway for another transaction. Although UCC § 2-713
on buyer's damages contains no provision allowing profits comparable to that in UCC
§ 2-708 on seller's damages, it was held before the Code that buyer could claim profits in
such a case. Norwood Lumber Co. v. McKean, 153 F.2d 753 (3d Cir 1946).
211. See Oswego Falls Pulp & Paper Co. v. Stekher Lithographic Co., 215 N.Y. 98,
109 N.E. 92 (1915); Allegheny Iron Co. v. Teaford, 96 Va. 372, 31 S.E. 525 (1898);
Hincldey v. Pittsburgh Steel Co., 121 U.S. 264 (1887).
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1197
the time of the contract. By the time for delivery the market price of
the goods has fallen to $80,000 and Buyer wrongfully rejects them.
It cost Manufacturer $70,000 to produce them, but because of a drop
in the cost of production that parallels the drop in the market price of
the goods, it would cost him only $60,000 to produce them if he began
at the time of the Buyer's rejection. Manufacturer sues Buyer for
damages.
Regardless of the availability of a market on which Manufacturer could sell
the goods, he is not limited to the $20,000 difference between the contract price
and the price that he would have realized had he resold the goods on the
market, for it assumed that by reselling these goods he would have lost a sale
of other goods that he would otherwise have arranged. He is allowed damages
under the general measure of recovery of Formula A. 212 The problem is not as
simple as that in Illustration 3a,213 however, for there a completed building
was involved, which had to be left on the premises of Owner, the party in
breach. Here, after rejection, the goods are in the hands of Manufacturer so
that in applying Formula A there must be subtracted from the $100,000 loss in
value, a sum as cost avoided that is equal to the value of the unsold goods to
Manufacturer. That sum is not the $80,000 market price, because a sale on the
market at that price would cause the loss of another sale; it is not the $70,000
actual cost, since if he were to produce them now he could do so for less; it is
rather the $60,000 reduced cost of production that would apply to a new order
arranged within a reasonable time after rejection, since it is this amount that
he could presumably save by adjusting his production as of that time to make
use of the rejected goods. His recovery is then based on the difference between
the $100,000 loss in value and the $60,000 cost avoided, or $40,000,214 of
which $30,000 can be attributed to the loss in volume and would have been
recoverable had there been no change in the market, and $10,000 can be
attributed to the market drop as reflected in the reduced cost of production.
Courts have not been so liberal where the injured party is a middleman
whose buyer has breached a contract for the sale of goods that the middleman
has bought from another. The middleman is generally treated like the em-
ployee under a personal service contract and is remitted to damages based
on the difference between contract price and market price, with no allowance
for lost volume. The assumption is that his demand exceeds his supply and that
therefore he has not lost a sale if he is obliged to sell the same goods twice.215
216. For an extensive discussion of the lost volume problem, see Harris, supra note 73,
at 599-605; Harris, A Radical Restatement of the Law of Seller's Damages: Michigan
Results Compared, 61 MicH. L. Rxv. 849, 906-10, 918-19 (1963). Exceptional cases in
which a middleman has been allowed to show lost volume include Locks v. Wade, 36 N.J.
Super. 128, 114 A.2d 875 (1955) (lease of a juke box of which the lessor had an unlimited
supply) ; Smead v. Sutherland, 118 Vt. 361, 111 A2d 335 (1955) (sale of a "Henry J.
Vagabond," a car not readily marketable) ; Wilhelm Lubrication Co. v. Brattrud, 197
Minn. 626, 268 N.W. 634 (1936) (sale of grease in a "highly competitive market").
217. The Code provisions are discussed in Harris, supra note 165, at 94-99, and the
author concludes that "while it is easy to reach bad results under section 2-708, it is not
absolutely necessary." Id. at 101. Comment 2 to that section says that it "permits the re-
covery of lost profits in all appropriate cases, which would include all standard priced
goods." This confuses standard price, which should not be determinative, with lost volume,
which should. Furthermore, even if UCC § 2-708(2) is applied to illustration 6(a) in spite
of the fact that the goods are not standard priced, it allows only damages based on the
"profit ... which the seller would have made from full performance by the buyer" and thus
would appear to limit him to $30,000, the difference between $100,000 and $70,000, and not
his full loss of $40,000, the difference between $100,000 and $60,000. In short, the draftsmen
evidently did not address themselves to problems of lost volume in a fluctuating market.
