Advancing The Concept of Public Goods: February 2003
Advancing The Concept of Public Goods: February 2003
Advancing The Concept of Public Goods: February 2003
net/publication/253422413
CITATIONS READS
169 5,959
2 authors:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
Inge Kaul, ed. 2016. Global Public Goods. Edward Elgar Research Collection View project
All content following this page was uploaded by Ronald U. Mendoza on 11 December 2014.
Recent decades have seen major shifts in what is considered and treated as private
and as public. Economic liberalization, technological advances, and privatization
have allowed markets to expand into new product areas and be integrated across
national borders. In addition, ever-increasing numbers of private corporations
have gone public, floating shares on stock markets.
As a result the public—people in general and shareholders in particular—want
to know much more about companies’ production and marketing principles.
Consumers insist on product labeling. Labor and environmental policies can no
longer be hidden behind boardroom doors. Public norms define expected stan-
dards. And civil society organizations assess and publicize corporate citizenship
(Keane 2001; UNRISD 2000). Moreover, private businesses engage in self-regula-
tion, in setting norms and standards, and in arbitrating conflicts—functions usu-
ally associated with the state (Cutler, Haufler, and Porter 1999).
Meanwhile, government programs increasingly follow market principles,
outsourcing service delivery to private providers and recovering costs through
user fees and other charges. There are also calls, from businesses and civil society
organizations, for governments to operate more transparently and accountably.
As the growing literature on good governance signals, the public sector often lacks
publicness.
Yet as Edwards and Zadek (in this volume) show, businesses and states are also
shining the spotlight of publicness on civil society organizations—on their rep-
resentativeness and legitimacy. The shifts between private and public thus reflect
greater shared concern for the public domain among all the main actors—the
state, businesses, civil society organizations, and households—and for what oth-
ers expect of them and how their private activities affect others (figure 1). A wider
arena, and probably a new era, of publicness have emerged.
Assessments of these trends vary widely. Some analysts applaud the greater
freedom granted to Adam Smith’s “invisible hand” (Micklethwait and Wooldridge
The authors are grateful to Isabelle Grunberg, Todd Sandler, Victor Venida, and Oran Young for
helpful comments.
78
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 79
FIGURE 1
The expanding public domain
Public
domain
Business Households
2000). Others fear that the world is headed toward ruthless “turbo” capitalism,
driven by shareholders and property owners (Luttwak 1999). Still others waver,
recognizing both risks and opportunities. As Giddens and Hutton (2000) point
out, optimists and pessimists write with equal fervor because they share the same
preoccupation: trying to strike the right balance between markets and states.
Markets and states are two of society’s mechanisms for coordinating eco-
1
nomic activity. Each plays a role in providing private as well as public goods.
Sometimes one mechanism works better, sometimes the other. It all depends on
2
the good (or service) to be provided. Curious, then, that there is hardly any debate
on how to strike the right balance between private and public goods. Yet that is
essentially the balance on which people’s well-being depends.
Even the lives of the richest people depend on this balance. Enjoying wealth
is difficult in the midst of crime, violence, political turmoil, virulent disease, or
excessive financial volatility. Thus public goods complement private goods.
Similarly, escaping poverty is difficult if there is no public consensus on respect
for all people’s lives—on people’s need to drink unpolluted water, eat safe food,
have a limited working day, enjoy the security of lawfulness, and be protected
against ill health. A decent life depends on having such goods in the public
domain, available for all people to consume.
But what are private goods? And what are public? Economics textbooks
define private goods as those that are rival in consumption and that have exclud-
3
able benefits (or costs). That is, consumption of a private good by one person or
group diminishes its availability for others—and one person or group can exclude
others from consuming it. Private goods meet the requirement for market trans-
actions. Their ownership can be transferred or denied conditional on exchange—
that is, paying their price.
80 CONCEPTS
Public goods are defined as having the opposite characteristics: as being non-
rival in consumption and having nonexcludable benefits. The market cannot
price these goods efficiently. Accordingly, they are often classified as market fail-
ures and as justified cases for government intervention. Thus the textbook defin-
itions return to the market-state issue: the provision of private goods is assigned
to the market, and public goods to the state. The public domain appears as a resid-
ual category, with states performing tasks that markets cannot. But as noted,“pri-
vate” can no longer simply be equated with markets, and “public” with states. Both
contribute, among others, to the public and private domains. Moreover, the prop-
erties of goods can change from being public to private and from private to public.
This chapter revisits the standard definition of public goods, suggesting that
a distinction be made between these goods’ basic or original properties (such as
being nonrival or nonexcludable) and their actual characteristics—those that
society has assigned to them. For some goods the basic and the actual qualities
may be the same. But for many, perhaps even most, they are not. According to this
expanded definition, public goods are those that are nonexclusive—that is, de
facto public in consumption.
The next section shows how this definition may require reconsidering some
aspects of the theory of public goods. The discussion then turns to global public
goods, the public goods of interest in this volume. The analysis covers the defin-
ition and typology of these goods, the politics of their provision, and the dimen-
sions of their production—highlighting issues clarified in subsequent chapters.
The discussion shows that to better understand global public goods, it is
important to advance the concept of public goods in general, including that of
4
national public goods. This is especially important because most global public
goods are national public goods that, in the wake of globalization, have gone
global.Viewed from the production side, they can be seen as national public goods
plus international cooperation (see also the chapter on institutions by Kaul and
Le Goulven in this volume). So, understanding global public goods requires
understanding national public goods, and under current conditions the theory of
public goods would be incomplete without a full discussion of global public
goods. This chapter identifies some aspects of the theory of public goods that may
need to be reconsidered and subjected to further study and policy debate.
Although the literature on public goods is extensive and diverse, there is a stan-
5
dard definition of public goods anchored on nonrivalry and nonexcludability.
But the properties of goods do not always correspond to this standard definition.
