Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition
Perfect Competition
PERFECT COMPETITION
a) The market is characterized by a large number of buyers and sellers, so that each
individual seller, however large, supplies only a small part of the total quantity
offered at the market.
b) The next assumption is that firms produce homogeneous products. If the products
were not homogeneous, the firm would have some discretion in setting price. The
assumptions of large numbers of sellers and of homogeneous products imply that the
individual firm in perfect competition is a price taker. The typical demand curve of
the firm is infinitely elastic, indicating that the firm can sell any amount of output at
the prevailing market price (P) as shown in figure 1.1.
Price
P D
1 Q (output)
FIGURE 1.1: DEMAND CURVE OF A COMPETITIVE FIRM
(a) There is a free entry and exit of the firms in the market. This assumption is
supplementary to the assumption of large numbers of buyers and sellers. If
barriers exist the number of firms in the industry may be reduced so that each one
of them may acquire power to affect the price in the market.
(b) There is free mobility of factors of production from one firm to another
throughout the economy.
(c) There is a perfect knowledge in the sense that the market participants have a
complete knowledge of the conditions prevailing on the markets. Buyers of the
product are well informed about the characteristics of the product being sold and
the prices charged by each firm.
Are these conditions realistic in the real world? If not why are we studying this
model?
It is obvious that there is no any industry in the real world that is perfectly competitive!
Nevertheless, this does not mean that studying perfect competitive model is useless.
An economic model may be quite useful no matter how pragmatic some or all of its
assumptions are. The real world cannot possibly be complemented in one single step.
Perfect competition assumes most of the dynamic forces as being constant and thus
allows the problem of product pricing to be easily understood.
Perfect competition has become a standard yardstick against which other types of market
structures can be compared, evaluated and understood better
How do we derive the supply curve of a firm under perfect competitive model?
The supply curve of the firm may be derived by joining the points of intersections of
Marginal Cost (MC) curve with successive demand curves.
Remember that a firm’s demand curve in a perfectly competitive market is horizontal
(see figure 1.1). In other words, it is the same as the prevailing market price.
Now, if we assume that the market price increases from P 1 to P2 as shown in figure 1.2(a),
then such an upward shift of the demand curve of the firm will give the positive slope of
the MC curve.
This implies that the quantity supplied by the firm increases as the price of a given
product rises. Thus, the firm will close down if price falls below P w, because at a lower
price the firm does not cover its variable cost as shown in figure 1.2(a).
Price, Cost
SMC Supply Curve
P2 P2
SATC
P1 P1
Pw SAVC Pw
w
O Xw X1 X2 Quantity of X O Xw X1 X2 Quantity of X
Figure 1.2 (a) Figure 1.2(b)
FIGURE 1.2: SUPPLY CURVE OF THE FIRM AND THE INDUSTRY
Note that if you plot the successive points of intersection of MC and the demand curves on a
separate figure such as 1.2 (b), you will find that the supply curve of the individual firm is
identical to its MC curve to the right of the shut down point w. Note that below Pw, the quantity
supplied by the firm is zero. As soon as the price level rises above the P w the quantity supplied
increases.
The industry supply curve is the horizontal summation of the supply curves of the individual
firms such as the one shown in figure 1.2(b). If we assume that prices of factors of production
and the level of technology are given and the number of firms is very large, then, the total
quantity supplied in the market at each price is the sum of the quantity supplied by all firms at
that price.
The equilibrium of the firm may be explained in two approaches. The first approach involves
using the total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC) curves. The second approach involves utilizing
the marginal revenue (MR) and marginal cost (MC) curves. We are going to study both
approaches in the following subsections.
In figure 1.3 we show the total revenue and total cost curves of a firm in a perfectly competitive
market.
The total revenue curve is a straight line through the origin showing that the price is constant at
all levels of output.
Since, the firm is a price taker and can sell any amount of output at the going market
price, with its TR increasing proportionately with sales.
The slope of the TR curve is the marginal revenue, which is constant and equal to the
prevailing market price, since all units are sold at the same price.
Thus in perfect competition the condition MR=AR=P holds.1
The shape of the total cost curve in figure 1.3 reflects the U shape of the average cost curve,
which originates from the law of diminishing returns.
The firm maximizes its profit at the output Qe, where the distance between the TR and TC
curves is very large compared to other points.