218. Illustration 2 is set out in text following note 57 supra.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1199
replacement part is $110, Buyer's damages can be based on $10 and any inquiry
into the value of the part to him personally can be avoided. Where the principle
of substitution cannot be applied, however, calculation of recovery will often be
complicated by factors that are peculiar to the particular circumstances of the
injured party. It is here that questions of foreseeability and certainty arise.
As was observed earlier, one of the handicaps that attends a system of con-
tract damages aimed at protecting expectations is that it requires a hypothesis of
the position in which the injured party would have found himself had both
parties performed. It is that hypothetical position that determines the loss in
value, and consequently the loss on the bargain,that resulted from the breach.
Although the determination of contract damages, and particularly of other loss,
may involve the same problems of multiple cause
21 9
and intervening cause 220
that enliven discussions of torts, they are of relatively less importance than the
problems of causation that are involved in the hypothesis required to fix the
loss in value.221
Even this aspect of causation, however, is often rendered academic by the
additional and more stringent requirement that the loss must have been foresee-
able by the party in breach at the time he made the contract.2 2 2 This means that
the court must put itself in the position of that party at that earlier time and
imagine what he could have foreseen with regard to the other party's position in
the event of full performance. Since the calculation of loss in value is based on
the court's later hypothesis in this regard, foreseeability and not causation ordi-
narily marks the effective limit of liability for breach of contract.
This requirement of foreseeability grew out of a realization that even where
the injured party has taken such steps as the law expects to avoid loss, a rule
allowing full compensation might impose on the party in breach a crushing
burden, greatly out of proportion to the benefit that he originally expected to
219. E.g., Krauss v. Greenbarg, 137 F2d 569 (3d Cir. 1943).
If a number of factors are operating one may so predominate in bringing about
the harm as to make the effect produced by others so negligible that they cannot
be considered substantial factors and hence legal causes of the harm produced.
Id. at 572 (Goodrich, I.).
220. E.g., Newsome v. Western Union Tel. Co., 153 N.C. 153, 69 S.E. 10 (1910), dis-
cussed at text accompanying note 260 infra; Nirdlinger v. American Dist. Tel. Co., 245 Pa.
453, 91 A. 883 (1914) (failure of burglar alarm system, which the defendant had contracted
to maintain, "did not cause the burglary"). Such cases usually, however, turn on the issue
of foreseeability rather than causation. See also note 252 infra.
221. For the peculiar difficulties posed in determining the loss in value where the party
in breach could have rendered alternative promises, see RESTATEMENT § 344; 5 Co"IN
§ 1079; 11 S. Wmnm.SToN & W. JAEGER, A TREATISE ON THE LAw OF CONTRACTS § 1407
(3d ed. 1961).
222. Another reason why causation tends to play a lesser role in contract than in tort
is the higher standard of certainty in the latter, which also tends to make the issue of
causation academic. Furthermore, although the issue of causation is an essential part of a
tort action in negligence, nominal damages may be awarded for breach of contract without
regard to the element of causation.
1200 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW[ [Vol. 70:n145
derive from his bargain. This is particularly true of compensation for loss of
collateral profits. As Hart and Honor6 have pointed out:
223. H. HARuT & A. HoxoRk, CAUSATION IN THE LAW 281 (1959), Cf. F. BACON,
MAxIMs OF THE LAW 1 (1936) :
It were infinite for the law to judge the causes of causes, and their impulsions one
of another, therefore it contenteth itself with the immediate cause, and judgeth the
acts by that, without looking to any further degree.
224. Illustration 2 is set out in text following note 57 supra.
225. 9 Ex. 341, 156 Eng. Rep. 145 (1854).
226. Id. at 354, 156 Eng. Rep. at 151.
227. Id. at 355, 156 Eng. Rep. at 151. The facts of Hadley v. Baxendale are not entirely
clear. The head-note states, among the facts that "appeared" at the trial below, that, "The
plaintiffs' servant told the clerk that the mill was stopped, and that the shaft must be
sent immediately." Id. at 344, 156 Eng. Rep. at 147. And yet "it is reasonably plain from
Alderson B's judgment that the court rejected this evidence," as the court pointed out in
Victoria Laundry (Windsor) Ltd. v. Newman Indus. Ltd., [1949] 2 K.B. 528, 537.
