Gold Is Money - Sennholz, H
Gold Is Money - Sennholz, H
Gold Is Money - Sennholz, H
CONTRIBUTIONS IN ECOMONICS
AND ECONOMIC HISTORY
Business and Politics in America from the Age of Jackson to the Civil War:
The Career Biography of W. W. Corcoran
Henry Cohen
The American Banking Community and New Deal Banking Reforms, 1933-
1935
Helen M. Burns
GOLD
1$
MONEY
Edited vvith all Introduction by
Jf[<Jns F. Sennholz
Contributions in Ecc)n()mics
and
Economic History, ~~u]mber 12
GREENWOOD PRES~)
Sennholz, Hans F
Gold is money.
3 No Shortage of Gold 41
Hans F. Sennholz
v
vi CONTE~TS
Epilogue 195
Index 199
Introduction
With the breakdown of the international monetary order in
August 1971, the world entered a new phase in international
finance and commerce. For sonle twenty-seven years, since
the Bretton Woods Agreement, the u.s. dollar had been the
most important currency to 'which the free world monetary
system was safely anchored. But the American suspension of
gold payments on August 15, 19~71, the dollar devaluations in
December 1971 and February 19 73, followed by sinking floats
1
vii
viii INTRODUCTION
Profes~Yor of Economics,
Southern .11linoisUniversity
3
4 G. C. WIEGAND
STABILITY
but misleading notion that America need not Hlet the tail," the
$50 billion worth of international trade, Hwag the dog," the
more than $1.1 trillion American economy. America's interna-
tional trade is not so much the HtaH of the dog" as the water
without which the dog can barely survive.
No politician is naive enough to suggest that the United
States follow Plato's blueprint--or the Russian and the
Chinese policies-and cut herself off from the rest of the
world, but neither politicians nor the great mass of the people
will admit that in order to be a part of the world, America must
adjust to the world. In The lvVali Street Journal (August 14,
1972), then Treasury Secretary (;eorge Shultz, for example,
called for Hthe development oJ~ international rules of conduct."
But these rules, he thought, ""luust leave room for that exercise
of national sovereignty which all nations must retain regarding
policies affecting the welfare of their citizens. " We recognize
Hthe growing economic interdependence aIJlong nations," but
if we find it politically expedient to pursue an inflationary
policy at home-for the welfare of the American people-we
should be free to do so.
For centuries, governments have searched in vain for a way
of combining the Hneeds for national sovereignty" with the
Hneeds for international cooperation." Now the experts and
politicians claim to have found the solution: floating exchange
rates, which will supposedly enable the governments to assure
ever rising prosperity within the country, without having to cut
America off from the rest of the world. The dollar is to be
permitted to Hfind its own level."
But what level? As long as consumption in the United States
does not exceed production, and the world has confidence in
the dollar, there is no need for a Cl:floating" rate. The world will
be happy to have a constant dollar as an international standard
of value. But if consumption in America exceeds production, as
it has since the 1950s, a ""floating" dollar will prove to be just a
euphemism for a progressively depreciating dollar. As long as
the deficit spending continues, wages increase faster than
16 G. C. WIEGAND
NOTES
which will probably buy the country some time, but ccthe time has
come to stop pussyfooting and get our accounts in order." (Speech
before the Economics Club in ))etroit, on March 18, 1969.)
19"fhe suspension of dollar convertibility, according to Treasury
Secretary George Shultz, ccfreed us to follow the domestic policies
that we feel are the important ones, vvithout having to worry so much
about international developments." (The Wall Street Journal, Au-
gust 14, 1972).
2
Gold vs. Fluctuating
Fiat Exchange Rates
MURRAY N. ROTHBARD
Professor of Economics,
Brooklyn Polytechnic Institute
24
Gold vs. Fluctuating Fiat E~rchlZnge Rates 25
on-then why not allow New York to issue its own "yorks,"
New Jersey its own "jersies," aqd then enjoy the benefits of a
freely fluctuating "market" between these various currencies?
But since we have one money, the dollar, within the United
States, enjoying what the Friedmanites would call "fixed
exchange rates" between each of the various states, we don't
have any monetary crisis within the country, and we don't have
to worry about the "balance of payments" between New York,
New Jersey, and the other states.
Furthermore, it should be clear that what the Friedmanites
take away with one hand, so to speak, they give back with the
other. For while they are staunchly opposed to tariff barriers
between geographical areas, their freely fluctuating fiat
currencies could and undoubtedly would operate as crypto-
tariff barriers between these areas. During the fiat money
Greenback period in the United States after the Civil War, the
Pennsylvania iron manufacturers, who had always been the
leading advocates of a protective tariff to exclude more
efficient and lower cost British iron, now realized that
depreciating greenbacks functioned as a protective device: for
a falling dollar makes imports more expensive and exports
cheaper. I In the same way, during the international fiat money
periods of the 1930s (and now from March 1973 on), the export
interests of each country scrambled for currency devaluations,
backed up by inefficient domestic firms trying to keep out
foreign competitors. And similarly, a Friedmanite world with-
in the United States would have the disastrous effect of func-
tioning as competing and accelerating tariff barriers between
the states.
And if independent currencies between each of the fifty
states is a good thing, why not go still one better? Why not
independent currencies to be issued by each county, city,
town, block, building, person? Friedmanite monetary theorist
Leland B. Yeager, who is willing to push thie reductio ad
absurdum almost all the way by advocating separate moneys
for each region or even locality, draws back finally at the idea of
Gold vs. Fluctuating Fiat Exchange Rates 33
back to the gold standard at a higher gold price, even he, as late
as October 1971 faltered and lconceded that perhaps a doubling
of the gold price to $70 migh.t be too drastic to be viable. And
yet now the market itself places gold at very nearly double that
seemingly high price. 6
Without gold, without an international money, the world is
destined to stumble into one acc:elerated monetary crisis after
another, and to veer back and forth between the ills and evils of
fluctuating exchange rates and oJf fixed exchange rates without
gold. Without gold as the basic Dloney and means of payment,
fixed exchange rates make leven less sense than fluctuating
rates. Yet a solution to the lDOSt glaring of the world's
aggravated monetary ills lies near at hand, and nearer than
ever now that the free-gold Ioarket points the way. That solu-
tion would be for the nations of the world to return to a classical
gold standard, with the prJice fixed at something like the
current free market level. 'With the dollar, say, at $125 an
ounce, there would be far more gold to back up the dollar and
all other national currencies. Exchange rates would again be
fixed by the gold content of each currency. While this would
sClrcely solve all the monetary problems of the world-there
would still be need for drastic reforms of banking and central
bank inflation, for example--a giant step would have been
taken toward monetary sanity. At least the world would have a
money again, and the spectre of a calamitous return to barter
would have ended. And that would be no small accom-
plishment.
