Moehrl V NAR Class Certification Order
Moehrl V NAR Class Certification Order
Moehrl V NAR Class Certification Order
Plaintiffs are seven individuals who sold their homes utilizing a local database of
properties for sale known as a Multiple Listing Service (“MLS”). As a condition of listing their
home on an MLS, each Plaintiff’s listing had to include a set offer of compensation to any broker
who found a buyer for their home. Each Plaintiff then paid that offer amount in connection with
the sale of their home. According to Plaintiffs, the rules implementing and governing the
requirement that an MLS listing include a set commission offer to the successful buyer-broker
are anticompetitive and caused them to pay artificially inflated, supracompetitive commission
rates. They have therefore brought the present antitrust action alleging that Defendant National
HomeServices of America, Inc., HSF Affiliates, LLC, The Long & Foster Companies, Inc., BHH
Affiliates, LLC, RE/MAX LLC, and Keller Williams Realty, Inc. (collectively, “Corporate
Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. Now before the Court are Plaintiffs’ motion to certify two classes of similarly
situated home sellers (Dkt. No. 301), and Defendants’ motion to exclude the opinions of two
expert witnesses on which Plaintiffs rely in seeking class certification (Dkt. No. 318). For the
reasons that follow, Defendants’ motion is denied and Plaintiffs’ motion is granted.
BACKGROUND
The following facts are taken from the record and are uncontested unless otherwise noted.
In the United States, most individuals buying and selling residential property do so with
association of real estate brokers and agents whose members are referred to as “Realtors,” a term
the NAR has registered as a trademark. The NAR’s members belong to one or more of about
1,200 local associations or boards, and 54 state and territory associations. Realtors cannot join
the NAR without also joining one of the state or local associations, and Realtors cannot join one
The vast majority of homes for sale in the United States are listed on an MLS, which is a
local or regional database of for-sale properties. There are hundreds of MLSs across the country,
each serving a specific local or regional market. Nearly 97% of MLSs are owned or operated by
one or more local Realtor associations. Those NAR-affiliated MLSs are governed by rules
promulgated by the NAR in its Handbook on Multiple Listing Policies (“MLS Rules”). The MLS
Rules are adopted and enforced by the MLSs. Given the prominent role MLSs have in the home-
selling process, participation in a local MLS is a practical necessity for real estate brokers. In
turn, to join an NAR-affiliated MLS, brokers must agree to follow the MLS Rules. Brokers who
violate the MLS Rules may face fines or the suspension or termination of their MLS access.
In addition, the NAR issues a Code of Ethics and its Standards of Practice and Case
Interpretations (“Case Interpretations”), both of which all brokers and local associations must
comply with as a condition of NAR membership. Violations of the Code of Ethics or the Case
Interpretations are punishable by fines and potentially expulsion from the NAR. Because most
2
NAR-affiliated MLSs require NAR membership as a condition for participation, participants in
those MLSs necessarily must comply with the NAR’s Code of Ethics and the Case
Interpretations. And even for the MLSs that allow non-NAR members to participate, those non-
Realtors are nonetheless bound by a separate MLS Standards of Conduct that mirrors the
At issue in this lawsuit are several rules set forth in the MLS Rules, Code of Ethics, and
Case Interpretations that, together, allegedly work to artificially inflate the commissions paid to
buyer-brokers (“Challenged Restraints”). Most prominently, Policy Statement 7.23 of the MLS
Rules requires that, when listing a home for sale on an MLS, the listing seller-broker must “make
(Pls.’ Corrected Mem. in Supp. of Class Certification, Ex. 26, 2021 MLS Rules at 37–39, Dkt.
No. 306-3.) The seller-broker’s offer must be expressed as either a fixed percentage of the
home’s gross sales price or a definite dollar amount. (Id. at 38.) Moreover, the listing cannot
“include general invitations by listing brokers to other participants to discuss terms and
Rule, a seller-broker is not allowed to submit, and an MLS is not allowed to publish, a listing
that does not include a blanket unilateral offer of compensation to the broker that finds a buyer
As a result of the Buyer-Broker Commission Rule, the seller rather than the buyer pays
the buyer-broker’s commission. Accordingly, a seller’s listing agreement with their seller-broker
will typically provide that the seller will pay a total commission to the seller-broker, often
expressed as a percentage of the home’s sales price, with a portion of that commission earmarked
to compensate the successful buyer’s broker. For example, a seller’s listing agreement might
3
require the seller to pay the seller-broker a total commission equal to 6% of their home’s sales
price, with half that amount going to the buyer-broker such that the seller-broker and buyer-
Further, the Challenged Restraints include at least three NAR rules that Plaintiffs contend
effectively prevent any negotiations over the commission paid to the successful buyer-broker.
First, the Code of Ethics’s Standard of Practice 16-16 prohibits buyer-brokers from “us[ing] the
terms of an offer to purchase[] to attempt to modify the listing broker’s offer of compensation.”
(Pls.’ Corrected Mem. in Supp. of Class Certification, Ex. 31, 2022 Code of Ethics at 13, Dkt.
No. 306-3.) Thus, the buyer-broker cannot attempt to condition the purchase of a home on the
Second, the Code of Ethics’s Standard of Practice 3-2 requires that any modification in the
the time that [buyer-broker] submits an offer to purchase . . . the property.” (Id. at 7.) And once a
buyer-broker “has submitted an offer to purchase . . . property, the listing broker may not attempt
to unilaterally modify the offered compensation.” (Id.) Third, Case Interpretation #16-15 advises
that any negotiations regarding the buyer-broker’s commission “should be completed prior to the
showing of the property.”1 (Pls.’ Corrected Mem. in Supp. of Class Certification, Ex. 115, Case
1
While Plaintiffs assert that Case Interpretation #16-15 requires that negotiations of buyer-broker
commissions take place before the property is shown, Defendants contend that Plaintiffs misinterpret the
Case Interpretation. According to Defendants, the Case Interpretation provides only that the best practice
is to complete commission negotiations before showing the property. Nonetheless, Defendants emphasize
that “commissions may be negotiated at any point in the transaction.” (Defs.’ Opp’n to Class
Certification, Ex. 35, Gansho Decl. ¶ 19, Dkt. No. 322-36.)
4
The remaining Challenged Restraints consist of the NAR rules that, in conjunction, create
Commission Rule, buyer-broker commission offers are necessarily visible to all MLS
participants. But Sections 18.2.4 and 19.12 of the MLS Rules go further and also permit buyer-
brokers to select the listings that they display to consumers (i.e., display on their personal
websites) based on buyer-broker commission offers. (2021 MLS Rules at 84, 91.) By contrast,
other NAR rules prevent consumers from viewing the universe of buyer-broker commissions
offered on the MLS. In particular, Sections 18.3.1 and 19.15 of the MLS Rules prohibit MLS
participants from displaying buyer-broker commission offers to consumers. (2021 MLS Rules at
85, 91.) Moreover, until January 1, 2020, the Code of Ethics permitted buyer-brokers to
represent to their clients that their services were free, “provided that all terms governing
availability of the offered . . . service are clearly disclosed at the same time” and the potential for
the broker “to obtain a benefit from a third party is clearly disclosed at the same time.” (Pls.’
Corrected Mem. in Supp. of Class Certification, Ex. 119, 2019 Code of Ethics, Standard of
and extend an anticompetitive market for real estate broker services by causing home sellers to
conspiracy alleged by Plaintiffs is the NAR, which promulgates the MLS Rules, the Code of
Ethics, and Case Interpretations. The NAR allegedly offers the following deal to co-conspirators:
in exchange for adhering to and enforcing the Challenged Restraints, the co-conspirators will be
2
The relevant Standards of Practice in the Code of Ethics were amended, effective January 1, 2020, such
that now a buyer-broker cannot advertise their services as free unless they, in fact, will not receive
financial compensation from any source for their services. (2022 Code of Ethics at 10.)
5
allowed to participate in the MLSs and gain the attendant benefits of supracompetitive
commission rates and protection from competition. Plaintiffs claim that Corporate Defendants
are among the offerees that have accepted the NAR’s offer, thereby entering into an antitrust
firms. Collectively, Corporate Defendants’ various brands own, operate, and franchise brokerage
firms throughout the United States. Most of Corporate Defendants’ revenues are derived from
the royalties they receive from their affiliated brokerages in the form of a percentage of the
conspiracy by requiring their brokerages, franchisees, or affiliated agents to join a local Realtor
association, participate in an MLS, or follow the Code of Ethics, each of which entails an
obligation to comply with and enforce the Challenged Restraints, among other NAR rules.
Plaintiffs further allege that Corporate Defendants participate in the antitrust conspiracy through
their extensive involvement with the NAR. In particular, Plaintiffs highlight evidence showing
that Corporate Defendants’ executives, employees, and affiliated agents have held positions on
the NAR’s Board of Directors, which is responsible for approving the MLS Rules and Code of
Ethics. Individuals associated with Corporate Defendants have also served in key roles on
Plaintiffs contend that together the NAR and Corporate Defendants have engaged in a
among real estate brokers in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. Each Plaintiff
sold a home on an MLS that implemented the Challenged Restraints and therefore paid a
purportedly inflated commission to the successful buyer-broker. Plaintiffs seek to represent two
6
classes consisting of homeowners who sold or intend to sell a home on one of twenty NAR-
affiliated MLSs covering various regions across the United States. (“Covered MLS”).
Specifically, Plaintiffs propose the following “Damages Class” pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil
Procedure 23(b)(3):
Home sellers who paid a commission between March 6, 2015, and December 31,
2020, to a brokerage affiliated with a Corporate Defendant in connection with the
sale of residential real estate listed on a Covered MLS and in a covered jurisdiction.
Excluded from the class are (i) sales of residential real estate for a price below
$56,500, (ii) sales of residential real estate at auction, and (iii) employees, officers,
and directors of defendants, the presiding Judge in this case, and the Judge’s staff.
In addition, pursuant to Federal of Civil Procedure Rule 23(b)(2), Plaintiffs seek to represent an
Current and future owners of residential real estate in the covered jurisdictions who
are presently listing or will in the future list their home for sale on a Covered MLS.
Excluded from the class are (i) sales of residential real estate for a price below
$56,500, (ii) sales of residential real estate at auction, and (iii) employees, officers,
and directors of defendants, the presiding Judge in this case, and the Judge’s staff.
DISCUSSION
Before the Court are Plaintiffs’ motion for class certification as well as Defendants’
motion to exclude the expert testimony of Plaintiffs’ two class certification experts. Because
Plaintiffs’ motion for class certification relies on the opinions of the two challenged experts, the
Court begins by addressing the admissibility of those experts’ opinions. See Am. Honda Motor
Co. v. Allen, 600 F.3d 813, 815–16 (7th Cir. 2010) (“[W]hen an expert’s report or testimony is
critical to class certification . . . a district court must conclusively rule on any challenge to the
expert’s qualifications or submissions prior to ruling on a class certification motion.”). The Court
7
I. Defendants’ Motion to Exclude Plaintiffs’ Class Certification Experts
To support certification of their proposed classes, Plaintiffs rely on the expert opinions of
Professor Einer Elhauge and Dr. Nicholas Economides. Defendants move to exclude both
experts.
Federal Rule of Evidence 702 and the Supreme Court’s decision in Daubert v. Merrell
Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 509 U.S. 579 (1993), govern the admissibility of expert testimony.
Ervin v. Johnson & Johnson, Inc., 492 F.3d 901, 904 (7th Cir. 2007). Rule 702 states:
(a) the expert’s scientific, technical, or other specialized knowledge will help the
trier of fact to understand the evidence or to determine a fact in issue;
(c) the testimony is the product of reliable principles and methods; and
(d) the expert has reliably applied the principles and methods to the facts of the
case.
“In Daubert, the Supreme Court interpreted Rule 702 to require the district court to act as an
evidentiary gatekeeper, ensuring that an expert’s testimony rests on a reliable foundation and is
relevant to the task at hand.” Gopalratnam v. Hewlett-Packard Co., 877 F.3d 771, 778 (7th Cir.
2017) (internal quotation marks omitted). The district court’s gatekeeping function requires the
court to engage in a three-step analysis before admitting expert testimony. Id. at 779.
Specifically, it must evaluate: “(1) the proffered expert’s qualifications; (2) the reliability of the
expert’s methodology; and (3) the relevance of the expert’s testimony.” Id. The proponent of the
expert bears the burden of demonstrating by a preponderance of the evidence that the expert’s
testimony satisfies the Daubert standard. Lewis v. CITGO Petroleum Corp., 561 F.3d 698, 705
8
A. Professor Einer Elhauge
Plaintiffs have retained Professor Einer Elhauge to conduct an economic analysis of the
evidence and provide his expert opinion on whether common economic evidence can answer
questions related to market definition, market power, liability, and impact. Elhauge is a professor
at Harvard Law School where he teaches antitrust law, among other subjects. In addition, he has
authored or coauthored multiple books and articles on antitrust law and economics. Elhauge has
testified as an expert in dozens of cases and states that he has “been qualified as an expert in
antitrust economics by all twenty-one court opinions to rule on that question.” (Defs.’ Mem. in
Supp. of Mot. to Exclude Experts, Ex. E, Elhauge Report ¶ 12, Dkt. No. 319-6.)
Defendants do not contend otherwise. Multiple district courts before which he has testified have
gone so far as to describe Elhauge as “an antitrust titan.” Castro v. Sanofi Pasteur Inc., 134 F.
Supp. 3d 820, 830 (D.N.J. 2015) (quoting In re Mushroom Direct Purchaser Antitrust Litig., No.
06-0620, 2015 WL 5767415, at *4 (E.D. Pa. July 29, 2015)). Nor is there any question that
Elhauge’s opinions are relevant. Thus, Defendants focus on the reliability of Elhauge’s
matter. Smith v. Ford Motor Co., 215 F.3d 713, 718 (7th Cir. 2000). Rather, even with respect to
the most well-qualified of experts, a district court must also be satisfied that the expert employed
a reliable methodology in reaching his conclusions. Id. That assessment “is generally limited to
Manpower, Inc. v. Ins. Co. of Pa., 732 F.3d 796, 808 (7th Cir. 2013). By contrast, “[t]he
soundness of the factual underpinnings of the expert’s analysis and the correctness of the
9
expert’s conclusions based on that analysis are factual matters to be determined by the trier of
fact, or, where appropriate, on summary judgment.” Smith, 215 F.3d at 718. While the reliability
inquiry is “flexible,” at bottom, it requires ensuring “that an expert, whether basing testimony
upon professional studies or personal experience, employs in the courtroom the same level of
intellectual rigor that characterizes the practice of an expert in the relevant field.” Kumho Tire
Co. v. Carmichael, 526 U.S. 137, 141, 152 (1999). Accordingly, an expert’s “work is admissible
only to the extent it is reasoned, uses the methods of the discipline, and is founded on data.
Talking off the cuff—deploying neither data nor analysis—is not an acceptable methodology.”
Lang v. Kohl’s Food Stores, Inc., 217 F.3d 919, 924 (7th Cir. 2000). A district court “enjoys
broad latitude both in deciding how to determine reliability and in making the ultimate reliability
determination.” Bryant v. City of Chicago, 200 F.3d 1092, 1098 (7th Cir. 2000).
Broadly speaking, Defendants attack Elhauge’s opinions as purely speculative and not
based on any methodology whatsoever. In particular, they assert that Elhauge fails to connect
adequately his conclusions to the evidence or the basic economic principles he draws upon in
reaching them. Where an expert’s “opinion evidence . . . is connected to existing data only by the
ipse dixit of the expert[, a] court may conclude that there is simply too great an analytical gap
between the data and the opinion proffered.” Gen. Elec. Co. v. Joiner, 522 U.S. 136, 146 (1997).
At the same time, the Seventh Circuit has “recognized that the line between conclusions and
methodology is not always an easy line to draw.” Gopalratnam, 877 F.3d at 781 (internal
quotation marks omitted). Ultimately, the question is whether there is “a rational connection
between the data and the opinion.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). Where, as here, an
expert is providing economic testimony, assessing reliability “presents some unique challenges,
as the Daubert rules were not developed with either antitrust or economics in mind.” In re
10
Dealer Mgmt. Sys. Antitrust Litig., 581 F. Supp. 3d 1029, 1049 (N.D. Ill. Jan. 21, 2022) (internal
quotation marks omitted). Thus, “[a]ntitrust courts have generally responded to questionable or
novel economic testimony by being fairly reluctant to exclude it under Daubert rules, while at
the same time scrutinizing admitted testimony carefully and often harshly under summary
judgment rules.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). Despite Defendants’ request that
Elhauge’s opinions be stricken in their entirety, their contentions regarding the analytical gap
between the evidence and Elhauge’s conclusions require the Court to consider the admissibility
First, Elhauge opines that the Challenged Restraints encourage overuse of buyer-brokers
by separating the consumer of buyer-broker services (i.e., the home buyer) from the payment for
those services. On the other hand, in a “but-for world” without the Challenged Restraints, buyer-
broker use would be rare. Defendants argue that this opinion is based on an overly simplistic
assumption that if buyers were forced to internalize the cost of buyer-broker services, they would
question the value of such services and many would opt against using a buyer-broker. Notably,
process and determined by the jury.” Manpower, 732 F.3d at 808. Further, “[i]n an ipse dixit
opinion, the expert asserts a ‘bottom line’ conclusion, but lacks any articulable facts to
substantiate that conclusion or completely fails to explain the reasoning or methods employed to
reach that conclusion.” In re Fluidmaster, Inc., Water Connector Components Prods. Liab.
Litig., No. 14-cv-5696, 2017 WL 1196990, at *7 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 31, 2017). Here, contrary to
Defendants’ contentions, Elhauge fully explains his reasons for believing that the Challenged
that a buyer’s perception of a product as having a lower price than its true price
11
disproportionately influences demand for that product. (Elhauge Report ¶ 148 & n.276.) He then
connects that research to Defendants’ former practice of advertising buyer-brokers as free to the
buyer and highlights a real-estate industry publication explaining to buyers that it is smart for
them to use a buyer-broker because they are not the ones paying their broker’s commission. (Id.
¶ 148.)
for failing to consider all the reasons cited by their own expert, Dr. Lauren Stiroh, for why
buyers would continue using buyer-brokers even if they paid for those services directly. But that
argument speaks only to the correctness of Elhauge’s conclusion and is a matter properly
addressed by cross-examination of both experts before a jury, not exclusion. Burton v. E.I. du
Pont de Nemours & Co., Inc., 994 F.3d 791, 826 (7th Cir. 2021) (“[V]igorous cross-examination,
presentation of contrary evidence, and careful instruction on the burden of proof are the
traditional and appropriate means of attacking shaky but admissible evidence.”); Stollings v.
Ryobi Techs., Inc., 725 F.3d 753, 766 (7th Cir. 2013) (“An expert may provide expert testimony
based on a valid and properly applied methodology and still offer a conclusion that is subject to
doubt. It is the role of the jury to weigh these sources of doubt.”); In re Dealer Mgmt. Sys., 581
F. Supp. 3d at 1060 (“[B]attle of the experts’ issues . . . should be resolved through cross-
examination, not Daubert motions.”). In short, the Court finds no yawning methodological gap
in Elhauge’s opinion that buyer-broker use would be rare in the but-for world and therefore
Relatedly, Elhauge concludes that sellers would almost always refuse to shoulder the cost
of buyer-broker commissions in the but-for world. He explains in detail how the Buyer-Broker
Commission Rule and the other Challenged Restraints incentivize sellers to offer
12
supracompetitive commission rates to buyer-brokers, lest they risk buyer-brokers steering
potential buyers away from the seller’s home. Absent the Challenged Restraints, according to
Elhauge, those steering incentives would disappear and sellers’ natural inclination to maximize
the net sales price of their home would result in few continuing to pay for their buyers’ brokers.
And those few who did so would pay significantly reduced commissions than what they pay in
the actual world. Notably, Defendants do not take issue with the concept of steering or the other
economic principles informing Elhauge’s opinion. Instead, Defendants again turn to the opinions
of their own expert to show all the reasons why sellers would have an economic incentive to
cover the successful buyer’s broker costs, even in the but-for world. While it is possible that
Defendants’ expert has the stronger argument, that is a matter for the jury to decide and not a
but-for world would be lower than those enjoyed by buyer-brokers in the present world. They
claim that Elhauge makes an entirely speculative leap from the general economic principle that
consumers want to pay lower prices to his conclusion that those few buyers who retained buyer-
brokers would pay less in a but-for world without the Challenged Restraints. The Court
disagrees. In fact, Elhauge fully explains the reasoning underlying his conclusion. For example,
he predicts that there would be decreased demand for buyer-brokers in the real world and
supports his prediction by considering how technological advances have decreased the value of
buyer-broker services. In particular, he notes that buyers can find homes without the assistance
of a buyer-broker through websites like Zillow. Elhauge then observes how, in more competitive
markets, the increasing use of the internet has reduced consumer costs, highlighting how
increases in the number of consumers using the internet to book air travel and to trade stocks has
13
been accompanied by corresponding decreases in commissions for travel agents and
advances. Moreover, Elhauge notes that his opinion is reinforced by NAR’s own internal studies
that reveal the real estate industry’s concerns about how technological advances risk reducing
demand for broker services. From there, Elhauge applies the undisputed economic principle that
decreased demand results in lower prices. Thus, far from making an unsupported extrapolation
from a general economic concept, Elhauge considers numerous pieces of evidence and data,
applies his knowledge of antitrust law and economics, and explains each step of his reasoning.
Elhauge provides similarly fulsome explanations as to other factors that would tend to lower
Defendants also point to multiple factors that Elhauge purportedly failed to consider that
suggest that buyer-broker commissions would remain the same in the but-for world. “Experts
who engage in cherry-picking of the evidence fail to satisfy the scientific method and Daubert.”
Van v. Ford Motor Co., 332 F.R.D. 249, 269 (N.D. Ill. 2019). Such impermissible cherry-picking
occurs where the expert “arbitrarily pick[s] and choose[s] among the same kind of scientific data
when formulating their opinions.” In re Fluidmaster, 2017 WL 1196990, at *21. But here,
Defendants only point to facts (or, more accurately, their interpretation of facts) that they believe
undermine Elhauge’s conclusion, and “their challenge goes to the weight of his opinion, and not
its admissibility.” In re Allstate Corp. Sec. Litig., No. 16 C 10510, 2022 WL 842737, at *14
(N.D. Ill. Jan. 10, 2022); see also Cates v. Whirlpool Corp., No. 15-CV-5980, 2017 WL
1862640, at *15 (N.D. Ill. May 9, 2017) (“[F]ailing to account for supposedly contradictory
information often is a question going to the weight of the evidence rather than its admissibility,
which a lawyer can address on cross-examination . . . .”); Jordan v. Dominick’s Finer Foods, 115
14
F. Supp. 3d 950, 963 (N.D. Ill. 2015) (“[O]bjections as to whether an expert considered certain
factors that the opposing side deems irrelevant generally go to the weight of the expert’s opinion,
not its admissibility.”). Despite their claims regarding Elhauge’s supposed lack of methodology,
Defendants’ arguments boil down to attacks on the soundness of his conclusions. At this stage in
the proceedings, such arguments do not provide a basis to exclude Elhauge’s expert opinions.
In one final attempt at excluding the above contested opinions, Defendants fault Elhauge
for stating that analysis from Plaintiff’s other expert, Dr. Nicholas Economides, confirms his
own predictions regarding the but-for world. According to Defendants, since Economides based
his analysis, in part, on Elhauge’s predictions, Elhauge’s claim that Economides’s analysis
confirms his predictions is circular. However, Elhauge does not rely on Economides’s analysis in
making his predictions; rather, he makes his predictions independent of Economides’s work and
then makes a concluding observation that his own opinions are consistent with and supported by
Economides’s analysis. The Court sees no issue with Elhauge citing Economides’s analysis as
further supporting and reinforcing his own opinions. See, e.g., Gopalratnam, 877 F.3d at 789
(“[A]s a general matter, there is nothing objectionable about an expert relying upon the work [of]
a colleague.”).
In short, the Court finds that Elhauge’s methodology is sufficiently reliable, as his
opinions are derived from his application of his extensive knowledge of antitrust law and
economics to the evidence in this case. See Forth Worth Emps. Ret. Fund v. J.P. Morgan Chase
& Co., 301 F.R.D. 116, 129 (S.D.N.Y. 2014) (admitting expert opinion “based in [the expert’s]
general knowledge of economic principles and of the market for mortgage-backed securities, and
his application of that understanding to the specific facts of the . . . case”). Further, Elhauge does
not rely on the type of unrealistic assumptions or cherry-picked facts that would call his
15
reliability into question. Defendants are free to attack the accuracy of his opinions at a later stage
of the case but, for now, they have given this Court no reason to exclude Elhauge as an expert.
common evidence can prove antitrust impact and damages. Economides is a professor of
economics at New York University’s Stern School of Business. He has a master’s degree and a
Ph.D. in economics, both from the University of California at Berkeley. Economides specializes
in industrial organization and antitrust, and he has published numerous articles on those topics.
they do not dispute either Economides’s qualifications or the relevance of his opinions. And the
Court is satisfied both that Economides is qualified to testify as to impact and damages and that
In his report, Economides begins by reviewing Elhauge’s findings regarding the relevant
market and the but-for world. He then turns to consider which markets to use as “yardsticks” to
compare against the markets served by the Covered MLSs. The goal of such a yardstick analysis
those restraints. As yardsticks, Economides looks to markets outside the United States. In
particular, he begins his analysis by identifying countries with similar levels of economic and
institutional development, which he measures using gross domestic product (or “GDP”) per
capita and corruption level3 as proxies. Economides also narrows potential yardsticks to
3
To measure corruption, Economides relies on Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions
Index. See generally Corruption Perceptions Index 2021, Transparency International,
https://www.transparency.org/en/cpi/2021 (last visited Mar. 20, 2023).
16
countries with populations above 10 million inhabitants. That initial screen leaves him with
seven countries: Australia, Belgium, Canada, Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, and the United
Kingdom. Then, Economides further narrows down that list by examining each country’s real
estate market and eliminating those that featured restraints similar to the Challenged Restraints
or other confounding characteristics. Based on that analysis, he concludes that Australia, the
Having identified his yardsticks, Economides goes on to find that in the three comparator
markets, only about 5–20% of home buyers used buyer-brokers as compared to 87% in the
United States. Moreover, those buyers who did employ buyer-brokers in the yardstick markets
paid only about 1–2% in commissions versus the 2–3% paid by buyers in the United States.
Further, sellers in the yardstick markets paid the same or less for seller-broker services, usually
about 1–3% whereas sellers in the United States paid 2–3%. Based on the evidence from the
yardsticks, Economides puts together two statistical models to explore whether a class member
would have paid lower commissions in the but-for world than what they paid in the actual world.
His models compare the distribution of buyer-broker commissions paid in the actual world to the
percentage of all class transactions that were impacted and the likelihood that any given
transaction was impacted. From those models, Economides concludes that 99.4–99.9% of all
Finally, to estimate damages, Economides creates a yardstick estimate of the rate paid to
buyer-brokers in the but-for world. To do that, Economides estimates for each yardstick country
the average rate paid to buyer-brokers in transactions involving them. He then averages the
estimates for all three countries to construct a single yardstick estimate of 1.55% commission
17
paid to buyer-brokers. Economides uses that yardstick estimate to calculate total damages for the
class equal to the total commissions paid in the actual world on all class transactions with
commission rates above 1.55% minus the total sales price multiplied by the 1.55% yardstick
commission rate. That formula estimates the total damages for the class at $13.7 billion. And to
calculate transaction level damages, Economides proposes multiplying the sales price by the
1.55% yardstick commission and subtracting that figure from the commission actually paid by
As an initial matter, the Court finds that “the yardstick approach is a well-established
methodology” in antitrust actions and Defendants “cannot complain that the methodology itself
is unreliable.” In re Dealer Mgmt. Sys., 581 F. Supp. 3d at 1073 (internal quotation marks
omitted); see also Fishman v. Est. of Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520, 551 (7th Cir. 1986) (“The concept of a
‘yardstick’ measure of damages, that is, linking the plaintiff’s experience in a hypothetical free
market to the experience of a comparable firm in an actual free market, is . . . well accepted.”).
Nonetheless, for a particular yardstick analysis to be considered reliable, the plaintiff bears the
burden of demonstrating the comparability of the proposed yardsticks. Loeffel Steel Prods., Inc.
v. Delta Brands, Inc., 387 F. Supp. 2d 794, 812 (N.D. Ill. 2005); In re Blood Reagents Antitrust
Litig., MDL No. 09-2081, 2015 WL 6123211, at *21 (E.D. Pa. Oct. 19, 2015). “Of course, exact
correlation is not necessary but the samples must be fair congeners.” Loeffel, 387 F. Supp. 2d at
812.
he failed to analyze whether the factors he used to select his yardstick countries were relevant to
predicting a country’s real estate brokerage practices. Typically, an expert’s yardstick analysis
will only be thrown out where the “expert has failed to perform any substantive analysis of those
18
factors most relevant to comparability.” In re Blood Reagents Antitrust Litig., 2015 WL
6123211, at *22. Otherwise, “[a]rguments about how the selection of data inputs affect the
merits of the conclusions produced by an accepted methodology should normally be left to the
jury.” Elorac, Inc. v. Sanofi-Aventis Can., Inc., No. 14 C 1859, 2017 WL 3592775, at *10 (N.D.
Ill. Aug. 21, 2017) (quoting Manpower, 732 F.3d at 808); see also In re Prograf Antitrust Litig.,
1:11-md-02242-RWZ, 2014 WL 7641156, at *3 (D. Mass. Dec. 23, 2014) (“Cases employing
the yardstick approach have recognized that product, firm, and market comparability are all
relevant factors in the selection of a proper yardstick. Because evaluating those factors generally
involves weighing facts, deciding whether the plaintiff has met this burden of showing
comparability ordinarily is a question for the trier of fact.” (internal quotation marks and citation
omitted)).
The Court disagrees with Defendants’ contention that Economides completely failed to
explain why he used a country’s per capita GDP, corruption perceptions index, and population as
initial screening factors for potential yardsticks. On the contrary, Economides explains that he
uses the first two factors to measure a country’s economic and institutional development, which
is important in identifying comparators since “[r]eal estate transactions take place in the context
of: (a) buyers’ and sellers’ willingness to pay, and (b) the risk and difficulty of transacting.”
(Defs.’ Mem. in Supp. of Mot. to Exclude Experts, Ex. F, Economides Report ¶¶ 22–23, Dkt.
No. 319-7.) Further, Economides states that he included the requirement that a comparator
country have a population of 10 million or more to ensure that his yardsticks encompassed a mix
Economides’ initial screening were used as comparators by the NAR in an internal report
19
discussing the increasing pressure on real estate brokers to reduce commission rates. (Pl.’s Resp.
to Defs.’ Mot. to Exclude Experts, Ex. 4, D.A.N.G.E.R. Report at 22, Dkt. No. 346-5.) In
particular, the internal NAR report notes that many brokers “fear . . . a realignment of fees as
charged in other countries in the world,” and then cites the average commission rates in the
United Kingdom, the Netherlands, Australia, Belgium, and Germany.4 (Id.) To demonstrate the
reliability of his methodology for choosing comparators, all Economides was required to do was
make a “rational connection” between the screening criteria and his selection of comparable
markets. Elorac, 2017 WL 3592775, at *10; see also In re Blood Reagents Antitrust Litig., 2015
WL 6123211, at *22 (“[A] proposed yardstick must be rejected as inadmissible where the expert
testimony is so deficient that ‘the comparison is manifestly unreliable and cannot logically
advance a material aspect of the proposing party’s case.’” (quoting Loeffel, 387 F. Supp. 2d at
813)). The Court concludes that he does so. While Defendants may genuinely believe that
Economides’s screening criteria are flawed, such claims of “reliance on faulty information is a
F.3d at 809; see also Koehler v. Infosys Techs. Ltd., No. 13-cv-885-pp, 2022 WL 4234946, at
*34 (E.D. Wis. Sept. 14, 2022) (“The defendants’ criticism[] that [the expert] incorrectly defined
the relevant labor market for comparison purposes [is] not [a] criticism[] that warrants exclusion
of his opinions.”).
argue that Economides’s analysis does not sufficiently account for the variation in brokerage
practices across his chosen yardsticks and does not control for the unique attributes of the market
4
The report also cites the rates in Singapore, which was not in Economides’s initial set of potential
comparators.
20
in the United States that predate the adoption of the Challenged Restraints. Those arguments
concern the factual underpinnings of Economides’s analysis and the quality of his conclusions,
and therefore implicate the probative weight of his opinions not their admissibility. Defendants
also criticize Economides’s analysis for using the nationwide averages from his comparator
countries as his yardsticks instead of some more narrowly tailored metric and for comparing
commission rates instead of commission amounts. But again, “[i]t is for the fact finder to
determine whether [an expert’s] choice of data inputs render his analysis either more or less
persuasive than that which is offered by Defendants.” In re Allstate, 2022 WL 842737, at *9; see
also Manpower, 732 F.3d at 809 (“That the reasoning behind [the expert’s data selection] could
be challenged as incomplete or faulty does not make it any less grounded in real data.”).
commission rate to calculate damages is arbitrary and does not fit Plaintiffs’ theory of liability.
In particular, Defendants assert that Plaintiffs cannot argue, on one hand, that buyer-broker usage
would be rare and sellers would generally not compensate them when used in the but-for world
and then turn around and, on the other hand, have an expert testify to a damages theory that
assumes that every home buyer in the but-for world will retain a buyer-broker who is
compensated by the seller at a 1.55% rate of commission. But Plaintiffs’ contention that buyer-
brokers would rarely be used and would generally be paid by buyers in the but-for world
implicitly acknowledges that a small number of but-for world transactions would involve a
buyer-broker whose commissions were covered by the seller. Thus, in calculating damages,
Economides explains that he adopted the “extremely conservative” assumptions that all class
member transactions would be among those rare transactions in the but-for world involving a
buyer-broker and that the buyer-broker would be paid by the seller. (Economides Report ¶ 81.)
21
Essentially, Economides adopts these conservative assumptions to avoid potentially
overestimating damages. For now, the Court concludes that Economides’s conservative
assumptions do not render his damages model unreliable. Whether that damages model is
Defendants as a basis for opposing certification of the Damages Class. The Court believes the
issue is better addressed in that context and will therefore discuss it further below.
To sum up, there is no question that Economides’s use of the established yardstick
methodology is reliable. And he sufficiently explains why his chosen yardsticks are comparable
to the relevant markets in this case. Although Defendants claim that Economides’s methodology
is unreliable, all they can do is point out weaknesses in his analysis. “Whether an expert might
have done a better job is not the test for the admissibility of his testimony.” Traharne v.
Wayne/Scott Fetzer Co., 156 F. Supp. 2d 697, 712 (N.D. Ill. 2001). Thus, the Court concludes
that Economides opinions are admissible. And because the Court is satisfied that both Elhauge
and Economides are qualified to testify as experts, employed a reliable methodology, and offer
relevant opinions, the Court denies Defendants’ motion to exclude them as experts in support of
class certification.
The Court next turns to Plaintiffs’ motion for class certification, which is governed by
Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23. To be certified, a proposed class must first satisfy the
(3) the claims or defenses of the representative parties are typical of the claims or
defenses of the class; and
22
(4) the representative parties will fairly and adequately protect the interests of the
class.
Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a); Messner v. Northshore Univ. HealthSystem, 669 F.3d 802, 811 (7th Cir.
2012). If Rule 23(a) is satisfied, then the proposed class must also fall within one of the three
alternatives set out in Rule 23(b). Lacy v. Cook County, 897 F.3d 847, 864 (7th Cir. 2018). In
this case, Plaintiffs seek to certify a Damages Class under Rule 23(b)(3), which requires that
“questions of law or fact common to class members predominate over any questions affecting
only individual members, and that a class action is superior to other available methods for fairly
and efficiently adjudicating the controversy.” They also seek to certify an Injunctive Relief Class
under Rule 23(b)(2), which applies where “the party opposing the class has acted or refused to
act on grounds that apply generally to the class, so that final injunctive relief or corresponding
Plaintiffs have the burden of showing by a preponderance of the evidence that Rule 23
has been satisfied. Lacy, 897 F.3d at 863. Moreover, Rule 23 is not “a mere pleading standard.”
Comcast Corp. v. Behrend, 569 U.S. 27, 33 (2013) (internal quotation marks omitted). Rather, a
plaintiff “must affirmatively demonstrate his compliance with Rule 23” through evidentiary
proof. Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). And a district court must conduct a “rigorous
analysis” before determining whether a plaintiff has satisfied each of Rule 23’s requirements. Id.
(internal quotation marks omitted). “Frequently that rigorous analysis will entail some overlap
with the merits of the plaintiff’s underlying claim [because] [t]he class determination generally
involves considerations that are enmeshed in the factual and legal issues comprising the
plaintiff’s cause of action.” Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Dukes, 564 U.S. 338, 351 (2011).
23
A. Rule 23(a)
Of the Rule 23(a) factors, Defendants only challenge Plaintiffs’ ability to satisfy the
commonality and typicality requirements. Nonetheless, the Court briefly notes that the
numerosity requirement is undoubtedly satisfied, as the proposed classes include individuals who
sold homes listed on one of the twenty Covered MLSs during the nearly six-year class period.
Thus, the membership of each proposed class can be expected to number in the thousands, at
minimum. E.g., Barnes v. Air Line Pilots Ass’n, Int’l, 310 F.R.D. 551, 557 (N.D. Ill. 2015)
(explaining that classes with at least forty members are generally found to satisfy the numerosity
requirement and that district courts can make evidence-based “common sense assumptions” in
that any Plaintiff’s interests are adverse to those of the class. See Starr v. Chi. Cut Steakhouse,
LLC, 75 F. Supp. 3d 859, 874 (N.D. Ill. 2014) (“To be an adequate representative, the named
Plaintiffs must not have ‘antagonistic or conflicting claims.’” (quoting Retired Chi. Police Ass’n
v. City of Chicago, 7 F.3d 584, 598 (7th Cir. 1993)). Further, class counsel have demonstrated
that they are experienced, qualified, and will adequately represent the interests of the class.5
Accordingly, the Court finds that the adequacy of representation requirement has been met.
Having found that Plaintiffs meet those two Rule 23(a) requirements, the Court considers
1. Commonality
For purposes of Rule 23(a)(2)’s requirement that there be questions of law or fact
common to the class, “even a single common question will do.” Wal-Mart, 564 U.S. at 359
5
This Court previously determined that Plaintiffs’ class counsel was adequate to represent the interests of
the class in granting Plaintiffs’ motion for appointment of interim co-lead class counsel. (Dkt. No. 171.)
Defendants raise no argument casting doubt on that conclusion.
24
(internal quotation marks and alterations omitted). However, “superficial common questions—
like whether . . . each class member ‘suffered a violation of the same provision of law’—are not
enough.” Jamie S. v. Milwaukee Pub. Schs., 668 F.3d 481, 497 (7th Cir. 2012) (quoting Wal-
Mart, 564 U.S. at 350). Rather, commonality requires the plaintiff to “assert a common injury
that is ‘capable of classwide resolution—which means that determination of its truth or falsity
will resolve an issue that is central to the validity of each one of the claims in one stroke.’” Lacy,
897 F.3d at 865 (quoting Wal-Mart, 564 U.S. at 350). Put differently, “the key to commonality is
‘not the raising of common questions but, rather, the capacity of a classwide proceeding to
generate common answers apt to drive the resolution of the litigation.’” Id. (quoting Wal-Mart,
564 U.S. at 350). “The critical point is the need for conduct common to members of the class.”
Phillips v. Sheriff of Cook Cnty., 828 F.3d 541, 553 (7th Cir. 2016) (internal quotation marks
omitted).
Although Defendants contend that Plaintiffs fail to satisfy Rule 23(a)’s commonality
requirement, their arguments on this point simply incorporate their arguments as to Rule
23(b)(3)’s predominance inquiry. Courts regularly observe that there is “a significant overlap
Allstate Ins. Co., 242 F.R.D. 421, 429 (N.D. Ill. 2007). Yet, at the same time,
“[p]redominance . . . is a standard far more demanding than the commonality requirement.” Reed
v. Adv. Health Care, 268 F.R.D. 573, 580 (N.D. Ill. 2009) (internal quotation marks omitted).
Indeed, the commonality “requirement has been characterized as a low hurdle, easily
surmounted.” Smith v. Aon Corp., 238 F.R.D. 609, 614 (N.D. Ill. 2006) (internal quotation marks
omitted).
25
Here, the Court finds that there is at least one central, common question in this case:
whether Defendants conspired to artificially inflate the buyer-broker commissions paid by the
class by adopting the Challenged Restraints, in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act. See
Suchanek v. Sturm Foods, Inc., 764 F.3d 750, 756 (7th Cir. 2014) (“Where the same conduct or
practice by the same defendant gives rise to the same kind of claims from all class members,
there is a common question.”); In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 985 F. Supp. 2d 1167,
1180 (N.D. Cal. 2013) (“Where an antitrust conspiracy has been alleged, courts have consistently
held that the very nature of a conspiracy antitrust action compels a finding that common
questions of law and fact exist.” (internal quotation marks omitted)). Indeed, because proof of
the alleged conspiracy focuses on the defendants’ standardized conduct as opposed to the
conduct of individual class members, “[a]ntitrust liability alone constitutes a common question
that ‘will resolve an issue that is central to the validity’ of each class member’s claim ‘in one
stroke.’” In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 985 F. Supp. 2d at 1180 (quoting Wal-Mart, 564
U.S. at 350)). The existence of this common question is sufficient to satisfy the commonality
requirement.
2. Typicality
A plaintiff’s claim will satisfy Rule 23(a)(3)’s typicality requirement where it “arises
from the same event or practice or course of conduct that gives rise to the claims of other class
members and is based on the same legal theory.” Lacy, 897 F.3d at 866 (internal quotation marks
and alteration omitted). “This requirement is meant to ensure that the named representative’s
claims have the same essential characteristics as the claims of the class at large.” Id. (internal
quotation marks omitted). In the antitrust context, typicality “will be established by plaintiffs and
all class members alleging the same antitrust violation by the defendants.” In re Ready-Mixed
26
Concrete Antitrust Litig., 261 F.R.D. 154, 168 (S.D. Ind. Sept. 9, 2009) (internal quotation marks
omitted).
According to Defendants, typicality is lacking here because Plaintiffs listed their homes
on only five of the twenty Covered MLSs and therefore Plaintiffs’ claims are not typical of the
class members whose homes were listed on the other fifteen Covered MLSs. However, such
“‘factual distinctions between the claims of the named class members and those of other class
members’ do not necessarily defeat a finding of typicality.” In re Sulfuric Acid Antitrust Litig.,
No. 03 C 4576, 2007 WL 898600, at *4 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 21, 2007) (quoting De La Fuente v.
Stokely-Van Camp, Inc., 713 F.2d 225, 232 (7th Cir. 1983)). That some class members listed
their homes on different MLSs than Plaintiffs does not create a typicality issue because all
Covered MLSs implemented the Challenged Restraints. See In re Ready-Mixed Concrete, 261
F.R.D. at 168 (“If the named class members’ claims are based on the same legal theory or arise
from the same course of conduct, factual differences in date, size, manner, or conditions of
purchase, the type of purchaser, or other concerns do not make plaintiffs atypical.” (internal
quotation marks omitted)). As a result, Plaintiffs’ claims share the same essential characteristics
B. Rule 23(b)(3)
With Plaintiffs having established the requirements of Rule 23(a), the Court next looks to
whether they have also met Rule 23(b)(3)’s predominance and superiority requirements such that
the Damages Class can be certified. The decision to certify a Rule 23(b)(3) class “is one that
depends on a careful assessment of the facts, of potential differences among class members, and
of the overall importance of the common issues of law or fact to the ultimate outcome.” Riffey v.
27
1. Predominance
As discussed above, Rule 23(b)(3)’s predominance requirement is similar to, but more
demanding than, Rule 23(a)’s commonality requirement. “[W]hereas Rule 23(a)(2) requires the
‘predominate’ over the individual ones.” Howard v. Cook Cnty. Sheriff’s Office, 989 F.3d 587,
607 (7th Cir. 2021). The predominance “‘inquiry trains on the legal or factual questions that
qualify each class member’s case as a genuine controversy,’ with the purpose being to determine
Messner, 669 F.3d at 814 (quoting Amchem Prods., Inc. v. Windsor, 521 U.S. 591, 623 (1997)).
The requirement will be satisfied “when common questions represent a significant aspect of a
case and can be resolved for all members of a class in a single adjudication.” Id. at 815 (internal
quotation marks and alterations omitted). Put differently, “common questions can predominate if
a common nucleus of operative facts and issues underlies the claims brought by the proposed
class.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). It is not necessary, however, that “every issue be
common” and “classes are routinely certified under Rule 23(b)(3) where common questions exist
and predominate, even though other individual issues will remain after the class phase.” Kleen
Prods. LLC v. Int’l Paper Co., 831 F.3d 919, 922 (7th Cir. 2016).
In undertaking the predominance inquiry, “the court must understand what the plaintiffs
will need to prove and must evaluate the extent to which they can prove their case with common
evidence.” In re Allstate Corp. Sec. Litig., 966 F.3d 595, 603 (7th Cir. 2020). The analysis
“requires the court to engage with the merits of the case, yet without deciding the merits.” Id.
Thus, “a court weighing class certification must walk a balance between evaluating evidence to
determine whether a common question exists and predominates, without weighing that evidence
28
to determine whether the plaintiff class will ultimately prevail on the merits.” Bell v. PNC Bank,
N.A., 800 F.3d 360, 377 (7th Cir. 2015). “Analysis of predominance under Rule 23(b)(3) ‘begins,
of course, with the elements of the underlying cause of action.’” Messner, 669 F.3d at 815
(quoting Erica P. John Fund, Inc. v. Halliburton Co., 563 U.S. 804, 809 (2011)). For a cause of
action arising under the Sherman Act, the essential elements are: “(1) a violation of antitrust law;
(2) individual injury, or impact, caused by that violation; and (3) measurable damages.” In re
Steel Antitrust Litig., No. 08 C 5214, 2015 WL 5304629, at *5 (N.D. Ill. Sept. 9, 2015) (internal
quotation marks omitted). Defendants contend that individual issues predominate as to each
a. Antitrust Conspiracy
To prove a violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must establish the existence of
relevant market.” Agnew v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 683 F.3d 328, 335 (7th Cir. 2012).
The Court determined above that the question of whether Defendants engaged in a conspiracy to
violate antitrust law is a common question that is central to all class members’ claims. Yet
Defendants contend that Plaintiffs cannot prove that Defendants entered into a conspiracy with
At issue in this case are the standardized rules promulgated by the NAR and then adopted
by Corporate Defendants, which, in turn, enforce those rules against their affiliated brokers
throughout the nation. Plaintiffs’ evidence includes Defendants’ own policies and representations
that reflect how the NAR and Corporate Defendants work together to implement and enforce the
MLS Rules, Code of Ethics, and Case Interpretations. Plaintiffs also highlight evidence showing
how various senior executives from each Corporate Defendant were extensively involved in the
29
NAR’s governance. That evidence regarding Defendants’ conduct in joining and advancing a
single agreement is undoubtedly common across the class, and the existence of the alleged
conspiracy will be one of the predominate issues in the litigation. See Amchem, 521 U.S. at 625
(“Predominance is a test readily met in certain cases alleging . . . violations of the antitrust
laws.”); Rohlfing v. Manor Care, Inc., 172 F.R.D. 330, 336–37 (N.D. Ill. 1997) (“The weight of
authority in antitrust cases indicates that the question of the existence of a conspiracy in restraint
of trade is one that is common to all potential plaintiffs, and the importance of this question
usually warrants treating them as a class.”). Indeed, the existence of a conspiracy in violation of
antitrust laws “is the prototypical example of an issue where common questions predominate,
because it is much more efficient to have a single trial on the alleged conspiracy rather than
thousands of identical trials all alleging identical conspiracies based on identical evidence.”
Kleen Prods. LLC v. Int’l Paper, 306 F.R.D. 585, 594 (N.D. Ill. 2015), aff’d, 831 F.3d 919 (7th
Cir. 2016).
Defendants insist that there are numerous individual issues as to when, where, and how
each Defendant participated in the alleged conspiracy that preclude a finding of predominance.
The Court finds two flaws in Defendants’ arguments on this point. First, Defendants improperly
conflate the existence of individualized proof as to each Defendant’s conduct with the need for
individualized inquiries. While the evidence might vary as to the nature of each Defendant’s
participation in the conspiracy, the same evidence will be relied upon by Plaintiffs and members
of the class. See, e.g., Messner, 669 F.3d at 815 (“If, to make a prima facie showing on a given
question, the members of a proposed class will need to present evidence that varies from member
to member, then it is an individual question. If the same evidence will suffice for each member to
make a prima facie showing, then it becomes a common question.” (internal quotation marks
30
omitted)); In re Air Cargo Shipping Servs. Antitrust Litig., No. 06-MD-1175 (JG)(VVP), 2014
on the allegedly unlawful actions of the defendants, not the actions of individual plaintiffs.”).
Second, Defendants’ arguments bear more on whether a conspiracy actually existed; they are
merits arguments that “might entitle them to summary judgment or a verdict in their favor” but
are inapplicable at the class certification stage. Kleen Prods., 306 F.R.D. at 594. At this stage, it
is enough “that the evidence either proving or disproving a conspiracy will be common to the
dispute that the question is common to the class and susceptible to classwide proof. Plaintiffs
have pleaded that the Challenged Restraints are unreasonable restraints of trade under both the
per se and Rule of Reason modes of analysis.6 The Court expresses no view on the proper mode
of analysis at this stage. For class certification purposes, it is enough that the issue can be
decided by evidence common to the class regardless of the applicable mode of analysis.
b. Impact
antitrust plaintiff must also show that they suffered an individual injury, or impact, from the
Sherman Act’s] cause of action; to prevail on the merits, every class member must prove at least
6
Under the Rule of Reason analysis, “the plaintiff carries the burden of showing that an agreement or
contract has an anticompetitive effect on a given market within a given geographic area.” Agnew, 683
F.3d at 335. By contrast, the per se analysis applies where “experience with a particular kind of restraint
enables the Court to predict with confidence that the rule of reason will condemn it” such that it can apply
“a conclusive presumption that the restraint is unreasonable.” Arizona v. Maricopa Cnty. Med. Soc’y, 457
U.S. 332, 344 (1982).
31
some antitrust impact resulting from the alleged violation.” In re Hydrogen Peroxide Antitrust
Litig., 552 F.3d 305, 311 (3d Cir. 2008). Antitrust “impact is often critically important for the
claim that may call for individual, as opposed to common, proof.” Id. Thus, under Rule 23(b)(3),
Plaintiffs must be able to show using common evidence that the Challenged Restraints injured
the members of the proposed Damages Class. Messner, 669 F.3d at 816. At the same time, their
“burden at the class certification stage [is] not to prove the element of antitrust impact, but only
to demonstrate that the element of antitrust impact is capable of proof at trial through evidence
that is common to the class rather than individual to its members.” Id. at 818 (internal quotation
marks omitted). Further, “[d]emonstrating that impact can be proved commonly is a separate
showing from demonstrating that the amount of damages can be proved commonly.” Reed, 268
F.R.D. at 582.
Plaintiffs’ theory of antitrust impact is that the Challenged Restraints maintain and extend
an anticompetitive equilibrium that result in sellers paying inflated commissions in each of the
Covered MLSs. As common evidence of classwide impact, Plaintiffs primarily rely on the expert
opinions of Elhauge and Economides. Among other things, they use Elhauge’s opinions to show
how the Buyer-Broker Commission Rule’s requirement that sellers make blanket unilateral
offers of fixed compensation to buyer-brokers works in conjunction with the other Challenged
incentives that, in turn, cause sellers to offer and pay uniform and supracompetitive commission
rates to buyer-brokers. Then, Economides uses his yardstick methodology to demonstrate how
the seller has paid a supracompetitive rate of commission in at least 99.4% of the class
transactions. Taken together, Plaintiffs contend that Elhauge and Economides’s analyses can be
32
used to show that the Challenged Restraints have impacted nearly all the individual class
transactions.
impact. They largely attack various aspects of Plaintiffs’ experts’ analyses to argue that those
opinions fail to establish that the Challenged Restraints cause an anticompetitive equilibrium that
affects the entire class.7 The Court addresses each of Defendants’ arguments in turn.
Defendants criticize Plaintiffs for their reliance on a steering theory to prove classwide
impact. Briefly, Plaintiffs’ contend that the Challenged Restraints incentivize home sellers and
their listing brokers to offer uniformly supracompetitive rates of commission because buyer-
brokers will steer their clients away from listings that offer less than the standard, artificially
inflated rates. Yet Defendants claim that Plaintiffs have no basis to assert that such steering
incentives would not exist absent the Challenged Restraints. Instead, they claim that even in the
but-for world, buyer-brokers would continue to want to be paid more rather than less, and
therefore sellers would continue to offer similar rates of commission to ensure an adequate pool
For purposes of the predominance inquiry, the Court must “investigate[] the realism of
[Plaintiffs’] injury . . . model in light of [Defendants’] counterarguments, and to that end [take]
evidence.” Parko v. Shell Oil Co., 739 F.3d 1083, 1086 (7th Cir. 2014). At best, Defendants
identify reasons to doubt Plaintiffs’ steering theory; such doubts go to the merits and are not a
7
At times, Defendants seem to suggest that Plaintiffs must have common evidence showing impact to
every single member of the class. Any such suggestion is incorrect. Suchanek, 764 F.3d at 757 (“If the
court thought that no class can be certified until proof exists that every member has been harmed, it was
wrong.”).
33
basis to deny class certification. Even in the abstract, it makes sense that the Challenged
Restraints would facilitate steering not only by requiring all MLS listings to include a single, set
offer of compensation, but also by allowing buyer-brokers to filter listings based on the offered
compensation while keeping buyers in the dark and severely restricting negotiations over buyer-
broker commissions.
abstract economic theorizing, Plaintiffs offer real-world evidence supporting the presence of
steering in residential real estate transactions. Most prominently, Elhauge analyzes data
regarding commission rates in the Covered MLSs and observes that commissions clustered
around standard rates in each Covered MLS. During the class period, at least 90% of home sales
standard rates. (Elhauge Report ¶ 201 & tbl. 8.) And 94% of sales in all Covered MLSs
compensated buyer-brokers at rates of between 2.4% and 3.0%, with 85.5% of commissions in
the Covered MLSs paid at one of four rates within that range: 2.4%, 2.5%, 2.8%, and 3.0%.
(Pls.’ Resp. to Defs.’ Mot. to Exclude Experts, Ex. 2, Elhauge Rebuttal Report ¶ 109, Dkt. No.
346-3.)
In response, Defendants point to variations in the data across the Covered MLSs to claim
that Elhauge’s clustering data actually evidences the individualized nature of the purported
steering incentives. For example, Defendants observe that the most common rate of commission
is offered in about 95% of transactions in the MLS serving Houston, whereas the most common
rate in the MLS serving Ohio and West Virginia is offered in only 39% of transactions. (Elhauge
Report ¶ 201 & tbl. 8.) Further, Defendants note that the median buyer-broker commission rate
in a given Covered MLS ranges from 2.4% to 3.0%, and assert that those variations show that
34
individual sellers value buyer-brokers differently. Yet, by themselves, those variations do not
create individualized issues of impact. “Neither a variety of prices nor negotiated prices is an
impediment to class certification if it appears that plaintiffs may be able to prove at trial
that . . . the price range was affected generally.” In re NASDAQ Market-Makers Antitrust Litig.,
169 F.R.D. 493, 523 (S.D.N.Y. 1996); see also In re Bromine Antitrust Litig., 203 F.R.D. 403,
415 (S.D. Ind. 2001) (“A wide range of . . . prices does not make it impossible to use common
proof to demonstrate impact.”). Consequently, that the effects of the alleged steering manifest
themselves somewhat differently across Covered MLS does not detract from Plaintiffs’ evidence
tending to show that steering inflates the commission-rate baseline across all Covered MLSs,
Plaintiffs also note that Elhauge’s expert opinions regarding steering incentives in the
residential real estate industry have been echoed by the Department of Justice and the Federal
Trade Commission. (Elhauge Report ¶¶ 191–92.) Finally, Plaintiffs highlight evidence showing
that Corporate Defendants themselves train brokers to wield the risk of steering against those
sellers who seek to pay lower rates of commission. Consistent with that training, Plaintiffs have
proffered evidence that tends to show that brokers affiliated with Corporate Defendants’ brands
do, in fact, tell sellers that reducing commissions below the standard rates for their market could
Thus, the Court finds that the evidence supports the plausibility of Plaintiffs’ contention
that the Challenged Restraints create steering incentives. Further, the evidence is common to the
class, since all class members sold their homes in MLSs subject to the Challenged Restraints.
35
ii. Predictions of Buyer-Broker Use in the But-For World
Next, Defendants argue that Plaintiffs’ theory of impact improperly relies on Elhauge’s
unfounded predictions regarding buyer-broker use in a but-for world lacking the Challenged
Restraints. Specifically, Defendants assert that Plaintiffs cannot prove on a classwide basis that
buyers would stop using buyer-brokers in the but-for world and, similarly, cannot prove that
would never be used in a but-for world and that sellers would never pay for them. As discussed
above in connection with Defendants’ Daubert motion, Elhauge only opines that the Challenged
Restraints encouraged overconsumption of buyer-brokers and that buyers would use buyer-
brokers less frequently in the but-for world. And for those buyers in the but-for world who did
use buyer-brokers, sellers would either not pay those buyers’ commissions or would pay a
significantly reduced rate. Elhauge adequately explains the reasoning behind his predictions as to
both buyers’ use of buyer-brokers and sellers’ willingness to pay for those services on the
buyers’ behalf. And Plaintiffs’ theory of classwide impact is not that class members were forced
to pay commissions that they would not have paid absent the Challenged Restraints; it is only
that the Challenged Restraints artificially inflated the commissions above what the class would
individualized question, Defendants tout the invaluable services provided by buyer-brokers that
buyers need but cannot receive from online services such as Zillow. Defendants also discuss the
reasons why sellers in the but-for world may still be inclined to pay for their buyers’ brokers. A
jury may well find compelling Defendants’ evidence and arguments regarding the benefits of
36
buyer-brokers and sellers’ incentives to cover those costs. But that simply underscores the point
that the correctness of Elhauge’s predictions regarding buyer-broker use in the but-for world is a
matter for the jury. Notably, Defendants’ evidence that buyer-broker use would be unchanged in
the but-for world is itself common to the class. That Defendants rely on common evidence to
disprove Elhauge’s predictions demonstrates the existence of a common question. See, e.g.,
Kleen Prods., 306 F.R.D. at 594 (explaining that the defendants did not demonstrate a lack of
common proof where their own evidence disproving an issue is common to the class); Foreman
v. PRA III, LLC, No. 05 C 3372, 2007 WL 704478, at *11 (N.D. Ill. Mar. 5, 2007) (explaining
that the predominance requirement “is met when there exists generalized evidence that proves or
marks omitted)).
Prior to its adoption of the Challenged Restraints, the NAR’s rules codified the practice
of subagency whereby real estate agents for buyers acted as subagents of seller-brokers and were
paid for by the sellers. But in the decades before the NAR formalized the practice, the subagency
system was widely used for residential real estate sales throughout the United States. While
Elhauge acknowledges that history, Defendants fault him for failing to square the long-standing
practice of sellers paying for their buyers’ brokers with his conclusion that sellers would no
involvement in shaping historical compensation practices in the real estate market. Moreover,
those earlier practices were themselves subject to antitrust scrutiny. See, e.g., United States v.
Nat’l Ass’n of Real Estate Bds., 339 U.S. 485 (1950). In any case, whether historical broker
37
compensation practice disproves Plaintiffs’ contention that most sellers would not compensate
buyer-brokers in the but-for world goes to the merits of Plaintiffs’ claims. For purposes of the
United States is common to a class consisting of homeowners who sold homes in various
In his expert report, Elhauge discusses how the Challenged Restraints resulted in the
adoption of so-called “hogging” provisions in listing agreements between sellers and seller-
brokers. Where a listing contains a hogging provision, the seller-broker may keep any portion of
the commission that is not paid to the buyer-broker. Going back to the example of a listing
agreement calling for a 6% total commission to be split evenly between the buyer and seller
brokers, if the buyer managed to negotiate their broker’s commission down from 3% to 1% , the
2% difference would not go back to the seller—who might then be inclined to reduce the home’s
sales price accordingly. Instead, the difference is retained by the seller-broker who now receives
a 5% commission. Elhauge opines that such hogging provisions further reduce the incentive to
negotiate commissions even within narrow bounds permitted by the Challenged Restraints. Yet
he also acknowledges that the listing agreements for around 11% of transactions in the Covered
MLSs did not contain a hogging provision but instead actually provided for variable rate
commissions based on whether the buyer used a buyer-broker.8 (Elhauge Report ¶ 208.)
reveals that individualized inquiries would be necessary to determine which class members’
8
Elhauge notes that while 11% of Covered MLS transactions featured listing agreements with variable-
rate commission provisions, the data also reflects that only 1.6% of Covered MLS transactions featured
variable-rate commissions and no separate buyer-broker. (Elhauge Report ¶ 208.)
38
listing agreements would have included a variable-rate provision in the but-for world. But if
Elhauge is correct that hogging provisions are a byproduct of the Challenged Restraints, it would
be self-evident that provisions allocating unpaid buyer-broker commissions would not be widely
Defendants claim that Economides’s yardstick analysis cannot show classwide impact. Because
the Court has already found Economides’s opinions admissible, Defendants’ criticisms of his
choice of yardsticks or other aspects of his methodology should be presented to the jury and do
Defendants also argue that Economides’s assumption that all class members would have
paid a 1.55% buyer-broker commission fails to account for real-world variations both within and
among the Covered MLSs and cannot be used to show common proof of impact. However,
Economides’s 1.55% yardstick commission rate was calculated for use in Economides’s
commissions paid across the Covered MLSs with those paid in the yardsticks, which led him to
conclude that nearly all class transactions were impacted. Again, Economides’s methodology is
sufficiently reliable and capable of measuring classwide impact. That showing suffices at the
Defendants assert that Plaintiffs’ claim that the Challenged Restraints artificially inflate
buyer-broker commission rates is contradicted by the evidence from the Northwest MLS. The
Northwest MLS is a non-NAR affiliated MLS (and thus not one of the Covered MLSs), that
39
recently stopped requiring listings to include an offer of compensation to buyer-brokers. Since
that rule change went into effect, 99.75% of sellers continue to offer compensation to buyer-
brokers, and 95% of those offers are at rates exceeding 2%. A similar outcome can be seen with
respect to the West Penn MLS, which has not required sellers to offer compensation to buyer-
brokers since 2013. Defendants claim that the data from these U.S.-based MLSs reveal the
individualized nature of the inquiries concerning why a given seller offers compensation to
While Defendants accuse Plaintiffs’ experts of ignoring evidence from the Northwest
MLS and West Penn MLS, Elhauge’s rebuttal report does address Defendants’ expert’s
discussion of the outcomes in those MLSs and explains why he found the evidence unpersuasive.
Among other things, Elhauge notes that the Northwest MLS did not entirely drop its version of
the Buyer-Broker Commission Rule but instead modified its requirement that listings contain a
¶¶ 40–41.) In other words, the Northwest MLS still requires sellers to make offers of
compensation, it just allows them to offer nothing whereas they previously had to offer at least 1
cent. The same is true as to the West Penn MLS. (Id. ¶ 59.)
The Court does not find the evidence of modest modifications made by two MLSs to one
through common proof. Certainly, Defendants may rely on evidence and expert opinions
regarding the Northwest MLS and West Penn MLS to rebut Plaintiffs’ claims as to the
Challenged Restraints’ impact. But even if that evidence proves persuasive, it reflects not the
existence of individual questions as to impact but rather the lack of impact—i.e., that the
Challenged Restraints do not cause the artificial inflation of buyer-broker commissions. Put
40
another way, if the rule changes in the Northwest MLS and West Penn MLS demonstrate the
absence of anticompetitive effect, that finding would apply equally across the class. And again, a
Finally, Defendants contend that Plaintiffs fail to propose a method that accounts for the
fact that the Challenged Restraints may actually benefit individual class members. They assert
that, under the Challenged Restraints, the cost of buyer-brokers is effectively added to the sales
price, whereas if buyers had to finance that cost on their own, it could cause a reduction in
housing prices. In addition, Defendants note that many class members may have been both buyer
and seller, such that any harm those class members incurred in paying buyer-broker commissions
All of Defendants’ arguments as to the benefits to the class are grounded in the class
members’ ability to pass on the cost of buyer-broker commissions to the buyer by including that
cost in their home’s sales price. But the Supreme Court has barred antitrust violators from
relying on such a “passing-on defense.” Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 392
U.S. 481, 494 (1968). Building on Hanover, the Supreme Court concluded in Illinois Brick Co. v.
Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 736 (1977), that antitrust plaintiffs may not recover on a pass-on theory of
damages. Under Illinois Brick, “only a purchaser who purchased goods directly from the
monopolist (or cartel member) can claim damages” and “[t]hat purchaser is entitled to the full
value of the damages stemming from the overcharge, even if it passed on some or all of the
Marion Healthcare, LLC v. Becton Dickinson & Co., 952 F.3d 832, 838 (7th Cir. 2020).
41
As this Court explained in a related antitrust challenge to the Challenged Restraints
brought by home buyers, it is the home sellers who are direct purchasers of buyer-broker
services, and any commission costs borne by buyers are simply “passed through” to them by
virtue of those costs being “baked into” their home’s purchase price. Leeder v. Nat’l Ass’n of
Realtors, 601 F. Supp. 3d 301, 309 (N.D. Ill. 2022). Hanover Shoe and Illinois Brick
demonstrate that there is no need for any individualized inquiries as to how the Damages Class,
consisting of direct purchasers, may have been able to benefit from their ability to pass on the
cost of buyer-broker commissions. See Messner, 669 F.3d at 823 & n.12 (“[U]nder Illinois Brick,
the ability of a direct purchaser to pass on higher costs to others does not undermine its ability to
sue under the Clayton Act.”). Rather, antitrust impact “occurs and is complete when the
defendant sells at the illegally high price (even if the buyer is only an intermediate buyer).”
Sports Racing Servs., Inc. v. Sports Car Club of Am., Inc., 131 F.3d 874, 883 (10th Cir. 1997)
(citing Hanover Shoe, 392 U.S. at 489)); see also Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co., 405 U.S. 251, 262
n.14 (1972) (“Courts will not go beyond the fact of . . . injury to determine whether the victim of
the overcharge has partially recouped its loss in some other way . . . .”).
The Court concludes that Plaintiffs have shown the existence of common questions
concerning antitrust impact that can be answered with common evidence such as Elhauge and
Economides’s expert opinions. Defendants fail to identify any individualized issues to rebut a
finding of predominance, as their arguments mostly concern the merits or otherwise address
Further, the two cases relied upon by Defendants to show that the issue of impact cannot
be resolved on a classwide basis are inapposite. First, Nichols v. Mobile Board of Realtors, Inc.,
42
675 F.2d 671 (5th Cir. 1982), similar to here, alleged an antitrust conspiracy to fix prices in the
real estate brokerage services market. However, the Fifth Circuit upheld a district court’s order
decertifying a class whose members paid purportedly inflated commissions to a broker, finding a
“fatal defect” preventing class certification in the “absence of any viable theory of generalized
proof for the fact of damage.” Id. at 678–79. There is no similar defect here, as Plaintiffs have
demonstrated that they can show classwide impact through Elhauge’s and Economides’s
opinions. Second, in Blades v. Monsanto Co., 400 F.3d 562 (8th Cir. 2005), the Eighth Circuit
found that class certification was not warranted despite evidence of a price-fixing agreement
where the defendants’ performance of the alleged agreement was “not across the board” and the
plaintiffs’ expert could not fill in the resulting gap. Id. at 573–75. By contrast, Plaintiffs’
evidence in this case tends to show that the Challenged Restraints inflated commission rates in
all Covered MLSs, and Elhauge is able to show a high risk of impact in nearly all individual
class transactions.
In short, Defendants cannot show that individual questions regarding impact predominate
over the common issues capable of common proof identified by Plaintiffs. Consequently, the
Court finds that Plaintiffs have satisfied the predominance requirement as to antitrust impact.
c. Damages
Defendants claim that there are flaws in Plaintiffs’ theory of damages that preclude class
certification. Of course, “[i]t is well established that the presence of individualized questions
regarding damages does not prevent certification under Rule 23(b)(3).” Messner, 669 F.3d at
815. Rather, at the class certification stage, Plaintiffs simply need to show that “there is a
classwide method for proving damages, and if not, whether individual damage determinations
will overwhelm the common questions on liability and impact.” Kleen Prods., 831 F.3d at 929.
43
And the Seventh Circuit has recognized that “in complicated antitrust cases plaintiffs are
damages.” Loeb Indus., Inc. v. Sumitomo Corp., 306 F.3d 469, 493 (7th Cir. 2002).
Here, Plaintiffs intend to calculate damages using Economides’s formula employing the
1.55% yardstick commission. The Court has already found Economides’s methodology
to claim that Economides’s damages model cannot be used to measure classwide damages
because of a mismatch between Plaintiffs’ theory of impact that claims buyer-broker use would
be rare in the but-for world and their theory of damages that assumes all buyers would have used
buyer-brokers and all class members would have paid their commissions at the 1.55% yardstick
rate.
The Supreme Court has held that “any model supporting a plaintiff’s damages case must
be consistent with its liability case, particularly with respect to the alleged anticompetitive effects
of the violation.” Comcast, 569 U.S. at 35 (internal quotation marks omitted). Put differently,
“Comcast holds that a damages suit cannot be certified to proceed as a class action unless the
damages sought are the result of the class-wide injury that the suit alleges.” Butler v. Sears,
Roebuck & Co., 727 F.3d 796, 799 (7th Cir. 2013). Yet, in Comcast, the Supreme Court was
confronted with a situation where the plaintiffs had proposed four theories of antitrust impact but
the district court only accepted one of those theories and rejected the rest. Comcast, 569 U.S. at
31. Nonetheless, the district court found that damages could be established using an expert’s
model that “did not isolate damages resulting from any one theory of antitrust impact” but
instead “assumed the validity of all four theories of antitrust impact initially advanced” by the
plaintiffs. Id. at 32, 36. After the Third Circuit affirmed the decision to certify the class, the
44
Supreme Court reversed it, finding that the expert’s “model failed to measure damages resulting
from the particular antitrust injury” on which liability was premised. Id. at 36.
By contrast, here, Plaintiffs have only a single theory of impact: that the Challenged
Restraints maintained and extended an anticompetitive equilibrium and caused the class to pay
“asserts only one theory of liability that cuts across the entire class.” Ploss as Tr. for Harry Ploss
Tr. DTD 8/16/1993 v. Kraft Foods Grp., Inc., 431 F. Supp. 3d 1003, 1018 (N.D. Ill. 2020). All
members of the Damages Class claim to have been damaged by paying inflated commissions as
a result of the Challenged Restraints, and Economides’s damages model aims to measure the
extent of their overpayment. See Butler, 727 F.3d at 800 (“[I]t was not the existence of multiple
theories in [Comcast] that precluded class certification; it was the plaintiffs’ failure to base all
damages they sought on the antitrust impact—the injury—of which the plaintiffs were
complaining.”). In turn, Plaintiffs seek to recover damages equivalent to the amount of the
class’s overpayment as opposed to a full refund of the buyer-broker commissions. That choice is
fully consistent with the bottom line of Plaintiffs’ theory of impact that nearly all class members
paid overinflated buyer-broker commissions, notwithstanding the fact that their theory also
suggests that most members were further harmed by having to pay any buyer-broker
commissions at all.
Certainly, in conservatively assuming that all class members would have both sold to
buyers using buyer-brokers and covered the buyer-brokers’ commissions, Economides’s model
likely leaves some damages on the table when viewed in conjunction with Plaintiffs’ theory of
impact. Nonetheless, Plaintiffs make a permissible strategic choice to seek only the damages that
they believe they can efficiently prove with certainty—the supracompetitive portion of the
45
class’s commission payments—and forgo the more complex task of determining which class
members are entitled to a full refund.9 Perhaps Plaintiffs’ choice might give a class member
reason to opt out of the class if they believe they are entitled to recover the entirety of the buyer-
broker commission. Smith v. Fam. Video Movie Club, Inc., 311 F.R.D. 469, 475 (N.D. Ill. 2015)
(“[A]ny putative class member who wants to seek compensation [not captured by the damages
model] will be free to opt out of the class and pursue those claims on an individual basis, and the
class notice should contain language informing the putative class members that this is the case.”).
But Defendants cannot defeat class certification by insisting that, if found liable, they should owe
the class more money than the figure produced by Economides’s damages model. See BCS
Servs., Inc. v. BG Invs., Inc., 728 F.3d 633, 640 (7th Cir. 2013) (“Once the plaintiff proves injury,
broad latitude is allowed in quantifying damages, especially when the defendant’s own conduct
impedes quantification.” (internal quotation marks omitted)); Smith, 311 F.R.D. at 481–82
(rejecting the defendant’s contention that the plaintiffs “are obligated to seek compensation for
every minute they may have worked without pay” in holding that predominance was met, even
though the plaintiffs’ method for calculating the class’s underpaid wages failed to capture
compensation for unrecorded off-the-clock work). Had Plaintiffs relied on a damages model that
assumed all class members would have paid nothing to buyer-brokers, Defendants would likely
finding of predominance either. They argue that Economides’s model fails to account for the fact
9
Had Plaintiffs chosen to seek damages in the form of a full refund of buyer-broker commissions, class
certification would not be precluded simply because individual inquiries might be necessary to identify
those few class members that would have paid buyer-broker commissions in the but-for world. See Bell,
800 F.3d at 379 (“The fact that the plaintiffs might require individualized relief or not share all questions
in common does not preclude certification of a class.”).
46
that the buyer-broker commissions are usually incorporated into a home’s sales price, such that
there would be a commensurate decrease in home prices in a but-for world where buyers pay
their own commissions, thereby leaving sellers in the same financial position. That claim is
simply a version of the passing-on defense barred by Hanover Shoe. Next, Defendants fault
Economides’s model for failing to account for variations among buyer-broker commission rates
within and across the Covered MLSs. But that does not appear to be the case. Economides’s
formulas measure the difference between the commissions actually paid and the amount the class
would have paid in the but-for world. Thus, under the formulas, class members who paid a
higher rate of commission will have higher damages and vice versa. Finally, Defendants claim
that Economides’s 1.55% yardstick rate is overly reliant on averaging. As already noted, the use
of estimates or analysis does not render a damages calculation unreasonable, and the quality of
At bottom, Defendants’ issues with Plaintiffs’ damages model go to the merits and do not
prevent certification of the Damages Class. And because Plaintiffs have shown that common
questions predominate as to each element of their claim under § 1 of the Sherman Act, the Court
2. Superiority
In addition to predominance, Rule 23(b)(3) also requires that the Court determine
whether a class action is the superior way to resolve Plaintiffs’ lawsuit. “The superiority inquiry
requires courts to assess the fairness and efficiency of class adjudication ‘with an eye toward
other available methods.’” Quinn v. Specialized Loan Servicing, LLC, 331 F.R.D. 126, 133 (N.D.
Ill. 2019) (quoting Mullins v. Direct Digit., LLC, 795 F.3d 654, 664 (7th Cir. 2015)). Superiority
will be found “when a class action would achieve economies of time, effort, and expense, and
47
promote uniformity of decision as to persons similarly situated, without sacrificing procedural
fairness or bringing about other undesirable results.” Wilkins v. Just Energy Grp., Inc., 308
F.R.D. 170, 190 (N.D. Ill. 2015) (internal quotation marks and alteration omitted).
Defendants’ sole basis for opposing superiority is their contention that mini-trials will be
necessary for each class member to resolve the various individual issues they raised in
connection with the predominance requirement. But the Court has already found that such
individualized inquiries will not be necessary or will not predominate. “[T]he predominance and
superiority inquiry are intertwined: generally, the more that common issues predominate, the
more likely that a class action is the superior vehicle for deciding the controversy.” In re
Evanston Nw. Corp. Antitrust Litig., No. 07-cv-04446, 2013 WL 6490152, at *3 (N.D. Ill. Dec.
10, 2013). Consequently, the Court’s findings above as to predominance weigh strongly in favor
of finding that a class action is the superior format for the litigation. Johnson v. Diakon Logistics,
No. 16-cv-06776, 2020 WL 405636, at *7 (N.D. Ill. Jan. 23, 2020). Moreover, the large number
of potential class members indicates the superiority of the class action device here. In re Steel
Antitrust Litig., 2015 WL 5304629, at *12. For these reasons, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have
Because certification is proper pursuant to Rule 23(b)(3), the Court grants Plaintiffs’
10
In finding that Plaintiffs have satisfied each of Rule 23(a)’s four requirements and Rule 23(b)(3)’s
predominance and superiority requirements, this Court’s decision is in accord with the decision of the
district court in Burnett v. National Association of Realtors, No. 19-CV-00332-SRB, 2022 WL 1203100
(W.D. Mo. Apr. 22, 2022), which also involved an alleged antitrust conspiracy based on the adoption and
enforcement of the Challenged Restraints. There, the district court granted the plaintiffs’ motion to certify
classes compromised of home sellers who sold a home listed on one of four MLSs covering the Missouri
region and paid a commission to the buyer-broker. The district court’s decision in Burnett provides
additional support for class certification here.
48
C. Rule 23(b)(2)
The Court next considers Plaintiffs’ request for certification of an Injunctive Relief Class
pursuant to Rule 23(b)(2). “The key to the (b)(2) class is the indivisible nature of the injunctive
or declaratory remedy warranted—the notion that the conduct is such that it can be enjoined or
declared unlawful only as to all of the class members or as to none of them.” Wal-Mart, 564 U.S.
at 360 (internal quotation marks omitted). Thus, a Rule 23(b)(2) class may only be certified
“when a single injunction or declaratory judgment would provide relief to each member of the
class.” Id. On the other hand, “[i]t does not authorize class certification when each individual
class member would be entitled to a different injunction or declaratory judgment against the
defendant.” Id.
Through the Injunctive Relief Class, Plaintiffs hope to obtain an injunction barring
Defendants from continuing to violate the antitrust laws by maintaining and enforcing the
Challenged Restraints. Unlike the Damages Class, which consists of home sellers who sold their
homes during the class period, the Injunctive Relief Class consists of current homeowners whose
homes are currently listed for sale or intend to list their homes for sale in the future. Yet
Defendants contend that Plaintiffs, each past home sellers, do not have standing to represent a
class consisting of present or future home sellers. To obtain injunctive relief, however, an
antitrust plaintiff “need only demonstrate a significant threat of injury from an impending
violation of the antitrust laws or from a contemporary violation likely to continue or recur.”
Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Rsch., Inc., 395 U.S. 100, 130 (1969). All but one of the named
Plaintiffs here have expressly indicated that they are likely to sell homes on a Covered MLS
again in the near future. (Pls.’ Corrected Mem. in Supp. of Class Certification, Ex. 5, Class
49
Representative Decls., Dkt. No. 306-5.) They therefore have standing to represent the Injunctive
Relief Class.
Plaintiffs request a single injunction that provides an equal benefit to every member of the class.
And courts have found that Rule 23(b)(2) is particularly applicable “when members of a putative
class seek uniform injunctive or declaratory relief from policies or practices that are generally
applicable to the class as a whole.” B.K. by next friend Tinsley v. Snyder, 922 F.3d 957, 971 (9th
Cir. 2019). Nonetheless, Defendants contend that certification pursuant to Rule 23(b)(2) is
improper because Plaintiffs are primarily seeking damages in this lawsuit rather than injunctive
relief.
It is true that Rule 23(b)(2) “does not extend to cases in which the appropriate final relief
committee’s note to 1966 amendment; see also Wal-Mart, 564 U.S. at 360 (holding that claims
for monetary relief may not be certified under Rule 23(b)(2) where “the monetary relief is not
incidental to the injunctive or declaratory relief”). However, Plaintiffs emphasize that the
Injunctive Relief Class seeks no monetary damages; that form of relief is sought only by the
Damages Class, for which Plaintiffs have sought and now been granted certification pursuant to
Rule 23(b)(3). While the Supreme Court stated in Wal-Mart that Rule 23(b)(2) “does not
authorize class certification when each class member would be entitled to an individualized
award of monetary damages,” 564 U.S. at 360–61, it was addressing a class that attempted to use
Rule 23(b)(2) as a vehicle to obtain both injunctive and monetary relief. Jermyn v. Best Buy
Stores, LP, 276 F.R.D. 167, 173 (S.D.N.Y. 2011). Wal-Mart does not speak to the certification of
separate Rule 23(b)(2) and Rule 23(b)(3) classes. Jermyn, 276 F.R.D. at 174 (“In this case,
50
unlike [Wal-Mart], a (b)(2) class is not seeking monetary relief, but only an injunction against
further statutory violations. It is a separately certified (b)(3) class that seeks money damages.”).
Moreover, the Seventh Circuit has indicated its approval of separate certification of damages and
injunctive relief classes. See, e.g., Chi. Teachers Union, Loc. No. 1 v. Bd. of Educ. of City of
Chi., 797 F.3d 426, 443 (7th Cir. 2015) (approving certification of a Rule 23(b)(2) class and a
request for certification of a Rule 23(b)(3) class that “siphoned th[e] portion of the complaint that
requested monetary relief and individual remedies”); Lemon v. Int’l Union of Operating Eng’rs,
Loc. No. 139, 216 F.3d 577, 581 (7th Cir. 2000) (“The district court could certify a Rule 23(b)(2)
class for the portion of the case addressing equitable relief and a Rule 23(b)(3) class for the
Thus, because the Injunctive Relief Class asks only for a single injunction that applies
generally to the class and there are Plaintiffs with standing to represent the class, certification is
proper under Rule 23(b)(2). Moreover, the existence of a separate Damages Class seeking
monetary relief does preclude certification. For these reasons, the Court grants Plaintiffs’ motion
D. Class Definition
Earlier in this case, Defendants HomeServices of America, Inc., HSF Affiliates, LLC,
BHH Affiliates, LLC, and The Long & Foster Companies, Inc. (collectively, “HomeServices”)
moved to strike from the class definition those class members who had signed a listing
Court denied HomeServices’s motion, finding that the matter would be better addressed at the
51
HomeServices’s contention that the class definitions should exclude those members whose
HomeServices does not dispute that none of the constituent HomeServices entities are
signatories to the unnamed class members’ listing agreements; those agreements are between the
unnamed class members from the class definitions raises three main questions. First, can the
Court decide the threshold issue of whether the unnamed class members agreed to arbitrate this
dispute or did the arbitration agreements delegate this determination to an arbitrator? Second, can
HomeServices enforce the arbitration agreements against the unnamed class members even
though they are nonsignatories to the relevant agreements? And third, even if HomeServices can
enforce the arbitration agreements, does that compel exclusion of the unnamed class members
from participating in a class action that would hold jointly and severally liable not only
HomeServices but the other alleged co-conspirator Defendants with whom the unnamed class
members have no colorable relationship? Both parties frame these questions as susceptible to a
Although the parties often argue as if the facts and the applicable law are the same across
the unnamed class members, that is not the case. Rather, the relevant arbitration provisions are
not identical and many vary materially in language and substance. Further, the brokerages that
included arbitration provisions in their listing agreements are located throughout the United
States. Thus, the answer to any one of the above three questions could vary depending on the
language of the particular arbitration provision and the applicable state’s contract law. See, e.g.,
AT&T Mobility LLC v. Concepcion, 563 U.S. 333, 339 (2011) (“[C]ourts must place arbitration
11
None of the named Plaintiffs’ listing agreements contained an arbitration provision.
52
agreements on an equal footing with other contracts and enforce them according to their terms.”
(citations omitted)); Sosa v. Onfido, Inc., 8 F.4th 631, 637 (7th Cir. 2021) (“A nonparty’s right to
enforce an arbitration agreement is governed by state law.”). Neither Plaintiffs nor Defendants
grapple with these important factual and legal differences in any real depth.12
file a separate motion regarding their request to exclude from the class definitions the unnamed
members whose listing agreements contained an arbitration provision. The Court believes that is
the best course. See, e.g., Garcia v. Jcpenney Corp., No. 12-cv-3687, 2016 WL 878203, at *7
(N.D. Ill. Mar. 8, 2016) (“[T]he sensible course in this case is to decide whether to certify the
class without considering the possibility of arbitration and then allow [the defendant], if it so
chooses, to file its motion to compel arbitration.”). Thus, the Court will certify Plaintiffs’
Damages Class and Injunctive Relief Class, but if HomeServices wishes to narrow one or both
classes, it may do so by separate motion. And, of course, the parties’ briefs in support of that
motion should be responsive to the concerns laid out by the Court here.
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, Defendants’ motion to exclude the expert opinions of Elhauge
and Economides (Dkt. No. 318) is denied, and Plaintiffs’ motion for class certification (Dkt. No.
301) is granted. The Court certifies the following class under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
23(b)(3):
Home sellers who paid a commission between March 6, 2015, and December 31,
2020, to a brokerage affiliated with a Corporate Defendant in connection with the
sale of residential real estate listed on a Covered MLS and in a covered jurisdiction.
Excluded from the class are (i) sales of residential real estate for a price below
12
The Court does not exclude the possibility that the issue can be resolved the same as to all unnamed
class members. At this time, the Court simply requires further elaboration of the issue before it can
decide.
53
$56,500, (ii) sales of residential real estate at auction, and (iii) employees, officers,
and directors of defendants, the presiding Judge in this case, and the Judge’s staff.
In addition, the Court certifies the following class under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
23(b)(2):
Current and future owners of residential real estate in the covered jurisdictions who
are presently listing or will in the future list their home for sale on a Covered MLS.
Excluded from the class are (i) sales of residential real estate for a price below
$56,500, (ii) sales of residential real estate at auction, and (iii) employees, officers,
and directors of defendants, the presiding Judge in this case, and the Judge’s staff.
The Court appoints Plaintiffs Christopher Moehrl, Michael Cole, Steve Darnell, Jack Ramey,
Daniel Umpa, and Jane Ruh as class representatives and appoints Cohen Milstein Sellers & Toll
PLLC, Hagens Berman Sobol Shapiro LLP, and Susman Godfrey LLP as co-lead class counsel.
ENTERED:
54