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1201
usual course of things, from such breach of contract itself."2 28 Under the "sec-
ond rule" he is liable for such loss "as may reasonably be supposed to have been
in the contemplation of both parties, at the time they made the contract, as the
probable result of the breach of it." 22 91 Damages recoverable under the second
rule have sometimes been described as "consequential" or "special" to distin-
guish them from damages recoverable under the first, which are termed "direct"
or "general." The use of the terms "general" and "special" is unfortunate, how-
ever, since they originated in, and are still properly applied to, the distinction
between those losses that are so usual that they need not be specifically set out
230
in the pleadings and those that are so unusual that they must be so set out.
Since it is best not to confuse problems of substantive liability with those of
pleading by employing the same terminology for both, it is better to use the
23 1
terms "direct" and "consequential."
That portion of Baron Alderson's dictum described as the "first rule" has
occasioned little controversy. In the typical case, the losses "arising naturally,"
and therefore recoverable under that rule, are those afforded under the standard
formulas based on market price and discussed earlier. This is so because losses
due to market shifts are classed among those "arising naturally," although as
Bonbright remarked:
Some of the most extraordinary and most unpredictable losses re-
sulting from breaches of contract are those due to unusual changes in
market price. On the other hand, one of the most "normal" and most
predictable types of loss resulting from a breach is the "incidental
expense" or loss of sales imposed upon a businessman by a failure to
2 32
receive a shipment of goods on the promised date of delivery.
In Illustration 2, for example, the "first rule," in the form of Formula C-B'2 33
using market price, is ordinarily applied on the assumption that Manufacturer
can find a substitute for the replacement part promised him by Supplier, even
though he may have to pay a higher price. If Manufacturer disputes this
assumption and claims damages for lost profits, he must bring himself within the
"second rule."
It is this branch of Hadley v.Baxendale that has been significant. By con-
fining damages, other than those arising "naturally," to those "in the contem-
plation of the parties, at the time they made the contract, as the probable result
of the breach of it," the courts in following the rule imposed an important new
228. 9 x. 354, 156 Eng. Rep. 151.
229. Id.
230. See McComitmIcK § 8. See, e.g., FED. I. Crv. P. 9(g).
231. See UCC § 2-715 which speaks of "consequential damages." See also 5 Corbin
§ 1011.
232. 1 J. BOx=InaIT, supra note 62 at 291. Cf. B.P. Ducas Co. v. Bayer Co., 163
N.Y.S. 32 (Sup. Ct. 1916) (failure of supply and sharp rise in prices, caused by embargo
when war broke out, were not "contemplated" at time of contract). It should be kept in
mind, however, that protection of the parties against shifts in the market is considered in
our society to be a principal function of the institution of contract.
233. Formula C-B' is set out in text following 186 supra.
1202 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW[l [Vol. 70:1145
limitati6n on the scope of recovery that the jury could allow. The restriction
was not unheralded. Courts during the eighteenth century had, for example,
limited recovery for breach of a promise to pay money to the principal sum with
interest, for in such a case, as Sedgwick wrote in the decade before Hadley v.
Bazendale, "it is well settled that the consequences of the nonperformance can-
not be inquired into any way."2 4 Even the test of "contemplation" was not an
original one and showed, among other influences, that of French law.2 8
In the course of his opinion, Baron Alderson suggested that, "had the
special circumstances been known, the parties might have specially provided for
the breach of contract by special terms." 238 Some of the cases that followed
picked up this dictum and read into the "contemplation" test a requirement of
"tacit assumption." In Globe Refining Co. v. Landa Cotton Oil Co., 23 7 Justice
Holmes declared that
the extent of liability ... should be worked out on terms which it
fairly may be presumed he would have assented to if they had been
presented to his mind.... [It] depends on what liability the defendant
fairly may be supposed to have assumed consciously, or to have war-
ranted the plaintiff reasonably to suppose that it assumed, when the
contract was made .... [M] ere notice to a seller of some interest or
probable action of the buyer is not enough. 238
The trend has now, however, gone the other way. The Restatement's
formulation of the rule states merely that
compensation is given for only those injuries that the defendant had
234. T. SFDGwicK, supra note 56, at 111.
235. Pothier gives the example of
a canon, who for want of having the horse that I had engaged to deliver to him,
and not having been enabled to get another, was prevented from arriving at the
place of his benefice in time to be entitled to his revenue; I should not be liable for
the loss which he sustained thereby, although it was occasioned by the non-per-
formance of my obligation; for this is a damage which is foreign to the obligation,
which was not contemplated at the time of the contract, and to which it cannot be
supposed that I had any intention to submit.