NOTES
Professor of Economics,
Grove City College
41
42 HANS F. SENNHOLZ
the world. It does not permit exchange rate changes and resists
government controls over international trade and payments.
The gold standard does in fact make it difficult to isolate one
country from another. After all, the common currency that is
gold wou!d invite exchanges of goods and services and thus
thwart an isolationist policy. For this reason completely
regimented economies cannot tolerate the gold standard that
springs from economic freedom and inherently resists
regimentation. The gold standard also exposes all countries
that adhere'to it to imported inflations and depressions. But as
the chances of any gold inflation and depression that would
follow .such an inflation are extremely small, the danger of
contagion is equally small. It is smaller by far than with the
floating fiat standard that suffers frequent disruptions and
uncertainties, or with the dollar-exchange standard that actual-
ly has inundated the world with inflation and credit expansion.
It must also be admitted that the gold standard is incon-
sistent with government controls over international trade and
payment. But we should like to question the objection that the
newly mined gold is not closely related to the growing needs of
business and that a serious shortage of money would have
developed without the issue of paper money. This popular
objection to the gold standard is rooted in several ancient
errors that persist in spite of the refutations by economists.
There is no shortage of gold today just as there has been no
such shortage in the past. Indeed, it is inconceivable that the
needs of business will ever require more gold than is presently
available. Gold has been wealth and the medium of exchange
in all of the great civilizations. Throughout history men have
toiled for this enduring metal and have used it in economic
exchanges. It has been estimated that most of the gold won
from the earth during the last 10,000 years, perhaps from the
beginning of man, can still be accounted for in man's vaults
today, and in ornaments, jewelry, and other artifacts through-
out the world. No other possession of man has been so jealously
guarded as gold. And yet, we are to believe that today we are
No Shortage of Gold 43
law of costs does not conflict with the basic principle of value
and price. Their determination originates in the consumers'
subjective valuations of finished products.
The law of costs obviously is applicable to gold. When its
exchange value rises, mining becomes more profitable, which
will encourage the search for gold and invite mining of ore that
heretofore was unprofitable because of low gold content or
other high mining costs. When additional quantities of gold are
offered on the market, its exchange value or purchasing power
tends to decline in accordance with the law of supply and
demand. Conversely, when its exchange value falls, the op-
posite effects tend to ensue.
That paper money is subject fo the law of costs is vehemently
denied by all who favor such money. After all, they retort, the
profit motive does not apply to its production and man-
agement. Its exchange value may be kept far above its cost of
manufacture through wise restraint and management by
monetary authorities.
It must be admitted that the law of costs works slowly on
money, more slowly indeed than on other goods. It may take
several decades before the paper money exchange value falls to
the level of manufacturing costs. After all, the fall is rather
considerable, from the value of gold for which the paper
money first substitutes to that of the printing paper. Few other
commodities ever experience such a large discrepancy be-
tween market value and manufacturing costs when the law of
costs begins to work. This original discrepancy does not refute
the applicability of the law; it merely offers an explanation for
the length of time needed for the price-cost adjustment.
It must also be admitted that a certain measure of restraint
prevents an immediate fall of the paper money value to the
level of manufacturing costs. Popular opposition prevents the
monetary authorities from multiplying the quantity of paper
issue too rapidly, which would depreciate its value at in-
tolerable rates and lead to an early disintegration of the
exchange economy. In a democratic society these monetary
No Shortage of Gold 49
spend and inflate and thus set into operation the law of costs.
Who would believe that such policies are not motivated by the
personal gains that accrue to the politicians in power?
This profit motive must be sharply distinguished from that
in the competitive exchange economy. When encompassed by
competition, the motive is a powerful driving force for the best
possible service to the ultimate bosses, the consumers. It raises
output and income, and leads to capital formation and high
standards of living. In the case of the monopolistic man-
ufacture of paper money by government authorities, the profit
motive finds expression in currency expansion, which is infla-
tion. In the end, when the law of costs has completely
prevailed and the exchange value of money equals the cost of
paper manufacture, not only the fiat money is destroyed but
also the individual-enterprise private-property· order. Infla-
tion· not only bears bitter economic fruits but also has evil
social, political, and moral consequences.
ion, call for more money until a desirable "price level" has
been attained. The "monetary requirements of business," as
seen by some economists, are conditioned by the ""level" of
commodity prices. A falling level is assumed to indicate the
need for more money; a stable level indicates the desirable
state of stability; and a rising level reveals an excess of money
over the true requirements. The level itself is said to vary
directly with the quantity of money in circulation. That is, it
rises or falls in proportion to the increase or decrease of the
money supply.
The notion of a price "level" must be rejected for being
deficient and misleading. Changes in the quantity of money do
not affect the prices of all goods at the same time and to the
same degree. They cause price upheavals, not uniform
changes of all prices. Just as the prices of all commodities and
services are determined by their demand and supply, so is the
purchasing power of money. If the supply increases, the
holders of the new money-either the federal government or
other institutions and individuals-are in the position to buy
more goods than they did before. Now, the prices of those
goods that are demanded in additional quantities tend to rise
while those of other goods at first remain unaffected. The
sellers of the products whose prices are rising reap an addition-
al income. They, too, can now purchase more than they could
before the increase of the money supply. Thus, prices continue
to rise until all prices have risen, but they do not increase
simultaneously and to the same degree. This fact causes some
people to gain and some people to lose. The sellers of products
or services marketed at higher prices obviously must gain if
they can continue to buy in markets not yet affected by price
rises. On the other hand, the sellers of products whose prices
have not yet risen must lose if they are purchasers in markets
with higher prices. When the readjustment process finally
comes to an end, the material position of all people has been
affected.
No Shortage of Gold 57
NOTE
I David Ricardo, "Principles of Political Economy and Taxation,
U in
Piero Sraffa, ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo
(Cambridge, England: University Press for the Royal Economic
Society, 1951), I, 362.
4
To Restore World Monetary
Order
HENRI'" IfAZLITT, Author
lIVilton, Connecticut
from inflation and had bought and sold dollars when required
to retain their own currency at a fixed parity, and if above all
the U.S. government had refrained from inflation and bought
dollars from and sold gold to foreign central banks on demand,
the system could have worked smoothly enough. All other
currencies would have maintained their fixed rate to the dollar,
the dollar would have maintained its fixed rate to gold, and so
all currencies would have maintained a fixed rate to gold.
To repeat: the trouble was not primarily technical. What was
wrong was that no direct discipline was put on any country but
the United States to keep its currency always convertible into
gold. The American authorities did not seem to have the
slightest realization of the immense responsibility that had
been put upon them to uphold the whole world monetary
network by refraining rigorously from inflation in order to
maintain continuous gold convertibility.