The main reason is that society can modify the (non)rivalry and (non)exclud-
ability of a good’s benefits. Goods often become private or public as a result of
deliberate policy choices. That is why consideration should be given to expand-
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 81
ing the definition—to recognize that in many if not most cases, goods exist not
in their original forms but as social constructs, largely determined by policies and
other collective human actions. According to this revised definition, public goods
are nonexclusive or, put differently, de facto public in consumption.
FIGURE 2
The basic properties of goods: a conventional approach to
public goods
RIVAL NONRIVAL
QUADRANT 1a QUADRANT 2
Examples: Examples:
• Milk • Research and development
• Land • Noncommercial knowledge (such as
EXCLUDABLE
QUADRANT 4 QUADRANT 3b
Examples: Examples:
• Atmosphere • Moonlight
• Wildlife • Peace and security/conflict
NONEXCLUDABLE
Note: These properties are basic in that they have not been altered by public policies or other human actions.
a. In the literature, goods that fall into this quadrant—those with rival and excludable benefits—are often automatically
deemed private goods. But as argued in this chapter, the properties of (non)rivalry and (non)excludability only signal a good’s
potential for being (public) private—not its de facto provision status.
b. Goods that fall into this quadrant are often called pure public goods—nonrival and nonexcludable in consumption. Most of
these can exist in variable quantities, ranging from adequately supplied (as with peace) to inadequately supplied (as with open
conflict). But the available “amount” of the good is the same for all consumers.
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 83
FIGURE 3
The socially determined status of goods: an expanded concept
of public goods
RIVAL NONRIVAL
QUADRANT 1 QUADRANT 2
PRIVATE GOODS 2A NONRIVAL GOODS MADE EXCLUSIVE
• Milk • Patented knowledge of manufacturing
• Land processes
• Education • Cable and satellite television
NONEXCLUSIVE
• As yet unknown “bads” (such as
EXCLUSIVE
undiscovered pollutants)
QUADRANT 4 QUADRANT 3
4A RIVAL GOODS MADE
PURE PUBLIC GOODS
(PARTIALLY) EXCLUSIVE
• Moonlight
• Atmosphere: air pollution permits
• Peace and security/conflict
• Fish stocks: fishing quotas
• Law and order/anarchy
• Toll roads
• Financial stability/excessive
financial volatility
• Economic stability/flagging growth
• Growth and development potential
4B RIVAL GOODS KEPT OR MADE
(such as an educated workforce)
NONEXCLUSIVEa
• Efficient/inefficient markets
• Atmosphere
• Communicable diseases
• Wildlife such as fish stocks
spreading/controlled or eradicated
• Public parks and nature reserves
• Knowledge embodied in
• Basic education and health care
pharmaceutical drugs
for all
a. There are two main types of goods in this category. The first are rival and nonexclusive, often referred to as common pool
resources. Because these goods are innately rival, intensive use can threaten their sustainability. The solution is often to make
such goods more exclusive, though not entirely so. New counterpart private goods such as pollution permits (see quadrant 4A)
are often invented to manage the use of these resources. In countries with air pollution controls, for example, the atmosphere
is still available for the general public to enjoy. But it can no longer be used excessively as a pollution sink by firms, which
must now buy privately held and tradable pollution permits. The second type of goods in this category includes basic education
and health care—public goods that can be made fully private but that are often made nonexclusive by policy choice.
84 CONCEPTS
Rival goods can also be kept or made nonexclusive; see quadrant 4B of figure
3. As noted for land, one policy option for doing so is to create a management
regime that maintains broad public access. Public parks and nature reserves are
examples. Another is to make rival goods available in such plentiful quantities that
there need not be any competition over who gets to use them. Many societies have
chosen this policy route for basic education and health services.
This approach is usually taken for two reasons. First, goods such as education
and health are often seen as human rights and as having intrinsic value. Societal
notions of fairness might require that education be made available to all in the
spirit of commodity egalitarianism (Tobin 1970). Second, an educated and
healthy population generates important private and public benefits. Educated
people tend to be more productive and to contribute more to economic growth
and development. Thus many countries have made basic education not just free
and universal but compulsory as well.
If basic education is assessed only in terms of its natural properties, it falls
into quadrant 1. But when judged on its actual form, as in figure 3, it must appear
three times. In quadrant 1 it figures as a private good of educated individuals. In
quadrant 4B it appears as a universally available, nonexclusive service. And in
quadrant 3 it shows up as having added to a country’s overall productivity and
economic growth potential. Two of its dimensions (in quadrants 4B and 3) are in
the public domain. As social institutions evolve, many goods—private and pub-
lic—develop into “mixed” cases, displaying both exclusive and nonexclusive
properties.
The goods in quadrant 3 in figures 2 and 3 are technically nonexcludable and
so also exist de facto in nonexclusive form. An example is moonlight. With cur-
rent technology, policymakers have no choice but to leave moonlight in quadrant
3. Its nonexcludability—and hence its nonexclusiveness—appears to be an innate
quality. Obviously such goods are not socially determined and so constitute a pos-
sible exception to the notion of mixed or evolving properties.
But goods can change their positions if new technology develops. Take tele-
vision signals. There was no question of public or private television before it
became possible to scramble television waves and to restrict transmission through
cables. Now some channels can be viewed only for a fee. As a result television falls
partly in the private domain (quadrant 2A in figure 3) and partly in the public
(quadrant 2B).
Returning to quadrant 3, the main goods are policy outcomes or overall con-
ditions such as peace, law and order, financial stability, efficient markets, and com-
municable disease control and eradication. Once these conditions exist, all people
can—and sometimes must—consume them. The goods’ benefits are indivisible,
so they exist for all in the same amount and with the same characteristics.
These goods are often more evident when undersupplied. For example, con-
flict is more noticeable than peace, which is often taken for granted. Similarly, peo-
86 CONCEPTS
ple realize that they are “part of the market” much more when a stock market
crashes and the value of their investments tumbles. Or they recognize the close
links between general health conditions when a flu epidemic strikes. The corre-
sponding public bads are also listed in quadrant 3.