R. POTWER, THE LAw OF OBLIGATI NS 91-92 (W. Evans trans. 1806). See generally,
Washington, supra note 57, at 97-108.
236. 9 Ex. at 355, 156 Eng. Rep. at 151.
237. 190 U.S. 540 (1903).
238. Id. at 543-45. See also British Columbia Saw Mill Co. v. Nettleship, L.R. 3 C.P.
499 (1868), on which Holmes relied in part. There Bovill, C.J., said that the liability "must
be something ... to which he has assented expressly or impliedly by entering into the
contract." Id. at 506. And Willes, J., added that if the liability claimed "had been presented
to the mind of the ship-owner at the time of making the contract, as the basis upon which
he was contracting, he would at once have rejected it." Id. at 508. Holmes had already
stated his view in 0. HOLrmES, THE CommoN LAw 302-03 (1881):
It is true that, when people make contracts, they usually contemplate the perfor-
mance rather than the breach .... [But] as the relation of contractor and con-
tractee is voluntary, the consequences attaching to the relation must be voluntary..
What the event contemplated by the promise is, or in other words what will
amount to a breach of contract, is a matter of interpretation and construction.
What consequences of the breach are assumed is more remotely, in like manner,
a matter of construction, having regard to the circumstances under which the
contract is made.
1203
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH
Two judges dissented. Federal knew, they argued, that the sugar was destined
for resale by Czarnikow.
I do not understand the law to be that before a seller is liable for loss
of profits, he must have known the terms and conditions of the sub-
contracts made on resale by his purchaser. That Federal did not know
the price or the terms of the contracts which Czarnikow had made
with its consignees
2 49
of the sugar was for the purpose of this action
immaterial.
Similar controversies may arise where there are claims for profits based on an
abnormal use of the goods 250 or an unusually profitable subcontract, 251 or for
losses due to the occurrence of an unexpected intervening event 252 or a peculiar
penalty provision in a subcontract. 253 The extent to which each of these must be
specifically foreseeable under the test of Hadley v. Baxendale is a matter on
which courts have disagreed.
Equally troublesome has been the substantial claim for a foreseeable loss of
profits against a promisor whose undertaking was in return for a relatively
insignificant fee. In the typical case the injured party's loss in value greatly ex-
ceeds the benefit that the party in breach was to have received in return. Indeed,
had the miller in Hadley v. Baxendale made his situation known to the carrier
when he gave him the broken shaft, the court would have been faced with such
2 54
a case and would, on its own dictum, have had to allow the miller's claim.
Many of the most notable examples of such cases have involved undertakings
by carriers to deliver goods, 255 by telegraph companies to transmit messages, 256
and by financial institutions to lend money.2 57 But these are by no means the
only instances in which courts have shown a reluctance to impose upon a prom-
isor a loss which, although foreseeable, is greatly out of proportion to the
benefit that he received in return for his promise. In a case with facts very
similar to those of Illustration 2, the Arkansas Supreme Court relied upon the
gross disproportion between the damages claimed and the benefit received in
25 s
denying recovery for lost profits.
261. Id. at 156, 69 S.. at 11. It is also possible that the court may deny recovery by
simply refusing to admit foreseeability. A typical example is Kerr S.S. Co. v. Radio Corp.
of America, 245 NY. 284, 157 N.E. 140 (1927), in which a business sent a long and
expensive radiogram in cipher directing the loading of a ship. When the radiogram was
not transmitted, the ship was not loaded, the freight was lost, and the business sued the
telegraph company for damages based on this loss. The New York Court of Appeals
reversed the judgment of the two lower courts which had held that, although the telegraph
company could not read the cipher, the message must have been understood, judging from
its length, its cost, and the names of the parties, as relating to a business transaction.
According to J. DAWS01" & W. HARVEY, CASES ON CONTRACTS AND CONTRACT REMmDES
46 (1969), the record indicated that a copy of the code book, which was widely used by
business firms, was kept along with others in the telegraph company's office for the use of
its customers, and about 80% of the radiograms sent were in some kind of code. But
Judge Cardozo wrote:
The defendant upon receiving from a steamship company a long telegram in
cipher to be transmitted to Manila would naturally infer that the message had
relation to business of some sort. Beyond that, it could infer nothing... Notice
of the business, if it is to lay the basis for special damages, must be sufficiently
informing to be notice of the risk.