But it was in order to permit and encourage inflation (though
no one dared to state it so bluntly) that the whole Bretton
Woods structure had been set up. It did permit an enormous
world inflation, although it did not, as the years went on,
permit enough inflation to satisfy the government officials of
most of the member countries, including our own.
And so successive steps were taken to validate or consolidate
past national inflations and to make bigger future inflations
possible. There was not a single participating currency that was
not devalued at least once, and some were devalued many
times. The British pound, whose par value up to 1931 had been
$4.86, was devalued in September 1949 from $4.03 to $2.80.
That action touched off twenty-five devaluations of other
currencies within a single week. Then in November 1967 the
pound was devalued again from $2.80 to $2.40. The French
franc and other leading currencies were devalued many times.
(Let me add here as a personal note, that I was repeatedly
unable to obtain from the International Monetary fund, when
writing my weekly economic column for Newsweek, any com-
plete record or tabulation of the number of devaluations of
To Restore World Monetary Order 65
currency unit; if its reserves got "too high, " it would be obliged
to revalue its currency unit upward. In other words, it would
be encouraged to continue to follow rash inflationary policies
because the penalties would be removed: it need not pay its
debts 100 percent on the dollar in which they were contracted,
but periodically could tell its foreign and domestic creditors
that its 10Us would be paid off at only 90 percent or less of
their original value.
On the other hand, a country would be penalized for follow-
ing prudent monetary and fiscal policies and refraining from
inflation. For in that case it would almost certainly gain
reserves from the inflating countries. Therefore it would be
obliged to upvalue its currency unit, that is, to bring about
deflation and lower prices at home, and so to hurt its export
trade by initially making its export prices higher for the
nationals of other countries.
This is what the Council of Economic Advisers calls making
"discipline symmetrical for both deficit and surplus coun-
tries." That is, you make discipline "symmetrical"» not only by
rewarding the heedless countries for inflating by allowing
them and even requiring th.em to keep devaluing, but you
"symmetrically" punish the prudent countries for not inflating
by requiring them to upvalue.
This part of the Economi(~ Advisers' plan implies fixed or
"established" official exchange rates, subject, however, to con-
stant change. But the Advisers also tell us that if other
countries wished, "the u.s.. proposal would permit either
transitional or indefinite periods of floating." Apparently, any-
thing is to be tolerated except a currency that keeps its value.
We come now to the most oDrtinous part of the u.s. plan.
The international monetary system must have what the
Advisers call "adequate reserves.. " As they explain: "Failure to
provide the system with adequate reserves puts deflationary
pressure on deficit countries." Translating this. into plainer
English, unless we keep supplying the more recklessly inflat-
68 HENRY HAZLITI
For the very reason that it puts such unrestricted power into
the hands of the world's central bank bureaucracy, there is a
frightening likelihood that some such plan will be adopted.
The only worse scheme I know of is the New York Times'
editorial proposal of February 20, 1973, that "The world now
needs a central bank to provide unlimited [italics mine] support
for any nation whose currency is in trouble." Here is the most
enticing invitation to reckless national inflation that could be
imagined. But perhaps this is really no different from the
Economic Advisers' proposal, with the IMF standing for that
central bank and handing out SDRs in exchange for no value
received whatever.
Of course, what the world really needs is the exact opposite
of all this. A nation or central bank that has got itself into
trouble through its own imprudence should be obliged to
borrow in the open market and at whatever rate its credit
standing warrants. It was a mistake of the International
Monetary Fund from the beginning to grant any country au-
tomatic credit. Instead of issuing still more SDRs through the
IMF, the SDRs already allotted should be retired. What each
nation originally got is a matter of record; it should be asked to
turn back that amount. The nations that have passed some of
them on should be allowed to buy them back from present
holders at the existing market rate for their own currencies.
Then the IMF itself should be dismantled, and asked to return
its own gold holdings to its member countries in proportion to
the respective quotas paid in. The IMF has served merely as a
world inflation factory. It imposes a constant threat of more
inflation as long as it exists.
These are, of course, only the first steps in reform. Eventu-
ally, what we need is not to phase out what remains of the gold
standard, as the Economic Advisers suggest, but to return to a
full gold standard.
The reason for this proposal is clear and imperative. The
constant convertibility of a currency into gold on demand, and
to any amount, and to anybody who holds it, is necessary
To Restore World Monetary Order 71
'77
78 JOHN A. SPARKS
sanction from the agreement of the parties. "9 The state's func-
tion is merely to enforce the wills of the parties if one or the
other should balk at doing what he had earlier agreed to do. As
Hayek said, the contract is the "instrument that the law sup-
plies to the individual to shape his own position. "1.0 "Status to
contract" as it is being used here means the enlargement of the
sphere open to the individual for the creation of voluntary
relationships with his fellow men. By contrast, the citizen of a
status society finds himself immobilized by legally created and
maintained restrictions.
In General
process," that is, "a fair procedure where the law is interpreted
in keeping with constitutional limitations. "29 Corwin shows that
as early as 1857 in the Dred Scott case the Supreme Court
interpreted the Fifth Amendment to prohibit the denial of
property because such a denial was substantively prohibited,
not because the procedure for enforcing the act in, question was
improper. 30 In several cases over the next eight decades the
Supreme Court struck down various attempts to regulate the
economy under the due process clauses of the Fifth and
Fourteenth Amendments. 31 Therefore, until the 1930s the fact
that a law was passed or a procedure established was not
. enough to satisfy the due process requirement. Interference
with property could not exceed constitutional limits.
Furthermore, when private property was taken under
procedures which were fair and under powers properly
granted to the government, the Constitution ordered a CCjust
compensation" to be paid. The determination of just com-
pensation was to be made in such a way that the owner had an
opportunity to be heard.
In summary, the protection against the taking of one's
property was procedural and substantial. After th~se hurdles,
if property was constitutionally available, remuneration had to
be paid for it. Personal and real property, including gold and
other money metals, was well protected by the Constitution.
In General
conclusion that the legal tender power was not just a war
emergency power but a regular peacetime power as well.
Much later, in the Gold ClaUlse Cases, the Supreme Court
relied upon a "broad and comprehensive national authority
over the subjects of revenue, finance and currency ... derived
from the aggregate of the powers granted to the Con-
gress embracing the powers to lay and collect taxes, to bor-
row money, to regulate commerce . . . to coin mon-
ey. . . . "37
.
However, the Legal Tender Cases contain more than
arguments about resulting powers. The pro-legal tender
Justices had to deal with specific constitutional provisions
opposing the Legal Tender Acts. The objections had been
eloquently raised by Chief Justice Chase in the first Legal
Tender Case (Hepburn v. Griswold) where the court had
found the acts unconstitutional.