Hence figure 3 illustrates that in most if not all cases, publicness and private-
ness are social constructs. It often takes a long time and repeated efforts to anchor
a good firmly in the public domain, as with equity or respect for human rights.
Similarly, it often takes a policy decision to make a good private. And in the fol-
low-up, it takes an elaborate institutional and organizational framework to define,
assign, and monitor private property rights, update and revise them as needed,
enforce them, and settle disputes.
Societal norms and decisions of what is and is not private and in the realm of
discretion of individual actors often reach deeply into what many perceive as the
private sphere of people’s lives—such as matters of matrimony and inheritance of
private property. Most societies recognize that people should not be abused, even
in the privacy of their homes and not even by their relatives. Children also enjoy
this right, along with broader freedom from violence. On a much broader level,
state borders can no longer be used as shields behind which to curtail human rights,
practice corruption, spew air pollution, or pursue publicly frowned-on policies.
The standard definition of public goods has illuminated many important
issues in the provision of such goods, including free riding and the prisoner’s
dilemma. But that definition does not fully capture the policy approach needed
when dealing with the novel nature of many of these goods. As a result many pub-
lic goods are still analyzed in an almost passive manner. Too often it is assumed
that a nonrival and nonexcludable good must be public, or that a rival and exclud-
able good must be private and is best left to the market.
That approach misses a basic point. Before goods appear in the market or in
the portfolio of state agents, policy choices have been made or norms established
to make the goods private in the sense of being exclusive or public in the sense of
being nonexclusive. And even if these decisions have already been made in the
past, that does not preclude rethinking them in light of new realities. “The pub-
lic will operates constantly, not only before and/or after. If it operated ‘before’, that
is tantamount to admitting that it operates afterward and at all times in between”
(Wildavsky 1994, p. 388).
The excludability or nonexcludability of goods often facilitates or hampers
such public policy choices. But it usually does not obviate the need to make them.
In any event, the defining characteristics of many public goods are not inherent
and are often socially endogenous. This issue has been noted in the literature
on public goods (Cornes and Sandler 1994, 1996; Malkin and Wildavsky 1991;
Marmolo 1999; Wildavsky 1994). Yet its recognition has not led to the formulation
of a definition to complement the standard one and help policymakers distinguish
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 87
Definition 1: Goods have a special potential for being public if they have
nonexcludable benefits, nonrival benefits, or both.
88 CONCEPTS
This definition does not differ much from the current textbook definition
except that it does not automatically categorize public or private goods based
merely on (non)rivalry and (non)excludability—properties clearly malleable and
subject to change by policy choice. This serves as a reminder to explore whether
and to what extent all goods with the potential for publicness are public in prac-
tice. If a good is found not to be public, it is worth asking whether this is desir-
able from various viewpoints, including considerations of efficiency and equity.
The complementary definition, referring to the actual properties of public
goods, would be:
Definition 2: Goods are de facto public if they are nonexclusive and avail-
able for all to consume.
use it, individuals usually need to have command over private means—to be able
to afford a computer, telephone line, and related costs. So, the Internet is not fully
in the public domain. Similarly, illiterate people remain excluded from large parts
of the world’s knowledge because they cannot absorb knowledge that exists in
written form. Only goods that are truly available for all people to consume qual-
ify as de facto or fully public. The consumption of a public good can be volun-
tary: some people may want to enjoy a beautiful sunset, others may not. Or it can
be mandatory: it is usually a requirement to respect traffic rules.
The case of access barriers must be distinguished from that of some individu-
als being able to afford a private exit strategy (up to a point) from a public condi-
tion. For example, people can protect themselves against crime and violence by
increasing the number of locks on their doors. But crime and violence remain in
the public domain. Making greater use of private goods to compensate for
degraded public goods—such as a public domain filled with negative externalities
and threats to human security and well-being—is what Cropper and Oates (1992)
call averting behavior. It may allow some individuals to avoid harm to their well-
being, often at high cost. But it does not change the character of the public domain.
In sum, public goods are those that are in the public domain because they are
technically nonexcludable, because they are placed or left there by policy choice,
or because they are allowed to be there inadvertently. To the extent that access bar-
riers limit their consumption, they are only partly public. Public goods thus form
important components of the public domain, but the public domain is more than
the ensemble of public goods.
More than the notion of public goods, the concept of the public domain is
actively and often heatedly debated. In some societies a public sphere remains a
13
rather unfamiliar concept. Yet as markets and states have expanded and become
more differentiated, they have moved out of and away from individual house-
holds, creating the private domain and the public. The actors in the public space
are primarily civil society organizations and the general public. But they are also
firms pursuing profits within publicly defined parameters and in the public spot-
light. The suggestion here is to refer to the various goods in the public sphere—
tangible and intangible—as public goods.
A more active, policy-driven approach to identifying public goods opens the door
for an equivalent expansion of other aspects of public goods theory and research.
The proposed expansion of the definition of public goods could thus be accom-
panied by further analyses of various provision-related policy issues. Here four
such issues are discussed: public choices, the difference between publicness in con-
sumption and publicness in utility, aggregation technologies and strategies, and
the adequacy of provision.
90 CONCEPTS
FIGURE 4
Triangle of publicness
Publicness in
consumption
Publicness in
Publicness in 0 the distribution
decisionmaking of (net) benefits
Other disempowered groups hold similar views. Thus civil society, with its
strengthened engagement in public policymaking, is seeking to change the “not
so public” nature of the public sphere. Perhaps precisely because of these efforts,
methodologies should be developed to systematically assess individual public
goods and the public domain as a whole against two criteria:
• The publicness—or participatory nature—of decisionmaking on which goods
to place in the public domain, how much of them to produce, how to shape
them, and how to distribute their benefits among all concerned.