245 N.Y. at 288, 157 N.E. at 141.
262. The RESTATEMENT uses the term "legal cause." RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF
TORTS § 9 (1965).
263. Patterson, The Apportionment of Business Risks Through Legal Devices, 24
COLUm. L. REV. 335, 342 (1924).
264. McCoRmicK § 138 at 567.
265. Farnsworth, supra note 1, at 590-99.
1208 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEWV [Vol. 70 :11k5
This argument rests on the same assumptions as does that for implied terms in
general: that reasonable contracting parties foresee what is foreseeable, and
that they provide expressly for risks that they foresee-assumptions that are
questionable at best, at least outside the realm of carriers, telegraph companies,
270
and the like.
The difficulty, however, in the cases where the injured party's loss in value
is greatly out of proportion to the benefit that the party in breach was to have
received in return, is not that the test of foreseeability unduly circumscribes
liability; on the contrary, it is that it does not restrict it enough. Although
Hadley v. Baxendale was originally seen as a limitation on liability, the problem
here is that it may not limit it enough. This difficulty even moved McCormick to
see merit in the widely repudiated "tacit agreement" test, although he recog-
nized that it
adds the fiction of a tacit promise to the original fiction of "contempla-
tion," and seldom is there anything in the situation more definite and
mandatory than the judge's sense of justice to tell him to find the
presence or absence of this silent promise to assume the risk. The re-
current cropping up of the idea in the opinions of the courts indicates
266. E.g., Gefter v. Rosenthal, 384 Pa. 123, 119 A.2d 250 (1956) (defendant caterer
charged the plaintiff's guests for checking their coats at plaintiff's wedding anniversary
dinner). There are, however, exceptions where recovery has been allowed. E.g., Lamm v.
Shingleton, 231 N.C. 10, 55 S.E.2d 810 (1949) (defendant's failure adequately to seal
the vault containing the body of the plaintiff's husband caused her shock) ; Westesen v.
Olathe State Bank, 78 Colo. 217, 240 P. 689 (1925) (defendant bank's failure to honor
the plaintiff's checks left him without financial resources on a trip to California).
267. See 5 Coanrm § 1010. For the older view, see note 238 supra.
268. See note 236 supra.
269. H. HART & A. HoNoRA, supra note 223, at 283-84.
270. Farnsworth, Disputes Over Omission in Contracts, 68 COLum. L. Rav. 860,
872-73 (1968).
19701 CONTRACTUAL BREACH 1209
that some of the judges have found the conception useful in giving
expression to this sense of justice of the situation.27 '
Such a patent fiction is, however, a poor device to use to gain flexibility.
Leon Green urged abandonment of the test of foreseeability of consequences
in favor of another which he described in this way:
The formula is one for use in determining whether the interest in-
volved is protected by the agreement. And it is not a contemplation of
consequences from a possible breach, but a contemplation of interests
which may be protected by the contract. Parties, in making contracts,
rarely contemplate the losses which would result from its breach. But
they do count the advantages they will gain from its performance.
What interests does the contractpromote or serve ?272
But in applying his suggestion he had difficulty in avoiding traditional reasoning.
Thus, in regard to a seller's breach of his promise to deliver goods, Green
stated that
the only interest, in the absence of peculiar information that will be
recognized as covered by their contract, will be [the buyer's] interest
in making a resale of the goods on the market .... Ma
271. McCopmicK § 141 at 580. But cf. McKibbin v. Pierce, 190 S.W. 1149 (Tex.
Civ. App. 1916) (promisor held liable although he refused to assume liability based on
special circumstances when he was given notice of them).
272. L. GRazz, RATioNALE oP PgoxmATz CAUSE 51 (1927).
273. Id. at 53.
274. McCoRmcK § 140.
Our rules should sanction, as our actual practice probably does, the award of
consequential damages against one who deliberately and wantonly breaks faith,
regardless of the foreseeability of the loss when the contract was made.
