148
148
148
Charles Tilly
University of Michigan
December 1976
.......................................
HISTORY,
Charles Tilly
University of Michigan
December 1976
s o c i o l o g i s t s and h i s t o r i a n s . It c a l l s f o r t h d r e a r y d i s q u i s i t i o n s on t h e
.. L ,
epistemology of ~ e i s t e s w i s s e n s c h a f ~ &
f l~a,t u l e n t t r a c t s on t h e e v i l s of
c h o i c e s b u t t o c h a t t e r , grumble, mumble, o r s h o u t ?
.. ,
. . Y e s , we have o t h e r c h o i c e s . W e can l o o k backward o r forward, and
I. - ...
..
.:,
. \:. speak s o f t l y b u t c l e a r l y about what w e see. Looking backward, w e can
?:
t h e European p r o l e t a r i a t .
The t o p i c i s o l d . It c e r t a i n l y a n t e d a t e s t h e i n v e n t i o n of sociology
b e f o r e s o c i o l o g y d e c l a r e d independence, and p u b l i s h e d i n t h e y e a r t h a t t h e
t h e e f f e c t of i n c r e a s i n g w e a l t h , s o i t i s t h e c a u s e of i n c r e a s i n g ' p o p u -
c a u s e of t h e g r e a t e s t p u b l i c p r o s p e r i t y . " I n Smith's a n a l y s i s , t h e .
i n c r e a s i n g d i v i s i o n of l a b o r r e s u l t e d from t h e r a t i o n a l d i s p o s i t i o n of t h e
f a c t o r s of p r o d u c t i o n -- l a n d , l a b o r and c a p i t a l -- by t h o s e who c o n t r o l l e d
v i t y , i t i n c r e a s e d t h e r e t u r n t o a l l f a c t o r s of p r o d u c t i o n , i n c l u d i n g
labor. I n d i r e c t l y , t h e r a t i o n a l d i s p o s i t i o n of r e s o u r c e s l e d t o t h e growth
growth of t h e p r o l e t a r i a t .
basic relationship.
f o r m a t i o n of t h e E n g l i s h p r o l e t a r i a t . Marx d e n i e d e m p h a t i c a l l y t h a t t h e
wresting of control over the means of production away from artisans and,
mainly for wages in agriculture, but available at bargain rates for indus-
trial production.
Marx had little to say about the numbers involved, or about how
those numbers changed from one period to the next. His implicit argument
in that regard .had two elements. First, the important increases in the
stant numbers. If that is the case, the growth of the proletariat directly
exploitation.
Here sociology and history come together. ~ a r x 'analysis, and his
tunity for complementary work by people from the two disciplines. There
is the opportunity to verify the main lines of Marx' analysis -- for example,
which people moved from artisanal or peasant production into various forms
those paths: which ones bore the most traffic? There is the opportunity to
integrate them into a general account of the flows of people by which the
. . elsewhere? In the century since Marx, one version or another of that double
question has dominated the agenda of modern European economic and social
,history. Some of the debate has pivoted on the facts: how many yeomen, for
example, did enclosures actually displace? Some of the debate has concerned
the proper way to state the questions: Weber and Tawney differed over the
of the debate has dealt with explanations: why did capitalism flourish
at specific times and places in the past. Why, then, might proud and self-
sufficient historians want to share them with mere sociologists? Well, both
look shows that one group of specialists within sociology has already
0
given h i s t o r i a n s v a l u a b l e a s s i s t a n c e i n i d e n t i f y i n g and assembling t h e
l o g i c a l e x p e r t i s e i s r e l e v a n t , perhaps even i n d i s p e n s a b l e .
l o g i c a l s u b d i v i s i o n s of t h e t a s k , not' d i s t i n c t temporal s t a g e s . If we
. .' ,'don't b e g i n w i t h a p i e c e of t h e t h i r d p a r t , w i t h a t e n t a t i v e account of t h e
e n t i r e p r o c e s s of p r o l e t a r i a n i z a t i o n , i n d e e d , w e a r e q u i t e l i k e l y t o
Components of growth? A t i t s s i m p l e s t , t h e a n a l y s i s c o n s i s t s of
d e f i n i n g p r e c i s e l y t h e change being a n a l y z e d , p r e p a r i n g a l o g i c a l l y
whether the independent weaver who hires himself out for the harvest
sions, these, except that they significantly affect the results of the
analysis.