• The publicness—or equity—of the distribution of benefits; that is, the extent
to which various groups (consumers of public goods) derive benefits.
These two criteria can be combined with the main, distinguishing criterion of
public goods:
• The publicness of consumption—the nonexclusiveness of the consumption
19
of public goods across individuals and groups.
Combining these three criteria (or dimensions) of publicness results, as suggested
by Kaul (2001), in an ideal “triangle of publicness” (figure 4). This triangle shows
a good that is public in consumption, based on decisionmaking that fully meets
the condition of the generalized equivalence principle, and with net benefits
evenly distributed across diverse population groups.
the private domain and into markets. Yet while the state was often taken out of the
production of tangible, excludable goods, it was expected to become more active
in the provision of more intangible but equally real and important goods, such as
respect for law or the creation of incentives for private activity.
It is probably because of the long-standing equation of public goods with
state-provided goods that only in 1983 did Hirshleifer draw attention to the fact
that “standard models have assumed…that there is nothing at all special on the
supply side, in the social technology for the production of public goods” (p. 372).
He proposed examining alternatives such as “social composition functions, i.e. as
different possible ways of amalgamating individual productions into social avail-
abilities of a public good” (p. 372, italics in the original). Since then a debate has
emerged on the aggregation technologies for various types of public goods. The
20
three main technologies are summation, weakest link, and best shot.
Public goods can require various inputs from different aggregation tech-
nologies. Climate stability is often mentioned as an example of a summation
process because it requires all countries to limit carbon dioxide emissions to cer-
tain levels. Yet some of the building blocks of this good show that other aggrega-
tion technologies are also used, such as the required technological advances in
cleaner energy that may be achieved through a best shot strategy (see figure 2 in
the chapter on institutions by Kaul and Le Goulven in this volume). Furthermore,
enabling all countries to stay within certain emission limits could call for a weak-
est link strategy of providing development assistance.
Moreover, different building blocks could be based on different production
or public policy partnerships, each following different incentives and requiring
different types of financing. The question of how the production of public goods
works has found limited attention because for many years public goods were often
financed and produced by the state. But since the 1980s government has become
less involved in the production of essentially private goods such as telecommuni-
cation services. Meanwhile, it has played a larger role in creating an enabling
framework for private and voluntary activities.
Yet few studies have followed particular goods to study how these changes
have affected the goods’ public-private properties and production processes.
There has often been an outcry about the marketization of goods. But an impor-
tant dimension is whether and to what extent marketization has been—or failed
to be—accompanied by public incentives to enable private actors to internalize
externalities. This information is important for understanding why goods may or
may not have been underprovided in certain instances.
In today’s multiactor world it is thus critical to think beyond the main types
of social aggregation technologies. It is important to examine in more detail the
various building blocks of public goods, exploring especially the types of incen-
tives that different groups, notably private actors, might require to be motivated
and able to deliver their expected contributions to a particular public good.
94 CONCEPTS
So far, public goods have been discussed without specifying the geographic or
jurisdictional reach of their benefits—local, national, regional, or global.22 This
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 95
section focuses on global public goods. It starts by identifying which public goods
have global benefits. An interesting issue is the extent to which some goods are
global naturally and others have become global by policy choice. The analysis then
considers whether any aspects of the provision of global public goods are specific
to their political decisionmaking and production. This second question sets the
stage for some of the points examined further in subsequent chapters.
Two main findings emerge. First, globalized national public goods are an
important class of global public goods. Second, the expansion of public goods the-
ory suggested earlier becomes even more important when considering global pub-
lic goods—because such goods require and create commonality in a world of
extreme disparities.
Definition 3: Global public goods are goods whose benefits extend to all
countries, people, and generations.
Goods can be potentially public as well as potentially global. That is, many goods
can be made public or global (or both) through human actions or public policies
(or both). This definition refers to goods that are already public and global—a
stringent requirement that might not be satisfied by any good. Hence, as suggested
in the 1999 precursor to this volume, a less strict but more useful definition could
be that a good qualifies as being globally public when it benefits more than one
group of countries and does not discriminate against any population group or
generation.
Global public goods are nothing new. Many, notably the global natural com-
mons, predate human activity. They include the atmosphere, the geostationary
orbit, the electromagnetic spectrum, and the high seas. And as long as humans
have been around, there have been externalities—many traveling the world, often
in a diffuse and not clearly traceable way, as with emissions of carbon dioxide and
other greenhouse gases.
But externalities alone did not create the links and interdependencies among
different parts of the world’s growing population. International cooperation has
also played an important role. The Earth’s landmasses have been claimed by and
assigned to various nations (turned into national and, from a global viewpoint,
private property). Following futile attempts to do the same for the high seas, it was
decided to declare them a common heritage of humankind accessible to all
(Mendez 1992).
The 15th and 16th centuries ushered in a new epoch in international rela-
tions, marked by the appearance of sovereign states in Europe and the expansion
of their colonial powers and trade links (Braudel 1986). But in recent centuries
96 CONCEPTS
and especially recent decades the volume of externalities and intentionally cre-
ated goods of global reach has surged, often growing exponentially:
• New technologies increasingly enhance human mobility as well as the
movement of goods, services, and information around the world.
• Economic and political openness have provided further impetus to cross-
23
border and transnational activity.
• Systemic risks have increased. The accumulating environmental degradation
caused by human activities poses many risks, including global climate
change. Integrated financial markets pose the risk of boom and bust cycles.
Growing socioeconomic inequities call into question the legitimacy of the
global system.
• International regimes are becoming more influential, often formulated by
small groups of powerful nations yet often claiming universal applicability.
Nations and groups have seen their public domains become interlocked and
their living conditions become interdependent (Cerny 1995; Stiglitz 1995;
Woods 2000). For example, an economic downturn in a major economy usually
affects many others through trade and investment links. Financial crises can
spread from one continent to another in a matter of hours, often not sparing
economies with good fundamentals. Lax food safety standards in one area can
create health problems in many distant places through international travel or
trade. And new global public platforms, such as the Internet, blunt many con-
ventional public policy tools, including those for controlling such public bads as
tax evasion, money laundering, drug trafficking, commercial fraud, and child
abuse. The public and policymakers all over the world increasingly find that pub-
lic goods they would prefer to have locally—or for bads, not have—cannot be
produced solely through domestic action. A growing number of national public
goods have gone global.
Like figure 3, figure 5 classifies global public goods primarily according to
their humanmade (social) properties. Bearing in mind the first section of this
chapter and figures 2 and 3, one can discern the differences between the original
and current properties of the goods in figure 5. As before, various goods have
moved within or across quadrants or are slated to do so. These changes in status
show that global public goods are public in two senses: public rather than private,
and global rather than national.
Given the conditions often summarized by the term globalization, many deci-
sions on whether and to what extent to make certain goods public or private—
decisions on which it is often difficult enough to reach consensus at the national
level—must now be made by nations together. Agreeing on policies can be diffi-
cult, as indicated by recent discussions of the World Trade Organization’s agree-
ment on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS).
The goods in quadrants 2 and 4 of figure 5 require harmonization of national
policies. Policy harmonization is often intended to encourage countries to inter-
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 97
nalize cross-border externalities: to help generate positive ones and to take back
negative ones. Several goods in quadrant 2B involve such efforts. Efforts to increase
the inclusiveness of such goods as international communication and transport sys-
tems are aimed at improving the worldwide availability of network externalities.
The same intention usually drives initiatives to increase adherence to norms and
standards, including for human rights, and foster respect for national sovereignty.
Most of the goods in quadrant 2B are oriented toward unleashing what various
national and transnational actors perceive as global benefits.
By contrast, many of the goods in quadrant 4 involve the internalization of
negative cross-border externalities. These spillovers can be diffuse, emanating
from almost all countries—as with carbon dioxide emissions, which combined
create the risk of global warming. Or they can originate in certain countries but
potentially affect all, as with the outbreak of a new contagious disease. The policy
response to diffuse externalities could be to establish an international regime that
all countries would be expected to comply with. The promotion of basic human
rights, shown in quadrant 2B, is an example. But depending on the public good
under consideration, alternative policy options might be preferable, as shown in
quadrants 4A and 4B.
Quadrant 4A lists goods with policy responses that involve defining and
assigning new (national) property rights, such as national pollution allowances or
the exclusive economic zones created by the 1982 UN Convention on the Law of
24
the Sea. Quadrant 4B includes goods involving measures similar to those in the
national context and are aimed at making certain crucial goods—such as basic
education and health care—universally available. Moral and ethical concerns
often motivate the international community to undertake such measures. But
sometimes externalities also matter. For example, there might be concern that the
potential global repercussions of failing states, including conflicts and wars, could
impose much higher costs in the future than addressing today the root causes of
25
political tension, such as extreme poverty and inequity.
A further message of figure 5 relates to the pure public goods listed in quad-
rant 3. Many of the goods in this quadrant are the same as those in figures 2 and
3. As national borders become porous and cross-border economic activity
increases, these goods become indivisible across borders, or transnational. All
nations face the same international economic conditions. All face the same con-
ditions in international financial markets. All face the same risk of global climate
change. Because of this indivisibility, environmental sustainability is included in
figure 5 as an umbrella concern whereby countries are encouraged to internalize
the environmental externalities they generate. Environmental sustainability
requires more than occasional, unfocused corrections. Fundamental changes are
needed in global production and consumption patterns to avoid irreversible envi-
ronmental damage and the possible foreclosure of future generations’ develop-
ment options.
98 CONCEPTS
FIGURE 5
The de facto mix of national goods and global public goods
RIVAL NONRIVAL
QUADRANT 1 QUADRANT 2
PRIVATE GOODS 2A NONRIVAL GOODS MADE EXCLUSIVE
• National biodiversity and wildlife • Commercial knowledge
• Languages and cultural traditions
• National public education programs
2B NONRIVAL GOODS KEPT OR
• National water resources
MADE NONEXCLUSIVE
• National poverty eradication
• International communication and
programs
transport networks
• Norms and standards
GLOBAL PUBLIC DOMAIN
• Respect for human rights
NATIONAL DOMAIN
NONEXCLUSIVE
and institutions
EXCLUSIVE
QUADRANT 4 QUADRANT 3
4A RIVAL GOODS MADE
PURE PUBLIC GOODS
(PARTIALLY) EXCLUSIVE
• Moonlight
• Geographic territory: exlusive economic
• Peace and security/conflict
zones such as those established by the
• Financial stability/excessive
UN Convention on the Law of the Sea
financial volatility
• Ozone layer: targets for reducing
• Economic stabilization/
emissions of ozone-depleting substances
global economic slowdown
• Atmosphere: targets or quotas for
• Efficient/inefficient (integrated)
reducing emissions of carbon dioxide
markets
• Environmental sustainability
4B RIVAL GOODS KEPT OR MADE • Communicable diseases
NONEXCLUSIVEa controlled or eradicated/spreading
• Atmosphere
• Global gene pool to promote food
securityb
• High seas
• Basic education and health care for allc
• Freedom from extreme povertyc
a. The goods in this quadrant are kept or made nonexclusive to current generations (as with education) and future generations
(as with the atmosphere).
b. Refers to the International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources for Food and Agriculture (see http://www.fao.org/ag/cgrfa/).
c. These goods are included in the Millennium Development Goals (to be achieved by 2015) adopted by the UN General
Assembly (see http://www.un.org/millenniumgoals/).
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 99
Politics. Nations have been described as communities with shared tastes. To some
extent this is correct. But consider the many political and other differences within
nations, such as those between rich and poor people. Tastes and preferences vary
even more between nations.