Id. § 141 at 581. For an example of a case in which the "wilful" nature of the breach was
taken account of in this connection, see Miholevich v. Mid-West Mut. Auto Ins. Co., 261
Mich. 495, 246 N.W. 202 (1933) (the insured, "a man without means," was not limited to
damages based on interest when his automobile insurer's "wilful neglect" to pay a judgment
caused his imprisonment and consequent "shame and mortification as well as loss of time").
See notes 203, 234 and 257 supra.
COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW [Vol. 70:1145
275. Comment, Lost Profits as Contract Damages: Problems of Proof and Limitallons
on Recovery, 65 YALa L.J. 992, 1020 (1956).
276. Frequently it is said that the defendant ought not to have to pay for un-
forseen injuries, because if he had foreseen such a liability he would have required
a larger compensation. This may sometims be true. It is probable in most cases,
however, that when a man is assenting to a contract he does not regard the risk
of his own nonperformance as great and he fixes the compensation with reference
to the cost of his performance and not with reference to the penalty for non-
performance.
5 CORBIN § 1008.
277. McCoRaicK § 32 at 124. McCormick also points out that in England "Problems
of certainty of amount are usually discussed under the vague rubric of 'remoteness.'" Id.
§ 25 at 98.
278. Griffin v. Colver, 16 N.Y. 489, 491 (1858).
279. RESTAATMENT § 331(1) provides that damages are recoverable "only to the ex-
tent that the evidence affords a sufficient basis for estimating their amount in money with
reasonable certainty." Comment 1 to UCC § 1-106 goes far beyond this and states that
the Code's provision that its remedies are to be "liberally administered to the end that the
aggrieved party may be put in as good a position as if the other party had fully performed,"
is intended to reject any doctrine that damages must be calculable with mathematical
accuracy. Compensatory damages are often at best approximate: they have to be proved
with whatever definiteness and accuracy the facts permit, but no more.
1970] CONTRACTUAL BREACH "1211
the beginning of June until the middle of August, the appellate court upheld
the exclusion of the testimony of an expert witness with respect to the estimated
profits made by other drive-in theatres in the area during the same period and,
by that particular theatre during the comparable period of the following year
and with respect to a market survey made before the theatre operator selected
the site. In the court's words,
loss of profits from a business which has not yet gone into operation
may not be recovered because they are merely speculative and in- 296
capable of being ascertained with the requisite degree of certainty.
The extent to which changes in the law of evidence, such as the relaxation of
the hearsay rule to admit business records more freely, and changes in the
techniques of business, such as greater reliance on analyses of costs and studies
of market behavior, will help claimants in meeting the requirement of certainty
remains problematical. 297
McCormick said that, like the test of foreseeability,
the standard of "certainty" was developed, and has been used, chiefly
as a convenient means for keeping within the bounds of reasonable
expectation
298 the risk which litigation imposes upon commercial enter-
prise.
Since there can be no recovery for profits which are not foreseeable, the
practical effect of the requirement of certainty is to deny recovery for some
profits even though they are foreseeable. It thus has an impact, beyond that
296. Id. at 618, 112 A.2d at 904.
297. See Comment, supra note 275, at 1018-19. Courts have even differed on whether
to award the value of a "chance of winning" where the alternatives are a certain gain
or nothing, and turn on a single event rather than on a number of transactions. In
Collatz v. Fox Wis. Amusement Corp., 239 Wis. 156, 300 N.W. 162 (1941), Collatz, by
estimating the number of jelly beans in a jar, became one of the nine contestants in a
quiz contest, in which he was one of the last two survivors. When both survivors failed on
the final round, the prize, a new automobile, was awarded to the other survivor on the
ground that, because he had been asked his question after Collatz, he was the last con-
testant eliminated. Collatz's claim for half the value of the car was denied, "for it cannot
be assumed nor is it susceptible of proof that had the contest proceeded to a proper finish
he would have become the winner." Id., 239 Wis. at 158, 300 N.W. at 164. In Wachtel v.
Nat'l Alfalfa Journal Co., 190 Iowa 1293, 176 N.W. 801 (1920), the plaintiff entered a
contest in which she could win one of many prizes, including a new automobile, by selling
subscriptions to the defendant's newspaper. After several weeks, when the plaintiff was
leading in her contest district, the defendant abandoned the contest in that district. The
court held that she was entitled to recovery, the amount to be determined by the jury on
the basis of the value of the prizes and her reasonable probability of winning one of them.