These dull but crucial decisions made, we can begin to ask how the
_ . . _ .- to guesses.at the real numbers later. For now, the thing to notice is
) . . that we can break down those numbers into geographic, temporal and, most
it happened. But the how, in this case, concerns the logical components
of the change.
Thus every landowning peasant who loses his land and becomes an agri-
In fact, the same individual often oscillates between the two categories
throughout his or her lifetime. The net effect of all such moves across
read him aright, Marx' implicit assumption was that natural increase was
.
.
. ,... . ,
an unimportant component of the growth of the European proletariat: the
- I deaths more or less balanced out the births, while net enlargements of
' .
. : .z.
. L
.. .. . .: .-
the proletariat.depended on new entries by.peoplewho began life as non-
r .:
f.
proletarians. This is where the components-of-growth analysis gets inter-
how often and how much? If natural decrease were the normal situation of
for their birth rates to run above their death rates. In that case, the
that of the population as a whole, the proletarian share of the total popu-
lation would tend to rise, even in the absence of lifetime mobility from
and mortality, still further alternatives are quite possible; for example,
the proletarian rate of natural increase could have risen over time.
the migration that matters consists of moves of proletarians into and out
and gains, its overall effect may have been nil, a substantial addition to
increase of the European proletarian population from 1500 to 1900 (or for
where P and P2 are the populations at the two points in time, IC and OC
1
are the numbers of persons who make lifetime moves into the category and
out of it, B and D are births and deaths of members of the category, IM and
Now, why should anyone care about these hypothetical numbers? For
more reasons than one. First, if we are to attempt any general account of
they may be very crude; they may consist, for example, of assigning an
indefinitely large positive value to the net effect of lifetime moves and
zero values to all the other components. That is the tone of Marx'
analysis. Adam Smith, on the other hand, wrote as if natural increase were
the only component differing significantly from zero. Thus in the absence
of any exact numbers, the simple knowledge of which domponents were posi-
control over the means of production. On the other hand, chat same exten-
from one generation to-thenext. To the extent that natural increase was
for artisanal and peasant themes in'that culture. To the extent that net
ence which come to us from, say, E. P. Thompson and Louis Chevalier may
result in part from their having studied populations which differed signifi-
cantly in these regards, or from their having implicitly assumed differing
well. Zero net migration over a long period may result from no moves in
either direction, from large but exactly equal flows of definitive in-
cations for social control, proletarian culture, class conflict and the
matched with even lower mortality. That is the difference between the death-
ridden experience of the sixteenth century and the long life of the twentieth.
n a t i o n a l s t a t e s b e f o r e t h e . f u l 1 bloom of n i n e t e e n t h - c e n t u r y p r o l e t a r i a n i -
a r e a s which h i s t o r i a n s have s t u d i e d i n t e n s i v e l y w i t h i n d i r e c t i n f e r e n c e s
from o t h e r , more g e n e r a l t r e n d s .
f a s t e r i n t h e e a r l y s i x t e e n t h c e n t u r y , a b i t slower i n t h e e a r l y seven-
-
t e e n t h , b u t g e n e r a l l y f l u c t u a t i n g around a q u a r t e r of one p e r c e n t p e r y e a r .
