(We Need To Print This) World-Bank-New-Book PDF
(We Need To Print This) World-Bank-New-Book PDF
(We Need To Print This) World-Bank-New-Book PDF
The
Long Term
Edited by
Steven Pennings
Growth Model
Norman V. Loayza
Applications
Fundamentals,
Extensions, and
The Long Term Growth Model
i
The Long Term Growth Model
Fundamentals, Extensions, and Applications
Edited by
Norman V. Loayza
Steven Pennings
iii
© 2022 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW
Washington DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000
Internet: www.worldbank.org
This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions
expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments
they represent.
The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy, completeness, or currency of the data included in this work and does not assume
responsibility for any errors, omissions, or discrepancies in the information, or liability with respect to the use of or failure to use the
information, methods, processes, or conclusions set forth. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on
any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the
endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.
Nothing herein shall constitute or be construed or considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of
The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.
Requests for permissions for the following chapters should be addressed to the relevant copyright holders or authorized licensors:
Chapter 6: First published as: Jeong, H. 2018. “Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development
Policy.” The Korean Economic Review, 34 (2): 237–265. Reproduced with permission. Further permission required for reuse.
Chapter 8: First published as: Devadas, S., I. Elbadawi, and N. V. Loayza. 2021. “Growth in Syria: losses from the war and potential
recovery in the aftermath.” Middle East Development Journal 13(2): 215–244. Reproduced with permission. Further permission required
for reuse.
Chapter 9: First published as: Hevia, C., and N.V. Loayza. 2012. “Saving and Growth in Egypt.” Middle East Development Journal, 4(1).
Reproduced with permission. Further permission required for reuse.
Cover photo: Anonymous, Trappen van Strada Reale in Valetta, Malta. 1900–1910, photochrom. Rijksmuseum, Amsterdam.
Report design: Spaeth Hill.
Contents
Acknowledgments xiii
Introduction 1
Motivation 1
Origins 2
This book 2
References 5
Boxes
5.1 Republic of Korea’s Economic Growth Experience 146
5.2 Rebalancing Components while Keeping I/Y Unchanged—A Comparison of the Effects
of IG/Y and IP/Y on GDP Growth 149
Figures
1.1 The Effect of Growth on Poverty (with unchanged inequality) 22
2.1 Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI)—Correlation with Per Capita
Income and Infrastructure Quality Score 40
2.2 Measured TFP Growth from LTGM-PC (ϕ = 0.17) Based on Growth
Accounting versus Actual TFP Growth 46
2.3 Incremental Output Growth from a 1 ppt increase in Public Investment in the LTGM-PC
(congestion, ζ = 1) 50
2.4 Incremental Output Growth from a 1 ppt increase in Private Investment in the LTGM-PC
(congestion, ζ = 1) 51
2.5 Private Investment Versus Public Investment in the LTGM-PC - Differences in Short-Run
Incremental Output Growth (ϕ = 0.17, congestion, ζ = 1) 52
2.6 Private Investment Versus Public Investment in the LTGM-PC - Differences in Long-Run
Incremental Output Growth (ϕ = 0.17, congestion, ζ = 1 ) 53
2.7 Incremental Output Growth from a 5-ppt. Increase in theEfficiency of Public
Investment in the LTGM-PC (congestion, ζ = 1) 56
2.8 Quantity versus Quality of Public Investment 57
3.1 Comparison of Factor Analysis and Principal Component Analysis 69
3.2 Annual TFP Growth Rate for All, OECD, and Developing Countries, Median and
Simple Average by Decade 72
3.3 Annual TFP Growth Rate for Developing Countries, Median and Simple
Average by Region and Decade 73
3.4 Annual TFP Growth Rate for Developing Countries, Average Weighted by
Real GDP by Region and Decade 73
3.5 Median of Subcomponent and Overall Determinant Indexes for All,
OECD, and Developing Countries by Decade 74
3.6 Variance Decomposition of TFP Growth Rate Corresponding to the Determinant
Subcomponent Indexes (by decade for all, OECD, and developing countries,
controlling for initial TFP and time effects) 76
3.7 Simulated Average TFP Growth rate by Region (with the scenario that a
country increases its overall determinant index to the highest index among
developing countries in its region over 15 years) 79
3.8 Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region (with the that a country replicates the
annual index change that its benchmark country has had in the last three decades) 80
3.9 Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region and Income Group
(with the scenario that a country increases its overall determinant index to the
highest index among developing countries over 15 years) 81
3.10 Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region and Income Group
(with the scenario that a country replicates the trajectory of the overall index of Korea,
which increases the index the most among all developing countries in the last three decades) 83
3.11 Projected TFP Growth Rates for Peru under Various Scenarios 84
4.1 LTGM Simulation: Baseline GDP Per Capita Growth in Angola:
annual growth rate, percentage 119
vii
Contents
viii
The Long Term Growth Model
ix
Contents
8.13 Distance to Higher Income Group Thresholds Based on GNI Per Capita 235
9.1 Saving and Growth: Average, 1980–2008 240
9.2 Saving and Investment: Average, 1980–2008 241
9.3 Pessimistic Scenario 248
9.4 Moderate Scenario 249
9.5 Optimistic Scenario 250
10.1 Saving and Growth 258
10.2 Saving and Investment 259
10.3 National, Private, and Public Saving in Sri Lanka 259
10.4 National and Domestic Saving in Sri Lanka 260
10.5 National, Private and Public Saving in Sri Lanka 260
10.6 Continuity Scenario 268
10.7 Optimistic Scenario 269
10.8 Reform Scenario 270
10.9 Saving, Investment, and the Current Account under the Reform Scenario 271
10.10 Solow Growth Decomposition under the Reform Scenario 271
Tables
2.1 The Composition of Infrastructure Stocks (Fay and Yepes 2003) 40
2.2 Indicators of Efficient Public Capital Stock – Different Methodologies 42
2.3 Baseline Parameters, Initial Conditions, and Paths of Variables 43
2.4 Elasticity of Output to Public Capital, ϕ (“usefulness”) 45
2.5 Median Values of Baseline Parameters and Paths of Variables by Income Group 48
2.6 Efficiency—Income Group Medians (with ϕ = 0.17; ζ = 1) 54
3.1 Linear Regression Results 77
3.2 Benchmark Countries with the Highest Overall Determinant Index as of 2014 by Region 79
3.3 Benchmark Countries with the Most Increase in the Overall Determinant Index during
1985–2014 by Region 80
4.1 Taxonomy of Fiscal Rules for Government Resource Revenues 103
4.2 Baseline Setup of the LTGM-NR: selected parameters, initial conditions, and trajectories of
exogenous variables (Symbol + indicates the parameter is taken from the standard LTGM) 113
4.3 Baseline Calibration to Angola (Default model): selected parameters, initial conditions, and
trajectories of exogenous variables 118
5.1 Summary of Assumptions for the Malaysia Business-as-Usual Baseline 139
5.2 Investment-to-Output Ratios by Country Income Groups, Average over 2006–2015 (percent) 141
5.3 Understanding the Drivers of Malaysia’s Falling Economic Growth Rates 146
5.4 Scenarios of Weak, Moderate, and Strong Reforms for the Projection of TFP
Growth for 2020–2050 150
6.1 Decomposition of Sources of Korea’s Growth of GDP per Capita (%) 166
6.2 Calibrated Parameter Values from Status-quo Approach 171
7.1 Average Annual Real GDP Growth under Different Scenarios 196
7.2 Average Annual Real GDP Growth under Different Scenarios 201
7.3 Marginal Labor Productivity in Industry and Services (relative to Agriculture) 202
7.4 Distortions Relative to Agriculture and Counterfactual Growth 203
8.1 No-Conflict Baseline Simulation— Values for Parameters, Initial Conditions,
and Projected Variables 215
8.2 No-Conflict Simulation—Upper and Lower Estimates for Projected Variables 216
x
The Long Term Growth Model
xi
Acknowledgments
Many people have made important contributions to make the LTGM project—and this book—possible.
First, we are indebted to a small group of people who helped get the LTGM project off the ground. Constantino
Hevia was key in this area; in collaboration with Norman Loayza, he co-wrote the first version of the pro-
to-LTGM in a policy application to Egypt around a decade ago (which is now chapter 9 in this volume). We
thank Constantino for his insights in formulating the model, many of which still permeate LTGM today. Two
other people helped turn the original application, written in Matlab code for a single country, into an accessible
spreadsheet-based tool for all countries. The first is Vinaya Swaroop, who as the World Bank’s Global Lead for
Growth in the early days of the LTGM project realized the LTGM’s potential and helped fund its development and
encourage its use. The second is Leonardo Garrido, who was Steven Pennings’s main collaborator at the time the
first LTGM toolkit was formed (and had produced his own variant of Hevia and Loayza’s model). Many of the
ideas that make the LTGM spreadsheet accessible and easy to use were Leonardo’s, and he did much of the hard
work in forming the first version of the LTGM spreadsheet with preloaded data for all countries. Diego Barrot
also helped with much of the early data analyses.
The second group of people we would like to thank are those working tirelessly in the background to assist with
the production of this volume and the data for the LTGM project in general. Jorge Guzman assisted with data
collection and spreadsheet maintenance over several years, which fed into the spreadsheets used in many of the
chapters. We are also particularly grateful to Federico Fiuratti who worked tirelessly to format over 100 graphs
and check the chapters in this volume, and took over Jorge’s responsibilities for data collection and spreadsheet
maintenance. We would also especially like to thank GCSTI and GCSDE for providing editing and graphic design
services on a tight timeline.
Third, we would like to thank our collaborators on the chapters of this volume, and those who provided
comments and inputs to them at critical times. This includes Sharmila Devadas, Young Kim, Fabian Mendez,
Arthur Mendes, Jorge Guzman, Rishabh Sinha, Hyeok Jeong, Ibrahim Elbadawi, Constantino Hevia, Brian Pinto,
Farrukh Iqbal, Santiago Herrera, Anushka Thewarapperuma, and Tomoko Wada, as well as many others listed in
the acknowledgments for individual chapters. Aart Kraay provided key inputs into the formation of the poverty
module in chapter 1, as did Luis Servén (Arthur Mendes also provided helpful comments). We would also like
to thank dozens of country economists and government officials—too numerous to list individually—who have
provided comments, suggestions, criticisms, and other feedback in around 50 country-level applications (the
majority of which are not listed in this volume). Many of the LTGM extensions, features, and simulation exercises
were developed in response to these comments.
Finally, we would like to thank the Trust Fund of the Republic of Korea and Anushka Thewarapperuma for
funding the production of this volume, and also for financial support for the development of the LTGM and its
extensions over several years. None of this work would have been possible without their generous support.
xiii
From the standpoint of fighting world poverty, nothing is more important than figuring out
which policies differentiate the fast-growing countries from the slow-growing ones.
Robert Barro (2002)
Introduction1
Norman V. Loayza and Steven Pennings
Motivation
Economic growth is the foundation on which social and economic development rests.2 Although it may not be
a sufficient condition for prosperity, it certainly is a necessary condition. Economic growth is needed to create
jobs and generate income opportunities, particularly in countries where young people are joining the labor
market in increasing numbers.3 Economic growth can foster innovation and entrepreneurship, which in turn
increases future growth, generating a virtuous cycle.4 It can be the foundation of political and social stability,
especially if it is inclusive and sustained.5 Economic growth provides resources for well-managed governments
to build infrastructure, from ports and roads to internet connection hardware and public services, from contract
enforcement to public safety.6
Economic growth is, therefore, the key to poverty alleviation, an essential objective of most, if not all, develop-
ing country governments and international development organizations, such as the World Bank.7 Moreover,
economic growth can contribute to reduced inequality and widespread prosperity if conditions of governance,
inclusivity, and sustainability are met.8
It is not surprising, therefore, that most policy makers around the world care deeply about economic growth.
In fact, virtually all national development plans feature economic growth projections for their countries.9 These
growth projections are often aspirational: they present what the country needs to develop and prosper and,
therefore, tend to be overly ambitious.
Though it is understandable why governments may want to “shoot for the moon” with their growth forecasts,
formulating unrealistic projections is misguided. They may lead to unsustainable levels of public deficit and debt,
as governments may assume that they can grow their way out of debt.10 More generally, unrealistic expectations
distort the planning of public and private services and investment. They create false expectations among the
public, which can lead to frustration and social instability. In the long run, unrealistic growth projections hamper
the credibility of those who formulate them and confuse and disappoint those who use them.
1
We are grateful to Federico Fiuratti for excellent research assistance.
2
Lucas 1988; Barro and Sala-i-Martin 2004; Acemoglu 2007; Jones and Vollrath 2013; Commission on Growth and Development 2008.
3
Cerra et al. 2022.
4
Romer 1990; Aghion and Howitt 1992; Kremer 1993; Jones 1995; Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1997; Aghion, Akcigit, and Howitt 2015;
Akcigit, Celik, and Greenwood 2016; Akcigit and Kerr 2018; Acemoglu, et al. 2018.
5
Alesina and Rodrik 1994; Barro 1991.
6
Easterly and Rebelo 1993.
7
Banerjee and Duflo 2020; Dollar and Kraay 2002; Kraay 2006.
8
Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2005; Sala-i-Martin 2006; Easterly 2006; Cerra, Lama, and Loayza 2022.
9
Chimhowu, Hulme, and Munro (2019) report that the number of countries with a national development plan has risen from about
60 to over 130 in the last two decades. Analyzing over 100 national development plans, they identify the types and content of the
plans, their implications for sustainable development agendas, and the ownership and political control of the processes leading to the
formulation of the national development plan.
10
Easterly 2001.
1
Introduction
Origins
The Long Term Growth Model (LTGM) was initially created as a basic, yet sound, way of assessing
whether growth projections were realistic or not. It used a standard neoclassical growth model, with
exogenous saving/investment and productivity rates, to formulate growth paths based on observable
initial conditions and reasonable assumptions on future growth drivers. However, it was soon clear
that the LTGM could do more than serve as a “reality check”; it had the potential to describe alterna-
tive growth scenarios and the determinants behind those scenarios. This proved to be very useful to
development practitioners, not only to generate more feasible growth paths but also to understand
the potential impact of different growth drivers that could be affected by economic policy. The model
also helped advise policy makers how growth might evolve in a business-as-usual scenario where those
growth drivers were unchanged.
This interest in the LTGM also generated a strong demand to make it richer and more complex, as users
posed questions that the standard LTGM could only partially address. The LTGM project expanded in
response to this demand and is now a suite of diverse and powerful models. These improvements, imple-
mented in specific papers and toolkits, consisted of examining the determinants of total factor productivity
with particular emphasis on policy, differentiating between public and private capital in their rates of return
and efficiency, accounting for natural resources as a complementary source of growth, and measuring the
impact not only on economic growth but also on poverty alleviation. Along with these technical refine-
ments, the LTGM as a project grew also in its applications to a diverse set of countries.
This book
This book is a collection of the technical papers that serve as background for the LTGM suite of models and
a selection of some of its country-specific applications. One of the main advantages of not only the standard
LTGM but also all its extensions is that they can be implemented using user-friendly spreadsheet-based tool-
kits. They, along with basic data to run the models and information on some of their applications, can be
found on the LTGM website: https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM. The list of the contributors who have
made this project possible, and to whom we are immensely grateful, are recognized in the Acknowledgments
of this book.
As implied in its title, the book is divided into three sections: fundamentals, extensions, and applications.
The fundamentals of the LTGM are presented in chapter 1. The model extensions to the standard LTGM
are presented in chapters 2−4. And the country-specific applications, covering different angles and contexts,
are presented in chapters 5−10.
Fundamentals
Chapter 1, “The Standard Long Term Growth Model,” presents the simplest version of the LTGM, which
adapts the Solow (1956)-Swan (1956) model for analyzing future growth paths in developing countries.
The standard LTGM is designed to be sufficiently simple so that it can be solved in a spreadsheet—to make
the simulations fully transparent—and to have sufficiently low data requirements so that it can be used
in almost any country. Unlike many growth models, the LTGM focuses on future transition paths (rather
than steady states) as convergence to a new steady state is sufficiently slow so that the transition period is
more relevant for policy makers. The LTGM toolkit also includes a poverty module to calculate the effect
of simulated future growth paths on poverty reduction.
2
The Long Term Growth Model
Like the original Solow-Swan model, the LTGM features exogenous saving/investment rates, total factor pro-
ductivity (TFP) growth, and population growth. However, the LTGM brings some refinements by allowing
for richer demographics (such as population aging or a “demographic dividend”), labor force participation
rates by gender, human capital (years of schooling), and types of foreign savings (the current account deficit
or external debt and foreign direct investment). The model allows users to simulate economic growth rates
based on initial conditions and assumptions of the future behavior of its drivers; alternatively, the model
allows users to determine the investment (and corresponding saving) needs given a target long-run growth
rate. Users can also experiment with different ways to accelerate growth.
Extensions
Chapter 2, “Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth,” separates the capital stock into public and
private portions in order to analyze the effect of an increase in the quantity or quality of public investment
on growth. The chapter constructs a new Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI) by combining quality indi-
cators for power, roads, and water. In the model, public investment generates a larger boost to growth if
existing stocks of public capital are low (relative to gross domestic product [GDP]) or if public capital has
a larger role in the production function. The chapter draws four implications. First, since the measured
public capital stock is roughly constant as a share of GDP across income groups, the growth effect of new
public investment is roughly constant across development levels. Second, since developing countries are
relatively short of private capital, private investment provides the largest boost to growth in those countries.
Third, although improving the efficiency of public investment has a sizable effect on growth in low-income
countries, the level of efficiency, if constant, does not affect the return to public investment. And fourth, an
expansion of public investment generates a modest but diminishing boost to growth in most developing
countries.
Chapter 3, “Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World,” attempts to link TFP to
economic and institutional reforms, thus making TFP less exogenous. The chapter identifies the main
determinants of TFP as innovation, education, market efficiency, infrastructure, and institutions. It then
constructs indexes representing each of these categories and, combining them through a principal compo-
nent analysis, obtains an overall determinant index for more than 100 countries annually for 1985–2015.
The chapter then examines the relationship between these determinant indexes and existing measures of
TFP through a variance decomposition and regression analysis. The variance decomposition shows that
the largest share of the variance in TFP growth is explained by market efficiency for advanced countries
and education for developing countries. The regression analysis shows that, controlling for country- and
time-specific effects, TFP growth has a positive and significant relationship with the overall determinant
index and a negative relationship with initial TFP. Chapter 3 uses this relationship to formulate a set of
simulations on the potential path of TFP growth for various improvements in TFP determinants. The
chapter presents and discusses some of these simulations for groups of countries by geographic region and
income level. This serves to illustrate how this extension can be used to generate a path for TFP that can be
fed into the standard LTGM spreadsheet.
Chapter 4, “Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long Term Growth,” analyzes how long-run
growth evolves in resource-rich countries. In particular, it evaluates how commodity price shocks and
discoveries/depletion of natural resources affect a country’s economic growth, and how this depends on dif-
ferent fiscal policy frameworks. For this purpose, the chapter adds a natural resource sector and government
fiscal policy to the standard LTGM. Commodity price shocks affect long-term economic growth mostly by
raising revenues for public investment. As a large share of resource income typically accrues to the govern-
ment, the increase in investment during a commodity price boom depends on the government’s fiscal rule.
Fiscal rules that prioritize public investment generally lead to the largest increases in long-term growth.
3
Introduction
However, structural surplus rules, which save commodity revenues, can also boost growth if they free up
savings for private investment. The response of incomes to natural resource discoveries is similar to the
response to price shocks; however, discoveries produce a direct effect on real GDP in addition to the indirect
effect through investment. This two-sector model also allows for a more accurate analysis of the effect of
other (non-resource) fundamentals on growth than the standard LTGM in resource-rich countries by
accounting for heterogeneity across sectors and the consequences of depleting reserves of natural resources.
However, since this is a supply-side model, it does not capture the short-run effects of price and discovery
shocks that operate through aggregate demand.
Applications
Chapters 5−10 present applications of the standard LTGM and its extensions to different countries around
the world. In addition, chapters 2–4, while focusing on LTGM extensions, also include country applications
to illustrate their models. For instance, chapter 3, on the drivers of total factor productivity, considers various
reform scenarios in Peru and corresponding TFP and economic growth projections; likewise, chapter 4, on
the natural resource extension, calibrates the model to Angola, a major oil producer, and presents several
simulations based on different scenarios of fiscal policy.
Chapters 5 and 6 study future and past growth in two rapidly developing Asian economies. Chapter 5
studies economic growth in Malaysia, with some historical analysis, but mostly with the purpose of assess-
ing Malaysia’s potential to sustain growth as it transitions to high-income status. It assesses the challenges
Malaysia faces in this regard, particularly the need to increase female labor force participation and improve
the educational performance of its young population. Chapter 6 studies the Republic of Korea’s growth
process—not looking forward—but as a retrospective of the remarkable growth experience of the country
in the last six decades. It notes how the main engine of growth in the Republic of Korea has evolved from
labor and human capital in the 1960s, to physical capital deepening in the 1970s, and to productivity growth
in the subsequent decades.
Chapters 7 and 8 consider two economies in South Asia and the Middle East with different growth trajec-
tories. Chapter 7 applies the LTGM to Bangladesh, recognizing the country’s robust economic growth in
the last several years and assessing whether it will be able to maintain high growth rates in the future. The
chapter concludes that capital investment, even at reasonably high rates, will not be able to sustain strong
growth if investment is not accompanied by productivity enhancing reforms. Chapter 8 studies the very
different case of Syria, a country devasted by a brutal war, and considers potential growth scenarios in the
aftermath of war. Syria’s growth will be driven by reconstruction assistance, repatriation of refugees, and
productivity improvements, and in turn determined by the post-war political settlement the country is
able to achieve.
Finally, the last two chapters of this volume present early applications of the predecessor of the LTGM.
Chapter 9 presents the first application of a proto-LTGM, where its analytical underpinnings are developed.
It studies the possibilities and limits of a saving-based growth agenda in Egypt. It concludes that if the
Egyptian economy does not experience productivity growth, stemming from technological innovation,
improved public management, and private-sector reforms, then a high rate of economic growth would
require saving rates that are highly unrealistic. Chapter 10 is chronologically the second application of the
proto-LTGM model. It documents the robust growth performance in Sri Lanka fueled by a large increase in
private savings in previous decades and asks whether these trends can be maintained. The chapter considers
the determinants of private saving rates and finds that they are likely to decline because of the looming
demographic transition in Sri Lanka. The chapter concludes that growth rates could remain high only if
public savings rise and the business environment improves, attracting foreign investment and increasing
productivity.
4
The Long Term Growth Model
Lessons
The LTGM project has produced a multitude of findings and policy implications in a wide array of coun-
try-specific applications conducted over the past decade. Though it is hard to summarize these findings
and implications, the following four takeaways are worth highlighting.
1. Although all fundamental economic conditions contribute to growth, their relative importance varies across
countries. This means that growth performance, constraints, and opportunities also vary with country context.
Country-specific conditions determine how sustainable growth is, what growth rates are feasible, and which
paths are the most effective to accelerate growth; and these often vary substantially across countries. Having
said that, the main growth drivers—TFP, human capital, physical capital, and labor—are all qualitatively
important, and analyzing growth in these terms provides a framework that is relevant in a wide variety of
country contexts.
2. Investment-led growth strategies are unsustainable in the long run. Physical capital investment, fueled by
domestic and external saving rates, can jump-start growth and keep it going for some years. This, however,
cannot be the basis of a long-run development strategy. Growth rates will fall as the capital stock expands
and the inevitable diminishing marginal productivity of capital sets in. To be sustainable, growth must
be broad-based, including progress in human capital, productivity, and/or labor force participation. This
applies not only to total investment but also to public investment.
3. It is hard to have high investment rates without high national savings rates. If capital accumulation
is relied upon to increase growth in the short and medium terms, the sources of funding cannot be
external for extended periods of time. External financial constraints will bite sooner rather than later,
exposing the country to a sudden stop or even reversal of capital flows and producing a collapse in
growth rates.
4. High growth usually involves fast productivity growth. The key to sustainable economic growth in the long
run is “total factor productivity” growth: the ability of firms to innovate and adopt new technologies and
achieve an efficient allocation of resources among firms and sectors in the economy. This is more likely with
a well-educated population, good infrastructure, effective government institutions, and a business-friendly
environment that rewards efficiency.
References
Acemoglu, Daron. 2007. Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton University Press.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-
Run Growth.” Handbook of Economic Growth, in: Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf (ed.), edition 1, volume 1,
chapter 6, pages 385−472, Elsevier.
Acemoglu, Daron, Ufuk Akcigit, Harun Alp, Nicholas Bloom, and William Kerr. 2018. “Innovation, Reallocation and
Growth.” American Economic Review 108(11): 3450−3491.
Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction.” Econometrica 60(2),
323–351.
Aghion, Philippe, Ufuk Akcigit, and Peter Howitt. 2015. “Lessons from Schumpeterian Growth Theory.” American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 2015, 105(5): 94−99.
Akcigit, Ufuk, Murat A. Celik, and Jeremy Greenwood. 2016. “Buy, Keep or Sell: Economic Growth and the Market for
Ideas.” Econometrica 2016, 84(3): 943−984.
Akcigit, Ufuk, and William Kerr. 2018. “Growth through Heterogeneous Innovations.” Journal of Political Economy
126(4): 1374−1443.
Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik. 1994. “Distributive Politics and Economic Growth.” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 109(2), 465–490.
5
Introduction
Banerjee Abhijit V., and Ester Duflo. 2020. “How Poverty Ends: The Many Paths to Progress—and Why They Might
Not Continue.” Foreign Affairs: https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2019-12-03/how-poverty-ends.
Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2),
407–443.
Barro, Robert J. 2002. Nothing Is Sacred: Economic Ideas for the New Millennium. MIT Press.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-I-Martin. 1997. “Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth.” Journal of
Economic Growth 2(1), 1–26.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 2004. Economic Growth. MIT Press. Second Edition.
Cerra, Valerie, Barry Eichengreen, Asmaa El-Ganainy, and Martin Schindler. 2022. How to Achieve Inclusive Growth.
Oxford University Press.
Cerra, Valerie, Ruy Lama, and Norman Loayza. 2022. “Links Between Growth, Inequality, and Poverty.” In Valerie
Cerra, Barry Eichengreen, Asmaa El-Ganainy, and Martin Schindler (editors) How to Achieve Inclusive Growth.
Oxford University Press.
Chimhowu, Admos O., David Hulme, and Lauchlan T. Munro. 2019. “The ‘New’ national development planning and
global development goals: Processes and partnerships.” World Development, Volume 120, pages 76−89.
Commission on Growth and Development. 2008. The Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive
Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2002. “Growth Is Good for the Poor.” Journal of Economic Growth 7, no. 3: 195–225.
Easterly, William. 2001. “Growth implosions and debt explosions: Do growth slowdowns cause public debt crises?”
Contributions to Macroeconomics 1, no. 1.
Easterly, William. 2006. “Inequality Does Cause Underdevelopment: Insights from a New Instrument.” Journal of
Development Economics Vol. 84, Issue 2, 755−776.
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo. 1993. “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal
of Monetary Economics 32, no. 3, 417–458.
Jones, Charles I. 1995. “R&D-Based Models of Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 103, August, 759−784.
Jones, Charles I., and Dietrich Vollrath. 2013. Introduction to Economic Growth. W. W. Norton & Company.
Third edition.
Kraay, Aart. 2006. “When Is Growth Pro-Poor? Evidence from a Panel of Countries.” Journal of Development Economics
Vol. 80, No. 1, pp. 198−227.
Kremer, M. 1993. “Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990.” The Quarterly Journal
of Economics 108(3), 681–716.
Lucas Jr., Robert E. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 22, No.
1 (July), pp. 3−42.
Mankiw, N., David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 107(2), 407–437.
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98(5), S71–S102.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 2006. “The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and … Convergence, Period.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(2), 351–397.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70:65−94.
Swan, Trevor. 1956. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” Economic Record 32:334−361.
6
Chapter 1
Abstract
The standard Long Term Growth Model (LTGM) is While growth constraints and opportunities are het-
a spreadsheet-based tool to analyze future long-term erogeneous across countries, the most common result
growth scenarios in developing countries, building on when applying the LTGM in developing countries is
the celebrated Solow-Swan growth model. The focus of that investment-led growth is unsustainable in the long
the tool is on simplicity, transparency, and ease-of-use, run. This is due to a rising capital-to-output ratio when
and it can also be used to assess the implications of investment is driving growth, which implies a dimin-
growth for poverty rates. The very low data requirements ishing marginal product of capital (MPK) that reduces
mean the tool can be applied in almost any country, and the effectiveness of new investment. Instead, sustainable
most of the required data are preloaded. Total factor growth requires broad-based growth fundamentals,
productivity (TFP), investment/savings, and human such as fast TFP or human capital growth, to keep the
capital are key growth drivers, but the model includes capital-to-output ratio down. Another challenge of
other growth fundamentals, such as demographics and high investment rates is that they usually require high
labor market participation (disaggregated by gender). rates of domestic savings.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is an expanded version of the model description of the standard LTGM on the LTGM website: https://
E
www.worldbank.org/LTGM. As such is it a little more technical than other chapters, and equation numbers correspond to those in the
LTGM spreadsheet. It builds on the model in Hevia and Loayza (2012), which is chapter 9 of this volume.
2
oth World Bank. Authors’ emails: nloayza@worldbank.org and spennings@worldbank.org. The views expressed here are the authors’,
B
and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. The authors are grateful
to Aart Kraay, Luis Serven, and Arthur Mendes for helpful comments and Jorge Luis Guzman and Federico Fiuratti for research
assistance. The authors also thank the Global Facility for Growth for Development Trust Fund, supported by the Korean government,
for financial support.
7
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
Introduction
The standard Long Term Growth Model (LTGM) is a spreadsheet-based tool to analyze future long-term
growth scenarios in developing countries. The tool helps policy makers answer important questions in their
own country, including: What growth goals are feasible? What combination of growth drivers (investment,
human capital, productivity, etc.) are required to achieve these growth goals? What growth rates might
occur if current trends in growth drivers continue? How sustainable is growth? What are the effects on
poverty? These questions lie at the heart of most growth strategies and help to link broad development
goals with specific policy interventions (promoting investment, increasing competition, etc). The standard
LTGM seeks to answer these questions in a simple and transparent way, and with sufficiently low data
requirements that the model can be applied in almost any country. Chapters 5−10 of this volume provide
a series of country case studies of how to apply the LTGM in practice.
The LTGM builds on the celebrated neoclassical Solow (1956)-Swan (1956) growth model, but extends the
model in several ways, and adapts it to the needs of policy makers.3 Investment/savings, TFP, and population
growth are key growth drivers as in the classic Solow-Swan model. However, the LTGM setup also includes
other growth drivers that are important in developing countries such as human capital, population aging,
and labor market participation (especially for women). Moreover, as most developing countries have at
least partially open capital accounts, the LTGM allows for a more detailed analysis of external savings,
including foreign direct investment and external debt. Based on the needs of policy makers, the LTGM
focuses on transition paths (rather than steady states) and includes a poverty module. Transition paths
are more useful for policy makers as convergence to a new steady state is often slow.4 The inbuild poverty
module captures the effect of growth (and inequality) on poverty, based on a log-normal approximation
of the income distribution.
The standard LTGM connects “Solow growth fundamentals” and economic growth in developing countries,
rather than connecting specific policies (or their ultimate determinants) to growth. Policy makers are often
interested in connecting individual policies with growth outcomes, but this task is difficult.5 The conceptual
approach of the LTGM breaks down this causal chain from policies to growth into two pieces: first from
policies to “Solow growth fundamentals” like investment, TFP, human capital, and population growth,
and second from these “Solow growth fundamentals” to economic growth. The LTGM analyzes the second
macroeconomic part of the chain, which can be thought of as reverse growth accounting in the future.6
As in a regular growth accounting exercise, the LTGM can be used to understand the proximate sources of
growth in a baseline under current trends, and compare the growth impact of changes in different growth
fundamentals as policy makers try to accelerate growth. However, the first part of the chain, from policies to
Solow fundamentals, can be sourced from elsewhere, including microeconomic studies or country-specific
judgement.7
3
The current version of the LTGM builds on earlier work by Hevia and Loayza (2012), which is chapter 9 in this volume.
4
oreover, developing countries are often buffeted by large and persistent shocks (shifting the steady state), and most
M
developing countries do not have the stable long-run growth rates of the US that motivated a focus on steady states.
5
See for example, Easterly (2001). Part of the problem is a lack of exogenous variation in policies.
6
I n a standard growth accounting exercise, one starts with a historical growth series and decomposes it into paths for different
growth fundamentals.
7
or example, the education literature has many estimates of the effect of different policy interventions on schooling rates.
F
The LTGM does not recommend specific policies itself as this also depends on the first stage of the chain: policies that boost
investment in country A might not work in country B.
8
The Long Term Growth Model
The LTGM is useful for long-run analysis, including planning/vision documents, but shouldn’t be used
for short-run growth analysis or forecasting. While the LTGM does produce year-to-year movements in
growth, in the short term these should be interpreted as the growth rate of potential gross domestic product
(GDP), not actual GDP. This is because the LTGM doesn’t include demand-side relationships that are
important in the short term.8 The LTGM also doesn’t provide a forecast of long run growth (what growth
rates will occur). This is partially because policies or growth fundamentals themselves might change, but
also because the long run is too uncertain for forecasts to be useful. Instead, LTGM simulations can be
thought of as a conditional long-run forecast; if Solow fundamentals evolve in a particular way, then growth
will follow a particular path. This is useful because one can utilize the cross-country distribution of growth
fundamentals to determine the feasibility of growth plans. For example, if growth targets can only be
achieved with investment rates (or other growth fundamentals) that don’t typically occur in other similar
countries, policy makers might like to rethink the feasibility of those targets.9
In practical terms, using the LTGM involves calibrating several parameters and then making assumptions
about the evolution of future growth fundamentals (or targets) until the end of the simulation period
(usually 2050). The few parameters required can usually be calibrated from international data sets such
as the Penn World Tables (PWT) or World Bank Development Indicators (WDI). Demographers at the
United Nations produce projections of population growth and other demographic variables. Future values
of other variables require more judgement, but can be based on the continuation of recent country-specific
trends or the performance of peer countries. For example, in some countries the investment share of GDP
might oscillate around a stable long-term average, and so that average would be a good assumption for the
future investment rate. Conversely, if TFP growth was volatile but had been exceptionally high in recent
years due to one-off factors, a better assumption might be for it to revert to a regional or income group
mean over time.10 Finally, users should take account of the natural bounds on different variables: human
capital (schooling rates) and labor force participation rates are bounded above, and so the growth rates of
each are likely to slow as a country approaches the frontier for these variables.
While analyses conducted using the standard LTGM usually find growth constraints and opportunities are
heterogeneous, a few common results are apparent in different country contexts. The most common of
these is that popular investment-led growth strategies are unsustainable in the long run. This is due to a
rising capital-to-output ratio when investment is driving growth, which implies a diminishing MPK that
reduces the effectiveness of new investment for growth. Instead, sustainable growth requires broad-based
Solow fundamentals, such as fast TFP growth or fast human capital growth, to keep the capital-to-output
ratio down. Moreover, high rates of investment need to be financed by either domestic or foreign savings. As
foreign savings can be fickle, high rates of investment in the long run usually require high rates of domestic
savings. Both of these common results are well known in the literature, and so the LTGM’s contribution
is in quantifying their size in specific countries, and also making them more accessible to policy makers.11
The rest of this chapter proceeds as follows. Section 1 provides an overview of the standard LTGM in
terms of its three building blocks—a production function, demographics/labor market, and capital
8
The World Bank MFMod is designed to capture these relationships; see Burns et al. (2019).
9
I n sub-model 2 of the LTGM, one can enter a target GDP growth rate and calculate the required investment share of GDP to
achieve that target (conditional on other growth fundamentals).
10
Regional or income group trends can also be used to interpolate missing data.
11
ore specifically, the inability of investment to generate long-run growth is built into any neoclassical growth model with
M
diminishing returns to capital, including the original Solow (1956) and Swan (1956) papers. It has been verified empirically
in development accounting exercises where capital deepening does not play a large role in explaining cross-country income
variation; see Hall and Jones (1999). The strong relationship between domestic savings and investment in open economies was
famously documented in Feldstein and Horioka (1980).
9
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
accumulation—and describes how to calibrate parameters and universal growth drivers (as in InputDataA
of the LTGM spreadsheet). Section 2 outlines the three sub-models in the LTGM spreadsheet (as in
InputDataB): sub-model 1 where a given investment path (input) affects growth (output); sub-model 2
which is used to calculate the investment rates (output) required to achieve a given growth target (input);
and sub-model 3 where paths for savings (domestic and foreign) are used as an input rather than a path
for investment. Section 3 derives an analytical equation for growth drivers, and provides some intuition for
common results. Section 4 presents the poverty module of the LTGM based on a log-normal approximation
of the income distribution. Section 5 concludes with some caveats and links to future extensions. Equation
numbers in this chapter correspond to those in the standard LTGM spreadsheet.
12
he LTGM assumes no unemployment or underemployment, so everyone in the labor force is employed. This is because the
T
concept of active job search, which distinguishes unemployment from nonparticipation in the labor market, is poorly defined
in many developing countries with high rates of informality or missing labor market institutions for job searches.
10
The Long Term Growth Model
Yt Yt
y tpc ≡ = t ω t = y t t ω t = At t ω t kt1−β htβ
N t Lt
y tpc+1 t +1 ω t +1 y t +1
=
y tpc t ω t y t
Growth in output per capita is just output per worker adjusted for changes in participation and the work-
ing-age population. Specifically, for a given growth rate of output per worker, output growth can be driven
by a demographic transition (growth in the working-age to population ratio gω,t+1), or an increase in labor
force participation (growth in the participation rate g,t+1).
1 + g ypc,t +1 = [1 + g ω ,t +1 ][1 + g ,t +1 ][1 + g y ,t +1 ] (3)
Physical capital accumulation. The final building block of the LTGM is a capital accumulation identity as
in equation 4. That is, physical capital for use in production next period Kt+1 is equal to new investment
today It, as well as the undepreciated current physical capital stock (1 – δ ) Kt (where δ is the depreciation
rate).
Kt+1 = (1 - d ) Kt + It (4)
In practical terms, this equation is usually expressed in terms of updating the capital-to-output ratio Kt/Yt:
K t +1 Yt +1 Kt It
= (1 − δ ) +
Yt +1 Yt Yt Yt
Calibrating the model. One of the advantages of the LTGM is that it only requires three parameters/
K
initial conditions: β (the labor share), δ (the capital depreciation rate), and 0 (the initial capital-
Y0
to-output ratio). Note, however, the calibration of each one can be important for the results. To solve
each of the three sub-models, we also need to input paths for exogenous variables which are universal
{ g A,t+1, g h,t+1, gω ,t+1, g ,t+1, g N ,t+1}t =0 . These variables are specified in the tab InputdataA in the LTGM
T −1
13
The K0/Y0 ratio is calculated as rkna/rgdpna in PWT 8.1 or 9.0, and rnna/rgdpna in PWT 9.1 or 10 (national accounts prices).
11
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
• g ,t+1 (growth rate of labor force participation, [LFP]). Historical data from the UN or country authorities
can be used as a guide. In practice, the most important determinant of g,t+1 is female LFP.
• gN,t+1 (exogenous population growth) and gω,t+1 (growth in the working-age to total population ratio).
These are both taken from the World Bank Health Nutrition and Population Statistics: population
estimates and projections (link) with gω,t+1 determined by the age structure of the population.
• gh,t+1 (exogenous human capital per worker growth) is usually taken from PWT (various years). Higher
human capital growth is usually due to more schooling of the workforce.14
14
evia and Loayza (2012) refer to this as ht = e φ (Et ) , which is the efficiency of workers with Et average years of schooling. If
H
Et = 0, ht = 1, so ht represents the efficiency of a worker with Et years of education relative to one with no education. If ht = 2,
average workers are twice as productive as a worker with no education. φ (E) governs the return to an extra year of schooling.
PWT is piecewise linear, where the marginal return to schooling is 13.4% for the first four years, 10.1% for the following four
to eight years, and 6.8% for years of schooling after that, schooling from Barro and Lee’s data set v1.3 (Inklaar and Timmer
2013, see equations 15 and 16). A later variant of PWT also uses Cohen-Soto-Leker’s data.
15
Using Lt = tωtNt, labor force growth can be expressed in the following terms, where gN,t+1 is population growth between t and
t+1: Lt +1 = t +1ω t +1 N t +1 = {1 + g , t +1 }{1 + g ω , t +1 } (1 + g N , t +1 )
Lt t ω t N t
12
The Long Term Growth Model
Rearrange to get the growth rate of capital per worker.16 Equation 5 determines capital accumulation (in per
I K
worker terms), where t is the investment share of GDP and t is the capital-to-output ratio.
Yt Yt
It Kt
(1 − δ ) + /
Yt Yt
(1 + g k ,t +1 ) = (5)
(1 + g N ,t +1 ) (1 + g ,t +1 ) (1 + g ω ,t +1 )
To solve the model, we need to update Kt/Yt. Start with an initial value K0/Y0, and then update the
capital-to-output ratio in the next period using equation 6 and the values for gk,t+1 and gy,t+1 we have
calculated in equations 5 and 2:
K t +1 kt +1 y t kt
=
Yt +1 kt y t +1 y t
K t +1 (1 + g k ,t +1 ) K t
= (6)
Yt +1 (1 + g y ,t +1 ) Yt
In sub-model 1 we can calculate the growth rate of GDP per capita using the following steps.
1. Calculate the growth rate of capital per worker using equation 5 (using exogenous & predetermined
variables, including the path for the investment share of GDP).
2. Calculate the growth rate of output per worker using equation 2 (using gk,t+1 from step 1).
3. Calculate the growth rate of output per capita using equation 3 (using gy,t+1 from step 2).
4. Update next period’s capital-to-output ratio using equation 6 (using gk,t+1 and gy,t+1 from steps 1 and 2).
It i K k
16
Note that = t and t = t because the Lt in numerator and denominator cancel.
Yt y t Yt yt
13
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
Next substitute equation 5 into equation 2 to remove the capital growth rate.
1− β
I K
(1 − δ ) + t / t pc
1 + g y ,t +1
Yt Yt
(1 + g A ,t +1 ) [1 + g h ,t +1 ]
β
=
(1 + g N ,t +1 ) (1 + g ,t +1 ) (1 + g ω ,t +1 ) [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ]
Then do some algebra to isolate I/Y on the left-hand side to yield equation 7 in the LTGM spreadsheet.
It Kt
1− β
{1+ g }(1 + g
pc
y , t +1 ) (1 + g ,t +1 ) (1 + g ω ,t +1 )
N , t +1
1− β 1− β 1− β
(1 − δ ) + / =
(1 + g A ,t +1 ) [1 + g h ,t +1 ] [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ]
β
Yt Yt
It Kt
1− β
{1 + g }(1 + g
pc
y , t +1 N , t +1 )
1− β
(1 − δ ) + / =
(1 + g A ,t +1 ) [1 + g h ,t +1 ] [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ]
β β β
Yt Yt
It Kt { pc
1 + g y ,t +1 }
(1 + g N ,t +1 ) 1− β
/ = 1 β β β − (1 − δ )
Yt Yt
(1 + g A ,t +1 ) [1 + g h ,t +1 ] [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ] β
1− β 1− β 1 − β 1−
1
It Kt
=
1 + {
g y ,t +1 1−β (1 + g N ,t +1 )
pc
} − (1 − δ )
(7)
1 β β β
Yt Yt 1 + g
( A ,t +1 ) [1 + g h ,t +1 ] [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ]
1− β 1− β 1 − β 1− β
Kt
Given {g ypc,t +1 }Tt =−01 one can calculate required investment using equation 7. As before, future values of
can
Yt
be updated for period t+1, t+2 using equation 6 with the growth rate of capital calculated from equation 5.
Equation 7 states that required investment is increasing in the desired per capita growth rate g ypc,t +1, the
deprecation rate δ, the population growth rate gN,t+1, and the capital-to-output ratio Kt/Yt. Growth in pro-
ductivity (gA,t+1), human capital (gh,t+1), the working-age population ratio (gw,t+1), and the participation rate
(g,t+1) all reduce the required investment rate.
17
I nitial values of CABt/Yt are taken from the MFMod Database and WDI. The World Development Indicators are the source of
FDIt/Yt (code: BX.KLT.DINV.WD.GD.ZS.) and Dt/Yt (calculated as DT.DOD.DECT.CD ÷ NY.GDP.MKTP.CD).
14
The Long Term Growth Model
I t St CABt
= − (8)
Yt Yt Yt
In sub-model 3 (CAB/Y constraint): Given a path for national savings as a share of GDP {St /Yt }Tt =−01 simply
combine with a path for the current account balance {CABt /Yt }Tt =−01 and use equation 8 to calculate It/Yt.
Then use steps 1−4 from sub-model 1 (section 2.1) to calculate growth. While equation 8 is almost trivially
simple, it forces users to think through how investment will be funded. One common finding of the LTGM
is that for plausible current account deficits, high investment rates require high domestic savings rates.
In sub-models 1 and 2 (CAB/Y constraint): A path for implied savings as: St/Yt = It/Yt – CABt/Yt.
CABt D Dt −1 / Yt −1 FDI
= − t − − t
Yt (1 + g y ,t ) (1 + g N ,t ) Yt (10)
pc
Yt
Combining equations 8 and 10, calculate the investment implied by an external debt constraint and paths
for national savings and FDI as in equation 11.
I t St FDI t Dt Dt −1 / Yt −1
= + + − (11)
Yt (1 + g y ,t ) (1 + g N ,t )
pc
Yt Yt Yt
Equation 11 states that investment can be funded by domestic savings, FDI, or external debt, where an
increase in FDIt/Yt acts as a perfect substitute for national savings (St/Yt). Equation 11 can be rearranged in
terms of the savings rate implied by the external debt path, FDI, and investment.
St I t FDI t Dt Dt −1 / Yt −1
= − − −
Yt Yt Yt Yt (1 + g ypc,t ) (1 + g N ,t ) (12)
18
For economies that are not open to capital flows, CABt/Yt ≈ 0, which implies It/Yt = St/Yt.
15
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
In sub-model 3 with an external debt constraint: Assume a path for external debt-to-GDP (Dt/Yt), and
paths for net inflows of foreign direct investment FDIt/Yt and domestic savings St/Yt, and use equation 11 to
calculate It/Yt. Then use steps 1−4 from sub-model 1 (section 2.1) to calculate growth.
In sub-model 1 and 2 an external debt constraint: Combine paths for Dt/Yt and FDIt/Yt with path for It/Yt
from sub-models 1 and 2 to generate implied savings using equation 12.
1 + g ypc,t +1 = [1 + g ω ,t +1 ] [1 + g ,t +1 ] (1 + g A ,t +1 ) [1 + g k ,t +1 ]
1− β β
[1 + g h ,t +1 ]
Taking logs, and using the approximation ln(1 +x) ≈ x (for small x) this becomes:
g ypc,t +1 ≈ g A ,t +1 + g ω ,t +1 + g ,t +1 + (1 − β ) g k ,t +1 + β g h ,t +1 (13)
I K
ln (1 + g k ,t +1 ) = ln1 + t / t − δ − ln (1 + g N ,t +1 ) − ln (1 + g ,t +1 ) − ln (1 + g ω ,t +1 )
Yt Yt
It Kt
g k ,t +1 ≈ / − δ − g N ,t +1 − g ,t +1 − g ω ,t +1 (14)
Yt Yt
I K
g ypc,t +1 ≈ g A ,t +1 + β ( g ω ,t +1 + g ,t +1 + g h ,t +1 ) + (1 − β ) t / t − δ − g N ,t +1 (15)
Yt Yt
The effect of most factors on growth in equation 15 depends on the labor share b, which averages around 0.5
across countries in PWT, but it is about 2/3 in Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD) countries and the US, but much lower in many resource-rich countries. The exception is TFP
growth (gA,t+1) which has the largest direct effect on growth: a 1ppt increase in TFP growth increases growth
by 1ppt (regardless of b). In contrast, a 1ppt increase in human capital growth (gh,t+1,) labor force partici-
pation rate growth (g,t+1), or working-age population share growth (gw,t+1) increase per capita GDP growth
by bppt. If b ≈ 0.5, then a 1ppt increase in each of these factors, has half the effect as a 1ppt increase in TFP
growth.
19
ote that a quantitative analysis should be done using the exact equations above because even small approximation errors can
N
compound over time.
20
This log-linear expression follows that in Hevia and Loayza (2012) and in chapter 9, but with different notation.
16
The Long Term Growth Model
Population growth (gN,t+1) and depreciation (δ) reduce per capita GDP growth by 1 - b, because they reduce
capital depth (capital per worker) by either reducing the amount of capital (δ) or increasing the number
of workers (gN,t+1).
In the final term of equation 15, the effect of an increase in the investment share of GDP depends on
Y
both the capital share (1 - b ), as well as the existing capital-to-output ratio (Kt/Yt). This term (1 − β ) t
Kt
multiplying the investment share of GDP is of course the marginal product of capital (MPK). Assuming
1 - b = 0.5, a large 10ppt increase in the investment share of GDP (e.g., from 20% to 30%), raises growth by
2.5ppt per year if K/Y = 2 (i.e., 0.5 × 0.1/2), but only 1.25ppt if K/Y = 4. This means that an investment-led
growth strategy, whereby the capital stock increases faster than GDP, will quickly become less effective over
time as the capital-to-output ratio increases. A common recommendation of a LTGM analysis is that to
ensure growth can be sustained, high investment rates must be accompanied by other reforms to boost
productivity, human capital, or labor force participation to mitigate the increase in K/Y.
y pc = A1/ β (K / Y )(1−β )/ β h L / N
Taking logs:
One can use this equation to conduct some comparative statics on the level of GDP per capita (GDPPC) in
the long run in response to one-time shocks to noncapital growth drivers. For example, consider a one-off
increase in TFP growth at time t that permanently raised the level of TFP by 1% (relative to its pre-shock
future path), but did not affect future TFP growth. By equation 15, this raises potential GDPPC in the
short run by 1%, but it will raise the level of GDPPC in the long run by (1/b)%, which is much larger. The
difference is that in the medium run, the higher level of TFP increases Y, which makes investment more
effective (lower K/Y) and increases the quantity of investment (via a fixed I/Y). In the long run, a one-time
1% increase in human capital, the participation rate, or the working-age to total population ratio all lead to
a 1% increase in GDPPC, which is 1/b larger than their short-run effects. A one-time increase in population
also has no effect on long-run GDPPC, as the short-run negative impacts of higher population growth in
equation 15 are offset by higher investment quantity and effectiveness in the medium−long run.
21
or example, an increase in investment (TFP growth) today will boost growth, but will increase (reduce) the capital-to-output
F
ratio tomorrow, making investment less (more) effective for growth. Any policy that increases growth today, will also increase
the quantity of future investment in absolute terms, given the standard assumption that the investment share of GDP is fixed.
K I
22
One motivation of this is that it ensures a fixed MPK in the long run. In steady state, = ÷ ( g Y + δ ) , so assumption can also
K Y
be motivated by assuming constant GDP growth rate gy and investment share of GDP along a balanced growth path. This also
implies the expression above cannot be used to evaluate the effect of a permanent change in the investment rate.
17
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
1− β It
g y ,t +t ≈ g y ,t +t + ×
K t Yt Yt (17)
1 Kt
ICORm ,t = (18)
1 − β Yt
The ICORm,t can easily be calculated from model parameters; suppose b = 0.5 and K0/Y0 = 2.2, then the
marginal ICOR is 4.4, so one needs to increase the investment share of GDP by 4.4ppts to boost headline
GDP growth by 1%.
Critically, the marginal ICOR is not constant over time. An investment-led growth strategy will rapidly
increase K/Y, leading to an increase in the marginal ICOR. This makes future investment less effective in
boosting growth. In addition, the marginal ICOR will be different from the average ICOR in equation 16,
because of the presence of the intercept g Y ,t +1.
Readers will note that the inverse of the marginal ICOR is just the marginal product of capital (MPK):
∂Y Y 1
MPK ≡ t = (1 − β ) t = . The net return on capital is Rt = MPKt – δ. A rising marginal ICOR as
∂K t K t ICORm ,t
K/Y increases during an investment-led growth program is the same as saying that the return to capital is
falling.
23
For example, see FT columnist Martin Wolf ’s analysis of growth in India (March 1, 2005) and China (April 3, 2018).
As the name suggests, the ICOR originally referred to net investment: ∆K t = I t / Yt −1 = ( I t − δ K t −1 ) / Yt . However, in practice
Net
24
∆Yt ∆Yt / Yt −1 ∆Y / Yt
net investment was hard to measure in developing countries due to a lack of data on depreciation rates and capital stocks. As
a result, many analysts approximated net investment with gross investment, giving the rule-of-thumb measure presented in
equation 16. It should be noted that the rule-of-thumb gross ICOR is not the same as the original net ICOR: the net ICOR will
be smaller by δ K t −1 / Yt , which could be important if growth rates are small. For example, with K/Y = 2 and δ = 0.05, the net
∆Y / Yt
ICOR is smaller by 5 if GDP growth is 2%, but only by 2 if GDP growth is 5%.
18
The Long Term Growth Model
exp (µ t +1 + σ t2+1 / 2)
1 + g ypc,t +1 = y tpc+1 / y tpc =
exp (µ t + σ t2 / 2)
(23)
1
= exp µ t +1 − µ t + (σ t2+1 − σ t2 )
2
25
Thanks to Aart Kraay for suggesting this approach. Although the distribution of income is always log normal, µ and σ vary
across countries and over time.
26
he CDF (proportion less than x ) is Pr(X ≤ x) = Φ(x), which is normsdist(x) in Excel. The inverse function Φ–1(Pr) is
T
normsinv(Pr) in Excel.
27
This is just the mean of a variable X if ln(X) (not X) is normally distributed with mean µ and deviation σ.
19
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
We can rewrite this as equation 24, which is used to update the mean of the underlying normal distribution
in sub-models 1 and 3.
1 2
µ t +1 = ln (1 + g ypc,t +1 ) + µ t − (σ t +1 − σ t2 ) (24)
2
Using the approximation ln(1 + g) ≈ g (for small g), this becomes: µt +1 ≈ g ypc,t +1 + µ t − 1 / 2 (σ t2+1 − σ t2 ) which
suggests that with constant income inequality (σ t2+1 = σ t2), an extra percentage point of per capita GDP
growth increases µ by one percentage point.
Steps to solve for poverty rates in sub-models 1, 2, and 3 using the log-normal distribution
In sub-models 1 and 3, growth fundamentals (investment, savings, etc.) determine the path of per capita
growth {g ypc,t +1 }, from which we calculate the change in the poverty rate. In sub-model 2 the path of growth
is set exogenously.28 The steps are as follows:
1. Assume a path for the Gini coefficient on income {Gt} from the first period until the end of the simulation
(this could also be a constant Gini coefficient), and then calculate σt for each year using equation 22.29
2. Choose an initial poverty line L and initial headcount poverty rate Pt at that poverty line. The pre-
loaded defaults are the international extreme poverty line (US$1.90/day 2011 PPP), and the extreme
poverty rate for the most recent household survey in PovcalNet. Alternatively, users can manually enter
their own {P,L} for the national poverty line (which is often quite different).30 Calculate the initial µt
using equation 21.31
3. For each period after the first, update µt+1 using equation 24.
4. For each period after the first, calculate the poverty rate Pt+1using equation 19 (given µt+1, σt+1 and L).32
28
I t is also possible to set a path for poverty in sub-model 2, and then calculate required investment to achieve it. In practice,
required investment rates were unstable, so this option is disabled by default in the LTGM sheet.
29
This can be done in Excel as σt = sqrt(2) ∗ NORMSINV (0.5 ∗ (Gt + 1)).
30
It is only the initial poverty rate P that affects the model. Changes in L (for example changing from per-day to per month, or
the currency of measurement), do not affect the model as µ scales accordingly.
31
This can be done in Excel as µi,t = ln(Li) −σi,t NORMSINV (Pi,t).
32
This can be done in Excel as Pt+1 = NORMSDIST((ln(L) – µt+1) / σt+1).
33
n increase in average income (keeping s constant) always reduces the poverty rate, so we follow Bourguignon (2007) and
A
make the elasticity positive by pre-multiplying by −1. The second equality in equation 25 comes from the mean of a log-
normal distribution ln y i = µ i + σ i2 / 2 (keeping σi constant) and the third equality comes from applying Leibniz’s rule to
equation 19. This equation is similar to equation 3′ in Bourguignon (2007). Here φ(.) is the normal probability distribution
function (in Excel NORMSDIST(x, 0, 1, FALSE) and equation 25 is (1/σt+1) ∗ NORMDIST ((ln(L) – µt+1)/σt+1,0, 1, FALSE)/
NORMSDIST ((ln(L) – µt+1)/σt+1).
20
The Long Term Growth Model
in the poverty headcount is large as a percentage of a very small base. The GEP is also higher in countries
that are more equal (a smaller Gini coefficient of income). As noted by Bourguignon (2007), this means
that a reduction in inequality has a “double dividend”: first it reduces poverty in and of itself, and second
it increases the growth elasticity of poverty.
lnL − µ t
φ
∂lnPt ∂Pt 1 1 σt
ε p ,t ≡− =− = (25)
∂ln y t ∂µ t Pt σ t lnL − µ t
Φ
σt
A closely related metric is growth semi-elasticity of poverty, which is defined here as the percentage point
change in poverty (e.g., a poverty rate of 26% → 25% is a 1ppt fall) for an extra 1% increase in per capita
income (i.e. from a 1% per capita growth rate) as in Equation 26—which is often more relevant than the
GEP for policy makers. Both the GEP and growth semi-elasticity of poverty are calculated as memorandum
items in LTGM spreadsheets.
∂Pt 1 lnL − µ t
∆p ≡ − = ε p ,t × Pt = φ (26)
∂ln y t σt σt
34
ore specifically, this is a kernel density estimate of the probability distribution function (PDF) of poverty. As per capita
M
income is log normally distributed in the LTGM, then the PDF of log of per capita income is just a normal distribution.
21
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
Poverty
line
100% Poverty
line
80%
60%
∆Poverty reduction
40% ∆Income
20%
GEP implementation in the LTGM spreadsheet: In the LTGM, users can input their own GEP instead of
using the one implied by the log-normal income distribution (equation 25). For sub-model 1, sub-model 3,
and sub-model 2 (with a non-poverty target), the poverty rate is given by:
Pt +1 = (1 − ε p ,t +1 × g ypc,t +1 ) Pt (27)
Alternatively, required per capita growth to achieve a poverty rate of Pt+1 (given Pt and εp,t+1):35
g ypc,t +1 = − ( Pt +1 / Pt − 1) / ε p ,t +1 (28)
35
I t is also possible to set a path for poverty in sub-model 2, and then calculate required investment to achieve it. In practice,
required investment rates were unstable, so this option is disabled by default in the LTGM spreadsheet.
22
The Long Term Growth Model
the population is given by equation 29, where kt ≡ exp(σt Φ-1(0.4) + µt) is the income cutoff that defines the
bottom 40% (which changes over time and across countries).36
The income share of the bottom 40% of the population (SB40) can be expressed as37
E ( y pc | y pc < kt ) × 0.4
SB 40 t ≡ pc
yt
0.4 −1 e µt +σ t /2Φ (Φ −1 (0.4 ) − σ t ) × 0.4 (30)
2
=
e µt +σ t /2
2
= Φ (Φ −1 (0.4 ) − σ t )
In terms of the Gini coefficient (using equation 22) the income share of the bottom 40% can be written as:
(
SB 40 t = Φ Φ −1 (0.4 ) − 2 × Φ −1 ((Gt + 1) / 2) (31) )
As such, the growth rate of average income of the bottom 40% is defined as the average income gross growth
rate 1 + g ypc,t +1 times the gross growth rate of the income share of the bottom 40% (SB40t+1/SB40t)
(
= 1 + g ypc,t +1 ) SBSB4040
t +1
pc
where g y ,t +1 is the economy-wide per capita growth rate as defined in equation 23, and σ is the SD of the
underlying normal distribution (which is a one-to-one transformation of the Gini coefficient by equation 20).
The Shared Prosperity Premium (SPP) (equation 33) is the excess income growth of the bottom 40%
pc
( g 40,t +1) over the average per capita growth rate of the whole economy g y ,t +1 : ( )
SPPt +1 ≡ ln (1 + g 40,t +1 ) − ln (1 + g ypc,t +1 ) ≈ g 40,t +1 − g ypc,t +1 (33)
Combining equations 33 and 32, one can see an expression for the SPPt+1, which is just the log growth rate
of income share of the bottom 40%.
Φ (Φ −1 (0.4 ) − σ t +1 )
SPPt +1 = ln (34)
Φ (Φ −1 (0.4 ) − σ t )
SB 40 t +1
= ln (35)
SB 40 t
36
This follows from the expression for a conditional mean of a log-normal distribution:
ln (kt ) − µ t − σ t2 ln (kt ) − µ t ln (kt ) − µ t
E ( X | X < kt ) = e µ +σ /2Φ Φ , Φ = 0.4.
2
σ t σ t where σt
37
To see this, we normalize the population to 1, which means that the mean per capita income y pc equals total income.
23
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
From equation 34 one can see that when there is no change in income inequality (such that σt+1 = σt
and Gt+1 = Gt), then the shared prosperity premium will be zero, and the growth rate of the incomes of
the bottom 40% will be the same as the per capita growth rate of the economy as a whole (recall from
equation 22 that σ t = 2 × Φ −1 ([Gt + 1] / 2)). As such, if income follows a log-normal distribution, then
there is a one-to-one relationship between the change in inequality (as measured by the Gini coefficient)
and the shared prosperity premium: a fall (raise) in inequality is equivalent to a positive (negative) shared
prosperity premium.
Shared prosperity implementation in the LTGM spreadsheet: Given equation 34, the Shared Prosperity
Premium enters the LTGM as an alternative way for the user to specify the path of inequality, or to
summarize the implications for the bottom 40% of a given path of Gini coefficient. As such, the shared
prosperity mostly enters in the sheet InputdataA when the user is specifying the path for inequality (and
the SPP is plotted in GraphsA).38
• If the user specifies a path for the Gini coefficient, then the implied Shared Prosperity Premium is
calculated using equation 34 as a residual (using equation 22 to substitute out for the Gini as an
intermediate step).
• If the user specifies a path for the SPP:
°° the user must still specify an initial Gini coefficient Gt for the first year, which is then converted into
5. Conclusions
This chapter has provided a description of the standard Long Term Growth Model (LTGM), which includes
three sub-models in the spreadsheet-based tool, a module that connects growth and poverty, and some
intuition about how the model works. For how the standard LTGM is applied in practice, the chapters in
part 3 of this volume provide some examples.39
One of the main advantages of the standard LTGM is its simplicity and transparency—which allow it to
be solved in a spreadsheet (without macros)—but simplicity and transparency also have costs. One of
those costs is that future paths for growth drivers are exogeneous in the model. While this is necessary
for simplicity and flexibility, and to enable the model to be solved in a spreadsheet, it limits the scope of
interactions between different growth drivers and the scope of policies to affect growth fundamentals (for
example, for investment to respond to taxation). Many other models in the growth literature relax these
assumptions, at the cost of complexity (among other things). In a standard Ramsey (1928)−Cass (1965)−
Koopmans (1965) neoclassical growth model, the investment/savings rate is endogenous as households
choose consumption and savings to maximize utility. In Romer (1990), Aghion and Howitt (1992), and
others, the TFP growth rate is endogenized through research and development and creative destruction.
38
he income growth of the bottom 40% in each of Model 1/1s/2/2s/3/3s is also summarized at a poverty memorandum item at
T
the bottom of each of those sheets and plotted in GraphsB.
39
Chapters 5 and 8 in Part 3 use the LTGM-PC rather than the standard LTGM, but how to calibrate and use the models are similar.
24
The Long Term Growth Model
In Lucas (1988) human capital accumulation is endogenous. Galor and Weil (1996), and others, model the
two-way interaction between fertility and economic growth. Other papers in the growth literature build
upon these early contributions.
Nonetheless, there are a number of ways that the basic model can be enhanced to respond to criticisms,
add functionality, and enhance realism without sacrificing simplicity and a spreadsheet-based setup. These
are explored in a number of extensions, including those later in this volume and a work in progress.
One of these criticisms is that there is no separate role for infrastructure or natural resources in the
production function (equation 1) despite the fact that much of the development discussion revolves
around infrastructure, and many developing countries export commodities. These concerns are addressed
in extensions in chapters 2 and 4 respectively. Another common criticism is that TFP growth is exogenous,
which is particularly problematic given its importance as a driver of long-run growth. The TFP extension
in chapter 3 seeks to unpack the deeper determinants of TFP growth, which can then be used as an input
into the standard LTGM spreadsheet. Finally, the traditional concept of human capital based on the years
of schooling misses important adjustments for schooling quality (Filmer et al. 2018) and health (Weil
2007). A human capital extension, in a “beta version” at the time of writing (and so not included in this
volume), translates these broader measures of human capital in the World Bank Human Capital Index
(Kraay 2018) for use as an LTGM input. Future work extending the LTGM to multiple sectors (especially
agriculture) and incorporating the effects of climate change are planned.
References
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction.” Econometrica 60(2), 323–351.
Barrot, D. 2016. “The Long Term Growth Model (LTGM): Reference Note on Data Issues,” Unpublished note.
Bourguignon, F. 2007. “The Growth Elasticity of Poverty Reduction: Explaining Heterogeneity across Countries
and Time Periods” in Eicher and Turnovsky (eds.) Inequality and Growth: Theory and Policy Implications. MIT
Press.
Burns, A., B. Campagne, C. Jooste, D. Stephan, and T. T. Bui. 2019. “The World Bank Macro-Fiscal Model Technical
Description.” Policy Research Working Paper No. 8965.
Cass, D. 1965. “Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation.” Review of Economic Studies 32,
July, 233–240.
Easterly W. 2001. “The Elusive Quest For Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics” MIT
Press.
Feldstein M., and C. Horioka. 1980. “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows.” The Economic Journal
90(258): 314−329.
Feenstra, R., R. Inklaar, and M. Timmer. 2015. ”The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.” American Economic
Review 105(10): 3150−82.
Filmer, D., H. Rogers, N. Angrist, and S. Sabarwal. 2018. “Learning-Adjusted Years of Schooling (LAYS): Defining a
New Macro Measure of Education.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 8591
Galor, O., and D. Weil. 1996. “The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth.” American Economic Review 86(3), 374−387.
Hall R., and C. Jones. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83−116.
Hevia C., and N. Loayza. 2012. “Savings and Growth in Egypt.” Middle East Development Journal 4, 1.
Inklaar R., and M. Timmer. 2013. “Capital, labor and TFP in PWT8.0.” https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/docs/capital_labor
_and_tfp_in_pwt80.pdf.
Koopmans, T. 1965. “On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth.” In The Econometric Approach to Development
Planning. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Kraay, A. 2018. “Methodology for a World Bank Human Capital Index.” World Bank Policy Research Working
Paper 8593.
25
1. The Standard Long Term Growth Model
Lopez H., and L. Serven. 2006. “A Normal Relationship? Poverty, Growth, and Inequality.” World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 3814.
Lucas R. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1): 3−42.
Pennings S. 2020. “The Utilization-adjusted Human Capital Index (UHCI).” World Bank Policy Research working
paper WPS 9375.
Pennings S. 2022. “A Gender Employment Gap Index (GEGI): A Simple Measure of the Economic Gains from Closing
Gender Employment Gaps, with an Application to the Pacific Islands.” World Bank Policy Research working paper
WPS 9942.
Ramsey, Frank. 1928. “A Mathematical Theory of Saving.” Economic Journal 38, December, 543–559.
Romer, Paul M. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98.
Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70:65−94.
Swan, T. 1956. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” Economic Record 32: 334−361.
Weil, D. 2007. “Accounting for the Effect of Health on Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122(3):
1265–1306.
World Bank. 2015. “A Measured Approach to Ending Poverty and Boosting Shared Prosperity: Concepts, Data, and
the Twin Goals.” Policy Research Report; Washington, DC: World Bank.
26
Chapter 2
Abstract
To analyze the effect of an increase in the quantity or capital stock is roughly constant as a share of gross
quality of public investment on growth, this paper domestic product (GDP) across income groups, which
extends the World Bank’s Long Term Growth Model implies that the returns to new public investment,
(LTGM), by separating the total capital stock into public and its effect on growth, are roughly constant across
and private portions, with the former adjusted for its development levels. Second, developing countries are
quality. The paper presents the Long Term Growth relatively short of private capital, which means that
Model Public Capital Extension (LTGM-PC) and private investment provides the largest boost to growth
accompanying freely downloadable Excel-based tool. in low-income countries. Third, low-income coun-
It also constructs a new Infrastructure Efficiency Index tries have the lowest quality of public capital and the
(IEI), by combining quality indicators for power, roads, lowest efficient public capital stock as a share of gross
and water as a cardinal measure of the quality of public domestic product. Although this does not affect the
capital in each country. In the model, public investment returns to public investment, it means that improving
generates a larger boost to growth if existing stocks of the efficiency of public investment has a sizable effect
public capital are low, or if public capital is particularly on growth in low-income countries. Quantitatively,
important in the production function. Through the lens a permanent 1ppt GDP increase in public investment
of the model and utilizing newly collated cross-country boosts growth by around 0.1–0.2ppts over the following
data, the paper presents three stylized facts and some few years (depending on the parameters), with the effect
related policy implications. First, the measured public declining over time.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 8604, originally published in October 2018.
E
The appendices and spreadsheet-based LTGM-PC tool are available at the Long Term Growth Model website: https://www.worldbank
.org/LTGM. Sharmila’s affiliation is based on when the article was written, not her current affiliation.
2
Sharmila Devadas and Steven Pennings, World Bank. Corresponding author email: spennings@worldbank.org. The views expressed
here are the authors’, and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.
The authors are grateful to Norman V. Loayza for guidance, Luis Serven for helpful comments, and Jorge Luis Guzman for research
assistance. The authors also thank the Global Facility for Growth for Development Trust Fund, supported by the Republic of Korean
government, for financial support.
27
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
1. Introduction
Inadequate infrastructure, especially public infrastructure, is often viewed as a key impediment to economic
growth and development in low- and middle-income countries. While increasing infrastructure investment
has been a part of national development strategies for decades, its perceived importance has gained prom-
inence with the rapid development of China and its infrastructure-led growth strategy, as well increased
infrastructure-specific finance through new bilateral lending, the Asian Infrastructure Bank, and the Belt
and Road Initiative.
Despite the importance of public infrastructure investment, there is wide disagreement about the size
and significance of its effect on growth in developing countries (Calderon and Serven 2014). On one
hand, the needs are clearly great—close to 700 million people do not have access to safe drinking water
and 1.2 billion are without electricity—and so one should expect a sizable impact.3 Several papers have
estimated large returns to infrastructure investment—most frequently cited, Aschauer (1989). But as infra-
structure investment is endogenous – for example, growth for other reasons might generate public revenues
which allows the construction of infrastructure—many of those empirical studies lack causal validity and
estimated impacts are implausibly large. Many other papers have found insignificant or negative impacts
(Bom and Ligthart 2014), possibly because public investment in developing countries often fails to generate
productive capital due to corruption and the presence of “white elephants” (Pritchett 2000).
Perhaps less appreciated is that there is a great deal of confusion in the empirical and policy discussion
about the dynamics and mechanisms through which public infrastructure investment would affect growth.
For example, empirical studies (and policy reports) are often vague about whether it is the level of infra-
structure that affects growth, or whether infrastructure investment (and hence changes in infrastructure
levels) affects growth. Likewise, empirical studies often have difficulty estimating when the boost to growth
might occur (whether the size of the effect will increase or decrease over time) and what country-level
factors determine the impact on growth (as different studies are for particular countries or reflect a
cross-country average). All these aspects are crucial for evaluating the effectiveness of a country’s public
investment–led growth plans.
This chapter makes contributions in two areas to try to address these gaps. First, we develop a model of
the effect of public investment on long term growth— called the Long Term Growth Model Public Capital
Extension (LTGM-PC)— that is simple enough to be solved in an Excel spreadsheet without macros (which
is provided as a companion to this chapter on the website www.worldbank.org/LTGM).4 Unlike coefficients
estimated in most empirical studies, the LTGM-PC allows for the effect of extra public investment to vary
across countries and over time within the same country. In the model, the effect of an increase in public
investment (or the quality of that investment) and the full dynamic growth path depend on country-specific
factors such as the scarcity of public capital (relative to gross domestic product [GDP]) and some crowd-
ing in of private investment. The model also allows for the fact that the public capital stock might be of
low-quality construction, which is a practical concern in many developing countries.
More technically, our model builds on the celebrated Solow-Swan growth model and another World Bank
Excel-based tool known as the Long Term Growth Model (LTGM), which is described in Chapter 1 of
this volume, which we refer to as the Standard LTGM. However, in the Solow-Swan model (and Standard
LTGM), capital is simply an aggregate, and so those models cannot simulate the specific effect of an increase
3
ttp://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2016/04/16/spending-more-and-better-essential-to-tackling-the
h
-infrastructure-gap.
4
The relevant data and parameters for all countries are already preloaded into the LTGM-PC spreadsheet.
28
The Long Term Growth Model
in public investment. In contrast, in the LTGM-PC, total capital is split into public and private portions.
The LTGM-PC retains many other realistic growth drivers and features of the Standard LTGM, including
other growth fundamentals (human capital, total factor productivity [TFP], demographics, labor market
participation by gender), and also the implications for poverty rates. Section 2 presents the model and
section 3 describes how it is implemented in the Excel-based tool.
Despite being theoretical, the chapter draws extensively on the empirical literature to guide the choice of
parameters. The most important parameter is the elasticity of output to public capital, φ, which we call the
usefulness of public capital. In section 5 we review the evidence from two meta-analyses and other literature,
which suggests an elasticity of up to φ = 0.17 for essential infrastructure and φ = 0.10 for generic public
capital like buildings (though users can also specify its value). We also calculate the country-specific scarcity
of public capital using a new public capital database from the International Monetary Fund’s (IMF’s) Fiscal
Affairs Department.
However, we could not find a suitable measure of the fraction of public capital that is of high quality (we
use “efficiency” and “quality” interchangeably).5 So in section 4 we develop a new cardinal Infrastructure
Efficiency Index (IEI) to quantify the extent to which public capital is of high quality in different countries.
The IEI is based on estimates of the fraction of roads that are in poor condition, water that never reaches
its final customers, and electricity that is lost through transmission and distribution.
Our second contribution is to document how the quantity and quality of public capital vary across
countries with different levels of development, and how this affects the impact of new public and private
investment on growth (section 6). This analysis is conducted through the lens of the LTGM-PC and utilizes
the cross-country data on the IEI and public capital stocks collected for the Excel-based tool.
Surprisingly, we find that the effect of an extra 1ppt of GDP of public investment on growth is roughly con-
stant across different levels of development.6 This puts us at odds with optimistic commentators claiming
that sizable “infrastructure gaps” mean a larger growth dividend from public investment in low-income
countries. But it also puts us at odds with pessimistic commentators who claim that the low efficiency of
public investment in developing countries—due to corruption and mismanagement, for example—means
that such projects have little effect on growth.7 Overall a 1ppt increase in public investment as a share of
GDP increases growth by 0.1–0.2ppts in our model, depending on the calibration. As public investment
is typically around 5% of GDP and usually less than 10% of GDP, higher public investment alone cannot
turn a slow-growing country into a tiger economy.
Instead, developing countries are short of private capital, both relative to GDP and in absolute terms. Private
capital as a share of GDP in low-income countries is only two-thirds of that in middle-income countries,
and almost one-half that in high-income countries. By our calculations, this means the return to private
capital is highest in low-income countries, relative to both advanced countries and also relative to the return
on public capital. This stems from the relatively low levels of private investment in low-income countries
(whereas public investment in low-income countries is actually larger as a share of GDP).
5
ther indices like the World Economic Forum’s infrastructure quality index or the IMF Public Investment Efficiency Index
O
(PIE-X) include survey-based scores or distance to the frontier analysis, which means that a quality or efficiency score does
not reflect the cardinal or absolute fraction of public capital operating as it should (see section 4). The literature uses the terms
quality and efficiency interchangeably as well.
6
his result follows from measured public capital as a share of GDP being roughly constant across countries with different levels
T
of development, which is possibly overstated in low-income countries with weak governance (Keefer and Knack 2007).
7
s in Berg et al. (2015), the level of efficiency in the LTGM-PC has no effect on the return to new public investment because the
A
low quality of new public investment is exactly offset by a greater need for public capital due to the poor quality of past public
investment. See sections 2 and 6.5.
29
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
However, low-income countries also have the most inefficient public investment—with an infrastructure
efficiency index one-fifth lower than middle-income countries and one-third lower than high-income
countries. Even though low-income countries might not be short of measured public capital—as public
investment is likely overstated in many low-income countries with poor institutions (Keefer and Knack
2007)—low-income countries are likely short of efficient public capital that is actually useful in production.
This means that in low-income countries: (i) the marginal product of efficient public capital—if it could be
installed—is extremely high, and (ii) there is substantial room for low-income countries to boost growth
through increases in efficiency. As high efficiency only affects output through new investment, countries
with high existing rates of public investment (and low existing efficiency) have the most to gain. However,
efficiency is extremely difficult to increase quickly, and so in practical terms the return to public investment
will still be similar across different levels of development (as claimed above).
8
I MF (2015): Public capital is the accumulated value of public investment over time, which is the principal input into the
production of public infrastructure, comprising economic infrastructure (transport and utilities) and social infrastructure
(public schools, hospitals and prisons).
30
The Long Term Growth Model
Each firm takes technology (TFP), At , and public services, St , as given, that is, these are externalities to the
firm. K tP is the private capital stock, htLt is effective labor, which can be further decomposed into ht, human
capital per worker, and Lt, the number of workers. 1 − β and β are private capital and labor income shares.
Next, we consider the following specification for public services St:
φ
G
St = Pt ζ (2A)
Kt
Gt is the efficient physical public capital stock—the public capital that is actually used in production. ζ cap-
tures whether public capital is subject to congestion (or not)—discussed further below. φ is the usefulness
of public capital (more technically the elasticity of output to efficient public capital).
Gt = θ t K tGm (2B)
Due to corruption, mismanagement, or pork-barreling, only a fraction θt ≤ 1 of measured public capital
is useful for production. The measured capital stock K tGm is what is recorded in international statistical
databases, and constructed using the perpetual inventory method. θt is the average efficiency/quality of
the public capital stock. Equations (1), (2A), and (2B) can be written in a more conventional production
function as:
Congestion (ζ ∈ [0,1])
In principle, the congestion parameter in equations (2A) and (3) can take values between: z = 1 (full
congestion) and z = 0 (no congestion). As long as z > 0, it is the ratio of public capital to private capital
that provides public services, rather than the absolute amount of public capital (Barro and Sala-i-Martin
1992).10 When there is a large amount of private capital relative to public capital, the public capital becomes
“congested” and its benefits diminish. The intuition for this is a road network: when there are too many
cars on the road, it becomes jammed, reducing its capacity to add to output.
In the Excel-based tool, we only allow for two cases, z ∈ {0,1} for simplicity. In our main “congestion”
specification, z = 1. This means that K tGm must grow faster than K tP to have a positive effect on output. In
this scenario, there are decreasing returns to scale to private inputs (private capital and effective labor),
9
See appendix A1.5 for a general idea of how the Standard LTGM differs from the LTGM-PC.
10
ongestion can also be measured in terms of both private capital and labor supply (see for instance Glomm and Ravikumar
C
[1997]) or aggregate output, but these do not result in substantial changes to the analysis (Eicher and Turnovsky 2000).
Aside from absolute congestion, there can also be relative congestion, in which case, congestion increases only if aggregate
usage increases relative to individual usage. See Eicher and Turnovsky (2000) for further details on how relative and absolute
congestion affect growth analysis.
31
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
and constant returns to scale to all inputs. In the appendix (available on the website www.worldbank.org/
LTGM) and in some parts of the chapter we take the alternative assumption that z = 0, public capital is a
pure public good. When z = 0, there are constant returns to scale to private inputs but increasing returns to
scale to all inputs, though as we assume f + (1 − β) < 1, endogenous growth through capital accumulation
is ruled out. z = 0 is a polar case—in reality, almost all public goods are characterized by some degree of
congestion.
where yt is output per worker and ktP is private capital per worker and ktGm is measured public capital per
worker (note the lower case). Lt = tωtNt, where Nt is total population, ωt is the working-age-population
ratio and t is the labor participation rate (labor force-to-working age population ratio). The above equa-
tion can then be used to calculate growth rates of output per worker from t to t + 1:
32
The Long Term Growth Model
(1−ζ )φ φ φ 1− β −ζφ β
y t +1 ω t +1 t +1 N t +1 At +1 θ t +1 ktGm
+1 kt +1
P
ht +1
= A θ k Gm k P h (5)
yt ω t t N t t t t t t
(
(1 + g A , t +1 )(1 + g θ , t +1 ) 1 + g kGm, t +1 ) (1 + g ) (1 + g )
φ φ 1− β −ζφ β
1 + g y , t +1 = (1 + Γ t +1 )
(1−ζ )φ
k P , t +1 h , t +1 (6)
where the growth rate of a variable x from t to t + 1 is denoted by gx,t+1, and G is the growth rate of the
number of workers:
1 + Gt+1 = (1 + g,t+1)(1 + gω,t+1)(1 + gN,t+1) (7)
1 + Gt+1 drops out from equation (6) in the congestion default (z = 1).
Y Y
To obtain output per capita, y tPC from equation (4), y tPC ≡ t = t t ω t . Rewriting this equation in terms
N t Lt
of growth rates:
1 + g Y ,t +1 = (1 + g yPC,t +1 ) (1 + g N ,t +1 ) (9)
+1 = (1 − δ ) K t
K tGm + I tG (10)
G Gm
The gross growth rate of measured public capital (not per worker) is:
I tG / Yt
K tGm Gm
+1 / K t = (1 − δ G ) + (11)
K tGm / Yt
The growth rate of measured public capital per worker, which enters equation (6), is:
G
K Gm L
(1 − δ ) + KI / /YY
G t
Gm
t
+1
1 + g kGm,t +1 ≡ tGm / t +1 = t t (12)
Kt Lt (1 + g )(1 + g ω )(1 + g
, t +1 , t +1 N , t +1 )
The stock of efficiency-adjusted public capital (which is actually used in production) evolves based on
the previous period’s efficiency-adjusted undepreciated stock and efficiency-adjusted new investment
θ tN I tG .
Gt +1 = (1 − δ G ) Gt + θ tN I tG (13A)
Readers will note that equation (13A) is the same as equation (1) in Berg et al. (2015), with the efficiency of
new investment being θ tN rather than ε. Consequently, all of Berg et al.’s results on the effects of efficiency
33
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
also go through here (discussed further below). Equation (13A) is also equivalent to equation (2) in Pritchett
(2000), who refers to g as the efficiency of public investment.11 Here one can interpret 1 /θ tN as the dollar cost
of providing an extra dollar of usable public capital. Hence, corruption or other rent seeking, which reduces
the quality of public investment, effectively increases the cost of a given increase in the productive capital
stock as found empirically by Olken (2007) and Collier, Kichberger, and Soderbom (2015).
qt is the average efficiency of existing public capital (rather than the efficiency of new investment).
Substituting Gt = θ t K tGm into Equation 13A and rearranging as 13B, one can see the qt+1 evolves as a weighted
average of the quality of existing public capital qt, and the quality of new investment θ tN .
θ t +1 = θ t
(1 − δ ) KG Gm
t
+ θ tN
I tG (13B)
(1 − δ ) K + I
G Gm
t
G
t (1 − δ ) K t + I t
G Gm G
As such, the quality/efficiency of the stock of public capital only changes when the quality of new invest-
ment projects is different from that of the existing public capital stock: θ tN ≠ θ t .12 Using equation (13B), the
growth in quality which enters equation (6) can be written as follows:
θ t +1 θ N I tG /Yt
1 + g θ , t +1 ≡ = (1 − δ G ) + t / (K tGm Gm
+1 / K t ) (14)
θt θ t K tGm /Yt
The quantity of private capital follows the same accumulation process as public capital. But with δP as the
private capital depreciation rate, and I tP as private investment. The growth rate of private capital per worker
is as follows:
P
(1 − δ ) + KI //YY
P t
P
t
1 + g k P ,t +1 = t t (15)
(1 + g ,t +1)(1 + g ω )(1 + g
, t +1 N , t +1 )
11
he measured public capital stock K tGm here is Gtm in Berg et al. (2015). Pritchett (2000) refers to K tG in his equation (2) as the
T
efficient capital stock.
12
he treatment of “new” investment versus maintenance expenditure requires some clarification. For instance, Buffie et al.
T
(2012), in their macroeconomic model of public investment effects, consider infrastructure investment as encompassing
net investment, as well as operations and maintenance; and treat the depreciation rate as exogenous. Kalaitzidakis and
Kalyvitis (2004), in their infrastructure-led growth model, specify the accumulation of public capital as a function of new
investment, and the depreciation rate depends on maintenance expenditure. Our model is more in line with Buffie et al.
(2012), in that depreciation is exogenous. Conceptually, I tG in our model could include spending on major repairs, which
along with new investment helps offset the capital decumulation effects of depreciation. But practically, we note that
maintenance spending is typically subsumed under public consumption data and hence is hard to gauge. (From a national
accounts perspective, the SNA (1993) notes “ordinary maintenance and repairs to keep fixed assets in good working order
are intermediate consumption. However, major improvements, additions or extensions to fixed assets which improve
their performance, increase their capacity or prolong their expected working lives count as gross fixed capital formation.
In practice, it is not easy to draw the line. . . . Some analysts . . . would favor a more “gross” method . . . all such activities are
treated as gross fixed capital formation.”) User concern about insufficient maintenance spending could thus be reflected
as higher depreciation rates. Developing countries tend to spend less on operations and maintenance, which could imply
higher depreciation rates than developed countries. (Devarajan, Swaroop, and Zou (1996), in a regression analysis for
a sample of developing countries, find public capital expenditure and economic growth to be negatively correlated but
that current expenditure has positive effects, illustrating how capital expenditure may have been excessive, while current
expenditure insufficient). However, developed countries are more likely to hold a higher share of more sophisticated
assets that are subject to faster depreciation, making the net implication for depreciation rates not readily obvious
(Arslanalp et al. 2010).
34
The Long Term Growth Model
I tG / Yt
g yPC,t +1 ≈ g A ,t +1 + β ( g , t +1 + g ω , t +1 + g h ,t +1 ) − (1 − β ) ( g N ,t +1 ) + φ θ tN −δ G
θ t K t / Yt
Gm
(16)
I /Y P
+ (1 − β − ζφ ) t P t − δ P
K t / Yt
From equation (16), one can see that a 1ppt increase in the public investment share of GDP increases
growth the following year by:
∂ g yPC,t +1 φ
= θ tN . (16A)
∂I tG /Yt θ t K tGm /Yt
φ
is the marginal product of efficient public capital (Gt), calculated by taking the derivative with
θ t K tGm /Yt
respect to Gt = θ t K tGm . This is multiplied by θ tN , such that an increase in public investment has a larger effect
on growth when new public investment is more efficient.
However, in most cases it is prudent to assume that the efficiency of new investment is the same as past
investment, θ tN = θ t . In this case, the effect of a 1ppt GDP increase in public investment is the marginal prod-
uct of measured public capital, φ/(K tGm /Yt ). To calculate how many extra ppts of GDP of public investment
an economy needs in order to increase growth by a percentage point, simply invert this ratio (K tGm /Yt )/φ .
We call this the public marginal Incremental Capital to Output Ratio (ICOR), because it is a close analog
of the traditional concept of ICOR.
An analogous expression is available for private capital:
∂ g yPC,t +1 1 − β − ζφ
= (16B)
∂ I tP /Yt K tP /Yt
The public capital portion of equation (16) in brackets is equal to the net growth rate of efficient public
θ N − θ t I tG /Yt
capital Gt. This can be further decomposed into an increase in quality t Gm and an increase
G θ t K t /Yt
I /Y
in quantity tGm t − δ G . The increase in quantity is simply the net growth rate of the measured public
K t / Yt
capital stock g K Gm = K tGm Gm
+1 / K t − 1 (which is not affected by the level of q).
θ N I tG /Yt θ tN − θ t I tG / Yt I tG /Yt
g Gt = t − δ G
= + −δG
θ t K t /Yt
Gm
θ t K t /Yt Gm Gm
K t /Yt (17)
Quality increase Quantity increase (= g K Gm )
One will note that if θ tN = θ t —that is the efficiency of public capital is constant—then the level of public
capital efficiency qt does not appear at all in equations (16A), (16B), or (17) and so does not affect growth.
This surprising result, which also appears in Berg et al. (2015), is because of two exactly offsetting forces in
the production function. First, lower quality/efficiency naturally means that there is a smaller increase in
35
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
efficient public capital for each extra 1ppt of public investment. Second, in economies with lower efficiency,
the stock of efficient public capital is scarcer, and hence has a higher marginal product.13
From equation (16), TFP growth gA,t+1 has the largest direct effect on growth. The effect of most other factors
depends on the labor share, β < 1. The larger is β, the lower is the effect of private capital accumulation
on growth. For both public and private capital accumulation, holding all else constant, the same level of
investment-to-output becomes less efficient as the capital-to-output ratio rises.
In practical terms, using the LTGM-PC involves choosing the path for several inputs in the future (exog-
enous variables), and then the LTGM-PC calculates the future implied path of the outputs (endogenous
variables). The LTGM-PC has three submodels (1–3) where the endogenous and exogenous variables in
the model are switched. Other growth drivers—growth in TFP (A), human capital (h), labor participation
rate (), working age-population ratio (ω), and population (N) respectively are always exogenous, as in the
Standard LTGM. The LTGM-PC also allows for output growth to affect poverty rates, as in the Standard
LTGM. More technically, the LTGM-PC has three “state” variables, which are predetermined at any point
and change slowly over time: the public and private capital stocks (usually expressed as a ratio to GDP) and
the average efficiency of installed public capital.
In this chapter, we mostly use Submodel 1 where future paths of public and private investment (as a
share of GDP) are exogenous, and the path of GDP (or GDP per capita) is endogenous. Alternatively, this
can be reversed and Submodel 2 can calculate the required public investment ratio to achieve a specified
growth target (given an exogenous private investment share). In both submodels 1 and 2, savings rates are
calculated as a residual for an assumed path of the current account balance to GDP ratio. In Submodel 3,
the user instead specifies national savings rates and public investment rates as exogenous, with the model
calculating implied private investment and growth rates.
13
ountries with different efficiency levels will have the same marginal product of public investment given the same parameters
C
and initial conditions. The marginal product of public investment depends on the marginal product of efficient public capital
and the translation of public investment to efficient capital and can be expressed as follows (using Equation (3) and (13)):
∂Yt +1 / ∂I tG = (∂Yt +1 / ∂θ t +1 K tGm
+1 )(∂θ t +1 K t +1 / ∂ I t ) = (φYt +1 / θ t +1 K t +1 )θ t
Gm G Gm N
Note that qt+1 and θ cancel out if efficiency is unchanged.
t
N
36
The Long Term Growth Model
• The future growth rates of the labor participation rate (g ), the working age-population ratio (gω,t+1),
,t+1
population (gN,t+1), human capital (gh,t+1), and pure TFP (gA,t+1), which are exogenous and can be
determined by the user.
• The growth rate of measured public capital per worker (gkGm,t+1), which is given by equation (12), using
the growth rate of the public capital stock (equation (11)) as an intermediate step.
• Private capital per worker growth (gkP,t+1) as given by equation (15).
• The growth rate of the efficiency of public capital (gθ,t+1) as given by equation (14) using the growth rate
of the public capital stock (equation (11)) as an intermediate step.
Finally, the model is closed by updating public capital-to-output using equation (18) and the private cap-
ital-to-output ratio using equation (19) (with the growth rates in per-worker terms):
K tGm
+1
= t
(
K G 1 + g kGm,t +1
) (18)
Yt +1 Yt 1 + g y ,t +1
=
(
K tP+1 K tP 1 + g k P ,t +1
) (19)
Yt +1 Yt 1 + g y ,t +1
• First, rearrange equation (8) to calculate required GDP growth per worker:
1 + g yPC,t +1
1 + g y ,t +1 = (20)
(1 + g ,t +1 )(1 + g ω ,t +1 )
• Then rearrange equation (6) to calculate the combined growth rate of efficiency-adjusted public capital
per worker (θ t K tGm /Lt ) required to generate the target growth in GDP per worker in equation (20).
Note here that gA,t+1, gh,t+1, and Γt+1 are all always exogenous, and the growth rate of private capital
per worker gkP,t+1 is calculated using equation (15) (as the private investment share is exogenous in
Submodel 2).
1/φ
1 + g y ,t +1
(1 + gθ ,t +1 )(1 + g k ) = θ θ KK
Gm
/ Lt +1
t +1 t +1
= (21)
(1 + g
( )
, t +1 1− β −ζφ
A , t +1 )[(1 + Γ t +1 ) (1 + g h,t +1 )β
Gm
Gm
/ Lt (1−ζ )φ
t t
] 1 + g k P ,t +1
14
igures for 2016, with the investment share of GDP from the World Bank MFMOD database on the public investment share
F
from the IMF FAD databases. Cross-country mean is 6.47% and cross-country median is 5.4% of GDP.
37
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
• Finally, one can rearrange equation (13A) in per worker terms to solve for the investment share of GDP
(recall that Γ is the growth rate of the number of workers, as in equation (7)):
(
I tG / Yt = [(1 + g θ ,t +1 ) 1 + g kGm,t +1 ) (1 + Γ t +1 ) − (1 − δ G )]
K tGm /Yt
θ tN /θ t
(22)
°° or equation (24) if instead they specify a path for external debt as a share of GDP (see the description
of the Standard LTGM for a derivation of these equations).15
I tP St FDI t Dt Dt −1 /Yt −1 I tG (24)
= + + − −
Yt Yt Yt Yt (1 + g yPC,t ) (1 + g N ,t ) Yt
Where CABt is the current account balance, FDIt is inbound foreign direct investment, and Dt is end-of-
year external debt.
• Once private investment is determined, the rest of the equations are the same as in Submodel 1.
15
Strictly speaking, in the LTGM, external debt, D, can capture all foreign portfolio assets and liabilities, which means D could be
decreasing if the country is accumulating foreign assets, for example through a sovereign wealth fund.
38
The Long Term Growth Model
n =1 )
where:
• I n equals the portion of efficient infrastructure type, n, calculated as 100 – electricity transmission and
distribution losses (% of output), 100 – water losses (% of provision), and paved roads (% of roads)
respectively;
• avg (2000 - latest): the average of available values of the infrastructure indicator, n, from 2000 until the
latest data point;
• latest available value (Starting 2000): the latest value available, the cut-off being the year 2000 (a country
is excluded if its latest data point is before 2000); and
• wn = infrastructure stock weight associated with each infrastructure, n. The weights are based on Fay and
Yepes (2003) and vary with income groups but not over time (see table 2.1).
16
ioja (2003) uses the physical infrastructure losses reported in World Bank (1994), weighted by corresponding infrastructure stock
R
shares according to Ingram and Fay (1994), to proxy the efficiency parameter for public capital stock in seven Latin American
countries and five industrialized countries. The infrastructure loss indicators comprise electricity power transmission and
distribution losses (% of output), faults per 100 main telephone lines per year, percentage of paved roads not in good condition,
and water losses (% of total provision). Calderon and Serven (2004, 2010) construct an infrastructure quality index based on the
first principal component of electricity losses, the share of paved roads, and the waiting time for telephone line installation.
39
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Table 2.1: The Composition of Infrastructure Stocks (Fay and Yepes 2003)
Figure 2.1: Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI)—Correlation with Per Capita Income and
Infrastructure Quality Score
IEI
BOL LTU
CMR CIV MNG CMR ZMB CIV
BGD MNG
SEN KHM
XKX BRA URY BRA KHM SEN
ECU URY KEN
KEN GHA NGA ALB
GAB GAB GHA
ALB
NER MOZ NAM
ETH NIC YEM NIC
VEN
0.6 MOZ YEM HND
NAM
0.6 VEN
HND
ETH
ZWE TZA ZWE
TZA
COD
TGO
BEN
0.4 0.4
6 7 8 9 10 11 2 3 4 5 6
ln (per capita income), PPP WEF Global Competitiveness Report 2014–2015,
(constant 2011, international US$) Infrastructure Quality Score
Figure 2.1 shows that the IEI has the expected properties, rising with GDP per capita (correlation: 0.72);
and the World Economic Forum (WEF) Global Competitiveness Report’s survey-based infrastructure
quality indicator (correlation: 0.68). According to the IEI, efficiency is highest in high-income countries
(including OECD members), with an average of 84%, followed by middle-income countries (77% for
upper-middle-income countries and 74% for lower-middle-income countries), and low-income countries
(58%). Further details on the sources of data and IEI summary statistics, as well as discussion on robustness
checks for the index are provided in appendix 2.
40
The Long Term Growth Model
cover 23 industrial countries (2005 paper), and 23 emerging and new EU member states (2010 paper), the
output measure is a composite of public sector performance based on a series of quantitative and qualitative
socioeconomic indicators, while the input measure is public sector spending (i.e., more than just public
investment). 17 For our model analysis purposes, we find that the results from these two papers may not be
suitable because (i) the outcome variable encompasses broad, indirect macroeconomic outcomes; and (ii)
efficiency is compared within a small group of countries—this may be particularly worrisome in the case
of the emerging market/new EU member sample.18
On the other hand, the IMF public investment efficiency indicator (PIE-X) covers more than 100 coun-
tries. The output variables are directly related to infrastructure—a quantity index (physical infrastruc-
ture coverage and provision of social services19) and a survey-based quality index20 respectively, as well
as a hybrid of the two; while the input variable is public capital stock per capita.21 While individual
country efficiency scores have not been published, group averages of the quantity indicator suggest that
advanced economies are 70% efficient (infrastructure output could be increased by 30% for the same
amount of public capital input), emerging markets are 60% efficient, while low-income developing
countries are at about 45% efficiency. Nevertheless, these are still relative performance indicators rather
than cardinal indicators of quality: a score of 70% does not mean that 30% of infrastructure stock is
not productive but rather the economy is operating 30% below the best performer in its peer group.
Aside from the above measures of inefficiency, there is also the IMF Public Investment Management
Index (PIMI) (see Dabla-Norris et al. 2012), a purely qualitative indicator based on scores for individual
country performance in terms of the investment process (project appraisal, selection, implementation,
and evaluation). While it provides information on relative performance across 71 developing countries
and shows a positive correlation with GDP per capita and indicators of governance quality, it is not
a cardinal indicator of the proportion of public capital that is productive, and only measures the
quality of input process. Despite this, Gupta et al. (2014) normalize the index on a 0–1 scale and use it
as a measure of efficiency-adjusted public capital effects on growth based on a sample of 52 countries.
They find that upper-middle-income countries have on average 57% efficient public capital stock
against 46% for lower-middle-income countries, and 38% for low-income countries.22
Table 2.2 summarizes the PIE-X and PIMI and how they compare against the IEI. While caution should
be exercised in comparing outcomes in absolute terms across different methodologies, one crucial
takeaway is that all methodologies point to a gap between high-income countries and low-income
countries. Thus, there appears to be substantial room for improvement in efficiency in low-income
countries, which could lead to a better growth performance.
17
ualitative indicators of corruption, red tape, judiciary efficiency, public infrastructure quality; and quantitative indicators of
Q
shadow economy size, secondary school enrollment, education achievement, infant mortality, and life expectancy; as well as
broad macroeconomic outcomes of income distribution, growth performance and stability, inflation, and unemployment.
18
S inha (2017) uses the emerging market/new EU member state average efficiency as a reference point for public investment
efficiency in Bangladesh.
19
ength of road network, electricity production, access to water, number of secondary teachers, and number of hospital
L
beds.
20
ased on the World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness Report survey responses on the quality of key infrastructure
B
services.
21
With GDP per capita as an auxiliary input variable.
22
We group Gupta et al. (2014)’s individual country calculations according to the World Bank income classification scheme.
41
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
42
The Long Term Growth Model
43
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
all public capital. This latter value is slightly larger than the estimates in Calderon, Moral-Benito, and
Serven (2015) of f = 0.07 − 0.10.
Bom and Ligthart (2014) look at 68 empirical studies23 which cover the period 1983–2008. These studies
are based on the production function approach and measure public capital in monetary and stock terms.
Bom and Ligthart’s meta-analysis indicates an average elasticity of output to public capital of 0.106 (not
reported), which is higher in the long run and for core public capital, but lower for the aggregate public
capital/national government level (compared to the regional/local government level).
Nunez-Serrano and Velazquez (2016) consider 145 papers24 which cover the period 1983–2011. The empir-
ical studies scrutinized are predominantly those that take a production function approach (85% of the
sample) and include studies that use nonmonetary (17%) and flow (7%) measures of public capital. They
find an average elasticity of output to public capital of 0.132, which is higher in the long run, 0.161. Though
with less statistical significance, there is also an indication that the elasticity value is higher with productive
public capital. The distinction between monetary and nonmonetary measures of public capital does not
have a discernible effect. A summary of select results from the respective meta-analyses of Bom and Ligthart
(2014) and Nunez-Serrano and Velazquez (2016) is presented in table 2.4.
Neither of the two meta-analyses contains a discussion of potential differences in f between developed and
developing countries. However, Calderon, Moral-Benitok, and Serven (2015),25 using a relatively extensive
cross-country sample, find that the long-run elasticity of infrastructure does not seem to vary with coun-
tries’ per capita income levels, infrastructure endowment, or population size.
23
f the 68 studies, 5 cover country groups (of which one is exclusively developing countries) and 63 are country-specific
O
(all advanced economies).
24
f the 145 studies, 26 cover country groups (of which five are exclusively developing countries) and 119 are country-specific
O
(of which five are developing countries).
25
In the study, infrastructure is measured as a composite of several physical infrastructure indicators (as opposed to the
monetary value of capital stock). A panel data set is used, comprising 88 countries that cut across different income levels and
infrastructure endowments.
26
e use the following data from the IMF to calculate the shares: general government capital stock and private capital stock in
W
billions of constant 2011 international dollars.
44
The Long Term Growth Model
Given different computation methodologies, aggregate K/Y ratios differ between the PWT 8.1 and the
IMF, and are on average lower in the latter case.27 We assume that public capital is mostly structures, and so
apply the 2% structures depreciation rate from PWT 8.1. The private capital depreciation rate is a residual
K Gm KP
determined by the country-specific PWT 8.1 depreciation rate for aggregate K: δ = δ G +δ P .
K K
5.2.3 Congestion (ζ = 1) versus pure public good (ζ = 0) and actual versus
measured TFP growth
Users of the LTGM-PC must choose either a calibration with congestion (ζ = 1) or without it (pure public
good ζ = 0). Unless users strongly feel that public capital in their country is not congested, we recommend
using the congestion calibration. We use this ourselves as the default for the results in this chapter and in the
Excel-based tool. The reason is that without congestion, actual TFP in the model (At in equation 1) tends to
depart from measured TFP using standard growth accounting exercises. In any practical application of the
LTGM-PC, the actual TFP growth rate is one of the most important assumptions, and also the most difficult
to calibrate. When using the congestion specification, the actual TFP growth rate is similar to what one
would get applying a standard growth accounting exercise. In contrast, without congestion the measured
TFP growth rate is above the actual TFP growth rate, and so cannot be used to guide the calibration of the
actual TFP growth rates without some kind of adjustment.
To see this, for each country we used the LTGM-PC to generate a growth path by assuming that actual TFP
growth (At) was the same as that recorded in PWT 8.1 (over a 10-year average).28 Then we performed a
standard growth accounting exercise on the generated growth rates (given growth rates of other growth
fundamentals, such as human capital and the total capital stock), to generate measured TFP growth. We
then compared the measured TFP growth to the inputted actual TFP growth.
Figure 2.2 plots actual (x-axis) versus measured (y-axis) TFP growth for the congestion (ζ = 1, LHS) and
pure public good (ζ = 0, RHS) calibrations. As one can see, generally actual and measured TFP growth are
27
oth sources of data use variations of the perpetual inventory method to estimate aggregate capital stocks and do not take
B
into account the destruction/damage of capital from wars/conflicts (which is naturally difficult to measure). Wars/conflicts
also reduce output, perhaps faster than they destroy capital, and so the aggregate K/Y ratio may rise as a country enters a
war/conflict. In the reconstruction period, it would not be surprising if measured public capital is extremely high because it
fails to take account of the public capital destroyed in the conflict.
28
o be clear, the exercise is not dependent on the source of assumed actual TFP growth, but just that its distribution across
T
countries is reasonable.
45
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Figure 2.2: Measured TFP Growth from LTGM-PC (ϕ = 0.17) Based on Growth Accounting versus
Actual TFP Growth
8 TJK 10
7 9 MLI
8 TJK
6 MDA
ARM
SLE 7 CHN MDA
5 KAZ
ARM
MLI ALB 6
4 CHNSRB 5 KGZ
KAZ
ALBSLE
ROMUKR
RUS MOZ
MOZ IRQ ETH GHA ROM
3 CAF
SVK
JOR
MNG 4 VCT
CAF
PANBFA LKA
ZMB
RWA
SRB
RUS
JORUKR
RWA
ARG NAM LSO SVKMNG
IRQ
2 GHA
ZMB
KGZ
LKA
LTU
POL
LSO
ZAR
TTO 3 LCA
BRB CPV UGA
GEO
TZA
IND
LTU
POL
NGA ARG
ETH
NGA HKG
TZA
CZE BEN MKD
MKD PER
IND
CPV
MNE SYR SWE
COG ZAR
HKG
1 NAM
VCT
PANPHL
LCA LVA
GEO
HUNTHA
NER
HRV
UGA
SWZKHM
MDG
BIH
2 KEN
GNQ
LAO
NER
PHL
IDN
MNE PER
CZE
LVA
TTO
BRB SVN
SWE
KEN COM
GNB
EST NPL
BGD
MEX DOM
MAR KHM SYR
HUN
HRV
MDG
NPLBGR
PAK
LAO MAR
MYS
MUS
DOMBFA
IDN
SUR CRI EST
BLR
MUS
BIHTHA
0
BEN
CMR
MEX
JPN
PRY
NLD
GBR
VNM
BGD
ISL
COL
SLV
CHE
KWT
PRT
SAU
CRI
TGO
DNK
ITA
JAM
BHR
LUX
BWA
TUN
USA
KOR
TUR
CYP
SENBRA
MWI
GIN
LBN
AZE
SGP
BLZ
COG
BLR
1 COL
GAB
CMR
GBR
SDN
ZWE
IRL
GTM
BWA
ISL
NZL
BLZ
BGR
TUR
VNM
KWT
ZAF
SAU
SEN
NLD
AUS AZE
LBN
TUN
MYS
SVN
KOR
USA
PAK
JPN
JAM
ESP
ZAF
FRA
DEU
AUS
GAB
NZL
URY
FIN
IRL CHE
DEU
PRY
ESP
FRA
URY
CAN TCD
SUR
COM
CAN
CHL
GTM
HND
BEL
SDN
ZWE
ISR SLV
DNKBRA
CYPSGP GNB
SWZ
AUT
MLT 0 HND
CHL
PRT
ITA
FIN
BHR
LUX
NOR
TGO
BEL
MWIAGO
ISR
GMB
–1 NOR
GMB
GNQAGO
ECU
BOL
AUT
BDI GIN
MLT
BDI
GRCVENTCD -1 ECU
–2 MRT
BOL
MRT
OMN
-2 VEN
GRC
–3 -3 OMN
–4 -4
–5 -5
–5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Actual TFP growth, % (PWT 8.1) Actual TFP growth, % (PWT 8.1)
Note: Excludes outliers, Liberia, and Macao, the former showing large negative measured TFP growth under congestion, and the latter large
positive measured TFP growth in the pure public good setting.
See table 2.3 on the calculation of actual TFP growth. Measured TFP growth is obtained using traditional growth accounting (with total capital
stock) based on the initial (2017) baseline output growth rates of the congestion and pure public good calibrations.
very similar (close to the 45-degree line) for the congestion specification, but less so for the pure public
good specification. Quantitatively, the mean absolute deviation (MAD) between actual and measured TFP
growth for congestion is around 0.6ppts, whereas for the pure public good specification it is twice as large
(1.2ppts), and also measured TFP growth is biased upwards.29
This result can be shown analytically with some mild assumptions. Let measured TFP growth
be g measA = g Y − β ( g h + g L ) − (1 − β )g K (where gk is the growth rate of the total capital stock),
and actual TFP growth in the LTGM-PC (from equation (3), rearranged in growth rates) be
g actual
A = g Y − β ( g h + g L ) − φ( g θ + g K Gm ) − (1 − β − ζφ )g K P . In order for standard growth accounting to inform
our TFP growth assumptions, we need g meas A = g actual
A which implies φ( g θ + g K Gm ) + (1 − β − ζφ )g K P = (1 − β )g K.
If we assume that (i) there is no trend growth in efficiency (gθ = 0, which must be true in the long run
as θ is bounded above by 1), and (ii) all capital stocks grow at approximately the same nonzero rate
( g K ≈ g K Gm ≈ g K P ≠ 0), then g meas A = g actual
A ⇒ ζ = 1.
A corollary is that if growth rates of the different types of capital are similar (and other fundamentals are the
same), then the growth rate of GDP generated by the LTGM-PC is consistent with a growth rate generated
by a canonical neoclassical model with aggregate capital like the Standard LTGM. We show this numerically
in appendix A1.3.
29
The MAD between actual and measured TFP growth when public capital was assumed to be less useful (φ = 0.1) was also
smaller for the congestion specification (0.6ppts) than the pure public good specification (1.0ppts).
46
The Long Term Growth Model
30
Cutoffs are expressed in GNI per capita (to 2 significant figures), calculated using the World Bank Atlas method.
31
Replication files for the main tables and figures are available from the authors upon request.
47
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Table 2.5: Median Values of Baseline Parameters and Paths of Variables by Income Group
The second answer is that developing countries have a shortage of public capital relative to their development
aspirations, but not relative to their current development level. That is, people in low-income countries
have many unmet needs, with public infrastructure capital being in just as short supply as everything else.
As the “usefulness” of public capital does not vary with income (Calderon, Moral-Benito, and Serven 2015),
the stability of the public capital-to-output ratio across income levels also means that the marginal product
of measured public capital (MPKGm) is not relatively larger in developing countries. As we will see in the next
section, this is the effect of an expansion of public investment on growth in the short run, with unchanged
efficiency. Specifically, we find that with our relatively generous calibration of usefulness (f = 0.17), that the
MPKGm is around 18.5% (±1%), which varies inversely with the public capital-to-output ratio (table 2.5,
panel B). After subtracting the depreciation rate of 2% (constant across countries), this yields a return to
48
The Long Term Growth Model
new public investment of around 16.5% (±1%) which also does not vary systematically across levels of
development. The relatively high absolute returns stem from the high assumed usefulness of public capital
in our default calibration. If instead we assumed f = 0.1 (for public buildings), then the return to public
investment falls to around 9% (±1%), though the ranking across income groups is unchanged.
While some might interpret the lack of a higher return to public investment in LI countries as a negative,
we are more sanguine. The lack of a low return also means that development banks need not refrain from
lending for infrastructure projects in countries with poor implementation capacity—as they are often
encouraged to do—because that low capacity also means the projects are even more in need.32
In contrast, it seems that LI countries have a shortage of private capital for their level of development, and
the scarcity of private capital falls with per capita income. Specifically, KP/Y is around 1.25 for LI countries,
around 1.80 for middle-income (MI) countries and 2.25 for HI countries (80% higher than that of LI
countries). Measured public capital is also the largest share of total capital in LI countries (44%) and
the lowest share in HI countries (28%). This reflects the fact that private financial markets are typically
underdeveloped in LI countries and so the private sector finds it difficult to raise funds for investment. In
some countries insecure property rights also reduce the incentive to invest in the first place.
A consequence is that the marginal product of private capital is the highest in LI countries (25%), which is
double that in HI countries (12%), with MI countries in between. Note that the MPKP does not vary exactly
inversely with the KP/Y across income groups, because of cross-country variation in the capital share 1−β.33
After subtracting depreciation (around 5%), the return to private investment is the highest in LI countries
(around 20%), lower in MI countries (13–17%) and lowest in HI countries (7%). Interestingly, the return
to private capital for LI countries is actually higher than for public investment (20% versus 16%), suggesting
that if savings are scarce, governments need to be careful that public investment does not crowd out private
investment.
As today’s capital stocks reflect past investment, one might expect that public investment would make up
a larger share of total investment in LI countries—which is exactly what we find. Public investment is 37%
of total investment in LI countries, double the share in HI countries (18%), with MI countries in between
(23%).34 Translated to a share of GDP, public investment spending decreases steadily with income per capita:
4% of GDP in HI countries, 5% in UMI countries, 6% in LMI countries, and 7% of GDP in LI countries.
Keefer and Knack (2007) argue that this is likely due to poor quality governance in developing countries,
rather than the level of income per se. Consistent with earlier results, private investment is particularly
lacking in LI countries—around 13% of GDP versus 17–18% of GDP in the other three income groups.
32
or example, Keefer and Knack (2007) argue that their “results therefore signal the need for donor agencies to exercise
F
particular caution in supporting public investment in countries with a weak institutional environment.”
33
he return to private capital is even higher with φ = 0.1 (though its ranking across groups is unchanged), as the penalty for
T
reducing the congestion of public capital is lower.
34
hese figures are average investment rates over 2001–2015. In steady state Kj/Y = I/Y = (gy + δ j) for j = G,P. If the countries in
T
table 2.5 were in steady state, headline GDP growth rates would need to be ≈3% for HI countries, ≈3.8% for UMI countries,
≈4.8% for LMI, and ≈5.6% for LI countries, which are fairly close to what we observe.
49
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Figure 2.3: Incremental Output Growth from a 1 ppt increase in Public Investment in the
LTGM-PC (congestion, ζ = 1)
a. HI b. UMI
0.25 0.25
0.20 0.20
%
0.15 0.15
%
0.10 0.10
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 17
20 9
20 21
2023
20 5
20 27
20 9
20 31
2033
20 5
20 37
20 9
20 41
2043
20 5
20 47
49
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
2
4
2
4
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
c. LMI d. LI
0.25 0.25
0.20 0.20
0.15 0.15
%
%
0.10 0.10
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 47
20 9
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
20 5
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
49
20 17
4
2
3
2
4
2
3
2
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
The second thing to note from figure 2.3 is that the increment to growth falls over time. This is because
as public capital accumulates, K Gm/Y increases, which reduces the marginal product of measured public
capital. This is intuitive: one would expect an increase in public investment to become less effective
in boosting growth over time as “infrastructure needs” are met. There is some heterogeneity across
income groups: the boost to growth is slightly less persistent in LI countries. If these countries had a
lower capital share (1−β), the marginal product of private capital which is “crowded in” would decline
more quickly (in addition to marginally higher K Gm/Y which means the marginal product of public
capital dwindles faster over time). However, there is little evidence LI countries have a lower capital
share.
Finally, the effect of an increase in public investment in the LTGM-PC (with f = 0.17 and z = 1) is, on
average, similar to the effect of a same-sized increase in aggregate investment in the Standard LTGM (brown
solid line) for all but HI countries. Specifically, the effect in the LTGM-PC is very similar to the Standard
LTGM for MI countries, slightly lower for LI countries, and higher for HI countries. The latter is because
HI countries tend to have the lowest share of total capital owned by the public sector. The effect of public
investment on growth is naturally much smaller in the LTGM-PC when f = 0.10 (dashed green line), but
is also much smaller than the comparable effect in the Standard LTGM (except in HI countries). Greater
consistency with the Standard LTGM is one reason we prefer the f = 0.17 calibration over the f = 0.10
calibration.35
35
ith the pure public good setting (appendix 3, graph A3.1), the immediate effect of higher public investment is broadly
W
similar to that of the congestion setting, but is more persistent.
50
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 2.4: Incremental Output Growth from a 1 ppt increase in Private Investment in the
LTGM-PC (congestion, ζ = 1)
a. HI b. UMI
0.35 0.35
0.30 0.30
0.25 0.25
0.20 0.20
%
%
0.15 0.15
0.10 0.10
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 17
20 9
20 21
2023
20 5
20 27
20 9
20 31
2033
20 5
20 37
20 9
20 41
2043
20 5
20 47
49
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
2
4
2
4
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
c. LMI d. LI
0.35 0.35
0.30 0.30
0.25 0.25
0.20 0.20
%
0.15
%
0.15
0.10 0.10
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 3
45
20 47
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
49
20 17
4
2
3
2
3
2
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
51
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
In the short run, based on equations (16A) and (16B), the difference in the short-run boost to growth from
similar increments to private and public investment-to-output ratios, respectively is given by equation (25).
One can see that short-run return to private investment is larger if (1 − β − ζφ ) /φ > K tP / K tGm . This condition
is violated (with public investment generating a larger increase in growth) when public investment is
relatively useful (high f relative to 1−β) and public capital is relatively scarce (high K tP / K tGm). One can see
this as the lower right region of figure 2.5(b).36
∂ g yPC,t +1 ∂ g yPC,t +1 Yt K tP
− = (1 − β − ζφ ) − φ K Gm (25)
∂ I tP /Yt ∂ I tG /Yt K tP
t
Private Public
The increment to growth from private investment in the short run is higher than that for public investment
whenever private capital stock is approximately less than double the public capital stock (figure 2.5(a)),
with f = 0.17 and z = 1). This occurs for 40% of countries, and the median KP/K Gm of countries with a
higher effect of private investment is 1.26. As the marginal product of private capital is higher in the pure
public good setting (since there is no congestion), the return to private investment is naturally higher.
Specifically, under the pure public good setting (see appendix 3, graph A3.3 (i)), the increment to growth
from private investment is higher for two-thirds of countries, and the median KP/K Gm of countries with a
higher increment is 1.60.37
In the long run, the increment to growth from private investment is higher for only a quarter of countries,
and for those countries the private and public capital stocks are roughly the same size (figure 2.6, f = 0.17,
z = 1). Under the pure public good setting (see appendix 3, graph A3.4(i)), the increment to growth from
Figure 2.5: Private Investment Versus Public Investment in the LTGM-PC - Differences in Short-
Run Incremental Output Growth (ϕ = 0.17, congestion, ζ = 1)
1.0 1.0
Incremental growth
0.8 AGO
is larger for private
0.8
investment
Private-Public Investment: SR
IRQ
incremental Growth, ppt
0.6 TTO
Capital share (1–beta)
TJK
0.6
0.4 VEN
OMN
MOZ OMN
IRQ
CAF
TJK
VEN
TTO
AGO SAU
MOZ
CHN
BOLECU
KHM
VCT
BLZ KWT
MEX
LAO
BWAMUS
NGA
AZEBHRPAK
GIN
GEO
GAB
THA
TUN
LCA
VNM
URY MAC
SLV
TUR
MRT
MNESEN
PER
ALBSGP
GTM
TZAKAZ
DOM PHLSUR LBN CHL
PAN
ARG
MNG COL
GNQ IND BGR
JOR
NER NPL IDN
GNQ
BOL
CAF ETH NZL CMR
LUXUGA MAR MLT
ETHBLZ JPN
ROM BGD
GRC ZAF
COG
SYR MYSMWI
MDG CPV
KGZ
NAM HKG
SDN
NOR
LTU IRL
SVK
KOR
ITA
ZWE
0.2 GNBSYR
COG
AZE
VCT
JAM
BFAMKD
POL
PRY CYP CZE
CAN LVA AUS
BRA
ISR
KHM
SAU 0.4 LSOBDI HNDFIN EST AUT
COM ECU GIN
MNG
CHN GNB
COMGMBLBR
ZAR
BENSWZ
ZMB NLD
MLIUSA
SLE HRV FRARUS
MDA
SWE ARMHUN
GBRCRI DEU BEL
SRB
BLR
MYS
GMB BWA
KWTLCA UKRESP
LSOBDI
MDG
MWI MUS
MEXNGA
TUN
PAK
BHR RWA
BIH KENPRT
URY
LAO
COL
VNM
THA TCD
0
JPN
BFA
RWA NER
NZL
ROM GAB
GEO TUR BRB TGO GHA ISL SVN
DNK LKA CHE
BRB
ZAR
LBR
ZMB
BIHSLE
BENJAM
MKD
KGZ GRC
JOR
CPV
SWZ
NAM
MRT
IND
BGD
PRY
POL
CMR
SLV
MNE
MACPER
SEN
BGR
ALB
LUX SGP
Incremental growth
UGA
TGO HRV MDA
USA CYP
FIN
FRA HKGNPL
TZA KAZARG is larger for public
HND
NLD
DNK NOR
RUS
LTU KOR
CZE
ITADOM
ISLPRT
MLI SWE UKRHUN
GTM
CAN
ZAF
SVNESTAUT
ESP SVK
LVAPHL SUR 0.2
KEN
GHA ARM
GBR
SDN CHE
DEU MAR
PAN BEL
LBN
AUS investment
–0.2 TCD LKA CRI IRL SRBBRACHL
IDN
ZWE ISR 1–beta = 0.17(K(P)/K(G)+1)
BLR MLT
–0.4 0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Private/public capital (K(P)/K(G)) Private/public capital (K(P)/K(G))
Yt K tP
Analytical Difference: (1 − β − ζφ ) − φ Gm . See equation (25).
K t
P
K t
KP K Gm
36
Readers will note that this is a rearrangement of (1 − β − ζφ ) / t > φ / t , which is an equivalent condition that the
Y Y
marginal product of private capital is higher than the marginal product of public capital.
37
When f = 0.10, more countries record a higher increment to growth from private investment: 84% of countries under the
congestion setting (see appendix 3, A3.3(ii)).
52
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 2.6: Private Investment Versus Public Investment in the LTGM-PC - Differences in Long-
Run Incremental Output Growth (ϕ = 0.17, congestion, ζ = 1 )
1.0 1.6
GIN
0.8
TJK
0.4
Private-Public Investment: LR
Private-Public Investment: LR
incremental Growth, ppt
TJK 0.2
0.4 GNB GRC
VEN BOL
TTO
AGO
OMN
ECU
MOZ
0.2 IRQETHBLZ
MNG
COG
GNQ AZE
MWI
BWA
SWZ CMR
BHR
GRC GNB 0 SYR
LSO
CAF
COM
BDI
SAU
VCT
RWA
KHM
LBR
CHN
MYS
KWT
SLE
BFA
MDG NER MNE
LCA
VNM
COL
ZARLAO
BEN MLI
THA
PAKMRT
BGD
PRY
UGA
BGR
SEN HUN
ARG
BIH KGZ
MUS
NZL
MKD
JAM
JPN
TGO MDA
KEN
GHA
GAB
TUN MACLUXLKA
HKG
SVN
SGPNPL
SVK
BOL OMN BRB
GMBZMBROMGEO
NAM
URY TUR
TCD
IND
POL
DNK
HRV
SWEPER
NLDFINARM
NORCZE
EST
KAZ
CRI PAN
LVA
TTO AGO MEX JOR FRA CAN
KOR
ZAF MAR
SWZCMR
ECUAZE
MNG BLZ MOZ IRQ
SLV
USA ALB
ISLPRT
CYP
RUSTZA
LTU
GBR CHEPHL AUS
ITA
ESP
AUT SRB CHL BLR
IDN
0 UGA
ARGLBR
SLE MWI
BHR
NER
MNE
BGRRWA
VNM
BFA BWA
KWT
LSO
BDI
LCASAUCOG
SYR
VCT
KHM
CHN
ETH
GNQ
CAF CPV HND UKR DOM DEU BEL
LKAKENHUN
MLI
SVK MDA
NPL
HKG SEN
BENMRT
BGD
ZAR
PRY
KGZ
BIH L
NZL
MKD
JAM MDG
COL
THA MYS
AO
PAK COM
MUS BRA
GHA
PAN
TCD
CRI SVN
ARM
EST
LVA
SWE NOR
CZELUX
MAC
TGO
SGP
KAZ
DNK
FIN
HRV
NLD PER
BRB
IND
NAM
ZMB
POL JPN
GAB
ROM
TURTUN
GEO
URYGMB
AUS CAN
MAR
ESP
GBR KOR
FRA
ZAF
TZA
LTU
PHL ALB
USA
ITA
PRT
ISLCYP
RUS JOR
SLV MEX ISR
BLR IDNCHE
SRB
CHL AUT
DEU DOM
HNDCPV NGA ZWE
BEL
BRA
UKR –0.2 GTM IRL
SDN LBN
ISR
ZWE NGA SUR
–0.2 IRLSDN
LBNGTM MLT
SUR
MLT
–0.4 –0.4
-0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Private-public investment: SR incremental growth, ppt Private-public capital (K(P)/K(G))
private investment is higher for around 40% of countries, and the median KP/K Gm of countries with a higher
increment is 1.24.38
Overall, for our sample of countries and calibration, public investment has stronger effects on growth than
private investment for most countries, assuming that the elasticity of output to public capital is relatively
high (f = 0.17) The approximate cut-off where public investment tends to have stronger effects is when
KP/K Gm > 2 (or equivalently, K Gm/KP< 0.5).39 In the short run, the boost to growth from public investment
is only larger than for private investment for most countries when there is congestion.
38
When f = 0.10, more countries would record a higher increment to growth from private investment (see appendix 3,
graph A3.4(ii)).
39
ngola and Iraq are outliers in figures 2.5(a) and 2.6(a), which may reflect that both have been involved in long drawn-out
A
conflicts. See footnote 25, for a further discussion of how K/Y ratios might be affected by war/conflict.
40
erg et al. (2015) show that for the Cobb-Douglas production function (as used here), these two are exactly offsetting.
B
However, even with the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function the two factors are mostly offsetting
unless public and private capital are extremely complementary (their figure 2.3).
53
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
φ
Marginal product of efficient public capital MPK eG = 0.226 0.234 0.259 0.296
θ t K t /Yt
Gm
I tG /Yt
Marginal product of efficiency MPe = φ 0.009 0.011 0.015 0.022
θ t K tGm /Yt
m = IG/Y/q = ppts increase in IG/Y equivalent to 1ppts increase in qN 0.045 0.065 0.079 0.125
after one year (also equivalent by 2040)
For a general description of the sources of data, see table 2.3.
Countries are classified according to the 2018 World Bank classification of countries by income for the 2017 calendar year.
* Multiply by 100 (except values in ppts) to obtain parameter/variable values in percentage share or growth terms (%).
** Number of countries for efficiency q is based on IEI data.
Calculations for θ K 0Gm /Y0 , MPK eG , MPe and µ, are formed by combining the data in table 2.5 with the efficiency q for each income group (not on
a constant group of countries).
being paved or water/electricity reaching their final destination. For MI countries, efficiency is about 74%,
or one-seventh lower. Efficiency is the lowest for LI countries, where only 59% of roads are paved or water/
electricity reach their final destination; which is about one-third lower than efficiency in HI countries.
One can also use the IEI to calculate the efficient public capital-to-output ratio θ K 0Gm /Y0. Because the public
capital-to-output ratio (K 0Gm /Y0 ) is roughly constant across levels of development, but efficiency q increases
with development, the combined efficient public capital-to-output ratio also increases with development.
Specifically, the efficient public capital-to-output ratio is around 0.75 in HI countries, 0.73 in UMI coun-
tries, 0.66 in LMI countries, and 0.57 in LI countries. This suggests that LI countries do not have a shortage
of measured public capital (as argued above), but rather a shortage of efficient public capital.
How should we interpret the efficient public capital to output ratio θ K 0Gm /Y0 for policy? Equation (26)
is the marginal product of efficient public capital ( MPK eG ) — the effect of an extra ppt of GDP of efficient
investment θ tN [I tG /Yt ] on growth (the derivative of equation 16 with respect to θ tN I tG /Yt ). One can see that
the MPK eG is inversely proportional to the efficient public capital-to-output ratio θ K 0Gm /Y0. As such, a low
efficient public capital-to-output ratio means that the return to an extra efficient unit of public investment
is high.
∂ g yPC,t +1 φ (26)
MPK eG ≡ =
∂[θ tN I tG /Yt ] θ t K tGm /Yt
Because LI countries have the lowest Gt /Yt = θ K 0Gm /Y0 they also have the highest MPK eG = 30%, which is
almost double the regular marginal product of public capital from section 6.1. In contrast, MI countries have
a MPK eG of about 25%, while HI countries, a lower MPK eG of 23%.41 The high MPK eG means that if a typical
LI country (with low efficiency) were somehow able to invest efficiently, the returns for growth would be
very high. But this is a hypothetical scenario. As Berg et al. (2015) and others point out, quickly increasing
41
he large absolute size of the MPK eG stems from the generous calibration of usefulness (f = 0.17). Instead, with f =0.10, the
T
MPK eG falls to 17% for LI countries, and 14–15% in MI and 13% HI countries.
54
The Long Term Growth Model
public investment implementation capacity is difficult, largely because public investment capacity has deep
determinants, such as poor institutional quality and a lack of relevant bureaucratic human capital.
In table 2.6, one can see that the MPe is highest in LI countries (0.022), which is more than double the rate
in HI (0.009) countries. UMI and LMI countries are in-between (0.011 and 0.015, respectively). As such
a 5ppt immediate increase in θ tN : for LI countries will raise growth by 0.022 × 5ppts = 11ppts, which is
similar to the boost to growth in the first period in figure 2.7. For HI countries, in contrast, a 5ppt increase
in efficiency would raise growth by a much lower 5ppts (0.009 x 5ppts). The MPe is inversely proportional
to the efficient public capital-to-output ratio, is increasing in the usefulness of public capital (f) and also
increasing in the public investment to output ratio (I tG /Yt ).
This last somewhat surprising result is because an increase in efficiency θ tN only affects new investment.
Intuitively, in countries with low public investment rates, an increase in the efficiency of new public invest-
ment will only have a small short-run effect on the average efficiency of installed capital—and hence on
growth—because the new efficient public capital is only a small fraction of the total capital stock. In these
countries, a permanent increase in the efficiency of public investment will still boost output, but it will just
take more time for these gains to materialize.
42
ow base efficiency is important because it is the percentage (not percentage point) increase in efficiency that determines the
L
effect on growth. A fixed 5 ppts increase in efficiency is a larger proportion of a low base.
43
s f is the elasticity of output with respect to efficient public capital, the effect of an increase in the efficiency is much lower
A
with f = 0.10 than with f = 0.17.
55
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Figure 2.7: Incremental Output Growth from a 5-ppt. Increase in theEfficiency of Public
Investment in the LTGM-PC (congestion, ζ = 1)
a. HI b. UMI
0.15 0.15
Initial : 0.87 Initial : 0.75
Scenario, in 2017 and onwards: 0.92 Scenario, in 2017 and onwards: 0.80
in 2035: 0.90 in 2035: 0.78
0.10 0.10
%
%
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 17
20 9
20 21
2023
20 5
20 27
20 9
20 31
2033
20 5
20 37
20 9
20 41
2043
20 5
20 47
49
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
20 5
20 47
49
2
4
2
4
1
3
20
20
20
20
c. LMI d. LI
0.15 0.15
Initial : 0.73 Initial : 0.59
Scenario, in 2017 and onwards: 0.78 Scenario, in 2017 and onwards: 0.64
in 2035: 0.76 in 2035: 0.63
0.10 0.10
%
%
0.05 0.05
0 0
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
20 17
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 27
20 9
20 31
20 41
20 3
45
20 47
49
20 3
35
20 37
20 9
2
4
3
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Congestion, ϕ = 0.17 Congestion, ϕ = 0.10
Instead, we calculate the size of the increase in the public investment rate (mSR ppts of GDP) equivalent to a
1ppt increase in efficiency. The larger the value of mSR, the more effective an increase in investment quality is
at boosting short-run growth (relative to boosting the quantity of investment). Setting MPe = mSR × MPK Gm
(from equations (27) and (16A)):
1 I tG /Yt 1 (28)
φ = µ × φ K Gm /Y
θ t K t /Yt
Gm
t t
A nice feature of this comparison is that it does not depend on measured public capital scarcity (K tGm /Yt ),
or the usefulness of public capital (f), which cancel out in equation (28). That is, greater scarcity and
usefulness increase MPe and MPK Gm proportionately and so do not affect the relative effectiveness of
quality versus quantity (though they do affect the aggregate size of both marginal products). Rearranging
implies:
I tG /Yt (29)
µSR =
θt
Equation (29) suggests that increases in investment quality are particularly effective in (i) countries with
a high rate of public investment (because only new investment is affected by the improved investment
management processes), and (ii) countries with low existing quality of public capital (so the improvement
56
The Long Term Growth Model
MOZ
0.13
NER VEN
MYS MNG
BOL
IND ECU
BHR
KGZ NAM
0.06 KOR
JOR
TUN SEN BEN
MUS NZL MDA GAB
HRV TUR MEX
BGR CMR TZA
KAZ LKA PAN
SGP POL KEN
USA PER HND TGO
SVK NOR HUN PRY
LTU URY
AUS
UKR CRI
0.03 DNK EGY
CYP
SRB ZAF CIV
IDN ARG
in quality is larger in percentage [not percentage point] terms). For LI countries, mSR = 0.13 ppts of GDP,
that is a 1ppt increase in the quality of public investment, has the equivalent effect on short-run growth as
a 0.13ppts increase in quantity of public investment. Given that improving investment processes could be
almost free (if feasible), saving 0.13ppts of GDP on public investment expenditure for the same short-run
growth outcome is good policy. Of course, improvements in quality are not as powerful elsewhere. For
MI countries, an extra unit of efficiency is worth mSR ≈ 0.07ppts of GDP of public investment, and for HI
countries (with the lowest I tG /Yt and highest quality θ) mSR = 0.05ppts.
For individual countries with available data on IEI and public investment, figure 2.8 plots the size of
recent public investment-to-output ratios (15-year average, 2001–2015) on the y-axis, and existing quality
(as reflected by the IEI) on the x-axis. The further a country is toward the top right of the figure, the more
effective a 1ppt increase in investment quality is relative to greater investment quantity. Lines represent the
locus of points for m = 0.05ppts, 0.1ppts or 0.2 ppts. Specifically, many LI countries have public invest-
ment-to-output ratios that are greater than 5% and efficiency levels lower than 0.6 and so fit on the upper
right-hand side with the most to gain. Most HI countries are on the lower left-hand side with high efficiency
and low public investment rates, suggesting limited gains from higher efficiency. Outliers are China (CHN)
and Malaysia (MYS), which appear to have relatively high efficiency levels (≈0.85) but can still make sizable
gains given relatively high public investment ratios of 20% and 11% respectively. China and Mozambique
benefit the most overall, where a 1ppt higher efficiency is equivalent to an ≈0.25ppts GDP increase in public
investment.
Our calculations so far have involved the short-run increase in investment equivalent to a 1ppt increase in
efficiency (mSR ). Instead, one might be interested in the permanent increase in investment that generates
the same increase in GDP per capita (GDPPC) by 2040 as a 1ppt increase in efficiency—what we call mLR
Using numerical simulations we find that the values of mSR and mLR are almost identical. This is because the
increase in efficiency (and equivalently sized increase in IG/Y) is small, which means that any nonlinearities
are second order.
57
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
7. Conclusion
In this chapter, we develop a new model of public investment and growth—the Long Term Growth Model
Public Capital Extension (LTGM-PC)—which is designed to capture the effect of increases in public
infrastructure investment quantity or quality on growth, while at the same time being simple enough to
solve in a spreadsheet without macros (the Excel-based tool is provided as a companion to this chapter at
the website www.worldbank.org/LTGM). Relative to the Standard Long Term Growth Model (LTGM), our
extension allows public and private capital to enter the production function separately and for public capital
to be of poor quality such that only a fraction can be used in production.
The effects of public and private investment on growth in our model vary substantially across countries
depending on whether the country is relatively short of public or private capital—but on average are similar
to the effect of aggregate investment in the Standard LTGM. We show analytically and numerically that
the effect of public investment on growth is higher when the public capital-to-output ratio is lower—that
is, when public capital is scarce. Conversely, in countries where public capital is abundant relative to other
factors—even if it is scarce in absolute terms—public investment will have a smaller effect on growth. The
growth impact is also larger when public investment is more useful, such as when it is in the form of essential
infrastructure (public investment in other areas will have a lower return).
In contrast with several popular narratives, we find the growth impact of an increase in public investment
is very similar across different levels of development. For a typical low- or middle-income country with
our default parameters, a permanent 1ppt of GDP increase in public investment in essential infrastructure
tends to boost growth by around 0.18ppts in the short term, but the boost to growth falls slowly over time as
public capital accumulates. Other less useful types of public investment (like public buildings) have a boost
to growth of around 0.1ppts. In contrast, a permanent 1ppt of GDP increase in private investment leads to a
slightly higher short-term boost to growth of about 0.22ppts, although the effect tapers off faster over time.
Model simulations also show that there can be substantial growth dividends from improvements in the
quality of new public investment. Our new Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI) suggests a public capital
efficiency loss of about 30 ppts for low-income countries, and 10–15 ppts for middle-income countries
(relative to the efficiency of high-income countries). For countries with poor quality public capital and a
large public investment share of GDP—such as many low-income countries—an increase in the quality of
public investment can be just as effective as a modest increase in quantity of public investment. For example,
for the typical low-income country, a 1ppt increase in efficiency boosts growth by the same amount as
a 0.13ppt of GDP increase in public investment. Despite this, the level of efficiency has no effect on the
marginal product of public capital because the low quality of new public investment is exactly offset by a
greater need for public capital due to the poor quality of past public investment (as in Berg et al. 2015).
In closing, it is worth mentioning a few caveats to our model and stylized facts. In order to keep the
LTGM-PC as simple as possible, we abstract from the effects of the financing of public investment via
distortionary taxation. In many cases this will act as a drag on growth, and so our growth impact should be
seen as an upper bound in that context (unless public investment can be financed by reducing unproductive
expenditure elsewhere). We also abstract from endogenous private investment and return-seeking interna-
tional capital flows. These factors might lead to a larger crowd-in of private investment, but they could also
amplify any negative impacts of distortionary taxation. Finally, our stylized facts depend on available data,
and the quality of that data. While we have data on many high- and middle-income countries, the sample
size for low-income countries is small, which might increase the volatility of our estimates.
Appendices and the LTGM-PC spreadsheet-based toolkit are available online at https://www.worldbank
.org/LTGM.
58
The Long Term Growth Model
References
Afonso, A., L. Schuknecht, and V. Tanzi. 2005. Public Sector Efficiency: An International Comparison. Public Choice
123(3-4): 321–347.
Afonso, A., L. Schuknecht, and V. Tanzi. 2010. Public Sector Efficiency: Evidence for New EU Member States and
Emerging Markets. Applied Economics. 42(17): 2147–2164.
Agénor, P. 2013. Public Capital, Growth and Welfare, Princeton University Press.
Albino-War, M. et al. 2014. Making the Most of Public Investment in MENA and CCA Oil Exporting Countries. Staff
Discussion Note 14/10. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Arslanalp, S., F. Bonhorst, S. Gupta, and E. Sze. 2010. Public Capital and Growth. IMF Working Paper 10/175.
Aschauer, D.A. 1989. Is Public Expenditure Productive? Journal of Monetary Economics 23: 177–200.
Barro, R., and X. Sala-i-Martin. 1992. Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth. The Review of Economic Studies
Vol. 59 (4): 645–661.
Barrot, Luis-Diego. 2016. Long-Term Growth Model (LTGM): Reference Note on Data Issues. World Bank Internal Note.
Baxter, M., and R. G King. 1993. Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium. American Economic Review 83: 315–334.
Berg, A., E. F. Buffie, C. Pattillo, R. Portillo, A. F. Presbitero, and L. F. Zanna. 2015. Some Misconceptions about Public
Investment Efficiency and Growth. IMF Working Paper No. 15/272.
Bom, P. R., and J. E. Ligthart. 2014. What Have We Learned from Three Decades of Research on the Productivity of
Public Capital? Journal of Economic Surveys. 28(5). 889-916.
Buffie, E. F., A. Berg, C. A. Pattillo, R. Portillo, and L. F. Zanna. 2012. Public Investment, Growth, and Debt Sustainability:
Putting Together the Pieces. IMF Working Paper No. 12/144.
Calderon, C., E. Moral-Benito, and L. Serven. 2015. Is Infrastructure Capital Productive? A Dynamic Heterogeneous
Approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics 30: 177–198.
Calderon, C., and L. Serven. 2004. The Effects of Infrastructure Development on Growth and Income Distribution.
World Bank PRWP 3400.
Calderon, C., and L. Serven. 2010. Infrastructure in Latin America. World Bank PRWP 5317.
Calderon, C., and L. Serven. 2014. Infrastructure, Growth and Inequality. World Bank PRWP 7034.
Collier P., M. Kichberger, and M. Soderbom. 2015.The Cost of Road Infrastructure in Low- and Middle- Income
Countries, World Bank Economic Review, 30(3): 522–548.
Dabla-Norris, E., J. Brumby, A. Kyobe, Z. Mills, and C. Papageorgiou. 2012. Investing in public investment: an index
of public investment efficiency. Journal of Economic Growth 17(3): 235–266.
Devarajan, S., V. Swaroop, and H. Zou. 1996. The Composition of Public Expenditure and Economic Growth. Journal
of Monetary Economics 37: 313–344.
Eden, M., and A. Kraay. 2014. Crowding-In and the Returns to Government Investment in Low-Income Countries.
World Bank PRWP 6781.
Eicher, T. and S. J. Turnovsky. 2000. Scale, Congestion and Growth. Economica 67: 325–346.
Fay, M., and Yepes, T. 2003. Investing in Infrastructure: What is Needed from 2000 to 2010? World Bank PRWP 3102.
Glomm, G., and B. Ravikumar. 1997. Productive government expenditures and long-run growth. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 21: 183–204.
Gupta, S., A. Kangur, C. Papageorgiou, and A. Wane. 2014. Efficiency-adjusted public capital and growth. World
Development 57:164–178.
Hevia, C., and N. Loayza. 2012. Savings and Growth in Egypt. Middle East Development Journal. 4(1).
Ingram, G. K., and M. Fay. 1994. Valuing Infrastructure Stocks and Gains from Improved Performance. Washington:
World Bank.
(IMF) International Monetary Fund. 2015. Making Public Investment More Efficient. Staff Report. Washington.
Jimenez, R. A., T. Serebrisky, and J. Mercado. 2014. Power Lost: Sizing Electricity Losses in Transmission and
Distribution Systems in Latin America and the Caribbean. Inter-American Development Bank.
Leeper, E., T. Walker, and S Yang. 2010. Government investment and fiscal stimulus, The Journal of Monetary Economics
57: 1000–1012.
59
2. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Kalaitzidakis, P., and S. Kalyvitis. 2004. On the macroeconomic implications of maintenance in public capital. Journal
of Public Economics Vol. 88(3-4): 695–712. March.
Keefer, P., and S. Knack. 2007. Boondoggles, Rent-seeking and Political Checks and Balances: Public Investment
Under Unaccountable Governments. The Review of Economics and Statistics 89(3): 566–572.
Nunez-Serrano, J. A., and F. J. Velazquez. 2016. Is Public Capital Productive? Evidence from a Meta-analysis. Applied
Economic Perspectives and Policy 39 (2): 313–345.
Olken, B. 2007. Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy
115(2).
Pritchett, L. 1996. Mind your P’s and Q’s: the cost of public investment is not the value of public capital. PRWP 1660.
World Bank. Washington, D.C.
Pritchett, L. 2000. The Tyranny of Concepts: CUDIE (Cumulated, Depreciated, Investment Effort) Is Not Capital.
Journal of Economic Growth 5. pp. 361–84.
Rioja, F. K. 2003. The penalties of inefficient infrastructure. Review of Development Economics 7(1), 127–137.
Romp, W., and J. De Haan. 2007. Public Capital and Economic Growth: A Critical Survey. Perspektiven der
Wirtschaftspolitik. Vol. 8. No. S1. pp. 6–52.
Serven, L. 2010. Infrastructure and Growth. Research Brief. Washington: World Bank.
Sinha, Rishabh. 2017. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh. World Bank PRWP 7952.
Straub, S. 2008. Infrastructure and Growth in Developing Countries. World Bank PRWP 4460.
System of National Accounts (SNA). 1993. United Nations Statistics Division.
World Bank. 1994. The World Development Report: Infrastructure for Development. Washington, DC.
60
Chapter 3
Abstract
This chapter provides a productivity extension of the identified. The variance decomposition results show
World Bank’s Long Term Growth Model (LTGM). that the highest contributor among the determinants
Based on an extensive literature review, the chapter to the variance in TFP growth is market efficiency for
identifies the main determinants of economic pro- the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
ductivity as innovation, education, market efficiency, Development (OECD) countries and education for
infrastructure, and institutions. Based on underlying developing countries in the most recent decade. The
proxies, the chapter constructs indexes representing regression results indicate that, controlling for coun-
each of the main categories of productivity deter- try- and time-specific effects, TFP growth has a pos-
minants and, combining them through principal itive and significant relationship with the proposed
component analysis, obtains an overall determinant TFP determinant index and a negative relationship
index. This is done for every year in the three decades with initial TFP. This relationship is then used to pro-
spanning 1985–2015 and for more than 100 coun- vide a set of simulations on the potential path of TFP
tries. In parallel, the chapter presents a measure of growth if certain improvements on TFP determinants
total factor productivity (TFP), largely obtained from are achieved. The chapter presents and discusses
the Penn World Table, and assesses the pattern of pro- some of these simulations for groups of countries by
ductivity growth across regions and income groups geographic region and income level. In addition, as
over the same sample. The chapter then examines a country-specific illustration, the chapter presents
the relationship between the measures of TFP and its simulations on the potential path of TFP growth
determinants. The variance of productivity growth is for Peru under various scenarios. An accompanying
decomposed into the share explained by each of its Excel-based toolkit, linked to the LTGM, provides a
main determinants, and the relationship between pro- larger set of simulations and scenario analysis at the
ductivity growth and the overall determinant index is country level for the next few decades.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of Kim, Y. E., and Loayza, N. V. (2019). “Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants
E
across the World.” Economia, 42(84), 36–93. An earlier version was published as World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS
8604. Appendix A is included at the end of this chapter, but appendixes B–E are available in the journal version, which is accessible at
the journal’s website: https://doi.org/10.18800/economia.201902.003. The spreadsheet-based LTGM-TFP tool is available at the Long
Term Growth Model website: https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
2
Young Eun Kim and Norman V. Loayza, World Bank. Corresponding author email: nloayza@worldbank.org. The views expressed
herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries
they represent. For helpful comments, we would like to thank Wen Chen, Steven Michael Pennings, Jorge Luis Guzman Correa, Zixi
Liu, Ha Nguyen, Luis Servén, Rongsheng Tang, Yong Wang, and participants in seminars at the World Bank, the Federation of ASEAN
Economic Associations, the Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, and Peking University.
61
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
“It is not by augmenting the capital of the country, but by rendering a greater part of that capital active
and productive than would otherwise be so, that the most judicious operations of banking can increase
the industry of the country.” Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
(page 131).
1. Introduction
With the same amount of inputs—including labor, human and physical capital, and materials—some
countries, sectors, and firms produce more and others less. This difference depends on how productive
they are in allocating and using resources in the production process. One of the most important lessons in
economics is that productivity improvement is key to sustained economic growth. (See, among others, Hall
and Jones 1999, Easterly and Levine 2001, and Caselli 2005.)
Productivity was a main concern of the fathers of modern economics, Adam Smith and David Ricardo, in
the eighteenth century, as they considered the advantages of specialization and trade as the basis for the
wealth of nations. In the first one-half of the twentieth century, as advanced economies started to recover
from the Great Depression, Hicks (1939) and Schumpeter (1942) emphasized the importance of pro-
ductivity improvements, linking them to enterprise renewal and “creative destruction.” When economists
turned their attention to developing countries, they described productivity growth as crucial in the search
for sustained growth and development. For Lewis (1954), Kuznets (1957), and Chenery (1960), economic
development required a structural transformation that shifted resources from less to more productive
sectors of the economy. More recently, since the productivity slowdown in developed countries in the
1970s, the lackluster growth of developing countries in the 1980s, and the collapse of the communist
regimes in Eastern Europe and East Asia in the early 1990s, interest in understanding the sources of growth
and productivity has grown exponentially (see Woo, Parker, and Sachs 1997; Ben-David and Papell 1998;
Easterly 2001; Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh 2008).
Placing the study of productivity in the context of economic growth research may bring about important
insights. In the 1950s, Solow and Swan developed a growth model in which changes in physical capital,
labor, and total factor productivity (TFP) determine the economy’s growth rate (Solow 1956; Swan
1956). It has proven to be a workhorse of growth theory and applications for over 50 years. A drawback
of this model, however, is that the path of TFP is assumed to be exogenous. At least since the mid-1980s,
theoretical economists have addressed this shortcoming. For example, Romer (1987, 1990), Grossman
and Helpman (1991), and Aghion, Philippe, and Howitt (1992) incorporated technological advances
through research and development (R&D) as a driver of long-run growth. Lucas (1988) argued that the
accumulation of human capital through education creates a positive externality that drives productivity,
which in turn explains long-run growth. Rebelo (1991) included both human and physical capital in a
composite measure that faces no decreasing returns, suggesting that continuous investment can lead to
long-term growth. Barro (1990) and Barro and Sala-I-Martin (1992) incorporated tax-financed public
goods and assumed that they complement private capital, so that concurrent investment in both public
and private capital could lead to growth in the long run. Engerman and Sokoloff (2000) and Acemoglu,
Johnson, and Robinson (2001, 2004) deepen the notion of public goods to argue that the role of political
and economic institutions is fundamental to economic growth. It can be said that in all these cases, the
proposed mechanisms driving productivity are ways of explaining economic growth in the long run
without resorting to exogenous changes.
The interest in understanding the microeconomic foundations of aggregate behavior has also led to import-
ant insights on productivity. Hopenhayn (1992), Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993), Caballero and Hammour
(1996), and Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996) pioneered research on the role of firm dynamics driving
62
The Long Term Growth Model
productivity and, consequently, economic growth. The conclusion from this extensive body of research is
that resource reallocation (including firm entry and exit, innovation and renewal, and structural transfor-
mation) explains a substantial share of productivity improvement in the economy. Resource reallocation
requires, however, a costly adjustment: the adoption of new technologies, the assimilation of production
inputs by expanding firms, and the shedding of labor and capital by declining firms. Differences in the
ease of resource reallocation can then explain why some countries are more productive than others. These
differences can be related to the level of development of the country (e.g., a lack of human capital and
functioning justice system; see Caballero and Hammour 1998 and Acemoglu and Zilibotti 2001) and to
the quality of government’s regulations and interventions (e.g., excessive labor regulations, subsidies to
inefficient sectors, and barriers of firm entry and exit; see Parente and Prescott 2000). Although more
refined in the mechanisms, the microfoundations literature points to the same conclusions as the aggregate
literature highlighted above, regarding the roles of innovation, education, regulatory environment, and
public goods and institutions in driving productivity.
The surge in theoretical research on economic growth and productivity has been paralleled by an enormous
empirical literature. A selected review is offered in the second section of the chapter. In brief, this empirical
research attempted to, first, test the validity of recent growth theories in contrast to (or in conjunction
with) the neoclassical growth theory, and, second, determine the quantitative importance of various pro-
posed drivers of growth. The first wave of empirical studies on new growth research focused on aggregate,
cross-country data. In academic circles, this line of work is best exemplified by Barro’s (1991) seminal study.
In the World Bank and other policy-oriented organizations, empirical studies such as Easterly and Levine
(1997, 2001), Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calderón (2005), and Loayza and Servén (2010) offered a guide for
understanding economic growth and its determinants, including policies and institutions. As micro-level
data became more widely available in the 1990s, a second wave of empirical research used data at the
industry and firm levels to study firm renewal, resource redistribution, and structural transformation. This
led to insights and findings that could not have been obtained using country-level data, as shown in Foster,
Haltiwanger, and Krizan (2001), Restuccia and Rogerson (2008), and Hsieh and Klenow (2009).
Considering numerous studies on economic growth and productivity published in the past few decades,
in this chapter we take stock of the main conceptual conclusions surrounding productivity growth and
synthesize the quantitative implications through original data collection and analysis. Apart from its inde-
pendent contribution, this chapter serves as background for an extension of the World Bank Long Term
Growth Model (LTGM, Chapter 1 of this volume). This extension quantifies how changes in TFP growth
are driven by changes in its underlying determinants, and, in turn, how changes in TFP growth lead to
different paths for economic growth.
The drivers of productivity growth can be grouped into five components (Kim, Loayza, and Meza-Cuadra
2016): innovation, to create and adopt new technologies; education, to spread these new technologies
throughout the economy and to develop the capacity of the workforce to assimilate them; market
efficiency, to promote the effective and flexible allocation of resources across sectors and firms; infrastructure
(in transport, telecommunication, energy, and water and sanitation), to support and facilitate the economic
activity of households, businesses, and markets; and institutions (in the regulatory, justice, policy, and
political systems), to provide social and economic stability, defend property rights, and safeguard basic civil
rights. These five components are interrelated and can clearly influence one another.
In this chapter we identify the main determinants of productivity growth, propose proxies to measure them,
assess the pattern of TFP growth across regions and over time, and quantify the relationship between the
TFP determinants proxies and TFP growth. For this purpose, we first conduct an extensive literature review
on productivity that considers not only concepts and theories but also empirical studies. Then, we estimate
TFP and construct indexes representing each of the five main determinants of TFP for a large group of
countries in the past three decades (from 1985 to 2014). Finally, we measure the relative contribution of
63
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
each of the main determinants to the variance of TFP growth, and we estimate their overall effect on TFP
growth. As mentioned above, these results are used to build a TFP module for the extended Long Term
Growth Model (LGTM).
In the rest of the chapter, section 2 presents a review of the literature; this is important because it not only
frames the context of the chapter but also helps to identify and categorize the drivers of TFP growth. Section
3 describes the methodology, including the selection of countries and variables, the estimation of TFP,
the construction of indexes to measure each TFP determinant category, and the variance decomposition
and regression analysis. Section 4 presents and discusses the main results, from descriptive statistics to
regression analysis. Section 5 uses the main results to generate simulations on the path of TFP growth if
certain reforms are accomplished. Section 6 concludes.
2.1 Innovation
Innovation, as the generation and adoption of new technologies, leads to the development of higher val-
ue-added activities, products, and processes and improves the performance of existing ones. Historically, a
small number of countries have created new technologies based on investment in research and development
(R&D) by the public and private sectors and an advanced level of human capacity and physical capital
(Furman and Hayes 2004; Griffith, Redding, and Reenen 2004). Other countries have then adapted and
adopted technological changes, with varying time lags and degrees of intensity (Comin, Hobijn, and Rovito
2008).
Using indicators such as investment in R&D, the number of patents, and the number of scientific and
technological journal publications, many studies show that the creation or adoption of a new technology is
positively associated with TFP growth (see, for example, Nadiri 1993; Chen and Dahlman 2004; Guellec and
van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie 2004). For instance, Jorgenson, Ho, and Stiroh (2008) and Oliner, Sichel,
and Stiroh (2008) show that Information and Communication Technologies (ICT) played a central role in
accelerating productivity in the United States (U.S.) from the mid-1990s to the 2000s after the lackluster
pace of productivity growth in the 1970s and 1980s. The comparison of Europe and the U.S. highlights the
critical role of new technologies in expanding productivity. Ark, O’Mahony, and Timmer (2008) show that
the productivity slowdown in Europe during the 1990s and 2000s is attributable to the lower contribution
of ICT to growth, the smaller share of technology-producing industries, and slower advances in technol-
ogy and innovation as compared to the U.S. Not only the development of new technologies but also the
adoption of existing ones play a substantial role in enhancing productivity and income growth. Comin and
Hobijn (2010) and Comin and Mestieri (2018), using data on the diffusion of more than 15 technologies
across a large number of countries over the last two centuries, show that varying patterns of the adoption
64
The Long Term Growth Model
and diffusion of technologies since 1820 account for at least 25 percent of the income divergence across
countries and 75 percent of the income difference between rich and poor countries.
2.2 Education
Education, as the knowledge and skills of the population, is essential to generate new technologies, as well as to
disseminate, adapt, and implement them throughout the economy. Education allows workers not only to produce
more and better, but also to expand and disseminate the technological frontier. For education to contribute to
productivity, it must consist of strong basic foundations and sufficient specialization, rich in both quantity and
quality, and spread throughout the population (Barro 2001; Hanushek and Woessmann 2015).
Studies suggest that indicators such as the number of schooling years and the completion rate of secondary
and tertiary education of the population are associated with output growth through both TFP improve-
ments and the direct contribution of human capital (Benhabib and Spiegel 1994; Griffith, Redding, and
Reenen 2004; Bronzini and Piselli 2009; Erosa, Koreshkova, and Restuccia 2010). Having a sufficiently high
level of education increases productivity growth in developing countries by enabling them to adopt new
technologies from frontier countries. Benhabib and Spiegel (2005), for example, show that a country’s aver-
age years of schooling (as a proxy for education) has a positive impact on TFP growth through technology
catch-up. Miller and Upadhyay (2000) show that education (also using the years of schooling as a proxy)
can affect how developing countries adopt new technologies through trade, with a positive impact on TFP.
Barro (2001) shows in a study of around 100 countries that the quantity and quality of education, using
the years of schooling and student test scores as respective proxies, are significantly related to economic
growth. Wei and Hao (2011) show that education quality, using government expenditure on education and
teacher-student ratios as proxies, is significantly associated with TFP growth in China.
65
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Regarding financial systems, Rajan and Zingales (1998) show that financial development facilitates economic
growth by reducing the costs of external finance to firms for a large number of countries in the 1980s. Beck,
Levine, and Loayza (2000) argue that financial development affects economic growth mainly through its posi-
tive effect on TFP. Buera, Kaboski, and Shin (2011) show that financial frictions distort the allocation of capital
and entrepreneurial talent across production units, adversely affecting TFP and sectoral relative productivity.
With respect to labor markets, studies show that regulations that provide flexibility in the allocation of labor
enhance productivity. Haltiwanger, Scarpetta, and Schweiger (2008) and Bartelsman, Gautier, and De Wind
(2016) show that employment protection regulations preclude efficient labor reallocation because they curb
job flows or discourage firms from adopting risky but highly productive technologies. Barro (2001) shows
that the education of female students has an insignificant impact on economic growth unlike that of male
students, suggesting that labor market reforms to incorporate female workers has a potential to increase TFP.
2.4 Infrastructure
Public infrastructure—in transport, telecommunication, energy, and water and sanitation—can provide
timely and cost-effective access to input and output markets, workplaces, and knowledge and information
sources, thus supporting all possible economic activities (Straub 2008; Galiani, Gertler, and Schargrodsky
2005). An appropriate infrastructure network—in terms of quantity, quality, and diversity—can complement
private capital and labor, increasing their returns and impact on economic growth. In this way, expanding
public infrastructure becomes a source of TFP growth.
The evidence that appropriate public infrastructure has a positive impact on productivity and economic
growth is convincing. Hulten (1996) shows that 25 percent of the growth difference between East Asia and
Africa over 1970−1990 is explained by the efficient use of infrastructure. Aschauer (1989) argues that public
capital stock, especially core infrastructure such as highways, airports, sewers, and water systems, was critical
in determining productivity in the U.S. over 1950–1989. Straub (2008) shows in a study of 140 countries
over 1989–2007 that the infrastructure stock has a positive external impact on growth, for example, by
allowing firms to invest in more productive machineries, decreasing workers’ commuting times, and pro-
moting health and education. Considering also a panel of countries over time, Calderón and Servén (2010,
2012, 2014) argue persuasively that infrastructure can have positive effects on both growth and distributive
equity. These beneficial effects, however, require a framework that regulates, organizes, and coordinates
the governments and companies that build public infrastructure and provide its services. Moreover, as
highlighted by Pritchett (1996) and Devadas and Pennings (2018), the amount of infrastructure spending
is not necessarily an indication of effective infrastructure investment. The quality of spending matters, and
this seems to be highly related to the strength of public institutions (World Bank 2003, 2017r).
2.5 Institutions
Public institutions—in the regulatory, justice, policy, and political systems—can promote social and eco-
nomic stability, provide a safe living and working environment, defend property rights, and safeguard
basic civil rights. The environment and policies that public institutions provide have a large, fundamental
impact on economic development (North 1990; Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2004). The evidence
that good governance (reflected in political stability, the rule of law, the protection of property rights,
bureaucratic quality, transparency and accountability, and the absence of corruption) has a positive effect
on productivity and economic growth is large, comprehensive, and convincing.
Barro (1991) shows in a study of around 100 countries for 1960–1985 that economic growth is positively
related to political stability and inversely to government-induced market distortions. Using ethnolinguis-
tic fractionalization as an instrumental variable for measures of government corruption, Mauro (1995)
finds that corruption has a statistically significant and economically large negative effect on economic
growth. Knack and Keefer (1995) find that property rights, proxied by contract enforceability and risk of
66
The Long Term Growth Model
expropriation, has a substantial impact on economic growth, even after accounting for capital accumulation.
Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi (2004) show that the quality of institutions, measured by a composite
indicator of the protection of property rights and the rule of law, has a positive impact on income levels
across a large sample of countries. Chanda and Dalgaard (2008) find that the quality of institutions (proxied
by a composite index of the rule of law, bureaucratic quality, corruption, the risk of expropriation, and the
government repudiation of contracts) is positively related to productivity. Easterly and Levine (2003) show
that institutions are channels for geographical endowments to have an impact on economic development.
They also show that when institutional quality is controlled for, macroeconomic policies do not account
for development, implying good governance leads to conducive macroeconomic environments.
The five categories of TFP determinants presented above span a comprehensive array of factors driving pro-
ductivity. They are also the channels through which other potential variables affect TFP. Some of them are
time-invariant, such as historical origins and geographic conditions. Their effect is captured by our proposed
determinants. For example, Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi (2004) show that geography has an impact on
incomes by influencing the quality of institutions. Other potential variables account for slow-moving processes,
such as social mobility and income inequality. Their effect on TFP growth, however, can be explained by education,
market efficiency, and governance. Consider, as an illustration, the following papers. Cingano (2014) shows that
income inequality has a negative impact on economic growth by impeding skill development among individuals
with poorer parental education background. Dabla-Norris et al. (2015) show that low-income households and
small firms face difficulties in accessing financial services, which decreases economic growth. Hoeller, Joumard,
and Koske (2014) argue that the lack of policies that provide more inclusive access to education, financial services,
and labor markets leads to income inequality, and eventually lower economic growth.
3. Methods
First, we present the sample of countries and years included in the analysis. Second, we report how TFP
growth at the country level is estimated. Third, we construct a set of indexes representing each of the main
productivity determinants; we then obtain an overall index by grouping the indexes together. Fourth, we
analyze the relationship between TFP growth and the proposed indexes of TFP determinants.
3.1 Sample
We conduct the statistical analysis using a sample of 98 developing and developed countries for the
period 1985–2014. They are selected from the larger sample of countries featured in the Penn World
Table (PWT) 9.0 and the World Bank World Development Indicators (WDI) databases. We exclude
countries that do not have a minimal set of historical data for statistical analysis, countries that depend
heavily on oil production (because the contribution of oil to output could result in a large overestimation
of TFP growth),3 and small countries, defined as those with a population of less than 2 million (in 2016)
(World Bank 2017m).
For the descriptive analysis of TFP growth across regions and decades (in section 4.1), we add 16 countries
for which data on the share of labor in income is missing in PWT 9.0 but available from the Global Trade
Analysis Project (GTAP) 9.0 (Aguiar, Narayanan, and McDougall 2016). For the descriptive analysis of TFP
determinants (in section 4.2), we additionally include 22 countries, which, though not having information
3
eavy dependence is defined as reliance on oil production for more than 32 percent of GDP on average during 2006–2015,
H
which is 90th –100th percentile among 98 countries with positive oil rents (World Bank 2017j); Angola (45%), Congo, Rep.
(46%), Equatorial Guinea (42%), Gabon (32%), Iraq (52%), Kuwait (47%), Libya (54%), Oman (37%), Saudi Arabia (44%),
and South Sudan (45%).
67
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
to obtain TFP estimates, do have data for the proposed determinant indicators. For growth projections in
the Long Term Growth Model (LTGM), we add back small countries, heavily oil dependent countries, and
those for which we can complete missing data from other sources and additional assumptions; thus, the
TFP extension of the LTGM can be applied to about 190 countries for growth projections.
We classify high-income countries that have been members of OECD for more than 40 years as the OECD group.
The rest of the countries are classified by region and income. We use the average of GDP per capita (World Bank
2017e) over 1985–2014 to break the sample into income quintiles. Appendix Table B.1 shows the country list by
region and income quintile groups, indicating their inclusion in the samples by type of analysis (descriptive and
statistical), data source (PWT, GTAP, and WDI), and other characteristics (oil rent and population).
RTFPjtNA RGDPjtNA
= /Q jt , t −1 ,
RTFPjtNA
−1 RGDPjtNA
−1
RTFPNA: TFP level, computed with RGDPNA, RKNA, EMP, HC, and LABSH
RGDPNA: Real GDP at constant national prices
RKNA: Capital stock at constant national prices
EMP: The number of people employed
HC: Human capital based on the average years of schooling from Barro and Lee (2013) and an assumed rate
for primary, secondary, and tertiary education from Caselli (2005)
LABSH: The share of labor income of employees and self − employed workers in GDP
j: country, and t: year
For our analysis, we calculate annual TFP growth rates by differencing the log-transformed TFP levels of
year t and t−1, ln(rtfpnat) − ln(rtfpnat−1).
As a robustness check, we calculate TFP mainly using data from the World Development Indicators database
(instead of PWT). In appendix E, we compare the results (on descriptive statistics and econometric analysis)
using this alternative TFP measure.
68
The Long Term Growth Model
Sub-
component Overall
index index
Common variance
Distinct variance
4
We select a factor, or a principal component in the case of PCA, with an eigenvalue higher than 1. In our analysis, there is only
one factor for each subcomponent index and one principal component for the overall index with an eigenvalue higher than 1.
5
I n order for the variables to enter factor/principal component analysis, they must have a sufficiently high degree of
commonality. We run the Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin test to examine whether the indicators have enough common variance. A test
value below the critical value of 0.5 means that an indicator or a group of indicators are unacceptable. For factor analysis, the
test results show that the selection of indicators as a group is acceptable with a value of 0.60 for innovation, 0.69 for education,
0.63 for market efficiency, 0.83 for infrastructure, and 0.92 for institutions. The test results for individual indicators in each
category are also above the critical value. For principal component analysis, used to construct the overall index, the test result is
0.88 for the group of the subcomponent indexes, and also above the critical value for each subcomponent index.
69
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
indicator of public investment in foundational human capital (World Bank 2017f); the shares of popula-
tion aged 25 and over with completed secondary education and with completed tertiary education (Barro
and Lee 2013) as indicators of educational attainment among workers; and a standardized international
test score— a single average of scores in math, science, and reading on the Programme for International
Student Assessment (PISA)— as an indicator of educational quality (OECD 2016a, 2016b, 2016c).
Market efficiency. To construct a subcomponent index for market efficiency (Effi), we classify markets into
output, financial, and labor markets. We select the World Bank Doing Business scores as an indicator of
output market efficiency, which measure the regulatory environment in terms of ease for firms to start a
business, trade across borders, register property, get credit, and the like (World Bank 2017a). We choose
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) Financial Development Index as an indicator of financial market
efficiency, which measures the level of financial development by including the size and liquidity of financial
markets, ease for individuals and firms to access financial services, and the ability of financial institutions
to provide services at low costs with sustainable revenues (Svirydzenka 2016). As indicators of labor market
efficiency, we construct an composite index, using factor analysis, consisting of minimum wage (% of value
added per worker), severance pay for redundancy dismissals (weeks of salary), and the share of women in
wage employment in the nonagricultural sector from World Bank databases (World Bank 2017h, 2017q).
Infrastructure. For a subcomponent index for infrastructure (Infra), we select fixed-telephone and mobile
subscriptions (per 100 people) (World Bank 2017c, 2017i); the length of paved roads (km per 100 people)
(International Road Federation 2017a, 2017b); electricity production (kw per 100 people) (OECD/IEA
2017); and access to an improved water source and improved sanitation facilities (% of population) (WHO/
UNICEF 2017b, 2017a).
Institutions. To construct a subcomponent index for institutions (Inst), we select the World Bank
Worldwide Governance Indicators. These include measures of voice and accountability (citizens’ par-
ticipation in selecting their government and freedom of expression); control of corruption (the extent
to which public power is exercised for personal gain); government effectiveness (the quality of public
services and policy formulation and implementation); political stability (the absence of politically moti-
vated conflict); regulatory quality (the ability of government to formulate and implement regulations that
promote private sector development); and the rule of law (the extent to which citizens have confidence
in and abide by laws) (Kaufmann and Kraay 2017).
When necessary, we impute missing values of the selected indicators to balance sample sizes across countries
and maximize the number of countries in the sample. We use different methods depending on the number
of available data and the characteristics of the indicators. For a country that has data for more than 10 out
of 30 years (1985−2014) for an indicator, we project a linear trend over years to impute missing values. For
a country that has data for less than 10 years, we replace missing values with a median value corresponding
to the country’s income and regional group. We apply a different method for PISA scores because available
data are less than for 10 years for all countries. Considering a statistically significant correlation of 0.66
(p-value<0.01) between PISA scores and log-transformed GDP per capita lagged by five years, we regress
PISA scores on the lagged log–transformed GDP per capita, controlling for time-effects in a cross-country,
time-series pooled data set.6 Then, we replace missing PISA scores with a median score by the country’s
income and regional group using scores predicted by the regression model. For minimum wage and sev-
erance pay, we apply the oldest available data (2014) to the period before 2014, because available data
(2014−2017) are insufficient to evaluate a time trend, and their values are difficult to impute based on the
country’s income and regional group.
6
PISAc,t = β0 + β1 ln (GDP per capita)c,t−5 + δt, c:country (1,…,76), t: year (2003/06/09/12/15); β0 = 187.1*, β1 = 28.7 *** (***:
p-value<0.01), R2=0.444.
70
The Long Term Growth Model
3.4 Relationship between the main determinants of TFP and TFP growth
The relative contribution of the main determinants to the variance of total factor
productivity growth
To help assess the relative contribution of the five main determinants to TFP growth, we decompose the
variance of the TFP growth rate (over t-5 to t) to that explained by each subcomponent index (at t-5),
controlling for an initial TFP level (at t-5) and time-effects for 98 countries. A review of measures of
relative importance based on variance decomposition by Grömping (2007) suggests that the “dominance
analysis” approach (Budescu 1993; Azen and Budescu 2003) is a reasonable method, mainly to deal with
the presence of covariance across individual determinants. This approach calculates the contribution of
a subcomponent index as the increase in the explained variance when the subcomponent index is added
to each subset of other subcomponent indexes. For instance, the contribution of the innovation index
(innovc,t) is computed by averaging7 the increase in the explained variance of TFP growth rate when
innovc,t is added to each of the 16 additive subsets of other four subcomponent indexes ({.}, {educc,t}, …,
{instc,t}, { educc,t, effic,t}, … {infrac,t, instc,t}, {educc,t, effic,t, infrac,t}, …, {educc,t, infrac,t, instc,t}, {educc,t, effic,t,
infrac,t, instc,t}.)
7
Two-step average: First, the additional contributions are averaged within a group of the same size of the subset, then the results
from the first step are averaged across groups with different sizes of the subset.
71
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
4. Results
4.1 Total factor productivity
Figure 3.2 shows that for 21 OECD countries, the median and (simple) average annual TFP growth rates are
positive during 1985–2004 and decrease below zero for 2005–2014; whereas for 93 developing countries, they
are negative during 1985–94 and increase above zero for 1995–2014. Figure 3.3 shows median and (simple)
average annual TFP growth rates for developing countries by region. For East Asia and Pacific, TFP growth
rates are positive for the last three decades between 0.4 percent and 1.3 percent. For Europe and Central
Asia, TFP growth rates are negative for 1985–1994, increase in the next decade to above 2.0 percent, and
decrease to around 1.2 percent for the last decade. For Latin America and the Caribbean, TFP growth rates
increase from around –0.4 percent during 1985–2004 to around 0.5 percent for 2005–2014. For Middle East
and North Africa, TFP growth rates increase from near zero or negative in 1985–94 to around 0.5 percent
in the next decade and decrease to below –0.5 percent in the last decade. For South Asia, TFP growth rates
are positive for the last three decades, ranging between 0.3 percent and 1.5 percent. For Sub-Saharan Africa,
TFP growth rates increase from around –1 in 1985–1994 to +1 in the two decades spanning 1994–2014.
Figure 3.4 shows regional average TFP growth rates weighted by total GDP (World Bank 2017d), the trend
of which is similar to that of the unweighted average TFP growth rates in figure 3.3.
Figure 3.2: Annual TFP Growth Rate for All, OECD, and Developing Countries, Median and
Simple Average by Decade
1.0
0.8
Annual TFP growth rate (%)
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
–0.2
–0.4
–0.6
–0.8
–1.0
85–94 94–04 04–14 85–94 94–04 04–14 85–94 94–04 04–14
All OECD Developing
Median Average
Source: Authors’ calculation, using PWT 9.0 data complemented, in a few cases, with GTAP data.
Note: The OECD group includes high-income countries that have been members of OECD for more than 40 years;
the former Soviet Union countries are excluded in the period 1985–1994 considering their independence in the early 1990s.
72
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 3.3: Annual TFP Growth Rate for Developing Countries, Median and Simple Average by
Region and Decade
3
Annual TFP growth rate (%)
–1
–2
94
94
94 4
4
4
–0
–1
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–
–
04
04
04
04
04
04
85
85
85
85
85
85
94
94
94
94
94
East Asia Europe and Latin Middle East South Asia Sub-Saharan
and Pacific Central Asia America and and Africa
the Caribbean North Africa
Median Average
Source: Authors’ calculation, using PWT 9.0 data complemented, in a few cases, with GTAP data.
Note: The former Soviet Union countries are excluded in the period 1985-94 considering their independence in the early 1990s.
Figure 3.4: Annual TFP Growth Rate for Developing Countries, Average Weighted by Real GDP
by Region and Decade
3
average weighted by GDP
Annual TFP growth rate,
–1
–2
4
4
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
04
04
04
04
04
04
85
85
85
85
85
85
94
94
94
94
94
94
East Asia Europe and Latin Middle East South Asia Sub-Saharan
and Pacific Central Asia America and and Africa
the Caribbean North Africa
Source: Authors’ calculation, using PWT 9.0 data complemented, in a few cases, with GTAP data.
Note: The former Soviet Union countries are excluded in the period 1985-94 considering their independence in the early 1990s.
For the innovation subcomponent index, the indicators carry similar weights (equation 3). A factor anal-
ysis shows that the subcomponent index accounts for 76 percent of the total variance of the indicators,
accounting for 90 percent of the variance of R&D expenditure (R&D), 61 percent of that of the number of
patents (patent), and 79 percent of that of the number of journal articles (article).
Innovc,t = 0.41 * z (R&Dc,t) + 0.34 * z (patentc,t) + 0.39 * z (articlec,t), (3)
73
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Figure 3.5: Median of Subcomponent and Overall Determinant Indexes for All, OECD, and
Developing Countries by Decade
a. World
100
80
60
40
20
0
4
94
94
94
4
94
94
94
4
–0
–0
–1
–0
–0
–1
–0
–1
–0
–1
–1
–1
–
–
–
–
05
05
05
05
05
05
85
85
85
85
85
85
95
95
95
95
95
95
b. OECD
100
80
60
40
20
0
4
4
4
4
4
4
4
–0
–0
–9
–9
–0
–9
–1
–0
–1
–9
–0
–1
–1
–1
–1
–9
–0
–9
05
05
05
05
05
05
85
85
85
85
85
95
95
95
95
95
85
95
c. Developing
100
80
60
40
20
0
4
4
4
14
4
4
4
–0
–1
–1
–1
–9
–0
–9
–0
–9
–9
–0
–9
–0
–1
–1
–9
–0
–
05
05
05
05
05
05
95
85
85
85
85
85
85
95
95
95
95
95
X − mean ( X )
where z ( X ) is standardized X , .
standard deviation ( X )
For the education subcomponent index, the performance-related indicators have similar weights and the
education-expenditure indicator has a lower weight (equation 4). A factor analysis indicates that the sub-
component index accounts for 55 percent of the total variance in the indicators, accounting for 20 percent
74
The Long Term Growth Model
of the variance of education expenditure (eduexp), 63 percent of that of secondary attainment (secondary),
75 percent of that of tertiary attainment, and 63 percent of that of PISA scores (pisa). The lower weight and
the smaller contribution of the education expenditure indicator to the common variance shows that this
indicator has a low correlation with the outcome indicators.
Educ,t = 0.20 * z(eduexpc,t ) + 0.36 * z(secondaryc,t) + 0.39 * z(pisac,t)
+ 0.36 * z(tertiaryc,t). (4)
For the market efficiency subcomponent index, the indicators are combined with similar weights
(in absolute terms) (equation 5). A factor analysis shows that the subcomponent index accounts for
69 percent of the total variance in the three indicators, accounting for 79 percent of the variance of
Doing Business scores (business), 78 percent of that of Financial Development Index (financial), and
49 percent of the labor index (labor). In turn, a factor analysis shows that the labor index accounts for
48 percent of the total variance of the minimum wage (minwage), 53 percent of that of the severance
pay (severance), and 52 percent of that of the share of women employed in the nonagricultural sector
(women).
Effic,t = 0.43 * z(businessc,t) + 0.43 * z(financialc,t) − 0.34 * z(laborc,t), (5)
where laborc,t = 0.45 * z(minwagec,t) + 0.47 * z(severancec,t) − 0.47 * z(womenc,t)
For the infrastructure subcomponent index, all indicators except for mobile subscription have similar
weights (equation 6). A factor analysis shows that the subcomponent index accounts for 65 percent
of the total variance in its indicators, accounting for 78 percent of the variance of the number of
telephone subscription (tele), 28 percent of that of mobile subscription (mobile), 64 percent of that
of paved road (road), 67 percent of that of electricity production (elec), 70 percent of that of access
to improved water source (water), and 76 percent of that of access to improved sanitation facilities
(sanit).
Infrac,t = 0.23 * z(telec,t) + 0.14 * z(mobilec,t) + 0.21 * z(roadc,t)
+ 0.21 * z (elec_(c,t)) + 0.22 * z(waterc,t) + 0.23 * z(sanitc,t). (6)
The institutions subcomponent index consists of the six indicators with similar weights (equation 7).
The subcomponent index accounts for 87 percent of the total variance in its indicators, accounting for 83
percent of the variance of voice and accountability (va), 90 percent of that of the control of corruption (cc),
93 percent of that of government effectiveness (ge), 71 percent of that of political stability (ps), 89 percent
of that of regulatory quality (rq), and 94 percent of that of the rule of law (rl).
Instc,t = 0.18 * z(vac,t) + 0.19 * z(ccc,t) + 0.19 * z(gec,t) + 0.16 * z(psc,t) + 0.18 * z(rqc,t) + 0.19 * z(rlc,t).(7)
The overall determinant index is a linear combination of the (standardized) five subcomponent indexes
with similar weights (equation 8). The overall index, obtained through a principal component analysis,
represents the innovation index with a correlation of 0.88; the education index, 0.90; the market efficiency
index, 0.94; the infrastructure index, 0.94; and the institutions index, 0.87.
Indexc,t = 0.43 * z(Innovc,t) + 0.44 * z(Educ,t) + 0.46 * z(Effic,t) + 0.47 * z(Infrac,t)
+ 0.43 * z(Instc,t). (8)
Appendix C shows the average values of the individual indicators, as well as the subcomponent and overall
indexes, over 1985–2014 by income and regional group.
75
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
4.3 Relationship between the main determinants of TFP and TFP growth
The relative contribution of the main determinants to the variance of total
factor productivity growth
Figure 3.6 shows the decomposition of the total explained variance of the TFP growth rate corresponding to
each of the main TFP determinants by decade for all, OECD, and developing countries (controlling for the
five-year-lagged TFP level and time-effects). For the OECD countries, a notable trend is that the contribu-
tion of the market efficiency index increases and accounts for 45 percent of the explained variance of TFP
growth in the last decade; whereas that of infrastructure decreases and explains the least. For developing
countries, in 1985–1994 the TFP determinant with the highest explanatory power of TFP growth variance is
Figure 3.6: Variance Decomposition of TFP Growth Rate Corresponding to the Determinant
Subcomponent Indexes (by decade for all, OECD, and developing countries,
controlling for initial TFP and time effects)
a. World
1985-1994 1994-2004 2004-2014
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6
b. OECD
1985-1994 1994-2004 2004-2014
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6
c. Developing
1985-1994 1994-2004 2004-2014
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6
76
The Long Term Growth Model
institutions; however, its contribution decreases afterward. The contribution of education increases over the
two decades and accounts for almost 50 percent of the explained variance of TFP growth in the last decade.
The variance decomposition analysis helps understand what drives the differences across countries regard-
ing TFP growth. It does not, however, indicate what the most important or relevant drivers of TFP growth
are for specific countries. For this, we would need to know the country-specific gaps in each determinant
of TFP. We turn to this issue in section 6, on simulations and scenario analysis. Before, however, we need
to obtain a reasonable estimate of the effect of the overall index on TFP growth, which we attempt next.
The relationship between the overall determinant index and total factor productivity
growth
Table 3.1 shows the regression results for equation 2 in which the TFP growth rate is a function of the
lagged overall determinant index and the lagged TFP level, along with country- and time-effects. We do
not attempt a regression with the five subcomponent indexes as individual regressors because they are very
highly correlated, and their estimated marginal effects would be contaminated by multicollinearity.
As table 3.1 shows, the lagged overall index and the lagged TFP level are statistically significant in all
regressions, with no, random, and fixed country-specific effects, respectively. Based on the Hausman test,
which suggests bias estimation if correlated country-specific effects are not considered, we choose to focus
on the regression with fixed (correlated, not random) country-specific effects.
77
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
In the fixed effects model, an increase of the lagged overall determinant index by 1.00 percent is associated
with an increase of the annual TFP growth rate by 0.05 percent, after controlling for the lagged TFP level
and country and time effects. Suggesting convergence, an increase of lagged TFP by 1.00 percent is asso-
ciated with a decrease of annual TFP growth rate by 0.10 percent, holding other variables constant. This
implies that countries with a higher level of TFP need to increase the determinant index more than those
with a lower level of TFP to achieve the same amount of increase in TFP growth. These results are robust
in terms of signs and significance when we use different lags of three and seven years (see appendix D).
They are also robust when we use the WDI-based data in the construction of TFP levels and growth rates
(see appendix E).
78
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 3.2: Benchmark Countries with the Highest Overall Determinant Index as of 2014
by Region
Figure 3.7: Simulated Average TFP Growth rate by Region (with the scenario that a country
increases its overall determinant index to the highest index among developing
countries in its region over 15 years)
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
Percent
1.0
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
decrease gradually. For South Asia, the average TFP growth rate stays in the range from 0.6 to 0.8 percent.
Using regional benchmarks limits the possibility of progress in TFP growth because the regional leaders
may not be very advanced themselves. Such is the case of India for South Asia.
Scenario II: Following the trajectory of the most improving TFP overall index in the region
Scenario II assumes that a country replicates the trajectory, in terms of annual change, in the last three
decades of the TFP overall determinant index corresponding to the regional benchmark country. The
regional benchmark under scenario II is the country whose overall determinant index increases the most
over 1985–2014 among all developing (non-OECD) countries in a given region (see table 3.3).
We apply the annual change in the index of the benchmark country over 1985–2014 to that of all countries
in the same region, starting from the initial index (2014) for the next 30 years and the average change over
2005–2014 for subsequent years.
79
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Figure 3.8 shows the predicted average TFP growth rate under scenario II. For East Asia and Pacific, starting
from the highest historical average TFP growth rate over 1985–2014, the average TFP growth rate is expected
to increase to 1.7 percent over the next 15 years and then decrease. For Latin America and the Caribbean
and Sub-Saharan Africa, the simulated average TFP growth rate increases for more than 30 years to 0.9 and
1.2 percent, respectively. For Europe and Central Asia and Middle East and North Africa, the average TFP
growth rate is expected to increase to 0.7 and 0.6 percent, respectively, over the next 20 years and decrease
gradually. For South Asia, the simulated TFP growth rate stays in the range from 0.6 to 0.9 percent.
Scenario III: Improving to the highest TFP determinant index among all developing
countries
Scenario III assumes that a developing country increases its overall determinant index to the highest
index among all developing (non-OECD) countries as of 2014, which is that of the Republic of Korea.
Table 3.3: Benchmark Countries with the Most Increase in the Overall Determinant Index
during 1985–2014 by Region
Region Country with the most increase in the overall index during
1985–2014
East Asia and Pacific Korea, Rep.
Europe and Central Asia Czech Republic
Latin America and the Caribbean Colombia
Middle East and North Africa United Arab Emirates
South Asia India
Sub-Saharan Africa Rwanda
Figure 3.8: Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region (with the that a country replicates
the annual index change that its benchmark country has had in the last three
decades)
2.0
1.5
1.0
Percent
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
We assume a country’s overall determinant index increases linearly from the value in 2014 to the index of
Korea over 15 years and keeps increasing with the same slope afterward.
Figure 3.9a shows that Sub-Saharan Africa, which has the largest gap with respect to the benchmark and
has a relatively low TFP growth rate, is expected to have the highest increase from its historical average over
1985–2014 (initial value in the graph) and reach the highest average TFP growth rate of 3.4 percent in 11
years and then gradually decline. South Asia is expected to increase its TFP growth rate to 3.2 percent in 11
Figure 3.9: Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region and Income Group (with the scenario
that a country increases its overall determinant index to the highest index among
developing countries over 15 years)
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
Percent
1.5
1.0
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
East Asia and Pacific Europe and Central Asia
Latin America and the Caribbean Middle East and North Africa
South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
Percent
1.5
1.0
0.5
–0.5
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Low Low middle Upper middle
a
Low: average GDP per capita over 1985–2014 (constant 2010 USD) ≤ $995; Low middle: $995-$3,895; Upper middle: $3,895-$12,055.
81
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
years and then decrease, similarly to Sub-Saharan Africa. East Asia and Pacific, with the highest historical
average, is expected to increase its average TFP growth rate to 2.5 percent in 11 years; this is smallest
gain from the historical average among all regions, reflecting its already high TFP growth in the past.
Latin America and the Caribbean, and Middle East and North Africa, with negative historical average TFP
growth, are expected to increase the average TFP growth rate to 2.2 and 2.1 percent, respectively, in 15 years.
For Europe and Central Asia, with a negative historical growth, the average TFP growth rate increases to
1.7 percent in 16 years and then decreases.
Grouping countries by income level reveals interesting patterns. Figure 3.9b shows that the low-income group
is expected to increase its average TFP growth rate the most to 3.3 percent in 11 years, the low-middle-income
group to 2.6 percent in 12 years, and the upper-middle-income group to 1.8 percent in 16 years. In all cases,
TFP growth gradually declines after reaching a peak, approaching around 1.5 percent in 35 years. These results
confirm the notion obtained from the regional results: a country, region, or group with a larger gap in the TFP
determinant index with respect to the benchmark has more to gain and can experience a substantial increase
in TFP growth if they conduct the corresponding reforms. For those with already high TFP growth and for
those whose TFP growth rises sufficiently, subsequent TFP growth will tend to taper down.
Scenario IV: Following the trajectory of the most improving TFP overall index
among all developing countries
Scenario IV assumes that a country replicates a trajectory, in terms of annual change, of the world bench-
mark country. This is the country that has increased its overall determinant index the most over 1985–2014
among all developing (non-OECD) countries, which is Korea. We apply the annual change in the index of
Korea over 1985–2014 to that of a country starting from the initial index (2014) for the next 30 years and
the average change over 2005–2014 for subsequent years.
Figure 3.10a shows that Sub-Saharan Africa, with the largest gap with respect to the benchmark and a
relatively low TFP growth rate, has the highest increase from its historical average over 1985–2014 (initial
value in the graph) and reaches the highest average TFP growth rate of 2.1 percent in 16 years. South Asia
is expected to increase its TFP growth rate to 2.0 percent in 16 years and decrease afterwards. East Asia and
Pacific, with the highest historical average TFP growth, has the smallest projected increase in TFP growth,
to 1.7 percent in 15 years. Latin America and the Caribbean, Middle East and North Africa, and Europe and
Central Asia, with negative historical average TFP growth, are expected to increase their TFP growth rates
to 1.2 to 1.4 percent in 19–20 years.
Figure 3.10b presents the results for income groups. It shows that the low-income group is expected to
increase its average TFP growth rate the most to 2.0 percent in 16 years, the low-middle income group to
1.7 percent in 17 years, and the upper-middle-income group to 1.2 percent in 20 years. The results in figure
3.10 confirm the insight that countries, regions, or groups with a larger gap with respect to the benchmark,
such as Sub-Saharan Africa, have more to gain in terms of future TFP growth, and those with higher TFP
growth, for example, East Asia and Pacific, have a slower subsequent TFP growth.
Figure 3.10: Simulated Average TFP Growth Rate by Region and Income Group (with the
scenario that a country replicates the trajectory of the overall index of Korea,
which increases the index the most among all developing countries in the last three
decades)
2.0
1.5
1.0
Percent
0.5
–0.5
–1.0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
East Asia and Pacific Europe and Central Asia
Latin America and the Caribbean Middle East and North Africa
South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa
2.0
1.5
Percent
1.0
0.5
–0.5
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35
Low Low middle Upper middle
a
Low: average GDP per capita over 1985-2014 (constant 2010 USD) ≤ $995; Low middle: $995-$3,895; Upper middle: $3,895-$12,055.
rates being harder to improve). In the case of Peru, we choose the historical level of TFP growth to be equal
to the average for the two most recent decades for which we have data, 1995–2014. This avoids the macroeco-
nomic and social crisis (recession, hyperinflation, civil conflict, and recovery) of the 1980s and early 1990s.
Similar analyses and choices can be made for each country whose future TFP growth is to be simulated.
In scenario 1, the overall TFP determinant index in Peru is assumed to reach the highest current index in
Latin America, which corresponds to Chile, in either 15 years (dark-red line) or 30 years (orange line).
The target rate of improvement is modest, and, correspondingly, the productivity gains are low. Reaching
Chile’s current index in 30 years brings no gain in TFP growth and reaching it in 15 years allows to obtain
83
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Figure 3.11: Projected TFP Growth Rates for Peru under Various Scenarios
Scenario 1: The overall index increases to the highest index in Latin America (Chile) in 15 or 30 years.
a. Overall determinant index b. TFP growth rate
180 2.5
160
140 2.0
120
1.5
Percent
Percent
100
80
1.0
60
40 0.5
20
0
0
40
18
28
38
00
48
10
50
23
33
43
20
30
05
15
35
45
95
25
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
20
Scenario 2: The overall index increases to the highest index among all developing countries (Korea, Rep.) in 15 or 30 years.
a. Overall determinant index b. TFP growth rate
180 2.5
160
140 2.0
120
1.5
Percent
Percent
100
80
1.0
60
40
0.5
20
0 0
00
10
30
40
50
43
8
20
18
28
8
05
15
25
23
3
95
35
45
4
3
3
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
20
Scenario 3: The overall index for the next 3 decades follows the trajectory of Colombia and Korea, Rep. in 1985–2014,
which shows the fastest increase in the overall index in Latin America and among all countries, respectively.
a. Overall determinant index b. TFP growth rate
180 2.5
160
140 2.0
120
1.5
100
Percent
Percent
80
1.0
60
40 0.5
20
0 0
50
00
30
10
20
40
18
28
48
3
33
38
43
95
05
15
25
35
45
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
20
84
The Long Term Growth Model
a TFP growth of 0.5 percent. The latter, modest gain, is consistent with a continuation in the rate of
improvement in the TFP determinant index that Peru has experienced since the mid-1990s.
Peru’s development aspirations demand a larger rate of economic growth, and this, in turn, requires a faster
TFP growth rate. This can be achieved only if the pace of reforms to improve the determinants of TFP
increases substantially. Scenarios 2 and 3 consider two such alternatives.
In scenario 2, the overall TFP determinant index in Peru is assumed to reach the highest index among all
developing countries (to be more precise, among all countries not belonging to the OECD for at least 40 years).
This country is Korea. As in scenario 1, we consider two cases, reaching Korea’s level in 15 years (dark-red
line) or 30 years (orange line). Both represent a departure from the previous trend, especially, of course, the
target of achieving Korea’s current TFP index in 15 years. The gains in TFP growth are correspondingly large:
focusing on the fast improvement case, TFP growth rises from nearly 0 percent to 1.5 percent in five years,
reaches 2.0 percent in twelve years, and then tapers down to about 1.5 percent by 2050. To be possible, this
scenario would represent a radical improvement of sustained and, for Peru’s standards, high TFP growth. But
is this target unrealistic? Scenario 3 presents a less ambitious and arguably more realistic case.
In scenario 3, the overall TFP determinant index in Peru is assumed to mimic the changes observed in the
index of the most improving countries in Latin American and in the world in the last three decades for which
we have data, 1985–2014, and then continue with the same trend. These countries are, respectively, Colombia
(orange line) and Korea (dark-red line). Imitating the Colombian improvement would render some gains for
TFP growth, sustained but slow, approaching 1.0 percent by 2050. However, this is hardly what Peru needs
to boost long-run economic growth. Imitating the Korean improvement is more promising and, of course,
more demanding. It would allow Peru to raise its TFP growth from nearly 0 percent to 1.0 percent in seven
years, reach almost 1.5 percent in about fifteen years, and then reduce gradually to over 1.0 percent by 2050.
For Peru, as for most countries around the world, sustained TFP growth is essential for economic growth. By
itself, however, it cannot support an ambitious growth target. It must be accompanied by a strong effort in
physical capital accumulation, labor force participation, and quality, as well as the required domestic savings.
6. Conclusion
This is the background chapter for the TFP extension of the World Bank’s Long Term Growth Model
(LTGM) that was presented in chapter 1. It proposes a way to project the future path of TFP growth for most
developing countries around the world if they were to follow a program of reforms that would approach
them to regional and global leaders. The chapter is accompanied by an Excel-based toolkit, which can be
used for scenario analysis on TFP and corresponding income growth (available at the LTGM’s website:
https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM).
Based on a comprehensive literature review, we select innovation, education, market efficiency, infrastruc-
ture, and institutions as the five main categories of TFP determinants. For each of these categories, we
construct an index as a linear combination of representative indicators (or proxies) by a factor analysis,
that is, by accounting for as much of the common variance in the indicators as possible. We then combine
the five subcomponent indexes into an overall index by the principal component analysis, which accounts
for as much of the total variance in the subcomponent indexes as possible.
Using dominance analysis, the variance decomposition of the TFP growth rate into the main subcomponent
indexes shows that for OECD countries, market efficiency contributes the most to the variance of TFP growth
and infrastructure, the least for the recent decade; and for developing countries, the contribution of education
increases continuously and is the largest among the determinants in the recent decade. Although the variance
decomposition of TFP into its determinants is not necessarily a guide for policy reform, it illustrates how the
85
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
observed variation in TFP growth can be explained differentially over time and across development levels. This
suggests patterns that countries can use to assess their own progress in the various determinants of productivity.
On its part, regression analysis shows that an increase in the overall determinant index is significantly
associated with an increase in the TFP growth rate, controlling for the initial TFP level and country- and
time-effects. Countries that have a larger room for improvement in the determinants of TFP and make a
stronger effort of reform would experience a larger increase in TFP growth, which is expected to rise over
time and then taper down. The slowdown of TFP growth in the long run is explained by the increasing
difficulty of expanding TFP when its level is higher (given the estimated negative regression coefficient on
past TFP) and the deceleration (in proportional terms) in the TFP determinant index itself.
Though significant and reasonable by historical standards, the increase in TFP growth is projected to be
between 2.5–3.0 percentage points in the best cases of substantial reform, not enough by itself to support
overly ambitious economic growth targets. Alongside productivity improvements, savings, investment,
labor participation, and human capital formation should continue to figure prominently in countries’
growth and development agendas.
This study has some limitations that should be considered when interpreting the results. One limitation
is that the TFP determinants could be endogenous in relation to TFP growth. To mitigate this risk, we use
lagged observations of the TFP determinant index in the variance decomposition and regression analyses.
This may be a more straightforward and less biased approach than using instrumental variables that could
be questionable (see Young 2017). Another limitation is that we do not include all possible determinants
of productivity, either as broad categories or specific indicators. For instance, we do not directly include
geographic conditions, workforce demographics, income and wealth inequality, or firm-specific entrepre-
neurship, and managerial ability (Feyrer 2007; Mastromarco and Zago 2012; Kremer, Rao, and Schilbach
2019). We attenuate the potential problem by including country-specific effects, a reasonable strategy to
control for productivity determinants that are persistent over time. Also, we include a number of indicators
that represent not only their limited definition but also proxy for a wider array of variables not represented
in our measurements. A third limitation deals with the well-known drawbacks of measuring productivity
as a residual. In a sense, the Solow residual is a “measure of our ignorance” (Abramovitz 1956), capturing
not only productivity proper but also a variety of factors, from excess capacity and natural resources to
heterogeneous and intangible capital (Hulten 2001; Corrado, Hulten, and Sichel 2009). Nevertheless, we
believe that focusing on average growth rates of TFP over several years (rather than on TFP levels or
high-frequency TFP growth) is conducive to reducing mismeasurement and allowing the possibility of
explaining TFP growth (Jorgenson and Griliches 1967). A fourth limitation is that the study focuses on
global patterns, not taking sufficiently into account country heterogeneity. The relative contribution of the
determinant indexes to the variance of TFP growth and the impact of the overall determinant index on
TFP growth could be different for each country and region, generally depending on the level of economic
development and the nature of their political and social environment. Despite these limitations, we expect
that this chapter and accompanying toolkit can be a starting point—an international benchmark—for
researchers and policy makers in their analysis of productivity and growth for particular countries.8
References
Abdih, Yasser, and Frederick Joutz. 2006. “Relating the Knowledge Production Function to Total Factor Productivity:
An Endogenous Growth Puzzle.” WP/05/74. IMF Working Paper.
Abramovitz, M. 1956. “Resource and Output Trends in the United States since 1870.” American Economic Review 46: 5–23.
8
See, for instance, Céspedes, Loayza, and Ramírez, forthcoming.
86
The Long Term Growth Model
Acemoglu, Daron, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2001. “Productivity Differences.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2):
563–606. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530151144104.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development:
An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.5.1369.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson. 2004. “Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run
Growth.” 10481. NBER Working Paper.
Aghion, Philippe, and Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction.” Econometrica 60 (2): 323–51.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2951599.
Aguiar, Angel, Badri Narayanan, and Robert McDougall. 2016. “An Overview of the GTAP 9 Data Base.” Journal of
Global Economic Analysis 1 (1): 181–208. https://doi.org/10.21642/JGEA.010103AF.
Alfaro, Laura, Areendam Chanda, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, and Selin Sayek. 2004. “FDI and Economic Growth:
The Role of Local Financial Markets.” Journal of International Economics 64 (1): 89–112. https://doi.org/10.1016
/S0022-1996(03)00081-3.
Alfaro, Laura, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, and Selin Sayek. 2009. “FDI, Productivity and Financial Development.”
World Economy 32 (1): 111–35. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01159.x.
Ark, Bart van, Mary O’Mahony, and Marcel P Timmer. 2008. “The Productivity Gap between Europe and the United
States: Trends and Causes.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 22 (1): 25–44. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.22.1.25.
Arnold, Jens, Giuseppe Nicoletti, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2008. “Regulation, Allocative Efficiency and Productivity in
OECD Countries.” 616. OECD Economics Department Working Papers. https://doi.org/10.1787/241447806226.
Aschauer, David Alan. 1989. “Is Public Expenditure Productive?” Journal of Monetary Economics 23 (2): 177–200.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(89)90047-0.
Azen, Razia, and David V Budescu. 2003. “The Dominance Analysis Approach for Comparing Predictors in Multiple
Regression.” Psychological Methods 8 (2): 129–48. https://doi.org/10.1037/1082-989X.8.2.129.
Barro, Robert J., and Jong Wha Lee. 2013. “A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950-2010.”
Journal of Development Economics 104: 184–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2012.10.001.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-I-Martin. 1992. “Public Finance in Models of Economic Growth.” The Review of
Economic Studies 59 (4): 645. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297991.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier I. Sala-i-Martin. 2004. “Chapter 10. Growth Accounting.” In Economic Growth, 2nd ed.
Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.
Barro, Robert J. 1990. “Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogeneous Growth.” Journal of Political
Economy 98 (5): S103–25. https://doi.org/10.1086/261726.
———. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (2):
407–43. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937943.
———. 2001. “Human Capital and Growth.” The American Economic Review 91 (2): 12–17. https://doi
.org/10.2307/2677725.
Bartelsman, Eric J., Pieter A. Gautier, and Joris De Wind. 2016. “Employment Protection, Technology Choice, and
Worker Allocation.” International Economic Review 57 (3): 787–826. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12176.
Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Norman Loayza. 2000. “Finance and the Sources of Growth.” Journal of Financial
Economics 58 (1–2): 261–300. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00072-6.
Ben-David, Dan, and David H. Papell. 1998. “Slowdowns and Meltdowns: Postwar Growth Evidence from
74 Countries.” Review of Economics and Statistics 80 (4): 561–71. https://doi.org/10.1162/003465398557834.
Benhabib, J., and Mark M. Spiegel. 2005. “Chapter 13 Human Capital and Technology Diffusion.” Handbook of
Economic Growth. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01013-0.
Benhabib, J., and M. Spiegel. 1994. “The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development. Evidence from Aggregate
Cross-Country Data.” Journal of Monetary Economics 144: 117–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7.
Benhabib, Jess, and M. M. Spiegel. 1994. “The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development Evidence from
Aggregate Cross-Country Data.” Journal of Monetary Economics 34 (2): 143–173. https://doi.org/http://dx.doi
.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7.
Benhabib, Jess, and Mark M. Spiegel. 2005. “Human Capital and Technology Diffusion.” In Handbook of Economic
Growth, 1:936–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01013-0.
87
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Bergoeing, Raphael, Norman V. Loayza, and Facundo Piguillem. 2016. “The Whole Is Greater than the Sum of Its
Parts: Complementary Reforms to Address Microeconomic Distortions.” World Bank Economic Review 30 (2):
268–305. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhv052.
Borensztein, E., J. De Gregorio, and J-W. Lee. 1998. “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?”
Journal of International Economics 45 (1): 115–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-1996(97)00033-0.
Bridgman, Benjamin, Shi Qi, and James A. Schmitz. 2009. “The Economic Performance of Cartels: Evidence from
the New Deal U.S. Sugar Manufacturing Cartel, 1934–74.” 437. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff Report.
Bronzini, Raffaello, and Paolo Piselli. 2009. “Determinants of Long-Run Regional Productivity with Geographical
Spillovers: The Role of R&D, Human Capital and Public Infrastructure.” Regional Science and Urban Economics
39 (2): 187–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2008.07.002.
Budescu, David V. 1993. “Dominance Analysis: A New Approach to the Problem of Relative Importance of Predictors
in Multiple Regression.” Psychological Bulletin. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.114.3.542.
Buera, Francisco J, Joseph P Kaboski, and Yongseok Shin. 2011. “American Economic Association Finance and
Development: A Tale of Two Sectors.” Source: The American Economic Review 101 (5): 1964–2002. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.
Caballero, and Hammour. 1998. “Jobless Growth: Appropriability, Factor Substitution, and Unemployment.”
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48: 95–99. https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0167
-2231(98)00016-5.
Caballero, R. J., and M. L. Hammour. 1996. “On the Timing and Efficiency of Creative Destruction.” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 111 (3): 805–52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2946673.
Calderón, César, and Luis Servén. 2010. “Infrastructure and Economic Development in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Journal
of African Economies 19 (Supplement 1): i13–87. https://doi.org/10.1093/jae/ejp022.
Calderón, César, and Luis Servén. 2012. Infrastructure in Latin America. The Oxford Handbook of Latin American
Economics. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199571048.013.0026.
Calderón, César, and Luis Servén.2014. “Infrastructure, Growth, and Inequality: An Overview.” 7034. World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-7034.
Canning, David, and Peter Pedroni. 2008. “Infrastructure, Long-Run Economic Growth and Causality Tests for
Cointegrated Panels.” Manchester School 76 (5): 504–27. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.2008.01073.x.
Caselli, Francesco. 2005. “Chapter 9 Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences.” Handbook of Economic
Growth. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01009-9.
Centre for Economic Performance. 2017. “World Management Survey.” 2017.
Céspedes, N., N. Loayza, and N. Ramírez. Forthcoming. Economic Growth in Peru: Causes and Consequences
(in Spanish). Lima: Fondo Editorial de la Universidad del Pacífico.
Chanda, Areendam, and Carl Johan Dalgaard. 2008. “Dual Economies and International Total Factor Productivity
Differences: Channelling the Impact from Institutions, Trade, and Geography.” Economica 75 (300): 629–61.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2007.00673.x.
Chang, Roberto, Linda Kaltani, and Norman V. Loayza. 2009. “Openness Can Be Good for Growth: The Role
of Policy Complementarities.” Journal of Development Economics 90 (1): 33–49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j
.jdeveco.2008.06.011.
Chen, Derek H C, and Carl J Dahlman. 2004. “Knowledge and Development A Cross-Section Approach.” 3366.
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper.
Chenery, Hollis B. 1960. “Patterns of Industrial Growth.” The American Economic Review 50 (4): 624–54. https://doi
.org/10.1257/jep.6.3.79.
Cingano, Federico. 2014.“Trends in Income Inequality and Its Impact on Economic Growth.” OECD Social, Employment,
and Migration Working Papers, no. 163: 0_1,5-59. https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jxrjncwxv6j-en.
Cirera, Xavier, and William F. Maloney. 2017. The Innovation Paradox : Developing-Country Capabilities and the
Unrealized Promise of Technological Catch-Up. Washington, DC: World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.
org/handle/10986/28341.
Coe, David T., Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander W. Hoffmaister. 2009. “International R&D Spillovers and Institutions.”
European Economic Review 53 (7): 723–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.02.005.
88
The Long Term Growth Model
Coe, David T., and Elhanan Helpman. 1995. “International R&D Spillovers.” European Economic Review 39 (5):
859–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(94)00100-E.
Coe, David Theodore, Elhanan Helpman, and Alexander W. Hoffmaister. 1997. “North-South R&D Spillovers.”
Economic Journal 107 (440): 134–49. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00146.
Comin, Diego, and Bart Hobijn. 2010. “An Exploration of Technology Diffusion.” American Economic Review 100 (5):
2031–59. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.5.2031.
Comin, Diego, Bart Hobijn, and Emilie Rovito. 2008. “Technology Usage Lags.” Journal of Economic Growth 13 (4):
237–56. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-008-9035-5.
Comin, Diego, and Martí Mestieri. 2018. “If Technology Has Arrived Everywhere, Why Has Income Diverged?”
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10 (3): 137–78. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20150175.
Corrado, C., C. Hulten, and D. Sichel. 2009 “Intangible Capital and U.S. Economic Growth.” The Review of Income
and Wealth 55(3): 661-685.
Dabla-Norris et al. 2015. “Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality : A Global Perspective.” IMF Staff Discussion
Note. https://doi.org/DOI:
Dar, Atul A., and Sal AmirKhalkhali. 2002. “Government Size, Factor Accumulation, and Economic Growth:
Evidence from OECD Countries.” Journal of Policy Modeling 24 (7–8): 679–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0161
-8938(02)00163-1.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2001. “Productivity Differences.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (2):
563–606. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530151144104.
Davis, Steven J., John Haltiwanger, and Scott Schuh. 1996. “Small Business and Job Creation: Dissecting the Myth and
Reassessing the Facts.” Small Business Economics 8 (4): 297–315. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00393278.
Devadas, Sharmila, and Steven Michael Pennings. 2018. “Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An
Extension of the World Bank Long-Term Growth Model.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 8604.
Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “The Regulation of Entry.”
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1): 1–37.
Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2004. “Trade, Growth, and Poverty.” The Economic Journal 114 (493): F22–49. https://
doi.org/10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.00186.x.
Easterly, William. 2001. “The Middle Class Consensus and Economic Development.” Journal of Economic Growth
6 (4): 317–35. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1012786330095.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4):
1203–50. https://doi.org/10.1002/ps.3780.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2003. “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic
Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00200-3.
Easterly, William, and Ross E. Levine. 2001. “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models.”
The World Bank Economic Review 15 (2): 177–219. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.269108.
Engerman, S, and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. 2000. “Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the
New World.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 217–32. http://scholar.google.com/scholar?hl=en&btnG=S
earch&q=intitle:Institutions+,+Factor+Endowments+,+and+Paths+of+Development+in+the+New+World#1.
Erosa, Andrés, Tatyana Koreshkova, and Diego Restuccia. 2010. “How Important Is Human Capital? A Quantitative
Theory Assessment of World Income Inequality.” Review of Economic Studies 77 (4): 1421–49. https://doi.
org/10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00610.x.
Fagerberg, Jan. 2000. “Technological Progress, Structural Change and Productivity Growth: A Comparative Study.”
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (4): 393–411. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0954-349X(00)00025-4.
Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar, and Marcel P. Timmer. 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.”
American Economic Review 105 (10): 3150–82. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130954.
Feyrer, James. 2007. “Demographics and Productivity.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1): 100–109.
Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J. C., and Krizan, C. J. 2001. “Aggregate Productivity Growth. Lessons from Microeconomic
Evidence.” In New Developments in Productivity Analysis, pp. 303–372. University of Chicago Press.
Furman, Jeffrey L., and Richard Hayes. 2004. “Catching up or Standing Still? National Innovative Productivity among
‘follower’ Countries, 1978-1999.” Research Policy 33 (9): 1329–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2004.09.006.
89
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
Galiani, Sebastian, Paul Gertler, and Ernesto Schargrodsky. 2005. “Water for Life: The Impact of the Privatization of
Water Services on Child Mortality.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (1): 83–120. https://doi.org/10.1086/426041.
Ghali, Khalifa H. 1999. “Government Size and Economic Growth: Evidence from a Multivariate Cointegration
Analysis.” Applied Economics 31 (8): 975–87. https://doi.org/10.1080/000368499323698.
Giavazzi, Francesco, and Guido Tabellini. 2005. “Economic and Political Liberalizations.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 52 (7): 1297–1330. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.05.002.
Griffith, Rachel, Stephen Redding, and John Van Reenen. 2004. “Mapping the Two Faces of R&D: Productivity
Growth in a Panel of OECD Industries.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (4): 883–95. https://doi
.org/10.1162/0034653043125194.
Grömping, Ulrike. 2007. “Estimators of Relative Importance in Linear Regression Based on Variance Decomposition.”
American Statistician 61 (2): 139–47. https://doi.org/10.1198/000313007X188252.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1991. “Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth.” The Review of Economic
Studies 58 (1): 43. https://doi.org/10.2307/2298044.
Guellec, Dominique, and B. van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie. 2004. “From R&D to Productivity Growth: Do the
Institutional Settings and the Source of Funds of R&D Matter?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 66 (3):
353–78. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2004.00083.x.
Hall, Robert E., and Charles I. Jones. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce so Much More Outper per Worker than
Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1): 83–116. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355399555954.
Haltiwanger, John, Stefano Scarpetta, and Helena Schweiger. 2008. “Assessing Job Flows across Countries:
The Role of Industry, Firm Size and Regulations.” 13920. NBER Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.1017
/CBO9781107415324.004.
Hanushek, Eric A., and Ludger Woessmann. 2015. The Knowledge Capital of Nations: Education and the Economics of
Growth. The MIT Press.
Hicks, John. 1939. Value and Capital. Edited by John Hicks. Oxford, United Kingdom: Clarendon Press.
Hoeller, Peter, Isabelle Joumard, and Isabell Koske. 2014. “Reducing Income Inequality While Boosting Economic
Growth: Can It Be Done? Evidence from OECD Countries.” The Singapore Economic Review 59 (01): 1450001.
https://doi.org/10.1142/S0217590814500015.
Hopenhayn, Hugo. 1992. “Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium.” Econometrica 60 (5): 1127–50.
Hopenhayn, Hugo, and Richard Rogerson. 1993. “Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General Equilibrium
Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (5): 915–38. https://doi.org/10.1086/261909.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–48. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1403.
Hulten, Charles R. 2001. “Total Factor Productivity: A Short Biography.” In New Developments in Productivity Analysis,
edited by Charles R. Hulten, Edwin R. Dean, and Michael J. Harper. https://doi.org/10.1080/09535310701571828.
Hulten, Charles R. 1996. “Infrastructure Capital and Economic Growth How Well You Use It May Be More Important
Than How Much You Have.” 5847. NBER Research Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.3386/w5847.
International Road Federation. 2017a. “Roads, Paved (% of Total Roads).” International Road Federation. 2017.
———. 2017b. “Roads, Total Network (Km).” International Road Federation. 2017.
Isaksson, A. 2007. “Determinants of Total Factor Productivity: A Literature Review.” Research and Statistics Branch,
UNIDO. http://www.rrojasdatabank.info/87573_determinants_of_total_factor_productivity.pdf.
Jerzmanowski, Michał. 2007. “Total Factor Productivity Differences: Appropriate Technology vs. Efficiency.” European
Economic Review 51 (8): 2080–2110. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2006.12.005.
Jolliffe, I . T. 2002. Principal Component Analysis. Springer Series in Statistics. https://doi.org/10.1007/b98835.
Jorgenson, Dale W., Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2005. Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the
American Growth Resurgence. The MIT Press. Vol. 3. http://ideas.repec.org/b/mtp/titles/0262101114.html.
Jorgenson, Dale W., Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2008. “A Retrospective Look at the US Productivity Growth
Resurgence.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 22 (1): 3–24. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.22.1.3.
Jorgenson, D., and Z. Griliches. 1967. “The Explanation of Productivity Change.” Review of Economic Studies 34:
349–83.
Kaufmann, Daniel, and Aart Kraay. 2017. “Worldwide Governance Indicators.” World Bank. 2017. www.govindicators.
org, accessed on 31 May 2017.
90
The Long Term Growth Model
Kim, Young Eun, Norman Loayza, and Claudia Meza-Cuadra. 2016. “Productivity as the Key to Economic
Growth and Development.” World Bank Research Policy Brief, no. 3. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/
en/314741472533203058/Productivity-as-the-key-to-economic-growth-and-development.
Knack, Stephen, and Philip Keefer. 1995. “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross–country Tests Using
Alternative Institutional Measures.” Economics & Politics 7 (3): 207–27. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0343.1995.
tb00111.x.
Kremer, Michael, Gautam Rao, and Frank Schilbach. 2019. “Behavioral Development Economics.” In Handbook of
Behavioral Economics—Foundations and Applications 2, edited by B. Douglas Bernheim, Stefano DellaVigna, and
David Laibson, 1st ed., 345–458. https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesbe.2018.12.002.
Kuznets, Simon. 1957. “Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations: II. Industrial Distribution
of National Product and Labor Force.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 5 (S4): 1–111. https://doi
.org/10.1086/449740.
Larson, Gregory Michael, Norman V. Loayza, and Michael Woolcock. 2016.“The Middle-Income Trap: Myth or Reality?”
World Bank Research & Policy Briefs, no. 1. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/965511468194956837
/The-middle-income-trap-myth-or-reality.
Lentz, Rasmus, and Dale T. Mortensen. 2008. “An Empirical Model of Growth through Product Innovation.”
Econometrica 76 (6): 1317–73. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA5997.
Lewis, Arthur W. 1954. “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour.” The Manchester School 22 (2):
139–91. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1006652108.
Loayza, Norman V., and Rei Odawara. 2010. “Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Egypt.” World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper. https://doi.org/10.1177/097493060900100105.
Loayza, Norman V., Pablo Fajnzylber, and César Calderón. 2005. Economic Growth in Latin America and the Caribbean :
Stylized Facts, Explanations, and Forecasts. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Loayza, Norman V., and Luis Servén. 2010. “Business Regulation and Economic Performance.” World Bank
Publications, No. 2554.
Lucas, Robert E. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1): 3–42.
https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7.
Mastromarco, Camilla, and Angelo Zago. 2012. “On modeling the determinants of TFP growth.” Structural Change
and Economic Dynamics 23 (4): 373–382.
Mauro, P. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (3): 681–712. https://doi
.org/10.2307/2946696.
Mello, L. R. de. 1999. “Foreign Direct Investment-Led Growth: Evidence from Time Series and Panel Data.” Oxford
Economic Papers 51: 133–51. https://doi.org/10.1093/oep/51.1.133.
Mendi, Pedro. 2007. “Trade in Disembodied Technology and Total Factor Productivity in OECD Countries.” Research
Policy 36 (1): 121–33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2006.09.028.
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.”
Econometrica 71 (6): 1695–1725.
Miller, Stephen M., and Mukti P. Upadhyay. 2000. “The Effects of Openness, Trade Orientation, and Human Capital
on Total Factor Productivity.” Journal of Development Economics 63 (2): 399–423. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304
-3878(00)00112-7.
Mulaik, Stanley A. 2009. Foundations of Factor Analysis. 2nd editio. Boca Raton: Taylor & Francis Group, LLC.
Munnell, Alicia H. 1992. “Policy Watch: Infrastructure Investment and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 6 (4): 189–98. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.6.4.189.
Nadiri, M. Ishaq. 1993. “Innovations and Technological Spillovers.” 4423. NBER Working Paper. https://doi
.org/10.3386/w4423.
Nicoletti, Giuseppe, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2003. “Regulation, Productivity and Growth: OECD Evidence.” Economic
Policy 18 (36): 9–72. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0327.00102.
North, Douglass C. 1990. “Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance.” Cambridge University
Press 5 (1): 1–153. https://doi.org/10.2307/2234910.
OECD/IEA. 2017. “Electricity Production (KWh).” OECD/IEA. 2017.
OECD. 2016a. “PISA: Mean Performance on the Mathematics Scale.” 2016.
91
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
92
The Long Term Growth Model
Woo, Wing Thye, Stephen Parker, and Jeffrey Sachs. 1997. Economies in Transition: Comparing Asia and Europe.
The MIT Press.
World Bank. 2003. World Development Report 2004 : Making Services Work for Poor People. World Bank. https://
openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/5986.
World Bank. 2017a. Doing Business 2017: Equal Opportunity for All. Washington, DC: World Bank Group. https://doi
.org/10.1596/978-1-4648-0948-4.
World Bank. 2017b. “Employment to Population Ratio, 15+, Total (%) (Modeled ILO Estimate).” World Development
Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017c. “Fixed Telephone Subscriptions (per 100 People).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017d. “GDP (Constant 2010 US$).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017e. “GDP per Capita (Constant 2010 US$).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017f. “Government Expenditure on Education, Total.” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017g. “Gross Capital Formation (Constant 2010 US$).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017h. “Labor Market Regulation Indicators.” Doing Business Database. 2017.
World Bank. 2017i. “Mobile Cellular Subscriptions (per 100 People).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank 2017j. “Oil Rents (% of GDP).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017k. “Patent Applications, Nonresidents.” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017l. “Patent Applications, Residents.” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017m. “Population, Total.” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017n. “Population Ages 0–14 (% of Total).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017o. “Research and Development Expenditure (% of GDP).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017p. “Scientific and Technical Journal Articles.” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017q. “Share of Women in Wage Employment in the Nonagricultural Sector (% of Total Nonagricultural
Employment).” World Development Indicators. 2017.
World Bank. 2017r. World Development Report 2017: Governance and the Law. World Bank. http://www.worldbank.
org/en/publication/wdr2017.
Young, Alwyn. 2017. “Consistency without Inference: Instrumental Variables in Practical Application.” London School
of Economics Working Paper. http://personal.lse.ac.uk/YoungA/ConsistencyWithoutInference.pdf.
93
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
94
The Long Term Growth Model
95
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
96
The Long Term Growth Model
97
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
98
The Long Term Growth Model
99
3. Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World
100
Chapter 4
Abstract
This chapter extends the World Bank’s Long Term surplus rules, which save commodity revenues, can
Growth Model (LTGM) with the addition of a nat- also boost growth if they free up savings for private
ural resource sector to analyze how long-run growth investment. The response of incomes to discoveries
evolves in resource-rich countries and the growth of natural resources is similar to the response to price
impacts of price shocks and resource discoveries. In shocks, although discoveries also produce a direct
the LTGM-Natural Resource Extension (LTGM-NR), effect on real GDP, in addition to an indirect effect
commodity price shocks affect long-term economic through investment. The LTGM-NR also captures the
growth through physical investment rates. As a large effect of other (non-resource) growth fundamentals
share of resource income typically accrues to the in resource-rich economies, and it is better suited
government, the size of the boost to investment in to general growth analysis in these countries than
a price boom depends on the government’s fiscal the standard LTGM. However, the LTGM-NR is a
rule. Fiscal rules that prioritize public investment, supply-side model, and so does not capture the short-
like a Hartwick Rule, generally lead to the largest run effects of price and discovery shocks that operate
increases in long-term growth. However, structural through aggregate demand.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 9965, originally published in March 2022.
E
The appendixes and spreadsheet-based LTGM-NR tool are available at the Long Term Growth Model website: https://www.worldbank
.org/LTGM. Affiliations are based on when the paper was written, not necessarily current affiliations.
2
orman V.Loayza, Arthur Mendes, Fabian Mendez Ramos, and Steven Pennings, World Bank. Corresponding author
N
email: spennings@worldbank.org. The views expressed here are the authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank,
its executive directors, or the countries they represent. The authors appreciate helpful comments from Sharmila Devadas, Lay Lian
Chuah, Jorge Luis Guzman, Young Eun Kim, and seminar participants at the World Bank’s Development Research Group hub in
Kuala Lumpur, Bank of Mexico, and Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean.
101
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
1. Introduction
The celebrated Solow-Swan neoclassical growth model analyzes how long-run economic growth depends
on growth fundamentals, such as productivity, savings/investment, human and physical capital, and
demographic trends (Solow 1956; Swan 1956; Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992; Hall and Jones 1999). The
World Bank’s Long Term Growth Model (LTGM; chapter 1 of this volume) is in this tradition, though it
is applied to simulations of future growth in developing countries. However, standard neoclassical models
are inappropriate for economies where the natural resource sector is sufficiently large to have a first-order
effect on growth, including many developing countries. Traditional neoclassical models are also silent on
how commodity price shocks and resource discoveries affect long-term growth for commodity exporters,
and the economic consequences of government policies that manage resource wealth.
The Long Term Growth Model–Natural Resource Extension (LTGM-NR) seeks to fill this gap by aug-
menting an otherwise-standard neoclassical growth model with a natural resource sector and government
fiscal policy. The model is designed to be accessible and transparent—a spreadsheet-based toolkit (without
macros) is freely downloadable at https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM with preloaded data for 56 resource-
rich countries (see appendix, table 1 for a list of available countries). The LTGM-NR first allows for the
evaluation of how commodity price shocks and discoveries of natural resources affect a country’s medium
to long-term economic growth and how it depends on different fiscal frameworks. Second, the model
analyzes how standard growth fundamentals, such as human capital, demographics, and productivity, affect
growth in resource-rich economies. The LTGM-NR allows for a more accurate analysis of the effect of these
fundaments than one-sector models, as those models do not account for heterogeneity across sectors or the
consequences of depleting reserves of natural resources. However, as the LTGM-NR is a supply-side model,
it does not capture the short-run effects of price and discovery shocks that operate through aggregate
demand.
The first step in analyzing country-specific commodity price shocks or discoveries is a resource accounting
exercise that evaluates the size of resource exports and reserves in each country, and hence the scale of
the direct impact of a given change in commodity prices or a resource discovery. We make this easier by
providing preloaded data on the resource sector in 56 countries. Our simulations incorporate some often
misunderstood accounting identities, such as the fact that commodity price fluctuations only directly affect
gross domestic income (GDI), whereas real gross domestic product (GDP) changes only indirectly (as real
GDP fixes the price of exports; see Kehoe and Ruhl 2008).
The second step is to trace out how higher GDI and government resource revenues affect investment
rates and long-term growth. As in a standard neoclassical model, a higher income boosts private savings
(assumed to be a fixed share of GDI) and, consequentially, private investment. But more important—since
a large share of the resource income typically accrues to the government—is how the government’s fiscal
policy affects investment.3 In short, fiscal rules that generate the largest increases in investment will generate
the fastest growth in the medium and long terms.
The LTGM-NR has two submodels: the LTGM-NR-Default, in which public investment responds directly to
fiscal policy via a simple fiscal rule, and the LTGM-NR-External-Balance that considers more sophisticated
fiscal rules and the relationship between public savings and the international capital flows.
3
ross-country evidence suggests that governments retain on average 65–85 percent of rents in the hydrocarbons sector and
C
40–60 percent of rents in the mining sector (IMF 2012).
102
The Long Term Growth Model
Spending allocation
Mostly Govt. consumption Public investment
(Historical budget shares) (Hartwick rule)
Timing of Spent on impact BBR BBR-HR
spending (Balanced budget rule) (“HR” in Default submodel)
Save for the future SSR SSR-HR
(Structural surplus rule) (Not in Default submodel)
Note: BBR = Balanced Budget Rule; SSR = Structural Surplus Rule; HR = Hartwick Rule.
The fiscal rules in both submodels are classified by whether the government saves or spends any extra
resource revenues, and if it spends them, whether that spending falls on public investment or government
consumption. For a temporary commodity price shock, a Balanced Budget Rule (BBR) is when the govern-
ment spends the extra revenues and a Structural Surplus Rule (SSR) when they are mostly saved in financial
assets. We usually assume that the spending allocation across investment/government consumption is kept
constant, but if all the extra spending is on public investment, we call it a Hartwick Rule (HR). This yields
four rules with different combinations of spending/savings and spending allocations: BBR, BBR-HR, SSR,
and SSR-HR (see Table 4.1).4
The LTGM-NR-External-Balance also analyzes how resource revenues and different fiscal rules interact
with international capital flows. This mostly affects the SSR, which often leads to large movements in
international borrowing/lending. Most important is the effect on the current account balance and private
investment. If the current account and private savings are relatively fixed, the extra public savings through an
SSR can crowd in private investment dollar-for-dollar, leading the SSR to have a similar path for investment
and growth as a BBR-Hartwick rule. In contrast, without crowding-in of investment (full adjustment of the
current account), the SSR in the External-Balance model performs similarly to that of the simple model
(which abstracts from international flows). Of course, real-world countries are somewhere in between
these two extremes, and so the strength of crowding in is chosen via a parameter that is calibrated to match
the data. In addition, the reduced international borrowing generated by a fiscal surplus under an SSR can
reduce the government’s interest bill—through reduced borrow and lower interest rates—which can free
up funds for public investment in the long run under the SSRs.
Angola case study. To illustrate how the LTGM-NR works, we discuss three simulations with the model
calibrated to Angola. First, we simulate the baseline “business-as-usual” growth path for Angola over the
next three decades. We find that, in the absence of major economic shocks or reforms, potential GDP
per capita growth declines slightly in the medium term but is expected to pick up in the longer term.
A growth decomposition shows that the “U-shaped” dynamics are driven by the interaction of improving
demographic trends, depleting oil reserves, and a transition of the economy away from oil. Finally, we show
that an unadjusted (“naïve”) calibration of the standard LTGM would generate an overly optimistic growth
path for Angola. This is because a one-sector model cannot account for the depletion of oil reserves that
is a drag on growth and the fact that the oil sector is much more capital intensive than the non-oil sector.
4
he difference between the SSR and SSR-HR depends on the timing of the analysis. In the short term, revenues are mostly
T
saved, and, consequentially, both rules yield a similar allocation of spending. However, they diverge substantially in the
medium and long terms, as fiscal surpluses under the SSRs can improve the government net asset position, freeing up funds for
extra spending. In this case, the SSR-HR would lead to a higher path of public investment than the SSR.
103
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Second, we evaluate the effects of a hypothetical oil price boom-and-bust cycle in Angola under each fiscal
rule. At the end of the oil price simulation (when oil prices are back at their original level), GDP per capita
is highest under the BBR-HR at 20%–25% above the baseline, as all of the higher government oil revenues
are invested during the boom years. However, under the other fiscal rules, GDP is only 5%–12% above the
baseline because of a much smaller increase in investment. The SSR-HR is the only rule that supports faster
growth for several years after the end of the oil price cycle. This is because the interest from the extra savings
during the oil price cycle is recycled into the budget, releasing resources for an almost permanent increase
in public investment. Third, we find that discoveries have a large and persistent impact on Angola’s growth
rate, especially under HRs. As before, the LTGM-NR only simulates the supply-side effects of these price
shocks and discoveries, not their short effects through aggregate demand.
Related literature. While there is a rich literature on managing the short-term cyclical effects of commodity
booms (for example, Kumhof and Laxton 2013; Mendes and Pennings 2020; Pieschacón 2012) and whether
natural resources are a curse or a blessing for development (see Van der Ploeg 2011 for a survey), the
mechanics of medium- to long-term growth in individual resource-rich economies are much less frequently
studied.5 The closest work is the modeling sections of Hansen and Gross (2018) and Arezki, Ramey, and
Sheng. (2018), who evaluate the effect of exploration and discoveries on medium-term macroeconomic
aggregates. While these models share some similarities with ours (in particular, the setup of the resource
sector), their purposes are very different. Those papers seek to explain estimated empirical relationships,
whereas we propose a simple and accessible tool for country-specific growth simulations and policy anal-
ysis. Our model is simpler but is calibrated to 56 countries individually, rather than to one representative
small open economy.6
The remainder of the chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the theoretical underpinnings of
the LTGM-NR, and Section 3 discusses a general calibration. Section 4 presents the applications to Angola,
and section 5 concludes.
where At0 is the total factor productivity (TFP) in sector 0, K t0−1 is the physical capital in sector 0 at the
end of period t − 1, and β is the labor share in the non-resource sector. Effective labor, htLt, is decomposed
into ht human capital per worker, and Lt, the labor force (number of workers). The labor force is defined as
Lt = tωtNt. Where Nt is total population, ωt is the working-age to population ratio, and t is the labor force
5
or empirical evidence on the resource curse in developing countries, see Terry Lynn (1999) and Wood (1999). For individual
F
country experience with the resource curse (Ghana and Angola), see Cust and Mihalyi (2017) for Ghana, and Richmond,
Yackovlev, and Yang (2013) for Angola. For countries that avoided the resource curve (Chile and Botswana), see Medina and
Soto (2007) and AfDB (2016).
6
I mportantly, our model lacks forward-looking decision-making by agents, as this is difficult to incorporate in a spreadsheet-
based model.
104
The Long Term Growth Model
participation rate (labor force to working-age population ratio). The variables At0 , ht , N t , ω t , and t are
exogenous and evolve at the following annual growth rates: g tA0 , g th , g tN , g tω , g t , respectively. Throughout
the model, exogenous variables are indicated with a bar index notation (as in g ).
The natural resource sector. The setup of the natural resource sector builds on Hansen and Gross (2018)
and Arezki, Ramey, and Sheng (2017) in being a Cobb-Douglas function of proven reserves (R) and phys-
ical capital (K), with decreasing returns in both R and K (equation (2)).7 This production function has
the desired property that the first reserves are relatively easy to extract—for example, being close to the
surface—but later reserves require more and more capital (or technology) to generate the same output, as
firms are forced to drill further underground or in less accessible locations.8
As countries produce multiple commodities, the natural resource sector, R, is further disaggregated into N
non-renewable resource industries i ∈ {1,…,N} (e.g., oil, natural gas, copper, gold, and others). As shown
in equation (2), the output of resource industry i, Qti , is produced using reserves Rti −1 and physical capital
K ti −1 in that industry,
where Ati is the TFP in industry i—which grows at exogenous rate g tAi —and gi is the share of resource rents
in industry i (then, 1 − gi is the capital income share). Capital and reserves are state variables determined
in the previous year t − 1.
The dynamics of reserves in each industry obey the following law of motion,
Rti = Rti−1 − Qti + Dti , i ∈ {1,…, N} (3)
where reserves in industry i at the end of period t, Rti , increases with an exogenous stream of discoveries,
Dti , and is endogenously depleted by the production of good i, Qti .
Equations (4) and (5) describe the evolution of physical capital in activity j ∈ {0,1,…,N} (non-resource
sector plus resource industries) and at the aggregate level, respectively,
K tj = (1 − δ ) K tj−1 + I tj , j ∈{0, 1,…, N } (4)
(5)
Kt = ∑
N
K tj
j =0
where δ is the annual depreciation rate (common across all activities), I tj is the investment in activity j, and
Kt is the aggregate capital at the end of period t.
National income/output and prices. The model economy represents a small, price taking, commodity
exporter. The non-resource good is freely traded with a constant price of US$1 (the numeraire), and is used
for private and government consumption, investment, and imports. All the proceeds from the resource
sector are exported at exogenous international prices pti in constant dollars.
7
ansen and Gross (2018) and Arezki, Ramey, and Sheng (2017) also include labor in the production function, but its share is
H
very small (0.13); so for simplicity we exclude it.
8
lternatively, Rti can be interpreted as a quality-adjusted index of reserves that take into consideration geological factors such
A
as ore grade (for minerals) or the composition of hydrocarbons (for petroleum and natural gas). As the highest quality mines
and oil fields tend to be explored first, further extraction and depletion reduces the quality of the remaining reserves, scaling
down the industry marginal product of capital (see Cochilco 2017). However, our default calibration of the model is not
adjusted for the quality of reserves.
105
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Real GDP and real GDI. There are two measures of the “size” of an open economy, real gross domestic
product (RGDP) and real gross domestic income (RGDI) (also known in the US as “Command-basis
GDP”).9 While these two are identical in a closed economy, they are often very different in countries with
volatile terms of trade like commodity exporters. The key difference between the measures is how exports
are deflated (Kehoe and Ruhl 2008).10
For RGDP, exports are deflated by the export price index, which for a country exporting one commodity
is simply pt1 /p01 (the current commodity price relative to its price in the base year, t = 0). This means that
changes in commodity prices have no direct effect on RGDPt (equation (6)). This is unsurprising, as RGDP is
designed to be a measure of quantities, which are not directly affected by commodity price shocks.
N N
RGDPt = Yt0 + ∑ pti Qti / ( pti / p0i ) = Yt0 + ∑ p0i Qti (6)
i =1 i =1
In contrast, RGDI is a measure of purchasing power: how much can be bought with the national income.
Hence, for GDI, exports are deflated by the consumption (or, equivalently, import) price index. In our
model, consumption goods are of the non-resource (numeraire) good, and so have a constant price of
US$1.11 Hence RGDI, denoted by Yt (without a superscript), is just the value of non-resource and resource
production (in terms of the numeraire)—as in equation (7),
(7)
Yt = Yt0 + Yt R = Yt0 + ∑ pti Qti
N
i =1
While neither RGDP nor RGDI is the “right” measure, we focus more on RGDI. Also, it makes more
sense to measure investment and savings relative to RGDI because consumption/investment goods are the
numeraire. In this case, let us denote lower case letters variables as a share of real GDI (e.g., zt ≡ Zt/Yt).
Investment. As in the standard LTGM, capital accumulation is the main endogenous driver of growth in
the LTGM-NR. To analyze the effects of different fiscal frameworks on the dynamics of growth in resource-
rich countries, we decompose aggregate investment (it) into private (itp ) and public (itg ) investment (see
equation (8)), though these are perfect substitutes in the production of new capital.12 Also, total investment
is allocated across sectors and industries of the economy (equation (9)),
it = itp + itg (8)
(9)
it = ∑ itj
N
j=0
In the LTGM-NR, private investment is an exogenous share of GDI (usually a fixed share), and public
investment depends on the government’s fiscal rule. The assumption of a fixed share of private investment
is a generalization of the Solow-Swan tradition.13 This generalization is an important departure from the
9
or the term “real gross domestic income” from the international System of National Accounts (SNA), see https://stats.oecd
F
.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=2244. The nomenclature can be confusing as the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) departs
from the SNA. The BEA calls GDP(I) (gross domestic product calculated using the income method) GDI; see https://www.bea
.gov/resources/learning-center/what-to-know-income-saving, which is why it need to use the term “Command-basis GDI”:
see https://www.bea.gov/help/glossary/command-basis-gross-domestic-product.
10
RGDP and RGDI are equivalent in a closed economy.
11
ommodity exporting economies typically import a wide range of imported goods (often manufactures), and so the
C
assumption of a constant import price is not too unrealistic.
12
For a variant of the LTGM where public and private investment are differentiated, see Devadas and Pennings (2019).
13
ore specifically, in the closed economy Solow-Swan model (without a government), savings are fixed as a share of GDP,
M
which means that investment is also a fixed share of GDP.
106
The Long Term Growth Model
literature (Hansen and Gross 2018; Arezki, Ramey, and Sheng 2017), where agents are forward looking and
allocate investment intertemporally based on its costs and benefits. However, the assumption of a fixed
share of private investment keeps the LTGM-NR simple and its mechanisms straightforward. The public
investment assumption stems from our application to resource-rich economies, where public investment is
often funded by commodity revenues. The determinants of investment vary across the LTGM-NR Default
and External-Balance submodels, which are discussed further below.
We also need to determine the allocation of aggregate investment across the non-resource and different
resource industries. Again, to keep the model simple, this is done via a rule of thumb where investment is
allocated across the different activities proportionally to (i) the marginal efficiency of capital and (ii) the
sector’s relative size (in terms of capital shares), as below:
µ
iti K ti−1 MRPK ti
= , for i ∈ {1, …, N } (10)
it K t −1 MRPK tDS
1/ µ
N K j
= ∑ t −1 ( MRPK tj )
DS µ
MRPK t (12)
j =0 K t −1
where MRPK tj denotes the marginal revenue product of capital (the dollar value of the marginal product
of capital) in activity j, 1 − g0 ≡ 1 − β, and MRPK tDS is a Dixit-Stiglitz (DS) aggregator of the MRPK across
all activities.14 The aggregator weights each activity by their capital shares, K tj−1 / K t −1.
While the rule of thumb is not derived from an optimizing framework, it is constructed to allocate invest-
ment to more efficient and larger industries (as would be the case in an optimizing framework) and has two
other appealing properties. First, across same-size industries, if activity i is 1% more efficient than activity j,
it receives m% more investment (i.e., if K ti −1 = K tj−1 → ln(iti / itj ) = µ ln( MRPK ti / MRPK tj )). Second, invest-
ment is allocated so that capital shares remain constant across sectors with the same marginal efficiency of
capital (i.e., if MRPK ti = MRPK tj → K ti / K tj = K ti −1 / K tj−1). Moreover, this rule of thumb is simple enough
to be solved in a spreadsheet. We usually calibrate m = 1.
14
ote that equation (10) does not apply for the non-resource sector (0) but equations (11) and (12) do. Investment in the non-
N
resource sector is determined residually as I t0 = I t − ∑iN=1 I ti . However, the normalization of equation (10) by MRPK tDS ensures
that it also holds for the non-resource sector.
107
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
where z tR − z tR are cyclical government resource revenues (as a share GDI)—i.e., the deviation of actual
resource revenues z tR from their “structural” or long-run values z tR (discussed below). The parameter q is the
marginal propensity to invest resource revenues: the fraction of cyclical resource revenues that is invested
each period.15 The variable it g is the exogenous baseline public investment—i.e., public investment as a
share of GDI that prevails in the absence of shocks (zero cyclical revenues). The term ε t ≡ − itg (z tR − z tR ) / τ R
is a technical adjustment to prevent double counting, as increases in commodity production will raise real
GDI, and hence itg through the constant term i g . εt is usually quantitatively small.
Government resource revenues (as a share of GDI), z tR, is obtained from a flat tax rate tR applied to resource
GDI, y tR ,16
z tR = τ R y tR (14)
The structural revenue, z tR, is based on structural prices, pti , and output, Qti :
N (15)
z tR = τ R ∑ pti Qti
i =1
The purpose of defining a structural revenue is to smooth out transitory fluctuations in actual revenues.
As discussed in section 3, structural prices are usually set at their (perceived) long-term levels. When pro-
duction is not the focus of the analysis, to keep the model simple, we set structural production equal to
actual production or a moving average. However, the LTGM-NR toolkit provides other specifications, such
as using baseline as reference production.17
Fiscal rules. The marginal propensity to invest, q, captures the pro-cyclicality of fiscal policy. The user
can choose any value of q, although more common values range between 0 and 1. This range nests three
popular fiscal rules:
• q = 0 captures a SSR (Structural Surplus Rule),
18
as cyclical resource revenues are saved (when prices are
high) and do not affect public investment.
• q = q hist captures a BBR (Balanced Budget Rule), where q hist is the historical fraction of the expenditure
that is spent on public investment. In this case, when the cyclical resource revenue increases by one
dollar, all windfall is spent, but only the fraction q hist in extra spending is channeled to investment (the
remaining 1 − q hist falling on government consumption).
• When q = 1, all cyclical resource revenue is spent, but it falls only on public investment, as prescribed
under a BBR-HR (Balanced Budget—Hartwick Rule).
15
The LTGM-NR spreadsheet also allows the parameter q to vary over time.
16
apturing, for example, royalties from the concessions of exploration of natural resources, tax-receipts from private extractive
C
enterprises, and profits from state-owned companies.
17
n equilibrium is defined as a collection of 15 endogenous trajectories {Yt0 , Qti , Rti , K tj , K t , RGDPt , Yt , it , it0 , iti , MRPK tj , MRPK tDS }
A
{itg , z tR , z tR } where j ∈ {0,1,…,N} with each endogenous variable specified as a function of the exogenous paths
{g t , g t , g tN , g tω , g t , Dti , pti , ι t p , ι t g , pti , Qti } and initial conditions {GDP0 , GDP0j , K 0 , K 0j , R0i , p0i , N 0 , ω 0 , 0 } that satisfy equations
Aj h
108
The Long Term Growth Model
The external sector. A key equation in this submodel is the constraint which imposes that aggregate invest-
ment must be equal to domestic savings less the current account balance (CAB),
it = st p + stg − cabt (16)
where st p and stg denote private and public savings, respectively, and cabt is the current account balance,
all expressed as a share of GDI. Public savings are endogenously determined by the fiscal rule in place
(details below), and private savings are assumed to be an exogenous share of GDI. The CAB is financed by
(exogenous) foreign direct investment (FDI) or newly created external debt (we abstract from other forms
of portfolio investment, as they are less common in developing countries):
where fdi t denotes FDI in period t, dt is the outstanding stock of external debt at the end of in period t,
both expressed as a share of GDI, and g tY is the net annual growth rate of GDI in period t. Equation (18)
decomposes external debt into private and public, dtp and dtg , respectively.
The relationship between the CAB and fiscal policy is an active debate in the literature and is likely to change
substantially from country to country.19 Much of this literature is about the response of private savings to
various shocks (e.g., Loayza, Schmidt-Hebel, and Serven 2000), though in our model we assume private
savings are simply a fixed share of GDI. In countries with open capital accounts, an increase in public
deficits can be funded by foreign savings—a larger current account deficit, resulting in what is known as the
“twin deficits.”20 In contrast, if the current account is relatively fixed as a share of GDI—for example, due to
thin capital markets or capital controls—then an increase in public savings could free up financial resources
for private investment. Ultimately, we let users choose the degree of crowding in of private investment via
a parameter l:
p dtp−1 dtg−1
dt − = −λ dtg − + dt p (19)
1 + gY 1 + gY
Private − sector deficit Fiscal deficit
Where dt p is the exogenous component of private external debt. Equation (19) implies that a one-dollar
fall in public net borrowing crowds in l dollars of private investment (funded by private net borrowing).21
The public sector. The public sector in the External Balance submodel is also more realistic than that in
the Default model. The government collects shares tR and t0 of the resource and non-resource sectors,
respectively (equations (20) and (21)). Total revenue is the sum of resource and non-resource revenue
(equation (22)). Revenues are used to finance a stream of public expenditure, which is decomposed into
government consumption (c tg )—which does not affect growth—and public investment (itg ) (equation (23)).
19
S ome empirical studies find that higher budget deficits lead to higher current account deficits; others show evidence of
the opposite or no significant impact. For a literature review on this subject, see Bussiere, Fratzscher, and Muller (2005) or
Cavallo (2005).
20
bbas et al. (2011) find that a one percentage point of GDP improvement in the fiscal balance is associated with one-third
A
percentage point improvement in the current account, though it is unclear how much of this adjustment is through private
savings.
dp
21
Note that itp = st p + fdι t + dtp − t −1 , where st p and fdι t are exogenous. In this case, a fall in the fiscal deficit must be
1 + gY
matched by a one-to-one increase in private investment on the left side.
109
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
We assume that the split of expenditure between consumption and investment is exogenous and calibrated
to match the historical share of public investment in expenditure (see equation (24)):
[Non-resource revenue]: z t0 = τ 0 y t0 (20)
where ηt is the share of expenditure falling on public investment (the remaining 1 − ηt on government
consumption).
The primary balance is the difference between revenues and non-interest expenditure and represents
the government’s net borrowing or net lending, excluding interest payments on the outstanding debt
(equation (25)). Public savings is defined as revenues less government consumption and represents the
amount of resources generated by the government to finance public investment or to pay off the external
public debt (equation (26)). Equation (27) describes the evolution of public external debt (as a share of
GDI). Each period, the debt grows at the gross rate (1 + rt −1 ) / (1 + g tY ), due to payments on the principal and
interest on the outstanding bonds, but decreases one-to-one with the primary balance,
[Primary balance]: bt = zt − expt (25)
1 + rt −1 g
[Public debt]: dtg = dt −1 − bt (27)
1+ gt
Y
where y is the debt-elasticity of the interest-rate spread, and d is the long-run external debt to GDI ratio.22
If dt−1 ≤ d, the government can issue debt at the world interest rate, rW. If dt−1 > d, an increase in debt of
1 percent of GDI leads to y percentage points increase in the country spread.
Fiscal rules. As in the Default submodel, a fiscal rule determines both the timing and composition of
government expenditure. The LTGM-NR External Balance allows for four types of rules: BBR, BBR-HR,
SSR, and SSR-HR (see Table 4.1), up from three types of rules in the Default submodel (where there is
no SSR-HR). The External-Balance submodel defines the timing aspect of fiscal rules in terms of how the
primary balance evolves.
22
For simplicity, the parameter d is usually set to zero or d0 but the user can choose other values.
110
The Long Term Growth Model
The BBR fixes the headline primary balance as a share of GDI at a target bt (usually fixed but could vary over
time exogenously) (see top line of equation (29)). This policy leads to pro-cyclical spending: a one-dollar
increase (fall) in resource revenues leads to (almost) exactly one-dollar increase (fall) in expenditure.
The SSR mitigates pro-cyclicality by fixing the structural primary balance at target b t . The structural
primary balance adjusts for the commodity cycle so that the primary balance tends to increase (decrease)
in periods of high (low) commodity prices.
More specifically, the structural primary balance is computed
based on structural resource revenues, bt = z t − expt , where the structural revenue, z t , is defined as in the
Default model (equation (15)). The following equation summarizes the fiscal target under BBRs and SSRs:
BBR : bt = bt + e t
[Fiscal rule] (29)
SSR : bt = b t + e t
where e t = φ (dtg−1 − d g ) adjusts the target by a fraction f of the deviation of the public debt-to-GDI ratio
from its long-run level, dg, thus ensuring debt sustainability. The parameter f ensures the stability of the
public debt and controls its volatility.23
The BBR and SSR can either keep the composition of spending constant or try to increase investment as
in table 4.1. As in the Default submodel, the high-investment rule is called a Hartwick rule (HR), though
its application here is more complicated and closer to how it is applied in practice. The principle behind
the HR is to prevent extra revenues earned from exhaustible natural resource from being used to finance
government consumption. Accordingly, under an HR, all cyclical resource revenue must be invested either
in physical or financial assets.24 The rule is implemented by adding the following inequality to the model:
this inequality states that the Sustainable Budget Index (SBI), the ratio of government consumption to
non-resource revenues, must be equal or lower than an exogenously determined threshold SBI t (typically
set to one for all t). An SBIt > 1 means that government consumption is being financed at least partially by
resource revenues. An SBIt < 1 means that resource revenues are being invested either in physical or financial
assets, while consumption is being financed only from non-resource revenues. Capping the SBIt to one
ensures that assets are being preserved (for a detailed discussion, see Lange and Wright 2004).25
The standard SBI rule (with SBI t = 1) works well for governments with moderate dependence on resource
revenues but might be too restrictive for countries where resource revenues represent a large part of the
budget. For example, Angola’s fiscal oil revenues account for more than 80 percent of total revenues. In this
case, it is inevitable that oil revenues are partially consumed to run basic functions of the government. For
that reason, the user of the LTGM-NR can choose any positive value for SBI t . A possibility is to set SBI t
to c 0g / z 00 implying that the SBIt cannot increase over time (as in section 4.B).26 Although this configuration
does not match perfectly the asset-preservation principle, it prevents the government from increasing
consumption in times of high resource revenues.
23
Condition f > (1 + rW)/(1 + gY) ensures that the debt-to-GDI ratio fluctuates within bounds around the long-run level. In the
limit f → ∞ the fiscal rule collapses to a debt-rule: dtg = d g .
24
S ome countries consider spending on education and health as investment in human capital, so the HR would not constrain
this type of expenditure.
25
otswana is the most celebrated country to incorporate the SBI rule in its fiscal framework for diamond revenues
B
(AfDB 2016).
26
Another possible application is to set SBI t to match historical SBI values.
111
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
On the surface, it seems that the HR has no effect when coupled with an SSR, as this rule already saves most
of the transitory windfalls in the short run. However, the HR prevents the government from increasing
consumption over time as the financial returns on the invested assets start to improve the fiscal budget.27
27
27
n equilibrium in the External-Balance submodel is defined as a collection of 12 endogenous trajectories
A
{Yt0 , Qti , Rti , K tj , K t , RGDPt , Yt , it , it0 , iti , MRPK tj , MRPK tDS } plus 14 endogenous variables (that are specific to this
p g p g g
submodel) {it , st , cabt , dt , dt , dt , z t , z t , z t , expt , c t , i , bt , rt } where j ∈ {0,1,…,N} with each endogenous variable specified
0 R g
as a function of the exogenous paths {g t , g t , g t , g tω , g t , Dti , pti , pti , Qti } and { st p , fdi t ,ηt , bt } as well as initial conditions
Aj h N
{GDP0 , GDP0j , K 0 , K 0j , R0i , p0i , N 0 , ω 0 , 0 , d0p , d0g } that satisfy equations (1)–(12) and equations (16)–(29) for every period t. For
HRs, the SBI inequality must also hold for a specified path SBI t at all periods.
28
e can map parameter gi into the measure of natural resource rents from GTAP as it quantifies the total income that can be
W
generated from the extraction of natural resources, less the cost of extraction, including the return on capital employed on the
extractive activity.
112
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 4.2: Baseline Setup of the LTGM-NR: selected parameters, initial conditions, and
trajectories of exogenous variables (Symbol + indicates the parameter is taken from
the standard LTGM)
113
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
of public investment to total expenditure over 2000–2019, taken from the IMF-World Economic Outlook
(WEO) and the Investment and Capital Stock Dataset provided by the IMF Fiscal Affairs Department
(IMF-FAD).
The External-Balance model requires five additional parameters: the private investment crowd-in param-
eter l, the average tax rate on the non-resource economy τ0, the debt-elastic interest spread y, the world
real interest rate rW, and how the budget balance responds to debt f. l measures the response of private
investment to the fiscal balance (equation (19)). Its default value is set to 0.15 (a one-dollar increase in net
government borrowing crowds in 15 cents of private investment) based on the average of estimates for
both industrial and less developed countries (see Chinn, Eichengreen, and Ito 2011). τ0 is set to match the
average ratio of non-resource revenue to non-resource GDP over 2000 (or most recent historical average).
Non-resource revenue is calculated as the difference between total revenue and resource revenue, provided
by IMF-WEO and IMF-WCE, respectively.29 Likewise, non-resource GDP is computed as the difference
between GDP and resource GDP. The baseline world annual real interest rate, rW, is set to 2 percent, which
is in line with the 10-year inflation-indexed US Treasury bond yields averaged over 2000–2019 from the
St Louis Federal Reserve Bank Economic Data (Series: WLTIIT).
The baseline debt elasticity of the interest spread is set to y = 0.1, which implies that a 10 percent of GDI
increase in the external debt leads to a one percentage point increase in the country’s interest rate.30 Finally,
we set f = 0.05, which is sufficient to prevent any explosive paths for public debt as f > rW.
Initial conditions. GDP for 2020 is taken from World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WB-WDI),
in constant 2010 U.S. dollars.31 In the absence of a data set containing comprehensive information on GDP
at the industry level for several commodity exporting countries, we proxy GDP in resource industry i
by exports of the resource good i. More specifically, GDP in industry i is set to match the average value
of exports as a share of GDP.32 The export data are taken from the UN-Comtrade Database (UN-CT),
which provides information on export value for all 11 commodities and all 56 countries pre-loaded in the
LTGM-NR, with a time series that usually starts in 2002.33
29
s a complementary data set for government revenues (total, resource, and non-resource), we use ICTD/UN-WIDER
A
Government Revenue Dataset (UN-GRD).
30
The range of estimates for y in literature varies widely across countries and papers. For example, while Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe
(2003) set y = 0.001 to match the volatility of the observed current-account-to-GDP ratio for Canada, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe
(2016) estimate y = 1 for Argentina. We adopt y = 1 as a compromise between these two seemingly extreme estimates.
31
LTGM-NR spreadsheet since updated to constant 2015 US dollars.
32
Initial GDP in industry i is computed as a share of total 2020 GDP. The default method is to use average value of exports in
industry i as a share of GDP since 2000. The following expression describes how the default initial real GDP in industry i is
computed:
i
GDP2020
1
= ∑
( p2010
i
/ pti ) × ExportsiUNCT
,t
× GDP2020
WDI
t ≥ 2000 WDI
N GDPt
average share of GDP in industry i since 2000
i
where pt is the real price (2010 U.S. dollars) of resource good i in period t taken from the World Bank Commodity Markets
Outlook. ExportsiUNCT
,t is exports value (current U.S. dollars) of resource good i in period t, and GDPtWDI is real GDP in period t
As ExportsiUNCT
,t is measured in current U.S. dollars, it is deflated by pti / p2010
i
.
33
Alternatively, we provide a measure of GDP in industry i derived directly from production data,
1 i
p2010 QiBP /USGS
i
GDP2020 = ∑ ,t
× GDP2020
WDI
BP /USGS
where Q i ,t is the estimated production of resource good i in period t. This information is collected from annual reports
by a BP-Energy Dataset for energy goods (oil, natural gas, and coal) and from the U.S. Geological Survey for mining goods
(cooper, gold, iron, etc.).
114
The Long Term Growth Model
As in the standard LTGM, the initial stock of capital-to-GDP ratio is calculated using the most recent
observation from PWT 10 (although earlier versions of PWT are also available).34 The initial capital stock
is split across activities to equalize the initial marginal revenue product of capital across j ∈ {0,…N}.35
Information on the initial stock of reserves in industry i is taken from the BP-Energy Dataset for oil,
natural gas, and coal, and from the U.S. Geological Survey Database (USGS) for mining industries, such
as copper, gold, and iron. As a stock variable, initial reserves are set to match the most recent observation
(usually 2017).
The External-Balance Model also requires initial public and private external debt. Reliable data on the
decomposition of external debt into private and public debt are often unavailable for developing commod-
ity exporting countries. Hence, in the baseline calibration, we assume that all initial external debt is public,
and initial private external debt is zero. This is obviously an extreme assumption, and country-specific data
should be used where available. We calibrate public external debt equal to the most recent observation on
total external debt taken from WB-WDI.
Trajectory of exogenous variables. The LTGM-NR requires the trajectories of a number of exogenous vari-
ables from 2021 until 2050. The key assumption of baseline simulations is that recent trends will continue in
the long term. In this case, we assume that historical averages (such as 2000–2019) will continue until 2050.
The first assumptions are the paths for actual and structural commodity prices. A structural price should
reflect its perceived long-term value, so the user could use a long historical average or a proper estimate of
the long-run price. For example, in section 4, we set the structural price of oil to US$50/barrel, which is the
estimated unconditional mean of oil prices from 1960 to 2020. The actual path of commodity prices can
be set to any value. Again, in section 4, we analyze the consequences of an increase in oil prices from US$50
to US$80/barrel. The default data source for commodity prices is the World Bank’s Commodities Prices
Dataset (WB-CPD–The Pink Sheet), although other sources are available (e.g., USGS and BP-Energy). Also,
the structural production of resources is usually assumed to follow the N-year moving average of actual
production.
Discoveries of natural resources are calibrated using data on annual production and reserves of the resource
good i, taken from BP-Energy (for energy industries) and the USGS (for mining). The time series of discov-
eries of good i in period t is computed as the change in reserves from period t − 1 to t plus production in
period t (as in equation (3)). In the baseline, the trajectory of discoveries of good i from 2020 to 2050 can be
set to match the historical average over the past 20 years. Naturally, predicting future discoveries of natural
resources is no trivial task, and using historical averages can be misleading. In this case, country-specific
data based on experts’ knowledge should be used when available.
The LTGM-NR requires paths for future TFP growth in each sector and industry. TFP data at the industry
level are usually unavailable for most developing countries. A simple approach is to assume that TFP
growth is homogenous across sectors. In this case, we can set TFP growth in each sector/industry equal
34
I n PWT 10 the capital-to-output ratio is computed as rnna/rgdpna, but in some earlier version (e.g. PWT 8.1) is calculated as
rkna/rgdpna.
35
More specifically, the initial capital stock in activity j must satisfy the following N + 1 equations,
(1 − γ j )GDI 2020
j
j
KY2020 = for j = 0,…, N
+ ∑ (1 − γ i )GDI 2020
N
(1 − β )GDP2020
0 i
i =1
j
where GDI 2020 ≡ ( ptj / p2010
j i
)GDP2020 denotes real GDI in activity j, year t; and g0 = β
115
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
to the average aggregate TFP growth over 2000–2019, from PWT 10. When available, the user should use
information on sectoral TFP growth.36
In the Default submodel, private and public sector investment data are taken from IMF-FAD, which decom-
poses total investment into private and public from 1960 to 2017. The paths for private investment, itp , and
the exogenous component of public investment, itg , are set equal their historical averages over 2000-2017,
reflecting “business as usual” investment rates.
In the External Balance submodel, private savings, st p, are set to match the observed average of private
savings (% of GDP) in 2000-2019, computed using data from the IMF-WEO and IMF-FAD. Similarly, the
share of public investment in total expenditure, ηt , is set to match the average ratio of public investment
to total expenditure over 2000–2017 (also IMF-WEO and IMF-FAD). For simplicity, the default fiscal
rule is the BBR-Default, with a zero target for the primary balance (bt = 0) and stable external public debt
(d g = d2020
g
), though the user can refer to the IMF-FAD for actual targets for the fiscal balance and debt in
specific countries. Finally, the exogenous component of the private debt, dt p is set to zero by default.
36
or example, the Chilean 2016 Annual Report of the National Productivity Commission documents a large heterogeneity of
F
TFP growth across the copper and non-copper sectors over 2000–2015, with an average fall of 1.0 percent in the copper sector
and average growth of 1.4 percent in the non-copper sector.
37
ore specifically, we want to calibrate oil income as a share of GDI consistently with the data collected in terms of GDP.
M
Angola’s oil exports at 2010 prices (~$80) averaged 50 percent of GDP over 2007–2015. To transform that information into oil
income as a share of GDI, we need to adjust both the numerator (oil exports at 2010 prices) and the denominator (real GDP).
First, we scale the numerator by 0.625 (50/80) to express oil income in 2020 oil prices ($50). Second, we compute real GDI in
2020 by scaling real GDP by 0.8 (i.e.,1 + (P2020
oil oil
/ P2010 − 1) × share of oil in 2020 GDP ≈ 1 − 0.4 × 0.5) . That is:
116
The Long Term Growth Model
for Angola, we use a cross-country average to calibrate the share of oil rents. More specifically, we set g oil
to 1/3 to match the average share of oil rents across large oil exporters, reported by GTAP (see Appendix
Figure 1 for details).
The initial capital-to-GDP ratio is set to 2.0, which is a compromise between PWT 8 (1.7 for 2011) and the
World Bank’s Macro-Fiscal Model Database (2.2 for 2011).38 The initial oil reserves are set to 9.5 billion of
barrels to match the latest estimates for Angola from BP-Energy.
Although PWT reports TFP data for Angola, identifying trend TFP growth is challenging due to the coun-
try’s extremely volatile business cycle. Instead, we set non-oil TFP growth to 1 percent to match the average
TFP growth in lower-middle-income countries over 2000–2019. The growth rate of oil TFP is set to zero,
which is the average TFP growth in large oil exporters over the past two decades (for details, see appendix,
figure 2).
Annual human capital growth is set to 0.7 percent, which was the average growth rate in Angola over
2000–2019 (PWT 10). Moreover, we incorporate the UN’s forecast of demographic trends for Angola,
which suggests that population growth will fall from about 3 percent in 2020 to 2 percent by 2050. The
working-age population is predicted to rise from 52 percent of total population in 2020 to 58 percent in
2050. Moreover, based on recent trends, the labor force participation rate is assumed to remain constant at
around 80 percent of the working-age population until 2050 (WB-WDI).
We set the government share in the oil sector tR = 0.7, which is the historical average of oil revenues (as a
share of oil GDP) in Angola over 2001–2013 (IMF-WEC, most recent data available). Private investment
is set to 20 percent of GDP to match the average observed in 2000–2017 (IMF-FAD). Due to exceptionally
large investments in energy infrastructure, public investment has been historically very high in Angola
(above 10 percent of GDP), but is expected to fall significantly over time, especially due to the likely decline
in oil revenues. Accordingly, we assume that public investment falls from 6 percent of GDI in 2023 to
2 percent by 2050. The marginal propensity to spend under the BBR is set to qBBR = 0.2, as public investment
averaged 20 percent of total government expenditure from 2000 to 2017 (IMF-FAD) (recall qSSR = 0.2 and
qHR = 1).
Finally, in the baseline we set the actual and structural price of oil to US$50 per barrel, which is the estimated
unconditional mean estimated with data since 1960 (see appendix, figure 5 for details for details). Also, we
assume discoveries of 400 million barrels of oil per year in the baseline, equal to the 25th percentile over
1990–2017 (BP-Energy data, see Figure 4.6, panel a).
Calibration to Angola (External-Balance submodel). For the External-Balance submodel, we set the
private savings rate and FDI to 19 and 1 percent of GDP, respectively, similar to their averages over the past
20 years. The public investment share in expenditure is set ht = 0.2 until 2050 (also the historical average).
Finally, we assume that bt = 0, which means a balanced budget for the BBR and a structural balance for the
SSR. We assume the default private investment crowd-in parameter l = 0.15 (Chinn and Ito 2011). For
more details of the calibration of the External-Balance submodel refer to appendix, table 4.
38
e opted to use PWT 8 and the Macro-Fiscal Model Database for 2011 because the new methodology adopted by PWT 9
W
and PWT 10 implies extremely high capital-to-GDP ratios for Angola. For example, PWT 10 reports a capital-to-GDP ratio
of 6 in 2019. This ratio would lead to a remarkably low marginal product of capital in Angola, which is inconsistent with the
country’s current level of development.
117
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Table 4.3: Baseline Calibration to Angola (Default model): selected parameters, initial
conditions, and trajectories of exogenous variables
SSR (q = 0); HR (q = 1)
Sectoral investment elasticity (m) 1 Assumption
B. Initial conditions
Real GDP per capita US$2,890* WB-WDI 2020
Exports of oil (I = 1) 50.8% of GDP UN-CT 2007–2015 average
Capital to GDP ratio: 2 PWT/MFMod 2011
Non-oil sector 1 Endogenous Equalize initial MRPKs
Oil sector 1 Endogenous Equalize initial MRPKs
Reserves of oil 9.5 Bi/barrels BP-Energy 2017
Participation rate, % of working-age population
male/female 80.2 / 76.4 WB-WDI 2017
Base year for oil prices 2010 User choice
Initial year of simulation 2020 User choice
C. Trajectory of exogenous variables, 2023–2050
Price of oil US$50/barrels World Bank Estimated mean 1960–2019
Private investment 20% of GDI IMF-FAD 2000-2017 average
TFP growth, non-oil sector 1% PWT 10 Median of LMCs, 2000–2019
TFP growth, oil sector 0% PWT 10 Median oil exporters, 2000–2019
Human capital growth 0.7% PWT 10 2000–2019 average
Oil Discoveries
Baseline & Discovery Shock 400m bbl/year BP-Energy 25th percentile 1990-2017
Price shock Endogenous** Assumption
Demographics:
Population growth 3.4→2.3% ILO Forecast for 2023–2050
Working-age population 51→59% pop. ILO Forecast for 2023–2050
Population, male 49.1% of pop. ILO Forecast for 2023–2050
Participation rate (M & F) ≈0 growth WB-WDI 2000–2019 average
Note: *Real 2010 US dollars. **Discoveries are set to keep reserves constant in per worker terms.
118
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 4.1: LTGM Simulation: Baseline GDP Per Capita Growth in Angola: annual growth rate,
percentage
8
Covid-19 Medium- and long-term simulation
pandemic
6
World Bank
2000s average WDI data
4
2%
2 Baseline (LTGM-NR)
2000–2019 average 1.5%
Percent
-2
-4
-8
2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
IMF forecast (WEO) World Bank WDI data Baseline (LTGM–NR)
Note: The solid orange line is a five-year moving average of GDP per capita growth in Angola (World Bank WDI).
39
All monetary values are expressed in constant 2010 U.S. dollars.
119
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Growth decomposition. To shed light on the U-shaped dynamics of baseline growth, Figure 4.2 d ecomposes
the contribution of each macro variable for GDP per capita growth in 2023 (initial year of the simulation),
2035 (minimum point for growth), and 2050 (last year).40 The decomposition shows that the drivers of
growth change over time. In 2023, growth is mainly driven by capital accumulation, with total investment
generating 3.4 percentage points (ppts) of growth. High population growth and depleting reserves of oil
push growth down by 2.3 and 0.5ppts, respectively. Non-oil TFP and human capital have only a moderate
contribution to growth of 0.7ppts.
The decomposition for 2035 suggests that the decline in the oil sector is the main reason for the 2023–2035
slowdown—the combined contribution to growth from oil investment and oil reserves falls from +1.5ppts
in 2023 to –0.1ppts in 2035. Appendix, figure 3 shows that while GDP per capita grows steadily at 3 percent
in the non-oil sector, it falls sharply in the oil sector (panel b). This decline is mainly driven by depleting
oil reserves, projected to halve by 2035 (panel c). Depleting oil reserves reduces oil output directly but also
disincentivizes investment in the sector, reinforcing the initial contraction (panel d).
Figure 4.2: Year-by-Year Decomposition of Baseline GDP Per Capita Growth: contribution of each
macro variable to growth, percentage points
2.0 0.7
3 Working-age population
2.2 Population growth
2 1.8 2%
Human capital growth
1.4 0.8
1.5 Non-oil TFP growth
1 0.9
0.6 Non-oil investment
0.5
0.2 0.3 0.4 Oil reserves
0
Oil investment
–1.2 Baseline GDP PC growth
–1 –1.8
–2.3 –0.5
–2
–0.8
–0.5
–3
2023 2035 2050
40
The growth decomposition captures the proximate determinants of growth only—for example, the induced effect of TFP on
investment is attributed to the latter, not the former. It is carried out period-by-period by a linear approximation of the effect
of each variable on GDP per capita, as in the following expression: Contribution of X to GDP per capita growth in t
For example, GDP per capita in Angola is given by DPPC t = GDPPC t0 + GDPPC toil = At0 (ht ω tt N t )β (K t0−1 )1− β / N t + p0oil Qtoil / N t .
In this case, the contribution of population growth to GDP per capita growth in period t is given by the following simple
∂ GDPPC t GDPt0 GDPtoil ∆N t GDPt0
expression: N ∆N t = − (1 − β ) −1 = − 1 − β %∆N t
GDPt GDPt GDPt N t GDPt
120
The Long Term Growth Model
Finally, the decomposition shows that the recovery after 2035 is explained by an improvement in demo-
graphic trends and a switch of the economy toward the non-oil sector, which has better fundamentals. More
specifically, population growth declines substantially, mitigating the negative impact on per capita growth
to –1.2ppts (up from –1.8ppts in 2035). In addition, the depletion of reserves (and lack of oil productivity
growth) leads gross investment in the oil sector to fall to nearly zero in the long term. As a result, investment
in the non-oil sector increases substantially over time, accounting for 2.2ppts of growth in 2050 (versus
1.4ppts in 2023). Moreover, as the non-oil sector accounts for an increasingly large share of the economy,
non-oil TFP and human capital increase their contribution to growth: in 2050, they jointly generate 1.3ppts
of growth (up from 0.7ppts in 2023).
LTGM-NR versus standard LTGM. To illustrate the importance of accounting for sectoral heterogeneity
in large resource-rich countries, we compare the baseline growth path implied by the LTGM-NR with
the standard “one-sector” LTGM. We produce a naïve calibration of the standard LTGM to be consistent
with the LTGM-NR at the aggregate level. Except for the labor share and TFP growth, which are discussed
below, the calibration of the two models is essentially the same (see appendix, table 5 for a full description).
It should be noted, however, that an adjusted calibration of the standard LTGM tracks growth very well in
the non-resource sector from the LTGM-NR.41
Figure 4.3 shows a large difference between the two models, with the naïve calibration of the standard
LTGM (solid black line) being substantially more optimistic than the NR extension (green line with crosses).
Figure 4.3: Baseline Growth Simulation: LTGM-NR Versus Standard LTGM (naïve calibration):
GDP per capita, Percent annual growth rate
4.3
Baseline (Standard LTGM)
4
3.65 Residual growth
1
Baseline (LTGM – NR)
Covid-19
Medium/long-term forecasts
0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Baseline A = Baseline + constant reserves
B = A + low labor share C = B + high oil TFP growth
Notes: Counterfactual A is equal to baseline but with reserves of oil constant over time in per worker terms. Counterfactual B is equal to A but
with a labor share of 0.34. Counterfactual C is equal to B but with 1 percent oil TFP growth.
41
The only adjustment required is to scale up the labor share in the standard LTGM to β = β PWT × GDPt /GDPt0 . In this case, the
standard LTGM captures almost perfectly non-oil growth in the LTGM-NR (see appendix, figure 6).
121
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Baseline GDP per capita growth under the standard LTGM starts at 3.7 percent in 2023 and accelerates to
4.3 by 2050. That speedy growth trajectory is in sharp contrast with the IMF medium-term projections or
the recent growth history in Angola.42
A combination of three factors explains the “excess” growth implied by the standard LTGM.43 First, and
quantitatively the most important, the standard LTGM does not account for depleting oil reserves. To assess
the magnitude of this effect, we run counterfactual “A” with the baseline LTGM-NR but keeping reserves
of oil constant over time.44 The vertical distance between the baseline and counterfactual A shows the
excess growth generated by not accounting for depleting reserves. The extra growth averages 1.1ppts over
2023–2050 but shrinks over time as the oil sector becomes less important as a share of GDP (see appendix,
table 3 for details).
Second, the Standard LTGM naïve calibration distorts the impact of growth fundamentals by ignoring the
heterogeneity in the labor share across sectors. In the standard LTGM, we set β = 0.34 to match the labor
compensation share in total income from PWT. This particularly low aggregate labor share is the outcome
of an economy highly dependent on oil, which is typically a capital-intensive industry.45 The LTGM-NR
specification is more suitable for large oil producers as it allows the user to choose the labor share specific
to the non-oil sector. Recall that in the baseline we set β = 0.56, which is a more conventional value for this
parameter—see appendix, figure 4—but also consistent with the aggregate labor share from PWT (0.56 x
initial non-oil share in GDI = 0.34).
The “distorted” low labor share in the naïve calibration of the standard LTGM boosts the effect of invest-
ment in physical capital on growth. As physical capital is reproducible, this makes growth much easier. In
the limit where the labor share is zero, the standard LTGM becomes an “AK” model that delivers perpetual
endogenous growth. To assess the net effect of the low labor share on growth, we run counterfactual B:
equals counterfactual A (baseline + constant reserves) but with the labor share lowered to 0.34 (as in the
standard LTGM). Not surprisingly, as investment is the main driver in Angola, the net effect is positive and
substantial: the distorted labor share leads to an extra 0.5ppts of growth on average (as shown by the vertical
distance between the dotted and dashed lines).
Third, in the naïve calibration of the standard LTGM we set aggregate TFP growth to 1 percent to match the
average in lower-middle-income countries over the past two decades. However, there is large heterogeneity
in TFP growth across sectors. Recall that in the LTGM-NR we set TFP growth in the non-oil sector to
1 percent but, based on evidence from large oil exporters, we assume no TFP gains in the oil sector (see
appendix, figure 2). To assess the effect of overestimated TFP growth rates, we run counterfactual D: equals
counterfactual C (baseline with constant reserves and low labor share) but with 1 percent oil TFP growth,
so aggregate TFP is also 1 percent, as in the standard LTGM. The excessive TFP growth leads to an extra
0.6ppts of growth on average over 2023–2050.
42
lthough Angola reported comparably high growth rates in the 2000s, this growth was related to developments in the oil
A
sector, which is a channel not built-in the standard LTGM. For more details of baseline growth in the standard LTGM, see a
growth decomposition in appendix, figure 7.
43
he remaining gap between the models is related to factors that are difficult to shut down for analytical purposes, such as the
T
structural differences between the production functions.
44
In fact, we keep reserves of oil constant in per worker terms, which implies that labor productivity does not fall over time due
to depleting oil reserves.
45
ppendix Figure 4 shows that Angola reported the lowest average labor share over 2000–2019 among LMCs (PWT 10). It also
A
shows that large oil exporters tend to have low labor shares, which is in line with the empirical evidence of low labor shares in
resource industries (see Lebdioui 2021).
122
The Long Term Growth Model
46
hese assumptions are based on the estimated forecast distribution of oil prices, using the World Bank’s Commodity Markets
T
Outlook data from 1960 to 2019. The price of US$80 is the 75th percentile of the distribution and US$50 is the unconditional
mean. See appendix, figure 5 for details.
47
Note that in reality, large movements in aggregate demand associated with the commodity price shock will cause disruption to
123
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Figure 4.4: The Effects of Oil Price Shocks in Angola: Comparison between different fiscal rules
and LTGM-NR models (incremental = scenario – baseline)
a. Price of oil, Real 2010 U.S. dollars/barrel b. Incremental GDI, Percent of baseline GDI
90 35
80
30
70
25
60
50 20
%
%
40 15
30
10
20
10 5
0 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Baseline Scenario
c. Incremental GDP, Percent of baseline GDP d. Incremental GDP per capita, Annual growth rate
25 5
4
20
3
15
2
%
%
10
1
5
0
0 -1
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
20 9
8
15 7
6
5
10
%
4
3
5 2
1
0 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
124
The Long Term Growth Model
generate a larger increase in GDP are the ones with the higher GDI in panel b: BBR-HR in both models,
with peak GDP about 20–25ppts above the baseline in 2035 (which is five years after the peak oil price).
In contrast, the BBR and SSR have a smaller boost to GDP, with a peak of 5–10ppts above the baseline in
2035. The SSR-HR in the Extended Balance submodel generates a boost to GDP that is more sustainable
and lasts well beyond the duration of the price cycle. Moreover, the SSR-HR outperforms the BBR-HR
(Default model) in the long run.
While the different rules do have a differential effect on GDP growth rates, it is perhaps less than might
be expected (see Figure 4.4, panel d). The peak increment to real GDP growth (relative to the baseline)
is about 5ppts in 2030 in the BBR-HR (for both submodels). In contrast, the other rules lead to a peak
increase in GDP growth of only about 1–2 ppts in 2030—despite a large increase in government revenue
(discussed below). Perhaps surprisingly, the increment to real GDP growth continues to be positive as oil
prices fall over 2030–2035, and only turns negative after 2035. For the SSR-HR, incremental GDP growth
remains positive until 2042.48 Another surprising result is that the BBR and SSR yield almost exactly the
same growth path in the External-Balance submodel. As we will discuss below, under this calibration with
h = 0.2 and l = 0.15 it does not make a large difference if oil revenues are saved or spent under these
two rules: each extra dollar of oil revenue becomes 20c of public investment if spent; or 15c of private
investment if saved.
Impact on public investment. The oil price shock triggers GDP growth, mostly because it leads to higher
public investment. In the Default submodel, the increase in public investment as a share of baseline GDI
is approximately qDzt (the marginal propensity to invest times the change in revenues). As oil revenues
account for almost 30 percent of GDI in 2020 (τ R y2020 oil
= 0.7 × 0.4 ), a 60 percent increase in oil prices would
boost revenues by nearly 20 percent of baseline GDI (see appendix, figure 8, Panel A). Under the SSR
q = 0, so public investment is unchanged, which is shown by the yellow line in Figure 4.4, panel e. In the
BBR-HR, q = 1, so all the additional revenues are spent, leading to an increase in public investment by
around 20 percent of baseline GDI at the peak, as shown by the green dashed line. Finally, under a BBR
q = 0.2, so 20 cents in the dollar windfall oil revenue is invested, yielding an increase in public investment
of about 4 percent of baseline GDI (maroon circled line). In all cases, public investment nearly returns to
baseline levels after the end of the price cycle in 2035. This feature stems from the assumption that structural
production of oil equals actual production, implying that θ ( z tR − z tR ) = θ ( Ptoil − $50 ) Qtoil = 0 for all q after
2035 as Ptoil returns to US$50 (equation (13)).
In the External-Balance submodel, the paths for public investment under the BBR and SSR are fairly similar
to their Default submodel counterparts. However, the deviations of BBR-HR and SSR-HR are worth noting,
as they both lead to persistently higher public investment, though for different reasons.
Under the BBR-HR, the oil sector expands rapidly during the oil price cycle, generating higher oil revenues that
are reinvested under the BBR-HR. Though this effect is present in other simulations, it is especially strong for
the BBR-HR. For example, in 2035, incremental revenues stand at 10 ppts of baseline GDP under the BBR-HR,
more than double the value generated by the BBR or SSR (see appendix, table 6 and appendix, figure 8).
The SSR-HR (pink dotted line) generates high public investment for many years after the end of the oil
cycle (extra 5ppts on average in 2036–2050, see appendix, table 8). This is because the extra interest savings
from paying down government debt are recycled into the budget, releasing extra resources for higher public
investment (for details, see appendix, figure 8).
domestic non-traded goods production. But these demand-side effects are not in this type of neoclassical model.
48
he reason is that oil prices have no direct effect on real GDP—only an indirect effect via investment, which continues to be
T
elevated as long as oil prices are above their steady-state level.
125
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Impact on private investment and spillovers. Private investment increases in all simulations, though
they can be much larger in the External-Balance submodel than the Default submodel. In the Default
submodel, private investment is 20 percent of GDI, so as GDI increases by 25–40 percent, private invest-
ment increases by 5–8ppts of baseline GDI (Figure 4.4, panel f). In the External-Balance model we assume
that if the public sector runs a surplus of one dollar, this will free up l dollars for private investment.
However, it is only the SSR and SSR-HR that generate substantial changes in the budget balance, and
hence it is only these two rules that feature larger increases in private investment with l > 0.49 With our
default calibration of l = 0.15, private investment increases further to peak at 8ppts above baseline by
2030 in the SSR and SSR-HR.
The combined effect of higher public and private investment provides a strong engine of growth in Angola
because of the low initial capital-to-output ratio (2), which makes GDP growth sensitive to investment
rates.
Extension: a higher investment crowd-in l parameter. Now we discuss an alternative parametrization
with a higher level of crowding-in of private investments, l = 1 (up from the default of l = 0.15). When
l = 1, the current account balance is effectively fixed as a share of GDI. As private savings and FDI are also
assumed to be fixed shares of GDI, then an extra dollar of fiscal surplus ends up funding an extra dollar of
private investment (up from 15 cents in the baseline).50
This calibration has little effect on BBR and BBR-HR rules, because they generate no additional fiscal
surplus, but allows the SSR and SSR-HR rules to generate much higher investment and growth rates. One
can see this on panel a of Figure 4.5, where private investment increases by 25ppts of baseline GDI for the
SSRs with l = 1 in 2030, rather than 8ppts in the simulations with the default calibration of l = 0.15. This
means the path for GDI with either SSR in the External-Balance submodel is now similar to the BBR-HR
(Figure 4.5, panel b), achieving a 35ppt increase in GDI by 2030 (though through higher private rather
than public investment). Moreover, the SSR-HR achieves the highest growth path—also peaks at 35ppts of
baseline GDI in 2030—but outperforms the other rules in the longer term. Finally, note that different from
the default calibration, the BBR and SSR yield very different trajectories with l = 1.
49
nder the BBR the budget is balanced, so there is almost no increase in the fiscal surplus. In practice there is sometimes a
U
small increase in fiscal savings, because the BBR is specified as a share of GDI, which increases with an oil price shock.
50
I n practice, the extra private investment could be supplied by a reduction of credit rationing and easing of loan conditions
or lower interest rates when domestic banks no longer purchase so many government bonds (though we do not model this).
The calibration also applies most effectively to countries with very closed current accounts. In contrast, a small l is more
appropriate for countries open to capital flows.
126
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 4.5: The Effects of Oil Price Shocks in Angola: High private investment crowd-in (λ = 1)
(fixed CAB as share of GDI)
25
20
15
%
10
0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
35
30
25
20
%
15
10
0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
BBR (Default model) SSR (Default model) HR (Default model) BBR (EB model)
SSR (EB model) BBR-HR (EB model) SSR-HR (EB model)
discovery shock to generate cyclical oil revenues—and, hence, different spending profiles across fiscal
rules—we set structural (long run) oil production equal to the baseline oil production.51
The first-order effect of an oil discovery is to increase reserves and, hence, production: a 1 percent increase
in reserves leads to g = 1/3 percent increase in oil production (see equation (2)). Panel b of Figure 4.6 shows
51
ote that this assumption is different from section IV.B, where structural production of oil was set equal to actual production.
N
That assumption was designed to isolate the effect of oil price shocks on the government spending profile. However, we now
want to explore the effects of higher oil output across different fiscal rules, keeping oil prices constant. This can be done
assuming that structural production is equalto the baseline, although similar results would be achieved by assuming that
structural production follows an N-year moving average of actual production.
127
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
Figure 4.6: The effects of oil discoveries in Angola: Comparison between different fiscal rules
and LTGM-NR models* (incremental = scenario – baseline)
a. Discoveries of Oil, Billions of barrels per year b. Reserves of oil, Billions of barrels
3.0 12
Scenario,
, large
BP–Energy data
2.5 discovery 10
2.0 8
1.5 6
%
%
1.0 Baseline, 25th 4
percentile since
0.5 1990 0.4 2
0 0
1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
4
1.8 3
2
1.6
1
1.4 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
0.6
1.0
0.4
0.5
0 0.2
-0.5 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
that the 2025 discovery raises oil reserves from 8 billion to 10 billion barrels, a 25 percent increase relative to
the baseline. In 2026, higher reserves boost oil production to nearly 2.2 million barrels per day, a 9 percent
increase relative to baseline (≈ γ × %∆R2025oil
, see panel c) in almost all models. As oil accounts for about
one-half of Angola’s economy, the increase in oil production boosts total GDP by about four percentage
points in 2026 (see panel d).
128
The Long Term Growth Model
After 2026, the impact on growth depends mostly on public investment, which, in turn, depends on
how the government spends/saves the windfall revenue generated by the discovery (figure 4.6, panel e).
The shock leads to extra revenues of 2–3 percent of baseline GDI until 2040 but declines sharply after
that due to depleting oil reserves (see Appendix Figure 9).52 This path is very similar across models
and rules, except from the BBR-HR, which generate higher growth and, hence, higher oil revenues in
the 2030s.
The BBR-HRs (both models) are the only rules that yield a faster growth rate for several years after the
discovery shock. As above, the BBR-HRs invest all windfall oil revenue, which increases GDP growth (oil
and non-oil) and private investment in relation to the baseline.53 In contrast, the simple BBRs (either
model), invest only 20 percent of the windfall, leading to a modest impact on growth after 2026.
The SSRs also generate a relatively small boost to public investment and long-term growth because the
extra revenues are mostly classified as cyclical and so are saved. The SSR in the Default submodel generates
the lowest growth path after 2026 as public investment remains constant and private investment increases
only modestly in relation to the baseline. As above, the SSRs in the External-Balance submodel also generate
a small amount of crowding-in of private investment (15 cents per dollar of fiscal surplus, see figure 4.6,
panel f).
Over the long term, the differences in public and private investment accumulate to modest differences in
the capital stock and GDP across the different fiscal rules. In the BBR-HRs (both submodels), GDP is about
8 percent above baseline by 2040, which is double the mechanical increase in 2026 (see figure 4.6, panel d).
However, by 2040, GDP under the non-HRs are similar to the initial shock in 2026 of 4 ppts above baseline
(variation 3.5–4.5ppts, depending on the rule). Finally, as above, the SSR-HR recycles interest savings into
higher public investment. While the increase in investment (public and private) does boost the productive
capacity of the economy under these rules, a higher rate of extraction reduces reserves, which is roughly
offsetting. Consequently, by 2040 around 75% of the initial discovery has been depleted (see panel b). See
appendix, table 9 and appendix, table 10 for further details.
5. Conclusion
This chapter develops the Natural Resource extension of the World Bank’s Long Term Growth Model
(LTGM-NR), which evaluates the effects of commodity price shocks and discoveries of natural resources on
medium- and long-term growth in resource-rich economies. The LTGM-NR augments a relatively standard
neoclassical model (the LTGM) by adding a resource sector and a government whose fiscal rule determines
how to spend or save resource revenues. The model is designed to be simple enough so that its mechanisms
are clearly understood, and its solution can be implemented in a spreadsheet (without macros). The
accompanying toolkit is preloaded with data for 56 commodity-rich economies and 11 resource industries
and can be adjusted to the needs of users.
In a calibrated version of the model to Angola, we find that population growth, depleting oil reserves,
and a reallocation of the economy toward the non-oil sector leads to a medium-term growth slowdown
and subsequent recovery in the long term. This nonlinearity is difficult to capture in standard one-sector
52
or example, in 2026, oil revenues increased by just above 2 percent of baseline GDI: a 9% increase in oil production x 35% oil
F
as share of total GDI in 2025 x 70% oil tax rate.
53
ecall that private investment increases in absolute terms because it is a fixed fraction of GDI, which increases relative to
R
baseline after 2025 due to the discovery.
129
4. Assessing the Effects of Natural Resources on Long-Term Growth: An Extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model
neoclassical models. Failing to account for sectoral heterogeneity, naïve calibrations could lead to large
differences in growth projections.
Next, we find that an increase in commodity prices can substantially affect real income (real GDI), though
only while prices remain elevated. In contrast, the effect on real GDP is smaller and delayed because only
the increase in the volume of production is counted (not the price effect). The boost to GDP is more
persistent—outlasting the price boom—but its size depends on the government fiscal rule. Not surprisingly,
Hartwick rules that invest all extra resource revenues generate the largest increase in GDP. Structural sur-
plus rules (SSRs) can potentially yield large growth rates in countries where higher public surpluses crowd
in private investment. However, in our default calibration for Angola, the crowd-in is small, and so SSRs
perform similarly to balanced budget rules where the fraction of extra spending on public investment is
equal to the historical average.
In contrast to price shocks, when resource discoveries become available for production, there is the same
immediate boost to GDP and GDI. The size of the gain largely depends on the share of resource rents in
resource production. The subsequent evolution of GDP depends on the fiscal rules in a similar way to price
shocks.
In closing, it is important to mention several caveats. First, the LTGM-NR is a simple neoclassical growth
model and so omits some mechanisms connecting the commodity sector and growth that are outside this
framework. Most important is the lack of an aggregate demand side, which means there is no stimulatory
effect of extra commodity-related spending on the local economy in the short run. Our model also lacks
channels through which commodity wealth might reduce long-term growth, such as Dutch Disease or a
growth-sapping political economy.
Second, governments may have many different objectives in designing fiscal rules governing the use of
resource revenues, beyond long-term growth. Other objectives include intergenerational equity (particu-
larly in countries with limited reserves), consumption smoothing, and reducing business-cycle volatility.
Often these objectives are conflicting. For example, our rule that delivers the fastest long-term growth
(a Hartwick rule) can also result in procyclical spending that exacerbates the business cycle in the short
term. As such, the findings in this chapter regarding the ranking of different rules reflect only one dimension
of performance —medium and long-term growth— and are not a blanket recommendation.
References
Abbas, S. M. Ali, Bouhga-Hagbe, Jacques & Fatás, A., Mauro P. and Velloso R., 2011. “Fiscal Policy and the Current
Account.” IMF Economic Review, Palgrave Macmillan; International Monetary Fund, vol. 59(4), pages 603–629,
November.
AfDB. 2016. Botswana’s Mineral Revenues, Expenditure and Savings Policy. African Development Bank, African
Natural Resources Center, 14(2):205.
Arezki, R., Valerie A. Ramey, and Liugang Sheng. 2017. “News Shocks in Open Economies: Evidence from Giant Oil
Discoveries.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Volume 132, Issue 1, February 2017, pages 103–155.
Bussière, M., Fratzscher, M., and Müller, G. J., 2010. “Productivity shocks, budget deficits and the current account.”
Journal of International Money and Finance Elsevier, vol. 29(8), pages 1562-1579, December.
Cavallo, M. 2005. “Understanding the twin deficits: new approaches, new results.” FRBSF Economic Letter, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, issue jul22.
Chinn M., B Eichengreen, and H Ito. 2011. “A Forensic Analysis of Global Imbalances.” NBER Working Paper 17513.
Collier,P., and B. Goderis. 2012. “Commodity Prices and Growth: An empirical investigation” European Economic
Review, 1241–1260.
Cochilco, editor.2017. Productividad en la Gran Mineria del Cobre, volume Comision Nacional de Productividad
(www.comisiondeproductividad.cl)
130
The Long Term Growth Model
Cust, J. F, and Mihalyi, D. 2017. “Evidence for a presource curse? oil discoveries, elevated expectations, and growth
disappointments.” Policy Research Working Paper Series 8140, The World Bank.
Devadas, Sharmila, and Pennings, Steven. 2019. Assessing the effect of public capital on growth: An extension of the
World Bank Long Term Growth Model. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development. 3. 22. 10.24294/jipd
.v3i1.10.
Hall, R. E., and Jones, C. I. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83-116
Hansen, J., and Gross, I. 2018. “Commodity price volatility with endogenous natural resources,” European Economic
Review Elsevier, vol. 101(C), pages 157–180.
IMF. (International Monetary Fund). 2012. Fiscal regimes for extractive industries: design and implementation,
Washington DC: International Monetary Fund,
IMF. (International Monetary Fund). 2021. World Economic Outlook: Managing Divergent Recoveries. Washington,
DC, April.
Kehoe, T. J., and Ruhl, K. J. 2008. “Are Shocks to the Terms of Trade Shocks to Productivity?” Review of Economic
Dynamics, Elsevier for the Society for Economic Dynamics, vol. 11(4), pages 804-819, October.
Kumhof M., and D. Laxton. 2013. “Simple fiscal policy rules for small open Economies” Journal of International
Economics 91: 113–127.
Lange, G-M., and M. Wright. 2004. “Sustainable Development in Mineral Economies: the Example of Botswana.”
Environment and Development Economics 9: 485–505.
Lebdioui, Amir. 2021. “The Multidimensional Indicator of Extractives-based Development (MINDEX): A new
approach to measuring resource wealth and dependence.” World Development, Elsevier, vol. 147(C).
Lledó, V., S. Yoon, X. Fang, S. Mbaye, and Y. Kim. 2017. “Fiscal Rules at a Glance.” Background note for the publication
of the IMF Fiscal Rules Database.
Mankiw, G., Romer, D., and Weil, D. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth.” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 107 (2): 407–437
Medina, J. P., and Soto, c. 2007. “Copper Price, Fiscal Policy and Business Cycle in Chile.” Working Papers Central
Bank of Chile 458, Central Bank of Chile.
Mendes A., and S. Pennings. 2020. “One Rule Fits All Heterogeneous Fiscal Rules for Commodity Exporters When
Price Shocks Can Be Persistent: Theory and Evidence,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 9400.
Pieschacón, A. 2012. “The value of fiscal discipline for oil-exporting countries.” Journal of Monetary Economics
Elsevier, vol. 59(3), pages 250–268.
Richmond, C. J., Yackovlev, I., and Yang, S. S. 2013. “Investing Volatile Oil Revenues in Capital-Scarce Economies; An
Application to Angola.” IMF Working Papers 13/147, International Monetary Fund.
Schmitt-Grohé S., and M. Uribe 2003 “Closing small open economy models” Journal of International Economics 61(1)
163-185.
Schmitt-Grohé, S., and Uribe, M. 2015. “How Important Are Terms of Trade Shocks?” NBER Working Papers 21253,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Schmitt-Grohé S., and M. Uribe. 2016. “Open Economy Macroeconomics.” Princeton University Press.
Solow, R. M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 65–94.
Swan, T. W. 1956. “Economic growth and capital accumulation.” Economic Record. 32 (2): 334–361.
doi:10.1111/j.1475-4932.1956.tb00434.x.
Terry Lynn, K. 1999. “The Perils of the Petro-State: Reflections on the Paradox of Plenty.” Journal of International
Affairs, 53(1): 31–48.
Van der Ploeg, F. 2011. “Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?” Journal of Economic Literature American Economic
Association, vol. 49(2), pages 366-420, June.
Wood, A. J. 1999. “Natural Resources, Human Resources and Export Composition: A Cross-Country Perspective.” In
Development Policies in Natural Resource Economies, ed. Jörg Mayer, Brian Chambers, and Ayisha Farooq, 39–52.
Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, Mass.: Elgar
131
Chapter 5
Abstract
This chapter studies economic growth in Malaysia, the effects of COVID-19). This decline is partly due to
with the purpose of assessing the potential to attain the demographics, but also a declining marginal product of
status and characteristics of a high-income country. private capital and slowing growth rates of total factor
Future economic growth is simulated under a business- productivity (TFP) and human capital. Strong reforms
as-usual baseline, where the growth drivers follow their are required for Malaysia to grow beyond what is
historical or recent trends, and under different scenarios expected based on historical trends, especially for human
of reform, using the World Bank Long Term Growth capital, female labor force participation, and total factor
Model (LTGM). Under the business-as-usual baseline, productivity. In the strong reform scenario, based on
Malaysia’s gross domestic product (GDP) growth is growth drivers achieving a target corresponding to the
expected to decline from 4.5 to 2.0 percent over the 75th percentile of high-income countries, GDP growth
next three decades, following the country’s transition to is expected to have a substantially higher trajectory,
high income in 2024 (which might be delayed due to reaching 3.6 percent by 2050.
JEL: D24, G14, G18, H54, I15, I25, J16, O16, O33, 043, 053.
Keywords: Economic growth, human capital, investment, labor force participation, total factor productivity,
innovation, education, market efficiency, infrastructure, institutions, Malaysia.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 9278, originally published in June 2020.
E
The appendices are available in the working paper version at the Long Term Growth Model website: https://www.worldbank.org
/LTGM. Sharmila and Jorge’s affiliations are based on when the article was written.
2
S harmila Devadas, Jorge Guzman, Young Eun Kim, Norman V.Loayza and Steven Pennings, World Bank. Corresponding author
email: spennings@worldbank.org. The views expressed here are the authors’, and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank,
its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. We appreciate comments from Yew Keat Chong, Firas Raad, Richard Record,
Shakira Binti Teh Sharifuddin, and seminar participants at the World Bank. To download the Long T erm Growth Model spreadsheets,
visit https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM
133
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
1. Introduction
Over the past few decades, Malaysia has recorded strong and sustained growth, apart from during periods
such as the Asian financial crisis in 1997, the global financial crisis in 2019 and—more recently—the
COVID-19 pandemic in 2020 (figure 5.1). As the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic will
hopefully be short lived, this chapter looks through the current growth volatility to focus on long-run
trends. Malaysia’s long-run growth performance has supported remarkable gains in social and economic
development, with a ninefold increase in per capita income over the last seven decades. The country is
expecting to transition to high-income status in the near future (figure 5.2), where high income is based on
the World Bank’s cross-country classification. This chapter studies Malaysia’s long-run economic growth
prospects as it attains the status and characteristics of a high-income economy.3
The government of Malaysia’s long-run and medium-run growth strategies are outlined in its Shared
Prosperity Vision (SPV) 2030 and 12th Malaysia Plan (respectively). The SPV and Malaysia Plan go
beyond high-income status, also ensuring growth is both sustainable and equitable. The October 2019
SPV sets out “a commitment to make Malaysia a nation that achieves sustainable growth along with
fair and equitable distribution.”4 The SPV blueprint proposes targets across key growth areas: regional
inclusion, the role of the small and medium enterprises (SMEs), human capital, labor market and
workers’ compensation, and social capital and well-being. The 12th Malaysia Plan, the next five-year
national development plan, is slated for 2021–2025. It aims to be aligned to SPV 2030, covering the
areas of economic empowerment (growth drivers and enablers), environmental sustainability, and social
re-engineering (essentially improving the well-being of the people and social cohesion).
Figure 5.1: Historical GDP Growth Figure 5.2: Historical Real GNI Per Capita Level3
15 Fore-
Actual
cast
12,800
10
6,400
5
Percent
0
3,200
–5
1,600
–10
–15
800
65
70
75
80
85
90
20 5
00
05
10
15
20
60
20
20
61
66
71
76
81
86
91
96
01
06
11
16
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
20
19
19
20
19
19
19
19
20
20
19
19
19
19
20
3
Methodology for figure 5.2: Calibrate the levels to GNI per capita Atlas method (NY.GNP.PCAP.CD) for 2018, and then cast
backwards using real GNI growth (NY.GNP.PCAP.KD.ZG). Horizontal orange line shown is the 2019–2020 high-income threshold.
4
The new government that assumed administration at the end of February 2020 has pledged to ensure the continuity of SPV 2030.
134
The Long Term Growth Model
This chapter simulates Malaysia’s long-run growth prospects using the World Bank Long Term Growth
Model (LTGM), a suite of spreadsheet-based tools building on the celebrated Solow-Swan growth model.
The Long Term Growth Model—Public Capital Extension (LTGM-PC) is used as the base model (Devadas
and Pennings 2019 and also chapter 2 in this volume), which allows for private and public investment to
have different effects on growth. Human capital and TFP growth are endogenized using LTGM’s Human
Capital extension (LTGM-HC) and TFP extension (LTGM-TFP) (Kim and Loayza 2019, and also chapter 3
in this volume), respectively. The LTGM-HC combines average years of schooling by age cohort with the
quality of education and health components to determine human capital. In the LTGM-TFP, the TFP
growth rate is calculated as the composite effect of TFP determinants: innovation, education, market
efficiency, infrastructure, and institutions. The models are described in more detail in appendix 1 and most
are available for download at www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
Our first result concerns a Malaysia’s business-as-usual baseline growth path, where the growth
drivers–public and private investment-to-GDP ratios, total factor productivity (TFP), human capital,
and labor force participation rates–follow their historical or recent trends (future demographic
projections taken from the United Nations (UN). We find trend GDP growth in Malaysia is likely to
fall from around 4.5 percent in 2020 to 2.0 percent in 2050, driven mostly by demographics, falling
private investment effectiveness, and declining TFP growth. Declining growth is common among peer
countries as they transition to high-income status.
However, this decline in growth is not destiny, and our second finding is that it can be partially offset by
economic reforms. Specifically, we simulate weak, moderate, and strong reforms for each growth driver,
with targets set with reference to the distribution of those values among high-income (HI) countries. While
weak reforms have little effect (relative to the baseline), moderate and strong reforms generate growth in
2050 that is 1.5 to 1.8 times that in the business-as-usual baseline (respectively).
The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. Section 1 presents the historical developments for each growth
driver. Section 2 discusses the assumptions regarding growth drivers and parameters used in the baseline
simulation. Section 3 shows the baseline GDP growth trajectory over the next three decades and analyzes the
contribution of each growth driver to both current growth rates and changes in the growth rate over 2020–2050.
Section 4 presents the impact on GDP growth of the different levels of reforms for each determinant of growth:
“weak” reform benchmarking at the 25th percentile among high-income countries; “moderate” reform, at
the 50th percentile; and “strong” reform, at the 75th percentile. Section 5 discusses the implications for GDP
growth when the effects of all growth drivers are combined for each scenario of weak, moderate, and strong
reform. Section 6, the conclusion, provides a summary of main findings and policy implications.
135
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
High-income status is defined by the World Bank as countries with gross national income (GNI) per capita
above US$12,376 in 2019–2020 (measured at Atlas exchange rates). In 2018, Malaysia’s GNI per capita was
at $10,460 (figure 5.2) and historical trends suggest that Malaysia is expected to pass the threshold in the
mid-2020s. However, this projection might be delayed due to the effect of COVID-19, causing a reduction
in the forecasted growth in 2020 and possibly in the early 2020s (figure 5.1).5
Aggregate investment-to-GDP has averaged 24% over the last two decades (figure 5.3), with public
investment trending down and private investment trending up (figure 5.4). During the late 1980s and
1990s, investment rates in Malaysia increased rapidly, reaching over 40% of GDP just before the 1997 Asian
financial crisis. High private investment-to-GDP rates were buoyed by the First Industrial Master Plan
(1986–1995), and liberalization and deregulation in the economy. In the 1990s, excessive investments also
occurred in certain sectors, especially the property sector. After the Asian financial crisis, the investment-
to-GDP ratio declined, with the fall mostly due to lower levels of private investment (not shown). In the
last 10 years, investment-to-GDP has averaged 24.6%. A closer look at the split between public and private
investment shows that public investment has been declining since 2012, falling from around 11% to 7%
of GDP in 2018. This is reflective of the government’s fiscal consolidation plan. At the same time, some
rebalancing has been observed with private investment rising from 15% to 17% of GDP.
The median TFP growth over the past 30 years (1985–2014) is 0.9% (figure 5.5). Since TFP is calculated as a
residual—growth less factor accumulation—it is volatile and oscillates with the economic cycle.
The human capital growth rate has experienced a downward trend since the early 1990s and it has averaged
roughly 0.6–0.7% in the 2010–2014 period (figure 5.6). Human capital is a commonly measured using the
average years of schooling, though in our forward-looking simulations we use a broader measure based
on the World Bank Human Capital Index that includes schooling quality and population health. In the
1980s and early 1990s, human capital grew at around 2.0% but now has slowed to 0.6%. As it is harder to
increase the average years of education when people are already well educated, countries often experience a
slowing growth rate of human capital over time. We expect this trend will continue for Malaysia as it moves
to high-income status.
Figure 5.3: Historical Investment-to-GDP (%) Figure 5.4: Historical Public and Private
Investment-to-GDP (%)
45 18
40 16
35 14
30 12
Percent
10
Percent
25
20 8
15 6
10 4
5 2
0
0
2000 2005 2010 2015
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
00
05
10
15
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
20
5
World Bank (2020) projects a growth rate of –0.1% under the baseline and –4.6% under a low-case scenario for 2020.
136
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 5.5: Historical TFP Growth Figure 5.6: Historical Human Capital Growth
8 2.5
6
2.0
4
2 1.5
Percent
Percent
0
1.0
–2
0.5
–4
–6 0
1961 1969 1977 1985 1993 2001 2009 1960 1968 1976 1984 1992 2000 2008
TFP growth PWT 9.0 30-year median (PWT9)
Source: PWT 9.0.
Source: PWT 9.0.
Total population growth was close to 1.3% over the past five years, after experiencing a downward
trend since 1990 (figure 5.7). Before 1990, population growth averaged 2.5–3.0%. Slower population
growth is typical of developing economies that transition into high-income economies and is expected
to continue. Slowing population growth also affects the share of population of working age (15–64),
which in turn affects the size of the labor force (figure 5.8). The share of the population between ages
0 to 14 has been declining, due to falling fertility, which has led to a “demographic dividend”: the share
of the population of working age grew by around 0.6% over 1965–2010, and then accelerated to 1.0% in
the 2000s (figure 5.9). Analytically, the LTGM suggests this demographic dividend contributed at least
0.3ppts to GDP growth throughout this period.6 Since 2010, we can observe a declining growth rate of
the share of the population of working age (figure 5.9), which has recently approached zero. This is the
result of an aging population—fewer children and longer life expectancy—and is a characteristic of an
economy transitioning to high income status. Examples of population aging can be found in developed
economies like Japan, the Republic of Korea and Western Europe, and is expected to continue.
Historically, the labor force participation rate has been stable at around 64%, until 2010 when it increased
to 68% by 2018 (figure 5.10). This is mostly due to higher female labor force participation (FLFP),
which increased from about 46% in the 1990–2010 period to 55% by 2018. In contrast, male labor force
participation has remained relatively constant at around 80% since 1990. Despite the increase in recent
years, Malaysia’s FLFP is still lagging its regional peers, such as Thailand, China, and Singapore and as
well as high-income peers (figure 5.11). Higher rates of FLFP increase the labor supply in the economy,
and hence the level of GDP per capita.
6
nalytically, the 0.6ppts of growth in the working age to total population ratio will be multiplied by the labor share of income,
A
which is 50%, resulting in about 0.3ppts to GDP growth each year.
137
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Figure 5.7: Historical Total Population Figure 5.8: Historical Population Age Cohort
Growth (%) Shares (%)
3.5 100
90
3.0
80
2.5 70
2.0 60
Percent
Percent
50
1.5
40
1.0 30
0.5 20
10
0
0
90
95
60
65
70
75
00
15
05
80
85
10
20
20
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
00
05
10
15
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
20
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
20
Source: WDI & UN Population Projections. Code: SP.POP.TOTL. Pop Age 0–14
Pop Age 15–64
Pop Age 65 and above
Figure 5.9: Historical Growth in the Working Figure 5.10: Historical Labor Force
Age-to-Population Share (%) Participation (%)
1.0 80
0.8 70
0.6 60
Percent
50
Percent
0.4
0.2 40
0 30
–0.2 20
–0.4 10
–0.6 0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
00
05
10
15
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
20
in table 5.1. We calibrate the LTGM-PC as the foundation of the analysis and add the LTGM-TFP extension
and the LTGM-HC extension to simulate TFP growth and human capital growth, respectively. Additionally,
short-to-medium term forecasts produced by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in its Article IV
report help us calibrate the future paths of public and private investment. We use population growth
projections (by age cohort) from the UN for demographic trends until 2050. The remaining projections
are determined by assuming that long-term trends in Malaysia remain constant and by performing some
138
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 5.11: Comparative Female Labor Force Participation in East Asia (%)
90
80
70
60
Percent
50
40
30
20
10
0
s
p.
nd
na
m
lH
lH
lH
ne
si
si
or
pa
Re
na
hi
la
ne
ay
t
ap
pi
Ja
pc
pc
pc
C
ai
et
a,
al
do
ilip
ng
Th
Vi
re
M
th
th
th
In
Si
Ph
Ko
25
50
75
Source: WDI using data for 2018. Code: SL.TLF.ACTI.FE.ZS.
steady state calculations. The labor share of income is calibrated to 50%, which is close to its value from
Penn World Tables version 9.0 (PWT 9).
Investment-to-GDP is assumed to remain around 24%, given recent trends and the IMF Article IV projec-
tions for the next few years. For the baseline, we calibrate public investment-to-output and private invest-
ment-to-output ratios (IG/Y and Ip/Y) of 6 percent and 18 percent, respectively (figure 5.12). This is based on
projections made by IMF (2019), which forecasts that IG/Y declines from 7.0 percent in 2019 to 6.2 percent
by 2023, and Ip/Y increases from 17.5 percent to 18.4 percent over the same five-year period.7 The calibrations
7
hese baseline projections by the IMF assume GDP growth of 4.8 percent, debt-to-GDP remaining around 50.0 percent, a
T
fiscal deficit around 3.0 percent, and roughly stable revenue mobilization rates over the next five years.
139
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
12 20
11 19
10 18
17
9
16
8
15
7
14
6 13
5 12
10
14
18
22
26
30
34
38
42
46
50
10
14
18
22
26
30
34
38
42
46
50
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
WDI IMF (2019) Calibration
are consistent with (i) the gradual downward trend in IG/Y in recent years amid fiscal consolidation, and (ii)
a rebalancing toward private investment.8
The baseline projections put Malaysia between the 75th and 90th percentiles of the distribution of IG/Y
among high-income countries and at the 50th percentile for Ip/Y (table 5.2). Generally, IG/Y declines and
Ip/Y increases as countries move from lower to higher country income group classifications. One reason
underlying the comparatively high IG/Y in Malaysia is that public investment includes investment spending
by state-owned enterprises (SOEs).9 While the classification of expenditure by SOEs as public investment
may differ country-to-country, there are some indications that public investment tends to be higher in
countries that have a significant presence of SOEs.10
The efficiency of public investment, as reflected by the Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI) in the LTGM-PC,
is high in Malaysia. Malaysia’s IEI score of 0.877 puts it at about the 50th percentile among high-income
countries. This indicates that infrastructure in Malaysia is well constructed and of high quality, which is
supported by the World Economic Forum’s survey on infrastructure quality for its Global Competitiveness
Index—Malaysia ranked 21st of 137 countries in 2017–2018. Given the high base, the potential growth
8
ur projections, indicative of longer-term trends, are also consistent with the near-term projections of the government for
O
IG/Y, but higher in the case of Ip/Y. Ministry of Finance Malaysia (2019) estimates IG/Y and Ip/Y at 6.5 percent and 16.8 percent
respectively for 2019 and forecasts these ratios at 6.1 percent and 16.3 percent respectively for 2020.
9
nown as non-financial public corporations (NFPCs) in Malaysia, these enterprises are public sector agencies undertaking
K
the sale of industrial and commercial goods and services. They include government-owned and/or government-controlled
companies. The government’s monitoring and reporting are focused on major NFPCs, which have government ownership
of more than 50 percent of total equity, minimum annual sales of at least MYR100 million and/or significant impact to the
economy (Ministry of Finance Malaysia 2018).
10
I n a list of 21 countries with the highest shares of SOEs among their top 10 firms and which also have at least 10 firms on the
Forbes Global 2000 list (Kowalski et al. 2013), Malaysia is ranked fifth. Among the top 10 countries on this list (China, United
Arab Emirates, the Russian Federation, India, Malaysia, Saudi Arabia, Indonesia, Brazil, Norway, and Thailand), we calculate
the median value for average IG/Y over 2006–2015 as 7 percent. Our calculations also indicate that the baseline projection of
6 percent for Malaysia’s IG/Y is slightly below the 75th percentile value for average IG/Y over 2006–2015 (6.8 percent) of high-
income fuel-based economies (fuel exports/merchandise exports >15 percent).
140
The Long Term Growth Model
impact from improvements in this measure of efficiency is limited, and so we assume quality is constant at
its current rate in the baseline and all scenarios.
The IEI is best thought of as capturing public capital construction quality, which does not capture other less
quantifiable, but important, aspects of public capital quality like poor project selection or an inflated cost of
construction. We are, thus, unable to properly examine the implications of improvements on these elements
in the model, especially in the context of cross-country comparisons. However, it does not mean that these
elements are not important for Malaysia. For instance, IMF (2019) notes that fiscal vulnerabilities include
reliance on off-budget spending and weaknesses in project appraisal, approval, and costing (Malaysia scores
lower than the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) average in terms of
its procurement systems).
Total factor productivity (TFP) growth is assumed to be at the historical growth rate of 0.9%, the median
over the period 1985–2014 in 2019, and then decline to 0.6% for the period of 2020–2050. This baseline
TFP growth rate was generated using the LTGM-TFP extension (Kim and Loayza 2019) which assesses a
country’s potential for improving TFP growth depending on its determinants—innovation, education, market
efficiency, infrastructure, and institutions. For the business-as-usual baseline, we assumed the TFP overall
determinant index, the composite index of the subcomponent indexes for the five categories of the determi-
nants, keeps increasing with the historical trend of the last 10 years. Specifically, we applied the average annual
change in the overall determinant index over 2009–2018 to the period of 2019–2050 as shown in figure 5.13a.
With this assumption, we simulated TFP growth using the LTGM-TFP extension. Figure 5.13b shows that the
TFP growth rate is expected to decrease gradually from around 0.90% to 0.64% over the next three decades.
141
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Figure 5.13: Business-as-Usual Baseline for the TFP Overall Determinant Index and the TFP
Growth Rate
120 1.0
0.90%
100
0.8
80
0.6
Percent
Percent
60
0.4
40
20 0.2
0 0
50
95
00
05
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
19
24
29
34
39
44
49
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Malaysia Business-as-usual baseline
Median over 1985–2014
We assume that future human capital growth begins at 0.6% in 2020 and declines to about 0.1% in 2050
(figure 5.14). The human capital growth path for the baseline is produced using the LTGM-HC extension.
We assume the average expected years of schooling in the future is the same as that of today’s children,
12.2 years. Because today’s new workers are better educated than older workers moving to retirement,
the average human capital of the workforce increases over time—despite no increase in schooling of
children—leading to a positive human capital growth rate. The declining rate of human capital growth
is because the average education quantity increases over time, and so the boost to the average from
higher-skilled young workers is smaller. Human capital also includes the quality of education, as well as
health. The health of the population is measured by adult survival rates (ASRs), which is the probability
that a 15-year old will reach their 60th birthday, and stunting rates, defined as the fraction of 5-year-olds
that are not stunted (see equation below).
In the baseline, we assume that schooling quality remains at its original level of 0.75, ASRs stay at 0.88,
and the not stunted rate stays at 0.79. Data on the health and education variables are taken from the World
Bank’s Human Capital Project.11 Due to a lack of historical data, we also assume that those rates apply to
the whole working-age population, and so schooling quality and health make no contribution to human
capital growth in the baseline. In terms of growth rates, human capital grows at about 0.6% in 2019–2020,
and it slowly declines to under 0.1% by 2050. The return to education is assumed to be 12%.
The capital-to-output ratio is assumed to be at its steady-state value of around 2.3. The steady-state
capital-to-output ratio is calculated as the ratio of the investment share of GDP to the sum of trend GDP
11
See https://www.worldbank.org/humancapital.
142
The Long Term Growth Model
0.7
0.6
0.5
Percent
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
00
21
23
25
27
29
31
33
35
37
39
41
43
45
47
49
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Baseline
growth and depreciation rate (see equation below).12 We divide total capital into public and private shares
from the IMF Fiscal Affairs Department Investment and Capital Stock Database 2017, resulting in 1.14 for
the public capital-to-output ratio (Kg/Y) and 1.11 for the private capital-to-output ratio (Kp/Y), respectively.
K I 0.242
= / (g y + δ ) = ≈ 2.28
Y Y 0.046 + 0.058
12
he GDP growth rate used is the average of 4.6% in the past 10 years, and the depreciation rate 5.8% from PWT 9. An
T
alternative approach is to calibrate the capital-to-output ratio using Penn World Tables data, which would have generated
a total capital-to-output ratio of around 3, and a lower growth rate over the next few years. But that growth rate was
inconsistent with other information, such as recent growth history and forecasts by policy institutions, so we chose the steady-
state approach instead.
143
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
0.7 14
0.6
12
0.5
10
0.4
8
Percent
0.3
Percent
0.2 6
0.1
4
0
2
–1.0
–2.0 0
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
60
65
70
75
80
85
90
95
00
05
10
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
20
HL GDP growth Forecast HL GDP growth China, Hong Kong SAR Republic of Korea
GDP PC growth Forecast GDP PC growth Singapore Taiwan
Sources: LTGM Calculations & East Asia and Pacific Economic Update
April 2020.
13
hanges in the working-age to total population ratio contribute approximately zero, as Malaysia is in the middle of a
C
transition between a demographic dividend and an aging population (see figure 5.9). Labor force participation is assumed to
be constant in the baseline, and so makes no contribution.
144
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 5.17: Net Investment Contribution to GDP Growth and Marginal Product of Capital
2.50 35
30
2.00
25
1.50
Percent
20
Percent
15
1.00
10
0.50
5
0 0
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 7
29
20 31
20 3
35
20 7
39
20 41
20 3
45
20 7
49
20 9
20 21
20 3
25
20 7
29
20 31
20 3
35
20 7
39
20 41
20 3
45
20 7
49
2
4
2
4
1
1
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Public investment (IG/Y) Marginal product of measured public capital (MPKGm)2/
Private investment (I /Y) P Marginal product of private capital (MPKP)3/
IG /Y
1/
Net public investment contribution to GDP growth ≈ φ tGm t − δ G .
K t / Yt
I P /Y
Net private investment contribution to GDP growth ≈ (1 − β − φ ) t P t − δ P .
K t / Yt
2/
Marginal product of measured public capital, MPK Gm = φ
. is obtained by taking the derivative of equation (16) in appendix 1 with
K tGm / Yt
respect to I tG / Yt . θ N = θ t , that is the efficiency of new investment remains the same as past investment
1− β −φ
3/
Marginal product of private capital, MPK P = P , is obtained by taking the derivative of equation (16) in appendix 1, with respect to I tP / Yt .
K t / Yt
Source: LTGM Calculations.
they add up to the total fall in growth over 2020–50. The normalization is necessary because over the long
term, the model is substantially nonlinear.14
As foreshadowed above, population growth is expected to fall by 0.8ppts over 2020–2050 which has a
normalized contribution of around 0.6ppts to the total baseline fall in GDP growth over the same period.
Declining population growth reduces the growth of the labor force, which directly reduces GDP growth.
This also reduces the marginal product of capital (which is proportional to the capital-to-output ratio),
which reduces the effect of investment on growth.15
Declining population growth affects GDP growth and GDP per capita growth differently (in contrast, other
growth drivers have the same effect on GDP per Capita and GDP growth).16 Falling population growth
actually raises per capita GDP growth: a 1ppt fall in population growth rate reduces the denominator (“per
capita”) by 1ppt but reduces GDP growth by less than 1 percentage point. In the baseline, GDPPC growth
falls by 1.66% in the baseline, but only 1.88% with constant population growth (appendix, figures 2.1–2.2).
The falling working age-to-total population ratio (WATP ratio) reduces GDP and per capita GDP growth
in the mid-2020s and also late 2040s (appendix, figures 2.3–2.4). The growth rate of the WATP ratio falls
14
ecause the model is nonlinear, the sum of the effects of changing growth drivers at one-by-one is not equal to the total
B
change in growth when the growth drivers change together. This is especially true over the long term when K tGm / Yt and K tP / Yt
change.
15
This direct effect is about 0.4ppts of GDP growth, with the indirect effect via the effectiveness of investment being the rest.
16
Note however, that the normalized contributions of the other growth drivers will be different for GDP and GDPPC growth.
145
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Table 5.3: Understanding the Drivers of Malaysia’s Falling Economic Growth Rates
This box aims to summarize the Republic of Korea’s economic growth experience as it transitioned to
high-income status. Jeong (2017, 2018) (and the next chapter in this volume) argues that the historical
growth drivers in Korea were diverse, but it was total factor productivity (TFP) growth and human
capital growth that helped sustain its development (figure B5.1.1), and these were more important
than physical capital accumulation. Real GDP per capita growth averaged almost 6% over 1960–2014,
WAP 9% 9
K/Y 23%
8 0.8
LFP 9%
7 1.7
6 3.0
5 1.9
1.0
4 3.7
%
10
4
01
98
99
00
20
19
-2
-1
-1
-2
-
-
60
10
70
80
00
90
19
20
19
146
The Long Term Growth Model
by 0.6ppts by the end of the simulation period, resulting in a contribution of 0.33ppts to the overall fall in
GDP growth over 2020–2050.
Falling TFP growth and Human Capital growth over 2020–2050 both account for around 0.4ppts of the
fall in the GDP growth over 2020–2050. The median TFP growth rate over 1985–2014 is 0.9% (the value
for the counterfactual), and the baseline TFP growth rate is expected to decrease from 0.9% to 0.6% over
the next three decades (figure 5.13, panel b). Human capital growth falls from 0.6% (the value in the
counterfactual) to 0.1% in the baseline, a 0.5ppts decline (figure 5.14). While this decline in human capital
growth is larger than that of TFP, GDP growth rates are also less sensitive to human capital, resulting in
similar contributions (appendix, figures 2.5–2.8).
Overall, the declining effectiveness of private investment makes the largest contribution to falling GDP
growth in the baseline (1.4ppts, or 40% of the total). In contrast, changing public investment effectiveness
makes little contribution. Investment rates (public and private) are constant in the baseline, but they can
still contribute to declining growth through changing marginal products. The marginal product of private
capital is currently very high, reflecting low rates of private investment after 2000 and solid historical
growth rates. As private investment is now higher, and growth is slower, the marginal productivity of private
investment is expected to fall through 2050 back to more normal levels.
In our model, the initial private capital-to-output ratio K p/Y is relatively low at 1.14 (about the same as the
public capital-to-output ratio K Gm/Y of 1.11), thus allowing for a much higher marginal product of private
capital. However, with high I p/Y at a constant 18 percent, K p/Y also increases faster than K G/Y (which increases
only slightly, due to a public investment share-to-GDP of 6%). As such, in the baseline the marginal product
of private capital shows a larger decline, and the GDP growth effect of I p/Y falls more noticeably over time.
147
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Additionally, we include a short box on the impact of rebalancing between public and private investment
(unchanged total investment), when discussing investment shocks to better understand their relative effects.
Percent
4 0
3 –0.05
2 –0.10
1 –0.15
0 –0.20
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049 2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049
Baseline Weak reform Strong reform Weak reform Strong reform
20 0.4
0.2
15
Percent
Percent
0
10
–0.2
5 –0.4
0 –0.6
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049 2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049
Baseline Weak reform Strong reform Weak reform Strong reform
Box 5.2: Rebalancing Components while Keeping I/Y Unchanged—A Comparison of the
Effects of IG/Y and IP/Y on GDP Growth
We consider two scenarios, in which total I/Y remains unchanged from the baseline at 24 percent.
In the first scenario, we increase IG/Y by 1ppt to 7 percent and reduce Ip/Y to 17 percent from 2020.
There is an initial decline in GDP growth in relation to the baseline (line with marker in panel a of
figure B5.2.1) given the loss of private investment impact at a high MPKP but the differential turns
positive by 2029 and remains so thereafter because KP/Y rises more slowly compared to the baseline
and MPKP is therefore higher (line with marker in panel b of figure B5.2.1).
In the second scenario, we reduce IG/Y by 1ppt to 5 percent and increase Ip/Y to 19 percent from 2020.
In contrast to the first scenario, there is an initial increase in GDP growth in relation to the baseline,
but the differential turns negative by 2027 (dotted line in panel a of figure B5.2.1), as KP/Y rises more
quickly compared to the baseline and MPKP declines faster (dotted line in graph B of Box Figure 3).
0.15 30
0.10
0.05 25
Percent
Percent
–0.05 20
–0.10
–0.15 15
20 0
20 2
24
20 6
20 8
30
20 2
33
20 4
36
20 8
40
20 2
46
20 8
50
20 5
20 7
39
20 1
43
20 5
20 7
49
20 9
20 1
23
20 5
20 7
29
20 1
20 3
4
2
3
2
4
2
3
3
2
4
2
1
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
+1pp IG/Y, -1pp IP/Y -1pp IG/Y, -1pp IP/Y +1pp IG/Y, -1pp IP/Y -1pp IG/Y, -1pp IP/Y
Baseline
149
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Table 5.4: Scenarios of Weak, Moderate, and Strong Reforms for the Projection of TFP Growth
for 2020–2050
150
The Long Term Growth Model
Figures 5.20-5.23: Simulated paths of the TFP overall determinant index and growth rates of
TFP, GDP, and GDP per capita under the scenarios of weak, moderate, and
strong reforms
Figure 5.20: TFP Overall Determinant Index Figure 5.21: TFP Growth
140 140
120 120
100 100
88 88
Percent
Percent
60 60
40 40
20 20
0 0
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049 2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049
Weak reform Moderate reform Weak reform Moderate reform
Baseline Strong reform Baseline Strong reform
3.5 5.0
4.5
3.0
4.0
2.5 35
3.0
2.0
Percent
Percent
2.5
1.5 2.0
1.0 1.5
1.0
0.5
0.5
0 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Weak reform Moderate reform Weak reform Moderate reform
Baseline Strong reform Baseline Strong reform
growth rates are lower than those of the business-as-usual baseline. The moderate reform scenario leads to
growth rates very similar to the baseline. Only with the strong reform scenario are the growth rates of TFP,
total GDP, and GDP per capita are expected to be higher than those of the baseline.
The key message of the simulations is that the improvement of the TFP overall determinant index needs to
be large and fast enough to maintain or accelerate TFP growth. In our econometric model for the LTGM-
TFP extension, the change in TFP growth rate depends on changes in TFP determinant subcomponent
indexes of innovation, education, market efficiency, infrastructure, and institutions, as well as the initial
level of TFP. A larger projected change in TFP growth rate occurs with larger proportional increases in
the TFP determinant subcomponent indexes and lower initial levels of TFP (see Kim and Loayza 2019).
151
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
In Malaysia’s case, the current TFP overall determinant index is higher than in other developing countries
on average; increasing it further is harder than in other countries with lower levels of the overall index. Also,
Malaysia’s current level of TFP is moderately high as compared to other developing countries. For these
reasons, achieving higher TFP growth in Malaysia is more difficult than in the past in comparison to many
other developing countries. Only with the scenario of strong reform are the growth rates of TFP, GDP, and
GDP per capita expected to be higher than those of the business-as-usual baseline.
17
owever, it should be noted that the health components improve the standards of living of Malaysians as a whole, and by
H
being healthy, they are able to learn and improve their educational attainment and also be healthier workers. The LTGM-HC
does not include the indirect effect of health on growth via high education.
18
his simulation is similar to that in the June 2019 Malaysian Macroeconomic Monitor, the differences being that: (i) baseline
T
has changed slightly to include a downward trend in TFP growth and (ii) quantity of education is also shocked.
152
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 5.24: Expected Years of Schooling Figure 5.25: Malaysia’s Quality of Education
0.9 8
0.8 7
0.7 6
0.6
5
Density
Density
0.5
4
0.4
0.3 3
0.2 2
0.1 1
0 0
7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Expected years of schooling Quality of education (based on test scores)
Distribution upper-middle-income countries Distribution upper-middle-income countries
Distribution high-income countries Distribution high-income countries
Malaysia 2018 25th pctl 50th pctl Malaysia 2018 25th pctl 50th pctl
75th pctl 75th pctl Korea Singapore
Source: HCI Source: HCI
Figure 5.26: Malaysia’s Stunting Rates Figure 5.27: Malaysia’s Adult Survival Rates
7 25
6
20
5
15
Density
Density
4
3 10
2
5
1
0 0
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
Children under 5 who are not stunted Adult survival rate
Figure 5.28: Human Capital Growth Due to Figure 5.29: GDP Growth Due to Human
Reforms Capital Reforms
1.2 5.0
4.5
1.0 4.0
3.5
0.8
3.0
Percent
Percent
0.6 2.5
2.0
0.4 1.5
1.0
0.2
0.5
0 0
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2045
Sources: Figures 5.25–5.28 from Human Capital Index; figures 5.29–5.30 from authors’ calculations.
153
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Figure 5.30: Malaysia’s Human Capital Figure 5.31: Malaysia’s GDP Growth Due
Growth—Disaggregation by to Human Capital Growth by
Components Component
1.0 5.0
Children under 5
0.9 not stunted 4.5
Adult survival rate
0.8 4.0
0.7 3.5
0.6 3.0
Percent
Percent
Quality of education
0.5 2.5
0.4 2.0
Quantity of
0.3 1.5
education
0.2 1.0
0.1 0.5
0 0
2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Baseline Qty Qty + Qlty Baseline Qty Qty + Qlty
Qty + Qlty + ASR Qty+ Qlty + ASR + Stunting Qty + Qlty + ASR Qty+ Qlty + ASR + Stunting
Source: Authors’ calculations.
of 2018, which is low in comparison to its regional peers (see figure 5.11) and also to its high-income peers
(see figure 5.32). We simulate increases from the current FLFP of 55% to the 25th (weak reform), 50th
(moderate reform), and 75th (strong reform) percentiles of FLFP of high-income economies, for which
the number of years to reach the target is 75th (long), 50th, and 25th (short) percentiles, respectively, in
the distribution of years that the high-income countries took from the Malaysia’s current level (in 2018)
to the target.19 We find that these increases in FLFP boost GDP growth by about 0.15ppts, 0.30ppts, and
0.40ppts over 2020–2050, respectively, relative to the business-us-usual baseline with unchanged FLFP
(figures 5.34–5.35).
19
or example, in the weak reform, the target FLFP is 62%, which is the 25th percentile among HI countries and of Croatia in
F
2018. For calculating a target duration to reach 62%, we identified eight high-income countries which show the path of FLFP
from Malaysia’s current level to the target (55% to 62%) within the time period of our database (1990–2018). Then the target
duration was calculated at 27 years, which is the 75th percentile in the years the eight countries took to reach from 55% to
62%. With the same approach, the moderate reform scenario targets 69% (Spain in 2018) over 23 years, and the strong reform
scenario, 74% (Netherlands in 2018) over 27 years (figure 5.33).
154
The Long Term Growth Model
0.045 80
0.040
75
0.035
0.030 70
Density
0.025
65
0.020
Percent
0.015 60
0.010 55
0.005
50
0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
45
Female labor force participation %
Distribution upper-middle-income countries 40
Distribution high-income countries 2019 2024 2029 2034 2039 2044 2049
Malaysia 2018 25th pctl 50th pctl Weak reform Moderate reform
75th pctl Baseline Strong reform
Source: WDI.
Figure 5.34: Malaysia’s GDP PC Growth Due to Figure 5.35: Malaysia’s GDP Growth Due to
Increases in FLFP Increases in FLFP
4.0 6
3.5
5
3.0
4
2.5
Percent
Percent
2.0 3
1.5 2
1.0
1
0.5
0
0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Weak reform Moderate reform
Weak reform Moderate reform
Baseline Strong reform
Baseline Strong reform
package of reforms are the same as those discussed individually in section 4; here we combine their effects.
The results are shown in figures 5.36 and 5.37.
In the weak reform scenario, based on increasing the growth determinants to the 25th percentile of
high-income countries (as above), growth is around 0.6ppts lower than the baseline in the early 2020s, but
converges to the baseline by around 2040. The initial fall in growth is due mostly to lower investment rates:
a fall in public investment (relative to the baseline) of around 1ppt of GDP, and a fall in private investment
155
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Figure 5.36: Malaysia’s GDP PC Growth Due to Figure 5.37: Malaysia’s GDP Growth Due to
Reforms Reforms
4.5 6
4.0
5
3.5
3.0 4
Percent
2.5
Percent
3
2.0
1.5 2
1.0
1
0.5
0 0
2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050
Weak reform Moderate reform Weak reform Moderate reform
MYS baseline Strong reform MYS baseline Strong reform
Source: Authors’ calculations.
(relative to the baseline) of around 2ppts of GDP. These have an immediate negative effect on growth—
especially the cut in private investment— given that the marginal product of private capital is initially very
high. Slower TFP growth, which is lower in the weak reform scenario than the baseline, also makes a small
negative contribution. The catchup in the medium term is driven mostly by human capital, where even
weak reforms boost growth relative to business as usual—albeit with a lag. The human capital lag is driven
by the time it takes better educated, healthier children to grow up to become more productive workers.
In the moderate reform scenario, growth is higher at all horizons and averages 0.6ppts higher over 2020–
2050. Public and private investment stays constant in the moderate reform scenarios (as in the baseline),
which is why the change in growth around 2020 is small. In addition, the moderate reform TFP growth
is very similar to baseline, and so makes little contribution in either direction. Consequently, the boost to
growth in the first 10–15 years in the moderate reform package is mostly due to higher FLFP. After that, the
boost to growth increases further as today’s children, with higher human capital, start to join the labor force
around 2035–2040. While GDP growth does still decline, it does so at a reduced rate and the downward
trend in GDP per capita growth is checked until 2040.
Finally, in the strong reform scenario, based on growth determinants at the 75th percentile of high-income
countries, growth is around 1.5ppts higher than the baseline over 2020–2050. The decline in GDP growth
(relative to 2020) is delayed until 2042, and GDP per capita growth is higher than its 2020 rate at almost
all horizons. Growth increases initially to 5.5%, mostly based on higher private (and public) investment.
Higher TFP growth and FLFP boost GDP growth as well, joined by human capital after around 2035–40.
It should be noted, however, that such a path represents the most optimistic path for growth and reforms.
6. Conclusions
The main findings of the chapter can be summarized as follows. With the business-as-usual baseline, the
GDP growth rate is expected to fall from 4.5% to 2.0% over the next 30 years (2020–2050), which covers
156
The Long Term Growth Model
the period of the country’s transition to high-income status and beyond. This decline is partly due to
demographics, but the other main causes are (i) a smaller contribution from private investment as private
capital accumulates and its marginal product declines, and (ii) the gradual moderation in the growth rates
of TFP and human capital, for which continuous improvements at a high growth rate become more difficult
as their levels increase.
Under the scenario of weak reform, the GDP growth rate is expected to decrease from 4.5% to 2.0% over the
next 30 years, which is similar to the result of the baseline. The impact is minimal compared to the baseline
because the expected paths of growth drivers under this scenario are similar to those of the baseline. Under
the scenario of moderate reform, the GDP growth rate is expected to decrease from 4.5% to 2.9%, which
is around 1.5 times the GDP growth rate of the baseline in 2050. Under the scenario of strong reform, the
GDP growth rate is expected to decrease from 4.5% to 3.6%, which is around 1.8 times higher than that
under the baseline in 2050. Higher overall investment-to-GDP due to a better fiscal position and private
investment ecosystem supports growth in the short-to-medium term, but its weakening incremental effect
must be offset by other factors. The strong reform scenario clearly illustrates how the stronger contributions
emanating from growth in human capital (0.28ppts growth increase with respect to the baseline, or 39%
of the growth differential), TFP (0.02ppts or 30%), and female labor force participation rate (0.30ppts or
24%) can, to some extent, mitigate the diminishing returns to physical capital accumulation over the long
term (7% of the growth differential in relation to the baseline).
The policy implications are derived from these results. Strong reforms are required to grow beyond what is
expected based on historical trends, especially for human capital (the quantity and quality of schooling, and
health), female labor force participation, and TFP. If Malaysia stays at the current level of educational quality
and health (similar to the 25th percentile of high-income countries), human capital will not contribute
much to economic growth. Improving human capital requires more focus on enhancing learning outcomes,
improving child nutrition, and providing adequate protection through social welfare programs (World
Bank 2018). Current female labor force participation is lower than the 25th percentile of high-income
countries, which is the benchmark of the weak reform scenario. Increasing it requires reducing or elimi-
nating barriers to economic opportunities for women through legal reforms, introducing more economic
and societal support for parents, and addressing gender norms and attitudes that perpetuate disparities
(World Bank 2019). Strong reforms to increase TFP growth require efforts from diverse stakeholders. Our
study shows that the gap between Malaysia’s current level (in 2018) and a target corresponding to the
75th percentile of high-income countries is relatively small for market efficiency but becomes increasingly
wider for innovation, infrastructure, education, and institutions. Some of them, such as education and
institutions, are expected to require two decades or more to improve to the target level of high-income
economies. As these determinants are intercorrelated, sustainable collaboration and cooperation among
the government, private sector, and civil society will be necessary.
Appendices and the spreadsheet-based toolkits are available online at https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
References
Devadas, S., and S. M. Pennings. 2019. Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the
World Bank Long Term Growth Model. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development 3(1): 22–55.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2019. Malaysia: Staff Report for the 2019 Article IV Consultation. Washington:
International Monetary Fund.
Jeong, H. 2017. Korea’s growth experience and the long-term growth model. Policy Research Working Paper WPS8240.
Washington, DC: World Bank Group.
Jeong, H. 2018. “Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy”
The Korean Economic Review, 34(2): 237–265.
157
5. Malaysia’s Economic Growth and Transition to High Income: An Application of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
Kim,Y. E., and Loayza, N.V. 2019.“Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants across the World.” Economia, 42(84),
36–93.
Kowalski, P., M. Büge, M. Sztajerowska, and M. Egeland. 2013. State-Owned Enterprises: Trade Effects and Policy
Implications. OECD Trade Policy Papers No. 147. OECD Publishing.
Kraay A. 2018. Methodology for a World Bank Human Capital Index. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8593.
Ministry of Finance Malaysia. 2018. Fiscal Outlook and Federal Government Revenue Estimates 2019—Public
Finance Statistics.
Ministry of Finance Malaysia. 2019. Economic Outlook 2020.
World Bank. 2018. Malaysia Economic Monitor December 2018: Realizing Human Potential.
World Bank. 2019. Breaking Barriers: Toward Better Economic Opportunities for Women in Malaysia. World Bank:
Kuala Lumpur.
World Bank. 2020. “COVID-19 and the East Asia and Pacific Region.” East Asia and Pacific Economic Update, April,
Washington, DC: The World Bank.
158
Chapter 6
Abstract
This chapter analyzes Korea’s growth process, not growth and human capital accumulation rather than
only rapid but also sustained for six decades at 6% the expansion of labor force or capital investment.
per year. The sources of such growth were balanced Counterfactual analysis of the neoclassical growth
among labor market demographic factors, capital model reveals that accelerated productivity growth
investment, human capital accumulation, and after the fast capital deepening was the key to the
productivity growth. However, the main engine of Republic of Korea’s long-term growth, avoiding the
growth evolved sequentially, e.g., labor and human middle-income trap. Appropriate calibration of the
capital factors in the 1960s, capital deepening in neoclassical growth model allowing time-varying
the 1970s, and then productivity growth for the transitional growth parameters explains Korea’s
following periods. We found that major sources of growth experience well and provides useful lessons
the six-decade sustained growth were productivity for sustainable development policy.
1
ditor’s note: This is a reprint of Jeong, Hyeok (2018), “Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable
E
Development Policy.” The Korean Economic Review, 34 (2): 237–265 (reprinted with permission).
2
yeok Jeong, Seoul National University, Graduate School of International Studies, Gwanak-ro 1, Gwanak-gu, Seoul 08826, Korea.
H
E-mail: hyeokj@gmail.com. This work was supported by the Global Facility on Growth for Development project between the World
Bank Group and Korea Development Institute [PO #7179114]. We appreciate the helpful comments from Steven Pennings, Luis
Serven, Jungsoo Park, audience from various conferences, and two anonymous referees. The views expressed here are those of the
author, and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.
159
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
1. Introduction
A casual observer of the Republic of Korea’s remarkable development experience, which Lucas (1993)
indeed called a “miracle”, is often impressed by its rapid and compressed growth experience but often
overlooks three important features of Korea’s development process3: (i) how much adverse Korea’s initial
conditions were; (ii) the sustainability, not just the speed, of growth which has continued for about 60 years,
overcoming various kinds of adverse initial conditions; and (iii) productivity growth, not capital deepening,
is behind such sustainable development. In fact, this is exactly why Korea’s development experience is
valuable for other developing countries.
The list of Korea’s adverse initial conditions includes almost all sorts of barriers to development, such as
colonial experience, civil war, corruption, lack of physical and human resources, political instability, which
are mentioned in the development literature as the critical hurdles to development for most developing
countries these days. Korea was a truly devastated poor nation when it started to take off toward the
miraculous growth, being unaware of what would be coming, maintaining the annual average growth rate
of real gross domestic product (GDP) per capita at 6% for almost six decades.
Not all developing countries could achieve such sustainable and rapid growth after World War II, and
Korea’s growth experience can be a useful benchmark case for them. However, Korea’s development expe-
rience per se would be of little help for the current developing countries because global environments
have changed, and each developing country faces different kinds of domestic socioeconomic and historical
conditions, hence different challenges and development goals. Only through the understanding of the
underlying mechanisms of Korean economic growth, would Korea’s successful development experience be
useful. This chapter attempts to contribute to such understanding by performing two kinds of quantitative
analysis. First, we decompose the sources of Korea’s real GDP per capita growth via an extensive growth
accounting analysis for the long-term 1960-2014 period, not only for the entire period but also for each
decade, using internationally comparable data. This analysis will provide the understanding of the Korea’s
long-run growth process from Korea’s take-off period to the recent low-growth period, which is first done
in the literature of empirical studies on Korea’s economic growth. It is worth mentioning that this kind of
long-term growth analysis can be extended to other countries and also be compared to the results of this
chapter because we use internationally comparable data.
Second, using the findings from the first decomposition analysis as building blocks, we calibrate the neoclas-
sical growth model to Korean economy in various ways of constructing a counterfactual analysis to sort out
the quantitative importance between transitional growth and long-term growth. This calibration analysis
also evaluates the validity of the use of the neoclassical growth model as a growth policy prescription tool
for the policy makers of developing countries, which is the World Bank’s recent initiative of the Long Term
Growth Model (LTGM) project.4 The LTGM project aims to help the policy makers of developing countries
design the national macroeconomic development policies from the perspective of the neoclassical growth
model. By predicting the future growth paths from the desired changes of investment and/or labor market
policies such as promotion of labor force participation or investment, policy makers can better envision
and quantify their development goals. This kind of quantitative policy design would be a great help in
articulating their policy goals and also in materializing the actual changes. Furthermore, an explicit use of
3
Hereafter, we will simply refer to “Korea” for the Republic of Korea.
4
he LTGM is an Excel-based tool that allows users to simulate future long-term growth for most of the world’s
T
developing and emerging economies, building on the neoclassical growth model. See chapter 1 of this volume and
https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
160
The Long Term Growth Model
a structural growth model in doing this kind of quantitative exercises is clearly beneficial. At the same time,
however, calibration of the structural model is always a challenge, particularly for prediction purposes in
response to policy changes. Therefore, it would be useful to see if such an exercise can in fact be applied to
a previous development experience for a country which already achieved the development goals that the
current developing countries are aiming for now. In this sense, the results of the application of the LTGM
to Korea’s development experience would deliver useful messages to other developing countries. We will
discuss the appropriate calibration strategy for this purpose.
This chapter consists of the following contents. We first describe the canonical neoclassical growth model
in section 2. This model will be applied to Korea’s economic growth for the 1960–2014 period to identify
the underlying sources of Korea’s GDP per capita growth in section 3 by growth accounting analysis. Based
on this analysis, we calibrate the model to Korea’s economic growth in two perspectives in section 4. First,
we use the model as a prediction tool for policy prescription in terms of predicting Korea’s growth process,
comparing the fitting performance across different calibration methods: conventional method of assuming
all key growth parameters at constant values versus a method of allowing time-varying transitional growth
parameters. Second, we evaluate the model as a descriptive tool to identify the influences of the transitional
and long-term growth policies for Korea’s long-term growth experience via various counterfactual analyses.
Both types of calibration exercises illuminate the important nature of Korea’s long-run growth and also the
validity of the use of the LTGM for developing countries. Section 5 concludes.
( )
β
Yt = K t1−β Lt , (1)
where the parameter β corresponds to the labor share in national income account. The effective unit of
labor L t is further decomposed into the quantity of labor Lt, the human capital per worker ht, and the
labor-augmenting technology level At such that
Lt = At ht Lt ,
which satisfies the canonical properties of the aggregate production function of the neoclassical growth
model, i.e., (i) monotonicity, (ii) diminishing returns and (iii) constant returns to scale. In terms of per
worker term, this can be represented by
161
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
where It denotes the capital investment and d the depreciation rate of existing capital stock. We follow
Solow’s convenience assumption that the investment is determined by the exogenous investment rate
g such that It = gYt.
Although already being well known, it is worth stating the key properties of the equilibrium dynamics for
this kind of neoclassical growth model, because we use a growth accounting formula which is c onsistent
with these properties. First, the diminishing returns property of the neoclassical growth model stabi-
lizes the equilibrium growth dynamics, i.e., the equilibrium growth path is stable to exogenous shocks
unlike the knife-edge property of the Harrod-Domar type of growth models. Second, in relation to this
property, there are two kinds of growth, transitional growth and steady-state growth. The steady-state
growth is the growth that is maintained in the long run, i.e., when the state of the economy grows at a
constant equilibrium rate. The transitional growth is the one which is manifested when the state variable
is deviated from the steady state. Solow’s (1956) fundamental contribution is that he articulated the
following two propositions: (i) the steady-state growth is determined only by the productivity growth,
i.e., the growth of the labor-augmenting technology At, and (ii) the transitional growth driven by the
pure capital investment effect is governed by the capital-output ratio Kt/Yt. For an economy in the
transitional growth path, the capital-output ratio increases when it is smaller than the steady-state value,
while it decreases vice versa. That is, the capital-output ratio is an important barometer whether the
economy is in steady state or in transition path. Note that capital stock increases even in steady state,
although this is not purely driven by investment. It is easy to see that this kind of capital accumulation
in steady state is not an investment effect. Suppose there is no productivity growth (no growth of At).
Then, there will be no growth in capital stock in steady state. That is, this kind of capital accumulation
is a productivity-growth-induced one. In contrast, the capital-output ratio is constant in steady state
whether the productivity grows or not. These arguments suggest that genuine capital accumulation effect
from investment per se, which we will call “capital deepening” effect, is captured by the capital-output
ratio, not by the capital-labor ratio.
Another feature of the aggregate production function in equation (2) is that the “productivity” is specified
in terms of the labor-augmenting technology rather than capital-augmenting technology or factor-neutral
technology. In fact, this particular specification is adopted in all neoclassical growth models, not just for the
Cobb-Douglas form. For the Cobb-Douglas form of production function, the three kinds of specification
of productivity, in fact, can be relabeled into the so-called total factor productivity (TFP). However, our
particular specification of technology is chosen in most of the growth literature because the stability of the
growth equilibrium is achieved only when the productivity is specified in terms of the labor-augmenting
technology, which is shown by Uzawa (1961). This critical proposition for the neoclassical growth model
seems to be rarely acknowledged these days.
Based on the above arguments about the properties of the neoclassical growth model, we specify our
aggregate production function in per worker term such that
1− β
y t = At ht (K t / Yt ) β
, (5)
which is another expression of the output per worker. From this specification, we obtain the growth
accounting formula that we will use:
1 − β
K
yˆ t = Aˆ t + hˆt + , (6)
β Y t
dy / dt
where the “hat” notation denotes the growth rate of the corresponding variable, e.g., yˆ t ≡ t . This
yt
approach of growth accounting for the neoclassical growth model with augmenting human capital was first
162
The Long Term Growth Model
adopted by Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992).5 Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare (1997) and Jones (2002) also
use this formula of growth accounting. Since these influential works on growth empirics, this specification
of growth accounting has become standard.
Such articulation of the consistency between theory and empirics is important for this chapter, because
the distinction between steady-state growth and transitional growth matters in the counterfactual analysis
via comparing various types of calibration of the neoclassical growth model to Korea’s growth experience,
which we will perform after the growth accounting analysis. The formula in equation (6) decomposes the
growth of output per worker into differentiated sources, i.e., the steady state growth (represented by Ât ) and
the transitional growth (represented by 1 − β K ), consistently with the neoclassical growth theory.
β Y t
Whether to consider the human capital effect as the steady state growth or the transitional growth depends
on how to specify the human capital accumulation dynamics. Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) specifies
the human capital dynamics subject to diminishing returns and consider its effect as transitional growth. In
earlier work, Lucas (1988) also incorporates human capital into the neoclassical growth model and shows
that steady state growth is possible through the human capital due to its spillover effect at aggregate level,
despite the presence of the bounded learning at individual level. Given this possibility, we consider the
human capital accumulation, ĥt in (6), as a source of steady state growth, with caution.
The conventional growth accounting formula that decomposes growth mechanically into factor
accumulation effects and total factor productivity (TFP), or the Solow residual, is given by
where the conventional total factor productivity (TFP) variable TFPt is measured as
Yt
TFPt = β = At (8)
β
K 1− β
t (ht Lt )
so that
t = β Aˆ t . (9)
TFP
This shows that the conventional TFP growth is a scaled-down version of our productivity growth measure
by the factor of labor share. The magnitude of the human capital growth effect from the conventional growth
accounting is smaller than our human capital growth effect also by the factor of labor share. In consequence,
the magnitude of the capital accumulation effect for growth measured by the capital-labor ratio following
the conventional way is always higher than our measure of capital deepening effect for growth. This is not
surprising because the capital accumulation effect in the conventional growth accounting formula includes
both the investment-driven effect and the productivity-induced effect, as we argued above. That is, the
capital accumulation effect measured by the growth in the capital-labor ratio as in conventional growth
accounting always overestimates the genuine effect of capital investment. This overestimation of capital
accumulation effect is avoided in our growth accounting formula in equation (6).
The typical measure of the level of development or national welfare is the GDP per capita yp,t ≡ Yt/Nt (where
Nt is the total population size) rather than the GDP per worker yt ≡ Yt/Lt above. GDP per capita differs from
GDP per worker by the two demographic compositions of the labor market: (i) the labor force participation
5
David (1977) is the early version of this approach without human capital.
163
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
rate SE,t ≡ Lt/NL,t and (ii) the working-age population share SW,t ≡ NL,t/Nt, where NL,t is the working-age
population (age group of 15–64) size, and Lt is the labor force size 6 such that
Yp,t = Sw,tSE,tyt, (10)
Our empirical target is to understand how this national welfare or development level changes over time.
Park and Shin (2011) also consider this kind of decomposition incorporating demographic aspects for
growth, mainly focusing on changes in the working-age population share.
Combining the output per worker growth accounting in equation (6) with this GDP per capita growth
decomposition, we have our final growth accounting formula
1 − β
K
y P ,t = S ˆ ˆ
W , t + S E , t + At + ht + . (11)
β Y t
6
e use labor force data from the World Development Indicators (WDI) for Lt to maintain consistency with the data use
W
protocol of the LTGM project so that there are possible differences in labor force participation rate between the national
sources and the WDI. Furthermore, using labor force instead of employment data may generate the different growth rate of
S
W , t . However, using the national source data, we find that labor force participation rate and employment rate tightly c
o-move
with each other, and the growth rates of S W , t between the two measures differ only by 0.1% for the sample period.
7
he original data source of the WDI labor variables such as working-age population and labor force participation rate is the
T
International Labor Organization (ILO) Statistics. The labor share and the capital depreciation rate variables are time-varying
in PWT 9.0, and we take the time-series averages during our sample period 1960–2014.
164
The Long Term Growth Model
In order to isolate the contribution of productivity growth to GDP per capita growth, we fix the values
capital-output ratio, human capital per worker, working-age population share, and labor force participation
rate at the 1960 values and vary only the labor-augmenting technology level as in the data. That is, the
counterfactual GDP per capita measure due to the productivity change is
1−β
A
y P,t = S W,1960 S E,1960 A t (K 1960 / Y1960 ) β h1960
We can similarly construct counterfactual measures of GDP per capita due to the changes of other
components. Figure 6.1 plots those counterfactual GDP per capita measures for each of the five components
of productivity (labeled as “A”), human capital per worker (labeled as “HC”), capital deepening (labeled
as “K/Y”), working-age population share (labeled as “WAP”), and labor force participation rate (labeled as
“LFP”). Table 6.1 summarizes the growth rates of the actual and the above counterfactual measures of GDP
per capita for the entire period as well as for each of the sub-period decades (1960s, 1970s, 1980s, 1990s,
and 2000s) and the remaining 2010–2014 period.
Figure 6.1 and Table 6.1 reveal interesting features about Korea’s economic growth for the last 55 years,
which are not well recognized in the literature. First, it turns out that the largest contributing component
to Korea’s real GDP per capita growth during the 1960-2014 period is the productivity growth rather than
each of the factor growth. The contribution of the productivity growth ( Ât ) is 1.9% each year on average.
The contribution of the human capital growth ( ĥt ) is 1.5% each year on average. The contribution of
1 − β
K
the capital deepening is 1.3% each year on average. The contributions from the labor
β Y t
market demographic changes are 0.5% from the increase in working-age population share (S W, t
) and also
0.5% from the increase in labor force participation rate (SW, t ) so that the combined contribution from
165
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
4,500
Counterfactual GDP Per Capita (2011 US$)
4,000
3,500
3,000
2,500
2,000
1,500
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
AL HC KY WAP LFP
Note: (1) Each line represents the counterfactual path of GDP per capita from the isolated growth of each variable. (2) “AL” Productivity growth
of labor-augmenting technology, “HC” Human capital growth, “KY” Capital deepening, “WAP” Changes of working-age population share,
“LFP” Changes of labor force participation rate.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
Table 6.1: Decomposition of Sources of Korea’s Growth of GDP per Capita (%)
the labor market demographic changes is 1.0%. This feature of productivity-driven growth of Korea may
come at a surprise, because the typical image for Korean economic growth for both external observers and
internal policy makers is investment-driven. However, recalling Korea’s sustained growth for about six
decades, this should not be a surprise from the neoclassical growth perspective, which states that long-run
growth is possible only through productivity growth. Regarding the speed of growth, there were many
developing countries which experienced growth as rapid as Korea during 1960s, 1970s, or 1980s. Such
examples include Mexico, Zambia, Gabon, and Mauritius. However, the rapid growth of those countries
166
The Long Term Growth Model
lasted only 10 to 20 years. The fundamental reason why Korea could maintain the 6% growth per year
for about six decades unlike those countries seems to be no longer puzzling. Korea’s growth experience
provides an empirically valid prescription for the importance of productivity for sustainable development
à la neoclassical growth models.
It is worth noticing that this contribution ordering among growth components depends on our way of
formulating growth accounting as in equation (6). Using the conventional growth accounting formula in
equation (7), the TFP contribution is 1.1%, human capital contribution is 0.9%, and capital per worker
contribution is 2.8%, so that the contribution measures for both productivity and human capital decrease
while the capital contribution measure increases, comparing to the results of our accounting method.
However, as we argued in section 2, part of the 2.8% contribution of capital accumulation per worker
is due to the productivity growth, hence the contribution of capital investment is overstated. Filtering
such induced capital accumulation effect out, the contribution of the capital investment turns to 1.3%.
Furthermore, as we argued again in section 2, the steady-state growth rate is determined by our productivity
growth measure Ât , not by the TFP growth. Bearing this in mind, however, we provide the conventional
TFP growth measure in the last column of table 6.1 for a reference.
The second interesting feature is that despite the above differences of contribution ordering, the magnitudes
of contribution are substantial for all components, ranging from 1.0% to 1.9%, none of which are negligible.
That is, the sources of growth are well balanced among productivity, human capital, capital deepening, and
labor market demography during the long-run process of Korea’s economic growth, without any of which
the annual growth rate of 5.9% could not have been realized.
Table 6.1 provides the decade-specific growth accounting results as well. Comparing these results across
decades, we find that the major contributing components change over time. In the initial development
stage of the 1960s, human capital growth was the major driving force for Korea’s growth, 2.2% each year
on average. Combined labor market demographic effects contributed to increasing GDP per capita by
1.1% each year in the 1960s, which is the second largest contributing component in 1960s. Interpreting the
human capital as quality of labor and labor market demographic changes as quantity of labor, combined
labor-related growth contributed to growth by 3.3% each year in the 1960s. That is, Korea’s growth in the
1960s period is labor-driven.
In the 1970s, however, capital deepening was the main engine of growth at 3.0% each year on average. The
capital deepening effect dropped remarkably to 0.8% in the 1980s, surging back to 1.9% in the 1990s, and
then diminished to 0.5% for the 2000s period and further to 0.3% for the 2010–2014 period. The 1970s
was the period when Korean economy made a dramatic transformation into a modern economy by the
export-oriented industrial policies and infrastructure building, which perhaps created the typical image of
Korea’s growth. This laid a solid physical foundation for the growth to follow.
For the remaining three decades of the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s, productivity growth was the main engine
of Korea’s growth. The productivity growth alone contributed to increasing the GDP per capita by 3.7%
per year on average in the 1980s, 2.3% in the 1990s, and 2.2% in the 2000s. The contribution shares of the
productivity growth out of the total growth of the GDP per capita were 43%, 38%, and 56% during the
1980s, 1990s, and 2000s, respectively.
Summing the above comparison of the decade-specific growth accounting results, we find that Korea’s
growth shows a sequential pattern in terms of the main engine of growth, first labor-human-capital-driven,
second capital-driven, and then productivity-driven. In particular, the productivity-driven growth lasted
for three decades, followed by the significant accumulation of human and physical capital. This sequential
pattern is an important feature of Korea’s growth, which was not acknowledged well in the literature.
Furthermore, this finding delivers an important lesson for growth policy design. The sequential feature of
Korea’s growth experience suggests that choosing the right sequence of focal growth policies may matter for
167
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
making the growth rapid and sustainable: initial growth policy focusing on promotion of labor participa-
tion and human capital investment (for creating the productive manpower of the economy), then focusing
on promotion of capital investment (for laying physical foundation of the economy), and then shifting
focus to productivity enhancing growth policies (for sustaining growth). This may explain why Korea did
not fall into the so-called middle-income trap.8
Table 6.1 delivers another noticeable pattern of Korea’s recent growth. From the neoclassical growth
theory perspective, the capital deepening effect, i.e., the changes in capital-output ratio indicate how far
or near the economy is to the steady state, because the capital-output ratio stays constant in a steady
state. The changing pattern of the capital deepening effects over time from table 6.1 seems to suggest that
the Korean economy is approaching to steady state quite quickly. After 2010, the capital-output ratio has
changed little, indicating that the Korean economy may be near the steady state. During this recent period
(2010–2014), the productivity growth dropped to 0.5% from the 2.2% of the 2000s period. This may reflect
the 2008–2009 global financial shock or perhaps the starting of the emergence of accumulated structural
problems. This chapter is silent about the causes of this sudden drop of productivity growth. However, it
is worth noticing that such a sudden drop of productivity growth happened when we observe a symptom
showing that Korean economy is near the steady state (little change in capital-output ratio). Furthermore,
for the 2010-2014 period, the largest contributing components to growth are labor related: human capital
growth (0.9%) and the increase in the labor force participation rate (0.8%). In particular, the increase in the
labor force participation rate is a big reversal of the trend. During the recent two decades of 1990-2010, the
contribution of labor force participation has been only 0.2%. This contribution surged back to the pre-1990
level. In fact, the composition of contributing shares of growth components for the 2010-2014 period is
a déjà vu of those of the 1960s period. All these symptoms are indeed concerning because they may be a
presage of the starting of long-run stagnation. It may be too early to conclude that the Korean economy
indeed entered into a long-run low growth because the duration of this period is only four years. However,
these features were never observed for the five-decade growth experience of Korea before 2010, and Korea
does need to pay attention to this change. At the same time, productivity growth is not predetermined and
there still exist ample opportunities of promoting productivity growth for Korea. In this sense, the Korean
economy seems to be at slippery slope for her next stage of development.
8
See Eichengreen, Park, and Shin (2012) for the recent discussion on the empirical evidence of middle-income trap.
168
The Long Term Growth Model
Korea’s economic growth in section 3 can be utilized in finding the right ways of calibrating the neoclassical
growth model in the following sense. Suppose there were policy makers in the past in Korea, say in the year
1970, who wanted to predict what would happen to GDP per capita growth after 1970 and the only available
information set was the data for the 1960–1970 period. Then, we may ask what the best way would be for
them to calibrate the underlying parameters of the model. We can answer this question because, unlike the
fictitious policy makers in 1970, we in fact know what actually happened after 1970 in Korea, so we can
evaluate the calibration method by evaluating the prediction performance against the actual data. We can
quantitatively compare the gaps between the model predictions and actual data ex post across different
calibration methods.
We find that it is important to take the transitional growth parameters (such as investment rate and labor
market demographic factors) as time-varying rather than as constant as is done in typical calibration
exercises of neoclassical growth models, while the prediction gap of assuming constant values for the long-
run growth parameters (such as human capital growth or productivity growth). Related, we also find that
the prediction performance of the conventional calibration method (assuming constant values for key
parameters) depends on the stage of development. The model with conventional calibration method works
very well for Korea when prediction time is 1990, while it performs poorly from the start when prediction
time is 1970 or 1980. This implies that the application of the conventional calibration of the neoclassical
growth model should be done with more care, the farther the economy is from the steady state. For instance,
during the initial stage of development after take-off, the target growth rate is not likely to be maintained
by the policy of a one-time promotion of investment rate, which is a frequent mistake made by the policy
makers in developing countries. The regression to the growth rate prior to such one-time investment policy
is the theoretical consequence of the diminishing returns property of the neoclassical growth model. Korean
growth experience indeed confirms this property empirically. In other words, it is important to continue
to promote investment in order to maintain or accelerate growth during the catchup period. However,
after the economy enters into a mature stage of development (after 1990s in case of Korea), such an effect
dwindles. In the following subsection, we will fully characterize the hidden interactions among parameters
of the model.
and the gross growth rate of the GDP per capita between period t and t + 1 is
1− β
Yt
y P ,t +1 γ t K + (1 − δ ) (13)
= Λtβ+1 t
y P ,t 1 + Nˆ t +1
where
( )( )( )( )
Λt +1 = 1 + SˆW, t +1 1 + SˆE ,t +1 1 + Aˆ t +1 1 + hˆt +1 ,
gt is the investment rate at period t, and Nˆ t +1 , SˆW ,t +1 , SˆE ,t +1 , Aˆ t +1 , and hˆt +1 are the growth rates of p
opulation,
working-age population share, labor force participation rate, productivity, and human capital between
periods t and t + 1, respectively. The growth equation (13) clarifies two things. First, the growth rate of GDP
169
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
per capita increases in investment rate gt, but this growth effect decreases in Kt/Yt, i.e., the capital-output
ratio of the base year. The latter decreasing growth effect from investment captures the diminishing returns
property of the neoclassical growth model. Second, it increases in growth rates of working-age population,
labor force participation rate, productivity, and human capital but decreases in population growth rate.
Now, in order to simulate the growth path using equation (13), we need to select the parameters (1 – β,δ)
and to calibrate the growth rates of Nˆ t +1 , SˆW ,t +1 , SˆE ,t +1 , Aˆ t +1 , and hˆt +1 . When we substitute these growth
rates with the actual data, we will get the precise growth rate. For the purpose of simulation, we should
choose a way to calibrate the growth rates of these five growth variables at period t + 1 as well as the
time-invariant parameters (1– β) and δ from the observed data. Furthermore, to apply the growth equation
(13) to the next period at period t + 2, we need to calibrate gt + 1 also. Typical neoclassical growth models
assume that Aˆ t +1 and Nˆ t +1 are constant for all periods, but they are silent about the changing rates of gt + 1,
SˆW ,t +1, SˆE ,t +1 and hˆt +1. For gt + 1, SˆW ,t +1 and SˆE ,t +1, we cannot make the non-zero constant growth assumption
because they are “share” variables which are upper-bounded. Thus, we need to choose a way to predict the
path for gt + 1, Sw,t + 1, and SE,t + 1 during the targeted future period for the simulation purpose. Furthermore,
these three variables are labeled as “time-varying policy parameters” which would change depending on
demographics and policies.
For the human capital growth hˆt +1 , the original Solow (1956) model is silent because it simply abstracts
the human capital away. Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992) augmented human capital to the Solow (1956)
model, assuming the diminishing returns property for the human capital, hence it is not a source of long-
run growth. In contrast, Lucas (1988) augmented human capital to the same Solow (1956) model but
postulated it as a source of long-run growth due to the linear dynamics and spillover effects of human
capital at the aggregate level. We are open to these two possible theoretical formulations and take the choice
between the two formulation of human capital dynamics as an empirical question. Jeong (2017) shows
the shape of the trend of the human capital per worker is rather close to linear than to concave, despite the
incorporation of the diminishing returns of schooling in measuring human capital as in Hall and Jones
(1999). Based on the above arguments, we categorize human capital growth as a similar kind of parameter
to productivity growth at least for the sample period of this study, although the underlying dynamics
of human capital would be different from productivity dynamics. However, the measurement of human
capital from schooling only should be taken with caution.
9
To recall, 1 – β = 0.602 and δ = 0.053.
170
The Long Term Growth Model
balanced growth path, along which the growth rates are determined mainly by the fundamental parameters
of technology and preferences. A consistent way of calibrating the labor market demographic factors with
this “steady-state assumption” is to choose that Sw,t + 1 = Sw,t = Sw,0 and SE,t + 1 = SE,t = SE,0 (so that SˆW ,t +1 = 0
and SˆE ,t +1 = 0 ) for all periods.
Suppose that a policy maker in Korea made this set of “steady-state assumptions” in 1970, and then
applied the benchmark growth model to simulate the GDP per capita for the future period of 1971–2014.
Suppose that the data available for this policy maker in 1970 are the 1960–1970 period data. Once deciding
to take the “steady-state” approach, the best way to calibrate the constant growth rates of gA, gh, and gN
would be to form an adaptive expectation such that the constant growth rate parameters would be the
annual average growth rates of the corresponding variables for the data-available period, i.e., the 1960–1970
period. In selecting the constant values for the investment rate, working-age population share, and labor
force participation rate, we may want to take the average values for the past sample period to smooth out
the shocks. However, if taking the averaging period too long, the average values would not represent the
true values of the parameters for the simulation period. Thus, the average values for the initial five-year
period prior to the starting date of simulation, for example, the 1966–1970 period values for the 1970
simulated prediction, are to be used to calibrate the investment rate, working-age population share, and
labor force participation rate.
We can repeat the above simulation exercise by changing the prediction year from 1970 to 1980 (using the
1970–1980 data) or to 1990 (using the 1980–1990 data) using the same calibration method. Comparison
of the three sets of prediction results would be informative because the Korean economy has evolved from
a transition economy toward a steady-state economy. The calibrated values for the three sets of simulated
prediction exercises, labeled as “Pred_70”, “ Pred_80,” and “ Pred_90,” respectively for the 1970, 1980, and
1990 simulations by the above steady-state calibration method are summarized in table 6.2. For the purpose
of referencing with other countries, in table 6.2, we also indicate the average purchasing-power-parity
(PPP) adjusted real GDP per capita level for each period when the parameter values of g0, Sw,0, and SE,0 are
chosen.10 For example, Korea’s average PPP-adjusted real income level was US$1,466 in the 1960s when the
investment rate was 0.27, working-age population share was 0.54, and the labor force participation rate
was 0.56.
Figure 6.2 compares the predicted paths of GDP per capita of the three simulations (similarly labeled as
in table 6.2), overlaid with the actual path (labeled as “Actual”). This comparison illuminates important
features of the LTGM as a simulated prediction device as follows.
10
ote that this real income measure is obtained from the “rgdpe” in PWT 9.0 divided by the WDI population data, hence it is
N
different from our GDP per capita measure which is calculated from the “rgdpna” in PWT 9.0. In table 6.2, we use the “rgdpe”
measure to facilitate the cross-country comparison of development level.
171
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
First, notice that the “Pred_70” simulation underpredicts the GDP per capita as shown in figure 6.2. It fits
only the very beginning-of-period data, i.e., for the 1971–1973 period. The prediction diverges way below
the actual one afterwards. This result is not a surprise because the investment rate, working-age popula-
tion share, and labor force participation rate all increased during the 1960s, hence the five-year average
values underestimate the future values. Furthermore, the investment rate and the working-age population
share further increased in the 1970s compared to the 1960s values. The investment rate got stabilized
after the early 1980s, and the increase of the working-age population share also slowed down after the
1990s. The labor force participation rate continues to show an increasing trend, except for the substantial
dip during the 1977–1986 period. Furthermore, Korea’s population growth rate has fallen monotonically
during the entire sample period from 3.0% in the 1960 to 0.4% in 2014. All these changes have increasing
effects of GDP per capita, which are not captured by the current calibration method. The growth rate
of human capital decreased after the 1990s, but the magnitude of decrease is small, much smaller than
the decreasing rate of capital deepening. The productivity growth rate has been more or less constant
during the sample period. Thus, the current calibration method is a reasonable one regarding productivity
growth and human capital growth. In sum, the underprediction of the Pred_70 using the steady-state cum
status-quo approach calibration method seems to be mainly due to the assumptions of the constant rates
of investment, working-age population, and labor force participation.
Observing the “Pred_80” simulation, we get similar results, although the fitting performance improves over
the “Pred_70” simulation. In contrast, the 1990 prediction, which uses the 1980s data, fits the data very
closely during the 17-year period (1991–2007), and then the model overpredicts the GDP per capita after
2008 with an increasing gap. The main reason behind the good fit for the 1991–2007 period is that there
were no clear trends for the investment rate, despite its fluctuations, so that the capital-deepening effects
are well captured by the constant investment rate assumption during this period. The overprediction of the
50,000
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Actual Pred_70 Pred_80 Pred_90
Note: (1) Each line represents the actual or the predicted path of GDP per capita at different starting date of simulation. (2) “Actual” Actual GDP
per capita, “Pred_70” Predicted GDP per capita in the year 1970, “Pred_80” Predicted GDP per capita in the year 1980, and “Pred_90” Predicted
GDP per capita in the year 1990.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
172
The Long Term Growth Model
“Pred_90” for the 2008–2014 period seems to be caused by various reasons: (i) the gradual slowdown of
human capital accumulation, (ii) decreasing investment rate, particularly after 2005, (iii) the stagnation of
working-age population share after 2000, and (iv) the sudden stagnation of productivity after 2010, which
can be confirmed by table 6.1.
Comparing the above patterns of predictions across Pred_70, Pred_80, and Pred_90, we learn that the
prediction performance of the LTGM would be good when the economy grows in the stabilized envi-
ronments, but the LTGM tends to underpredict when the parameters of investment rate, working-age
population share, and labor force participation rate are actively changing. The prediction performance of
the conventional calibration method (assuming constant values for key parameters) depends on the stage
of development. The model with the conventional calibration method works very well for Korea when the
Korean economy entered into the stable stage after 1990, while it performs poorly for the early catchup
periods of the 1970s and 1980s. This illustrates that the application of the conventional calibration of the
neoclassical growth model should be done with more care, the farther the economy is from the steady state.
11
S ee Feenstra, Inklaar, and Timmer (2015) and User Guide of PWT 9.0 for more detailed discussion about the capital
construction of the PWT 9.0 data.
173
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Actual Simul Average
Note: (1) Each line represents the actual or the predicted path of GDP per capita using different calibration methods. (2) “Actual” Actual GDP
per capita, “Simul” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating at fully time-varying parameters, and “Average” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating at
constant parameters of average values during the sample period.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
started to emerge only after 1985 and gradually widened afterward. This implies that the compositional
changes in aggregate capital seems to matter only after the mid-1980s.
The “Average” represents mainly the long-run average growth effect holding the labor market demography
and investment rates fixed. Therefore, the difference between “Average” and “Simul” reflects the contri-
bution of the promotion of transitional growth policies such as changes in investment rate, working-age
population, labor force participation, and population growth. This effect seems to be substantial, so that
the promotion of transitional growth policies did matter for Korea’s growth.
We can further decompose the time-varying transitional growth policy effects between the effects only
from labor demography changes and the effects only from changes in the investment rate.12 The simulations
labeled as “Demography” and “Investment” in figure 6.4 represent such effects, respectively. “Both” captures
the combined effect. It is interesting to notice that using the nonlinear trends of labor market demography
and investment parameters, the model (simulation “Both”) can fit the data very well, even though we fix
the “fundamental growth parameters” of human capital growth rate and productivity growth rate. In this
sense, the LTGM can be a promising tool to predict what would happen in response to the changes of labor
market and investment policies and environments, with the appropriate selection of the long-run growth
rates of productivity and human capital.
The good fit of the model simulation to Korean economic growth by allowing the time-varying labor
market demography and investment parameters does not imply that the main engine of Korea’s growth is
the transitional growth sources. Such fitting performance is based on the productivity and human capital
12
Here, we use the quartic-polynomial-fit trend for each time-varying variable rather than using the actual data.
174
The Long Term Growth Model
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Simul Average Labor Investment Both
Note: (1) Each line represents the actual or the predicted path of GDP per capita using different calibration methods. (2) “Simul” Predicted GDP
per capita calibrating at fully time-varying parameters, “Average” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating at constant parameters of average values
during the sample period, “Demography” Predicted GDP per capita allowing time-variation only for the labor market demography parameters,
“Investment” Predicted GDP per capita allowing time-variation only for the investment rate parameter, and “Both” Predicted GDP per capita
allowing time-variation for both labor market demography and investment rate parameters.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
growth rates of 1.9% and 1.5% every year in the background. To evaluate the role of such fundamental
growth parameters, we simulate the model at the time-varying labor market demography and investment
parameters, but turn off the productivity growth, human capital growth, or both to zero. The simulated paths
of the real GDP per capita of these simulations, are labeled as “No g_h,” “No g_A,” and “Neither,” respec-
tively, in figure 6.5. This shows that Korea’s growth performance would have been unimpressive, although
the investment and labor market demographic factors had been actively promoted as in Korea, if they had
been the only sources of growth.
In the year of 2014, Korea’s real GDP per capita is US$34,300 in 2011 US dollars using national prices and
US$35,103 using PPP adjusted prices according to the PWT 9 data. The Korea’s PPP-adjusted real GDP
per capita in 2014 is slightly lower than that of Japan (US$35,358) and a little higher than that of Spain
(US$33,864) in the same year. In 1960, Korea’s PPP-adjusted real GDP per capita was US$1,175 which was
lower than those of Kenya, Tanzania, Bangladesh and Haiti, while those of Japan and Spain were US$5,351
and US$5,741, respectively. Without human capital growth, Korea’s 2014 real income level would have been
US$14,597 (close to the level of Brazil in 2014). Without productivity growth, Korea’s 2014 real income
level would have been US$12,178 (close to the level of South Africa in 2014). With neither productivity and
human capital growth, Korea’s 2014 real income level would have been US$5,970 (close to level of Bolivia in
2014). The above comparison clearly illustrates that the main backbones of Korea’s “miraculous growth,” as
is asserted by Lucas (1993), are the productivity growth and human capital accumulation, although the
active promotion of labor market demography and investment played a non-negligible role as well. That
is, Korea’s growth experience shows that the most critical factors for successful and sustainable growth are
the productivity and human capital growth, i.e., the fundamental sources of long-run growth rather than
the sources of transitional growth, which confirms the key insights of the neoclassical growth theory.
175
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Note: (1) Each line represents the actual or the predicted path of GDP per capita using different calibration methods. (2) “Simul” Predicted
GDP per capita calibrating at fully time-varying parameters, “Both” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating at constant fundamental parameters
of human capital and labor-augmenting productivity growth, “No g_h” Predicted GDP per capita with no human capital growth, “No g_A”
Predicted GDP per capita with no labor-augmenting productivity growth, and “Neither” Predicted GDP per capita with neither human capital
nor labor-augmenting productivity growth.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
The above counterfactual analysis of varying growth sources quantitatively identifies the roles of transi-
tional versus long-run growth. It suggests that the major sources of sustainable and fast growth for Korea
were the productivity and human capital growth, although the time-varying promotion of investment and
labor force participation also played significant roles as well. It is worth mentioning that the two types of
growth (transitional and fundamental growth) are not independent from each other, so that the above
counterfactual analysis results do not sum up in an accounting way. In fact, this is the key nature of the
neoclassical model and the difference from the simple growth accounting analysis in section 3. For example,
the gap between the simulated GDP per capita in 2014 from “Simul” with full variation of parameters and
that of “Neither” in figure 6.5 (which captures the whole effect of productivity and human capital growth) is
larger than the simulated income level in 2014 from “Average” in figure 6.3 (which captures the growth from
the constant rates of productivity and human capital growth at average values). This can happen because
the magnitude of the diminishing returns to capital investment changes over the capital accumulation
process, and it interacts with the fundamental growth parameters. During the initial stage of development
when the capital stock is not abundant relative to output (i.e., capital-output ratio is low), the magnitude
of diminishing return is not big, hence the size of the induced extra capital accumulation from productivity
growth would not be large. Such an interaction effect between capital and productivity becomes larger
as the capital-output ratio increases. From the growth accounting analysis in table 6.1, we discussed the
sequential feature of Korea’s growth such that productivity growth was accelerated after 1980 and became
the major engine of Korea’s growth. This is exactly the period when the speed of capital deepening started
to slow down so that the rapid 2.2% to 3.7% growth in productivity per annum during the 1980–2010
period, higher than the sample period average productivity growth rate at 1.9%, played an important role
of overcoming the diminishing returns to capital investment. This seems to be a critical reason behind the
sustained growth of Korea for six decades.
176
The Long Term Growth Model
The above calibrations use the long-run average rates of growth of human capital and productivity for the
entire period. The policy makers in 1970 might not have the precise estimates for the six-decade long-run
growth of productivity and human capital growth. For them, the best estimates would have been formed
by the adaptive expectation using the average values during the 1960–1970 period, which we used in cali-
bration 1 in the previous subsection. There we found that the model simulation “Pred_70” predicts much
lower than the actual data, and the discrepancy emerges very shortly after the beginning of simulation.
Then, from the viewpoint of the 1970 policy makers, it is an interesting exercise to predict what Korea’s
growth path would look like if Korea had implemented the growth policies of increasing the transitional
growth parameters for investment and labor force, maintaining the 1960–1970 growth rates of productivity
and human capital (gA = 0.8%, gh = 2.2%). Learning from the above counterfactual analysis that allowing
the time-varying transitional growth parameters improves the prediction performance of the model from
the above analysis, we may evaluate the effects of the time-varying promotion of the transitional growth
parameters at the time of 1970, when policy makers would use the estimates for the productivity and human
capital growth from the past data from the 1960–1970 period.
Figure 6.6 compares the predicted path of such simulation “Pred_70_C2” with that of conventional calibra-
tion “Pred_70_C1” (same as the “Pred_70” in figure 6.2). The gap between “Pred_70_C1” and “Pred_70_C2”
measures the expected effect of increasing the transitional growth parameters for investment and labor
force for the 1970 policy makers. Figure 6.6 suggests that the effect of such a transitional growth policy is
substantial. Furthermore, the model fit for the first decade or so after the prediction time is very close to the
data, which shows that the simple neoclassical growth model can be a good device for the policy makers for
the decade-period growth prediction. That is, the LTGM can be used for the policy makers of developing
countries in assessing the short- or medium-term growth effects from the promotion of investment and
labor force participation, based on the above analysis of Korea’s growth experience. A caveat here is that the
1960–1970 period human capital growth rate of 2.2% is higher than the entire sample period average of 1.5%.
Figure 6.6: Role of Time-Varying Transitional Growth for Policy Prescription in 1970
40,000
30,000
20,000
10,000
0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Year
Actual Pred_70_C1 Pred_70_C2
Note: “Actual”: Actual GDP per capita, “Pred_70_C1” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating both transitional and fundamental parameters at
constant values from the 1960–1970 data, and “Pred_70_C2” Predicted GDP per capita calibrating both fundamental parameters at constant
values from the 1960–1970 data but allowing time-varying values for transitional growth parameters.
Source: WDI and PWT 9.0
177
6. Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy
At the same time, however, we should emphasize that such a growth effect from the promotion of tran-
sitional growth parameters is conditional on sustaining the productivity and human capital growth at
fairly high rates, 0.8% and 2.2%, respectively. We already showed in figure 6.5 that turning off the engines
of fundamental growth could have made Korea’s growth performance negligible. So, it would be an error
for the 1970 policy makers to expect the substantial growth only from the investment and labor force
participation promotion. Furthermore, Korea’s stellar performance of growth was not simply based on
maintaining the 1960–1970 growth rates of productivity and human capital. The “Actual” GDP per capita
in 2014 (US$34,300) still exceeds the “Pred_70_C2” GDP per capita in 2014 (US$24,265) in a big order
of magnitude by US$10,000, which is attributed to the acceleration of productivity growth. Thus, we may
conclude that the proper advice for the 1970 policy makers (i.e., the policy makers of developing countries
where their GDP per capita levels are close to that of Korea in 1970) would be to bolster the fundamental
growth parameters, particularly, the productivity growth, together with the expansion of investment and
labor force.
5. Conclusion
Korea’s remarkable growth experience itself may inspire the developing world because Korea started such
development from the comprehensive set of adverse conditions (colonization, massive civil war, corruption,
lack of physical and human resources, political instability and incessant ideological conflicts, etc.) that are
often mentioned as critical barriers to development among the current developing countries. However,
without clarifying and quantifying what are actually behind such a growth process, Korea’s development
experience would be useless for other developing countries. This chapter attempted to provide such a quan-
titative analysis to shed light on the underlying mechanisms of Korea’s growth from the macroeconomic
perspective using the framework of the neoclassical growth model, which is the workhorse of the World
Bank’s LTGM project.
From the decomposition analysis, we found that the most important source of Korean economic
growth for the 1960–2014 period was productivity growth, contributing to the growth of GDP per
capita by 1.9% each year on average for 55 years. The second largest contributing component was
human capital accumulation (1.5% each year), and the capital deepening effect was the third (1.3%
each year). The labor market demographic compositional changes such as the increases in working-age
population share and labor force participation rate also contributed to the GDP per capita growth
substantially by 1.0% each year. These results show that the underlying sources of Korea’s growth
were fairly balanced among different growth components, while productivity growth was the main
driving force behind the scene. Furthermore, the major contributing components to growth evolved
over time from labor demography and human capital in the 1960s to capital deepening in the 1970s to
productivity growth for the following three decades. In particular, the accelerated productivity growth
after 1980 was a critical reason for the sustainable growth for Korea because such productivity growth
contributed to overcoming the force of diminishing returns to capital investment which has a tendency
to slow down the growth.
This picture is different from what many of the first generation of Korea’s development policy makers used
to have in mind, who would consider the human and physical capital accumulation as the main engines of
Korean growth. It was, in fact, the case in the 1960s and 1970s. In the 1960s, human capital growth, based
on rapid expansion of universal education at primary and secondary levels of schooling, was the main
engine of Korea’s growth. In the 1970s, capital deepening due to the increasing investment rate promoted by
export-oriented industrial policies indeed was the main engine of Korea’s growth. However, what bolstered
Korea’s sustaining growth throughout, particularly for the 1980–2010 period, was the productivity growth,
which has been rarely emphasized in most discourses about Korean economic growth.
178
The Long Term Growth Model
We characterized the important features of the LTGM as a simulated prediction or policy prescription tool,
by calibrating the model to Korea’s growth experience ex post in various ways. We found that conventional
calibration (assuming constant growth parameters) of the neoclassical growth model poorly fits Korea’s
growth path when Korean economy was in early transition periods. However, for the period after 1990 (when
we consider the Korean economy started to enter the stability period), even the conventional calibration of
the model predicts the actual growth fairly well. Even for the fast transition period before 1990, we found
that the model fits Korea’s growth path very well by allowing time-varying transitional growth parameters
(labor market demographic composition changes and investment rate) with maintaining fundamental
growth parameters (productivity and human capital growth rates) at constant values. Such goodness of fit
of the neoclassical growth model is a (pleasant) surprise because the model is not built to fit the data in a
reduced-form way. This tells us that the LTGM can provide a useful tool for policy guidance for the policy
makers in designing their growth policies.
Finally, our counterfactual calibration analysis suggests that the fundamental importance of productivity
and human capital for sustainable growth is confirmed by Korea’s growth experience, despite the significant
contribution of the promotion of investment and labor force expansion. This is the ultimate lesson from
Korea’s growth experience, which should be delivered to the policy makers of the developing countries that
aim to achieve such a miraculous transformation. This chapter leaves the studies about more concrete micro
mechanisms and policy measures behind for future research. The main contribution of this chapter is to
point where the priority of the development policy and strategy should be directed to, and to quantify its
effects on growth, based on Korea’s growth experience.
References
David, Paul. 1977. “Invention and accumulation of America’s economic growth: A nineteenth-century
parable,” Carnegie-Rochster Conference Series of Public Policy V. 6: 179–228.
Eichengreen, Barry, Donghyun Park, and Kwanho Shin. 2012. “When Fast-Growing Economies Slow Down:
International Evidence and Implications for China.” Asian Economic Papers V. 11(1): 42–87.
Feenstra, Robert C., Inklaar, Robert, and Timmer, Marcel P. 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World
Table” American Economic Review 105(10), 3150–3182.
Hall, Robert E., and Jones, and Charles I. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker
Than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics V. 114(1): 83–116.
Hevia, C., and N. Loayza. 2012, “Savings and Growth in Egypt.” Middle East Development Journal 4(1).
Jeong, Hyeok. 2017. “Korea’s Growth Experience and Long-Term Growth Model.” Policy Research Working Paper No.
8240, World Bank.
Jeong, Hyeok. 2018. “Analysis of Korea’s Long-Term Growth Process and Lessons for Sustainable Development Policy.”
The Korean Economic Review 34 (2): 237–265.
Jones, Charles (2002), “Sources of U.S. Growth in a World of Ideas,” American Economic Review, V. 92(1): 220-239.
Klenow, Peter J., and Rodriguez-Clare, Andres. 1997. “The Neoclassical Revival in Growth Economics: Has It Gone
Too Far?” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997 Cambridge, M.A., MIT Press, pp. 73–103.
Mankiw, Gregory, Romer, David, and Weil, David. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic
Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics V. 107(2): 407–437.
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics V. 22: 3–42.
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. 1993. “Making a Miracle.” Econometrica 61(2): 251–272.
Park, Donghyun, and Shin, Kwanho. 2011. “Impact of Population Aging on Asia’s Future Growth.” ADB Economics
Working Paper Series No. 281.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1):
65–94.
Uzawa, Hirofumi. 1961. “Neutral Inventions and Stability of Growth Equilibrium.” Review of Economic Studies
V. 28(2):117–124.
179
Chapter 7
Abstract
Bangladesh has achieved robust economic growth in order to sustain the high real GDP growth rate seen
for the last 10 years, with real gross domestic product in the recent past. The country will fail to achieve
(GDP) growing by more than 6 percent on average each high growth in the absence of strong TFP growth
year. This chapter investigates whether the country will despite meeting the levels of investment as outlined
be able to maintain such high levels of growth going in the 7th Five Year Plan. The model is also used to
forward. The chapter uses the Long Term Growth gain insights on government debt sustainability given
Model (LTGM), which is calibrated to the Bangladesh different growth scenarios. The analysis highlights the
economy to analyze various growth scenarios. The significance of meeting revenue targets in maintaining
main finding of the chapter is that it is crucial for sustainability, considering the planned expansion in
the country to focus on reforms to raise TFP growth expenditures.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 7952, originally published in January 2017.
E
Appendices are available in the working paper version, or at https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
2
Rishabh Sinha, World Bank. Email: rishabhsinha@worldbank.org. I am grateful to Afroza Alam, Hans Beck, Simon Davies, Ralph Van
Doorn, Zahid Hussain, Sheikh Tanjeb Islam, Frederico Sander, Muhammad Waheed, and workshop participants from the Ministry of
Finance, Bangladesh and the Bangladesh Bank for many useful insights and suggestions. The World Bank’s Long-Term Growth Model
(as in chapter 1) has been used extensively for the quantitative analysis presented in the paper. The findings, interpretations, and
conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International
Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the
World Bank or the governments they represent.
181
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
1. Introduction
Bangladesh has seen robust economic growth during the last decade with real GDP growing by more
than 6 percent on average every year during 2006–2015 (Figure 7.1). Additionally, the economy has seen
a long-term acceleration in growth since the late 1970s when the real GDP was growing by just over
4 percent annually. The acceleration in real GDP growth has also translated to an acceleration in real GDP
per capita growth, as the gap between real GDP growth and population growth has been widening over
time.3 Beginning from US$352 in 1980, real GDP per capita (measured in 2010 US dollars) crossed US$700
in 2008 and is on mark to cross US$1,000 next year. The sustained economic growth during the last few
decades has helped the country graduate from a low-income country to a lower-middle-income country
as classified by the World Bank (World Bank 2015).
To better understand the sustained growth achieved by the country, it is useful to explore how some of the
key growth drivers have evolved during this period. Capital accumulation has been a key driver of economic
growth for many countries, and Bangladesh is no exception to this phenomenon. Bangladesh has realized
a continued rise in the investment share of GDP during the last 35 years. The investment share of GDP has
almost doubled from 14.4 percent of GDP in 1980 to 28.9 percent of GDP in 2015 (Figure 7.2). Most of this
increase has been driven by gains in private investment. With respect to its Asian neighbors, the country
currently has a higher investment rate compared to Pakistan and Nepal but lags behind China and India.
The country has witnessed many changes in the labor market that have been important for growth. The
demographic transition has led to a decline in the dependency ratio with the share of the working-age pop-
ulation rising continuously over time. Starting from 52 percent of the total population in 1980, the working
age population share grew by more than 13 percentage points in the last 35 years (Figure 7.3). The growth
Figure 7.1: GDP and GDP per Capita Average Annual Growth Rate
6
Average annual growth rate (%)
–2
–4
–6
65
70
95
05
10
15
97
98
98
99
00
20
0
9
9
–2
–1
–1
–1
–1
–1
–1
–1
–2
–2
11–
71
81
66
61
91
76
86
06
01
96
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
19
3
Real GDP per capita saw negative growth during 1960–1980 but has been rising ever since.
182
The Long Term Growth Model
35
30
Investment Share of GDP (%)
25
20
15
10
0
81
83
85
87
89
91
93
95
97
99
01
03
05
07
09
11
13
15
20
20
19
20
19
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
19
19
19
20
20
20
Total Private
65
60
55
50
80
82
84
86
88
90
92
94
96
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
20
20
20
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
19
20
19
20
20
received further tailwind from increasing participation rates. The aggregate participation rate rose from
approximately 45 percent in the mid-1970s to over 60 percent in the 2010s, largely due to the massive jump
in the female labor force participation rate that grew from a low base of 12 percent in 1989 to 30 percent in
2013. What has been most encouraging is that not only the quantity but also the quality of labor resources
has been rising over time. The Penn World Table (PWT) human capital index for Bangladesh has grown by
more than 1.5 percent per year on average during 1990–2010.
Apart from growth in underlying factors of production— capital and labor—economic growth can also
be derived from advances in technology or through an efficient use of existing resources. The growth in
the productivity of resources, or Total Factor Productivity (TFP), has been an important driver of growth
183
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
for many countries.4 The TFP growth rate for Bangladesh during 2001–2011 has just been above zero,
implying that the strong growth seen during the period was not aided by either technology adoption or
through efficiency in resource allocation. On the other hand, India and China, who also realized healthy
economic growth during the same period, were aided significantly by productivity, with TFP growing by
1.3 percent and 2.9 percent on average each year, respectively. However, the uptick in TFP growth since
the later 2000s is encouraging, and continued reforms can help the country move into an era of sustained
positive TFP growth.
The important question going into the future is whether the country can continue on its path of accel-
erating growth or not. The goal is to identify areas that need reform and quantify the relative merit of
alternative growth strategies. Such an analysis will help isolate factors that are most likely to be the key
drivers of growth. The analysis uses the standard Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)—as in chapter 1 of
this volume—to answer these questions. The model uses investment, savings, and productivity as building
blocks and ties these variables to economic growth. The model also includes labor market forces that are
important in driving growth, together with an external sector through which additional investment can
be sourced. An important finding from the growth equation obtained after solving the model shows that
investment becomes less effective in generating growth with an increase in the capital-to-output ratio. This
implies that the same level of the investment share of output will generate lower growth if capital in the
economy is growing faster than output. Hence, an investment-led growth strategy in absence of reforms
that focus on growth of productivity, human capital, and participation will eventually run out of steam.
The model is calibrated for Bangladesh by matching some of the standard moments in the growth liter-
ature. An appealing feature of the model is that it is fairly parsimonious with regards to the parameters.
Nonetheless, robustness checks are performed around the parameter values used in the benchmark exercises.
The calibrated model is then used to perform several quantitative exercises that feature different scenarios
on how the drivers of growth evolve over time.
The main finding of the analysis is that for Bangladesh to sustain a high real GDP growth rate, it is essential
that the country focuses on reforms that drive TFP growth. An investment-led strategy that boosts the
investment share to 35 percent by 2020, coupled with improvements in the efficiency of public capital, will
deliver a GDP growth of 5 percent for the next decade. However, maintaining such a level of investment will
deliver lower than 5 percent GDP growth beyond 2025 in absence of TFP growth, as a high capital-to-output
ratio will make investment less and less productive in generating growth. Alternatively, a sustained high
GDP growth path in absence of TFP growth will require massive investments that exceed the levels targeted
by the government. More alarmingly, the required investments will soon reach levels that are unrealistic
to attain.
Finally, the model can also be used to infer what the implied growth paths spell for the sustainability
of the government debt position. The country has a low government debt to GDP ratio which stood at
34 percent at the end of 2015. The analysis finds that the government debt situation is sensitive to gov-
ernment operations and that meeting tax revenue targets is essential to keep the government debt to GDP
ratio in check. The government debt sustainability will face additional risk if the government overshoots
its expenditure without making much progress on the revenue front.
4
he estimated TFP growth series is usually volatile and is also sensitive to the method of estimation. TFP is estimated as a
T
residual after accounting for all factors of production, and the estimates across studies are bound to differ if they employ a
different production function or measure factors of production differently. For example, estimates of TFP will differ for a study
that accounts for human capital based on schooling compared to a study that does not account for human capital gains that
stem from schooling.
184
The Long Term Growth Model
where Kt is the aggregate capital stock, ht is the human capital per worker and Lt is the total number of
workers present in the economy. At denotes the common total factor productivity term that captures the
productivity of both factors of production. The time invariant parameter β is the aggregate labor share of
income. As seen from the production function, output growth can be achieved through three channels—
accumulation of capital resources, accumulation of labor resources, and productivity growth.
Accumulation of physical capital is realized via investment. The next period capital stock Kt+1 equals the
undepreciated portion of the previous period’s capital stock Kt together with the investment made in the
previous period It. The capital accumulation equation is given by
Kt+1 = (1 – δ)Kt + It (2)
where d represents the per period depreciation rate of physical capital.
The effective labor used in production is the product of human capital per worker ht and the total number
of workers Nt present in the economy. Human capital per worker determines the productivity of labor
resources and is assumed to increase with increases in years of schooling. The total number of workers
employed in production depends on population as well as the labor market. The total number of workers
employed can be written as
Lt = rt wt Nt (3)
where rt is the participation rate, wt is the working-age population to population ratio, and Nt is the total
population. Effective labor in the economy can grow as a result of either an increase in human capital per
worker or through an increase in the total number of workers. The total number of workers, in turn, can
increase via increases in participation rate, working-age population to population ratio, or population.
Equation (1) can be used to express the output in per capita terms. Dividing both sides of the equation by
total population yields
y tpc = ρ t ω t At kt1−β htβ (4)
where y tpc is the output per capita and Kt is the capital per worker. Equation (4) can be used to calculate
growth of output per capita from t to t + 1
1− β β
y tpc+1 ρ t +1 ω t +1 At +1 kt +1 ht +1
=
y tpc ρ t ω t At kt ht
(5)
which can be rewritten in terms of various growth rates from t to t + 1 as follows
(6)
where growth rate of a variable x from t to t + 1 is denoted by gx,t + 1.
185
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
In order to make analytical progress, the relationship between investment and capital per worker needs to
be established. The capital accumulation equation (2) can be written as
K t +1 Lt +1 Kt It
= (1 − δ ) +
Lt +1 Lt Lt Lt
Dividing both sides of the above equation by Kt writing in per worker terms and growth rates gives
It
Yt
(1 + g k ,t +1 )(1 + g N ,t +1 )(1 + g ρ ,t +1 )(1 + g ω ,t +1 ) = (1 − δ ) +
Kt
Yt
Rearranging the above equation so as to isolate the growth rate of capital per worker gk,t + 1 yields Equation (7)
below
It
(1 − δ ) + Yt
Kt
Yt
(1 + g k ,t +1 ) = (7)
(1 + g N ,t +1 ) (1 + g ρ ,t +1 ) (1 + g ω ,t +1 )
Equations (6) and (7) characterize the growth of the economy and are used for quantitative analysis.
However, before embarking on the quantitative exercises, it is important to understand what drives growth
in this model.
It
Y
g ypc,t +1 ≈ g A ,t +1 + β ( g ρ ,t +1 + g ω ,t +1 + g h ,t +1 ) + (1 − β ) t − δ − g N ,t +1 (8)
Kt
Yt
The above equation offers many insights regarding the drivers of growth. First, the TFP growth gA has the
largest direct effect on growth where a 1 percentage point increase in TFP leads to a 1 percentage point
increase in the growth rate of output per capita. Second, the production function parameter β plays an
important role in determining the relative importance of capital and labor growth in driving aggregate
growth. The larger the labor share of income, the more responsive is the output growth to increases in
participation rate, working-age population to population ratio, and human capital per worker. Conversely,
the larger the labor share of income, the lower the effect of capital accumulation in generating growth.
Finally, it is important to note that keeping all else constant, the same level of the investment share of output
can lead to different output growth rates depending on the level of capital-to-output ratio ( YK ) of the
economy. Investment becomes less effective as the capital-to-output ratio rises in the economy. This implies
that the same level of the investment share of output will generate lower growth if capital in the economy
grows faster than the output. Hence, an investment-led growth strategy in absence of reforms that focus on
growth of productivity, human capital, and participation will eventually run out of steam.
186
The Long Term Growth Model
In the next section, I begin with the quantitative analysis and examine various growth scenarios for the
country. The first step of the analysis requires the calibration of the model to the Bangladesh economy.
Following calibration of the model, the long-term growth scenarios for the country are considered by asking
two related questions. First, how much growth can be achieved under various reasonable paths of growth
drivers and second, what time paths of growth drivers, in particular investment, are essential to realize a
given growth path.
0.6
0.5
Labor Share of Income
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
Bangladesh LMI—mean LMI—median
5
See Hertel, Tsigas, and Narayanan (2002) on details regarding the calculation of labor shares in the GTAP database.
187
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
much higher rate of depreciation such as computers, software, and so forth. The aggregate depreciation
rate for the country is likely to inch upward as the capital mix shifts toward assets that have a higher
depreciation rate. The robustness exercises discuss the sensitivity of findings to the choice of higher
depreciation rates.
• Initial capital-to-output ratio: K 0 = 2.78. The initial capital-to-output ratio is calculated using the
Y0
capital stock and GDP data from the PWT 8.1. The most recent year for which data are available from
the PWT 8.1 is 2011 which is used to calculate the specified value of capital-to-output ratio. Figure 7.5
below compares the capital-to-output ratio of the country with some of its neighbors. The capital-to-
output ratio of the country is lower compared to China, driven by the fact that China has made massive
investments in capital stock over the last few decades. Though still in a range with other neighbors
except Nepal, the capital-to-output ratio is somewhat higher for Bangladesh. As seen in equation (8),
a higher value of capital-to-output ratio puts downward pressure on the growth impact from increasing
investment.
• Growth rate of human capital per worker: g = 1.3%. The historical trend in human capital index from
h
the PWT 8.1 provides guidance regarding the reasonable path of human capital per worker going forward.
The PWT 8.1 reports the index based on the Barro-Lee method that takes into account both the years
of schooling as well as returns on education. The PWT 8.1 data are available for the period 1990–2010.
After reaching a peak during the second half of the 1990s, the growth of human capital index has been on
a downward trend (Figure 7.6). The average growth rate stood just below 1.4 percent during the period
2006–2010. It seems likely that the growth rate of human capital will continue its gradual decline with
contributions from gains in primary education diminishing as it reaches absolute levels. As such, the
human capital per worker growth rate is assumed to be 1.3 percent per annum going into the future.
• Growth rate of TFP: gA = 0%. A TFP index for the country is calculated using the data and methodology
listed in PWT 8.1 and using the labor share of 0.51 obtained from the GTAP database. The growth rate
4.0
3.5
3.0
Capital-to-output ratio
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0
Bangladesh China India Nepal Pakistan Sri Lanka
188
The Long Term Growth Model
of TFP is generally volatile, and it is also true for the case of Bangladesh as seen in figure 7.7. The TFP
was on an upward trend from the 1980s till it suddenly dropped in 2001. After remaining in the negative
territory for another two years, the TFP growth started trending upwards again. The average growth
rate of TFP during 1991–2011 has barely managed to remain in the positive territory. Given the volatile
nature of TFP growth and the average recorded for the 1991–2011 period, it is assumed that the country
will not experience any meaningful TFP growth in the long term.
• Growth rate of population: gN. The population projections have been sourced from the World Bank’s
Human Development Network estimates. According to the Human Development Network, the annual
population growth rate for the country will decline from the present 1.2 percent to 1.0 percent by 2021
and 0.7 percent by 2030.
• Growth rate of working-age population to population ratio: gw. In addition to the population forecasts,
the Human Development Network also provides projections for the working-age population of men
and women separately (Figure 7.8). The projections indicate that the aggregate working-age population
to population ratio in Bangladesh will continue to rise and reach almost 70 percent by the year 2030, a
gain of 4 percentage points from the current levels.
There are two more time paths that are needed to run the growth simulations— investment share of GDP
It
and participation rate (rt). Both these drivers of growth are expected to play a big role going forward
Yt
and have been identified as such by the policy makers. For this reason, I consider different scenarios for
their time paths that help in identifying their relative importance.
I
• Investment share of GDP: Ytt . Bangladesh has realized a continued increase in the investment share
of GDP during the last 35 years. The investment share of GDP has almost doubled from 1980 to 2015,
with most of the increases coming from private investment. Needless to say, capital accumulation has
been an important driver of growth in the country. This point is illustrated in figure 7.9, which shows
the average GDP per capita growth rate during 2011–2015 against the average investment share during
the same period for more than 200 countries for which data are available from the World Development
2.0
Growth rate of human capital index (%)
1.5
1.0
0.5
0
1991–1995 1996–2000 2001–2005 2006–2010
189
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
1
Growth rate of TFP (%)
-1
-2
-3
1991–2011 average
-4
-5
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
1.4 70
1.0
68
0.8
67
0.6
66
0.4
0.2 65
0 64
6
18
19
20
21
22
23
27
28
29
30
1
2
1
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Indicators database.6 The relationship between the two variables is positive and highly significant.
However, a more important question is whether capital accumulation can deliver a sustainable high
level of growth going into the future.
Average investment as a share of GDP for the country during 2011–2015 was upwards of 28 percent, and
the country delivered higher growth than what is expected at that level of investment. The country has a
higher investment rate compared to Pakistan and Nepal but lags behind China and India. This suggests
6
Note that for some countries data for 2015 are not available, in which case the average reflects the average during 2011–2014.
190
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 7.9: Average GDP per Capita growth versus Average Investment Share of GDP
Correlation = 0.37***
10
Average GDP per Capita Growth., 2011–2015 (%)
CHN
BGD
LKA IND
5
NPL
PAK
–5
–10
0 20 40 60
Average Investment Share of GDP, 2011–2015 (%)
50
40
Investment share of GDP (%)
30
20
10
0
Bangladesh China* India** Nepal** Pakistan Sri Lanka
Aggregate Private Public
that the country has some room to expand its investment share of GDP. However, as can be seen from
figure 7.10, the deficit in investment share with respect to India is not due to low public investment in
Bangladesh. Average public investment as a share of GDP during 201 2014 outpaced that of India by more
than 2.5 percentage points. The targets from the 7th Five Year Plan are used to chart a reasonable path of
investment. Specifically, I assume that the aggregate investment share of GDP increases from the present
levels to 34.4 percent of GDP by the year 2020 and remains at that level beyond 2020. This is based on the
plan targets on public investment, which rises from 6.5 percent of GDP in 2016 to 7.8 percent of GDP by the
191
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
year 2020. This implies that private investment as a share of GDP expands by approximately 3 percentage
points to reach 26.6 percent by 2020. I assume that both public and private investment continue to remain
at the same level beyond 2020.
With regards to investment, there is a concern that public investment is not as efficient as private investment.
This means that a percentage point expansion in public investment will deliver lower growth compared to
a percentage point expansion in private investment. On the other hand, it is possible to generate additional
growth by increasing the efficiency of public investment. To capture the differences in efficiency across
public and private investment, it is assumed that a unit of public investment I tG equals only a fraction
q ∈ (0,1) of private investment I tP which is perfectly efficient. The total effective investment It is given by
I t = qI tG + I tP (9)
There are many studies that have studied the efficiency of the public sector (for example Afonso et al. 2005,
2010). The quantitative findings from these studies can be used to discipline the parameter governing
the efficiency of public investment q. Afonso, Schuknecht, and Tanzi (2010) report that for the sample
countries, the same level of public sector output can be produced using 41 percent less resources on average.
This implies a capital efficiency of 59 percent. The efficiency of public investment for Bangladesh is assumed
to be a bit lower than the mean efficiency at 55 percent because the developing countries in the sample have
lower efficiency rates.
• Participation rate: ρ . The aggregate participation rate is the weighted average of the male and female
t
participation rates. The male labor force participation rate in the country has remained near 80 percent
for many decades and is similar to what is observed in many countries worldwide. On the other hand,
the female labor force participation stands at 34 percent and has considerable room for improvement.
The country has achieved around a 10 percentage point increase in female labor force participation
during the last decade and provides a basis for further expansion going forward. However, I analyze the
prospective expansion in the female labor force participation separately in order to isolate its impact
on growth.
I construct the following four scenarios in order to quantify the growth impact of improvements in invest-
ment and female labor force participation. Note that all other variables, such as growth rate of human
capital per worker, growth rate of TFP, and so forth are unchanged across scenarios and follow the time
path as previously defined.
• Baseline Scenario: Public and private investment share of GDP rises according to 7th Five Year Plan
targets till 2020 and remains at the 2020 level going forward. The efficiency of public investment remains
at 0.55 throughout and there is no change in the female labor force participation rate.
• Efficiency Scenario: Public and private investment follow the same path as in the Baseline Scenario,
and the efficiency of public investment grows linearly from 0.55 in 2015 to 1.00 in 2020. There is no
change in the female labor force participation rate.
• Participation Scenario: Public and private investment follow the same path as in the Baseline Scenario,
and the female labor force participation rate grows linearly from 34 percent in 2015 to 45 percent in
2020. There is no change in the efficiency of public investment.
• Efficiency + Participation Scenario: Public and private investment follow the same path as in the
Baseline Scenario, and the efficiency of public investment grows linearly from 0.55 in 2015 to 1.00 in
2020. The female labor force participation rate also grows linearly from 34 percent in 2015 to 45 percent
in 2020.
The simulation results corresponding to the four scenarios are shown in figure 7.11. Apart from demo-
graphic changes, the only drivers of growth operating in the Baseline Scenario are capital accumulation
and growth of human capital per worker. The GDP growth rate increases marginally till 2021, driven by an
192
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 7.11: GDP Growth under Baseline, Efficiency, Participation and Efficiency & Participation
Scenarios
Real GDP growth (%) baseline scenario Real GDP growth (%) efficiency scenario
10 10
9 9
Plan target Plan target
8 8
7 7
6 6
5 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
16
20 7
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
23
24
25
26
20 7
28
20 9
30
16
17
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
23
24
25
26
20 7
28
29
30
2
2
1
2
1
2
1
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Real GDP growth (%) participation scenario Real GDP growth (%) efficiency +
participation scenario
10 10
9 9
Plan target Plan target
8 8
7 7
6 6
5 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
6
17
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
23
24
25
26
20 7
28
29
30
16
17
18
19
20
20 1
22
23
24
25
26
20 7
28
29
30
2
2
2
2
1
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
expanding investment share of GDP. The GDP growth rate remains below the 5 percent mark for the entire
period till 2021. The growth rate starts declining past 2021 and falls below 4 percent in 2028. In addition to
the forces driving growth in the Baseline Scenario, the linear rise to efficiency of public investment provides
a further push to economic growth. Similar to the Baseline Scenario, the growth rate increases till 2021 and
is slightly higher than the Baseline Scenario. The GDP growth rate peaks in 2021 under both scenarios, at
which time the growth under the Efficiency Scenario outperforms the growth under the Baseline Scenario
by more than one-half a percentage point. Even though public investment is a small share of the aggregate
investment, an increase in its efficiency has a non-trivial impact on economic growth.
The efficiency of public investment is unchanged under the Participation Scenario. Instead, the aggregate
participation rate rises, driven by improvements in female labor force participation. The growth rate under
the Participation Scenario rises somewhat till 2020 and its behavior is very similar to the growth under
the Baseline Scenario. However, the linear increase in the female labor force participation rate means that
growth is higher compared to the Baseline Scenario. The 11 percentage point increase in female labor
force participation spread across five years on average adds more than 1 percentage point to GDP growth
each year. The growth rate declines by about 75 basis points in 2021, as growth in the participation rate
193
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
comes to an end. Like the previous scenarios, the growth rate continues to decline gradually and falls
below 4 percent by 2029. The last scenario considers the joint impact of improvements in the efficiency
of public capital and female labor force participation rate. Similar to the Efficiency Scenario, the growth
rate increases faster compared to the Baseline and Participation scenarios. In addition, the growth rate
starts at a higher level, owing to the impact from the higher participation rate. The growth rate declines
gradually beginning in 2022, but unlike previous scenarios the growth rate manages to remain above the
4 percent mark by 2030.
An important point to consider here is that the growth rate under all scenarios starts declining after the
first few years. Equation (8) illustrates why this happens. Keeping everything constant, an increase in the
capital-to-output ratio will lead to lower growth. This means that if capital is growing faster than output,
the growth rate will be on a downward trajectory. Figure 7.12 plots the capital-to-output ratio for the
different scenarios. Note that the capital-to-output ratio is increasing throughout for every single scenario.
This rising capital-to-output ratio creates drag on the growth rate. In the first few years, the negative impact
of the rising capital-to-output ratio is offset by increases in investment share, efficiency of public capital,
and/or female labor force participation. However, as these sources cease to operate in the later years, the
rising capital-to-output ratio chips away at the growth rate. In this respect, it is important to understand a
secondary role of growth drivers other than investment. Not only do these drivers of growth create growth
directly, they also provide downward pressure on the capital-to-output ratio. In this way, they indirectly
ensure that investment remains relatively productive in generating growth.
Figure 7.12: Capital-to-Output Ratio under Baseline, Efficiency, Participation and Efficiency &
Participation Scenarios
3.9
3.7
3.5
Capital-to-output ratio
3.3
3.1
2.9
2.7
2.5
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
23
24
25
27
28
30
2
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
194
The Long Term Growth Model
noted in equation (8) the TFP growth has the largest direct effect on growth, where a 1 percentage point
increase in TFP leads to a 1 percentage point increase in the growth rate of output per capita, and second,
a growth in TFP adds to output without changing the level of capital in the economy, thereby pushing
the capital-to-output ratio down and making investment more productive. While the average annual TFP
growth in the country during 2001–2011 has barely been upwards of zero, the upward trend during the
period suggests that the country can achieve a positive TFP growth rate for an extended period of time if
appropriate reforms are enacted. Two additional growth scenarios are carried out to quantify the impact of
TFP growth on economic growth:
Figure 7.13: GDP growth under Baseline, E+P, High Growth I & II scenarios
8 Plan target
7
High growth II
6
E+P High growth I
5
4
Baseline
3
2
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
7
he estimated average annual TFP growth for Bangladesh during the period ranged between 0.1–0.5 percent across the various
T
methods considered by the authors.
195
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
Figure 7.14: Capital-to-Output Ratio under Baseline, E+P, High Growth I & II scenarios
3.9
3.7
3.5
Capital-to-output ratio
3.3
3.1
2.9
2.7
2.5
30
19
20
23
26
28
29
16
18
22
24
25
15
27
17
21
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Baseline E+F HG 1 HG 2
Table 7.1: Average Annual Real GDP Growth under Different Scenarios
is above the plan target when TFP grows by 1.5 percent per year. The average annual growth rate under
High Growth Scenario II during the plan period outpaces the average annual plan growth rate by more
than 30 basis points. The growth rate remains above the 7.0 percent mark for many years and does not fall
below 6.5 percent even after 15 years. Table 7.1 summarizes the growth outcomes under various scenarios.
It is interesting to note that the difference in average growth rates between High Growth Scenarios I
and II, and the Efficiency + Participation Scenario increases with time. This happens because the gap in
capital-to-output ratios between the former and the latter increases with time as additional growth achieved
via TFP increases, which does not add to capital accumulation (Figure 7.14).
In summary, sustaining a high growth rate requires a sustained increase in TFP growth. An investment-led
strategy coupled with improvements in efficiency of public capital will deliver a growth of 5 percent for
the next decade. However, maintaining an investment share of GDP beyond 2025 will deliver lower than a
5 percent growth as capital-to-output ratios keep growing, making investment less productive.
196
The Long Term Growth Model
• Baseline Scenario: All variables, for example the growth rate of human capital per worker, follow the
same path as in the Baseline Scenario of the previous exercise. Note that the investment share of GDP,
which was an input in the previous exercise, is the output of this exercise.
• Participation Scenario: Except for the female labor force participation rate, all other variables follow
the same path as in the Baseline Scenario. The female labor force participation rate grows linearly from
34 percent in 2015 to 45 percent in 2020.
• High Growth Scenario I: Except for TFP growth, all other variables follow the same path as in the
Participation Scenario. TFP grows by 1.0 percent each year.
• High Growth Scenario II: Except for TFP growth, all other variables follow the same path as in the
Participation Scenario. TFP grows by 1.5 percent each year.
The results of the simulation are shown in figure 7.15. Barring demographic changes, the only driver
of growth operating in the Baseline Scenario is the growth of human capital per worker. The previous
exercise showed that the 7th Five Year Plan targets will fail to deliver planned GDP growth under the
Baseline Scenario. Not surprisingly, figure 7.15 shows that the required investment share of GDP that
delivers planned growth overshoots planned investment. However, the more important finding is the stark
gap in required investment and planned investment. The required investment share of GDP exceeds the
planned investment share by more than 13 percentage points in 2016 and rises steadily to cross 25 percent
by 2020. The required investment share rises fast over time and reaches unfeasible levels soon and reaches
almost 65 percent by 2022. The gap between the required investment and planned investment is somewhat
lower under the Participation Scenario as steady increases in the female labor force participation rate
share the burden of delivering high desired growth. Yet, the require investment share of GDP exceeds the
planned investment share significantly, and the gap between the two cross the 20 percent mark in 2020.
Though lower than the required investment share in the Baseline Scenario, the investment share under the
Participation Scenario also reaches unfeasible levels soon enough and crosses the 65 percent mark in 2024.
These results suggest that targeting sustainable GDP growth rates in the 7–8 percent range via boosting
investment without TFP growth is bound to result in disappointment.
Like in the previous section, the quantitative findings here are to inform that high TFP growth is
essential if high levels of GDP growth are to be achieved, as TFP growth keeps required investment
within feasible limits. The required investment share of GDP is close to planned investment share when
TFP grows by 1.5 percent each year. In fact, barring the last plan year, the planned investment share
exceeds or remains close to the required investment share. The growth of the required investment share
is muted in the presence of TFP growth compared to the earlier two scenarios as TFP growth keeps the
capital-to-output ratio low, thereby maintaining the productivity of expanding capital stock. However,
sustaining 8 percent growth for a long period of time may still prove challenging, as the required
investment share crosses 60 percent of GDP and reaches almost 50 percent of GDP under High Growth
Scenarios I and II, respectively.
197
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
Figure 7.15: Required Investment Share of GDP under Baseline, Participation and High Growth I
& II Scenarios
70 70
60 60
50 50
40 40
Plan target Plan target
30 30
20 20
30
20 5
20 6
20 7
28
20 9
15
20 1
22
20 3
24
16
20 7
18
20 9
20
15
16
17
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
20 3
20 4
25
20 6
20 7
28
20 9
30
2
2
2
1
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Required investment share of GDP (%) Required investment share of GDP (%)
High growth I & II
80 80
70 70
60 60
50 50
40 40
Plan target Plan target
30 30
20 20
15
16
20 7
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
20 3
24
20 5
20 6
20 7
28
20 9
30
15
16
20 7
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
20 3
24
20 5
26
20 7
28
20 9
30
2
2
1
2
2
2
2
2
1
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
198
The Long Term Growth Model
Equation (10) suggests that investment can be greater than national savings if the economy is able to run a
current account deficit. The current account balance can be further decomposed as the acquisition of net
foreign assets NFAt less the incurrence of net foreign liabilities NFLt:
For simplicity, it is assumed that there are no changes in the stock of net foreign assets (DNFAt = 0).
The change in net foreign liabilities equals the flow of foreign direct investment FDIt augmented by the
accumulation of the external debt during the period. Incorporating these in the previous equation gives:
Substituting the value of CABt from equation (11) in equation (10) and dividing both sides by Yt yields the
relationship between investment, national savings, and the external sector in terms of share of GDP:
Dt −1
I t St FDI t Dt Yt −1 (12)
= + + −
Yt Yt Yt Yt (1 + g ypc,t ) (1 + g N ,t )
Equation (12) captures the fact that investment can be boosted via three channels—increase in national
savings, increase in foreign direct investment, and increase in external debt.
The time paths of national savings, foreign direct investment, and external debt are taken from the 7th Five
Year Plan targets which are summarized below:
• Starting from 29.0 percent in 2015, savings to GDP rises to 31.9 percent by 2020
• Starting from 0.9 percent in 2015, FDI to GDP rises to 3.0 percent by 2020
• Starting from 25.1 percent in 2015, external debt to GDP rises to 37.4 percent by 2020
All the above variables are assumed to remain at the 2020 level from that year onward. Like in the previ-
ous section, four alternative growth scenarios are considered—Baseline, Participation, and High Growth
Scenarios I and II.
Figure 7.16 shows the GDP growth paths under different scenarios when investment responds to the exter-
nal sector. The behavior of growth paths under various scenarios is very similar to the behavior seen earlier
in section 3.1. An aspect of difference is the sudden jump in growth rate in 2017, which was absent in the
previous case. This happens because the GDP growth during 2016 is a function of investment made in the
previous year, which is the same across the two exercises. Investment becomes responsive to the external
sector beginning in 2016, which has a one period delayed impact on growth that shows as the initial bump.
Under the Baseline Scenario, the GDP growth rate crosses the 6 percent mark in two intermediate plan
years and averages 5.7 percent during the entire plan period. The growth rate starts declining past 2021
and remains just above 4 percent by 2030. As expected, the growth rate under the Participation Scenario
is higher compared to the Baseline Scenario and exceeds it by around 1 percentage point during each of
the plan years. The growth rate declines by about 80 basis points in 2021 as the growth in the participation
rate comes to an end. The growth rate continues to decline gradually and is just 10 basis points above the
growth rate under the Baseline Scenario in 2030. With an annual TFP growth rate of 1 percent, the GDP
growth rate breaches the 8 percent mark in 2017 and averages just below 8 percent during 2016–2020. The
GDP growth rate declines past 2020 as the female labor force participation rate stabilizes. Yet, the growth
rate remains above 6.5 percent for many periods. The implied growth rate is above the plan target when TFP
grows by 1.5 percent per year. The average annual growth rate under the High Growth II Scenario during
199
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
Figure 7.16: GDP Growth under Baseline, Participation and High Growth Scenarios when
Investment Responds to External Sector
Real GDP growth (%) baseline Real GDP growth (%) baseline
10 10
9 9
7 7
6 6
5 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
16
17
18
19
20
20 1
22
20 3
24
20 5
26
20 7
28
20 9
30
16
17
18
20 9
20
20 1
22
20 3
24
20 5
26
20 7
28
20 9
30
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Real GDP growth (%) high growth I and II Real GDP growth (%)
10 10
9 9
7 7
High growth II
6 6
5 High growth I 5
4 4
3 3
2 2
20 9
20
20 8
20 9
20
20 8
18
22
23
20 6
20 9
30
18
22
23
20 6
29
30
16
24
20 5
16
24
20 5
20 1
20 7
20 1
27
17
17
2
2
2
2
1
1
2
2
2
2
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
the plan period outpaces the average annual plan growth rate by more than 1 percentage point during most
of the plan years. The growth rate remains above the 7.0 percent mark till 2026 and does not fall below
6.5 percent even after 15 years.
The implied investment share of GDP obtained using equation (12) is higher than the investment shares
used in section 3.1. While the national savings as a share of GDP is lower than the investment share, even
under the assumption that public capital is perfectly efficient (q = 1), this is more than offset by the foreign
direct investment (FDI) assumed to flow in each year. With an expanding external debt to GDP ratio,
the implied investment share becomes even larger compared to the assumed path of investment share in
section 3.1. This implies that the obtained growth path for a particular scenario will be higher compared to
the corresponding scenario in which the investment is independent of changes in the external sector. This
can also be seen by comparing the five year average rates shown in table 7.2 to the corresponding table 7.1
presented in section 3.1.
In summary, all exercises underline the importance of a sustained high TFP growth in attaining a sustained
high GDP growth. An investment-led strategy by itself will not be able to deliver high growth for many years
as, without other factors driving growth, a resulting increase in capital-to-output ratio will keep chipping
200
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 7.2: Average Annual Real GDP Growth under Different Scenarios
at the growth impact of investment. Given the importance of TFP growth, it is essential to identify factors
that can generate high TFP growth growing forward. In the next section, I examine the quantitative impact
of one such factor—a more efficient allocation of existing resources across sectors.8
8
lease see appendix A.2 for a brief discussion on factors that are important in driving TFP growth. This discussion is a summary
P
of the survey on productivity by Syverson (2011). The interested reader should read the paper, as the discussion here highlights
only some of the important factors that can lead to productivity growth and in no way provides a comprehensive listing of such
factors.
201
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
Table 7.3: Marginal Labor Productivity in Industry and Services (relative to Agriculture)
12
10
Taxes relative to agriculture
0
2000 2005 2010 2015
Services Industry
that restrict movement of resources across sectors. The distortions disappear if there are no frictions to
movement of resources across sectors. To the extent that these distortions are positive for a particular sector,
when measured relative to agriculture, they imply a barrier to movement of resources out of agriculture
and vice versa. Figure 7.17 plots these taxes for industry and services relative to agriculture. The trend in
distortions captures the trend in marginal productivity gaps seen in table 7.3.
In order to quantify the gains from a better resource allocation, I perform a simple counterfactual exercise.
I ask how much economic growth can be achieved by Bangladesh if the present level of distortions in the
country are changed to what is observed in peer countries.9 Table 7.4 below reports the counterfactual
growth in real GDP per capita, together with distortions that deliver this growth. Real GDP per capita
will more than double if the distortions in the country are reduced to the levels observed in China. On
the other hand, real GDP per capita has the potential to increase by about 20 percent if distortions equal
what is observed in India, which has a similar level of distortions in industry but much lower distortions
in services.
In the next section, I discuss how fiscal policy can be incorporated in the model and analyze different growth
scenarios in terms of sustainability of the government debt position.
9
The estimates of distortions for peer countries have been taken from Sinha (2016).
202
The Long Term Growth Model
Dividing both sides of the above equation by GDP next period Yt+1 and using the growth rates, the following
debt accumulation equation is obtained that features variables as a fraction of GDP and the growth rates
previously considered.
203
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
The simulations in section 3.1 outline the various growth scenarios for the economy. Under the Baseline
Scenario, the annual GDP growth rate for the next 15 years varies in the range of 4–5 percent, whereas
under the most optimistic High Growth Scenario II the annual GDP growth rate varies in the range of
6.5–8.5 range. An interesting question in this regard is whether such a huge variation in growth rates spells
remarkably different implications with regards to the government debt position or not. To make quanti-
tative progress on this front, the time path of government operations needs to be fed into equations (13)
and (14). In the spirit of previous sections, the 7th Five Year Plan projections for government operations are
used till 2020 after which the variables are assumed to remain at the level targeted in 2020. The assumptions
on government operations are summarized below:10
• Starting from 9.3 percent in 2015, tax revenue reaches 14.1 percent of GDP by 2020
• Starting from 1.5 percent in 2015, non-tax revenue reaches 2.0 percent of GDP by 2020
• Starting from 10.5 percent in 2015, current expenditures reach 13.9 percent of GDP by 2020
• Starting from 2.0 percent in 2015, interest payment reaches 2.5 percent of GDP by 2020
• Starting from 6.9 percent in 2015, government capital expenditure reaches 7.8 percent of GDP by 2020 11
The analysis of fiscal policy is carried out for the scenarios listed in section 3.1. Note that in all the scenarios
aggregate investment remained the same, while the effective investment differed depending on the efficiency
of public capital. Figure 7.18 plots the time path of the government debt to GDP ratio for the different
scenarios. The government debt to GDP ratio rises steadily over time as the growth rate of GDP outpaces
the growth rate of government debt. The debt ratio rises slower across different scenarios as the growth
rate of GDP increases. Under the High Growth Scenario II that features a 1.5 percent annual increase of
TFP, the debt ratio rises slowest and reaches just above 63 percent by 2030. In contrast, the debt ratio rises
fastest under the Baseline Scenario and closes on the 80 percent mark by 2030. Yet, the government debt
situation remains sustainable across all scenarios.
Figure 7.18: Government Debt to GDP under Baseline and other Growth Scenarios
110
90
70
50
30
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
28
29
27
30
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Baseline E+F HG 1 HG 2
10
Intermediate year values for all variables correspond to what has been targeted in the Seventh Five Year Plan.
11
This is consistent with the inputs provided in section 3.1.
204
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 7.19: Government Debt to GDP under Baseline, and other Growth Scenarios
(with tax revenue at 9.3 percent)
110
90
70
50
30
19
16
17
18
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Baseline E+F HG 1 HG 2
The discussion above suggests that the sustainability of government debt is a foregone conclusion, as it
remains sustainable even if the economy experiences tepid growth going forward. However, such a conclu-
sion overlooks the fact that the debt situation is closely tied to government operations and is not determined
only by economic growth. To test whether debt sustainability faces risks if the underlying conditions of
government operations are not met, I conduct a simple counterfactual. Specifically, I analyze the risks
of government not meeting the tax revenue targets as laid out in the 7th Five Year Plan with regards to
the debt situation. Keeping all else the same, I assume that the tax revenue to GDP ratio fails to improve
going forward and stays at 9.3 percent. Figure 7.19 illustrates the sharp contrast to the findings above.
Like figure 7.18 before, the government debt to GDP ratio is increasing under each scenario but is rising
at a much faster rate. The government debt surpasses GDP by 2030 even under the most optimistic High
Growth II Scenario and lies just below 125 percent of GDP under the Baseline Scenario.
The debt ratio reaches alarming levels if the revenue targets are not met. Such high debt ratios might bring
the sustainability of government debt under serious threat. The exercise shows that the government debt
situation is sensitive to government operations and that meeting tax revenue targets is essential in keeping
the government debt to GDP ratio in check. The government debt sustainability will face additional risk if
the government overshoots its expenditure without making much progress on the revenue front.
6. Conclusion
Bangladesh has achieved a robust economic growth for the last 10 years, with real GDP growing by more
than 6 percent on average each year. The magnitude of GDP growth has also come a long way from the
4 percent average annual growth rate of the late 1970s. The economic growth has also coincided with other
favorable development outcomes like poverty reduction, literacy growth, etc. However, the more important
question going forward is whether the country can maintain high levels of growth seen in the last decade
and, if possible, accelerate the growth rate. To quantify the long-term growth prospects of the country, this
chapter uses the Long Term Growth Model (as in chapter 1 of this volume). The model is calibrated to
match key moments of the Bangladesh economy, and the calibrated model is then used to analyze various
growth scenarios.
205
7. Long-Term Growth Scenarios for Bangladesh
The main finding of the analysis is that for Bangladesh to sustain a high real GDP growth rate, the country
must focus on reforms that drive TFP growth. Even if Bangladesh manages to meet the levels of investment
as outlined in the 7th Five Year Plan, it will fail to maintain GDP growth rates achieved in the past decade
without a corresponding support from TFP growth. This also means that attaining high GDP growth in the
absence of growth in TFP will require investments much higher than planned levels that surpass realistic
thresholds very soon.
An important factor that can provide a modest but meaningful contribution to economic growth in the
medium term is the growth in female labor force participation. The country has made significant progress
in raising the female labor force participation, but there is still massive scope for improvement. An 11 per-
centage point increase in the female labor force participation rate spread over the next five years can add
more than 1 percentage point to GDP growth on average each year.
The model is also used to gain insights on government debt sustainability given different growth scenarios.
The analysis highlights the significance of meeting revenue targets while considering the expansion in
expenditures. While the government debt for Bangladesh stands at a benign level, it has the potential to
rise to cross the level of the country’s GDP in the next 15 years if the revenue targets are not met. The
sustainability of government debt will come under additional pressure if the actual expenditure overshoots
the already increasing planned expenditure.
Appendices are available in Working Paper WPS 7952, or at https://www.worldbank.org/LTGM.
References
Afonso, A., L. Schuknecht, and V. Tanzi. 2005. “Public Sector Efficiency: An International Comparison.” Public
choice 123(3-4): 321–347.
Afonso, A., L. Schuknecht, and V. Tanzi. 2010. “Public Sector Efficiency: Evidence for New EU Member States and
Emerging Markets.” Applied Economics 42(17): 2147–2164.
Bernanke, B. S., and R. S. Gurnayak 2002. “Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer, and Weil Seriously.” Handbook
of Economic Growth Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, eds. Volume 1A: 473–552, Amsterdam:North-Holland.
Feenstra, R. C., R. Inklaar, and M. P. Timmer 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.” American
Economic Review 105(10): 3150–3182, available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt.
Hertel, T. W., M. Tsigas, and B. G. Narayanan. 2002. “Primary factor shares.” Global Trade, Assistance, and Production:
The GTAP 5 Data Base.
Narayanan, B., A. Aguiar, and R. McDougall. 2015. “Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 9 Data Base.”
Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.
Planning Commission, Bangladesh 2015. “7th Five Year Plan, FY2016–FY2020: Accelerating Growth, Empowering
Citizens.” General Economics Division, Planning Commission, Government of the People’s Republic of Bangladesh.
Sinha, R. 2016. “Sectoral Productivity Gaps and Aggregate Productivity.” Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS 7737,
World Bank Group, Washington, DC.
Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94.
Syverson, C. 2011. “What Determines Productivity?” Journal of Economic Literature 49(2): 362–365.
Swan, T. 1956. “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation.” Economic Record 32: 334–361.
World Bank. 2015. “WB Update Says 10 Countries Move Up in Income Bracket.” Press Release: July 1, 2015,
The World Bank.
World Development Indicators Database 2016. The World Bank.
206
Chapter 8
Abstract
This chapter addresses three questions: (i) what would the assumed levels of reconstruction assistance, repa-
have been the growth and income trajectory of Syria in triation of refugees, and productivity improvements
the absence of war; (ii) given the war, what explains the associated with three political settlement outcomes: a
reduction in economic growth; and (iii) what potential baseline (Sochi-plus) moderate scenario, an optimistic
growth scenarios for Syria could there be in the after- (robust political settlement) scenario, and a pessimistic
math of war? Conflict impact estimates point to neg- (de facto balance of power) scenario. Respectively for
ative gross domestic product (GDP) growth of –12% these scenarios, GDP per capita average growth in the
on average over 2011–2018, with output contracting next two decades is projected to be 6.1%, 8.2%, or 3.1%,
to about one-third of the 2010 level. In post-conflict respectively, assuming a final and stable resolution of
simulation scenarios, the growth drivers are affected by the conflict.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of Sharmila Devadas, Ibrahim Elbadawi, and Norman V. Loayza. 2021. “Growth in Syria: losses
E
from the war and potential recovery in the aftermath.” Middle East Development Journal 13: 2, 215–244 with an earlier version as
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 8967. Appendixes are available at the journal website: https://doi.org/10.1080/17938
120.2021.1930829. Affiliations are based on when the paper was written, not necessarily current affiliations.
2
S harmila Devadas, World Bank; Ibrahim Elbadawi, Economic Research Forum; Norman V. Loayza, World Bank. Corresponding
author email: nloayza@worldbank.org. The paper represents the views of the authors and does not necessarily reflect those of the
World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. The authors are grateful to staff of the United Nations Economic
and Social Commission for Western Asia, including Ahmad Shikh Ebid for sharing information and data, as well as to Shanta
Devarajan, Young Eun Kim, Aart Kraay, Aljaz Kuncic, Rabie Nasser, Khalid Abu-Ismail, and the reviewers and editor of MEDJ for
helpful comments. Nurlina Shaharuddin and Izzati Ab Razak provided excellent research assistance. All remaining errors are the
responsibility of the authors.
207
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
1. Introduction
This chapter addresses three questions. First, what would have been the growth and income trajectory
of Syria in the absence of war? Second, given the war, what explains the reduction in economic growth
in terms of growth drivers— physical capital, demographics and the labor force, human capital, and
total factor productivity? And third, what potential growth scenarios for Syria could there be in the
aftermath of war given various assumptions on key growth drivers? Post-conflict, these growth drivers
will be affected by the levels of reconstruction assistance and repatriation of refugees, driven, in turn, by
potential political settlement outcomes. To obtain plausible quantitative answers to these three questions,
the chapter uses an extension of the World Bank Long Term Growth Model (LTGM) that accounts for
the role of fundamental growth drivers in a clear and straightforward way. The chapter builds on data
and insights by academic researchers and international organizations, such as the United Nations and
the World Bank.
The scale and intensity of the violence and destruction associated with the civil war that engulfed the
Syrian Arab Republic since 2011 have very few parallels in recent history. The Syrian Observatory for
Human Rights (SOHR) estimates the total death toll (from March 15, 2011 to March 15, 2019) at a
staggering 570,000 (2.7% of Syria’s population in 2010). The United Nations Economic and Social
Commission for Western Asia (UN-ESCWA)— which conducted an elaborate sectoral analysis of the
economic cost of the Syrian civil war— puts the cumulative destruction of the physical capital stock by
end of 2017 at almost US$120 billion (ESCWA 2018), two times the GDP level in 2010 and about five
times the GDP level some seven years into the conflict. And in terms of the cost to the overall economy,
World Bank (2017) estimates that, from 2011 until the end of 2016, the cumulative losses in gross
domestic product (GDP) reached a whopping US$226 billion, about four times the Syrian GDP in 2010.
These assessments broadly cohere with calculations of the country’s night-light intensity by Ceylan and
Tumen (2018) and Li et al. (2017), with the latter suggesting that by 2017, Syria had lost about 80% of
its city night-light.
Moreover, in addition to the massive death and destruction, this war has also created an unprecedented
number of refugees and internally displaced persons. According to the United Nations High Commissioner
for Refugees (UNHCR), there are about 5.6 million registered refugees from Syria in neighboring countries
(26% of the population in 2010). However, accounting for unregistered refugees in just the three countries
of Egypt, Jordan, and Lebanon would raise the aggregate number to more than 7 million, around one-third
of Syria’s population in 2010 (UNHCR 2018). Adding these numbers to the roughly 6.3 million internally
displaced persons in Syria, we have almost two-thirds of the 21 million Syrian citizens who have been forced
out of their homes. To appreciate the global impact of the Syrian refugees and displaced crisis, it suffices
to note that the former accounts for more than 23% of the total number of refugees worldwide, while the
latter is estimated at 20% of the total number of global internally displaced persons.
The losses incurred by Syria are great, but it is not false hope to look toward recovery and further strengthening
of the country’s socioeconomic fundamentals beyond its pre-war situation. Chen, Loayza, and Reynal-Querol
(2008) conduct a comprehensive evaluation of the aftermath of civil war using event-study analyses across
41 countries over 1960–2003. They show that recovery to pre-conflict levels and further improvements are
possible for a country afflicted by war when lasting peace is achieved. Other studies focusing on World War II
(WWII) indicate countries returned to their pre-war trends 15 to 20 years post-war (Organski and Kugler 1977,
1980), and that countries suffering large negative output shocks grew systemically faster during the subsequent
decades due to reconstruction dynamics (Milionis and Vonyo 2015). Because of the massive destruction of
the factors of production in Syria at a scale more common in interstate wars than civil conflicts, the lessons
208
The Long Term Growth Model
from the post-WWII reconstruction of Europe and insights from modern growth theory could be useful
in assessing the post-conflict growth potential for Syria. Jánossy (1969) postulates that fast growth during
reconstruction is not only the result of higher returns to physical capital accumulation (which diminish as
capital grows in relation to output) but also depends on structural factors like the reorganization of economic
activity and the reallocation of production factors. One of the key lessons from the experience of post–WWII
growth in the European countries and Japan, for example, was that the rapid growth impact of the massive
rebuilding of physical capital was made possible, not only by the Marshall Plan resources, but also by the
relatively limited wartime depreciation of the human capital base and technological potential (Smolny 2000).
The implication of the above for the post-conflict economic reconstruction agenda for Syria is that the
restoration of human capital should be accorded the highest priority. And this should be alongside the
rebuilding of physical capital, which will unavoidably be a key component of the agenda. Further, attention
also needs to be paid to other factors contributing to total factor productivity (TFP), including institutions
and market efficiency.
However, the prospects for mobilizing meaningful multiyear financing for reconstruction and
development and for achieving a critical mass of voluntary refugee returns would hinge on the nature
of the ultimate political settlement of the conflict. A lopsided political settlement may deter refugees,
with strong lingering uncertainty about security and economic prospects, to return. Some of the main
impediments hindering repatriation include the dispossession of refugees’ homes and mandatory
military conscription for men of age. Therefore, and despite the “invitation” for refugees to return
home and the refugee camps being set up within Syria, it is not surprising that only a few thousand
returned in 2017, mostly motivated by push factors in the recipient countries. Indeed, this very limited
response did not mark the opening of the flood gates for massive repatriation in the following years
(POMEPS 2018).
Moreover, the volume of the funding required for reconstruction has been estimated from US$250
billion by the United Nations (UN), more than 10 times the estimated GDP in 2018, to as high as
US$1 trillion (POMEPS 2018), by far more than could be provided by Syrian allies. Thus, a genuine
reconstruction plan for Syria would best be served by robust support from the wider international
community, who have indicated a preference for a more robust political settlement (Elbadawi et al.
2019). The international community can provide some reconstruction aid that would support and
encourage the return of refugees, infrastructure investment, and policy reform. This includes aid
for geographically dispersed economic reconstruction (such as rebuilding infrastructure and access
to health and education) and institutional reform (including security, property rights, and access
to justice) that benefits various segments of the population fairly (Yahya and Kassir 2017). Djankov
and Reynal-Querol (2010) find that both per capita income and civil war are jointly determined by
idiosyncratic country-specific phenomena, some which are of particular relevance to Syria, such as
sectarian and ethnic polarization. Consequently, policies are needed to rectify structural problems that
make countries, and specifically, Syria more prone to conflict.
Subscribing to the context discussed above, this chapter uses the World Bank Long Term Growth Model–
Public Capital Extension (LTGM-PC) by Devadas and Pennings (2019) (and chapter 2 in this volume)
to simulate a counterfactual of no-conflict scenario (in section 2), to estimate the impact of conflict (in
section 3), and to assess the potential post-conflict growth for Syria (in section 4). The after-war projections
are carried out for three political settlement scenarios: a baseline moderate scenario (Sochi-plus, mainly
operated by Iran, Russia, and Turkey, with some involvement from the United Nations); a high optimistic
scenario (robust political settlement, brokered by the United Nations); and a pessimistic scenario (de facto
balance of power).
209
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
The LTGM-PC has been developed from another World Bank tool, the Long Term Growth Model (LTGM)
(chapter 1 in this volume). In the Standard LTGM, which follows the Solow-Swan growth model, the
production function is the traditional Cobb-Douglas specification with aggregate capital and effective labor
as imperfect complements. There, public and private capital have the same effect on output. The LTGM-PC
extends the Standard LTGM by separating total capital stock into private and public portions, with the
former adjusted for quality, while retaining other features of the LTGM, including other growth drivers
(demographics and the labor force, human capital, and TFP). The LTGM-PC can be used to analyze the
effect of an increase in the quantity or quality of public investment on growth, and to compare the effects
of public investment and private investment (see appendix 1 for details).
In the LTGM-PC, the effect of an increase in either the quantity or quality of public investment
and the full dynamic growth path depends on country-specific factors, such as the scarcity of public
capital (relative to GDP). The model also allows for the fact that public capital stock might be of
low-quality construction, which is a practical concern in many developing countries. It contains a new
Infrastructure Efficiency Index (IEI) that combines quality indicators for power, roads, and water, as
a cardinal measure of the quality of public capital in each country. The LTGM-PC draws extensively
on the empirical literature to guide its choice of other parameters, the most important of which is the
elasticity of output to public capital, and publicly available databases to calculate key variables. We
run all our simulations using the LTGM-PC Excel-based toolkit available at https://www.worldbank.
org/LTGM.
Our chapter complements earlier modelling work by World Bank (2017), the most comprehensive study
to date on the Syrian toll of war, in four ways. One, it provides a straightforward and transparent analysis
of how GDP evolves based on projections for the growth drivers. World Bank (2017) uses a dynamic
general equilibrium model to simulate the effects of the conflict through three channels— physical capital
destruction, casualties, and economic disorganization, with the last calculated as a residual based on
estimated GDP losses. Two, data-wise, we use estimates of physical damage across all types of capital, whereas
World Bank (2017) determines destruction in their simulations based on physical damage assessments only
in the housing sector. Three, with a greater certainty of the end of conflict, we focus on growth scenarios in
the aftermath of war, rather than mostly assessing conflict impact based on different end-time scenarios.
Four, we also attempt to provide a more up-to-date assessment of the impact from the conflict, that is until
the end of 2018.
Under the counterfactual simulation, our baseline projection shows an average real GDP growth of 5.3%
per annum over 2011–2018, which would have led to real GDP rising from US$60 billion in 2010 to US$91
billion and real GDP per capita rising from US$2,857 to US$3,774 by 2018. In contrast, our simulations of
the impact of conflict point to a negative annual GDP growth of –12% on average (across all three scenarios,
central, lower, and upper estimate projections) over 2011–2018, resulting in a GDP level of US$22 billion in
2018, which is only 24% of the counterfactual GDP level in 2018. Comparing the conflict versus no-conflict
simulations suggests a cumulative loss in GDP potential of about US$300 billion over 2011–2018. About
64% of the average negative GDP growth from 2011 to 2018 under the conflict simulation is due to physical
capital destruction. Physical capital destruction reflects the compounded effects of large outright damages,
low new investments, and a falling output base that is adversely affected by all growth drivers. Demographics
and labor account for about 15%, human capital 7%, and TFP 13% of negative GDP growth on average
over the conflict years (2011–2018).
In our post-conflict simulations, we assume that the three political settlement scenarios are associated
with different levels of reconstruction assistance and different degrees of voluntary mobility of refugees.
These in turn affect key drivers of growth: public and private investment and the labor force. We also
make different assumptions for human capital growth and TFP growth across the three scenarios.
210
The Long Term Growth Model
Depending on the scenarios, our simulation results suggest that it would take between 10 and 20 years
for Syria to reach its pre-conflict GDP level and between 10 and 30 years to recover its pre-conflict
GDP per capita level (both at 2010 constant prices). If there were to be an unsanctioned and misguided
“forced” repatriation of refugees, this would result in significantly lower GDP per capita compared to the
voluntary mobility case. Under voluntary return, labor would adjust gradually to capital reconstruction,
thus keeping labor productivity from falling.
4 4
5.0
4.5
Percent
Percent
2 2
0 0
–2 –2
–4 –4
95
96
97
98
20 9
00
20 1
02
20 3
04
20 5
06
20 7
08
09
10
19 5
96
19 7
19 8
20 9
20 0
20 01
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
20 07
2008
20 9
200
20 11
2012
2013
2014
2015
16
0
9
0
9
9
0
0
1
20
20
19
19
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
IMF WEO, Oct 2018 IMF WEO April 2011, 6-year average, 2011-2016
WDI/MFMod 2018 IMF WEO April 2011 (dashed line indicates estimate/projection)
WDI/MFMod 2018, 10-year average, 2001–2010
IMF WEO Oct 2018, 10-year average, 2001–2010
3
orld Development Indicators (WDI) data for Syria are available up to 2007. For 2008–2010, we use data on GDP growth
W
from the World Bank’s internal macroeconomic and fiscal model (MFMod), November 2017 vintage. See Burns et al. (2019)
for more information on the model.
211
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
The growth rates of total population and the working-age population share averaged 2.5% and 0.8%,
respectively, over 2001–2010 based on latest UN estimates (United Nations 2017)— figure 8.3a. As a gauge
of projections prior to the conflict, United Nations (2011) indicated average growth rates for these two
variables of 1.7% and 1.0%, respectively, over 2011–2020 and 1.5% and 0.3% over 2021–2030 compared to
2.5% and 0.5% over 2001–2010 (figure 8.3b).
The labor force participation rate (LFPR) had been moderating, declining from 54.5% in 1995 to 44.9%
in 2010, with an average growth over 2001–2010 of –1.5% (figure 8.4a). This phenomenon occurred
despite relatively strong economic growth, distinguishing Syria from other countries— no other Middle
East and North Africa (MENA) economy had a similar rate of decline in the LFPR over the same period,
30
25
Percent of GDP
Percent of GDP
25 25.2
20
20
21.5 23.1
15
15
10 10
08
97
98
99
00
20 1
02
20 3
04
20 5
06
20 7
09
10
19 5
96
19 7
19 8
20 9
20 0
20 01
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
20 07
2008
20 9
200
20 11
2012
2013
2014
2015
95
96
16
0
9
0
9
9
0
0
1
20
20
19
19
20
19
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
Gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) (WDI, 2018) GCF (IMF WEO, April 2011), dashed line indicates estimate/
projection
GFCF 7-year average, 2001–2007 (WDI, 2018)
GCF 6-year average, 2011–2016 (IMF WEO, April 2011)
Gross capital formation (GCF) (IMF WEO, Oct 2018)
GCF 10-year average, 2001–2010 (IMF WEO, Oct 2018)
3 3
2 2
1 1
0 0
0
05
15
30
40
05
5
-9
-0
-1
-0
-1
-2
-9
11-
1-
-
-
06
06
91
16
21
01
96
96
01
91
20
3
20
19
20
20
20
20
20
19
20
19
19
Total population (United Nations 2017) Total population (United Nations 2011)
Working-age population/total population Working-age population/total population
(United Nations 2017) (United Nations 2011)
Total population (United Nations 2013)
Working-age population/total population
(United Nations 2013)
Note: Dashed lines indicate projections for years beyond
UN report dates.
212
The Long Term Growth Model
54.5 54.8
4 4
50 50
45.8
44.9 2 2
Percent growth
Percent growth
40 40
0 0
0.2
30 30
–1.5 –2 –2
–1.3
20 –4 20 –4
19 5
96
19 7
98
20 9
00
20 01
20 2
03
20 4
05
20 6
20 7
08
20 9
10
19 5
19 6
19 7
19 8
20 99
20 0
20 01
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
20 07
2008
20 9
200
20 11
2012
2013
14
9
9
0
0
9
9
9
0
0
1
20
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
LFPR (WDI, ILO-modelled estimates, 2018), LHS LFPR (WDI Archive, ILO-modelled estimates, 2013), LHS
Growth in participation rate Growth in participation rate
Average growth, 2001–2010 Average growth, 2001–2010
Average growth, 2011–2014
except Yemen. Nasser and Mehchy (2012) note that a sizeable portion of the economically active population
that went out of the labor force in the 2000s consisted of women in the agriculture sector (affected by the
drought and higher fuel prices in the second half of the 2000s), and workers becoming students. Early
in the conflict, the International Labour Organization (ILO)-modelled estimates suggested a stabilizing
participation rate after 2010 (Figure 4(b)), though some caution needs to be exercised in taking this at face
value given uncertainty surrounding the underlying data.4
Human capital growth in Penn World Tables (PWT) 9 (Feenstra, Inklaar, and Timmer 2015), which uses
Cohen, Soto, and Leker (CSL) data (Cohen and Soto 2007; Cohen and Leker 2014) for the average years of
schooling of the population ages 25 and above, averaged 1.0% for the 10 years up to 2010.5 Figure 8.5a shows
average years of schooling based on select age groups under both CSL and Barro and Lee (BL) measures.
Barro and Lee (2015) projections indicate a continued rise in the average years of schooling absent conflict,
for the population ages 15–64: 1.6 years over 2011–2030. Figure 8.5b shows human capital growth, based
on the schooling years under CSL and BL measures. While fluctuations and differences are obvious decade
to decade, there is consistency in a long-term average of approximately 1.5%.
TFP growth, averaged 1.4% over 2001–2010 based on calculations by The Conference Board (2018). Our
own estimations following the methodology in Kim and Loayza (2019) also suggest an average growth rate
of 1.4% for the same period.6 See figure 8.6.
4
I LO-modelled estimates are based on projections for GDP-related variables and population structure. The 2013 estimates draw
on IMF WEO April 2013 and United Nations (2013). However, the IMF stopped publishing projections for Syria effective 2012,
and ILO uses the regional median growth to extrapolate GDP growth for Syria.
5
See the documentation, “Human Capital in PWT 9.0.” (https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/docs/human_capital_in_pwt_90.pdf).
6
FP is measured by growth accounting. Syria data for output, physical capital, human capital, and employed persons are from
T
PWT 9. Labor share is proxied by the average for four relatively conflict-free middle-income MENA economies (Djibouti,
Jordan, Morocco, and Tunisia).
213
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
10 4.0
Average years of schooling
9 3.5
growth, percent
7 2.5
6 2.0
5 1.5
4 1.0
3 0.5
2 0
80
90
00
10
20
30
40
90
20
0
03
04
00
01
20
20
20
20
20
19
19
19
20
–2
–2
–2
–2
–
11–
81
01
21
31
91
20
19
20
20
20
19
Cohen, Soto and Leker (25 and above) Cohen, Soto and Leker (25 and above)
Cohen, Soto and Leker (25–64) Cohen, Soto and Leker (25–64)
Barro and Lee (25 and above) Barro and Lee (25 and above)
Barro and Lee (25–64) Barro and Lee (25–64)
Barro and Lee (15–64); dashed line Barro and Lee (15–64); patterned bar
indicates projection indicates projection
4 1.4
2
Percent
0
1.41
–2
–4
–6
–8
03
04
05
06
07
08
95
96
97
98
99
01
02
09
10
0
20
20
19
20
19
19
19
19
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Kim and Loayza methodology (KL) (2019) The Conference Board (TCB) (2018)
KL (2019), average 2001–2010 TCB (2018), average 2001–2010
214
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 8.1: No-Conflict Baseline Simulation— Values for Parameters, Initial Conditions, and
Projected Variables
Input value
Parameter/variable* 2010/ Average, Average,
Note Calibrated pre-conflict 2011–2030
A. Constant parameters
Labor share β (1) 0.520
Aggregate capital depreciation rate δ (2) 0.048
Public capital depreciation rate δ G
(2) 0.031
Private capital depreciation rate δ P
(3) 0.062
B. Initial conditions
Initial capital-to-output ratio K0/Y0 (4) 2.560
G
Public capital share of total capital K /K (5) 0.450
Initial public capital-to-output (6) 1.152
ratio K 0G / Y0
Initial private capital-to-output (6) 1.408
ratio K 0P / Y0
C. Projected variables, central path (2010/11–30)
Investment-to-output ratio I/Y (7) 0.215
Public investment-to-output ratio IG/Y (7) 0.086
Private investment-to-output ratio IP/Y (7) 0.129
Human capital growth gh (8) 0.010
TFP growth gA (9) 0.014
Population growth rate gN (10) 0.016
Working-age-to-population share, (10) 0.006
growth gw
Labor force participation rate, growth gϱ (11) 0.000
Note: *Multiply by 100 to obtain parameter/variable values in percent share or growth terms (%).
(1) PWT 9. Average of 2010 values for Djibouti, Jordan, Morocco, and Tunisia.
(2) δ is PWT 8.1 data for Syria. δG is the PWT 9 depreciation rate for nonresidential structures.
(3) δP is derived as the residual from a weighted average calculation of δ based on δG and KG/K.
(4) Calibrated based on long-term averages of I/Y , GDP growth and δ In steady-state, output grows at the same rate as capital stock, which
allows us to write, K/Y = I/Y/(gY + δ) where gY is average output growth. We use: 30-year averages of I/Y (22%), gY (4.1%), and δ (4.5%).
(5) Calibrated based on average shares for lower-middle-income countries and oil-based economies (fuel exports/total merchandise
exports ≥ 30%). KG/K data is from the IMF FAD Investment and Capital Stock Database 2017.
(6) K 0G / Y0 and K 0P / Y0 are derived by applying KG/K to K0/Y0.
(7) Gross fixed capital formation (% of GDP), average for 2001–2007 from WDI. Public investment share assumed at 40% based on World
Bank (2017) and IMF (2010).
(8) PWT 9. Average growth rate, 2001–2010.
(9) Authors’ estimate. Average growth rate, 2001–2010.
(10)
United Nations (2011).
(11)
Based on the stabilizing participation rate observed in the 2013 ILO-modelled estimates.
since the PWT 9 value puts Syria on the border of the 75th percentile of lowest capital-to-output, K/Y ratios,
and is below the respective averages of lower-middle-income countries and low-income countries, as well
as MENA countries.
We also consider lower and upper estimates based on adjustments to some of the central projections for
growth drivers— table 8.2 displays these calibrations. Notes to tables 8.1 and 8.2 explain the calibrations.
Figure 8.7 shows the trajectory for the level and growth of GDP in Syria based on the calibrations.
The baseline assumptions are consistent with a long-term GDP growth average of close to 5.0%.
215
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
Table 8.2: No-Conflict Simulation—Upper and Lower Estimates for Projected Variables
6
4
5
3
Percent
Percent
3 2
2
1
1
0 0
20 11
20 2
20 3
20 4
15
20 6
20 17
20 8
20 19
20 0
20 4
20 5
20 21
20 2
20 3
20 6
20 27
20 8
20 29
30
20 11
20 2
20 3
20 4
20 5
20 6
20 17
20 8
20 19
20 0
20 21
20 2
23
20 4
25
20 6
20 27
20 8
20 29
30
1
2
1
2
20
2
1
2
1
1
20
2
1
2
1
2
2
2
20
20
20
5,000
US$, 2010
125 4,500
4,000
100
3,500
3,000
75
2,500
50 2,000
30
10
20 11
2012
2013
2014
2015
20 6
20 17
2018
20 19
20 0
20 21
2022
2023
2024
2025
20 6
20 27
2028
20 29
30
200
20 11
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
20 17
2018
20 19
20 0
20 21
2022
2023
2024
2025
2026
20 27
2028
2029
20
2
2
2
20
20
216
The Long Term Growth Model
Average real GDP growth of 5.3% over 2011–2018 in the absence of conflict would have led to real GDP
rising from US$60 billion in 2010 to US$91 billion, and real GDP per capita rising from US$2,857 to
US$3,774 by 2018 (upper estimate: GDP of US$95.3 billion and GDP per capita of US$3,997 in 2018;
lower estimate: GDP of US$87.6 billion and GDP per capita of US$3,649 in 2018).
217
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
The above numbers might understate fatalities and migrants. The cumulative number of fatalities from the
war is hard to ascertain. SOHR data put Syrian fatalities at 494,892 over March 2011 – December 10, 2018,7
higher than what is suggested by UN population statistics. The UNHCR populations of concern data show
that compared to 2016, total registered Syrian refugees and asylum-seekers increased in 2017 by 746,811
(figure 8.8a). While the equivalent 2018 data are not available, from data on refugees in selected neighboring
countries, we note that when compared to 2017, refugees had increased by 184,398 to 5,663,675 in 2018,
around one-third of the remaining population in Syria in 2018 (patterned bars in figure 8.8a). Based on
this, the UN population statistics may be understating refugees by about 900,000. However, if we discount
the 1 million refugees born in exile supposedly included in the UNCHR data, then the underrepresentation
of population “loss” in the UN population statistics due to the use of outdated UNHCR data disappears.
Of greater concern then is that the UN population statistics likely do not include non-registered Syrians in
neighboring countries, for which estimates vary but tend to go up to more than a million; see, for instance,
Vignal (2018) and World Bank (2019). UNDP and UNHCR (2019) put the difference between estimated
total Syrians and registered Syrian refugees at about 1.6 million in December 2018. The difference is wholly
accounted for by Egypt, Jordan, and Lebanon.
Consequently, as a lower estimate to population growth, we calculate an added decline in the Syrian
population of 1.8 million, building in additional conflict deaths of 200,000 and unregistered Syrian migrants
of 1.6 million. This would reduce the 2018 population from 18.3 million to 16.5 million giving a negative
average growth of –3.0% over 2011–2018.
May 2018 ILO-modelled estimates show the overall LFPR at 43.0% in 2018, giving an average negative
growth of –0.5% over 2011–2018. World Bank (2019) shows 2017 LFPRs for men and women above 15
years of age at 79.1% and 11.9%, respectively, versus 73.0% and 13.0% in 2010. We use the ILO estimates
in our central projection, and for a possible upper estimate, consider an increment in the LFPR by 2018
based on the changes in participation rates reported in World Bank (2019).
a. Total Syrian refugees and asylum-seekers b. Profile of Syrian refugees in selected neigboring countries
7
6.46
Total
6 5.72 5.48
5.48 5.66
5.13
4.86 60+ yrs
5 4.59
Million persons
3.97
4 3.73 18–59 yrs
3 2.52
2.39 12–11 yrs
2
5–11 yrs
0.76
1 0.70
0–4 yrs
... ...
0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 0 10 20 30 40 50 60
All countries (source: UNHCR populations of concern*) Female Male
Turkey and MENA (source: UNHCR populations of concern*) Percent of total refugees in Egypt, Iraq, Jordan, Lebanon,
Selected neigboring countries (source: UNHCR Turkey, and North Africa (5,663,675 as at December 31, 2018)
Operational Portal Refugee Situations) Source: The UNHCR Population Statistics Reference Database
*Comprises refugees, asylum-seekers (pending cases), and others and the UNHCR Operational Portal Refugee Situations—
of concern. Syria Regional Refugee Response.
(https://data2.unhcr.org/en/situations/syria).
7
http://www.syriahr.com/en/?p=108723.
218
The Long Term Growth Model
• for age groups, α = 1: 15–19 and α = 2:20–24,who are still in school, we use the attainment in t – 5 for
the same group α, adjusted to account for changes in enrollment ratios, ∆enroll ga, j ,t 9 for age group α in
education level j (primary, secondary, and tertiary; incomplete and complete) during the transition
period from t – 5 to t, i.e.
(2)
s ga ,t = s ga ,t −5 + ∑ ∆enroll ga, j ,t Durja,t −5
j
Dur is the corresponding duration system of education level j , which we assume to be unchanged.
Average total years of schooling for each age group sta is then a composite of the respective average years of
schooling of men (m) and women (f) in that group:
Pop af ,t a Popma ,t
sta = s af ,t × + s ×
Popta (3)
m , t
Popta
a =1 Popt(15−64) (4)
8
The nomenclature follows Barro and Lee (2013, 2015).
9
We base the enrollment adjustment factor formula on Barro and Lee (2013) (their table A.2).
10
http://uis.unesco.org/country/SY.
219
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
and boys, keeping them steady thereafter.11 Regarding tertiary education, the UIS data rather surprisingly
suggest an increment of about 10 percentage points in the gross enrollment rate during the conflict from
26% in 2010.12 We build in this increment over 2010–2015, applying the same enrollment rate for men and
women, and keep it unchanged thereafter. Primary school duration is assumed to be 6 years (6–11 years),
secondary school, 6 years (12–17 years), and university 4 years (18-21 years). Appendix 3 provides further
details on how we arrive at the average years of schooling in 2018.
Our approach constrains changes to the national average of schooling years to arise from shifts in the
distribution of the total population by age and gender, and in enrollment ratios. Because we use past
composite values of average years of schooling, we do not consider changes in completion rates. This
approach also does not consider other types of heterogeneity in educational attainment, for instance, that
depend on the socioeconomic status or geographical origination of migrants and conflict victims. Verme
et al. (2016) find that Syrian refugees in Jordan and Lebanon in fact tend to have slightly lower levels of
educational attainment than pre-conflict Syrians.
To obtain human capital growth, we continue to use the same method and returns to education as in
PWT 9. For the central projection using UN population statistics, we find that average years of schooling
would have declined by 1.467 years for the population ages 15–64 with human capital contracting by an
annual average growth of –2.59% over 2011–2015 and –0.56% over 2016–2018, respectively. With the
additional decline of 1.8 million in the Syrian population for the lower estimate, average years of schooling
declines only marginally more— by 1.499 years.
3.1.4 TFP
The key element that feeds into the model of TFP growth in Kim and Loayza (2019) is an overall index of
TFP determinants, the determinants being education, infrastructure, innovation, institutions, and market
efficiency. The composite index stood at 30.33 for Syria in 2010 on a scale between 1 and 100. We estimate
the trajectory of this index over 2011–2018 by calibrating its subcomponents.
For the education index, we calculate a decline that is proportionate to our estimates of the fall in average
years of schooling of the working-age population. For the infrastructure index, we build in a decline that is
proportionate to the relative total light in Syria over time estimated by Li et al. (2017). For the institutions
index, the estimation is based on the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) across six dimensions
(Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2010). For the innovation and market efficiency indices, we assume that
these evolve proportionately to a weighted average of the indices for infrastructure and institutions.
This gives an overall TFP determinant index of 15.98 in 2018, almost one-half the 2010 level. The associated
average annual TFP growth over 2011–2018 is –1.6%. Further details are provided in appendix 4.
11
e use a simple average calculation to obtain the 2015 primary enrollment rate based on a net enrollment rate for school-
W
age children of 60% (UNICEF 2016) and secondary enrollment rate of 45%. The net enrollment rate for school-age children
appears to have been relatively stable after 2015, amounting to 61% in 2018 (World Bank 2019).
12
Milton (2019) discusses how Syria’s higher education system survived quantity wise, despite general expectations that higher
education suffers relatively more during conflict, but that quality had been eroded and political control over campuses increased.
220
The Long Term Growth Model
Average
Parameter/variable Note 2010 2018
2011–2018
A. Constant parameters
Labor share β (1) 0.520
Aggregate capital depreciation rate δ (1) 0.048
Public capital depreciation rate δ G
(1) 0.031
Private capital depreciation rate δ P
(1) 0.062
B. Capital-to-output (K/Y) ratios
G
Initial public capital-to-output ratio K 0 / Y0 (1) 1.152
G
Simulated K c / Y (with damage) (2) 1.141 1.029
P
Initial private capital-to-output ratio K 0 / Y0 (1) 1.408
P
Simulated K c / Y (with damage) (2) 1.144 0.708
221
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
/ Y2010 Ij
(1 − δ j ) (1 − d2011
j
) + K2010
j
2010 / Y2010
growth in adjusted capital per worker, 1 + g kcj , 2011 = (5)
( , 2011 )
1 + g (1 + g ω ,2011 1 + g N ,2011 )
)(
j
D2011
j
where d2011 = j
, the proportion of capital damaged in 2011.
K 2010
1 + g y ,2011 = [(1 + Γ 2011 )(1−ζ )φ ](1 + g A , 2011 )(1 + g θ , 2011 ) (1 + g kcG ,2011 ) (1 + g kcP ,2011 )
φ 1− β −ζφ
(1 + g h ,2011 )
φ β
• The process is repeated for periods 2012–2018. Damages to K tj are apportioned across the conflict
period based on the estimates discussed in section 3.1.1. Damages are apportioned between public and
private capital based on their relative cumulative shares as at end 2015, made available by ESCWA. We
assume the same shares for each time t (that is, 40% of damages are attributable to public capital, 60%
to private capital).
Under the central projection, both KG/Y and KP/Y are lower in 2018 (1.029 and 0.708, respectively)
compared with 2010 (1.152 and 1.408, respectively), but more so in the latter case, since the damage
value for private capital is higher. In the lower and upper estimate scenarios for selected growth drivers
(table 8.4), the K/Y ratios in 2018 are slightly higher than in the central projection but remain lower than
the 2010 levels.
Figure 9a– 9b shows the outcomes of simulations for GDP level and growth over the conflict years
given the calibrations in tables 8.3 and 8.4. Our simulations of the impact from the conflict across
the three scenarios (central, lower, and upper estimate projections) from 2011–2018 indicate that the
depletion of factors of production alone may account for about 87% of the negative GDP growth on
average, and further, that about 64% of the average negative growth is due to physical capital destruction.
Demographics and labor account for about 15%, human capital 7%, and TFP 13% of GDP growth on
average over the conflict years.
The decrease in physical capital reflects the compounded effects of large outright damages, low net invest-
ment rate, and a falling output base (which is adversely affected by all growth drivers). The prominent
effective losses due to physical capital destruction are worsened by the lack of investment. This echoes the
observation by World Bank (2017) that capital destruction itself might have relatively subdued effects in
a well-functioning economy, as in the aftermath of a natural disaster; but in the case of conflicts, the fall
in investments due to disruptions in economic organization reinforces the adverse effects from physical
capital damages. Having said that, our estimate of physical capital decrease is greater than the estimate in
World Bank (2017) because of methodological reasons: we take into account the monetary value of physical
capital destroyed, as reported by ESCWA (2018), as well as depreciation and gross investment, directly in
the calculation of the capital stock; while World Bank (2017) assumes that the resulting capital stock keeps
the same proportion with respect to the initial capital stock as the stock of housing does. Consequently,
World Bank (2017) finds that the impact of capital destruction on GDP growth is not as immense. They
find that in a scenario with only capital damage, GDP only decreased by –3.5% from the pre-conflict
GDP level in the sixth year of conflict, compared to the –65.2% decrease in the scenario where all shocks
222
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 8.4: Simulation of Syria’s Conflict Years (2011–2018) —Lower and Upper
Estimates and Impact on Capital-to-Output Ratios
Average 2011–
Variable Note 2018
2018
A. Lower estimate
Population growth gN (1) –0.030 0.000
Human capital growth gh (2) –0.019 –0.006
Capital-to-Output (K/Y) Ratios (with Damage)
G
Simulated K c / Y 1.180 1.091
P
Simulated K c / Y 1.175 0.737
including casualty and economic disorganization were included. The impact for growth when there is only
casualty is comparable to the capital stock damage case at –3.9%. Economic disorganization has the biggest
impact, with GDP decreasing by –59.8% from the pre-conflict level on the sixth year of conflict. Overall,
notwithstanding the differences in the relative importance of factors, the cumulative GDP loss is similar at
US$226 billion over 2011–2016 (in 2010 prices), almost four times the GDP level in 2010.
Comparisons against the no-conflict scenario suggest a cumulative loss in GDP potential of between
US$289 and US$300 billion over 2011–2018 (figure 10a). Our estimates point to a continued loss in
2017–2018 because of the damage to physical capital and negative TFP growth. This varies somewhat
from ESCWA (2018) and others like Devarajan and Mottaghi (2017), Gobat and Kostial (2016), and
World Bank (2017), all of which point to a trough in actual GDP contraction around 2012–2013.
ESCWA (2018) estimates average GDP growth of –10% over 2011–2017, with growth turning positive
in 2017. ESCWA also projects a GDP level of US$27 billion in 2017 against a no-conflict counterfactual
of US$86 billion. Our estimates seem to mimic these results, pointing to a GDP growth of –12% on
average over 2011–2018 (across all three scenarios under the conflict simulation), with an average
GDP level of US$22 billion in 2018 (against a no-conflict scenario of US$91 billion). Per capita GDP is
estimated at US$1,154 in 2018 under the central projection (upper estimate: US$1,381; lower estimate:
US$1,200).
223
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
–10 –15
–15
–20
–20
–25
–25
–30 –30
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
50
2,500
40
US$ bil, 2010
2,000
US$, 2010
30
1,500
20
10 1,000
0 500
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
Scenario (II)–Central projection Scenario (II)–Lower estimate Scenario (II)–Upper estimate
Note: GDP in 2010 amounted to US$60 billion (IMF WEO October
2018). GDP per capita in 2010 amounted to US$2,857, based on
population of 21.018 million (United Nations 2017).
Figure 8.9b: Average Impact of Different Growth Drivers on GDP during the Conflict
(across Central, Lower and Upper Estimate Projections)
0 50
–5 40
US$ bil, 2010
Percent
–10 30
–15 20
–20 10
–25 0
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
TFP Physical capital Physical capital
Demographics and labor force Human capital All factors of production (excluding TFP)
All growth drivers (including TFP)
224
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 8.10: GDP Loss Based on the Conflict Simulation Compared to the Counterfactual of
No Conflict
–10 –500
–20
–1,000
US$ bil, 2010
–30
US$, 2010
–40 –1,500 Cumulative loss:
Cumulative loss: US$ 9,623
–50 US$ 289 b
–2,000
Cumulative loss:
–60 Cumulative loss:
US$300 b US$10,763
–2,500
–70
–80 –3,000
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
225
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
We also look at a second broad case of forced repatriation of refugees. Forced repatriation would
contravene UN principles that care for the safety and welfare of refugees,13 but it may be instigated
by local and international voices eager for a quick resolution of the refugee issue.14 Under a forced
repatriation scenario, all refugees in neighboring countries are assumed to return to Syria, regardless
of the type of political settlement and associated reconstruction amounts. Therefore, in this case,
refugee returns are assumed to be disconnected from the size of the reconstruction program. We thus
have six scenarios in total— three for each of the two different broad cases of voluntary mobility and
forced repatriation, respectively. These are summarized in table 8.5. We discuss the projections for the
growth drivers in section 4.1 and present the resulting simulations for Syria’s growth over the next 30
years in section 4.2.
Table 8.5: Key Factors in the Post-Conflict Scenarios for Growth Drivers
13
The UN principle of non-refoulement, codified in Article 33 of the 1951 UN Refugee Convention, requires that “no contracting
state shall expel or return a refugee in any manner whatsoever to the frontiers of territories where his life or freedom would be
threatened.”
14
The limitations that the UN non-refoulement principle places on repatriation is frequently resented by states. Host countries
are often impatient to see uninvited refugees leave. Countries of origin are sometimes impatient to see them return and signal
the end of conflict. Moreover, donor states are eager to bring an end to the long-term refugee assistance programs that they
fund.
226
The Long Term Growth Model
St I t CABt
= + where CABt = TBt + IBt = –NCTt – ∆NFLt (7)
Yt Yt Yt
(Note: St = saving excluding net current transfers, CABt = current account balance excluding net current
transfers, TBt = trade balance, IBt = income balance, NCTt = net current transfers, and ∆NFTt = change in
net foreign liabilities.)
External financing may take the form of (non-debt creating) aid and grants (higher NCTt ) or direct invest-
ment and loans (higher foreign liabilities, thus increasing ∆NFTt ). If the foreign funds lead to an equivalent
amount being spent on tradables (for example, the imports of capital goods), the current account will be in
deficit, ceteris paribus. If the foreign funds do not lead to the purchase of tradables, the current account will
be in balance, ceteris paribus; see Elbadawi, Kaltani, and Schmidt-Hebbel (2008) for a related discussion on
how the utilization of aid monies affects current account balances and exchange rates. In our simulations,
CABt ∆FFt
=− where NCt + ∆NFLt = ∆FFt, the inflow of foreign funds. So, there is a corresponding amount
Yt Yt
being spent on tradables. This gives us equation (8). ∆FFt varies across the three post-conflict scenarios
as described in table 8.5: beginning in 2019, US$12.5 billion per year over a 20-year period under the
optimistic scenario; US$7 billion per year over a 20-year period under the baseline scenario; and US$3
billion per year over a 10-year period under the pessimistic scenario. An even distribution of foreign funds
over the 20-year and 10-year periods is assumed following the reasoning in the ESCWA (2017) report. On
the one hand, the country’s absorptive capacity of investment will progressively increase over time. On the
other hand, national sources provide larger investment funding as the economy recovers. A stable provision
of foreign funds alongside rising domestically funded investment is consistent with this chapter’s assumed
investment rates with respect to GDP, which are not excessively high in comparison to other post-conflict
recovery experiences.
I t S t ∆FFt (8)
= +
Yt Yt Yt
It CABt
If we assume of 5% (as per the central projection of our conflict simulation), and of around
Yt Yt
S
–30%15 at the end of the conflict, this would give us t of approximately –25%. This is about 50 percentage
Yt
points below Syria’s pre-conflict long-term average: 23%.16 For the post-conflict pessimistic scenario, we
St
calibrate the transition for Syria’s by 50 percentage points to 25%, in eight years, based on the experience
Yt
15
This is based on the 2017 estimate of the trade balance share of GDP by ESCWA (2018).
16
20-year average, 1991–2010 (WEO data).
227
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
of Lebanon. Lebanon was subject to persistent political instability during its recovery. External assistance
specific to its reconstruction program was limited, though it did receive large capital inflows attracted by
high interest rates that enabled it to run current account deficits. For the optimistic scenario, we assume
that Syria’s saving ratio increases by 60 percentage points to 35% in five years, following the timeline
and change experienced by Kuwait as it recovered to its pre-conflict saving-to-GDP level. Resource-rich,
high-income Kuwait made a strong recovery after the sharp decline, as its oil production capacity was
quickly restored amid a comprehensive economic recovery and reconstruction program (Sab 2014). For
S
the moderate scenario, we take an average of the projections for t under the other two scenarios. See
appendix 5 for further details. Yt
It
Of projected , we continue to assume a public investment share of 40%. This is consistent with the
Yt
estimated relative shares of destruction between public and private capital. We keep new public investment
efficiency unchanged at 0.570 under the pessimistic scenario and assume a rise from 0.570 to 0.734 by 2038
under the baseline. For the optimistic scenario, we assume a rise to the average IEI for the upper-middle-in-
come (UMI) group of 0.769 by 2038.
17
From our calculations using details in the UN population statistics, this is in addition to about 112,000 returnees from mid-
2019 to mid-2020, giving a total of 4.3 million returnees, or 76% of registered refugees residing in neighboring countries over
2019–2035.
228
The Long Term Growth Model
4.1.4 TFP
We assume a gradual rebuilding of the overall TFP determinants index. Under the optimistic scenario, we
increase this index from 15.98 in 2018 to 35.42 by 2028 and 75.76 by 2048 based on the trajectory of the
Republic of Korea’s index over the 30-year period, 1985–2014. Korea is the best performer in the sample of
countries used in Kim and Loayza (2019). This gives an average annual TFP growth of 1.4% over 2019–2048
under the optimistic scenario, a rate which implies about 10 years to rebuild TFP to pre-conflict levels. For
the pessimistic scenario, we repeat the exercise, but based on the index of the United Arab Emirates (UAE),
the best performer among MENA countries. This would imply an increase in Syria’s index to only 21.72
by 2028 (still below pre-conflict level) and 32.74 by 2048. The corresponding average annual TFP growth
over 2019–2048 for the pessimistic scenario would be 0.3%. For the moderate scenario, we assume TFP
18
UIS: the net primary enrollment rate rose from 81.9% in 1973 to 94.8% in 1987, while the net secondary enrollment rate
increased from 39.3% in 2000 to 66.9% in 2010.
229
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
growth rates that are the average of the rates under the optimistic and pessimistic scenarios, which implies
an average annual TFP growth of 0.9% over the same time period.
230
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 8.6: Simulation for Post-Conflict Syria – Projected Variables
Scenario
Optimistic Moderate Pessimistic
Parameter/variable* Note 2018 Average
2019– 2029– 2039– 2019– 2029– 2039– 2019– 2029– 2039–
2028 2038 2048 2028 2038 2048 2028 2038 2048
Public investment-to-output ratio IG/Y - voluntary (1) 0.010 0.251 0.185 0.140 0.170 0.157 0.120 0.091 0.100 0.100
mobility case
- forced repatriation case 0.250 0.183 0.140 0.168 0.155 0.120 0.088 0.100 0.100
P
Private investment-to-output ratio I /Y (1) 0.040 0.376 0.277 0.210 0.255 0.236 0.180 0.136 0.150 0.150
Figure 8.11a: Post-Conflict Simulation of GDP in Syria— Scenarios under the Voluntary Mobility
Case
Percent
10.0 7.5
7.5 5.0
5.0 2.5
2.5 0
0 –2.5
–2.5 –5.0
43
19
43
20 1
23
25
27
29
20 1
33
35
37
39
20 1
45
47
19
20 1
23
20 5
20 7
29
20 1
33
20 5
20 7
39
20 1
20 5
47
4
2
4
2
3
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
180
US$, 2010
5,500
160 5,000
140 4,500
120 4,000
3,500
100
3,000
80
2,500
60 2,000
40 1,500
20 1,000
20 8
20 6
20
20 2
24
20 8
30
20 2
34
20 6
20 8
40
20 2
44
20 6
48
20 8
20
22
24
26
20 8
30
20 2
34
36
20 8
40
20 2
44
46
48
2
4
1
3
2
4
1
3
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
On the other hand (and most importantly), regarding GDP per capita, growth rates under the forced
repatriation case are lower over the refugee influx period (figure 8.12, right). For instance, at the height
of repatriation in the moderate scenario, GDP per capita growth is lower by 1 percentage point when
compared to voluntary mobility. Growth rates recover thereafter. However, GDP per capita levels remain
lower in the forced repatriation case than in the voluntary mobility case for the entire period under our
review. In the moderate scenario, GDP per capita level is on average lower by US$76 (at 2010 constant
prices) over 2019–2048. This is because of lower physical capital in per worker terms, which reduces labor
productivity and output per capita relative to the voluntary mobility case. Of all the scenarios, it is the
optimistic case where forced repatriation is the least adverse— as refugees already want to return given
relatively good conditions for growth.
4.2.3 How long would it take Syria to reach higher income group thresholds?
Prior to the conflict, Syria’s gross national income (GNI) per capita based on the World Bank Atlas
Methodology (US$1,840 as of 2007) placed it in the LMI category, and at a level that was about one-half
the then UMI threshold.
232
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 8.11b: Impact of Different Growth Drivers under the Voluntary Mobility Case
Real GDP Level - Moderate Scenario Real GDP Growth - Moderate Scenario
180 12.5
160 10.0
140
7.5
120
Percent
US$ bil, 2010
5.0
100
80 2.5
60 0
40
–2.5
20
0 –5.0
19
20 1
23
25
27
29
20 1
33
35
37
39
20 1
43
45
47
20 8
20
20 2
24
20 6
20 8
30
20 2
34
20 6
20 8
40
20 2
44
20 6
48
4
2
4
1
3
2
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
–0.5
11.0
–2.0
9.0
–3.5
Percent
7.0 –5.0
Percent
5.0 –6.5
–8.0
3.0
–9.5
1.0
–11.0
–1.0 –12.5
19
20 1
23
25
27
29
20 1
33
35
37
39
20 1
43
45
47
19
20 1
23
25
27
29
20 1
33
35
37
39
20 1
43
45
47
2
4
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
233
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
Percentage points
Percentage points
1.0
0.5 0.5
0 0
–0.5 –0.5
–1.0
–1.0
–1.5
–2.0 –1.5
–2.5 –2.0
20 8
20
20 2
24
20 6
20 8
30
20 2
34
20 6
20 8
40
20 2
44
20 6
48
20 8
20
20 2
24
20 6
20 8
30
20 2
34
20 6
20 8
20 0
20 2
44
20 6
48
2
4
1
3
2
4
4
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Real GDP level Real GDP per capita level
17.5 20
15.0 0
12.5 –20
US$ bil, 2010
US$ bil, 2010
10.0 –40
7.5 –60
5.0 –80
2.5 –100
0 –120
–2.5 –140
20 18
20 0
20 2
24
20 6
20 8
30
20 2
34
20 6
20 8
40
20 2
44
20 6
48
20 8
20
20 2
20 4
26
20 8
30
20 2
20 4
36
20 8
40
20 2
44
20 6
48
4
2
3
2
4
2
2
2
3
1
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Note: Each scenario reflects the difference that is calculated as forced repatriation case - voluntary mobility case.
234
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 8.13: Distance to Higher Income Group Thresholds Based on GNI Per Capita
13,000
High-income: 12,056
12,000
11,000
10,000
GNI per capita, current US$
9,000
8,000
7,000
6,000
5,000
Upper-middle-income: 3,896
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
Lower-middle-income: 996
0
10
12
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
28
30
32
34
36
38
40
42
44
46
48
50
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Conflict Counterfactual (no conflict) Pessimistic Moderate Optimistic
Note: GNI per capita based on the World Bank Atlas Methodology for Syria is only available up to 2007. We impute future values based on actual
GDP per capita growth up to 2010 (at 2010 prices), our projections for GDP per capita growth over the conflict and post conflict periods (both
also at 2010 prices). We account for inflation up to 2019 based on US inflation rates.
On using GDP growth rates to proxy GNI growth rates, our calculations based on pre-conflict data suggest the growth rates of GDP per capita
in current US$ and GNI per capita based on the Atlas Methodology on average are quite close (e.g., 1998–2007: 7 percent versus 8 percent;
1993–2007: 5 percent versus 4 percent)
The post-conflict scenarios (pessimistic, moderate and optimistic) reflect the voluntary mobility case.
In figure 8.13, we show that at the tail end of the conflict (using 2018 as a reference point), Syria appears
to have fallen just below the LMI threshold. While once again surpassing this threshold is very likely in
the next few years, it would possibly take 18 and 26 years under the optimistic and moderate scenarios,
respectively, to breach the UMI threshold, and beyond 2050 for the pessimistic scenario. In contrast, in
the counterfactual of no conflict, Syria might have passed this level in about six years, that is by 2024. This
means that from 2010, while it could have taken Syria 14 years to become an UMI country, it may now take
about double, or even triple that time.
5. Conclusion
In this chapter, we use the Long Term Growth Model– Public Capital Extension (LTGM-PC, chapter 2 in
this volume) to answer three questions pertaining to Syria’s economic growth in the aftermath of its civil
conflict: What might have been the counterfactual of no conflict? What was the impact of the conflict? And
what are the possible growth paths given different scenarios post-conflict?
Our simulations of the conflict impact suggest an average GDP growth of –12% over 2011–2018, with
GDP declining to almost one-third the pre-conflict level. Cumulatively, the loss in GDP amounted to about
US$300 billion when compared against the counterfactual. These results are broadly in line with findings in
235
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
other studies. An added insight is that we identify how the different growth drivers might have contributed
to the decline in GDP. Close to 65% of the average negative GDP growth throughout the conflict years is
due to physical capital destruction, followed by destruction in labor (15%), TFP (13%), and human capital
(7%). This breakdown sets the stage for the analysis of Syria’s post-conflict GDP potential, which depends
on the projected evolution of these growth drivers.
The post-conflict outlook for the growth drivers depends on the political settlement outcome, which
directly affects the availability of reconstruction funds and the voluntary mobility of refugees. Voluntary
mobility would not only be preferable on humanitarian grounds but also on economic terms. The political
settlement scenario will also affect human capital and productivity growth rates.
In the voluntary mobility case, under our moderate scenario (partial political settlement with strong guar-
antees for micro-security and property rights), the average GDP per capita growth over 2019–2038 is 6.1%,
assuming a final and stable resolution of the conflict. With the inflow of reconstruction funds amounting
to US$140 billion spread over 20 years, the main growth driver over the 20-year period is physical capital
accumulation amid average investment-to-output of about 41%. As investment-to-output reverts to a lower
level, especially after the assumed 20-year annual inflow of reconstruction funds, the contributions from
human capital and TFP growth are just as relevant as physical capital growth. Syria reaches its 2010 GDP
per capita level by 2033, implying two “lost” decades from conflict.
Under the optimistic scenario (robust political settlement), with exceptionally high investment-to-output of
over 60% in the first decade (2019–2029), it would still take Syria about one decade to surpass its 2010 GDP
per capita level. Under the pessimistic scenario of limited guarantees for micro-security and property rights,
low reconstruction funds of US$30 billion (1.5 times the GDP level in 2018) and investment-to-output
close to the pre-conflict average, Syria’s GDP per capita reaches its pre-conflict level in about three decades.
Respectively for the optimistic and pessimistic scenarios, projected average GDP per capita growth rates
over the next two decades (2019–2029 and 2030–2039) are 8.2% and 3.1%, respectively.
While the reconstruction and expansion of physical infrastructure are essential, the importance of strength-
ening human capital and the factors underlying TFP growth cannot be overstated. We have only accounted
for population and enrollment effects on human capital growth. However, the quality of education and
health will also likely be impeding factors that would have to be addressed in Syria’s quest for growth.
Appendices are available at the journal website: https://doi.org/10.1080/17938120.2021.1930829.
References
Barro, R. J. and J. W. Lee. 2013. “A new dataset of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010.” Journal of
Development Economics 104: 184–198.
Barro, R. J. and J. W. Lee.. 2015. Education Matters: Global Schooling Gains from the 19th to the 21st Century. New York,
NY: Oxford University Press. Data source: http://barrolee.com/data/oup_download_c.htm.
Burns, A., B. P. M. Campagne, C. Jooste, D. A. Stephan, and T. T. Bui. 2019. “The World Bank Macro-Fiscal Model
Technical Description.” Policy Research Working Paper 8965, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Ceylan, E. S., and S. Tumen. 2018. “Measuring Economic Destruction in Syria From Outer Space.” The FORUM Policy
Portal. Economic Research Forum, Cairo, Egypt. https://theforum.erf.org.eg/2018/06/19/measuring-economic
-destruction-syria-outer-space/.
Chen, S., N. V. Loayza, and M. Reynal-Querol. 2008. “The Aftermath of Civil War.” The World Bank Economic Review
22 (1): 63–85.
Cohen, D., and L. Leker. 2014. “Health and Education: Another Look with the Proper Data.” CEPR Discussion Papers
No 9940. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.
236
The Long Term Growth Model
Cohen, D., and M. Soto. 2007. “Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results.” Journal of Economic Growth
12(1): pp.51–76.
Devadas, S., and S. M. Pennings. 2019. “Assessing the Effect of Public Capital on Growth: An Extension of the World
Bank Long-Term Growth Model.” Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development 3(1): 22–55.
Devarajan, S., and L. Mottaghi. 2017. “Middle East and North Africa Economic Monitor, April 2017: The Economics
of Post-Conflict Reconstruction in MENA.” Washington, DC: World Bank.
Djankov, S., and M. Reynal-Querol. 2010. “Poverty and Civil War: Revisiting the Evidence.” Review of Economics and
Statistics 92 (4): 1035–1041.
Elbadawi, I., B. Fallah, M. Louis, S. Makdisi, J. Yousef, R. Albinyana, and S. Tumen. 2019. “Repatriation of Refugees
from Arab Conflicts: Conditions, Costs and Scenarios for Reconstruction.” FEMISE EUROMED Report: FEMISE
and ERF (copyright @ FEMISE Association).
Elbadawi I. A., L. Kaltani, and K. Schmidt-Hebbel. 2008. “Foreign Aid, the Real Exchange Rate, and Economic Growth
in the Aftermath of Civil Wars.” The World Bank Economic Review 22(1): 113–140.
ESCWA (United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Western Asia). 2017. “The Strategic Policy Alternatives
Framework (SPAF) Syria Post-Conflict (Executive Summary).” The National Agenda for the Future of Syria
(NAFS) Programme.
ESCWA (United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Western Asia).2018. “Syria at War – Seven Years On
(The Economic Implications of the Conflict in Syria).” Presentation at Consultation Meeting on Policy Alternatives
for Post-Conflict Reconstruction and Economic Recovery. National Agenda for the Future of Syria. August.
Feenstra, Robert C., R. Inklaar, and M. P. Timmer. 2015. “The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.” American
Economic Review 105(10): 3150–3182. Available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt.
Gobat, J., and K. Kostial. 2016. “Syria’s Conflict Economy.” IMF Working Paper No. 16/13. Washington DC:
International Monetary Fund.
Hevia, C., and N. Loayza. 2012. “Savings and Growth in Egypt.” Middle East Development Journal. 4(1).
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2010. “Syrian Arab Republic: 2009 Article IV Consultation.” IMF Country
Report No. 10/86. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2011. World Economic Outlook (WEO). Washington DC: International Monetary
Fund. April
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2018. World Economic Outlook (WEO). Washington DC: International Monetary
Fund. October
Jánossy, F. 1969. The End of the Economic Miracle: Appearance and Reality in Economic Development. ISAP, New York.
Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2010. “The Worldwide Governance Indicators: A Summary of Methodology,
Data and Analytical Issues.” Policy Research Working Paper 5430, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Kim, Y. E., and N. Loayza. 2019. “Productivity Growth: Patterns and Determinants Across the World.” Policy Research
Working Paper 8852, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Li, X., D. Li, H. Xu, and C. Wu. 2017. “Intercalibration between DMSP/OLS and VIIRS Night-Time Light Images to
Evaluate City Light Dynamics of Syria’s Major Human Settlement during Syrian Civil War.” International Journal
of Remote Sensing 38(21).
Milionis P., and T. Vonyo. 2015. “Reconstruction Dynamics: The Impact of World War II on Post-War Economic
Growth.” American Economic Association: 2016 Annual Conference.
Milton, S. 2019. “Syrian Higher Education during Conflict: Survival, Protection, and Regime Security.” International
Journal of Educational Development 64: 38–47.
Nasser, R., and Z. Mehchy. 2012. “Determinants of Labor Force Participation in Syria (2001–2010).” Economic
Research Forum Working Paper No. 698. July.
Organski, A. F. K., and J. Kugler. 1977. “The Costs of Major Wars: The Phoenix Factor.” American Political Science
Review 71(14) :1347–66.
Organski, A. F. K., and J. Kugler. 1980. The War Ledger. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
POMEPS (Project on Middle East political Science). 2018. “The Politics of Post-Conflict Reconstruction.” POMEPS
Studies 30. https://pomeps.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/09/POMEPS_Studies_30_Post-Conflict_Web.pdf.
237
8. Growth in Syria: Losses from the War and Potential Recovery in the Aftermath
Sab, R. 2014. “Economic Impact of Selected Conflicts in the Middle East: What Can We Learn from the Past?” IMF
Working Paper No. 14/100. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Smolny, Werner. 2000. “Post-war Growth, Productivity Convergence and Reconstruction.” Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 62, 5: pp. 589–606.
SCPR (Syrian Center for Policy Research). 2016. “Syria. Confronting Fragmentation! Impact of Syrian Crisis Report
2015.” February.
The Conference Board. 2018. “Total Economy Database™ —Growth Accounting and Total Factor Productivity,
1950–2016.” November. https://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/.
UNICEF (United Nations Children’s Fund). 2016. “Syria Crisis Education Strategic Paper— London 2016 Conference.”
———. 2018. “A Future Stolen: Young and Out-of-School.”
United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. 2011. “World Population Prospects:
The 2010, Volume 1: Comprehensive Tables.”
United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. 2013. “World Population Prospects:
The 2012, Volume 1: Comprehensive Tables.”
United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. 2017. “World Population Prospects:
The 2017 Revision.” https://population.un.org/wpp/DataQuery/.
UNDP (United Nations Development Programme) and UNHCR (United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees).
2019. “Regional Strategic Overview—Regional Refugee and Resilience Plan in Response to the Syria Crisis.”
United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees (UNHCR). 2018. “Fourth Regional Survey on Syrian Refugees’
Perceptions and Intentions on Return to Syria (RPIS).” July 2018.
Verme, P., C. Gigliarano, C. Wieser, K. Hedlund, M. Petzoldt, and M. Santacroce. 2016. “The Welfare of Syrian
Refugees: Evidence from Jordan and Lebanon.” Washington, DC: World Bank.
Vignal, L. 2018. “Perspectives on the Return of Syrian Refugees. In Syrians in Displacement.” Forced Migration Review
Issue 57: February.
World Bank. 2017. “The Toll of War— The Economic and Social Consequences of the Conflict in Syria.” Washington
DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2018. World Development Indicator (WDI). Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2019. “The Mobility of Displaced Syrians— An Economic and Social Analysis.” Washington DC:
World Bank.
Yahya, M., and J. Kassir. 2017. “Coming Home? A Political Settlement in Syria Must Focus on Refugees.” Policy
Outlook: Carnegie Middle East Center, March.
238
Chapter 9
Abstract
This chapter illustrates the mechanisms linking at current rates of national saving and would require
national saving and economic growth, with the pur- a saving effort that is highly unrealistic. For instance,
pose of understanding the possibilities and limits of financing a constant 4% growth rate of gross domestic
a saving-based growth agenda in the context of the product (GDP) per capita with no TFP improvement
Egyptian economy. This is done through a simple the- would require a national saving rate of around 50%
oretical model, calibrated to fit the Egyptian economy, in the first decade and 80% in 25 years! However, if
and simulated to explore different potential scenarios. productivity rises, sustaining and improving high
The main conclusion is that if the Egyptian economy rates of economic growth becomes viable. Following
does not experience progress in productivity— the previous example, a 2% growth rate of TFP would
stemming from technological innovation, improved allow a 4% growth rate of GDP per capita, with a
public management, and private-sector reforms—, national saving rate in the realistic range of 20-25%
then a high rate of economic growth is not feasible of GDP.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of Hevia, C., and N. Loayza. 2012. “Saving and Growth in Egypt.” Middle East Development
E
Journal, Vol. 4, No. 1, and an earlier version as World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 5529. This chapter represents the first
version of the model that would go on to evolve into the standard LTGM (chapter 1) several years later. As such, the model presented
in the chapter differs in notation and substance from the main LTGM of chapter 1. Appendices are available at the journal website:
https://doi.org/10.1142/S1793812012500022. Affiliations are based on when the paper was written, not necessarily current affiliations.
2
onstantino Hevia and Norman V.Loayza, World Bank. Corresponding author email: nloayza@worldbank.org. The views expressed in
C
this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, their Boards of Directors, or the countries
they represent.We are grateful to Minister Mahmoud Mohieldin, Farrukh Iqbal, Santiago Herrera, Inessa Love, Alan MacArthur, Tarek
Moursi, Brian Pinto, Ritva Reinikka, Luis Servén, Lyn Squire, and two anonymous referees for useful insights and comments. We are
indebted to Hoda Youssef and Yuki Ikeda for data collection and to Tomoko Wada for editorial assistance.
239
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
Introduction
The relationship between national saving and economic growth is quantitatively strong and robust to
different types of data and methodologies (Mankiw et al. 1992; Attanasio et al. 2000; Banerjee and Duflo
2005; among many others). Countries that have high saving rates for long periods of time tend to experience
large and sustained economic growth. A prime example is the experience of the developing countries in
East Asia, such as China, Singapore, the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, and Taiwan (Young 1995;
figure 9.1).
It is only understandable, therefore, that goals to increase economic growth usually refer back to concerns
for raising national saving. In the last decades Egypt has been above the typical (or median) country in
the world regarding both growth and saving. Its development aspirations, however, require a stronger
performance on both accounts.
To be sure, some of the relationship between growth and saving reflects the positive impact that higher
income has on improved saving (Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel, and Serven 2000). However, no less important is
the causality that runs from higher saving to larger growth, where the mechanism resides on the well-known
process of capital accumulation. Improved national saving provides the funds to take advantage of more
and larger investment opportunities. This, in turn, increases the capital stock which, when effectively used
for economic production contributes to higher output growth. Although in theory domestic investment
does not have to be supported by national saving, in practice the connection between the two is quite close.
This is especially true in the long run, when external sources of funds can be tapped only in a restricted
manner: large current account deficits cannot be sustained indefinitely. This is exemplified by the strong
10
y = 0.1303x – 0.0078
t = 7.26
CHN
R² = 0.345
8
6
Per capita GDP growth (%)
KOR
TWN
THA SGP
IND
MUS
4 POLIRL
IDN
HKG
LKA CYP BLR MYS
CHL LUX
SVN TKM
UGA SWZDOMLVA
PAK EGY
TUN
TUR BGR KAZSVK
SDN NOR
LTU PRT ESP FINCZE
2 TCD GBR PAN MAR
AUSAUT TTO
RWA URY
BFA
CRI
ISL
USA
ROM
COL
HUN
SWE
DNK
GRCCAN BEL NLD
DEU
JPN
ITA
FRA EST
NZL
ARGPER MEX JOR
GHA BRAJAM
ECU IRN CHE
BEN SLV PHL
HND
GTM FJI PRY
ZAF DZA
MLI GMB
SENMRT BOL KEN
MWI
0 SLE KGZ PNG VEN
TGO UKR
NERCAF SAU
–2 HTI
CIV
–4
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
National saving rate (%GDP)
240
The Long Term Growth Model
relationship between the average saving and investment rates across countries in the last three decades, as
depicted in figure 9.2. Mirroring its saving-growth situation, Egypt conforms to the cross-country pattern
regarding the relationship between saving and investment. The links in the relationship between saving
and growth are not, however, mechanical but depend on the quality of the financial system and public
institutions in general. Without an efficient financial system, the best investment opportunities will not
be matched with the available saving (Levine 2005). Likewise, without proper public institutions (that
guarantee macroeconomic stability and contract enforcement, for instance), accumulated capital may
remain idle or ineffectively used (Hall and Jones 1999; Easterly and Levine 2001). This points to the crucial
importance of the efficiency or productivity with which physical capital, human capital, and labor are used
in the production process. The growth of factor productivity is what in the end determines whether a saving
and investment effort will result (or not) in improved economic growth.
The objective of this study is to illustrate the mechanisms linking national saving and economic growth
in Egypt. We will do this through a simple theoretical model, calibrated to fit the Egyptian economy,
and simulated to explore different potential scenarios. Our goal is to understand the two-way connection
between saving and growth and the possibilities and limits of a saving-based growth agenda, in the context
of the Egyptian economy.
The optimality of saving behavior can be addressed from different angles. The most common in the academic
literature is the perspective of optimal saving as the behavior that maximizes a consumer welfare function.
This, however, may be too abstract for the needs and objectives of policy practitioners. For this reason, we
pose the problem of optimal saving from the perspective of financing a given rate of economic growth while
simultaneously achieving external sustainability. First, we present the basic elements of a simple model,
constructed with the purpose of understanding optimal saving from this perspective. Next, we calibrate
the model to the Egyptian economy, using parameters and relationships obtained in the received literature
for the country. Using the calibrated model, we perform some simulations that clarify the relationships
between saving, productivity, and growth, allowing us to discuss policy options for improving economic
growth in Egypt.
45
y = 0.5611x + 0.1127
t = 14.49
40 R² = 0.6775
CHN
35 TKM
SGP
Investment Rate (%GDP)
KOR
EST THA DZA
30 LVA
IRN
MYS
SVK BLR
CZE JPN
TUNJOR IDN
CYP HKG
25 ROM HND
LKA PRT
HUNAUS KAZ
BGR MUS
IND
MARUKR
JAM ESP SVN CHE
POL PRY PNG NOR
MRT LTU NZL PER MEX
ISLGRC
EGYFIN
AUT TWN
LUX
CHL VEN
MLI ECU
GMB TURPANITA DEU
IRL SAUNLD
TTO
20 KGZ
MWI
SWZ
CRI DOM
KENBFAHTI PHLCAN
COLZAF FRA
DNK BEL
FJI USABRA
TGO GHA PAK
SEN
ARG
GBR SWE
TCD SDN
BEN
RWA
GTM
15 URY
UGA BOLSLV
NER CIV
10 SLE CAF
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
National saving rate (%GDP)
241
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
where Yt denotes output, Kt is the stock of physical capital, Lt denotes the amount of effective labor input,
At is a measure of the level productivity of capital and labor, and the technology parameter α ∈ Î (0,1)
measures the relative contribution of capital to the production of output—in a competitive economy,
the parameter α coincides with the share of output distributed as payments to capital. As mentioned
above, in the appendix we consider a multi-sector version of the model, where each sector has its own
productivity parameter and factor shares. There, we examine the possibility that each sector faces specific
distortions to output and capital/labor allocations. The multi-sector version of the model allows us to
interpret changes in aggregate productivity as reflecting changes in both sectoral productivities and sectoral
allocation distortions.
We abstract from distributional issues and assume that labor is homogeneous across the population.
Following Bils and Klenow (2000) and Hall and Jones (1999) we assume that every worker has been trained
with Et years of schooling with f rate of return per year of education, delivering productivity e φ Et per
worker. Thus, effective labor is given by
Lt = e φ Et N t , (2)
where Nt denotes the total number of workers. In this specification, fEt measures the relative efficiency of a
worker with Et years of schooling relative to one with no schooling. Note that in this formulation, a worker’s
efficiency depends not only on the years of schooling but also on the quality and relevance of education
for production purposes.
Capital depreciates at a constant rate δ between time periods, but can be augmented through investment.
Namely, the stock of capital evolves according to
Kt+1 = (1 − δ) + It (3)
where It denotes aggregate investment.
Abstracting from valuation changes, the current account deficit at period t, CADt, is defined as the change
in net foreign liabilities of the whole economy; that is,
CADt ≡ Bt+1− Bt = rBt + Ct + Gt + It − Yt − TRt , (4)
where Bt is the stock of net foreign liabilities due at period t; r is the world interest rate, assumed constant for
simplicity; Ct denotes private consumption; Gt denotes government expenditures; and TRt denotes the flow
of net external current transfers (worker remittances plus official grants) that are not reflected as changes
in the country’s net foreign liabilities.3
3
istorically, workers’ remittances and official grants to Egypt have been an important fraction of GDP, averaging about 5% in
H
the present decade.
242
The Long Term Growth Model
If we let StN = Yt + TRt − rBt − C t − Gt denote aggregate national saving, the previous equation can be
rearranged into the familiar investment-saving gap identity of an open economy,
I t = StN + CADt . (5)
That is, domestic investment It can be financed through national saving or through external borrowing
(i.e., foreign saving).
External solvency requires that the current value of foreign liabilities be no larger than the present value of
net exports, and can be obtained by iterating forward on the current account identity, equation (4), namely,
∞
1
∑ 1+ r Yt + j + TRt + j − I t + j − C t + j − Gt + j = (1 + r ) Bt .
( )
j
j =0
This solvency condition imposes certain assumptions about the functioning of international capital mar-
kets that are difficult to reconcile with the experience of emerging market economies. In particular, it fails
to capture the financial frictions that are pervasive in developing countries. For this reason, we follow
Milesi-Ferretti and Razin (1996) and impose a sufficient condition for current account sustainability that
is also appealing in terms of its realism.
We assume that the economy is required to maintain the ratio of foreign debt to gross domestic product
constant, namely, that
Bt
= β for all t . (6)
Yt
This constraint can be due to the reluctance of foreigners to lend money when the level of debt is sufficiently
high, or because the government wants to maintain a safe level of foreign borrowing relative to output.4
Using the definition of the current account, the last constraint imposes the following restriction on the
current account deficit as a fraction of gross domestic output,
CADt Bt +1 Yt +1 Bt Y
= − = β t +1 − 1 . (7)
Yt Yt +1 Yt Yt Yt
That is, the ratio of the current account deficit to the value of output depends upon the net foreign
liabilities as a fraction of GDP, b, and on the growth rate of output, Yt+1/Yt. For example, if the economy
is a net borrower (b > 0) and contemplates growing (Yt+1 > Yt), then it must necessarily run a current
account deficit.
We find it convenient to rewrite all previous equations in per-worker terms. Introducing the definition of
effective labor equation (2) into the production function equation (1) and dividing the resulting expression
by Nt gives
y t = At ktα (e φ Et )
1−α
(8)
where yt =Yt/Nt denotes output per worker and kt =Kt/Nt is capital per worker. More generally, throughout
the chapter lowercase letters are used to denote variables in per-worker terms.
4
lternatively, we could assume that the interest rate that the country pays on its foreign debt, r, depends on the difference
A
between the actual and some target level of the debt-to-GDP ratio. With this modification, there is an endogenous risk
premium that induces the debt-to-GDP ratio to converge to the target value in the long run (Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe 2003).
Because of this fact, we conjecture that the main message of the paper is the same in the alternative model.
243
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
Following the same approach, we write the equilibrium equations (3), (5), and (7) in per-worker terms,
kt+1(1 + γNt) = (1−δ)kt +it, (9)
and
cadt
= β (1 + γ yt )(1 + γ Nt ) − 1. (11)
yt
where γNt = Nt+1/Nt − 1 denotes the growth rate of the workforce between periods t and t + 1. More generally,
we denote by γxt the (net) growth rate between periods t and t + 1 of any variable xt.
We now use the previous equations to write a condition that relates saving and growth. First, we use the
production function, equation (8) at periods t and t + 1 to write the growth rate in output per worker as
1−α
(1+γ yt ) = (1+γ At )(1+γ kt )α e φ ( Et+1 − Et ) (12)
That is, the (gross) growth rate of output (1 + γyt) depends upon the growth rate of productivity (1 + γAt),
the growth rate of the stock of capital (1 + γkt), and the growth rate of human capital e φ ( Et+1 − Et ).
Second, introducing the investment-saving equation (10) into the capital accumulation equation (9) and
rearranging gives
it y t s N + cadt y t
(1 + γ kt ) (1 + γ Nt ) = 1 − δ + =1−δ + t .
y t kt yt kt
This equation describes the growth rate of the stock of capital per worker as a function of the growth rate of
the workforce γNt, the depreciation rate δ, the national saving ratio with respect to output StN /y t , the current
account deficit as a fraction of GDP cadt/yt , and the degree of capital deepening in the economy kt/yt.
Imposing the sustainability condition, equation (11) into the last equation, the evolution of the capital
stock becomes
yt
(1 + γ kt ) (1 + γ Nt ) = 1 − δ + {σ t + β[(1 + γ yt )(1 + γ Nt ) − 1]} , (13)
kt
where σ t = stN /y t denotes the national saving ratio with respect to GDP.5
Finally, introducing equation (13) into the output growth equation (12) gives an expression that links the
growth rate of output per worker to the national saving ratio st, the growth rate of productivity γAT, the
growth rate of the workforce γNT, the increase in human capital f(Et+1−Et), and the level of capital deepening
kt/yt,
α
yt
1 − δ + {σ t + β[(1 + γ yt )(1 + γ Nt ) − 1]} k
(1 + γ yt ) = (1 + γ At ) 1 + γ Nt
t
e (1−α )φ ( Et+1 − Et ) . (14)
5
Note that stN /y t is neither the national saving rate nor the domestic saving rate as defined in the national accounts statistics.
y N = y t − rbt + TRt
The national saving rate is defined as stN /y tN where t is national disposable income, whereas the domestic
saving rate is defined as st /y t , where stD = y t − c t − g t is domestic saving.
D
244
The Long Term Growth Model
This equation shows that output growth is positively associated with the national saving ratio and with
the growth rate in productivity, the workforce, and human capital. As the economy grows, however, the
capital-GDP ratio kt/yt changes as well. Therefore, the level of saving required to finance a given growth rate
in output per worker varies through time.
Productivity growth is determined exogenously and directly in this version of the model. In the multi-sector
extension examined in the appendix, aggregate productivity growth depends on both sectoral productivity
improvements (proportional to the importance of the sector in final output) and the (sudden or grad-
ual) elimination of any sector-specific distortion. While the former can be a continuous and permanent
process, the latter can only have a temporary impact (until the reallocation of resources across sectors is
completed).
Throughout the chapter, we have assumed that investment is fully transformed into capital (see equation (3).
However, the efficiency of investment to generate productive capital may be diminished in contexts of
institutional or regulatory weaknesses (Rodrik and Subramanian 2009). To the extent that these weaknesses
may also have a negative impact on TFP improvements, they would reinforce the need for higher savings
to achieve a given rate of economic growth. This effect would be moderated, nonetheless, if higher saving
rates in turn have a positive impact on the efficiency of investment. This may occur through a variety of
channels, for example, the beneficial effect of higher savings on the quality of financial intermediation
(Allen and Gale 2000) and the competitiveness of the exchange rate (Rodrik 2008).7
6
This approximation is only for illustration purposes. We always use equation (14) to compute the experiments.
7
onsider the standard model as described in the text, but assume that the capital accumulation equation is given by
C
Kt = (1 − δ)Kt + λIt so that λ represents the efficiency of each unit of investment. The baseline model assumes λ = 1; however,
in a context of, for instance, institutional weakness where investment expenditures do not fully lead to productive capital, λ may
be lower than 1. Considering this possibility, the only thing that changes in equation (14) is that the term yt/kt now appears
multiplied by the parameter λ. Therefore, solving for the saving ratio, st, given a target growth rate, γyt, leads to
1/α
1 kt 1 + γ yt − β (1 + γ y t ) (1 + γ Nt ) − 1
σt = (1 + γ Nt ) − 1 + δ
λ yt (1 + γ At ) e (1−α )φ (Et +1 − Et )
Everything else constant, the lower the efficiency of investment (smaller λ), the higher the saving rate would have to be in
order to achieve the same growth rate. On the other hand, if the efficiency of investment depended positively on the saving rate
(through the mechanisms mentioned in the text), the need for higher saving rates would be correspondingly moderated.
245
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
• The current capital-output ratio: k /y = 2.6. This is the ratio estimated for the year 2008, using the
t t
methodology and basic information from Loayza and Honorati (2007). This chapter applies the
perpetual inventory method to accumulate investment in order to produce a measure of the capital
stock. For this purpose, it uses a depreciation rate of 0.04, consistent with that used in this study (see
below).
• The capital share in output: α = 0.5. This is an average of the most sensible estimates available. Using
time-series analysis, Loayza and Honorati (2007) estimate the capital share in Egypt, to be 0.35. This
is also the average across countries that Bernanke and Gürkaynak (2002) obtain using factor payment
data from national accounts. Herrera (2009) uses a combination of national accounts information and
labor survey data for Egypt to arrive at a larger estimate of the capital share in Egypt, 0.6.
• The annual capital depreciation rate: δ = 0.04. This is the depreciation rate used in the estimation of the
capital stock and follows the seminal work of Nehru and Dhareshwar (1993).
• The annual growth rate of the labor force: γNt = 0.025. This is the average growth rate of the number
of workers for the period 2001–2008, as estimated from Egypt’s national employment statistics. This
represents an update of the estimate presented in Loayza and Honorati (2007).
• The annual average increase in education: (Et+1 − Et) = 0.12. Education is proxied by the average number
of schooling years in the adult population, as reported in Said (2008) for Egypt for the period 1980–
2000. This estimate for the average increase in schooling is similar to that obtained using the Barro and
Lee (2001) database for the same period.
• The average annual rate of return to education: ϕ = 0.05. This is proxied by the average rate of return for
each year of schooling, as reported in Herrera (2009) for Egypt for the period 1988–2006.
• The current (or targeted) level of net foreign liabilities as a ratio to GDP: β = 0.2. This corresponds to
the official “international investment position” on average for the period 2001–2007, as reported by the
International Monetary Fund’s (IMF’s) Balance of Payments Statistics.
tr
• Net income plus transfers from abroad, as a ratio to GDP: −rβ + t = 0.052. The numerator of this
yt
ratio is equal to the difference between Gross National Disposable Income (GNDI) and gross domestic
product (GDP), and the ratio corresponds to the average for the period 2001–2007. It is obtained from
statistics reported by the World Bank and the IMF.
Productivity scenarios. A key parameter in the simulations presented below is the rate of growth of total
factor productivity, γAT. The available estimated rates of TFP growth in Egypt vary according to the period
under consideration and the method of estimation (Herrera 2009; Loayza and Honorati 2007). They range
from approximately –1.5% to 2.5%, with the extreme rates lasting for short periods of time. Our goal
here is to establish what a reasonable range is for TFP growth for long periods of time (say 25 years, the
simulation horizon). On the one hand, it is difficult to understand how TFP growth rates can be negative
for a sustained period of time, unless there is prolonged macroeconomic disarray (e.g., hyper-inflation, civil
conflict, or systemic financial crisis). In times of socioeconomic stability, a reasonable lower bound for a
TFP growth rate is 0, representing lack of progress. On the other hand, it is also difficult to accept long-run
TFP growth rates that exceed those that the highest growing countries have been able to achieve for a
sustained period of time. According to the TFP growth estimates presented in Bernanke and Gürkaynak
(2002), only the top 5 percent of countries in the world have been able to achieve an average growth rate
246
The Long Term Growth Model
of TFP around 2% during the period 1965–1995. This, then, seems to be a reasonable upper bound for
TFP growth for a sustained period of time in Egypt. In the simulations that follow, we will consider three
scenarios: pessimistic, moderate, and optimistic, depending on whether the TFP growth rate is 0%, 1%, or
2%, respectively.
247
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
50
40
30
20
10
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324
Years
National saving/GDP
Physical capital
Domestic saving/GDP accumulation 92%
Investment/GDP
Proportion
0.6
0.9 0.5
0.4
0.3
0.8
0.2
0.1
0.7 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 192021 222324
Years Years
TFP growth
Physical capital accumulation
Human capital accumulation
fixed saving ratio). The contribution of physical capital to economic growth declines over time (implying
a declining share with respect to that of human capital in the Solow growth decomposition, shown on the
right side of the lower panel).
Let us now turn to the moderate scenario, where TFP grows at a constant rate of 1% (figure 9.4). The
first simulation indicates that achieving a target of GDP per worker growth rate of 4% is still a difficult
goal. It would require a jump in national saving/GDP from the current 20% to about 30% and then a
further increase over time to around 40% in 25 years. (As explained above, investment would be larger than
national saving given the participation of foreign investors, and domestic saving lower than national saving
because of net transfers from abroad in the form of official grants and workers’ remittances.) The lion’s
share of the contribution to growth would still need to come from capital accumulation, with one-fourth
coming from TFP growth (see Solow growth decomposition on the right side of the upper panel). However,
although the required increase in national saving is substantial, it is no longer infeasible (as was the case
248
The Long Term Growth Model
30
25
20
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324
Years
National saving/GDP
Physical capital
Domestic saving/GDP accumulation 67%
Investment/GDP
Growth decomposition
Growth of GDP per worker
2.50 1.0
0.9
0.8
2.25 0.7
Proportion
0.6
Percent
0.5
0.4
2.00 0.3
0.2
0.1
1.75 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 192021 222324
Years Years
TFP growth
Physical capital accumulation
Human capital accumulation
with zero TFP growth). In fact, similar or even larger jumps in national saving have taken place in East Asian
countries, most notably China, and have supported their remarkable growth performance.
The second simulation under the moderate scenario shows the behavior of GDP per worker growth when
national saving stays at the current level of 20% of GDP. Given TFP growth of 1%, the growth rate of GDP
per worker is expected to rise gradually from about 2.1% to 2.4% in the 25 years of the simulation period.
In contrast to the case of zero TFP growth, when TFP grows even moderately, the same rate of national
saving leads not only to higher but also to increasing GDP per worker growth. TFP growth alleviates the
restriction of foreign saving, producing a level of investment rate of 1 percentage point of GDP higher than
national saving (and 6 percentage points higher than domestic saving). Moreover, TFP growth reduces the
pressure of diminishing capital returns, which combined with higher investment leads to an expansion of
the contribution that capital accumulation makes to output growth (see the Solow growth decomposition
on the right of the lower panel in figure 9.4).
249
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
Finally, let us consider the optimistic case, where TFP grows at a 2% rate (figure 9.5). According to the first
simulation (upper panel), the required saving rates to finance a 4% GDP growth per worker is only slightly
higher than current averages. National saving would need to rise to about 24% of GDP and then gradually
decrease to 21%, meaning that the same growth target can be financed with a lower saving effort over time.
As the Solow growth decomposition shows, now one-half the contribution to GDP per worker growth
comes from TFP. It is this impulse that relieves the pressure on capital accumulation which can now take
second stage on the generation of economic growth.
The second simulation under high TFP growth indicates that GDP per worker growth will start strong and
increase even further, from 3.1% to 4.2% in the 25 years of the simulation horizon (figure 9.5. lower panel).
This is achieved even while maintaining the national saving rate at the current level of 20% of GDP. As the
Solow growth decomposition shows, the contribution of capital accumulation actually grows over time,
from about 20% to 40% of economic growth. More strongly than in the moderate case, the growth of TFP
allows higher participation of foreign saving (and thus a larger investment rate), produces a higher level of
national saving, and alleviates the pressure of decreasing capital marginal productivity.
25
Percent
Physical
TFP
20 capital
growth
accumulation
50%
42%
15
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324
Years
National saving/GDP
Domestic saving /GDP
Investment/GDP
0.6
Percent
3.5 0.5
0.4
0.3
3.0
0.2
0.1
2.5 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 222324 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 192021 222324
24
Years Years
TFP growth
Physical capital accumulation
Human capital accumulation
250
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 9.1: Required Saving Rate to Finance 4% Per Capita GDP Growth
(benchmark calibration and parameter variations to check for robustness)
251
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
chapter is, in fact, reinforced. Take, for example, the economy with moderate TFP growth in table 9.1. The
required national saving rate to finance 4 percent of GDP per capita growth increases to 41 percent in
5 years, 49 percent in 10 years, and 81 percent in 25 years. These rates are substantially larger than those
obtained under the baseline calibration. Likewise, table 9.2 shows that when the capital share in output
decreases, projected growth rates decrease as well over the next 25 years relative to the baseline calibration.
The intuition for this result is as follows: as the capital share in output decreases, the contribution of capital
to total output decreases as well. Thus, if growth is to be sustained through capital accumulation alone
(instead of productivity growth), investment must increase at a substantially higher rate, inducing a higher
burden on domestic saving. The need to increase productivity to achieve growth is even more important
when α decreases relative to the baseline calibration.
Consider now the depreciation rate, δ. In the baseline calibration we set δ = 0.04. While this is a standard
value, many studies consider higher depreciation rates. We thus study the properties of our model when
the annual depreciation rate of capital is 6 percentage points. As above, our results are reinforced with
the new calibration. Table 9.1 shows that, for any degree of TFP growth, national saving rates required to
finance a growth rate of GDP per capita of 4 percent invariably increase as δ increases from 0.04 to 0.06.
Likewise, table 9.2 shows that, given a level of TFP growth, projected per capita GDP growth rates are lower
when the depreciation rate increases. In effect, as δ increases, a larger fraction of capital depreciates from
year to year. Thus, if GDP growth rates are to remain constant—as the exercises in table 9.1 assume—the
investment rate must increase to maintain the same growth rate in the stock of capital. Given TFP, this
can be achieved only through an increase in national saving. Likewise, if the national saving rate remains
constant, increasing the depreciation rate induces lower capital accumulation, and therefore, a lower GDP
per-capita growth (table 9.2).
Table 9.2: Projected Per Capita Growth Rate if Saving Rate Remains at 20% of GDP
(benchmark calibration and parameter variations to check for robustness)
Productivity growth scenarios Per-capita GDP growth rate over time (%)
5 years 10 years 25 years
Pessimistic scenario: γA = 0%
Baseline calibration 1.0 0.9 0.8
Capital share, α = 0.35 0.9 0.8 0.7
Depreciation rate, δ = 0.06 0.0 0.2 0.4
Long-run debt/GDP, β = 0.4 1.2 1.0 0.8
Moderate scenario: γA = 1%
Baseline calibration 2.1 2.2 2.4
Capital share, α = 0.35 1.9 2.0 2.1
Depreciation rate, δ = 0.06 1.0 1.6 2.1
Long-run debt/GDP, β = 0.4 2.3 2.4 2.5
Optimistic scenario: γA = 2%
Baseline calibration 3.1 3.6 4.2
Capital share, α = 0.35 3.0 3.3 3.5
Depreciation rate, δ = 0.06 2.1 3.0 3.9
Long-run debt/GDP, β = 0.4 3.4 3.8 4.3
252
The Long Term Growth Model
Consider finally an increase in the targeted value of foreign debt as a fraction of GDP, β. In the baseline
calibration we chose β = 0.2 to match historical evidence in Egypt. But 20 percent of GDP of foreign debt
is somewhat low based on the international evidence. By increasing the targeted level of debt to GDP
ratio, Egypt could reduce the dependence on national saving and rely more on foreign saving to finance
its domestic investment. Thus, in the final experiment we assume that β increases from 20 percent of
GDP to 40 percent of GDP. While, in effect, a larger fraction of domestic investment can be financed by
foreign investors, we find this effect to be quantitatively small. Consider, for example, the moderate TFP
growth scenario in table 9.1. While it is true that the required national saving decreases when β doubles,
these declines are small: in a 25-year span, the difference between domestic saving rates under the baseline
calibration relative to the higher debt calibration never exceeds 2 percentage points. Similarly, if the national
saving rate is fixed at 20 percent of GDP (table 9.2), projected growth rates are very similar when compared
to those in the baseline calibration.
In summary, we performed a number of robustness checks relative to some parameters that are difficult
to calibrate or subject to controversy: the capital share in output, the depreciation rate of capital, and the
targeted level of foreign debt to GDP. In all cases, our main message remains intact: a growth agenda based
on increasing national saving alone is not sustainable; a successful development strategy requires large and
persistent increases in productivity.
Table 9.3: Required Saving Rate to Finance 4% Per Capita GDP Growth
8
or an analysis of total factor productivity in Egypt, see Loayza and Honorati (2007), Favaro, Garrido, and Stucka (2009), and
F
Herrera et al. (2010).
253
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
Table 9.4: Projected Per Capita Growth Rate if Saving Rate Remains at 20% of GDP
Our main conclusion is that if the Egyptian economy does not experience progress in productivity—stem-
ming from technological innovation, improved public management, and private-sector reforms—, then a
high rate of economic growth is not feasible at current rates of national saving and would require a saving
effort that is highly unrealistic. However, if productivity starts to rise to at least moderate levels, sustaining
and improving high rates of economic growth becomes viable. For the goal of achieving high economic
growth, the national saving effort can realistically only be alleviated by forceful and purposeful productivity
improvements.9
The following describes selected policy measures and reforms that could be implemented to foster sustained
productivity growth in Egypt. These measures broadly fall under the areas of institutional reform and
infrastructure provision.
Consider first the privatization of state-owned firms. In 1991, over 300 state-owned firms were identified
as candidates for privatization in Egypt (Law 203). Evidence suggests that firms privatized under the new
law enjoyed a substantial increase in productivity. In effect, this improvement in productivity was observed
with great strength during the 1990s, the period when most of the privatization wave took place: privatized
firms increased investment expenditures, profitability, and overall efficiency (Omran 1997). Related to this
point is the observation that, historically, a unit of investment by the private sector is almost invariably more
productive than a unit of public investment (World Bank 2008). Moreover, there is evidence that non-in-
frastructure public investment crowds out private investment in Egypt (Fawzy and El-Megharbel 2004).
Today, many firms identified by Law 203 as candidates for privatization still remain publicly owned—the
privatization wave was temporarily stalled in the late 1990s, but partially resumed in mid-2004. In light
of the above evidence—and, more generally, worldwide evidence—it is expected that continuing with the
privatization effort is likely to promote significant productivity gains.
An analysis of firm-level data shows that Egypt has experienced substantial progress in labor and total factor
productivity between 2004 and 2008 (World Bank 2009). Moreover, the same study reports substantial
progress in improving the overall investment climate during these years. In effect, the country experienced
significant improvements in the tax code, in customs and tax administration, and in how costly it is to
open a new business—in monetary and non-monetary terms. Yet, firms still report macroeconomic and
regulatory uncertainty as the main constraints on their operations and growth. Therefore, effort should be
devoted in simplifying rules and providing consistent and clear information (see Helmy [2005] for the case
of bankruptcy regulation); and in reducing macroeconomic uncertainty, mainly through the consistent and
predictable conduct of monetary policy—and, therefore, the management of inflation.
9
I n any case, increasing the national saving rate is still a desirable objective. Hevia, Ikeda, and Loayza (2010) discuss policy
measures targeted at increasing national saving independently of productivity.
254
The Long Term Growth Model
In addition, more effort should be devoted to improving public infrastructure, preferably through changes in
the composition of public expenditures and increased private sector participation (Fawzy and El-Megharbel
2004). In effect, since the mid-1990s infrastructure investment has suffered a substantial decline—mostly
due to lower public investment. While the current level of infrastructure in Egypt is what is expected given
its national income, the low level of investment is unlikely to sustain the current stock of infrastructure
given its natural depreciation and aging. Estimates in Loayza and Odawara (2010) suggest that increasing
infrastructure investment from 5 to 6 percentage points of GDP is expected to raise the annual per capita
growth rate of GDP by about 0.5 percentage points in the medium term and about 1.0 percentage point in
the long run. Moreover, if the increase in infrastructure investment does not imply a heavier tax burden,
the increase in growth would be substantially larger. In fact, there is ample room for private sector par-
ticipation—alone or in partnership with the government—especially in the transport sector (Ragab and
Fouad 2009). Because infrastructure and other factors of production complement each other, an increase
in infrastructure investment is expected to increase the productivity of physical capital and labor. In effect,
in the light of our simple model, an increase in the level of infrastructure is immediately reflected as an
increase in total factor productivity. It should be noted, however, that increasing infrastructure investment
does not necessarily mean building new roads or new telephone lines. The maintenance and improvement
of the current infrastructure should also be amply beneficial.
The model, calibration, and simulation presented in the chapter provide a stylized analytical tool to exam-
ine the possibilities and limitations of a saving-based growth agenda. In our view, it focuses on the most
relevant issues for the current Egyptian experience. Although it may be applicable to other countries and
contexts, various extensions would surely be needed to accommodate specific cases. A richer model would
take into account, among other things, the disaggregation of savings into its public and private components
and the relationship between the two; the behavioral response of private savings to changes in income,
demographic structure, and economic uncertainty; the changing nature of external solvency in the presence
of concessional borrowing, international financial shocks, or financial deepening; and the sectoral sources
of improvement in total factor productivity. This we leave for future work.
Appendices are available at the journal website: https://doi.org/10.1142/S1793812012500022.
References
Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale. 2000. Comparing Financial Systems. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Attanasio, Orazio P., Lucio Picci, and Antonello Scurco. 2000. “Saving, Growth and Investment: A Macroeconomic
Analysis Using a Panel of Countries.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (2): 182–211.
Banerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Duflo. 2005. “Growth Theory Through the Lens of Development Economics.” In
Handbook of Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf, eds. Vol. 1A, pp. 473–552. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
Barro, Robert, and Jong-Wha Lee. 2001. “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications.”
Oxford Economic Papers 53 (3): 541–563.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Refet S. Gürkaynak. 2002. “Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer, and Weil Seriously.”
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, Vol. 16, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Refet S. Gürkaynak, 11–72. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow. 2000. “Does Schooling Cause Growth?” American Economic Review 90 (5): 1160–1183.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models.” World
Bank Economic Review 15: 177–219.
Favaro, Edgardo, Leonardo Garrido, and Tihomir Stucka. 2009. “The Global Crisis and the Egyptian Economy.”
Mimeo. World Bank.
Fawzy, Samiha, and Nihal El-Megharbel. 2004. “Public and Private Investment in Egypt: Crowding-Out or Crowding-
In?” The Egyptian Center for Economic Studies, Working Paper Series ECESWP96-A.
255
9. Saving and Growth in Egypt
Gollin, Douglas. 2002. “Getting Income Shares Right.” Journal of Political Economy. Vol 110(2): 458–474.
Hall, Robert E., and Jones, Charles I. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker
Than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83–116.
Helmy, Omneia. 2005. “The Efficiency of the Bankruptcy System in Egypt.” The Egyptian Center for Economic
Studies, Working Paper Series ECESWP100-E.
Herrera, Santiago. 2009. “Egypt Beyond the Crisis: Medium Term Challenges for Sustained Growth.” Mimeo. World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Herrera, Santiago, Hoda Selin, Hoda Youssef and Chahir Zaki. 2010. “Egypt Beyond the Crisis—Medium Term
Challenges for Sustained Growth.” Mimeo. World Bank.
Hevia, Constantino, Yuki Ikeda, and Norman Loayza. 2010. “Saving in Egypt: Trends and Explanations.” Mimeo.
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(4): 1403–1448.
Levine, Ross. 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence.” In Handbook of Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion
and Steven Durlauf, eds. The Netherlands: Elsevier Science.
Loayza, Norman, and Maddalena Honorati. 2007. “Investment and Growth in Egypt.” Mimeo. World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Loayza, Norman, and Rei Odawara. 2010. “Infrastructure and Economic Growth in Egypt.” Mimeo. World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Loayza, Norman, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis Servén. 2000. “What Drives Private Savings Across the World.” The
Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (2): 165–181.
Mankiw, Gregory, David Romer, and David Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (2): 407–437
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin. 1996. Current-Account Sustainability. Princeton Studies in International
Economics No. 81. Princeton, NJ: International Economics Section, Princeton University.
Nehru, Vikram, and Ashok Dhareshwar. 1993. “A New Database on Physical Capital Stock:
Sources, Methodology, and Results.” Revista de Análisis Economico 8 (1): 37–59.
Omran, Mohammed. 1997. “Performance Consequences of Privatizing Egyptian State-Owned Enterprises: The effect
of Post Privatization Ownership Structure on Firm Performance.” Multinational Finance Journal, Vol. 1.
Ragab, Adla, and Hisham Fouad. 2009. “Roads and Highways in Egypt: Reform for Enhancing Efficiency.” The
Egyptian Center for Economic Studies, Working Paper Series ECESWP152-E.
Rodrik, Dani. 2008. “The Real Exchange and Economic Growth.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activities 2: 365–412.
Rodrik, Dani, and Avind Subramanian. 2009. “Why did Financial Globalization Disappoint?” IMF Staff Papers 56 (1):
112–138.
Said, Mona. 2008. “The Fall and Rise of Earnings and Inequality in Egypt: New Evidence from the Egypt Labor
Market Panel Survey 2006.” In The Egyptian Labor Market Revisited, ed. Ragui Assaad, 53–81. New York and Cairo:
American University in Cairo Press.
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie, and Martín Uribe. 2003. ‘’Closing Small Open Economies.’’ Journal of International
Economics 61 (1): 163–185.
World Bank. 2008. “Transforming Egypt: A Development Policy Review.” World Bank, Washington, DC.
World Bank. 2009. “Egypt Investment Climate Assessment 2009: Accelerating Private Enterprise-Led Growth.” World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Young, Alwyn. 1995. “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth
Experience.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (3): 641–680.
256
Chapter 10
Abstract
In the aftermath of its long-standing civil war, Sri peaceful environment. The government of Sri Lanka
Lanka is keen to reap the social and economic bene- has two goals regarding these issues. First, increasing
fits of peace. Even in the middle of civil conflict, the public saving to 1.5 percent of gross domestic prod-
country was able to grow at rates that surpassed those uct by 2013; and second, increasing international
of its neighbors and most developing countries. It is investment in the country by letting the current
argued, then, that the peace dividend may bring about account deficit increase to 4.0–5.0 percent of gross
even higher rates of economic growth. Is this possi- domestic product in the coming years. If these goals
ble? And if so, under what conditions? To be sure, Sri are achieved, what can be expected for growth of
Lanka’s high growth rate in the past three decades gross domestic product in the country? To answer this
did not come for free. It took an increasing effort of question, this chapter presents a neoclassical growth
resource mobilization in the country, with a rise in model with endogenous private saving, calibrates
national saving from 15 percent of gross domestic it to fit the Sri Lankan economy, and simulates the
product in the mid-1970s to 25 percent in 2010. This behavior of growth rates of gross domestic product
rise in national saving was fundamentally fueled and and related variables under different scenarios. In
sustained by the private sector. In the future, however, what the authors call the reform scenario, total factor
the private saving rate is likely to decline because the productivity would increase from 1.00 to 1.75 percent
demographic transition experienced in the country per year. This would produce a gross domestic prod-
is bound to produce higher old dependency rates in uct growth rate of about 6.5 percent in the next five
the next two decades. However, the public sector has years, 4.6 percent by 2020, and 3.5 percent by 2030,
much room for reducing its deficits and increasing the end of the simulation period. This robust growth
public investment. Similarly, external investors are performance would be supported at the beginning
likely to encounter attractive and profitable invest- mainly by capital accumulation but later on mainly
ment projects in the coming years in a reformed and by productivity improvements.
1
ditors’ note: This chapter is a reprint of World Bank Policy Research Working Paper WPS 6300, originally published in January
E
2013. This chapter represents the second version of the model that would go on to evolve into the Standard Long Term Growth Model
(LTGM) (chapter 1) several years later. As such, the model presented in the chapter differs in notation and substance from the main
LTGM of chapter 1. Appendixes are available at the LTGM website: http://www.worldbank.org/LTGM or http://documents.worldbank
.org/curated/en/854661468101377762/Saving-and-growth-in-Sri-Lanka. Affiliations are based on when the paper was written, not
necessarily current affiliations.
2
onstantino Hevia and Norman V.Loayza, World Bank. Corresponding author: nloayza@worldbank.org. The views expressed here
C
are the authors’, and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent. We are
grateful to Francis Rowe, Brian Pinto, and Luis Servén for guidance and support for this project. We thank Mona Prasad and Susana
Lundstrom for data and related advice. Tomoko Wada provided excellent research assistance.
257
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
1. Introduction
In the aftermath of its long-standing civil war, Sri Lanka is keen to reap the social and economic benefits of
peace. Even in the middle of civil conflict, the country was able to grow at rates that surpassed those of its
neighbors and most developing countries (see figure 10.1). It is argued that the peace dividend may bring
about even higher rates of economic growth. Is this possible? And if so, under what conditions? The key
to answer these questions resides in the interaction between Sri Lanka’s potential for capital accumulation
and the likelihood of strong productivity improvements in the coming years.
Goals to increase economic growth usually refer back to concerns for raising national saving. This is at least
partially warranted because the relationship between national saving and economic growth is quantitatively
strong and robust to different types of data and methodologies (Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992; Attanasio,
Picci, and Scurco 2000; and Banerjee and Duflo 2005; among many others). Countries that have high saving
rates for long periods of time tend to experience large and sustained economic growth (see figure 10.1).
A prime example is the experience of the developing countries in East Asia, such as China, Singapore, the
Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Thailand, and Taiwan, China (Young 1995).
To be sure, some of the relationship between growth and saving reflects the positive impact that higher
income has on improved saving (Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel, and Serven 2000). However, no less important
is the causality that runs from higher saving to larger growth, where the mechanism resides on the well-
known process of capital accumulation. Improved national saving provides the funds to take advantage of
more and larger investment opportunities. This, in turn, increases the capital stock, which effectively used
for economic production contributes to higher output growth. Although in theory domestic investment
does not have to be supported by national saving, in practice the connection between the two is quite
close (Aizenman, Pinto, and Radziwill 2007). This is especially true in the long run, when external sources
of funds can be tapped only in a restricted manner: large current account deficits cannot be sustained
indefinitely. This is exemplified by the strong relationship between the average saving and investment rates
across countries in the last three decades, as depicted in figure 10.2.
In Sri Lanka, as in most other countries, capital accumulation depends crucially on the country’s ability
to save. National saving in Sri Lanka increased from below 15% of GDP in the mid-1970s to about 25%
4
LKA
-2
-4
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
National saving rate (%GDP)
258
The Long Term Growth Model
30
LKA
25
20
15
10
0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
National saving rate (%GDP)
of GDP in 2010 (see figure 10.3). This is a remarkable trend. However, it is the private sector which has
supported this positive trend, while the public sector has decreased its savings since the mid-1980s, even
dissaving since the 1990s.
Most national savings in Sri Lanka have originated from income inside the country. From the mid-1980s,
domestic savings have been 75–80% of national saving (see figure 10.4). A non-negligible share, however,
has originated from income from abroad. Official grants were the majority of foreign income in the late
1970s and early 1980s, while workers’ remittances increased from almost nothing in the mid-1970s to 5%
of GDP by the early 1980s. Since then, workers’ remittances have remained in the range of 5 to 7% of GDP,
explaining the majority of the difference between national and domestic saving.
1975–2010
30
25
20
15
10
–5
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
National saving (% of GDP) Private saving (% of GDP)
Government saving (% of GDP)
259
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
1975–2010
30
25
20
15
10
–5
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
National saving (% of GDP) Domestic saving (% of GDP)
Workers’ remittances (% of GDP)
In Sri Lanka, the domestic investment rate has been traditionally higher than the national saving rate, with
a resulting sustained current account deficit (see figure 10.5). Except for a few years in the early 1980s when
the current account deficit jumped as high as 16% of GDP, it has remained at around or below 5% of GDP.
The inflow of resources from abroad has helped the country maintain higher rates of growth than its national
saving rate alone would have predicted (see figure 10.1). Although foreign financing is expected to continue
in the future, it is likely to remain within the confines of its historical rates with respect to economy’s size.
The links in the relationship between saving and growth are not mechanical but depend on the quality
of the financial system and public institutions in general. Without an efficient financial system, the
best investment opportunities will not be matched with the available saving (Levine 2005). Likewise,
without proper public institutions (that guarantee macroeconomic stability and contract enforcement,
for instance), accumulated capital may remain idle or ineffectively used (Hall and Jones 1999; Easterly
1975–2010
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
-5
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Current account deficit (% of GDP) National saving (% of GDP)
Domestic investment (% of GDP)
260
The Long Term Growth Model
and Levine 2001). This points to the crucial importance of the efficiency or productivity with which
physical capital, human capital, and labor are used in the production process. The growth of factor
productivity is what in the end determines whether a saving and investment effort will result (or not) in
improved economic growth.
The objective of this study is to illustrate the mechanisms linking national saving and economic growth
in Sri Lanka. Moreover, recognizing that private saving is not directly a policy lever but an endogenous
variable, the study will assess the role and potential contribution of public saving in generating growth. We
will do this through a simple theoretical model, calibrated to fit the Sri Lankan economy, and simulated
to explore different potential scenarios. Our goal is to understand the two-way connection between saving
and growth and the possibilities and limits of a saving-based growth agenda, in the context of Sri Lanka’s
economy.
An optimality of saving behavior can be posed from different angles. The most common in the academic
literature is the perspective of optimal saving as the behavior that maximizes a consumer welfare function.
This, however, may be too abstract for the needs and objectives of policy practitioners. For this reason, we
pose the problem of optimal saving from the perspective of financing a given rate of economic growth while
simultaneously achieving external sustainability.
The chapter proceeds as follows. First, we present a simple model, constructed with the purpose of under-
standing the necessary level of national and public saving to generate a given rate of economic growth (that
is, following the optimality perspective described above). The model is neoclassical in the sense that the
factors of production—labor and physical and human capital—are subject to decreasing marginal returns.
Had we used instead an endogenous growth model with constant marginal returns to capital, changes
in the rate of capital accumulation would have had permanent effects on long-run growth, a result not
supported by the evidence (Bernanke and Gürkaynak 2002; Caselli 2005; Easterly and Levine 2001; Hall
and Jones 1999). Moreover, methodologically it is more straightforward to examine both the limitations of
a saving-based growth agenda and the role of productivity improvements in the context of the neoclassical
model than the endogenous growth model.
Second, we calibrate the model to Sri Lanka’s economy, using parameters and relationships obtained in the
received literature for the country. Third, using the calibrated model, we perform some simulations that
clarify the relationship between public and national saving, productivity, and growth, allowing us to discuss
policy options for improving economic growth in Sri Lanka. And fourth, we provide some concluding
remarks, arguing that for the country to grow at rates comparable to those of the East Asian tiger economies,
the public sector must contribute substantially to national saving, and institutional and economic reforms
must lead to strong and persistent productivity improvements.
Where Yt denotes output, Kt is the stock of physical capital, Lt denotes the labor input, At is a measure of
the level of total factor productivity (TFP) of capital and labor, and the technology parameter α ∈ (0, 1)
261
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
measures the relative contribution of capital to the production of output—in an economy operating under
perfect competition, a measures the share of output distributed as payments to capital.
We abstract from distributional issues and assume that all workers have the same level of human capital.
Following Bils and Klenow (2000) and Hall and Jones (1999), we assume that each worker has been trained
with zt years of schooling, which deliver a productivity of exp (φzt) efficiency units of labor per worker,
where exp(.) denotes the exponential function. Thus, φzt measures the relative efficiency of a worker with zt
years of schooling relative to one with no schooling. Thus, if we let Et denote the working-age population,
effective aggregate labor supply is given by
Lt = exp(φzt)Et. (2)
Capital depreciates at a constant rate δ per year, but can be augmented through investment. Namely, the
stock of capital evolves according to
Kt+1 = (1−δ)Kt + It, (3)
where It denotes aggregate investment.
Abstracting from valuation changes, the current account deficit at period t, CADt, is defined as the change
in net foreign liabilities of the whole economy, or
CADt ≡ Bt+1 – Bt = rBt + Ct + Gt + It – Yt – TRt, (4)
where Bt is the stock of net foreign liabilities due at period t; r is the world interest rate, assumed constant
for simplicity; Ct denotes private consumption; Gt denotes government consumption expenditures; and
TRt denotes the flow of net external current transfers (worker remittances and official grants) that are not
reflected as changes in the country’s net foreign liabilities.3
If we let StN = Yt + TRt − rBt − C t − Gt denote aggregate national saving, equation (4) can be rearranged into
the familiar investment-saving gap identity of an open economy,
I t = StN + CADt . (5)
That is, domestic investment It can be financed through national saving or through foreign saving
(i.e., through an increase in net foreign liabilities).
External solvency requires that the current value of foreign liabilities be no larger than the present value of
net exports, and can be obtained by iterating forward on the current account identity, equation (4), namely,
∞
1
∑ 1+ r Yt + j + TRt + j − I t + j − C t + j − Gt + j = (1 + r ) Bt .
( )
j
j =0
This solvency condition imposes certain assumptions about the functioning of international capital mar-
kets that are difficult to reconcile with the experience of emerging market economies. In particular, it fails
to capture the financial frictions that are pervasive in developing countries. For this reason, we follow
Milesi-Ferretti and Razin (1996) and impose a sufficient condition for current account sustainability that
is also appealing in terms of its realism.
In Hevia and Loayza (2011) we assumed that the economy was required to maintain the ratio of net
foreign liabilities to GDP constant. For the case of Sri Lanka, this might be too strong an assumption, given
3
orker remittances and other transfers from abroad are quite important for Sri Lanka, representing over 5% of GDP in the last
W
decade.
262
The Long Term Growth Model
expectations of larger foreign participation in domestic investment during the next years. We thus assume
that the ratio of net foreign liabilities to GDP is allowed to evolve through time according to,
Bt/Yt = βt (6)
where {βt} is an exogenous sequence. For example, if βt increases for a number of years and then becomes
constant, the economy is increasing its foreign indebtedness and, thus, the foreign participation in domestic
capital formation. On the other hand, if βt decreases through time, the economy is reducing its foreign
indebtedness. The proposed modification to the solvency condition is a reduced form approach aimed to
capture the reluctance of foreigners to lend money when the level of debt is sufficiently high, or because
the government wants to maintain a safe level of foreign borrowing relative to output.
Using the definition of the current account, equation (6) imposes the following restriction on the current
account deficit as a fraction of gross domestic output,
CADt Bt +1 Yt +1 Bt Y
= − = β t +1 t +1 − β t . (7)
Yt Yt +1 Yt Yt Yt
That is, the ratio of the current account deficit to the value of output depends upon the net foreign liabilities
as a fraction of GDP at times t and t + 1, and on the growth rate of output, Yt+1/Yt.
For quantitative purposes, we find it convenient to rewrite all previous equations in per capita terms. To
that end, let Nt denote total population at time t and, for any aggregate variable Xt, let xt = Xt/Nt denote the
corresponding variable in per capita terms. Thus, introducing the definition of effective labor, equation (2)
into the production function, equation (1) and dividing the resulting expression by Nt gives the following
expression for GDP per capita:
y t = At ktα (exp (φ z t ) e t )
1−α
. (8)
In general, the labor force variable et = Et/Nt varies through time as the demographic characteristics of the
economy changes.
Following the same approach, we write the equilibrium equations (3), (5), and (7) in per capita terms as
kt+1 Γ N,t+1 = (1−δ)kt + it, (9)
it = stN + cadt , (10)
cadt
= β t +1 Γy ,t +1 Γ N ,t +1 − β t (11)
yt
Here and throughout the chapter, expressions like Γx,t+1 = xt+1/xt denote the gross growth rate of any variable
xt between periods t and t + 1.
We now use the previous equations to write a condition that relates national saving and growth. First, we
use the production function in equation (8) at periods t and t + 1 to write the gross growth rate in output
per capita as
( )
1−α
Γy ,t +1 = Γ A ,t +1 Γ αk ,t +1 exp φ ( z t +1 − z t ) Γ e ,t +1
(12)
That is, the growth rate of output per capita Γy,t+1 depends upon the growth rate of productivity ΓA,t+1, the
growth rate of the stock of capital, Γk,t+1 the growth rate of human capital exp[φ (Zt+1 – Zt)], and the growth
rate of the labor force Γe,t+1.
263
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
Second, introducing the investment-saving equation (10) into the capital accumulation equation (9) and
rearranging gives
it y t s N + cadt y t
Γ k ,t +1 Γ N ,t +1 = 1 − δ + =1−δ + t .
y t kt yt kt
This equation describes the growth rate of the stock of capital per person as a function of the growth rate
of the population ΓN,t+1, the depreciation rate δ, the national saving ratio with respect to GDP stN /y t , the
current account deficit as a fraction of GDP cadt/yt, and the degree of capital intensity in the economy kt/yt.
Imposing the sustainability equation (11) into the last equation, the evolution of the stock of capital becomes
yt
Γ k ,t +1 Γ N ,t +1 = 1 − δ + {σ t + β t +1 Γ y ,t +1Γ N ,t +1 − β t } ,
kt (13)
where σ t = stN / y t denotes the national saving ratio with respect to GDP. 4
Finally, introducing equation (13) into the output growth equation (12) delivers an equation that links
the growth rate of output per capita to the national saving ratio σt, the growth rate of productivity ΓAt, the
growth rate of the population ΓNt, the growth rate of the labor force Γet, the growth rate in human capital
exp[φ(zt+1 − zt)], and the capital-output ratio kt/yt,
α
yt
1 − δ + {σ t + β t +1 Γ y , t +1 Γ N , t +1 − β t } k
( )
1−α
Γ y , t +1 = t
Γ A, t +1 exp φ ( z t +1 − z t ) Γ e , t +1 . (14)
Γ N , t +1
Equation (14) is the key equation that associates the growth rate of GDP per capita with the national saving
ratio st
4
Note that stN / y t is neither the national saving rate nor the domestic saving rate as defined in the national accounts statistics.
The national saving rate is defined as stN / y tN where y tN = y t − rbt + trt is national disposable income (per capita), whereas the
domestic saving rate is defined as stD / y t , where stD = y t − c t − g t is domestic saving (per capita).
264
The Long Term Growth Model
saving and provide estimates of the aforementioned reduced form private saving equation based on a large
cross-section, time-series data set.
We decompose the national saving ratio as the sum of the private and public saving ratios, σ tp and σ tg ,
respectively, or
σ t = σ tp + σ tg . (15)
The functional form of the private saving rate at time t is assumed to be,
σ tp = ζ 1σ tp−1 + ζ 2σ tg + ζ 3 log y t + ζ 4 log y t −1 + ζ 5odt + ζ 6 ydt + η ,
where odt denotes the old age dependency rate, ydt is the young age dependency rate, and ζi, = 1,…,6 and η
are constants. Thus, the private saving ratio depends on its own lagged value, on the public saving rate, on
the current and lagged (log) levels of GDP per-capita, and on the old age and young age dependency rates.
The parameters ζi, = 1,…,6 are set according to Loayza, Schmidt-Hebbel, and Servén’s (2000) estimates. The
constant η is a country-specific fixed effect which will be removed by differencing the previous equation.
In particular, lagging the previous equation and taking the difference gives
Inserting this equation into (15) gives the national saving ratio at time t as a function of the public saving
ratio at time t, the structural characteristics of the economy, and lagged private saving ratios,
In the quantitative section of the chapter we perform two sets of experiments. In the first experiment, we
find the public saving rate required to achieve a certain growth rate of GDP per capita, recognizing that the
private saving rate evolves endogenously as a function of the characteristics of the economy. In the second
experiment, we fix a path for the public saving ratio and let the private saving ratio and GDP per capita
evolve endogenously through time. These exercises are described in detail after we discuss the calibration of
the parameters of the model and the estimation of the demographic characteristics of the economy based
on data from Sri Lanka.
2.2 Calibration
Before we can use the model to simulate potential scenarios, we need to calibrate it with information
specifically related to Sri Lanka’s economy. The main pieces of information are the following:
• The current capital-output ratio: kt/yt = 1.314. This is the ratio estimated for the year 2010, using a
perpetual inventory method to accumulate investment in order to produce a measure of the capital
stock. Given the war-related destruction of factories, transport facilities, buildings, and other forms
of capital, we cannot assume a fixed and relatively low depreciation rate (0.04– 0.08, as in most of the
literature). We allow the depreciation rate to vary and, in order to identify it, assume a constant rate of
TFP growth equal to 0.0107, the average reported for Sri Lanka in the last decades by Jorgenson and
Vu (2005), Collins (2007), and Son (2010).5
• The capital share in output: α = 0.35. This is the average across countries that Bernanke and Gürkaynak
(2002) obtain using adjusted factor payment data from national accounts. There is no comparable
Sri Lanka-specific estimate for the capital share.
5
n the importance of considering a different depreciation rate for Sri Lanka when estimating the capital stock, see Duma
O
(2007).
265
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
• The annual capital depreciation rate: δ = 0.08. This is the depreciation rate used in Klenow and
Rodríguez-Clare (2005) in their chapter of the Handbook of Economic Growth. It is a bit larger than the
depreciation rate assumed in other cross-country studies (e.g., 0.06 in Caselli, 2005). We use this higher
rate because it is similar to the average depreciation rate for Sri Lanka in the last few years (after the civil
war ended) as obtained in the process of estimating the capital stock (see above).
• The annual growth rate of the labor force, ΓEt, is obtained from the future demographic projections for
Sri Lanka population ages 15–70, presented in United Nations (2011), World Population Prospects: The
2008 Revision.
• The annual increase in education: (zt+1 – zt) = 0.05104. Education is proxied by the average number of
schooling years in the adult population. This estimate for the annual increase in schooling is taken from
an updated version of the Barro and Lee (2001) data set and corresponds to the average annual change
for the period 1990–2010.
• The annual rate of return to education: φ = 0.07. This rate of return is used in Bernake and Gurkaynak
(2002) and Collins (2007) in their growth accounting exercises, which also consider the average number
of schooling years in the adult population as the proxy for education (and human capital in general).
• The ratio of net foreign liabilities to GDP, βt, is assumed to rise from its current value of 0.45 to 0.60
gradually in 15 years. This approximately corresponds to the government’s target of a current account
deficit of 4–5% of GDP over the next five years and declining afterwards. The current ratio of net
foreign liabilities to GDP is obtained from updating the Lane and Milesi-Ferreti (2007) database. The
Official “international investment position” for Sri Lanka is not available in the International Monetary
Funds’ (IMF’s) Balance of Payments Statistics.
• Productivity scenarios. A key parameter in the simulations presented below is the rate of growth of
total factor productivity, ΓAt. The available estimates for TFP growth in Sri Lanka indicate an average
of around 1.00% growth per year in the last few decades (Jorgenson and Vu 2005; Collins 2007; and
Son 2010). We consider this TFP growth rate in a first scenario, which we call “continuity scenario”. If
Sri Lanka is able to reform its economy and institutions along the lines proposed in recent government
plans, the country’s TFP growth rate is likely to increase substantially. For the second scenario, we use the
average TFP growth rate of the top quarter of countries in a worldwide sample as a benchmark for what
is possible under economic reform (Bernanke and Gürkaynak 2002). This is approximately equal to the
1.75% per year rate which we use for what we call the “reform scenario.” Finally, if Sri Lanka is able to
conduct all of its intended reforms and also benefit from a positive international environment, its TFP
growth rate could increase even further. We use the rate of 2.50% per year in an “optimistic scenario.”
This is clearly an upper limit, which very few countries have been able to obtain in a sustainable manner.
3. Simulations
Using the model developed above and the calibration parameters, we can perform different numerical
exercises to give answers and insights regarding the links between saving, investment, productivity, and
growth. We perform two basic, complementary simulations. The first one is designed to measure the saving
rates that are required to finance a given rate of economic growth. This rate is set to 7.2% of GDP per capita
growth for the period 2011–2015. This corresponds closely to the government’s target GDP growth rate of
8.0% for the next five years. After this period, economic growth is determined by the dynamics of the model.
This target growth rate is clearly ambitious from historical and cross-country perspectives for Sri Lanka.
The second simulation changes perspectives and asks what economic growth rates can be financed if the
public saving rate is increased to a given level. In accordance with government plans, the public saving rate
is assumed to increase gradually from its current level of –2.0% of GDP to 1.5% by 2013, and stay constant
from then onwards. This implies a reduction in the government deficit to 5.0% of GDP and an increase
266
The Long Term Growth Model
in public investment to 6.5% of GDP by 2013. In both simulations, private saving is allowed to change
endogenously in response to changes in public saving, demographic characteristics, and income growth.
Both simulations are dynamic in the sense that they follow the evolution of the economy for an extended period
of time, chosen to be 20 years in our case. Also in both cases, we compute the corresponding Solow growth
decomposition in order to understand the role played by factor accumulation and productivity advances in
the process of economic growth. As mentioned in the previous section, the simulations are performed under
three scenarios regarding the behavior of total factor productivity. TFP growth is assumed to be 1.00%, 1.75%,
and 2.50%, and the corresponding scenarios are labeled, Continuity, Reform, and Optimistic, respectively.
The basic simulation results are presented in figures 10.6–10.8. In each of them, the upper panels correspond
to the simulation where the growth rate of GDP per worker is the target; and, conversely, the lower panel shows
the simulation where the public saving rate is set to a given level. In turn, in each panel we show three graphs:
the first contains the projected national, public, and private saving rates (with respect to GDP) annually for the
period 2010–2030; the second shows the projected annual per capita and aggregate GDP growth rates for
the same period; and the third presents a Solow growth decomposition for the years 2011–2016, showing the
percentage of contributions of physical capital accumulation, total factor productivity, and labor (including
human capital and labor force).
We first discuss the continuity and optimistic scenarios to highlight how the saving-growth relationship
changes as productivity growth differs radically. We then present the Reform scenario. We do it in greater
depth than in the previous two cases because, in our perspective, it represents the most reasonable situation
under a feasible set of international conditions and, most importantly, internal reforms.
Let us then start with the continuity scenario (figure 10.6). The first simulation (upper panel) shows that,
in the absence of a substantial improvement in TFP growth, the demands on capital accumulation to attain
the goal of 7.2% GDP per capita growth (8.0% GDP growth) in the next five years are excessively large. In
fact, as the growth decomposition indicates, more than 80% of GDP per capita growth would have to be
supported by physical capital accumulation. The national saving rate would have to increase enormously
from 25% to 50% of GDP, requiring a rise in public saving to over 30% of GDP and even further in the
course of the twenty-year horizon. The private saving rate would decrease by more than one-half, in part
as a reaction to the large increase in the public saving rate.
The second simulation shows that if the public saving rate is increased to 1.5% of GDP, GDP growth would
be above 6.0% only in the first years and then decrease gradually to about 4.5% by 2015 and a bit over
2.0% by 2030. The lion share of the contribution to GDP growth (76%) in the next five years would be
given by capital accumulation. Given the impulse of public saving, the national saving rate would increase
and remain above its current value for the next seven to eight years but would then decrease following the
declining trend of private saving. Continuity in TFP growth thus implies a rate of economic growth that,
although respectable by international standards, is far below the ambitious targets for the country.
In the other extreme, let us consider the optimistic scenario, where TFP grows at a 2.5% rate (figure 10.7).
According to the first simulation (upper panel), in order to finance a 7.2% GDP growth per capita (8.0%
GDP growth) in the next five years, national saving would need to rise from 25 to 33% of GDP. In turn,
this would require an increase in public saving to almost 10% of GDP by 2015. This would entail a strong
effort, but a feasible one at that. As the Solow growth decomposition shows, now TFP would contribute
about 35% to GDP per capita growth. The large impulse from TFP under this scenario relieves the pressure
on capital accumulation substantially to attain the high target of economic growth.
The second simulation under the optimistic scenario indicates that, with a small improvement in public
saving, GDP growth would average 8% in the next few years and stay over or around 7% for the next
decade. Then, it would decline to about 5% by 2030, the end of our simulation horizon. With the impulse
267
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
Labor input,
0.6 10 TFP, 15%
2%
0.5
8
0.4
6
Percent
0.3
0.2 4
0.1
2
0
–0.1 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
Physical capital,
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
83%
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth
Public saving GDP growth rate
0.25
8
0.20
6
Percent
0.15
0.10 4
0.05
2
0
–0.05 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
Physical capital,
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
76%
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth
Public saving GDP growth rate
of public saving, the national saving rate would increase to around 27%, and private saving would decrease
only slightly. As the Solow decomposition shows, the contribution of TFP growth would account for 37%
of GDP growth in the next five years.
Let us now turn to the reform scenario, where TFP grows at a constant annual rate of 1.75% (figure 10.8).
The first simulation indicates that achieving a target of GDP per capita growth rate of 7.2% (8.0% GDP
growth) in the next five years is indeed a difficult goal. It would require a jump in national saving from
the current 25% to about 40% of GDP by 2015, which in turn would require public saving to rise to 20%
of GDP. The lion share of the contribution to growth would still need to come from capital accumulation,
with only one-fourth coming from TFP growth. The required increase in national saving is substantial but
has been observed in East Asian countries, most notably China. With free and endogenously determined
private saving, however, the needed increase in national saving would have to be supported by an incredibly
large expansion of public saving.
268
The Long Term Growth Model
Labor input,
40 10 2%
TFP, 35%
30 8
20 6
Percent
10 4
0 2
–10 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
Physical capital,
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
63%
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth
Public saving GDP growth rate
Labor input,
30 10 2%
TFP, 37%
25
8
20
6
Percent
15
10 4
5
2
0
–5 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
Physical capital,
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth 61%
Public saving GDP growth rate
The second simulation under the reform scenario (figure 10.8) shows the behavior of GDP growth if the
public saving rate is increased to 1.50% of GDP by 2013. Given TFP growth of 1.75%, the growth rate of
GDP would stay around 7.0% in the next five years and then gradually decline to 4.5% by 2020 and 3.5%
by the end of the simulation period. Note that the difference between GDP growth and per capita GDP
growth diminishes over time as population growth approaches zero.
Given the impulse in public saving, the national saving rate would increase from 25% to 27% by 2013 and
then slowly decline back to 25% by 2030. In turn, the private saving rate would follow a secular, though slow,
decrease from 27% to 23% of GDP by the end of the simulation period. The trend in the private saving rate
is due to the combination of three significant forces. The first is the increase in public saving, which would
generate a small compensating decline in private saving. The second is the expected substantial rise in the
old dependency rate, which would lead to a gradual fall in the private saving rate. (The expected decrease
in the young dependency rate would have the opposite effect but its magnitude is much smaller.) The third
269
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
20
15 4
10
5 2
0
–5 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
Physical capital,
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
73%
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth
Public saving GDP growth rate
15
10 4
5
2
0
–5 0
10
15
20
25
30
10
15
20
25
30
Physical capital,
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
67%
National saving Private saving Per capita GDP growth
Public saving GDP growth rate
is the rise in income related to GDP per capita growth; this would produce an increase in the private saving
rate. It seems, then, that the first two negative forces win over the last one, generating the decline, albeit
slow, in the private saving rate.6
The behavior of the national saving rate would be followed to some extent by the rate of domestic invest-
ment (figure 10.9). Domestic investment would rise during the next few years, prompted by the rise in
public and national savings, and then decline gradually. The difference between saving and investment,
that is, the current account deficit, would be close to 5% of GDP in the next 5 years and then decline to
about 2% by the end of the simulation period. The larger initial current account deficit is consistent with
the assumed increase in net foreign liabilities from 45% to 60% of GDP in the next 15 years.
6
he variation in the slope across simulations and scenarios is related to the projected change in public saving and GDP growth.
T
The effect of demographic factors is constant across simulations and scenarios.
270
The Long Term Growth Model
Figure 10.9: Saving, Investment, and the Current Account under the Reform Scenario
TFP growth of 1.75% per year public savings raised to 1.5% of GDP by 2013
35
30
25
Ratio to GDP
20
15
0
2010 2015 2020 2025 2030
Current account deficit National saving Investment
The Solow decomposition presented in figure 10.8 indicates that in the next five years, physical capital
accumulation would account for 65% and TFP improvements for about 30% of GDP growth. The relative
contribution of the factors of production to economic growth would not be constant over time, however.
It would change over the course of the simulation period, as shown in figure 10.10. As noted before, in
the first years capital accumulation would contribute by far more than any other production factor to
economic growth. However, its relative contribution would decline as the capital stock grows and, there-
fore, faces diminishing returns. Over the course of the simulation period, the capital-output ratio would
gradually increase from 1.30 in 2010 to 2.00 in 2020 and 2.25 in 2030. With an increase in this ratio, the
70
60
50
40
Percent
30
20
10
–10
2010 2015 2020 2025 2030
TFP Physical capital Human capital Labor force
271
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
marginal product of capital declines, and so does its contribution to GDP growth. On the other hand, the
contribution of improvements in TFP would increasingly become most important, tying that of capital
accumulation by 2025 and surpassing the 50% mark by 2030. Regarding the labor input, for most of the
simulation period the contribution from the labor force would be negative given that the working-age
population is expected to experience a declining trend in the next two decades. The contribution of human
capital would be, conversely, positive and increasing in relative terms, reaching almost 10% by 2030. This
is likely to be an underestimation of the role of human capital, however, because much of the gains in TFP
could not be achieved were it not for strong human capital investment and growth.
4. Conclusions
Even during the protracted, 25-year-long civil war, Sri Lanka’s economy was able to grow at an average rate
of 4.6% per year, a rate higher than three-fourths of the countries around the world. Expectations for even
higher growth in the aftermath of civil conflict are, thus, understandable. This chapter attempts to measure
what can be projected for GDP growth in Sri Lanka in the next two decades under different scenarios for
productivity improvement and public saving.
To be sure, Sri Lanka’s high growth rate in the last three decades did not come for free. It took an increasing
effort of resource mobilization in the country. In the mid-1970s, the rate of saving and investment were,
respectively, 15% and 17% of GDP. By 2010, they reached 25% and 28%, respectively, an increase of at least
10 percentage points. The rise in national saving was fundamentally fueled and sustained by the private
sector. Is it reasonable to expect increasing private saving rates in the future? Most likely, they will not rise
much further. The demographic transition experienced in Sri Lanka indicates that in the next two decades
the old dependency rate will rise considerably, producing a decline in private saving rates. This decline
would be lessened if per capita income increased, as expected, but the trend would not be reversed.
Notwithstanding its high rates of capital investment in the last decades, Sri Lanka is still a country with a
relatively low capital-to-output ratio and with significant infrastructure needs. The public sector, which
currently features negative saving rates, has much room for reducing its deficits and increasing public
investment. Similarly, external investors are likely to encounter attractive and profitable investment projects
in the coming years in a reformed and peaceful environment. The government of Sri Lanka has the goals
of increasing public saving to 1.5% of GDP by 2013 and allowing an increase in international investment
in the country, amounting to a current account deficit of 4–5% in the coming years.
If these goals are achieved, what can be expected for GDP growth in the country? To answer this question,
we have presented a neoclassical growth model with endogenous private saving, calibrated it to fit the Sri
Lankan economy, and simulated the behavior of GDP growth rates and related variables under different
scenarios. If improvements in productivity continue at the average rate experienced in the last decades (TFP
growth of 1%), GDP growth would be above 6.0% in the first years and then decrease gradually to about
4.5% by 2015 and a bit over 2.0% by 2030. This is an adequate result but is much lower than what the Sri
Lankan people and their government deem as necessary to develop. To increase growth, forceful economic
and institutional reforms are needed. Under what we call the reform scenario, TFP growth would increase
to an average rate of 1.75% per year, leading to GDP growth of about 6.5% in the next five years, 4.6% by
2020, and 3.5% by 2030, the end of the simulation period (see table 10.1). This robust growth performance
would be supported at the beginning mostly by capital accumulation but later on mainly by productivity
improvements.
The challenge, then, is how to obtain large and sustained productivity improvements, in the context of
solvent fiscal accounts and international investment participation. We leave it for further work to identify
the specific policy measures that can generate these essential improvements.
272
The Long Term Growth Model
Table 10.1: Reform Scenario TFP growth of 1.75% per year (public savings raised to 1.5%
of GDP by 2013)
Year
2012 2015 2020 2030
GDP per capita growth 6.3% 5.3% 4.2% 3.3%
GDP growth 7.1% 6.0% 4.6% 3.5%
Solow decomposition - Contribution (%):
TFP 28% 33% 42% 53%
Physical Capital 70% 64% 55% 41%
Human Capital 4% 4% 6% 7%
Labor Force –2% –2% –3% –1%
Source: Authors’ calculations.
References
Aizenman, Joshua, Brian Pinto, and Artur Radziwill. 2007. “Sources for financing domestic capital—Is foreign saving
a viable option for developing countries?” Journal of International Money and Finance. 26 (5): 682–702.
Attanasio, Orazio P., Lucio Picci, and Antonello Scurco. 2000. “Saving, Growth and Investment: A Macroeconomic
Analysis Using a Panel of Countries.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (2): 182–211.
Banerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Duflo. 2005. “Growth Theory Through the Lens of Development Economics.” In
Handbook of Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion, and Steven N. Durlauf, eds. Vol. 1A, pp. 473–552. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
Barro, Robert, and Jong-Wha Lee. 2001. “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications.”
Oxford Economic Papers 53 (3): 541–563.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Refet S. Gürkaynak. 2002. “Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer, and Weil Seriously.”
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, Vol. 16, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Refet S. Gürkaynak, 11–72. Cambridge,
MA: MIT Press.
Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow. 2000. “Does Schooling Cause Growth?” American Economic Review 90 (5): 1160–1183.
Caselli, Francesco. 2005. “Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences.” Handbook of Economic Growth 1 (1):
679–741.
Collins, Susan M. 2007. “Economic Growth in South Asia: A Growth Accounting Perspective.” In South Asia: Growth
and Regional Integration, ed. Sadiq Ahmed and Ejaz Ghani, 45–60. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Duma, Nombulelo. 2007. “Sri Lanka’s Sources of Growth.” IMF Working Paper, WP/07/225.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models.” World
Bank Economic Review 15: 177–219.
Gollin, Douglas. 2002. “Getting Income Shares Right.” Journal of Political Economy. Vol 110(2): 458–474.
Hall, Robert E., and Jones, Charles I. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker
Than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83–116.
Hevia, Constantino, and Norman Loayza. 2011. “Saving and Growth in Egypt.” Mimeo. World Bank, Washington,
DC.
Jorgenson, Dale W. and Vu, Khuong. 2005. Information Technology and the World Economy. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics, Vol. 107, No. 4, pp. 631-650
Klenow, Peter J., and Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2005. “Externalities and Growth.” Handbook of Economic Growth 1 (1):
817–861.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. 2007. “The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended
Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970–2004.” Journal of International Economics 73, November, 223–250.
273
10. Saving and Growth in Sri Lanka
Levine, Ross. 2005. “Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence.” In Handbook of Economic Growth. Philippe Aghion
and Steven Durlauf, eds. The Netherlands: Elsevier Science.
Loayza, Norman, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel and Luis Servén. 2000. “What Drives Private Savings Across the World.” The
Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (2): 165–181.
Mankiw, Gregory, David Romer, and David Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (2): 407–437.
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin. 1996. Current-Account Sustainability. Princeton Studies in International
Economics No. 81. Princeton, NJ: International Economics Section, Princeton University.
Son, Hyun H. 2010. “Human Capital Development.” Asian Development Review 27 (2): 29–56.
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie and Martín Uribe. 2003. ‘’Closing Small Open Economies.’’ Journal of International
Economics 61 (1): 163–185.
Srinivasan, Thirukodikaval N. 2005. “Productivity and Economic Growth in South Asia and China.” The Pakistan
Development Review 44 (4): 479–503.
Young, Alwyn. 1995. “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth
Experience.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (3): 641–680.
274