The Constitution, Chase had said, prohibited the state
legislatures from passing any laws impairing the obligation of
contracts. Further, by refusing to grant such a power to the
federal Congress, the Founders assumed that no such authori-
ty would be exercised by that body either. 38 Also, added Chase,
the Fifth Amendment forbade the taking of property without
due process of law. Contracts were property, and clearly con-
tracts were being impaired and property improperly taken
when debts and obligations were diminished in value. 39
Justice Strong attempted to counter Chase's assertions.
Whenever Congress passes a bankruptcy act or declares war,
claimed Strong, many contracts are impaired and a great deal
of property is taken with the mere flourish of the legislative
pen. If such acts are constitutional, then the fact that contracts
are impaired and property ta.ken by the enactment of legal
tender laws is just another case where the power of Congress
may be exerted for a legitimate purpose, but in the process
annul or impair contracts. 40
Chase's rejoinder was that the power to declare war and to
make uniform bankruptcy laws were examples of expressly
90 JOHN A. SPARKS
During the period between the Legal Tender Cases and the
New Deal, the weakening of protections for property and
contracts was occurring in ways too numerous to explore within
the confines of this paper. 45 These changes were to surface
dramatically in 1933 and 1934. However, attention will now be
directed to establishment of the Federal Reserve System in
1914.
The Federal Reserve Act of 1914 presented no constitutional
problem to legal commentators. Most had conceded the posi-
tion of McCulloch v. MarylancJt6 where Justice Marshall
asserted that the establishment of a national bank was
legitimately derived from the power to coin and borrow
The Legal Standing of Gold 91
issued under the laws of the United States [emphasis mine]. "~R
In less than a month, Roosevelt issued another executive
order which required "all persons . . . to deliver . . . to a
Federal Reserve Bank ... all the gold coin, gold bullion, and
gold certificates . . ." which they then owned. 59 There were
some minor exceptions. 60 Member Federal Reserve Banks who
were to receive this gold were merely conduits. Gold
deposited with them had to be turned over to Federal Reserve
District Banks. 61 If that was not enough, Congress gave further
power to the President by passing an amendment to the
Agricultural Adjustment Act:, called the Thomas Amend-
ment. 62 The amendment allowed for note issuance up to $3
billion and a proclamation by the President reducing the gold
content of the dollar by no more than half.
Private and public contracts still contained provisions calling
for payment in gold or its equivalent in value. Many contracts
and "'almost all bonds~~ public or private contained gold clauses
in 1933. 63 "Gold Clauses" were nullified by a Joint Congres-
sional Resolution which claimed that the clauses obstructed
the power of Congress to regulate the value of money and keep
". every dollar of equal value. 641'herefore, "every provision con-
tained in or made with respect to any obligation which purports
to give the obligee a right to require payment in gold ... is
declared to be against public policy. . . . Every obligation,
heretofore or hereafter incurred ... shall be discharged upon
payment, dollar for dollar, in any coin or currency which
at the time of payment is legal tender for public and private
debts. "65
Another executive order followed 66 and on January 15, 1934,
the President requested new legislation to "'organize a curren-
cy system that will be both sound and adequate. "67 He said in
part:
94 JOHN A. SPARKS
ty.88 But the central question concerns the legal status of gold
ownership in the light of the gold clause cases referred to
above: HIn view of the involved reasoning of the Gold Clause
Cases . . . it is possible that the Supreme Court, on some
theory, might hold that the use of gold clauses would still be
ineffective, even after our right to hold gold has been
restored. "89 Barring favorable judicial construction, the "gold
ownership" privilege established by recent legislation is but a
shadow of the full-fledged, pre-1934 right of ownership.
NOTES
ISir Henry Maine, Ancient Law (London: Dent and Sons, 1917), p.
100.
2Holzer v. Deutsche Reichsbahn-Gesellschaft, 159 Misc. 830, 290
N~Y.S. 181,191.
3F. A. Hayek, The Constitution ofLiberty (Chicago: The Universi-
ty of Chicago Press, 1960), p. 154.
4Archibald R. Lewis, Emerging Medieval Europe (New York:
Knopf, 1967), p. 24.
5Clarence A. Carson, The Flight from Reality (New York: The
Foundation for Economic Education, Inc., 1969), p. 336.
6W. E. Lunt, History of England (New York: Harper & Row,
Publishers, 1957; 4th ed.), p. 176.
7Ibid., pp. 237, 246.
IlLunt, History of England, p. 289.
9"Contractus legem ex combentione accipiunt," Digest of
Justinian, 16, 3, 1, 6, in Henry C. Black, ed., Law Dictionary (St.
Paul, Minn.: West Publishing Co., 1957), p. 398.
IOHayek, Constitution of Liberty, p. 154.
II Lewis, Emerging Medieval Europe, pp. 17, 20.
,,)7Ibid., Sec. 2.
51112 USCA Sec. 248 (n).
.,)9Executive Order No. 6102, 31 CFR, 1936 ed., Part 50 (April 5,
1938).
60Each person was allowed to keep no more than $100 worth of gold
coins and certificates, gold customarily used in a legitimate industry
or profession (dentist, jeweler) and gold coins having special value to
collectors. Gold coin and bullion earmarked for a foreign government
or foreign central bank was not ordered in. Executive Order 6102,
Sees. 2(a), 2(b), and 2(c).
61Ibid., Sec. 5.
6248 Stat. L. 51 (May 12, 1933). Note that twice in 1936 the AAA was
held unconstitutional. Butler v. U.S., 296 U.S.l, and Rice Mills v.
Fountenot, 297 U.S. 110. Finally, in 1939theactwasupheldduetoa
change in court personnel. U. S. v. Rock Royal Co., 307 U. S. 533. 'See
Lyman A. Garber, Of Men and Not ofLaw (New York: Devin-Adair,
1966), pp. 34-35.
63Charles H. Pritchett, The American Constitution (New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1959), p. 250.
64H. ]. Res., 192, 73d Cong., 1st Sess. (1933).
6.'>Another part of the s~me resolution abrogated gold clauses in
U. S. government obligation.
66Executive Order No. 6260, 31 CFR, 1938 ed., Part 50.
67Public Papers of Franklin D. Roosevelt, III, 40-45; Krooss, A
Documentary History of Banking, p. 2789.
6RKrooss, A Documentary History of Banking, p. 2790.
69 31 USCA 440, 48 Stat. L. 337.
7°Ibid., Sec. 2(a).
71Ibid., Sec. 2(b) 3.
72public Papers of Franklin D. Roosevelt, III, 64-66.
73Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio R.R., 294 U.S. 240,55 S. Ct. 407,
79 L. Ed. 885 (1935). See also Perry v. United States, 294 U.S. 330,
55 S. Ct. 432, 79 L. Ed. 912 (1935) where the court denied Congress
the right to abrogate gold clauses in government obligations but then
denied the plaintiff recovery because he could show no/damage.