The world is globalizing. But are the various dimensions of today’s realities—
such as decisionmaking—globalizing in tandem and at the same pace? This ques-
tion is especially important for global public goods because they affect all people.
More precisely, the question is whether the global scope of these goods’ benefits
and costs has been accompanied by a corresponding publicness in national and
international policymaking. This question is urgent because publicness in con-
26
sumption is often a requirement, not an option.
As noted, some people—notably the world’s richer people—sometimes have
the option of exiting from the public domain and protecting themselves through
various private means. Where commercial airline travel is too unsafe, private jets
100 CONCEPTS
TABLE 1
Global natural commons Free (managed) access. In their original state these goods are
(such as the atmosphere typically rival and nonexcludable. Some global natural commons
or the high seas) (such as the ozone layer) have taken on the social form of a
managed access resource. But they are usually still available
for all to consume—though sometimes only in limited measure.
can be used. Or where global warming occurs, it may be possible to escape some
of its effects by retreating to air conditioned rooms. Poor people rarely have such
private exit options.
As Hirschman (1970) emphasizes, when people have no exit options—when
they cannot refuse consumption—they cannot help but belong to the commu-
nity of stakeholders. Often the only strategy available to them is to seek a
stronger voice and more direct participation in matters that affect their lives.
Such “no exit” situations are often the case for global public goods. It is not sur-
prising that civil society has become more active and determined, and in some
cases more forceful, in making its voice heard. Developing countries are also
becoming more concerned about gaining seats at the tables of international
negotiations.
A stronger voice is often sought for its own sake, in the interest of democracy
and pluralism. But it is often sought to enhance decisionmaking and increase the
economic, technical, and political feasibility of policy actions. When international
cooperation is required to curtail costly, inefficient global public bads, an effective
voice for all is also critical. This is particularly evident in cases where international
institutions are assigned to implement international standards to promote certain
public goods (such as international security and international financial stability),
often resulting in incursions on domestic policymaking and lawmaking. The legit-
imacy of such incursions hinges on more participatory decisionmaking (Woods
2000). Hence it is important to assess the main global public goods, notably those
involving high interdependence, against the ideal triangle of publicness.
Figure 6 shows how select global public goods are likely to differ from the ideal
triangle. In each case it would be important to define clear indicators and reliable
measurement methodologies, but doing so is beyond the scope of this chapter.
27
The triangles in figure 6 are intended to encourage research and debate. The
chapters in part 2 of this volume shed further light on the politics of global public
goods provision, including its participatory nature and the fairness of negotia-
tions. The case studies in part 4 provide additional information on decision-
making and the distribution of benefits for specific global public goods.
Production. Few global public goods are “readymade.” Even the few that are, such
as the natural global commons, often require international management regimes
for their sustainable use. Most global public goods follow a complex, multidi-
mensional, multilayered, multiactor production path. Accordingly, many are also
likely to comprise a variety of building blocks. These building blocks can include
national public goods, which may require harmonization or upgrading for all to
enjoy a higher level of provision.
But especially where externalities of activities undertaken by households and
firms are involved, private goods and changed patterns of private behavior may
also be among the key building blocks. These often call for complementary
102 CONCEPTS
FIGURE 6
Examining global public goods through the triangle of publicness
PC PC = Publicness in consumption PC
PD = Publicness in decisionmaking
PB = Publicness in distribution
of (net) benefits
PD PB PD PB
Case A: The ideal triangle of publicness Case B: Decisionmaking is not completely
public, but consumption and the
distribution of benefits are.
Example: G-7 stabilization of major currencies.
PC PC
PD PB PD PB
Case C: The distribution of benefits is not Case D: The distribution of benefits and
completely public, but consumption and decisionmaking are not completely
formal decisionmaking are. public but consumption is.
Example: The multilateral trade regime. The World Example: International financial architecture.
Trade Organization (WT0) follows a one-country, one-
vote procedure and so appears to satisfy publicness in
decisionmaking. Yet many developing countries have
limited influence in the trade negotiations process.
PC PC
PD PB PD PB
Case E: Public goods—including global Case F: The shaded area represents a
public goods—often have limited regional public good with growing
benefits for women. Furthermore, there externalities—making this good more
are very few women in leadership public in consumption, globally. It would
positions, leading to limited publicness be interesting to examine if it also
in decisionmaking. becomes more public in benefits and
decisionmaking. Example: Water management.
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 103
national public policy actions, such as the provision of incentives. In addition, the
production paths of global public goods are often likely to include international
arrangements such as the World Trade Organization or the Global Fund to Fight
AIDS, Tuberculosis, and Malaria (see http://www.globalfundatm.org/). The chap-
ter on institutions by Kaul and Le Goulven (in this volume) discusses in more
detail the production paths and building blocks of global public goods. Examples
of elements that might enter the production cycles of global public goods are pro-
vided in table 2.
In many ways the process of assembling the various building blocks of
global public goods is similar to that of producing national public goods.
National public goods, however, can no longer be provided without due atten-
tion to their emerging international dimension. For example, international
financial stability requires that every country be concerned with its own fun-
damentals as well as any threat of contagion from other countries. The same is
true for goods such as communicable disease control and climate stability: with-
out international cooperation, no amount of domestic spending could fully
ensure the national public good. Hence, viewed from the production side, many
global public goods can be seen as the sum of national public goods plus inter-
national cooperation.
Notwithstanding the importance of international cooperation, the issue of
subsidiarity also needs to be raised: why would centralization—and thus inter-
national cooperation—be desirable? It is prudent to insist that the burden of
proof be on those who advocate increased national policy harmonization or joint
production at the international level. The reason lies in the tremendous diversity
of conditions around the world. Increased provision of a global public good often
requires all countries, even all people, to accept a change in global trends. But
moving in the same direction is often best achieved through policy pluralism
rather than standard approaches (as some of the case studies in this volume high-
light). Allowing for policy pluralism increases the transaction costs involved in
producing global public goods because it may entail more management support,
monitoring, and reporting. Yet these costs could be modest relative to the dead-
weight losses of excess centralization and standardization. Policy pluralism would
also be ideal when there is much debate on the best approach to providing cer-
tain goods, such as financial stability, for example.