Note that at lower and higher levels of output total profit is not maximized. For instance,
at output levels smaller than Qa and larger than Qb the firm incurs losses because the total
cost is greater than the total revenue as shown by the shaded areas.
Cost/Revenue
TC
TR
O Qa Qe QbQuantity/Unit of time
1
Note that the average revenue is equal to price; AR=TR/Q=PQ/Q=P
FIGURE 1.3: PROFIT MAXIMIZATION - TOTAL APPROACH
The total revenue approach is a bit problematic to use especially when firms are combined
together in the study of the industry. The alternative approach, which is based on the marginal
cost and marginal revenue, uses price as an explicit variable, and shows clearly the behavioral
conditions that lead to profit maximization.
ii) The second condition for equilibrium requires that the MC be rising at the point of its
intersection with the MR curve. This means that the MC must cut the MR curve from
below. Put it differently, the slope of the MC must be steeper than the slope of MR.
Price, Cost
SMC
E* E
P =MR
The MR and MC curves in the figure 1.5 intersect at the point “E” where MC cuts MR from
below. The profit maximizing output is therefore Qe.
Price, Cost
SMC
SATC
P* E P =MR
A B
0 Qe Quantity/unit of time
FIGURE 1.5: PROFIT MAXIMIZATION - MARGINAL APPROACH
The equilibrium price 0P* is equal to Short run Marginal Cost (SMC) at the equilibrium level of
output Qe. The short run average total cost (SATC) at output 0Q e is Qe B. On the other hand, the
total cost which is given by the average cost multiplied by quantity is thus represented by the
rectangle 0ABQe.
At the equilibrium level of output, total revenue is represented by the area of the rectangle 0P*E
Qe. Thus the firm is earning revenue in excess of total costs; which represents the supernormal
profit equal to the area AP*EB. This is to be contrasted from normal profit which is the rate of
return necessary to keep the factors of productions in their present use.
(i) Normal profit is defined as the level of profit necessary to keep factors
of production in their present use.
(ii) Super normal profit is defined the level of profit in excess of normal
profit.
F C
P* E P=MR=AR=D
Pw w
O Xe Quantity of X
FIGURE 1.6: BREAK EVEN AND SHUT-DOWN POINT
The point at which the firm covers its variable costs is called the “shutdown point.” In figure 1.6
the shut down point is denoted by the point w. if price falls below Pw, the firm does not cover its
variable costs and is better off if it shuts down.
(i) If, at the best level of output, P (i.e price) exceeds SATC the firm is
maximizing total profits; if P is smaller than SATC but larger than
AVC, the firm is minimizing total losses; if P is smaller than
AVC, the firm minimizes its total losses by shutting down.
(i) If the total cost of the firm, i.e. the fixed cost and variable costs are
just being covered, then the firm is said to be breaking even and this is
known as break even point
(iii) If the firm is making losses but the losses only extend to the level of
the fixed costs, then the firm is said to be at its shut down point.
The industry is in equilibrium when the quantity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied as
shown in figure 1.7, where P* is equilibrium price and Q* is equilibrium quantity.
Price D S Price
SMC
SATC
P* P* E
S D
O Q* Qty/time O Q* Qty/time
Figure 1.7(a) Industry Figure 1.7(b) Firm
FIGURE 1.7: SHORT RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF THE INDUSTRY
Price
D S
S1 SMC1
SAC1
LMC
P0 P0
SMC2 SAC2
LAC
P* P*
0 Q1 Q2 Quantity 0 Q1 Q2 Quantity
Figure 1.8(a) Figure 1.8(b)
FIGURE 1.8: LONG RUN EQUILIBRIUM OF THE FIRM
Figure 1.8 (b) shows how firms adjust to their long run equilibrium position. If the price is P 0, the
firm is making excess profit working with the plant whose cost is denoted by SAC 1. It will
therefore have an incentive to build new capacity and it will move along its LAC. At the same
time new firms will be entering in the industry attracted by the excess profits. As the quantity
supplied in the market increases, the supply curve in the market will shift to the right and price
will fall until it reaches the level of P* (in figure 1.8a) at which the firms and the industry are in
long run equilibrium.