74Norman v. Baltimore & Ohio R.R., in Charles G. Fenwick, ed.,
Cases on American Constitutional Law (Chicago: Callaghan & Co.,
1953), p. 318.
75Ibid., p. 320.
The Legal Standing of Gold 103
79 79 Stat. L. 5.
110 12 USCA Sec. 413, 82 Stat. L. 50 (March 18, 1968).
Illlt is estimated that some $287 million in gold was retained illegal-
ly in the hands of the public. Friedman and Schwartz, A Monetary
History, pp.464-465n.
1l2Gold Regulations Sec. 54.12
1l3Literature is available on gold coin investment and gold mining
stock ownership, both of which a.re legal. See Donald]. Hoppe, How
to Invest in Gold Coins, and How to Invest in Gold Stocks (New
Rochelle: Arlington House, 1970 and 1972).
1l4Gold Regulations, Sec. 54.20 as amended.
Il.5Gold Regulations, Sec. 54.4(14),. 54.22-54.25.
1l6Gold Regulations, Sec. 54.1,4 (b).
1l7"President Signs Ownership Bill," Coin Investments Market Let-
ter 1, no. 19 (August 1974), Coin Investments, Inc., Birmingham,
Mich.
IlIlRene A. Wormser and Donald L. Kemmerer. "Restoring 'Gold
Clauses' in Contracts," American Bar Association Journal 60:
942-946.
1l9Ibid., p. 946.
9OJohn V. Van Sickle and Benjamin A. Rogge, Introductory
Economics (New York: D. Van :Nostrand, 1954), p. 543.
91Faustino Ballve, Essentials of Economics (New York: The
Foundation for Economic Education, 1963), p. 7.
92Sennholz, 'The Crisis in International Economic Relations
(Hillsdale, Mich.: Hillsdale College, March 1973), 2 Imprimis, No.3.
6
The Role Of Gold
In The Past Century
DONALD L. KEMMERER
Professor of Economics,
University of Illinois
104
Gold in the Past Century 105
trade of about half that amount each year, easily the world's
greatest at the time. This was toward the end of the Boer War
(1899-1902), an era of frequent clashes on India's Northwest
Frontier, and mounting tensions in Europe. Yet, Britain's
bullion reserves against all bank notes and deposits of the
nation ranged from 3.5 to 3.0 percent and her net exports of
bullion in anyone year never exceeded $33 million. If there
were fears of inadequate liquidity to carry on this enormous
trade, they were muted. How did she do it? She had heavy
investments overseas earning her citizens substantial profits
every year, she carried almost half the world's shipping, and
London's CCCity," or financial center, was the world's most
important. Although merchandise imports exceeded mer-
chandise exports every year" the British were living within
their income, living off the profits of good investments and not
(yet) trying to save the world. All of this gave her pound
sterling great credibility. If a currency has that, it does not
need a substantial gold backing.
Going back to the 1873-1914 era, a study of resumptions of
specie payments is also rewarding. I dug into this subject some
years ago because I was unhappy about generalizing from the
American experience of 1875··1879 that Amercians know best.
Ministers of Finance, Secretaries of the Treasury, leading
bankers-i.n brief those with responsibility for successfully
putting their nation back on a gold standard-were, almost to a
man, fearful that they did not have enough gold, that a run on
their CClimited" supply by speculators and others would
succeed, humiliate the nation, and damage their own repu-
tations. All of this is understandable. Some of them piled up
rather enormous reserves against that CCmoment of truth,"
notably in Austria and Russia. But in actual practice the most
important ingredients for success were a firm announcement
of intention combined with a. clearly sincere effort to carry it
out. It came down most of all to confidence. Japan had showed
her sincerity by minting and jlssuing gold coin and at the same
time withdrawing paper bank notes and silver when she
110 DONALD L. KEMMERER
French sometimes say, "In the land of the blind, the one-eyed
man is king."
The 1933 devaluation of the dollar was unique in the annals
of devaluation, and yet for the next generation many
Americans were wont to generalize from it. We devalued then,
we said, because prices had fallen too much. One may well ask
what sort of a financial patent :medicine a devaluation is that it
cures all our economic ills. M[ost devaluations are reluctant,
even forced, admissions by a nation that it has inflated its
currency too much, or at least has done so to a greater degree
than the nations around it. Devaluation is essentially a nation's
way of declaring bankruptcy and trying to start over. Our 1971
and 1973 devaluations are of this kind. But a devaluation
purposely to bring about a rise in prices and thereby cheat a
segment of society in the course of doing so has always seemed
to me to be particularly inexcusable.
Within a decade of the appearance of Gustav Cassel's and
Joseph Kitc4in's writings doubting that there was enough
monetary gold, Professors Frank D. Graham and Charles
Whittlesey of Princeton brought out The Golden Avalanche,
which became a best seller. The so-called mint price of gold,
the $35 an ounce figure of recent memory, was really not a
market price at all, but rather the number of dollars, of 13.71
grains each, that a troy ounce of gold (480 grains) would coin
into, i. e., almost exactly 35. So, when the United States cut the
size of the dollar from the previous 23.22 grains to the new
figure of 13.71 grains, it autornatically changed the mint price
from $20.67 to $35. This was a 69 percent rise in the price of
gold, with the Mint required to "buy" (take as if to coin) all the
gold anyone brought to it, without limit. The devaluation of
January 1934 raised the dollar value of American reserves from
$4 billion to $6.8 billion and stimulated the gold mining
business beyond imagination. The stock of The Homestake
Mining Company of California, the nation's largest gold mine,
. paid $2 extra monthly from July 1934 to May 1937 and in
116 DONALD L. KEMMERER
the other end of the line . . . with the tax payers to give him
strength. When the people's right to restrain public spending
by demanding gold coin was taken from them, the automatic
flow of strength from the grass roots to enforce economy in
Washington was disconnected." (Commercial and Financial
Chronical, May 6, 1948).
As the United States over the ensuing two decades ran
deficits year after year, with only rare exceptions, and in-
creased its money supply in so doing, som,e of these surplus
dollars found their way to European central banks. (They were
presumably redeemable in gold, thus as good as gold.) In the
1940s they were very welcome and at times in the 1950s too,
although by then their amount was causing anxieties. As major
nations recovered from the ravages of war, they preferred to
keep more of their reserves in gold itself, and some countries
demanded gold for dollars. Despite our excess of merchandise
exports over imports, which of itself would have attracted gold
to the United States, this country had an adverse balance of
payments. Short-term liabilities to foreigners rose from $6.9
billion in December 1945 to $13.6 in December 1957 to $28.8
in 1964 to $41.7 in December 1970 to $60.7 billion at the end of
1972. Obviously, our creditors became concerned as they
watched us, year after year, live beyond our means, offer more
and more IOUs, and draw down our most liquid assets, gold.