Given the complexity of producing global public goods, there is no easy or
standard formula for ensuring their adequate provision. International studies
often note another handicap: the fact that there is no institution with coercive
powers. Perhaps this is just as well. More important are efficient, effective mea-
sures to ensure proper feedback loops: from international agreements to imple-
mentation, from implementation to policymaking and if necessary renegotiation
of agreements, and so on. The actors most likely to ensure that this process moves
beyond narrow national self-interests might not always be governments, since
104 CONCEPTS
TABLE 2
National public goods National civil aviation regimes and facilities, which serve
national purposes but, if in line with international agreements,
also constitute important building blocks of a global public good:
the international civil aviation network.
Private goods and activities Bed nets purchased by households as a contribution to the global
and their externalities public good of malaria control or use of solar energy panels by
businesses as a contribution to climate stability.
they are territorially bound. They might be transnational businesses, civil society
organizations, and members of the public. As Sen (1999) points out, these actors
often pursue interests and concerns independently of their nationalities.
C ONCLUSION
This chapter has suggested a rethinking of three notions underpinning the theory
of public goods. First, it has shown that properties of (non)rivalry in consump-
tion and (non)excludability of benefits do not automatically determine whether
a good is public or private. “Public” and “private” are in many—perhaps most—
cases a matter of policy choice: a social construct. Some goods lend themselves
more easily to being either public or private. Nevertheless, it is important to dis-
tinguish between a good’s having the potential of being public (that is, its having
nonrival and nonexcludable properties) and its being de facto public (nonexclu-
sive and available for all to consume).
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 105
Second, public goods do not necessarily have to be provided by the state. All
actors can, and increasingly do, contribute to their provision. And third, a grow-
ing number of public goods are no longer just national in scope, having assumed
cross-border dimensions. Many have become global and require international
cooperation to be adequately provided.
Rethinking the concept of public goods along these lines has a number of
implications for the theory of public goods and opens up an important new
research agenda. This includes the question of how in various cases publicness in
consumption is matched with publicness in decisionmaking and with equity in
the distribution of a good’s benefits—the issues raised by the triangle of public-
ness. Furthermore, recognizing the provision of public goods as a multiactor
activity calls for reconsideration of the current concept of optimal provision as
well as for renewed analysis of the production process of public goods.
These issues are even more urgent at the international level, particularly when
one considers international cooperation in support of global public goods. The
reasons are that at the international level there is no real equivalent to the institu-
tion of the state and that the global public has far more diverse interests and pref-
erences than any national public. Furthermore, many people—indeed, entire
countries—often find themselves in “no exit” situations. Under these conditions
a decisionmaking and production process for global public goods that is more
participatory and “bottom up” is perhaps most ideal.
In summary, Desai (in this volume) is correct when stating that the debate on
global public goods cannot simply build on the existing theory of public goods.
The theory must be updated to reflect current realities. This chapter has tried to
do just that, and opens the door to debate and discussion on a host of new issues.
The chapters that follow address many of these issues, offering the opening salvo
in this debate.
N OTES
For discussions on the evolution of the concept of public goods, see Desai (in this vol-
ume) and Buchanan and Musgrave (1999).
6. Pilot projects and schemes for greenhouse gas emissions trading are already
under way; see Cozijnsen (2001), Sandor (2002), and Castro and Cordero (in this vol-
ume).
7. Quotas and other quantitative limits are often only one part of a comprehen-
sive system of sustainable ecosystem management. See, for instance, the discussion in
the Reykjavik Conference on Responsible Fisheries in the Marine Ecosystem at
http://www.refisheries2001.org.
8. The Bolar provision under the World Trade Organization agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) allows manufacturers
of generic drugs to develop production and regulatory procedures before patents
expire to shorten the long period of preparing generics for the market. Research on
patented drugs is part of this provision (WTO 2001).
9. Respect for human rights and the norm of equity are viewed by some as pure
public goods. The reason is that they are relational goods—no one can have them
alone. For example, for a person to be treated equally, he or she needs to receive this
treatment from others. Such goods exist only if a person can relate to others—so in
that sense the goods are nonrival and nonexcludable. Furthermore, the more wide-
spread is the acceptance of certain norms, the more established and firm they are for
all individuals. Each additional user provides additional benefits to existing users
(Rao 1999). So, all who accept a norm such as equity also benefit from it being shared
as widely as possible—from being nonexclusive. But while it is nonrival and nonex-
cludable in the abstract, its application to the functioning of society often has distri-
butional consequences and so encounters political opposition. As a result respect for
human rights is sometimes an exclusive good—withheld from all or some population
groups.
10. In figure 3 technically nonexcludable goods often fall into quadrant 3. Goods
that are public by policy design—that are kept or made nonexclusive—fall into quad-
rants 2B and 4B. Goods (or bads) that are inadvertently public are those that have yet
to be discovered. An example is HIV/AIDS in its nascent stages several decades ago.
11. For further information, see the British Antarctic Survey homepage at
http://www.antarctica.ac.uk/.
12. Stiglitz (2000, p. 149) refers to “efficient government” as a public good.
13. For perspectives on the state and civil society in different cultures, see
Rosenblum and Post (2002). For diverse ethical perspectives on the concept of
boundaries, including political and jurisdictional ones, see Miller and Hashmi (2001).
14. Sandler (in this volume) explains how the risk of free riding and other types
of collective action problems vary with the nature of the good. Barrett (in this vol-
ume) takes this discussion forward by showing how cooperation strategies can be
designed to minimize noncompliance with international agreements.