r e s u l t from t h e c o l l a t i o n of r e p o r t e d f i g u r e s f o r i n d i v i d u a l p l a c e s
a s i t i s on t h e f i r s t . I f t h e f i g u r e s a r e c o r r e c t , Europe de-urbanized
t h e population i n l a r g e c i t i e s . I t i s p o s s i b l e t h a t t h e normal n a t u r a l
d e c r e a s e of c i t i e s grew l a r g e r a s s a n i t a t i o n , n u t r i t i o n and h e a l t h c a r e
d e c l i n e d , t h a t t h e normal n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e of r u r a l a r e a s i n c r e a s e d a s
First, Europe's larger cities were unhealthy places, and may well have
gotten unhealthier as they grew. Second, the food supply of large cities
growth may well have overrun the general capacity of European agriculture
that particular cities and their immediate hinterlands could produce enough
directly with our inquiry into the origins of the proletariat. Two kinds
of employment were growing rapidly in the Europe of 1600 to 1800; they were
surely growing more rapidly in small towns and rural areas than in.big
cities. One was wage-labor in agriculture. The other was cottage industry
nition; it was the principal case Marx had in mind. The growth of cottage
industry did not necessarily proletarianize; tha,tdepended on who held
control of the means of production. But in fact the major European forms
teenth and eighteenth centuries, and that the growth of a rural proletariat
wi.th an increase in the total European population from fifty or sixty mil-
lion to around 500 million. That makes a net rise of about 450 million.
. ' . agriculture who supplied the bulk of their own labor requirements and
By 1900, the great majority of the 500 million Europeans were wage-
workers and their households. Now, setting limits on all these speculative
numbers is itself an important task for theory and research. Since at this
account for. ' (It would also, incidentally, give us a net increase of some-
rhere
numbers, we must ask when and how the increase occurred.
The timing of total population growth sets important limits on the
rose from under 200 million to around 500 million during the nineteenth
- century, a large part of the net increase in the proletariat must also
areas as England, Poland and Spain, it is quite possible that by 1800 some-
thing like 100 million Europeans were already proletarians and their
'.togive priority to farms and villages. From the nineteenth century on-
(millions of persons)
1500 1800 1900
non-proletarians: peasants,
artisans, landlords, officials, etc. 30 100 200
who owned an acre of land, or so-called artisans who had nothing but a
Reclassification
' I
vagaries.. They produce a variety of non-agricultural goods and services,
seek in general to maintain all their offspring on the land. With natural
cultivation of the available land. The result is then that per captia in-
chase goods and services they cannot produce profitably. They accumulate
capital and reinvest it in land and equipment. Such children as they can-
not profitably employ on the land they place in other forms of enterprise.
Over the long run, their p.er capita income tends to rise. The specialists
The two models identify two quite different exits from the peasantry.
capitalizes. The peasant strategy leads to wage labor for two reasons:
cmtrol over the land and over other means of production. English enclo-
b
the context for proletarianization where the landlord tolerated it, but
dairy farming produced a later, slower and more subtle form of proletarian-
ization where the landlord would not tolerate manufacturing. In the Flan-
coast moved into agricultural wage labor, while those of the interior
moved into a mixture of agriculture and textile industry, and shifted their
for their wares and as entrepreneurs assumed control over the means of
Silesia and the Rhineland (Kisch 1959, 1965, 19'68). In both places the
growth of rural textile production undercut the urban craft guilds. But
small number of chartered merchants worked with large landlords who were
In the Rhineland proletarianization was likewise the main trend, but a '
Kisch does not give us the details of labor force recruitment, lifetime
tion was the main component of the proletariat's growth. Natural increase
and migtatianmrPst have been important in both Silesia and the Rhineland.
Natural Increase
The proletariat grows through natural increase when, in any given period,
more proletarians are born than die. Perhaps we should distcnguish between
fragments into pieces too small to support the heirs, we may debate how
much of chat family's move into the proletariat is due to natural increase.
The same is true of the "extra" child of a peasant family who.spends life
a s a s e r v a n t o r day-laborer. Yet a t l e a s t some of t h e r e s u l t i , n g expansion
of t h e p r o l e t a r i a t i s a t t r i b u t a b l e t o n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e . .
ignored. It is t h e n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e of f u l l - f l e d g e d p r o l e t a r i a n s . I f , on
r e l a t i v e growth of t h e p r o l e t a r i a t w i t h o u t any s k i d d i n g of p e a s a n t s o r
d i f f e r e n t i a l n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e was t h e p r i n c i p a l component i n t h e r e l a t i v e
s u s p e c t t h a t t h e p r i n c i p a l component w a s n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e r e s u l t i n g from
p r e c i s e l y y e t , I propose t h e f o l l o w i n g h y p o t h e s i s : on t h e average, p r o l e t a r -
. .