The condition for the long run equilibrium of the firm is that the marginal cost be equal to the
price and to the long run average cost: LMC = LAC = P*. Also note that at th long run
equilibrium, the short run marginal cost is equal to the long run marginal cost and the short run
average cost is equal to the long run average cost. Thus, given the above equilibrium condition,
we have: SMC = LMC = LAC= LMC=P=MR
Solution
(a) Note that in a perfectly competitive market, price is equal to: average revenue;
marginal revenue; and demand. Thus, the equilibrium price is the firm’s demand
curve since all firms take price as given.
QD = QS
70,000-5,000P = 40,000+2,500P
30,000 = 7,500P
4 = P
In summary, the equation of demand curve for the perfectly firm in this industry
is given by P=T.Shs4.00/=. That is, the firm can sell any quantity at that price.
(b) In order to find the number of firms in this industry, we must find the market
equilibrium quantity. This is obtained by substituting the equilibrium price of
T.Shs 4.00/= into either the market demand function or the market supply
function:
QD = QS
70,000-5,000(4) = 40,000+2,500(4)
70,000-20,000 = 40,000+10,000
50,000 = 50,000
Since all firms are identical and each firm produces 500 units of output, when the
industry is in the long run equilibrium, there will be 100 such firms in the industry
(i.e.50, 000500=100)
1.7 Equilibrium of the Industry in the Long Run
The industry is in the long run equilibrium when firms are producing at the minimum point of
the LAC as shown in figure 1.9. At the price P the industry is in equilibrium because profits are
normal and all costs are covered so that there is no incentive for entry or exit. That is, the firm
just earns the normal profit (neither excess profit nor losses) shown by the equality,
LAC=SAC=P which is observed at the minimum point of the LAC curve (figure 1.9b). With all
the firms in the industry being in equilibrium and with no entry or exit, the industry supply
remains stable, and given the market demand (DD) in figure 1.9(a), the price P is a long run
equilibrium price.
P P
D
S
O Q O Q
Figure 1.9(a) Figure 1.9(b)
FIGURE 1.9: EQUILIBRIUM OF THE INDUSTRY IN THE LONG RUN
And the same long run marginal cost curve given by:
(a) Assuming the market is in the long run equilibrium, how much kilograms will
each firm sell per day?
(b) What are the long run average cost and marginal cost at the level of output in part
(a)?
The market demand for maize is given by Q D=2,500,000-500,000P, where QD is the quantity
demand of rice per day and P is the price of maize.
(c) Given your answer to part (a) what will be the price of maize in the long run
equilibrium?
(d) How many kilograms of maize will be demanded
(e) How many firms (sellers) will be in the industry?
Solution
(a) Each firm supplies in the long run when the LAC is equal to the market price or
(marginal cost). Thus, we equate LAC to LMC as follows;
100
0.01q-1+ q =0.02q-1
100
q -0.01q=0
100
q =0.01q
100=0.01q2
10,000=q2
100=q
(b) Then the long run average and marginal cost are given by substituting q=100 into
the LAC and LMC functions as follow
100
0 . 01q−1+
LAC = q
= 0.01(100)-1+100/100
= 1-1+1
= 1
LMC = 0.02(100)-1
= 1
(c) Note that the long run supply function is equal to the LMC, which is also equal to
price level, i.e. P=MC;P=1
(d) Substitute the price level (i.e.P=1) into the demand function
(d) If we divide 2,000,000 by 100 kilograms supplied by each firm we should be able
to get 20,000 kilograms.
Numerical example
Each firm in a competitive market has an identical cost function C(q)=16+q2 , with marginal cost
MC=24. The market demand function is q=24-p.
(a) Find the individual’s firm supply function and the market supply function (assuming that
there are “n” many firms).
(b) What is the condition for this market to be in the long run equilibrium?
(c) Assuming that the market is in the long run equilibrium, how many firms are in this
market? (Hint: first find the equilibrium price and quantity as functions of “n”. Then, solve
for “n”).
Solution
Qs = Qd
np
⇒ =24− p
2
48
⇒ p=
n+ 2
p 24
⇒q= =
2 n+2
The zero profit condition says that total revenue=total cost, so:
2
48 24 24
×
n+2 n+2
=16+
n+2 ( )
1152 576
⇒ =16+
n+2 n+2
1152 576
⇒ − =16
n+2 n+2
576
⇒ =16
n+2
⇒n=4
48
p∗ =8
(d) Equilibrium price is 4 +2 and equilibrium quantity is
Q*=24-p*=16
Q∗¿ 16
q∗¿ = =4 ¿
(e) Individual firm’s supply is 4 4
SUMMARY