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 107
R EFERENCES
Acocella, Nicola. 1998. The Foundations of Economic Policy: Values and Techniques.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Anheier, Helmut, Marlies Glasius, and Mary Kaldor, eds. 2001. Global Civil Society
2001. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Arce M., Daniel G., and Todd Sandler. 2001. “Transnational Public Goods: Strategies
and Institutions.” European Journal of Political Economy 17 (3): 493–516.
———. 2002. Regional Public Goods: Typologies, Provision, Financing, and
Development Assistance. Stockholm: Sweden Ministry for Foreign Affairs, Expert
Group on Development Issues.
Barzel, Yoram. 1997. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. 2nd ed. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Braudel, Fernand. 1986. The Perspective of the World: Civilization and Capitalism,
15th–18th Century. Vol. 3. New York: Harper & Row.
Breton, Albert. 1965. “A Theory of Government Grants.” Canadian Journal of
Economics and Political Science 31 (2): 175–87.
Bromley, Daniel W., ed. 1990. Essays on the Commons. Madison: University of
Wisconsin Press.
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 109
Buchanan, James M., and Richard A. Musgrave. 1999. Public Finance and Public
Choice: Two Contrasting Visions of the State. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Cerny, Philip G. 1995. “Globalization and the Changing Logic of Collective Action.”
International Organization 49 (4): 595–625.
Cornes, Richard, and Todd Sandler. 1994. “Are Public Goods Myths?” Journal of
Theoretical Politics 6 (3): 369–85.
———. 1996. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Cozijnsen, Jos. 2001. “The Development of Post Kyoto Emissions Trading Schemes
in Europe: An Analysis in the Context of the Kyoto Process.” In Malik Amin
Aslam, Jos Cozijnsen, Svetlana Morozova, Marc Stuart, Richard B. Stewart, and
Philippe Sands, eds., Greenhouse Gas Market Perspectives: Trade and Investment
Implications of the Climate Change Regime. Geneva: United Nations Conference
on Trade and Development. [http://www.unctad.org/ghg/Publications/GHG_
MktPersp.PDF].
Cropper, Maureen L., and Wallace E. Oates. 1992. “Environmental Economics: A
Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 30: 675–740.
Cullis, John, and Philip Jones. 1998. Public Finance and Public Choice. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Cutler, A. Claire, Virginia Haufler, and Tony Porter, eds. 1999. Private Authority and
International Affairs. Albany: State University of New York Press.
Demsetz, Harold. 1967. “Toward a Theory of Property Rights.” American Economic
Review 57 (2): 347–59.
Dixit, Avinash K. 1996. The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics
Perspective. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Giddens, Anthony, and Will Hutton. 2000. “In Conversation.” In Will Hutton and
Anthony Giddens, eds., Global Capitalism. New York: New Press.
Held, David, Anthony McGrew, David Goldblatt, and Jonathan Perraton. 1999.
Global Transformations. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms,
Organizations, and States. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1983. “From Weakest-link to Best-shot: The Voluntary Provision of
Public Goods.” Public Choice 41: 371–86.
Kaul, Inge. 2001. “Public Goods in the 21st Century.” In Global Public Goods: Taking
the Concept Forward. Discussion Paper 17. New York: United Nations
Development Programme, Office of Development Studies.
Kaul, Inge, Isabelle Grunberg, and Marc A. Stern. 1999. “Defining Global Public
Goods.” In Inge Kaul, Isabelle Grunberg, and Marc A. Stern, eds., Global Public
Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century. New York: Oxford
University Press.
110 CONCEPTS
Keane, John. 2001. “Global Civil Society?” In Helmut Anheier, Marlies Glasius, and
Mary Kaldor, eds., Global Civil Society 2001. New York: Oxford University Press.
Luttwak, Edward. 1999. Turbo-Capitalism: Winners and Losers in the Global Economy.
New York: HarperCollins.
Malkin, Jesse, and Aaron Wildavsky. 1991. “Why the Traditional Distinction between
Public and Private Goods Should Be Abandoned.” Journal of Theoretical Politics
3 (4): 355–78.
Marmolo, Elisabetta. 1999. “A Constitutional Theory of Public Goods.” Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization 38 (1): 27–42.
Meehan, Johanna, ed. 1995. Feminists Read Habermas: Gendering the Subject of
Discourse. New York and London: Routledge.
Mendez, Ruben. 1992. International Public Finance: A New Perspective on Global
Relations. New York: Oxford University Press.
Micklethwait, John, and Adrian Wooldridge. 2000. A Future Perfect: The Challenge
and Hidden Promise of Globalization. New York: Times Books.
Miller, David, and Sohail H. Hashmi, eds. 2001. Boundaries and Justice: Diverse Ethical
Perspectives. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Musgrave, Richard A., and Peggy B. Musgrave. 1989. Public Finance in Theory and
Practice. 5th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Nicholson, Walter. 1998. Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions. 7th
ed. New York: Harcourt.
Oakland, William H. 1991. “Theory of Public Goods.” In Alan Auerbach and Martin
Feldstein, eds., Handbook of Public Economics. Vol. 2. Amsterdam: North-
Holland.
Olson, Mancur. 1971 [1965]. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the
Theory of Groups. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for
Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Papandreou, Andreas A. 1998. Externality and Institutions. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Rao, J. Mohan. 1999. “Equity in a Global Public Goods Framework.” In Inge Kaul,
Isabelle Grunberg, and Marc A. Stern, eds., Global Public Goods: International
Cooperation in the 21st Century. New York: Oxford University Press.
Risse-Kappen, Thomas, ed. 1995. Bringing Transnational Relations Back In: Non-state
Actors, Domestic Structures and International Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Rosen, Harvey. 1999. Public Finance. 5th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Rosenblum, Nancy L., and Robert C. Post. 2002. Civil Society and Government.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Salanie, Bernard. 2000. The Microeconomics of Market Failures. Cambridge, Mass.:
MIT Press.
ADVANCING THE CONCEPT OF PUBLIC GOODS 111