, . . iansi?responded t o economic expansion w i t h g r e a t e r d e c l i n e s i n m o r t a l i t y and
g r e a t e r i n c r e a s e s i n f e r t i l i t y t h a n t h e n o n - p r o l e t a r i a n p o p u l a t i o n , and
responded t o economic c o n t r a c t i o n w i t h g r e a t e r i n c r e a s e s i n m o r t a l i t y b u t
ho greater d e c l i n e s i n f e r t i l i t y t h a n t h e n o n - p r o l e t a r i a n ; t h e consequence
t h a t it did.
n a t u r a l i n c r e a s e of p a r i s h e s w i t h r u r a l i n d u s t r y d u r i n g t h e y e a r s from 1670
of Bohemia and Rudolf Braun's portrayal of the Zurich Uplands all bring out
growing regions of rural industry. In his fairly direct attack on the prob-
Bottesford.
rapid population growth -- too many people for the available land. But
tion.
How and why would the natural increase of proletarians tend to exceed
holds control their own means of production, the chief opportunities for
who could remain home into adulthood, and especially into marriage and
adult was to marry in. Persons who entered as servants, apprentices, day-
l a b o r e r s and t h e l i k e o r d i n a r i l y a c q u i r e d no c o n t r o l over t h e household
a d u l t p o s i t i o n s t h u s depended on t h e r a t e a t which s e n i o r p o s i t i o n s i n
t i v a t i o n a l s o provided new a d u 1 t . o p p o r t u n i t i e s .
Under t h e s e c i r c u m s t a n c e s , c o u p l e s adapted b o t h t h e i r m a r r i a g e r a t e
and t h e i r f e r t i l i t y t o t h e p r o b a b l e a v a i l a b i l i t y of a d u l t p o s i t i o n s and t o
t h e n i n e t e e n t h c e n t u r y i s c o n t r o v e r s i a l i n t h e p r e s e n t s t a t e . o f o u r knowledge.
<
:' ,
.
.: Furthermore, t h e main r e l a t i o n s h i p s a r e h a r d t o d i s e n t a n g l e e m p i r i c a l l y
i n n u t r i t i o n b o o s t e d f e r t i l i t y and d e p r e s s e d m o r t a l i t y s i m u l t a n e o u s l y
t h a t people a d j u s t e d m a r r i a g e and f e r t i l i t y t o t h e a v a i l a b i l i t y of a d u l t
- f e r t i l i t y c o n t r o l s h o r t of t h e s e l f - c o n s c i o u s e f f i c a c y of t w e n t i e t h - c e n t u r y
contraception.
P r o l e t a r i a n s f a c e d a d i f f e r e n t s e t of circumstances. To t h e e x t e n t
in the many variants of domestic industry, the standard labor unit was
several spinners and tenders (see Tilly and Scott 1977). To work in these
children began bringing in income at'an early age and the further fact that
income peaked early in life and then declined with enfeebling age increased
Net Migration
t,
rather different ways: as a crude component of growth, and as a process af-
was negative: the continent shipped out many more migrants than it took in,
and the bulk of the out-migrants were proletarian. Before 1750 the net out-
flows were small: colonists to the Americas, Slavs into continental Asia,
trickles of settlers into other parts.of the world. With the accelerating
up as well. A plausible estimate for the period from 1800 to World War I
fore 1900, those out-migrants came disproportionately from the British Isles.
Perche (Charbonneau 1970). The roughly 300 migrants from Tourouvre and
vicinity and their numerous descendants played a major part in the settle-
ment of Quebec. Labor recruiters intervened into a local but very active
.,. , . . in the vicinity of two million people. That small country sent almost
.. .