American holdings of gold dropped from $22.9 billion in
December 1957 to $15.5 billion in December 1964 to $11.1 in
December 1970.
To reassure our creditors and make our own citizens aware of
the worsening situation, our government applied a series of
"band-aid" remedies, such as recalling families of servicemen
abroad, forbidding American citizens to own gold abroad,
taxing investments made overseas, lowering tourists' customs
free allowances, to name just a few. When in 1960 the price of
gold rose to over $40 on the free market for gold iIi London, we
arranged with other central banks to dump enough gold onto
that market to drive the price down to $35 again and remove
Gold in the Past Century 119
the danger sign from public sight. That was in one sense "the
first appearance of the "two-tier system" of gold prices-$35
officially and something else on the London gold market. Eight
years later, in March 1968, the hunger of gold buyers had
become so insatiable that central bankers no longer wanted to
dip into their reserves to hold down the price of gold. 'Total
central bank gold reserves in the free world had actually
shrunk because of this dipping, and did so despite free gold
production of $11 billion of gold in that time. So now this
coterie of central bankers, the United States a ringleader,
proudly announced their solution, namely, have a two-tier
system of pricing gold. They made a virtue, or at least a
solution, of what they had regarded as a menace eight years
before. Few experts thought this new-old solution would last
long.
During those eight years, Treasury officials and others came
forth with all kinds of promises and good resolves, but we
never got around to the fundarnental problem of balancing the
budget and thus staunching the constant outflow of dollars and
of restraining the buildup of short-term indebtedness. True,
we had to wage a costly war in Asia in the 1960s, but if that was
of top priority, then expenditures for other foreign aid, con-
tinuing farm price-support programs, and welfare programs
should have been curtailed until we were in a position to afford
them again. Instead we kept them all, created more dollars,
some of which went abroad, and further increased our short-
term liabilities. These traveling dollars enlarged the reserve
accounts of foreign nations and encouraged them to inflate
too-and they did. Since the A.merican dollar was the world's
reserve currency, an honor accorded the dollar and a special
privilege accruing to the United States, we should have be-
haved more responsibly in maintaining its integrity.
Everyone knows the rest of the story, where all this has
ended. With our trade situation worsening and short-term
liabilities mounting at an alarming rate in the spring and
summer of 1971, President Nixon finally announced on August
120 DONALD L. KEMMERER
Economist, Chalcedon,
Canoga Park, California
122
Greenback Dollars and Federal Sovereignty 123
to the coins bearing his image. The modern world is not so far
removed from ancient paganism.
The framers of the Constitution had gained considerable
experience with the economic effects of an unlimited gov-
ernmental sovereignty over the monetary unit. The paper
money inflations of the colonial era, followed by the disastrous
Revolutionary wartime inflation, and finally another threat of
inflation by Daniel Shays' rebellious supporters in Massa-
chusetts (1786-1787), served as sufficient warnings for the men
in Philadelphia. Gerald Dunn{~ has written that "the Founding
Fathers regarded political control of monetary institutions
with an abhorrence born of bitter experience, and they seri-
ously considered writing a sharp limitation on such gov-
ernmental activity into the Constitution itself. Yet they did
not, and by 'speaking in silences' gave the government they
founded the near-absolute authority over currency and
coinage that has always been considered the necessary conse-
quence of national sovereignty."l1 The results of their failure to
include specific prohibitions against federal fiat money (as the
Constitution does contain with regard to state governments)
were not to become manifest until the great upheaval of 1861-
1865. There had been prelinlinary warnings, however: the
Panics of 1819, 1837, and 185'7, all created by prior monetary
inflations.
course, that the Bank, as the nation's central bank, was more
conservative, more responsible than unregulated (or less reg-
ulated) state banks. Only recently has this thesis been
challenged. Hugh Rockoff has estimated that the transfer may
have increased the money supply by less than 2 percent. 18 State
banks were far more inflationary as depositories than the In-
dependent Treasury system, introduced in 1840, abandoned in
1841, and reintroduced in 1846. That system was not involved
in fractional reserves. But state banks may have been no worse
than the Second Bank. Thus, the estimate of Roger
Taney-Secretary of the Treasury in 1833 and later Chief
Justice of the Supreme Court-was probably correct. His
justification for the use of state banks in preference to a central
bank for the government's deposits was based on the question
of limited versus total sovereignty: "For no one of these
corporations will possess that absolute, and almost unlimited
dominion over the property of the citizens of the United
States, which the present bank holds, and which enables it at
any moment, at its own pleasure, to bring distress upon any
portion of the community, whenever it may deem it useful to
its interest to make its power felt. The influence of each of the
state banks is necessarily limited to its own immediate
neighborhood, and they will be kept in check by the other local
banks. "19 If the people must tolerate the sovereignty of banks
in currency matters, let that sovereignty be limited and local.
The Jacksonian persuasion was decentralist to the core.
There was another factor in the Jacksonians' hostility to
banking. Bray Hammond, the leading historian of banking
during the Jacksonian period (and an uncompromising admirer
of central banking), has called attention to this factor. What
most offended them about banking was the character of the
banks as limited liability corporations. Unincorporated
partnerships in which the partners bore the full personal
responsibility for the failure of the bank were not regarded
with the same intense hatred. 20 Grant a bank a corporate char-
ter, however, and a "vast monopoly," to use Taney's words, is
Greenback Dollars and Federal Sovereignty 129
Which groups benefited and which ones paid more than their
share of the war's costs? On this point, obviously a crucial one,
historians cannot seem to agree.
Farmers: These were the most numerous segment of the
population throughout the nineteenth century. Mitchell con-
cludes that farmers as a group were net losers during the war,
CCamong the most unfortunate" of all producers. 52 But Emerson
Fite explicitly rejects Mitchell's conclusion in the case of west-
ern farmers; they prospered, paid off mortgages and other
debts, saw their incomes grow, and the West received eager
immigrants from eastern farming areas. This would indicate a
fall in productivity of eastern farms, however. Depopulation of
eastern rural areas was widespread. 53 The effects of price infla-
tion and war expenditures did not hit all farmers equally.
Wage-earners: Mitchell states unequivocally that "in no case
did the wage-earners escape a considerable loss of real income.
