Unit 1,2&3
Unit 1,2&3
Unit 1,2&3
UNIT 1
ISSUES IN MACROECONOMICS
Macroeconomic seeks to analyze those problems that affect eh economy as a whole; such
problems cannot be adequately studied with reference to an individual product, firm or
industry. For example, the effect of introduction of new technology (say computers) is not
limited to a single product or industry also, it will affect the structure of economic activity in
the economy as a whole; it will affect the rate of economic growth; it will affect the level of
employment (or unemployment); it will affect the general price level; it will affect the country’s
balance of payments, etc. All those problems and issues that affect the economy as a whole are
studied in macroeconomics.
Real Flow
Real flows depict the way that commodities and products & services are produced and
consumed in the economy.
Money Flow
Money flows depict the way that money and credit circulate in the economy as
income turns into savings and investment and back again
Example
Suppose a person provides 5 acres of land on rent to a company, for which he receives ₹
1,00,000 every month as rent. It indicates a money flow of ₹ 1,00,000 as factor income, from
the company to the person, and at the same time there is a flow of factor of production (land)
of the equal amount from the person to the company, indicating the real flow. So, we can say
that the situation prevails in the whole economy.
From slide 36 its consumer price index
Leading Indicators
Leading indicators are a heads-up for economists and investors who hope to anticipate trends.
Bond yields are thought to be a good leading indicator of the stock market because bond traders
anticipate and speculate about trends in the economy. However, they are still indicators, and
are not always correct.
New housing starts also are a leading indicator. If housing starts rise, it means builders are
optimistic about the demand in the near future for newly constructed homes. If housing starts
fall, builders are getting cautious. That's a sign that home sales are slowing, or at least that
builders fear they soon will.
The overall money supply, which is tracked by the federal government, is a more complex
leading indicator. Generally, if there is plenty of money out there, in consumers' pockets, in
bank accounts, and in bank vaults ready to be invested in business expansion, it's a signal that
the economy will be strong.
for example; the percentage of people wearing hard hats on a building site is a leading safety
indicator. A lagging indicator is an output measurement, for example; the number of accidents
on a building site is a lagging safety indicator. The difference between the two is a leading
indicator can influence change and a lagging indicator can only record what has happened.
Lagging Indicators
Lagging indicators can only be known after the event, but that doesn't make them useless. They
can clarify and confirm a pattern that is occurring over time. The unemployment rate is one of
the most reliable lagging indicators. If the unemployment rate rose last month and the month
before, it indicates that the overall economy has been doing poorly and may well continue to
do poorly.
The Consumer Price Index (CPI), which measures changes in the inflation rate, is another
closely watched lagging indicator. There are few events that cause more economic ripple
effects than price increases. Both the overall number and prices in key industries like fuel or
medical costs are of interest.
If we want to know how many sales have been made this month, we simply count them. If we
want to know how many accidents have occurred on the factory floor, we consult the accident
log. These are lag indicators. They are an after-the-event measurement, essential for charting
progress but useless when attempting to influence the future.
COINCIDENT INDICATORS
Coincident indicators are analyzed and used as they occur. These are key numbers that have a
substantial impact on the overall economy.
Personal income is a coincident indicator of economic health. Higher personal income numbers
coincide with a stronger economy. Lower personal income numbers mean the economy is
struggling. The gross domestic product (GDP) of an economy is also a coincident indicator.
Coincident indicators define the business cycles of the economy. This means that they are the
primary indicators that are used to define whether the economy is in a recession or expansion
in a given quarter, a process known as business cycle dating.
Coincident indicators do not typically reflect present economic conditions but report on data
from the recent past. Different coincident indicators may have a long or short lag time between
the reported indicator and the real underlying phenomenon that the indicator is meant to
measure. These lags occur because it takes time to collect, tabulate and report the data, and can
range from anywhere between one day and up to one year (for final or revised data).
For example, if an upsurge in solar panel manufacturing is reported, it may show the effect
that incentive programs for alternative energy sources are having. Payroll data can show the
kind of recent demand companies have had for employees and their levels of productivity. If
salaries have increased from a comparable period, it may indicate that companies are lately
engaging in more business, seeing increased revenue, and can afford to pay higher salaries to
attract skilled workers.
Referring to current payroll data as a coincident indicator can also show the capacity that
employees have to spend money back into the economy. Increases in salary could allow
for flexible expenses to increase, as well as create the potential for luxury expenditures. This
would show that the economy has been robustly productive recently and which segments of it
are expressing the most strength and stability.
Difference between the indicators
Leading indicators are considered to point toward future events.
Lagging indicators are seen as confirming a pattern that is in progress.
Coincident indicators occur in real-time and clarify the state of the economy.
IIP
Index of Industrial Production (IIP) is an index that shows the performance of different
industrial sectors of the Indian economy.
The IIP is estimated and published on a monthly basis by the Central Statistical Organisation
(CSO). As an all-India index, it gives general level of industrial activity in the economy.
According to the CSO. “It is a composite indicator that measures the short-term changes in the
volume of production of a basket of industrial products during a given period with respect to
that in a chosen base period.”
Importance of Index of Industrial Production
The IIP is used by public agencies including the Government agencies/ departments including
that in the Ministry of Finance, the Reserve Bank of India etc. for policy purposes. The all-
India IIP data is used for estimation of Gross Value Added of Manufacturing sector on quarterly
basis.
Similarly, the data is also used extensively by analysts, financial intermediaries and private
companies for various purposes.
Data collection for IIP
The IIP is constructed by the CSO using secondary data. Data is sourced from 14 source
agencies in various Ministries/Departments. But the major source of data for IIP is the
Department of Industrial Policy and Promotion that supplies data for 322 out of 407 item
groups with a weight of 47.54% in overall IIP.
IIP is released every month in the form of Quick Estimates with a time-lag of 6 weeks as per
the norms of IMF.
Components of IIP
The IIP is basically divided into three sectors though a use-based classification is also provided
by the CSO.
The UNSD recommends inclusion of Mining & Quarrying; Manufacturing; Electricity, Gas
steam and Air-conditioning supply; as well as Water supply, Sewerage, Waste management
and Remediation activities in IIP. But due to constraints of the data availability on monthly
basis, the modified IIP has been limited to Mining, Manufacturing and Electricity sectors only.
Following are the three sectors of the IIP as per the revision based on 2011-12 series.
(i) Mining,
(ii) Manufacturing and
(iii) Electricity
Besides the main classification of the index into three sectors ie., mining, manufacturing and
electricity sectors, the IIP is also prepared based on Use based classification. Here, the
industries are divided into six use-based sectors:
Primary Goods,
Capital Goods,
Intermediate Goods,
Infrastructure/ Construction goods,
Consumer durables and
Consumer nondurables.
Core industries in the IIPThe Eight Core Industries comprise 40.27 % of the weight of items
included in the Index of Industrial Production (IIP). These industries are: Coal, Crude Oil,
Natural Gas, Refinery Products, Fertilizers, Steel, Cement and Electricity.
MANUAL ON COMPILATION OF
INDEX NUMBER OF WHOLESALE PRICES IN INDIA
Agricultural commodities: In practice, there are three types of wholesale markets viz.,
primary, secondary and terminal in the agricultural sector. The price movements and price
levels in all three vary. Price movement in the terminal market may tend to converge toward
the retail prices Option o collect the wholesale prices for these three different stages of
wholesale transactions exists for agricultural commodities though the primary market is
prepared.
Ministry of Agriculture has defined wholesale price as the rate at which relatively large
transaction of purchase, usually for further sale, is effected. Various state agencies concerned
with the collection of wholesale prices of agricultural commodities are following the concept
of Ministry of Agriculture. However, there are certain variation with regard to inclusion or
exclusion of incidental charges, duties and taxes, For e.g., in Andhra Pradesh, the wholesale
prices include incidental charges such as weighment charges, cost of bags and sales tax. In
Gujarat, the wholesale prices are inclusive of packing charges and taxes. In Punjab and Tamil
Nadu. the wholesale prices are inclusive of incidentals. In Haryana, the wholesale prices for
agriculture commodities exclude taxes but include arat, weighment and the lorry charges,
whereas, non-agricultural products include sales tax, etc.
Non-agricultural commodities: For non-agricultural commodities, which are predominantly
manufacturing items, the problem arises, as there are no established sources in markets. This
is true of mining and fuel items also. The issue of ex-factory vis-à-vis wholesale prices for non-
agriculture items have been discussed by the successive Working Groups set up for the revision
of WPI and all have reached the conclusion that in practice, it is not feasible to collect wholesale
prices for most of the manufacturing items It has also been observed that the margin of
wholesalers in case of non-agricultural commodities remains unchanged for over a long period
of time. As a result, it is felt that the trends in the index compiled on the basis of ex-factory
prices would not be much different from the index if compiled on the basis of wholesale prices
if it were feasible to get these prices The last Working Group has recommended collecting
wholesale prices from the markets as far as possible, because the economy is moving towards
globalisation and open trade with inputs increasing in the commodities set
The wholesale price as defined for WPI: The concept of wholesale price adopted in practice
represent the quoted price of bulk transaction generally at primary stage. The price pertaining
to bulk transaction of agricultural commodities may be farm harvest prices, or prices at the
village mandi market of the Agricultural Marketing Produce Committeel procurement prices,
support prices. For manufactured goods the wholesale prices are administered prices, ex-
factory gate/ex-mill, ex-mine level. Ex-factory prices exclude rebate if any, other taxes and
levies are excluded though excise duty is currently included.
Wholesale price and producer price: The wholesale price as defined above differs from
producer (output) prices as the latter excludes all kind of taxes and transport charges. In 1993
SNA, Producer(output) price is defined as the amount receivable by the producer from the
purchaser for a unit of a good or service produced as output minus VAT or similar deductible
tax, invoiced to the purchaser. It excludes any transport charges invoiced separately. It excludes
any transport charges invoiced separately by the producer. However, the producer (input)
prices include retail or wholesale margins
2) Choice of Base
Year The well known criteria for the selection of base year are (i) a normal year ie. a year in
which there are no abnormalities in the level of production, trade and in the price level and
price variations, (ii) a year for which reliable production price and other required data are
available and (iii) a year asrecent possible and comparable with other data series at national
and state level. The National Statistical Commission has recommended that base year should
be revised every five year and not later than ten years.
3) Selection of Items, Varieties/ Grades, Markets:
To ensure that the items in the index basket are as best representatives as possible, efforts are
made to include all the important items transacted in the economy during the base year. The
importance of an item in the free market will depend on its traded value during the base year.
At wholesale level, bulk transactions of goods and services need to be captured. As the services
are not covered so far, the WPI basket mainly consists of items from goods sector, in the
absence of single source of data on traded value, the selection procedures followed for
agricultural commodities and non-agricultural commodities have also been different.
Agricultural commodities: As there is a little scope of emergence of new commodities in the
agriculture, the selection of new items in the basket is done on the basis of increased importance
in wholesale markets, Varieties, which have declined in importance, need to be dropped in the
revised series. Final inclusion or exclusion of an item in the basket is based on the process of
consultation with the various departments. The exercise of adding /deleting commodities,
specifications and markets is completed once the consultation process is over. In the existing
WPI series, items, their specifications and markets have been finalized in consultation of with
the Directorate of E&S (M/O Agriculture), National Horticulture Board, Spices Board, Tea
board, Coffee Board and Rubber Board, Silk Board, Directorate Of Tobacco, Cotton
Corporation of India etc.
Mining Items: For deciding on the inclusion and exclusion of mineral items, their grades,
market centers etc. suggestions of Indian Bureau of Mines are taken into account.
Specifications of coal, coke and lignite have been decided in consultation with the Department
of Coal. Likewise for selection of petroleum products the Ministry of Petroleum is consulted
and for electricity suggestions are taken from Central Electricity Authority.
Manufactured Products: Selection of items from manufacturing sector, as a whole is the most
tedious and time taking process. To ensure complete coverage, selected items have to represent
not only the organized manufacturing sector but also vast informal sector
1. Organized Manufacturing Sector Regular time series data on value of production are
available through Annual Survey of Industries covering factory sector. The criterion for
selection of items has been based on the cut off traded value of a product during the
base year. The traded value of a product is the sum total value of output as per ASI base
year+ Excise duty+ Imports during base year- Exports during the base year. WPI 1993-
94 adopted a cut off traded value of Rs. 120cr. All possible efforts are made to establish
a proper concordance between the NIC classification adopted in ASI and ITC (HS)
classification for imports and exports quantum. The problem of concordance arises in
case of textile items and for this segment, the selection of items has been done with the
help of Office of the Textile commissioner. Some of the items may not feature in the
final basket even though the traded value is above the cut off point. This may be due to
poor specifications or non-availability of regular deta source for continuous pricing
2. Unregistered/unorganized manufacturing sector: Units falling in this sector add
substantial portion to the total manufacturing production in the economy. Unorganized
manufacturing sector covers traditional sectors like handlooms, sericulture, coir, khadi
and village industries and modem segments like SSI and power looms. Further the
small-scale sector encompasses both organized and unorganized segments of the
manufacturing sector. But for informal sector, all encompassing time series data on
value of production are not available. In the past, Working groups have made efforts to
pool value of production data from disparate sources like results of surveys on Own
Account Enterprise (OAE),Directory Manufacturing Establishment (DME) and Non-
Directory Manufacturing Establishment (NDME), Economic Census and its follow up
surveys and Census of Registered SSI units. The last Working group could not use these
data sources mainly because it found the data available either farther from the chosen
base year or were incompatible. However, some items from silk coir, power looms and
handlooms based were included on the suggestions of agencies responsible for these
segments.
The selection of specification/ grade variety in respect of manufactured products as also
the selection of sources for supplying regular price data is done with help of production
data. Selection of data sources is done on subjective sampling basis. For each item, a
list of 10 major manufacturers/ producers is prepared and efforts are made to seek
willing cooperation from the top five manufacturers for regular supply of weekly
wholesale price quotations. Data collection is done on conditions of confidentiality. At
least five price quotations in respect of representative grades are included in the index.
In case there are less then five manufacturers of an item, then all the units are raped in
to furnish the price date
4) Derivation of Weighting Diagram:
Weights used in the WPI are value weights not quantity weights as its difficult to assign
quantity weights. Distribution of the appropriate weight to each of the item is most important
exercise for reliable index. Unlike consumer price indices, where weights are derived on the
basis of results of Expenditure Surveys, several sources of data are used for derivation of
weights for WPI
Because of non-availability of updated Supply and Use Table (SUT), the approach, finding
favour with the successive Working groups, is based on top down stratified compartmentalized
system. Under this approach, weights are first assigned at Major group level from outside with
due account made for exclusion of services from the total value of transactions in the economy.
This method for weighting diagram represents more accurately structural changes at higher
level of aggregation. Further, compartment system also ensures that wherever data for a more
recent year are available they can be used, while in other compartments data from more distant
year can be achieved. This has also made it possible to use different sets of data sources for
agricultural and manufacturing items.
Weights of Agriculture commodities: For building of the weights of agricultural
commodities, the data on sale of agricultural commodities is not available as there is large
number of markets. Therefore, to arrive at the approximate traded value of agricultural
commodities; an indirect method of arriving such estimates is used. These weights are based
on the Marketed value (MV) arrived at by multiplying Marketed Surplus Ratio (MSR) to the
estimates of Value Of Production (VOP) of agricultural commodities. The estimates of VOP
are based on the estimates of quantity of production, as brought out by the Directorate of
Economics and Statistics(DES), and an average price of a commodity
The ratio of quantity marketed to quantity produced gives the MSR.
The estimates of MSRS are based on the results of Comprehensive Scheme on Cost of
Cultivation of DES and other sources. The Directorate of Marketing and Inspection, MO
Agricultural, is also responsible to generate MSRs
In practice MSRS are worked out on the basis of production value of three years average
production to remove the bias on account of fluctuation in individual commodity and over all
production. No estimates of MSRS are available in the case of new items of fruits, vegetables
and flowers, and these are finalized separately by the working group, based on the related crops.
MSRs of flowers and meat items are kept 100 considering that production of these is mainly
for market sale
Manufactured items: As discussed above, the traded value of manufactured products ie, total
production excise duty- imports - exports value for the year are worked out from various
sources. Final weights of each item is based on its traded value plus pro rata imputed traded
value of items which need to be excluded from the basket due to various reasons.
In the current series traded value of items falling under 'Other manufacturing' have been
imputed amongst other items in the remaining sub-groups of 'Manufactured products' as there
was only one item featuring above the cut-off mark. Retaining it would have led to extreme
fluctuations. Similarly weight of crude petroleum was distributed pro rata amongst fuel items,
as procuring its wholesale prices was not possible.
5) Collection of Prices;
In WPI pricing methodology used is specification pricing. Under this, in consultation with the
identified source agencies, precise specifications of all items in the basket are defined for repeat
pricing every week. All characteristics like make, model, features along with the unit of sale,
type of packaging, if applicable, etc are recorded and printed in the price collection schedule.
At the time of scrutiny of price data all these are kept in mind. This pricing to constant quality
technique is the cornerstone of Laspeyres formula. In case of changes in quality and
specifications, due adjustments are made as per the standard procedures.
The collection of base prices is done concurrently while the work on finalisation of index basket
is on. Therefore, price collection is normally done for larger number of items pending
finalisation. Once the basket is ready, current prices are collected only as per the final basket
from the designated sources. Weekly prices need to be collected for pre-determined day of the
week. For the current senes prices are quoted on the basis of the prevailing prices of every
Friday. Agricultural wholesale prices are for bulk transactions and include transport cost. Non-
agricultural prices are ex-mine or ex-factory inclusive of excise duty but exclusive of rebate if
any.
6) Treatment of prices collected from open market & administered prices:
There are some items which constitute part of index baskets but the prices for these items are
either totally administered by the Government or are under dual pricing policy The issue of
using administered prices for index compilation is resolved by taking into account appropriate
ratio between the levy and non-levy portions. Where these ratios are not available, the issues
can be resolved through taking the appropriate number of price quotations of the administered
prices and the open market prices after periodic review:
Due to variation in quality and different price movements of the commodities belonging to
unorganized sector, separate quotations from organized and unorganized units have to be taken
and merged based on the turnover value of both the sectors at item level. For pricing from
unorganized sector, adequate number of price quotations has to be drawn out of the list of units
by criteria of share of production as far as possible
7) Classification structure
The Working Groups over the period have been suggesting to bring the classification of various
items under different groups and sub-groups as per the latest revised National Industrial
Classification (NIC) which in turn is comparable to International Standard Industrial
Classification (ISIC). The classification based on NIC renders the WPI data amenable to
comparison with the Index of Industrial Production (IP) and National Income data.
The grouping and classification of WPI is also useful for in depth analysis as separate inflation
rates can be worked out for groups with items whose prices are given to extreme fluctuations,
affected by international prices or have administered prices. Apart from the headline inflation
based on WPI, core inflation, manufactured products inflation, primary articles inflation etc.
can be easily computed. The classification structures adopted in the WPI (1993-94) series is as
below:
The classification of manufactured products' is similar to the classification adopted in the index
of Industrial Production (IP) except that the sub group of Other Manufacturing has not been
retained and its traded value has been imputed in to remaining sub-groups
8) Methodology of Index Calculation
Actual index compilation is done in stages, though due to computerization now, the machines
do all complex calculations. In the first stage, once the price data are scrutinized, price relative
for each price quote is calculated Price relative is calculated as the ratio of the current price to
the base price multiplied by 100 ie. (P₁/P0)X100. Assigning weights at quotations level is
difficult, as it needs detailed data
In the next stage, commodity item level index is arrived at as the simple arithmetic average of
the price relatives of all the varieties (each quote] included under that commodity. An average
of price ratio relative is used under implicit assumption that each price quotation collected for
an item/commodity index compilation has equal importance ie the shares of production value
is equal Where as if the ratio of average prices is adopted instead, the implicit assumption
would be that importance of each price quotation depends on its price level in the base period
and all the quantities produced are equal. Since quantities produced at unit level are not equal
the average of price relatives method is preferred to arrive at tem level index in WPI
Next the indices for the sub groups/groups/ major groups are compiled and the aggregation
method is based on Laspeyres formula as below:
The e weights are value weights. Aggregation is first done at sub-group and group level. All
commodities index is compiled by aggragating Major group indices
9) Handling of the Seasonal Commodities
There are number of agriculture items, especially some fruits and vegetables, which are of
seasonal nature. When a particular seasonal item items on pro rata basis with in the sub-group
of vegetables or fruits. The underlying assumption is that if the items remained available, the
prices of these items would have moved in the same proportion as the prices of the other items
in the sub-group, which did remain available. This is equivalent to giving a greater weight to
the remaining items. The seasonality problem can be sorted by adopting other mathods like, i)
prices of unavailable disappears from the market and its prices are not available because of its
being out of season, the weights of such item is imputed amongst the other tems can also be
extrapolated forward from the period of availability or ii) if such seasonal Item has insignificant
weight it can be taken permanently from the basket etc.
10) Procedure for Estimation for Non-response and Data Substitution
As the series grow older, many of the items in the basket tend to disappear from the market, or
item specification may change or the source agency may no longer manufacture the item
a. If the source agency stops manufacturing and the item is still available in the market,
then efforts are made to locate and fix another representative source producing item
with matching specification.
b. In case no suitable substitute is available, the weight of the item is imputed to similar
other item or among other items of the sub-group/group. The criterion for imputation
is that the price movement of the outgoing item and the item to which weight is
imputed similar. Imputation of weight is not a long-term solution and ultimately
replacement has to be effected
c. .In case item with different specifications need to be taken in the basket as a substitute
then the new price and old price is linked by splicing
Substitution and replacement: First of all it should be ensured that the prices of both the price
quotations, outgoing quotation (old price) and incoming quotation (new price) are collected
concurrently for some time and respective price movements observed for any extreme variation
Splicing is done by working out a ratio (linking coefficient) of concurrent price quotations and
multipled by the base price as below:
Price relatives and worked out by dividing the current price with the updated base price.
Splicing can be done other way round, wherein, linking coefficient can be worked out by
dividing old price (outgoing quote) with the new price (incoming quote) and multiplied by the
current price
In WPI the substitution is effected from the date final indices are compiled. The effective date
and the splicing ratio are documented properly.
11) Provisional Vs Final:
Primary objective of WPI is to bring out an estimate of headline inflation for the economy.
Because of late receipt of price data part of the price data cannot be utlized as the WPI is
released on weekly basis. The weekly indices are compiled after a short gap of two weeks only
as compared to other Indices, indices, which are compiled on monthly basis. The WPI are,
therefore released provisionally and final revised indices, incorporating all possible quotations,
are released after a gap of two months.
12) Data collection mechanism
At present data collection for WPI is solely based on voluntary basis, Price data pertaining to
'Primary articles and Fuel & petroleum products are mainly collected through administrative
Ministries/Departments PSUs and state government Departments For Manufactured products,
apart from some government sources, data collection is done through Chambers of Commerce.
Trade Associations, Business Houses and leading Manufacturing Units
13) Linking Factor:
In order to maintain continuity, the time series data on wholesale price index, it is important to
provide inking factor so that new series when released may be compared with the outgoing
one. It provides a basis for determination of cost escalation and wage settlement and secondly,
generates a lang time series data for analytical purposes
There are three commonly used methods for linking new series with old one ie (1) arithmetic
conversion method (ii) ratio method and (iii) regression method. In arithmetic linking method
the relationship between the indices in the old series (y) and those in the new series (X) is
assumed to be linear Le y = cx, where c is the conversion factor given by
The linking factor for the WPI, which has been published officially, has been based on
arithmetic conversion method. The linking factor is worked out only at aggregate level for all
commodities. Because of the vast changes in the commodity baskets, it has not been found
feasible to compile linking factor at group/ sub-group level. Even though for analytical purpose,
it would be very useful to have linking factor at desegregated level.
14) Approval and Release of revised Series
As per the established practice, a Working Group is set up for revision of existing WPI series
with the approval of the Minister in-charge of the Department of Industrial Policy & Promotion.
Detailed deliberations on all aspects including methodological issues are held first at the level
of sub groups and thereafter in the Working Group. The views expressed at both the levels and
recommendations based thereon are incorporated in the report of the Working Group
The Report of the Working Group is first placed before the Technical Advisory Committee on
Statistics of Prices & Cost of Living (TAC on SPCL) in Central Statistical Organisation (CSO)
and thereafter before the Committee of Secretaries (COS). It is only after acceptance of the
report by the TAC on SPCL and its subsequent approval and appropriate direction of the COS:
the Office of the Economic Adviser through press release introduces the revised series of WPI
HDI
What is the Human Development Index (HDI)?
The HDI serves as a frame of reference for both social and economic development. It is a
summary measure for monitoring long-term progress in a country’s average level of human
development in three basic dimensions: a long and healthy life, access to knowledge and a
decent standard of living. The HDI was introduced in 1990 to emphasize that people and their
capabilities should be the ultimate criteria for assessing the development of a country, not just
economic growth.
History of the human development concept
For decades, the economic growth paradigm dominated the national development discourse.
However, in the 1980s unemployment levels escalated; and access to social services
deteriorated in many countries including some industrialised countries while at the same time,
economic production was expanding. In other words, high rates of economic growth did not
automatically translate into improved human well-being. During the same period, some
countries were registering improvement in human well-being with modest economic growth.
These raised questions around the nature, distribution and quality of economic growth. It
became clear that economic growth alone is not an adequate yardstick for a country’s level of
development. The need for a conceptual shift and alternative policy options that create a
balance between economic growth and protection of the interest of poor and marginalised
members of society became imperative. The HDI, which was introduced in the first Human
Development Report published in 1990, was a response to this demand. The idea of a composite
index that measures socio-economic progress was conceived by Mahbub ul Haq arenowned
economist, whose vision was to come up with one measure which is as crude as the GDP, but
“not as blind to social aspects of human lives as the GNP is
Importance of Human Development Index
It is necessary to determine social measures of development for calculating the overall
development of a nation. Human Development Index measures the socio economic factors and
therefore, is considered very effective in measuring the performance of a country in terms of
these factors.
HDI acts as a tool in evaluating the socio-economic status of nations around the world every
year and as such acts as a reliable indicator of the development of the nations.
How Is the HDI Measured?
The HDI is a summary measurement of basic achievement levels in human development. The
computed HDI of a country is an average of indexes of each of the life aspects that are
examined: knowledge and understanding, a long and healthy life, and an acceptable standard
of living. Each of the four components is normalized to scale between 0 and 1, and then the
geometric mean of the three components is calculated.2
The health aspect of the HDI is measured by the life expectancy, as calculated at the time of
birth, in each country, normalized so that this component is equal to 0 when life expectancy is
20 and equal to 1 when life expectancy is 85.2
Education is measured on two levels: the mean years of schooling for residents of a country
and the expected years of schooling that a child has at the average age for starting school. These
are each separately normalized so that 15 mean years of schooling equals one, and 18 years of
expected schooling equals one, and a simple mean of the two is calculated.2
The metric chosen to represent the standard of living is GNI per capita based on purchasing
power parity (PPP), a common metric used to reflect average income. The standard of living is
normalized so that it is equal to 1 when GNI per capita is $75,000 and equal to 0 when GNI
per capita is $100. The final Human Development Index score for each country is calculated
as a geometric mean of the three components by taking the cube root of the product of the
normalized component scores.
Limitations of the HDI
Human Development is a broad concept which cannot be captured in one composite. The HDI
suffers Data availability influences what is captured in the HDI. Other important dimensions
of human development such as political freedom, environmental sustainability and degree of
people’s selfrespect are not currently measured. The HDI also is not designed to assess progress
in human development over a short-term period because some of its component indicators are
not responsive to short-term policy changes. Thus, the index partially measures past
achievements as the components are made up of both stock and flow variables. This is a source
of frustration for many governments
Future Possibilities Since its introduction in 1990, the HDI’s analytical framework,
methodology and data have been subjected to rigorous scrutiny. Some of the major criticisms
have led to major refinements of the methodology and component indicators but limitations
still remain. The measures of human development will depend on availability of social
indicators measuring political freedom and gender disaggregated indicator of wealth and other
economic well-being
UNIT 2
MULTIPLIER PRINCIPLE
The cumulatively reinforcing induced interaction between consumption, production, factor
payments, and income that amplifies autonomous changes in investment, government
spending, exports, taxes, or other shocks to the macroeconomy. The multiplier principle is so
named because relatively small autonomous changes generate relatively larger, or multiple,
induced changes in aggregate production. This principle is commonly represented by a
multiplier, which is a specific number with a value greater than one.
The essence of the multiplier principle is that relatively small changes in autonomous
expenditures or other shocks cause relatively large overall changes in aggregate production and
income. The multiplier principle works because a change in autonomous expenditures triggers
a change in aggregate production, factor payments, and income, which then induces changes
in other expenditures, especially consumption. These induced expenditures then cause further
changes in aggregate production, factor payments, and income, when then induce further
changes in expenditures. The process is cumulative and reinforcing.
The multiplier principle is a direct implication of Keynesian economics. The key to the
multiplier principle is induced expenditures, expenditures that depend on aggregate production
and income, especially induced consumption expenditures. Induced consumption
expenditures, as captured by the marginal propensity to consume, are the cornerstone of
Keynesian economics.
Another Round
The $750 of consumption expenditures remaining in the circular flow generates another round
of aggregate production, factor payments, income, and consumption.
The new exhibit to the right presents the circular flow model as it stands with the $750 billion
of consumption expenditures poised to enter the production markets for the payment of
aggregate production. Click the [Induced Consumption] button to illustrate the results of this
additional round of expenditures.
Circle flow
While the numbers are a bit different, the process is much the same.
First, $750 billion enters into the product markets for the purchase of $1 trillion worth
of consumption goods.
Second, this $750 billion is once again revenue received by the business sector as
payment for the production.
Third, this $750 billion revenue is then used by te business sector as factor payments to
the resources that produce this round of consumption goods.
Fourth, this $750 billion of factor payments becomes additional income of the
household sector.
Fifth, the $750 billion of income received by the household sector is once again divided
between consumption ($563 billion) and saving ($187 billion), based on the marginal
propensity to consume (and save).
With this round, a portion of the $750 billion household sector is leaked out of the circular flow
as saving and a portion remains as consumption expenditures, which will generate another
round of aggregate production, factor payments, income, and then even more consumption
expenditures. And so it goes.
A Bunch of Rounds
The circular flow is likely to experience several additional rounds of aggregate production,
factor payments, income, and consumption expenditures. Each subsequently round, however,
is smaller than the previous round, meaning that the process eventually winds down to infinitely
small values.
But with each round, additional aggregate production is generated. The first round generates
$1 trillion of capital goods production. The second round generates $750 billion of
consumption goods production. The third round adds another $563 billion of consumption
goods production to the total.
The first three rounds has a total of $2.313 trillion, almost 2 1/2 times the initial injection of
investment expenditures. How much higher will it go?
A Bunch of Rounds
The answer is given by the exhibit to the right, which summarizes several rounds of the circular
flow.
The first round generates $1 trillion in production, $750 billion in consumption, and
$250 billion in saving. This round is triggered by the initial $1 trillion investment in
capital.
The second round generates $750 billion in production, $563 billion in consumption,
and $187 billion in saving. This round is triggered by the $750 billion of consumption
from the first round.
The $563 billion of consumption from the second round then generates $563 billion in
production, $422 billion in consumption, and $141 billion in saving in the third round.
The values for production, consumption, and saving are also presented for rounds four
through six. The first six rounds combine for $3,288 billion in production, $2,466
billion in consumption, and $822 billion in saving.
In these first six rounds, the increase in aggregate production of $3,288 billion generates an
identical $3,288 billion of income. This income is divided between consumption and saving
based on the marginal propensity to consume (0.75) and the marginal propensity to save (0.25).
The $2,466 billion in consumption is 75% of the income ($2,466 = $3,288 x 0.75). The $822
billion in saving is 25% of the income ($822 = $3,288 x 0.25).
The totals for remaining rounds of activity beyond round six (seven through infinity)
are also listed in the table. These rounds generate and additional $712 billion in
production, $534 billion in consumption, and $178 billion in saving. Once again the
production (and income) total is divided between consumption and saving based on the
marginal propensities to consume and save.
The grand totals of all rounds are presented at the bottom of the table, which are $4
trillion in production, $3 trillion in consumption, and $1 trillion in saving. As might be
expected the grand total of production (and income) is also divided between
consumption and saving based on the marginal propensities to consume and save.
The overall change in aggregate production ($4 trillion) is a multiple of the initial change in
investment that triggered the process ($1 trillion). In this case the multiple is four times --
aggregate production increases by four times the increase in investment. The change in
aggregate production and income is divided between consumption ($3 trillion) and saving ($1
trillion) based on the marginal propensity to consume (0.75) and marginal propensity to save
(0.25). The overall change in saving ($1 trillion) is exactly the same as the initial change in
investment ($1 trillion). Using other terminology, injections equal leakages.
1 1
m= =
(1 - MPC) MPS
Where MPC is the marginal propensity to consume and MPS is the marginal propensity to
save.
If, for example, the MPC is 0.75 (and the MPS is 0.25), then an autonomous $1 trillion change
in investment expenditures results in a change in aggregate production of $4 trillion.
While the simple expenditures multiplier can be derived from the basic two-sector Keynesian
multiplier, it also works for models with more sectors, as long as consumption is the only
induced expenditure. If, for example, autonomous government purchases change by $1 trillion,
then the change in aggregate production is $4 trillion, the same as with a $1 trillion change in
investment expenditures. Moreover, the same change in aggregate production is realized if
autonomous exports or consumption expenditures change by $1 trillion.
Paradox of Thrift
The Paradox of Thrift is the theory that increased savings in the short term can reduce savings,
or rather the ability to save, in the long term. The Paradox of Thrift arises out of the Keynesian
notion of an aggregate demand-driven economy.
An increase in the rate of saving reduces consumption in the economy which, in turn, reduces
total output (via Keynesian consumption). According to British economist John Maynard
Keynes, when people save during a recession, the level of consumer spending decreases, which
eventually slows down economic growth.
Line I shows the relationship between investment spending and Gross Domestic Product
(GDP). Line S shows the correlation between savings and GDP. When people wish to increase
savings from S to S1, it leads to a fall in real investment (OH to OT) and income (OY to OY1).
Criticisms of the Paradox of Thrift
The Paradox of Thrift, while practical in its reasoning, attracted numerous criticisms from neo-
classical economists. The neo-classical economists argue that a consumer saving is viewed by
the market as a signal of supply-side inefficiency. A consumer saving sends the signal that the
consumer DOES NOT WANT to consume any of the goods in the market at the prevailing
market price.
Therefore, producers should either lower the price or change the goods and services being
produced. Thus, the action of not consuming does not reduce future output but merely forces
the market to optimize.
Under standard neo-classical economic growth theory, saving is essential to economic growth
and technological innovation. Most modern theories of innovation argue that a threshold level
of capital needs to be reached before innovation can occur. Technological innovation can
significantly raise the total amount of output in an economy.
ACCERALTOR THEORY
There are two fundamental macro-economic principles viz., the multiplier and the acceleration.
J.M. Keynes who developed the multiplier, ignored the effects of induced investment.
According to Paul Samuelson, in the long run, the effect of an increase in spending world not
stop with the effect of an increase in spending world not stop with the multiplier expansion of
income, as Keynes has pointed out, for this higher income level would, in turn, have
implications for other parts of the economy. An increase in national output or income will lead
to an increase in investment. Such investment, which depends on national income or its rate of
change, is called induced investment.
In reality, we observe that a business firm’s decision to make new investment depends on the
rate of change of sales (demand for its product) or of output, because the demand for capital
goods is a derived demand.
Thus, anything, which increases consumer demand (or demand for consumption goods like
textiles) such an increase in per capita income will always be beneficial to the capital goods
producing industry (such as textile producing machineries). In other words, aggregate
investment depends not on the absolute level of output but on the rate of change of national
income or output.
Let us suppose an investment of Rs 100 crore leads to an increase in national income of Rs 500
crore. However, with this multiple increase in income, business firms might very well decide
to proceed with another round of increased investment spending, that they could supply the
output needed by an economy in which national income has just increased.
This is the process of induced investment, which depends on the rate of change of output or of
sales: Ip = f (ΔY), where Ip is induced private investment which depends on (i.e., is a function
of) change(s) in national income (ΔY).
The Acceleration Principle
The implications of induced investment become very clear when we study the acceleration
principle. The principle refers to the relationship between increase in total output (income) and
the additional investment spending that occurs due to such output (income) increase.
In short, the acceleration principle explains why the increase in national income often results
in a more than proportionate increase in investment spending and why the amount of
investment studying depends not on the absolute level of business activity but on whether that
level is increasing or decreasing.
So, a change in national income or output induces (or leads to) a change in investment.
However, a small change in national income or output leads to an accelerated change in
investment. The accelerator principle, developed by J.M. Clark, refers to the accelerated effect
on investment of a small change in the demand for or output (sales) of consumption goods.
Assumptions
The acceleration principle is based on three main consumptions:
1. First, investment has both autonomous and induced components.
2. Investment depends not on the absolute level of output or demand but on the rate of
increase in NNP or in total demand. If the rate of increase is growing, investment
spending will increase; if the rate of income is stable, investment will be constant; if
the rate of increase declines, investment will fall.
3. The acceleration principle also emphasises the extreme volatility of investment as
compared with other components of aggregate demand. It suggests that any percentage
change in aggregate demand may result in much larger percentage changes in
investment spending.
Illustration of the Principle:
In producing output (whether shoes or cars or clothing) firms seek to use that stock of capital
(machines, inventories, plants) that allows the most profitable operation of the firm. The
acceleration principle is based on the idea that an increase in demand for consumer goods (food,
clothing, furniture) produces a far greater increase in demand for producer or capital goods
(food processing equipment, looms, and lathes).
Net investment in the addition to the stock of capital, but the stock of capital needs to grow
only if the level of output or sales increases. The relationship between capital and output
illustrates this point. For example, if for every Re 1 of output the economy requires 50 paise
worth of capital, the capital/output ratio would be 2.
The capital/output ratio (K/Y) is the value of capital (K) needed to produce a given level of
output divided by the value of that output (Y).
If the capital/output ratio remains steady (and capital is fully utilised), capital must increase for
the economy to produce more output. With a capital/output ratio of 2, for example, a Rs 10
crores increase in output would require a Rs 20 crores increase in capital. Because investment
in the increase in capital (I = DK), investment must also depend upon the rate of increase in
output.
With a fixed capital/output ratio of 2, the relationship between investment and output is:
1 = 2 ΔY
or I = K/Y × Δ Y
This equation illustrates the accelerator principle of investment: investment will increase only
if the national income or output increases. If output is high but fails to increase in a particular
year, investment will fall to zero. If output declines, there will be net disinvestment as business
firms will allow their capital stock to depreciate without replacement.
Thus, investment in an economy depends not on the level of income but on how fast output —
or the level of business sales — is rising or falling. To raise investment, output not only has to
grow; it has to grow by increasing rate.
The accelerator principle of investment is that investment depends upon the growth of output
and implies that investment will be unstable. Investment will fall simply because output grows
at a slower rate. For investment just to remain stable, output growth must be constant rate.
The Accelerator:
We assume that the capital-output ratio is 2:1, i.e., two units of capital are required to produce
one unit of output. The name acceleration principle is given since net investment depends upon
the acceleration or deceleration of output.
Importance:
The acceleration principle can work in both directions.
The acceleration principle makes the following two predictions:
1. Investment spending will fluctuate more sharply (widely) than demand for consumer
(final) goods.
2. Investment spending can start to decline even when sales are rising (though at a slower
rate that before).
These two phenomena contain the seeds of business cycles. They together explain why a
private enterprise economy is inherently unstable. When an industry gradually reaches its
capacity level of output, a continued increase in aggregate demand will bring about an
accelerated increase in investment spending.
Even before capacity output is reached, the continuation of that condition can set the
acceleration principle in motion. The enlarged induced investment spending adds to aggregate
effective demand and causes a further rise in national income through the multiplier.
However, like the multiplier the accelerator can work in both the directions. Thus, once a rise
in aggregate demand begins to slacken, however, the operation of the acceleration principle
can cause investment spending to decline. This, in its turn, will slow the growth of aggregate
demand still further and can set the stage for a general downturn in business activity.
Qualifications:
The acceleration principle, however, only provides a partial explanation of investment demand.
Investment is also governed by present and future profits. Future profits are the main rationale
for investment and they figure extensively in the evaluation of investment projects. It seems
that any analysis of investment demand must include both profits and the acceleration principle,
or some variant of it.
Certain qualifications will have to be introduced in the simple acceleration theory:
1. Lags:
Investment lags behind the change in income. That is, planned investment for the third quarter
(made in the second quarter) is based on the actual change between the first and second
quarters, rather than the forecast change between the second and third quarters
2. Business outlook:
Secondly, if the general business outlook is optimistic, businesses will be more inclined to
think that an output increase will be permanent so they will more inclined to invest, than if the
business outlook is pessimistic.
3. Capacity limits:
When a rapid rise in output leads to large planned investment, there are often physical limits to
the rate at which actual investment can take place. The industries which produce capital goods
themselves have capacity limitations.
4. Profile:
Business firms usually prefer to expand internally, by using their own funds. Therefore, we
could expect profits to be a factor in the determination of investment. Investment usually varies
directly with profits.
5. Inventories:
Business investment in plant and equipment mainly depends on profit prospects and the rate of
interest at which money is borrowed to purchase an asset. Usually, inventory investment (i.e.,
investment in stocks of goods held by business to even out delivery and sales) varies
proportionately with sales and output and, thus, fits the simple accelerator model.
TOBINS Q THEORY:
****Write the ppt content first and continue with this****
The firm needs money for investment. This money can be raised either by borrowing or by
selling shares, equity, etc. When the firm sells the share, the buyer buys the share to earn a
capital gain from the increase in the market value of the shares.
The purchaser of share, therefore, purchases shares when he expects a high capital gain. This
is because:
During boom:
The share price is high. The firm by selling only few shares can raise a lot of money. Thus
when stock markets are high, firms are willing to sell equity to finance investment than when
the stock market is low. James Tobin was the first person to explain this relation between the
stock market and investment and that is why it is also referred as “Tobin’s q” theory.
q = market value of the firm/ Replacement cost of capital
Or
q = Value the stock market places on the firm’s asset /Cost of producing those assets
(i) If q ratio is high → it means the price of share is high.
... Firms will invest more.
(ii) If q > 1 → Firm will buy physical capital, that is, add to the capital stock.
Reason
for every Rupee worth of new machinery, the firm can sell the stock for q rupee and earn a
profit = q – 1.
In other words, when q > 1, firms find it profitable to acquire additional capital because value
of capital exceeds the cost of acquiring it.
Thus, when q > 1 → Investment will increase.
Consumption function
The Keynesian consumption function expresses the level of consumer spending depending on
three factors.
Yd = disposable income (income after government intervention – e.g. benefits, and taxes)
a = autonomous consumption (consumption when income is zero. e.g. even with no income,
you may borrow to be able to buy food)
b = marginal propensity to consume (the % of extra income that is spent). Also known as
induced consumption.
Consumption function formula
C = a + b Yd
This suggests consumption is primarily determined by the level of disposable income (Yd).
Higher Yd leads to higher consumer spending.
This model suggests that as income rises, consumer spending will rise. However, spending will
increase at a lower rate than income.
At low incomes, people will spend a high proportion of their income. The average propensity
to consume could be one or greater than one. This means people spend everything they have.
When you have low income, you don’t have the luxury of being able to save. You need to
spend everything you have on essentials.
However, as incomes rise, people can afford the luxury of saving a higher proportion of their
income. Therefore, as incomes rise, spending increases at a lower rate than disposable income.
People with high incomes have a lower average propensity to spend.
In this diagram, the consumption function has shifted to the upwards (to the left. (C1 to C2).
This means consumers are spending a higher % of their income. This could be due to a rise in
property prices which increases consumer confidence and lead to higher consumer spending.
FUNCTIONS OF MONEY
Money performs a number of primary, secondary, contingent and other functions which not
only remove the difficulties of barter but also oils the wheels of trade and industry in the present
day world. We discuss these functions one by one.
1. Primary Functions:
The two primary functions of money are to act as a medium of exchange and as a unit of value.
i) Money as a Medium of Exchange:
This is the primary function of money because it is out of this function that its other functions
developed. By serving as a medium of exchange, money removes the need for double
coincidence of wants and the inconveniences and difficulties associated with barter. The
introduction of money as a medium of exchange decomposes the single transaction of barter
into separate transactions of sale and purchase thereby eliminating the double coincidence of
wants.
This function of money also separates the transactions in time and place because the sellers and
buyers of a commodity are not required to perform the transactions at the same time and place.
This is because the seller of a commodity buys some money and money, in turn, buys the
commodity over time and place.
When money acts as a medium of exchange, it means that it is generally acceptable. It,
therefore, affords the freedom of choice. With money, we can buy an assorted bundle of goods
and services. At the same time, we can purchase the best and also bargain in the market. Thus
money gives us a good deal of economic independence and also perfects the market mechanism
by increasing competition and widening the market.
(ii) Money as Unit of Value:
The second primary function of money is to act as a unit of value. Under barter one would have
to resort to some standard of measurement, such as a length of string or a piece of wood. Since
one would have to use a standard to measure the length or height of any object, it is only
sensible that one particular standard should be accepted as the standard. Money is the standard
for measuring value just as the yard or metre is the standard for measuring length.
The monetary unit measures and expresses the values of all goods and services. In fact, the
monetary unit expresses the value of each good or service in terms of price. Money is the
common denominator which determines the rate of exchange between goods and services
which are priced in terms of the monetary unit. There can be no pricing process without a
measure of value.
The use of money as a standard of value eliminates the necessity of quoting the price of apples
in terms of oranges, the price of oranges in terms of nuts and so on. Unlike barter, the prices of
such commodities are expressed in terms of so many units of dollars, rupees, francs, pounds,
etc., depending on the nature of the monetary unit in a country.
2. Secondary Functions:
Money performs three secondary functions: as a standard of deferred payments, as a store of
value, and as a transfer of value. They are discussed below.
(i) Money as a Standard of Deferred Payments:
The third function of money is that it acts as a standard of deferred or postponed payments. All
debts are taken in money. It was easy under barter to take loans in goats or grains but difficult
to make repayments in such perishable articles in the future. Money has simplified both the
taking and repayment of loans because the unit of account is durable.
Money links the present values with those of the future. It simplifies credit transactions. It
makes possible contracts for the supply of goods in the future for an agreed payment of money.
It simplifies borrowing by consumers on hire-purchase and from house-building and
cooperative societies.
(ii) Money as a Store of Value:
Another important function of money is that it acts as a store of value. “The good chosen as
money is always something which can be kept for long periods without deterioration or
wastage. It is a form in which wealth can be kept intact from one year to the next. Money is a
bridge from the present to the future. It is therefore essential that the money commodity should
always be one which can be easily and safely stored.”
Money as a store of value is meant to meet unforeseen emergencies and to pay debts. Newlyn
calls this the asset function of money. “Money is not, of course, the only store of value. This
function can be served by any valuable asset. One can store value for the future by holding
short-term promissory notes, bonds, mortgages, preferred stocks, household furniture, houses,
land, or any other kind of valuable goods. The principal advantages of these other assets as a
store of value are that they, unlike money, ordinarily yield an income in the form of interest,
profits, rent or usefulness…,and they sometimes rise in value in terms of money.
On the other hand, they have certain disadvantages as a store of value, among which are the
following: (1) They sometimes involve storage costs; (2) they may depreciate in terms of
money; and (3) they are “illiquid” in varying degrees, for they are not generally acceptable as
money and it may be possible to convert them into money quickly only by suffering a loss of
value.”
Keynes placed much emphasis on this function of money. According to him, to hold money is
to keep it as a reserve of liquid assets which can be converted into real goods. It is a matter of
comparative indifference whether wealth is in money, money claims, or goods. In fact, money
and money claims have certain advantages of security, convenience and adaptability over real
goods. But the store of value function of money also suffers from changes in the value of
money. This introduces considerable hazard in using money or assets as a store of value.
(iii) Money as a Transfer of Value:
Since money is a generally acceptable means of payment and acts as a store of value, it keeps
on transferring values from person to person and place to place. A person who holds money in
cash or assets can transfer that to any other person. Moreover, he can sell his assets at Delhi
and purchase fresh assets at Bangalore. Thus money facilitates transfer of value between
persons and places.
3. Contingent Functions:
Money also performs certain contingent or incidental functions, according to Prof. David
Kinley. They are:
(i) Money as the Most Liquid of all Liquid Assets:
Money is the most liquid of all liquid assets in which wealth is held. Individuals and firms may
hold wealth in infinitely varied forms. “They may, for example, choose between holding wealth
in currency, demand deposits, time deposits, savings, bonds, Treasury Bills, short-term
government securities, long-term government securities, debentures, preference shares,
ordinary shares, stocks of consumer goods, and productive equipment.” All these are liquid
forms of wealth which can be converted into money, and vice-versa.
(ii) Basis of the Credit System:
Money is the basis of the credit system. Business transactions are either in cash or on credit.
Credit economises the use of money. But money is at the back of all credit. A commercial bank
cannot create credit without having sufficient money in reserve. The credit instruments drawn
by businessmen have always cash guarantee supported by their bankers.
(iii) Equaliser of Marginal Utilities and Productivities:
Money acts as an equaliser of marginal utilities for the consumer. The main aim of a consumer
is to maximise his satisfaction by spending a given sum of money on various goods which he
wants to purchase. Since prices of goods indicate their marginal utilities and are expressed in
money, money helps in equalising the marginal utilities of various goods. This happens when
the ratios of the marginal utilities and prices of the various goods are equal. Similarly, money
helps in equalising the marginal productivities of the various factors. The main aim of the
producer is to maximise his profits. For this, he equalises the marginal productivity of each
factor with its price. The price of each factor is nothing but the money he receives for his work.
(iv) Measurement of National Income:
It was not possible to measure the national income under the barter system. Money helps in
measuring national income. This is done when the various goods and services produced in a
country are assessed in money terms.
(v) Distribution of National Income:
Money also helps in the distribution of national income. Rewards of factors of production in
the form of wages, rent, interest and profit are determined and paid in terms of money.
4. Other Functions:
Money also performs such functions which affect the decisions of consumers and governments.
(i) Helpful in making decisions:
Money is a means of store of value and the consumer meets his daily requirements on the basis
of money held by him. If the consumer has a scooter and in the near future he needs a car, he
can buy a car by selling his scooter and money accumulated by him. In this way, money helps
in taking decisions.
(ii) Money as a Basis of Adjustment:
To carry on trade in a proper manner, the adjustment between money market and capital market
is done through money. Similarly, adjustments in foreign exchange are also made through
money. Further, international payments of various types are also adjusted and made through
money.
It is on the basis of these functions that money guarantees the solvency of the payer and
provides options to the holder of money to use it any way, he likes.
INFLATION
1 Year 2020 was unprecedented with the global pandemic of COVID-19 induced social
distancing disrupting economic activity globally. At the domestic level, two opposing forces
were at play. On the one hand, there was a dampening of demand owing to lower economic
activity. On the other hand, supply chain disruptions have caused spikes in food inflation that
have continued to persist during the unlocking of the economy, though the effect has softened
in the recent months. Overall, headline CPI inflation remained high during the lockdown period
and subsequently as well, due to the persistence of supply side disruptions (Table 1). At the
global level, inflation remained benign on the back of subdued economic activity as a result of
COVID-19 outbreak and sharp fall in international crude oil prices in advanced economies. In
Emerging Markets and Developing Economies (EMDEs), there was slight fall in inflation on
account of weaker economic activity, though there has been uptick in inflation in some
economies ending at similar levels as in the previous year (IMF, 2020)
Current Trends In Inflation
5.2 Headline inflation based on CPI-Combined (CPI-C) was on a downward path from 2014 to
2018. Though a rising trend was observed since 2019, a moderation in inflation is clearly
visible now (Figure 2). The average CPI-C inflation, which was 5.9 per cent in 2014-15, fell
continuously to 3.4 per cent in 2018-19 and recorded 4.8 per cent in 2019-20. It however
increased to 6.6 per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec) before easing to a 15-month low of 4.6 per cent
in December 2020. Within various groups of CPI-C, the increase in inflation in the current year
was mainly driven by rise in food inflation, which increased from 0.1 per cent in 2018-19 to
6.7 per cent in 2019-20 and further to 9.1 per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec), owing to build up in
vegetable prices. However, the swift steps taken by the Government eased food inflation
significantly to 3.4 per cent in December 2020 from a high of 11 per cent in October 2020. CPI
Core (non-food non-fuel) inflation declined from 5.8 per cent in 2018-19 to 4.0 per cent in
2019- 20 and averaged 5.4 per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec) (Table 2). Rise in core inflation in
the current year is mainly on account of miscellaneous group which primarily consists of
services. Inflation in transport & communication, which have maximum weightage in the
miscellaneous group, increased to 9.4 per cent in the current year as compared to 2.4 per cent
in 2019-20. Further, volatility in gold and silver prices also pushed core inflation up. However,
at major group level of CPI-C, significant fall has been observed in housing inflation from 6.7
per cent in 2018-19 to 4.5 per cent in 2019-20 and further to 3.3 per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec).
WPI inflation declined from 4.3 per cent in 2018-19 to 1.7 per cent in 2019-20 and further to
(-) 0.1 per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec). It remained negative from April to July 2020 and stood
at 1.2 per cent in December 2020 (Figure 3). The decline in WPI inflation in the current year
is mainly on account of fuel & power. Persistent volatility in the global crude oil prices during
the year led to fall in inflation of major fuel products. WPI fuel & power inflation dropped
sharply from 11.6 per cent in 2018-19 to (-) 1.8 per cent in 2019-20 and further to (-) 12.2 per
cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec). WPI food inflation declined from 6.9 per cent in 2019-20 to 4.2
per cent in 2020-21 (Apr-Dec) and WPI core inflation increased to 0.8 per cent in 2020-21
(Apr-Dec) as compared to (-) 0.4 per cent in 2019-20
The rural-urban difference in CPI inflation, which was high in 2019, saw a decline in 2020.
From July 2018 to December 2019, CPI-Urban inflation was consistently above CPI-Rural
inflation, mainly on account of the differential rates of food inflation between rural and urban
areas witnessed during this period. However, in the current year, CPI-Urban inflation has
moved closely with CPI-Rural inflation (Figure 4). Although food inflation in rural and urban
areas has almost converged now (Figure 5), divergence in rural-urban inflation is observed in
other components of CPI (Figure 6). Inflation in non-food components of CPI is higher in urban
areas as compared to rural areas in the current year. While fuel & light inflation is (-) 0.1 per
cent in rural areas, it is 6.7 per cent in urban areas. The rural-urban differential in other
components is in the range of 1.6 to 2.3 percentage points, except housing, which is not
compiled for rural areas
CPI-IW is a price index released by the Labour Bureau to measure the impact of price rise on
the cost of living for working class families spread across certain select industries. The base
year of CPI-IW has been revised from its earlier 2001 to a more recent base year of 2016
WHICH MEASURE OF INFLATION Reflected Economic Activity Better IN 2020-21?
5.26 The previous two sections indicate the role of supply-side constraints, especially in the
case of perishable vegetables contributing to inflation. Since February 2017, CPI-C inflation
and WPI inflation have been moving more or less in tandem till beginning of 2019-20. After
this period, gap has emerged, which has widened in the recent months (Figure 19). Between
April-July 2020, WPI inflation has been in the negative region while CPI-C inflation has been
above 6 per cent. The major feature in this widening gap is that this has happened in a period
witnessing high food inflation. The shaded region in Figure 19 shows the period during which
CFPI inflation has remained higher than non-food inflation. The movement in CPI-C inflation
is quite contrary to the weak demand conditions prevalent in the economy in the recent months
owing to the COVID-19 crisis. Food items have a large weight of around 39 per cent in the
CPI-C index. This means that shocks to food prices can have large impacts on CPI-C inflation.
5.27 For the period April 2020 to November 2020, CPI-C is weakly related to IIP growth while
WPI inflation and CPI-C Core inflation are positively and strongly related to IIP growth.
Therefore, core CPI-C inflation and WPI Inflation, have been more in sync with the demand
conditions in the economy. During the period April 2020 to November 2020, the correlation
coefficient between WPI inflation and YoY growth in IIP is around 0.8 while the correlation
coefficient between CPI-C core inflation and IIP growth has been 0.9. The correlation between
Figure 19: CPI-C and WPI Inflation Source: NSO and OEA, DPIIT Note: The shaded region
in the graph represents the period where Consumer Food Price Inflation has been higher than
Non-Food inflation 182 Economic Survey 2020-21 Volume 2 IIP growth and CPI inflation
during the same period is 0.2. Similarly, we can see high correlation of CPI Core inflation and
WPI inflation with other metrics of production and demand in the Indian economy
A tight monetary policy may have a role in managing inflation in case of excess demand driving
high inflation. However, the current scenario presents a different picture. The current spike in
CPI inflation driven by spike in food prices is mainly a supply-side phenomenon. This can be
easily assessed from the fact that arrivals in the market, for agricultural commodities like onion,
tomato and potato that have witnessed spikes in recent times, have been much lower compared
to the previous years (Figure 20). Further, the weights of all items in CPI-C are based on NSO
Household Consumption Expenditure Survey 2011-12. Weight of food items in the index might
have significantly decreased over the decade since 2011-12. There is a need to capture the
revised weight of food items in the index to correctly depict the true Prices and Inflation 183
picture of inflation in the country. Further, in the context of increasing retail e-commerce
transactions, it is important to include such new sources of price data for the construction price
indices
Measures To Control Inflation
5.35 The Government reviews the price situation regularly and has taken number of measures
from time to time to stabilize prices of food items. In the wake of rising prices of pulses, onion
and potato, the Government has taken several steps to improve the availability of these
commodities and make them available to consumers at affordable prices. These include: i.
Banning the export of onion w.e.f. 14.09.2020, revoked w.e.f. 1.01.2021. ii. Imposition of stock
limit on onion under the EC Act w.e.f. 23.10.2020 to prevent hoarding, lapsed 31.12.2020. iii.
Easing of restrictions on imports, facilitating imports at integrated check-posts, issuance of
licenses for imports and reduction in import duties. These measures have resulted in increased
imports of onion, tur dal and masur dal in the country and resultant cooling of prices.
How Inflation Cause Unemployment
There are a few different scenarios where inflation can cause unemployment. However, there
is not a direct link. Often we will notice a trade-off between inflation and unemployment – e.g.
in a period of strong economic growth and falling unemployment; we see a rise in inflation
The Phillips Curve suggests there is a trade off between unemployment and inflation. Higher
demand reduces unemployment but causes inflation
Also, it is important to bear in mind, (especially in the current climate) If the economy has
deflation or very low inflation and the monetary authorities target a modest rate of inflation,
then this may help boost growth and reduce unemployment.
In this Phillips curve, the increase in AD has caused the economy to shift from point A to point
B. Unemployment has fallen, but a trade-off of higher inflation.
If an economy experienced inflation, then the Central Bank could raise interest rates. Higher
interest rates will reduce consumer spending and investment leading to lower aggregate
demand. This fall in aggregate demand will lead to lower inflation. However, if there is a
decline in Real GDP, firms will employ fewer workers leading to a rise in unemployment.
Visa Royal
Eventually, the various monarchs that reigned over Europe noted the strengths of banking
institutions. As banks existed by the grace, and occasionally explicit charters and contracts, of
the ruling sovereignty, the royal powers began to take loans to make up for hard times at the
royal treasury, often on the king's terms. This easy financing led kings into unnecessary
extravagances, costly wars, and arms races with neighboring kingdoms that would often lead
to crushing debt.
In 1557, Philip II of Spain managed to burden his kingdom with so much debt (as the result of
several pointless wars) that he caused the world's first national bankruptcy—as well as the
world's second, third, and fourth, in rapid succession. This occurred because 40% of the
country's gross national product (GNP) was going toward servicing the debt.5 The trend of
turning a blind eye to the creditworthiness of big customers continues to haunt banks today.
To Energise Priority Sectors: Banks were collapsing at a fast rate – 361 banks
failed between 1947 and 1955, which converts to about 40 banks a year! Customers lost
their deposit with no chance of recovering them.
A Neglected Agricultural Sector: Banks favoured large industries and
businesses and neglected the rural sector. Nationalisation came with a pledge to support
the agricultural sector.
Expansion of Branches: Nationalisation facilitated the opening of new
branches to ensure maximum coverage of banks throughout the country.
Mobilisation of Savings: Nationalising the banks would allow people more
access to banks and encourage them to save, injecting additional revenue into a cash-
strapped economy.
Economic and Political Factors: The two wars in 1962 and 1965 had put a
tremendous burden on the economy. The nationalisation of Indian banks would give
the economy a boost through increased deposits.
CENTRAL BANK
What is a Central Bank
A central bank controls the supply of money as well as how it reaches the consumer. It can not
only print and inject money into the economy, but also regulate commercial banks distribution
of it.
The central bank controls monetary policy, which includes power over inflation, exchange
rates, and the money supply. It has a number of tools by which it uses to control such. For
example, it can set interest rates to control inflation, buy foreign currencies to weaken the
domestic currency, and engage in open market operations by purchasing assets from financial
institutions.
In turn, the central bank uses monetary tools to meet its objectives. These range from country
to country, but generally include targets for inflation, unemployment, economic growth, and
financial stability.
Objectives of Central Bank
The objectives of central banks have largely changed over the years, due to disastrous economic
events. For example, back in the 1970s, the main goal of central banks was to ensure full
employment. However, the focus on employment blinded central banks attention on inflation.
Rather than maintain price stability, central banks would pump money into the economy to
ensure people were being employed. Yet this came at the cost of inflation.
For example, in 1973, there was a massive oil crisis that was to be named the ‘OPEC crisis’. It
led to a sharp increase in the unemployment rates across the developed world. In retaliation,
central banks opened the taps and supplied the economy with money in the hope of boosting
investment and jobs.
Whilst the plan worked, it boosted employment in the short-term, but created long-term effects.
Double digit inflation occurred into the 1980s and employment equally suffered. As a result,
central banks learnt that a more balanced approach is needed – one that focuses on several
objectives rather than one.
Examples of the central banks objectives include:
Price Stability
Full Employment
Financial Stability
Economic Growth
Exchange Rate Stability
1. Price Stability
Price stability is probably one of the leading objectives of central banks. After the high levels
of inflation in the 1970s and 1980s, and the disaster that was the Great Depression of 1929,
control over prices is a key element of central banking policy.
2. Full Employment
Going back through history, full employment was one of the leading objectives of the central
bank. However, as the welfare state has expanded and the understanding of monetary policy
increased, it has taken a backwards step.
Nevertheless, full employment is still a relatively important objective. Most central banks
would take action if employment starts keeping up. Usually, this is done by lowering the
interest rates to fuel cheaper credit to businesses. In turn, businesses would use the cheap credit
to invest and expand its operations, thereby stimulating jobs in the process.
3. Financial Stability
The central bank often acts as lender of last resort in order to maintain financial stability. For
instance, most commercial banks need short-term loans in order for them to be able to align
their assets and liabilities.
On occasion, a commercial bank may have to pay a loan to another financial institution, but
their assets are tied up in long-term loans and other illiquid assets. As a result, they need some
short-term liquidity to meet their obligations, which is where the central bank comes into play.
4. Economic Growth
Economic growth is important to central banks as it generally means more jobs and better living
conditions. When there is economic growth, it is often associated with increased business
investment, improving employment, and increasing demand.
Now economic growth is an objective for central banks but is not necessarily its main one.
They often have to weigh up the pros and cons, as controlling inflation and prices may be more
beneficial than stimulating the economy. Nevertheless, central banks will often look to prop up
the economy if they can do so whilst also maintaining price stability.
5. Exchange Rate Stability
For one reason or another, a nation may face a currency shock by which the demand for its
currency declines rapidly. This may be due to a domestic political output or a financial crisis.
In turn, this creates instability within the markets, which central banks look to avoid.
COMMERCIAL BANK
The term commercial bank refers to a financial institution that accepts deposits,
offers checking account services, makes various loans, and offers basic financial products
like certificates of deposit (CDs) and savings accounts to individuals and small businesses. A
commercial bank is where most people do their banking.
Commercial banks make money by providing and earning interest from loans such as
mortgages, auto loans, business loans, and personal loans. Customer deposits provide banks
with the capital to make these loans
Significance of Commercial Banks
Commercial banks are an important part of the economy. Not only do they provide consumers
with an essential service, but they also help create capital and liquidity in the market.
They ensure liquidity by taking the funds that their customers deposit in their accounts and
lending them out to others. Commercial banks play a role in the creation of credit, which leads
to an increase in production, employment, and consumer spending, thereby boosting the
economy.
As such, commercial banks are heavily regulated by a central bank in their country or region.
For instance, central banks impose reserve requirements on commercial banks. This means
banks are required to hold a certain percentage of their consumer deposits at the central bank
as a cushion if there's a rush to withdraw funds by the general public.
Special Considerations
Customers find commercial bank investments, such as savings accounts and CDs, attractive
because they are insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and money can
be easily withdrawn. Customers have the option to withdraw money upon demand and the
balances are fully insured up to $250,000. Therefore, banks do not have to pay much for this
money.1
Many banks pay no interest at all on checking account balances (or at least pay very little) and
offer interest rates for savings accounts that are well below U.S. Treasury bond (T-bond) rates.
Consumer lending makes up the bulk of North American bank lending, and of this,
residential mortgages make up by far the largest share. Mortgages are used to buy properties
and the homes themselves are often the security that collateralizes the loan. Mortgages are
typically written for 30 year repayment periods and interest rates may be fixed, adjustable, or
variable. Although a variety of more exotic mortgage products were offered during the U.S.
housing bubble of the 2000s, many of the riskier products, including pick-a-payment mortgages
and negative amortization loans, are much less common now.
Automobile lending is another significant category of secured lending for many banks.
Compared to mortgage lending, auto loans are typically for shorter terms and higher rates.
Banks face extensive competition in auto lending from other financial institutions, like captive
auto financing operations run by automobile manufacturers and dealers.
Bank Credit Cards
Credit cards are another significant type of financing. Credit cards are, in essence, personal
lines of credit that can be drawn down at any time. Private card issuers offer them through
commercial banks.
Visa and MasterCard run the proprietary networks through which money is moved around
between the shopper's bank and the merchant's bank after a transaction. Not all banks engage
in credit card lending, as the rates of default are traditionally much higher than in mortgage
lending or other types of secured lending.
That said, credit card lending delivers lucrative fees for banks—interchange fees charged to
merchants for accepting the card and entering into the transaction, late-payment fees, currency
exchange, over-the-limit, and other fees for the card user, as well as elevated rates on the
balances that credit card users carry from one month to the next.
What Role Do Commercial Banks Play in the Economy?
Commercial banks are crucial to the fractional reserve banking system, currently found in most
developed countries. This allows banks to extend new loans of up to (typically) 90% of the
deposits they have on hand, theoretically growing the economy by freeing capital for lending.
Quantitative tools
The tools applied by the policy that impact money supply in the entire economy, including
sectors such as manufacturing, agriculture, automobile, housing, etc.
Reserve Ratio
Banks are required to keep aside a set percentage of cash reserves or RBI approved assets.
Reserve ratio is of two types:
Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR) – Banks are required to set aside this portion in
cash with the RBI. The bank can neither lend it to anyone nor can it earn any interest
rate or profit on CRR.
Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR) – Banks are required to set aside this portion
in liquid assets such as gold or RBI approved securities such as government securities.
Banks are allowed to earn interest on these securities, however it is very low.
Open Market Operations (OMO):
In order to control money supply, the RBI buys and sells government securities in the
open market. These operations conducted by the Central Bank in the open market are
referred to as Open Market Operations.
When the RBI sells government securities, the liquidity is sucked from the market, and
the exact opposite happens when RBI buys securities. The latter is done to control
inflation. The objective of OMOs are to keep a check on temporary liquidity
mismatches in the market, owing to foreign capital flow.
Qualitative tools
Unlike quantitative tools which have a direct effect on the entire economy’s money supply,
qualitative tools are selective tools that have an effect in the money supply of a specific sector
of the economy.
1. Margin requirements – The RBI prescribes a certain margin against collateral, which in
turn impacts the borrowing habit of customers. When the margin requirements are
raised by the RBI, customers will be able to borrow less.
2. Moral suasion – By way of persuasion, the RBI convinces banks to keep money in
government securities, rather than certain sectors.
3. Selective credit control – Controlling credit by not lending to selective industries or
speculative businesses.