300 thousand migrants to North America between 1840 and 1914. The bulk
ideal candidates for emigration seem to have been young people who had
already made the move from farms and villages to a nearby, slow-moving
!J
American opportunities flowing back to Denmark, and who helped the migrants
find the passage money, j.obs and housing. The chains also made it easier
for those who disliked America to return home. But their main effect
been the accumulating evidence of high mobility levels before the period
(e.g. Bukatzsch 1951, Cornwall 1967, Gaunt 1976, Hammer 1976, Hollingsworth
1971, Patten 1973, Poussou 1974, Sabean 1971). Americans of the last
average year about 20% of the population have changed residence -- and
, a great mariy of them have moved within the same community. Comparable.
industrialization.
ant part in rural and small-town life, occupying a significant part of the
greatest incentive to follow the trail of better wages into a new labor
quintessential proletarians.
full artisan or peasant and the full proletarian -- the Alpine peasant
the communities in which they had rights and solidarity, and placed them
in communities in which they had neither. If the choice had been sharper
and more dramatic in either regard, one might suppose that the proletar-
ians would have resisted their fate with greater determination and effec-
tiveness. When the choice was sharp and the proletarianizing populations
still embedded in their communities, they did often fight back. They
fought by attacking others who were seizing control of the means of pro-
duction, and they fought by adopting family strategies which limited the
all the graceful refinements which make the problem interesting. For
deal. Surely the absolute number of peasants, artisans, and other non-
possible that at first they increased more rapidly than the population
out for attention. At a minimum we need contrasts among the legal enserf-
components. .It must specify their interplay. All this requires a more
account of the whole process, We have not, by any means, completed that
The modification fits nicely with that brand of Marxian analysis, typi-
cussed at all. It tells us we need not make some drastic choice between
1q quantitative" and "qualitative" analyses, between numbers and people,
it leads right back to honest history, history rooted in real times and
places.
A red flag, you might say. The idea of Karl Marx as the master historical
demographer containssomet;h~~ngto
offend historians of almost every
the flag of whole cloth. On the contrary: it is athingof gaps and patches.
The available sociology traces a broad pattern across the banner's riotous
design.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
REFERENCES
Lutz Berkner
Karlheinz Blaschke
C.J. Bakatzsch
J .D. Chambers
A.V. Chayanov
Louis Chevalier
Carlo Cipolla
Alain Corbin
Julian Cornwall
John Durand
Richard A. Easterlin
M.W. Flinn
John Foster
David Gaunt
.
H. J Habakkuk
Carl Hammer
-.
1976 "The o obi lit^ of Skilled Labour in Late Medieval England. Some
Oxford Evidence, Vierteljahrschrift fir Sozial- and Wirtschafts-
geschichte, 63: 194-210.
Michael Hanagan
T.H. Hollingsworth
Kristian Hvidt
V.K. Iatsounski
1971 "Le r81e des migrations et : d l'accroissement nature1 dans la '
Arthur E. Imhof
~erbertKisch
1968 "Prussian Mercantilism and the Rise of the Krefeld Silk Industry.
Variations Upon-an Eighteenth-Century Theme," Transactions of the
American Philosophical Society, n.s., 58, Part 7.
Rrnbst ~lzka
J.T. Krause
William Langer
Peter Laslett
Ronald Lee
Giovanni Levi
David Levine
Thomas McKeown
Franklin F. Mendels
Marc Merlove
1973 The Rise of the Western World. A New Economic History. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Bo Ohngren
John Patten
Luciano Pellicani
Diedrich Sa.alfeld
David Sabean
Lawrence Schofer
Lennart Schon
Paul A. Slack
Margaret Spufford
E.P. Thompson
1963 The Making.of the English Working Class. London: Gollancz.
Louise A. Tilly
Michael Vester
1974 The Dutch Rural Economy in the Golden Age, 1500-1700. New Haven,
Yale University Press.
Immanuel Wallerstein
E.A. Wrigley
1977 "Fertility Strategy . for the Individual and the Group," in Charles
Tilly, ed., Historical-Studiesof Changing Fertility. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, forthcoming.