See, favoring recovery, RzSTATEMENT '§ 332; 5 CoPamx § 1030; McConacKc § 31. See atso
Pollack v. Pollack, 39 S.W2d 853 (Tex. Comm. App. 1931), where life expectancy tables
were used to calculate whether, and for how long one brother would outlive the other.
That case is criticized in 45 HA.v. L. Rnv. 585-86 (1932). According to Bonbright, the
value of a chance is the discounted value of what it will confer on its possessor. 1 J. BON-
BRrGHT, supra note 62, at 348. Courts have been less sympathetic toward recovery where
the uncertain event is within the control of the injured party himself. See, e.g., Western
Union Tel. Co. v. Hall, 124 U.S. 444, 458 (1888) (sender's telegram ordering purchase
on market delayed a day, following which no purchase was made because of large ad-
vance in market during delay; damages based on market rise were denied on ground that
"it is not found that he would have resold the next day at the advance").
298. McCoumcir § 28 at 105.
1214 COLUMBIA LAWF REVIEW7 [Vol. 70:114 5
of the test of foreseeability, in shifting part of the risk of the contracted venture
from the promisor to the promisee, and further diminishes the protection that
the law affords the promisee's expectations. Fuller and Perdue suggested that
Where the test of foreseeability is met, but the court still feels that liability
would impose on the party in breach a risk disproportionate to the rewards
that he expected under the contract, "the test of certainty is the most usual
surrogate."29 9 As has already been observed, it may be that in some cases where
the test of foreseeability is met, full compensation for collateral profits would
nonetheless be objectionable. Still, the requirement of certainty has, in this
regard, the same disadvantage as the test of foreseeability, in that it tends to
support all-or-nothing recovery rather than the sharing of the risk. Further-
more, it has the additional drawback that it purports to be directed, not at
considerations of risk, but at considerations of proof and of control of excessive
awards.
Even in situations where the claim is to collateral profits, so that the
problems of proof are greatest and the risk of excessive verdicts is highest,
it is hard to defend a requirement that attempts to cope with the necessity for
speculation by denying recovery altogether rather than by resorting to reason-
able approximation. That there is some judicial sympathy for this view is
suggested by two lines of cases that have eroded the requirement of certainty.
In the first, courts have relaxed or abandoned the requirement where they have
concluded that it has been met with respect to the "fact" of loss and the only
remaining questions go to the "extent" of loss.800 In the second, they have
relaxed or abandoned the requirement where the breach has been characterized
as "willful," 301 in spite of the general tenet that the amount of contract damages
does not depend on the character of the breach. To the extent that these cases
herald a general relaxation of the requirement of certainty in favor of the
normal burden of persuasion, they are to be applauded.
- Sometimes, failure to meet the requirement of certainty does not pre-
clude all recovery, but merely results in a lesser amount of damages. Where
loss in value is uncertain, the expectation interest may be protected by resort
to market price, as where compensation for delay in the construction of a
CONCLUSION
302. See RESTATErmET § 331(2) ; 5 CoaniN § 1029. Where there is such an alterna-
tive under a standard formula, a court may be particularly reluctant to allow profits in
the face of an objection that they are uncertain.
303. The Behan case is discussed in text accompanying notes 141-43 supra. See
Fuller & Perdue, supra note 12, at 373-77, and note that this is one of the explanations
of the rule of Flureauv. Thornhill mentioned in note 14 supra.
304. Examples of instances in which courts have taken some account of the nature
of the breach are collected in note 9 supra. In none of these instances do the courts speak
in terms of "penalty," however, but rather in terms of the basis or measure of damages
or the applicability of some limitation on damages-whether damages are to be based
on the expectation or the reliance interest, whether damages are to be measured by cost
to complete or by market price, whether damages are to be measured by the rise in
market price or the loss of resale profit, or the extent to which the loss must be foreseeable
and certain. But if the consequence of an aggravated breach is to impose on the party in
breach a heavier liability than would be imposed for an innocent breach, the effect is to
penalize him for the aggravated nature of the breach. The most appealing of the instances
are those discussed in text accompanying notes 98-117 supra and in note 189 supra, for if
no account is there taken of the nature of the breach, the party in breach may wilfully have
broken his promise for the purely selfish reason that he would be financially better off by
nonperformance than by performance. See the discussion of Illustration 3g in text following
note 125 supra, indicating that a gain of this sort is not directly recoverable by the injured
party.
1216 COLUMBIA LAW REVIEW