. . . While the fluctuations of real wages are seen to have been
by no means uniform in all cases, there is no industry in which
the advance in money wages kept pace with the advance in
prices."54 Most workers-98 percent of them-earned less
than $2.50 per day in 1860, and they did not all work through-
out the year, given seasonal employment and trade cycle dis-
ruptions. 55 Most men earned from $1 to $1.50 per day. Money
wages for the highest paid workers in 1860 appreciated least
rapidly-by one-fourth to one-third-while lower paid work-
ers received increases of two-thirds to three-fourths. 56 Real
wages fell, given the doubling of prices. 57 In a later study,
Mitchell admits the weakness of the available data; never-
theless, he remains convinced that wage-earners were worse
off in 1865 than in 1860. 58 Currency depreciation, he estimates,
amounted to cca confiscation of perhaps a fifth or sixth of real
incomes."59 (The costs were borne willingly, for the most part,
except in 1864, when the gold premium was at its highest. 60)
Thus, concludes Mitchell, C'the chief cause of the extraordinary
advance in American prices between 1862 and 1865 was the
Greenback Dollars and Federal Sovereignty 137
But Congress every day passes laws that affect the value of
property and of money, and therefore incidentally the
value of contracts. The other day the Senator from Iowa
[Mr.. Grimes] introduced a bill to establish a street
railroad in the city of Washington. We were all in favor of
it; but did any Senator dream that by doing that he was
impairing the obligation of contracts? And yet we affected
the value of omnibuses that now run on the streets of
Washington. Every act that you pass, almost every event
in our political history now, impairs the value of prop-
erty.93
NOTES
IOn the sociological distinction between power and authority, see
Robert A. Nisbet, The Social Bond (New York: Knopf, 1970), pp. 142
ff.; Nisbet, The Sociological Tradition (New York: Basic Books,
1966), Ch. 4.
2Ethelbert Stauffer, Christ and the Caesars (Philadelphia: West-
minster Press, 1955), p. 36.
3Ibid., p. 38.
4lbid.
.5lbid., pp. 55-56.
6Nisbet, Tradition and Revolt (New York: Random House, 1968),
p.163.
7R. J. Rushdoony, Politics of Guilt and Pity (Nutley, N. J.: Craig
Press, 1970); Nisbet, .The Quest for Community (New York: Oxford
University Press [1st ed., 1953] 1969).
IIF. A. Hayek, The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1944), Ch. 10.
91'he portraits of Lincoln and Secretary of the Treasury Salmon P.
Chase appeared on some of the U. S. Notes in 1862 and 1863 (Lincoln:
$5; Chase: $1). However, when Spencer Clark, chief ~lerk of the
National Currency Division of the Treasury, had his own portrait
placed on half a million 5 cent notes ("shinplasters"), Representative
Russell Thayer thought he had gone too far. He introduced the
prohibiting legislation, which then passed and is still in force. On the
story of the prohibition, see William P. Donlon, United States Large
Size Paper Money, 1861 to 1923 2d ed. (lola, Wis.: KraiIse, 1970),
p.17.
wGary Palmer, "Still Saving Kennedy Halves?" COINage (Sep-
tember 1969): 7.
IIGerald T. Dunne, Monetary Decisions of the Supreme Court
(New Brunswick, N. J.: Rutgers University Press, 1960), Preface.
12Jackson to Lewis Guly 16, 1820); cited by Charles G. Sellers,
"Banking and Politics in Jackson's Tennessee," Mississippi Valley
Historical Review (now the Journal ofAmerican History), 41 (1954):
76.
13Jackson to Benton (n.d.); cited in ibid., p. 77. See also Jackson's
State of the Union Message (December 5, 1836); reprinted in
Herman E. Krooss (ed.), Documentary History of Banking and
Currency in the United States (N ew York: Chelsea House and
Greenback Dollars and Federal Sovereignty 151
President, Chalcedon,
Canoga Park, California
157
158 ROUSAS JOHN RUSHDOONY
Gold Standard
[leavy Light
Shekel 252i grs. troy 1261 grs.
Mina 50 shekels 12,630 grs. troy 6,315 grs.
Talent 3000 shekels 758,000 grs. troy 379,000 grs.
Silver Standard
Shekel 224+ grs. troy II2t grs.
Mina 50 shekels 11,225 grs. troy 5,660 grs.
Talent 3000 shekels 673,500 grs. troy 336,750 grs.
silver. This is required because justice calls for full value at all
times. To short-weight a man either in selling him grain or
money is theft, and the law declares plainly, "Thou shalt not
stear~ (Exodus 20: 15). A false weight or shekel of gold or silver
is "spoil" or "despoiling the people" and is contrary to ""law and
justice" (Moffat's rendering, Ezekiel 45: 9).
Second, a very limited state is allowed by biblical law, and its
taxing power is limited to a head tax, or poll tax, on all males
over twenty years of age, and the same for all (Exodus 30:
11-16). ,The basic social financing is not by the state, but by
means of the tithe, which finances religion, education, health,
welfare, etc. 7
Third, biblical law has no prison system but rather requires
restitution. A thief restores the thing stolen, plus a penalty,
from double the value of the article to four- or five-fold,
depending on the nature of the item. Thus, ""If a man shall steal
an ox, or a sheep, and kill it, or sell it; he shall restore five oxen
for an ox, and four sheep for a sheep" (Exodus 22: 1). Sheep
have an income potential as a source of wool, as meat, and for
breeding, so that more than double restitution is required.
Oxen were valuable for their meat and hide, and very im-
portant as well-trained beasts of burden, capable of hauling
greater weight than horses; hence, their value was greater.
Crime thus did not pay: full value had to be restored; the
habitual criminal had to be executed.
The goal of the law was thus restitution, where offenses
occurred (full value retained for property), and full value in all
monetary transactions by requiring a standard and unchanging
weight of gold and silver as the medium of exchange. Not only
is hard money the standard of Scripture, but it is plainly
declared to be the law of God. This is a very serious considera-
tion. It accounts fo~ the persistence, in times of a biblically
governed faith, of a demand for hard money. Insufficient
attention has been paid to the critique of debased coinage by
the early Church Fathers. The reformers were also aware of
Hard Money and Society in the Bible 163
Rulers have not changed much since Luther's day. They still
debase the currency and blame the people for the resulting
inflation.
Matthew Henry (1662-1714) said of Leviticus 19: 35-37, "He
that sells, is bound to give the full of the commodity, and he
that buys, the full of the price agreed upon, which cannot be
done without just balances, weights, and measures."9
It is clear, from the foregoing, that the kind of society that
biblical law calls for has a certain rigidity of framework with
respect to values. God's unchanging law governs all things, and
God requires that all weights and measures represent His
requirement, that they be full value. The matter can be
expressed thus: a modern definition of money has it that
money is a representation of ,;vealth or property. This is a fair
definition of a paper currency: it is a representation of wealth,
not the real thing, and its value is fluid and changeable. In
terms of the biblical requirement, money cannot be a rep-
resentation of wealth: it must be wealth, so that all transactions
should be exchanges of wealth, not of real wealth for a symbol
or representation of wealth.
Biblical law thus has a rigid framework in order that men
may have .freedom within that framework, and so that
164 ROUSAS JOHN RUSHDOONY
The sad fact is that the same tragedy is being reenacted today.
The issues are essentially the same, and the same is true of the
principles at stake.
NOTES
IGeorge Bush, Notes, Critical and Practical, on the Book of
Leviticus (New York: Ivison & Phinney, 1857), p. 214.
2A. R. S. Kennedy, "Money," in James Hastings, ed., A Dictionary
of the Bible (New York: Charles Scribner's Sons, 1919), III, 419.
3For much valuable data on U.S. coinage, see R. S. Yeoman, A
Guide Book of United States Coins, published annually by Western
Publishing Company. The 1971 edition (p. 3), in citing the rise of the
price of coins (as well as their decline at times, and the reasons why),
listed first the fact that "The trend of our economy is inflationary."
4For more on biblical law, see R. J. Rushdoony, Institutes of
Biblical Law (Nutley, N.J.: The Presbyterian & Reformed Publish-
ing Company, 1972).
'';See Gary K. North, Introduction to Christian Economics (Nutley,
N. J.: Craig Press, 1973).
6Cited in Charles T. Fritsch, "Proverbs," in The Interpreter's Bible
(New York: Abingdon Press, 1955), IV, 874.
Hard Money and Society in the Bible 175
Professor of Economics,
Claremont Men's College
176
Is the Gold Standard Gone ]4"orever? 177
was reasonably steady over the period, the price levels at the
end of the period were not far different than at the beginning.
To say that this is in contrast to experience since 1914, or even
in the last three decades, is gross understatement.
.T here seems to be little dispute about the facts. In a speech
delivered at 'loronto, Canada, in December 1972, Arthur
Burns, the chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, recognized it as follows:
the official price, thus casting aside the second generic re-
quirement for a gold standard: the agency prepared to buy and
sell gold for money, and money for gold.
The "closing of the gold window" in August 1971 placed the
United States and the USSR in a very similar position. Both
countries have monetary units defined in terms of gold;
neither country has an effective agency prepared to buy and
sell at the monetary price. There is no convertibility of the
ruble into gold, either domestically or internationally, nor is
there any convertibility of the dollar into gold, either domes-
tically or internationally. Both currencies are, in effect,
irredeemable paper money, although, to be sure, the dollar is
bought, sold, and loaned on the world's markets fairly freely,
while the amount of paper rubles or coins bought, sold, or
loaned is negligible and such exchanges as do exist are either
black market or in the nature of commodity purchase and sale
rather than money.
A few months ago, just after the latest crisis in the interna-
tional money markets, the Wall Street Journal, in a thoughtful
editorial entitled "Rethinking the Dollar Problem" (March 2,
1973), suggested that the appropriate action called for a
tightening of credit by the U. S. Federal Reserve System, thus
increasing interest rateshere, and for a loosening of credit in
Germany, thus lowering interest rates there..This is precisely
the mechanics of the first line of adjustment under the gold
standard. The adjustment mechanism is virtually automatic
instead of requiring the wise decisions of central bankers who
have the courage to forego short-run domestic political
advantages for the sake of international harmony and well-
being.What happens is almost precisely the reverse, as is
indicated by the recent attempts of the Reserve authorities to
"jawbone" down higher interest rates in the United States-to
mention only one inconsistency in American monetary policy.
The international monetary system is still suffering from
belief in a mythology stemming, it would appear, from an
emotional rather than logical hangover from the depression
Is the Gold Standard Gone Forever? 189
NOTES
IThis was the result of the statute of 1834 which. provided for a
10-percent alloy instead of the prior 1/12ths, and of the codification
of 1873, repeated again in the Gold Standard Act of 1900. I omit
references to the bimetallic standard.
2Houghton-Mifflin Economics/Business News, Spring 1973, p. 8.
3See, for example, the discussion in Triffin, Our International
Monetary System: Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow (New York:
Random House, College Division, 1968), pp. 119-124.
4William M. Clarke and George Pulay, :The World's Money (New
York: Praeger, 1971), p. 70.
'''The Role of Gold (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise
Association, Public Policy Studies, 1963), p. 79.
Epilogue
It is not money, as is sometimes said, but the destruction of
money through inflation that is the root of many evils. Since
these chapters were written, in the spring of 1973, the global
inflation has accelerated its monetary destruction and thereby
evoked more ominous economic, social, political, and moral
consequences. In most parts of the world the annual deprecia-
tion rates of the national monetary units now exceed 10 percent
and are rising steadily. Even in the United States the overall
cost of living data as issued by the federal government is rising
breathlessly at two-digit rates. Inflation of such force is
corrosive to the social fabric of society; it becomes the great
destroyer of the social order.
And yet, there is no foreseeable end to the monetary
destruction as the ideological and political forces that are giv-
ing rise to such destructive policies continue to gain strength
and support. Most people and their elected representatives
and officials in high government offices do not understand the
inflation dilemma. They are searching in vain for solutions in
political courage and integrity and more government control.
But in the fog of confusion and ignorance even the most
determined statesman, if he ~,ere to emerge, could not find his
way to safety. Nothing can stop inflation until the
redistributive society learns to exert discipline and moderation
and the economic gospel of ](eynesianism that is dominating
public education is forever discredited.
In the darkness of economic ignorance inflation ravages the
195
196 EPILOGUE
middle class and destroys the social order. Gold, which has
been man's money throughout the ages, is an important ba-
rometer of this destruction. As gold investors we may rejoice
about the soaring gold price, but as members of a highly
productive society we are fearful of the ominous consequences
of the paper money depreciation, which the rising gold price so
distinctly reveals. Rampant inflation not only impedes social
cooperation and division of labor, but also breeds massive
unemployment and deep depression. The .economic disrup-
tion it causes, together with its radical redistribution of wealth
and income, lead to social upheaval, lawlessness, and depriva-
tion. Ugly strikes may paralyze economic life, bloody riots may
cripple the cities and disrupt the distribution of essential
goods. As it becomes impoverished and embittered by infla-
tion, the· middle class may clamor for law and order, food and
jobs, and return to normalcy by force, if necessary. It may
welcome "strong leaders" with emergency powers over prices,
wages, rents, and many other aspects of economic life in order
to restore economic and social order. But unfortunately, strong
governments can only suppress certain disorders; they cannot
restore the marvelous market order that can only spring from
individual freedom.
In spite of their great popularity, governmental controls
over prices do not alleviate the inflation dilemma. On the
contrary, they seriously hamper economic production, create
shortages of vital goods and services, breed black markets, and
above all, create confusion and disorder whenever and
wherever they are applied. They merely constitute attempts at
elevating political might over economic law; and their in-
evitable failures again and again offer cogent proof of the
futility of such attempts.
The lowly u.s. penny offers an example of this failure. It is
about to become worth more as a piece of copper than as aU. S.
coin. Like all silver coins before it, the penny, too, will soon
disappear from circulation, hiding from inflation. Therefore,
in blindness and desperation the men of the u.s. Treasury
Epilogue 197
~~01
202 INDEX