Chapter 13 Direct Price Discrimination Price Discrimination Is The Practice of Charging Different Prices To Different Buyers or Groups of

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 4

Chapter 13 Direct Price Discrimination

Price discrimination is the practice of charging different prices to different buyers or groups of

buyers based on differences in demand. Charging lower prices to low-value consumers also

means that you charge high-value customers higher prices, making the practice controversial. If

the higher prices arise from the higher costs of serving small mom-and-pop shops, then the

higher prices are not discriminatory.

In a direct price discrimination scheme, we can identify members of the low-value group, charge

them a lower price, and prevent them from reselling their lower-priced goods to the higher-value

group (arbitrage). In an indirect discrimination scheme, we cannot perfectly identify the two

groups or cannot prevent arbitrage, so we must find indirect methods of setting different prices to

the two different groups.

The Robinson-Patman Act is part of a group of laws collectively called the antitrust laws

governing competition in the U.S. Under the Robinson-Patman Act, it’s illegal to give or receive

a price discount on a good sold to another business. This law does not cover services or sales to

final consumers. Antitrust economists have long recognized that the Robinson-Patman Act

discourages discounting. If companies have to offer the same price to every customer, they are

less likely to reduce price to their most price-elastic customers. Consumers don’t like knowing

that they’re paying a higher price than other consumers. This is summed up in popular sayings

like “Only schmucks3 pay retail [prices].”

So, if you’re price discriminating, it’s important to keep the scheme secret if you can. Otherwise,

you may lose your high-value customers to rivals who don’t price discriminate (or who hide it

better).
Chapter 14 Indirect Price Discrimination

When a seller cannot directly identify who has a low or high value, the seller can still

discriminate by designing products or services that appeal to different consumer groups. This

indirect price discrimination scheme differs from the direct schemes of the previous chapter

because high-value customers could clip coupons if they wanted. Fear of such “cannibalization”

is characteristic of most indirect price discrimination schemes. Price discrimination is not always

profitable. Sometimes, it is better to offer only a single product as the risk of cannibalization is

too great. Indirect price discrimination is not only a pricing issue, but also a product design issue.

So far, we’ve been discussing ways of price discriminating between different customers— that

is, setting different prices to different people or groups of people. Here, we consider the case of a

single customer who demands more than one unit of a good. This is an individual demand curve.

Note the difference between an individual and an aggregate demand curve. With an aggregate

demand curve, each point represents a different consumer with a different value for a single unit

of the good. For an individual demand curve, each point represents the value that a single

consumer is willing to pay for an additional unit.

We can also use bundling in a slightly different context—when consumers have different

demands for different items. Bundled pricing5 allows a seller to extract more consumer surplus if

willingness to pay for the bundle is more homogeneous than willingness to pay for the separate

items in the bundle. For example, the bundling of channels allows cable TV providers to extract

65% more consumer surplus than if the channels were priced separately.6
Chapter 16 Bargaining

Bargaining, it is the alternatives to agreement that determine the terms of agreement, regardless

of the precise form of the negotiations. If you can increase your opponent’s gain to reaching

agreement (or decrease your own), you make your opponent more eager to reach agreement, and

this allows you to capture a bigger share. Player has just two possible strategies: bargain hard or

accommodate. If both bargain hard, they’ll reach no deal, and each earns nothing; if both

accommodate, they split the gains from trade. If one player bargains hard and the other

accommodates, the player who bargains hard takes higher gain.

To summarize: the strategic view of bargaining suggests that if you can commit to a position,

you can capture a bigger share of the gains from agreement. But committing to a position is

difficult because it requires you to act against your self-interest.

John Nash, the same mathematician responsible for Nash equilibrium, proved that any

reasonable bargaining outcome would split the gains from trade. We call this an “axiomatic” or

“nonstrategic” view of bargaining because it does not depend on the rules of the bargaining game

or whether players can commit to a position. This nonstrategic view of bargaining tells you that

if you can decrease your own gain to reaching agreement by improving your outside option, you

become a tougher bargainer—because you have less to gain by reaching agreement.

In the end, this raises the obvious question, which is better? The answer is that “it depends” on

the particular setting in which you find yourself. If you can credibly commit to a position by, for

example, making a take-it-or-leave-it offer, then go ahead. If, as is more likely, commitment is

costly or not credible, then try to change the alternatives to agreement, as they determine the

terms of agreement.
Chapter 18 Auctions

Auctions are often used in conjunction with bargaining. In this case, the auction identified a

potential negotiating partner, and the student used the outside alternative of rival bids to

negotiate a deal. A variety of auction formats are available, and we start with the most familiar.

In an oral or English auction, bidders submit increasing bids until only one bidder remains. The

item is awarded to this last remaining bidder. Stronger losing bidders lead to higher winning

bids.

A Vickrey or second-price auction is a sealed-bid auction in which the item is awarded to the

highest bidder, but the winner pays the second-highest bid. Vickrey auctions are also useful for

auctioning off multiple units of the same item. The highest bidder wins the item at a price equal

to the highest bid. In contrast to a second-price auction, in a sealed-bid first-price auction, you

have to pay the amount you bid. Consequently, each bidder faces a trade-off: He can bid higher

and raise the probability of winning, but doing so lowers his surplus (or profit) if he does win.

In equilibrium, each bidder shades his bid; that is, he balances these two effects by bidding

below his value. In these auctions, experience is the best teacher. In general, you should bid more

aggressively—shade your value less—if the competition is stronger.

Bidders can raise profit by agreeing not to bid against one another. If collusion is suspected, do

not hold open auctions; do not hold small and frequent auctions; do not announce the winners or

the winning bids.

To avoid the winner’s curse in common-value auctions, bid below your estimated value. Bid as if

your estimate is the most optimistic and everyone else thinks it is worth less. Oral auctions return

higher prices in common-value auctions because they release more information.

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy