Lecture 6 Trade Agreements

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 32

International economics

th
6 lecture
Trade agreements
Economic Integration
World leaders have recognized that the reduction or elimination of
artificial barriers to trade is necessary for expanding world trade. The
worldwide postwar efforts to expand foreign trade included the elimination
of tariff barriers through the World Trade Organization and the
stabilization of currencies through the International Monetary Fund. At the
same time as these efforts went forward on the international level, many
countries around the world also pursued economic cooperation at the
regional level. Regional economic cooperation is based on the premise
that countries in a region connected by historical, geographical, cultural,
economic, and political similarities may be able to strike more intensive
cooperative agreements for mutually beneficial
• economic advantages.
From GATT to WTO
In 1947, 23 countries signed the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT) in Geneva. To join GATT, countries must adhere to the most
favored nation (MFN) clause, which requires that if a country grants a
tariff reduction to one country, it must grant the same concession to all
other countries. For example, if the USA cuts its tariff from 20 percent to 10
percent on wool sweaters from Australia, it must grant the same
concession on wool sweaters from all other countries. The MFN clause
also applies to quotas and licenses.
From GATT to WTO
• GATT members have held many talks since 1947 to expand and promote
world trade. First, GATT members held periodic meetings from 1947 to
1952 to cut specific tariffs.
• Second, the Kennedy Round (1964–7) covered across-the-board tariff
reductions on industrial products. Perhaps the most important part of the
Kennedy Round was to reduce trade barriers between the USA and the
European Economic Community.
• Third, the Tokyo Round (1973–9) of multilateral trade negotiations
discussed the reduction of nontariff barriers. The most important part of
these agreements is a series of detailed codes spelling out permissible
and non-permissible “good” behavior by governments in almost all
nontariff measures.
From GATT to WTO
• Fourth, the Uruguay Round (1986–93) discussed the expansion of trade
liberalization to include services, intellectual property rights, and
agricultural products.
• The new organization, known as the World Trade Organization (WTO),
has replaced the GATT since the Uruguay Round accord became
effective on January 1, 1995. Today, the WTO’s 144 members account
for more than 97 percent of world trade. The WTO has five major
functions: (1) administrating its trade agreements; (2) acting as a forum
for trade negotiations; (3) monitoring national trade policies; (4) offering
technical assistance and training for developing countries; and (5)
cooperating with other international organizations. China joined the
WTO in 2001. China’s WTO membership has further legitimized the idea
of free trade.
From GATT to WTO
The WTO has more power to enforce the rules of international trade
than the GATT. Under the WTO there is a powerful dispute-resolution
system, with three-person arbitration panels. Countries may bring
charges against their trading partners to a WTO panel. WTO members
cannot veto the panel’s rulings, as was the case under GATT. If an
offending country fails to comply with panel recommendations, its
trading partners are guaranteed the right to compensation. As a final
resort, the trading partners are given the right to impose countervailing
sanctions against the offending country.
From GATT to WTO
• In November 2001, WTO members began to explore a new round of
talks with the aim of further liberalizing global commerce. Major issues
include a moratorium on tariffs for electronic commerce, easier access
to foreign markets for high-tech, banking, and insurance exports,
elimination of agricultural subsidies, tougher labor standards around the
world, revision of US antidumping laws, and more time for developing
countries to liberalize trade.
Non-Discrimination Principle according to WTO

• Non-discrimination has two elements


• Most-favored nation (MFN) applying to border measures
• Each member must grant treatment to all other members as
favorable as it extend to any individual member country
• National Treatment (NT) applying to behind-the-border
measures
• Foreign goods within a country should be treated no less
favorably than domestic good with regard to tax policies and
other regulations
Figure 8.1: Non-Discrimination Principle

© Kenneth A. Reinert, Cambridge University Press 2021


GATT/WTO rounds of multilateral trade
negotiations
Multilateralism versus Regionalism
• The term multilateralism refers to the GATT/WTO system and the trade negotiations
that take place within it
• One of the founding principles of this system is nondiscrimination
• Involves the most favored nation (MFN) and national treatment (NT) sub-
principles
• “Regionalism” refers to a violation of the nondiscrimination principle in which one
member of a regional trade agreement (RTA) discriminates in its trade policies in
favor of another member of the RTA and against nonmembers
• Has been allowed by the GATT/WTO under certain circumstances:
• Free trade areas (FTAs)
• Customs unions (CUs)
• Interim agreements leading to an FTA or CU “within a reasonable length of
time
Economic integration
Economic integration refers to the commercial policy of discriminatively
reducing or eliminating barriers only among the nations joining together.
• Preferential trade arrangements
• Provide lower barriers to trade among participating nations
than on trade with non-member nations.
• The loosest form of economic integration.
• Example: British Commonwealth Preference Scheme,
established in 1932 between the United Kingdom and
members of the British Empire
Steps to economic Integration
Free trade areas
 Free trade areas
 Removes all barriers to trade among members, but each nation retains its
own barriers to trade with non-members.
 Examples:
 European Free Trade Association (EFTA), 1960, between United Kingdom, Austria,
Denmark, Norway, Portugal, Sweden and Switzerland
 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), 1993, between the United States, Canada
and Mexico
Customs union
 Customs union
 Removes all barriers to trade among members and harmonizes
trade policies toward the rest of the world.
 Examples:
 European Union (EU), or European Common Market, 1957, between West Germany,
France, Italy, Belgium, the Netherlands, and Luxembourg.
 Zollverein, 1834, between large number of sovereign German states
Common market
 Common market
 Removes all barriers to trade among members, harmonizes trade
policies toward the rest of the world, and allows free movement of
labor and capital among member nations.
 Example:
 European Union (EU) achieved common market status in 1993.
Economic union
 monetary union, agreement between two or more states creating
a single currency area. A monetary union involves the irrevocable
fixation of the exchange rates of the national currencies existing
before the formation of a monetary union. Historically, monetary
unions have been formed on the basis of both economic and
political considerations. A monetary union is accompanied by
setting up a single monetary policy and establishing a
single central bank or by making the already existing national
central banks the integrative units of a common central banking
system
Economic union
 Economic union
 Removes all barriers to trade among members, harmonizes trade
policies towards the rest of the world, allows free movement of labor
and capital among member nations, and unifies monetary and fiscal
policies of members.
 Most advanced type of economic integration.
 Examples:
 Benelux, formed after World War II between Belgium, the Netherlands and
Luxembourg
Trade-Creating Customs Unions
• Trade creation occurs when domestic production in a member
nation is replaced by lower-cost imports from another member
nation.
• Leads to increased welfare for members as nations
specialize in comparative advantages.
• Leads to increased welfare for non-members as increased
real income spills over into increased imports from rest of the
world.
• In Figure 10.1, removing the tariff increases social welfare, recapturing the
deadweight losses.
FIGURE 10-1 A Trade-Creating Customs Union.

Salvatore: International Economics, 12th Edition © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.
FIGURE 10.1. A Trade-Creating
Customs Union.
DX and SX represent Nation 2’s domestic demand and supply curves of commodity X.
At the tariff-inclusive PX =$2 before the formation of the customs union, Nation 2
consumes 50X (GH),with 20X (GJ) produced in Nation 2 and 30X (JH) imported from
Nation 1. Nation 2 also collects a tariff revenue of $30 (MJHN). Nation 2 does not
import commodity X from Nation 3 because of the tariff-inclusive PX > $2. After Nation
2 forms a customs union with Nation 1 only, Nation 2 consumes 70X (AB), with 10X
(AC) produce domestically and 60X (CB) imported from Nation 1 at PX = $1. The tariff
revenue disappears, and area AGJC represents a transfer from domestic producers to
domestic consumers. This leaves net static gains to Nation 2 as a whole equal to $15,
given by the sum of the areas of shaded triangles CJM and BHN.
Trade-Diverting Customs Unions
• Trade diversion occurs when lower-cost imports from non-members are
replaced by higher cost imports from members.
• By itself, trade diversion lowers welfare as it shifts resources away from comparative
advantages.
• Trade diverting customs union also results in trade creation. Change in welfare
depends on relative magnitude of creation and diversion.
• In Figure 10.2, the shaded triangles represent gains from trade creation. The
rectangle represents the loss of tariff revenue (that is not compensated with
consumer surplus gain).
FIGURE 10-2 A Trade-Diverting Customs Union.
FIGURE 10.2. A Trade-Diverting
Customs Union.

DX and SX represent Nation 2’s domestic demand and supply curves of


commodity X, while S1 and S3 are the free trade perfectly elastic supply curves
of commodity X of Nation 1 and Nation 3, respectively. With a
nondiscriminatory 100 percent tariff, Nation 2 imports 30X (JH) at PX = $2 from
Nation 1. After forming a customs union with Nation 3 only, Nation 2 imports
45X (C B) at PX = $1.50 from Nation 3. The welfare gain in Nation 2 from pure
trade creation is $3.75 (given by the sum of the areas of the two shaded
triangles). The welfare loss from trade diversion proper is $15 (the area of the
shaded rectangle). Thus, this trade-diverting customs union leads to a net
welfare loss of $11.25 for Nation 2.
Trade-Diverting Customs Unions

• It was once believed that any movement toward freer trade would increase
welfare, so formation of a customs union would necessarily result in increased
welfare for members and non-members.
• In 1950, Viner showed that formation of a customs union could increase or
reduce welfare, depending on the circumstances under which it takes place.
• Difficult to measure gains/losses empirically.
• Attempts to measure static welfare effects of the EU result in surprisingly small
gains of 1-2% of GDPs.
The Theory of the Second Best and Other Static Welfare
Effects of Customs Unions

• Theory of the Second Best


If all conditions required to maximize welfare cannot be satisfied,
trying to satisfy as many conditions as possible does not
necessarily or usually lead to the second-best position.
• Creation of customs unions may not be the second-best choice relative to free trade.
The Theory of the Second Best and Other Static Welfare
Effects of Customs Unions

• Conditions More Likely to Lead to Increased Welfare


1. Higher pre-union trade barriers of member nations.
2. Lower customs union’s trade barriers with non-members.
3. Greater number of nations forming customs union, and the larger their size.
4. More competitive rather than complementary economies of member
nations.
5. Closer geographical proximity of member nations.
6. Greater pre-union trade and economic relationship among potential
member nations.
The Theory of the Second Best and Other Static
Welfare Effects of Customs Unions

Other Static Effects of Customs Unions


1. Administration savings from elimination of customs officers, border patrols,
and others.
2. Reduction in demand for imports from and supply of exports to rest of the
world will likely lead to improvement in collective terms of trade of member
nations.
3. By acting as a single unit, customs union will likely have more bargaining
power than members separately.
Dynamic Benefits from Customs
Unions
Dynamic Benefits of Customs Unions
1. Increased competition, leading to greater efficiencies and technological
improvements.
2. Economies of scale from the enlarged market.
3. Stimulus of investment to take advantage of enlarged market, and to meet
increased competition.
4. Better utilization of community resources as labor and capital move freely
(assumes common market).
Thank You

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy