Text 4 - Teece Competition & Innovation
Text 4 - Teece Competition & Innovation
Text 4 - Teece Competition & Innovation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dtab049
Advance access publication date: 3 September 2021
Original Article
Abstract
This paper gives a fresh account of competition in the digital economy. Economic analysis in the field of
industrial organization remains largely focused on a sophisticated version of the Schumpeter–Arrow debate,
which is unresolved and largely irrelevant. We posit the need to look at competition anew. Static models of
monopoly firms and markets in equilibrium are often used to characterize Big Tech firms’ size and scope. We
suggest that this characterization is inappropriate because the growth and diversification of many digital firms
lead to a situation of broad-spectrum competition that cuts across markets. Current market positions do not
reflect entrenched monopoly power but are vulnerable to competitive pressure of disequilibrating forces aris-
ing from the use of data-driven operating models, astute resource orchestration, and the exercise of dynamic
capabilities. A few strategic errors by management in the handling of internal transitions and/or external chal-
lenges and they could be competitively impaired. The implications of a more dynamic understanding of the
competition process in the tech sector are explored. We consider how big data and entrepreneurial man-
agement impacts firm performance. We also explore the nature of different types of rents (Schumpeterian,
Ricardian, and monopoly rents) and suggest a modified long-term consumer welfare standard for competi-
tion policy. We formulate preliminary tests and predictors to assess dynamic competition. Our perspective
advances a policy stance that favors innovation.
JEL classification: O3, O33
1. Introduction
In the past 20 years, a small group of large US firms known under the moniker of “Big Tech”
has developed many of the digital products and services that consumers use.1 These firms are
Apple, Amazon, Facebook, Google, Microsoft, and Netflix. The expansion of these business
organizations is a defining feature of today’s digital economy. They have accounted for over
50% of the growth in equity value in US markets over the past 20 years. The rise of Big Tech
has raised many political concerns. In this paper, we focus on competition policy and sidestep
issues relating to democratic threats, the control of content, or free speech. We believe such issues
are analytically separable from the monopoly power problems that competition policy concerns
itself with.
1 To avoid useless repetition, we use “products” as a shorthand for “products and services”.
© The Author(s) 2021. Published by Oxford University Press in association with Oxford University Press and the
Industrial and Corporate Change Association.
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License
(https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted reuse, distribution, and reproduction in any
medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1169
The rise of Big Tech firms is having the welcome effect of causing a resurgence of interest in
industrial organization. The emerging scholarship is mixed. On the one hand, there is a tendency
to treat Big Tech firms as different because innovation in general (both technological and business
model), and technical inputs in particular (big data, intelligent algorithms, and skilled engineers),
clearly impact market structure and economic performance. On the other hand, industrial age
explanations like monopoly power, anticompetitive leveraging, and predatory mergers are often
used to supply theories for the durability and diversification of Big Tech firms. There is little or
no mention of the role of entrepreneurship and management or of new operating models that
deliver value in new and better ways.
2 As we write this, we remind the reader of the old Coase’s (1972) remark whereby “if an economist finds
something—a business practice of one sort or other—that he does not understand, he looks for a monopoly
explanation”. Coase’s remark retains a ring of truth today.
3 Of course, one might add that falling prices can be sustained over monopoly if input prices are declining. But
the evidence of falling input costs is mixed. Moreover, the past years have seen the addition of multiple costs on digital
platforms arising from increased privacy protection obligations, as well as safety and cybersecurity risks.
4 Quoted in Rainey (2019), In recent years several international organizations have invested efforts into this
enterprise. The OECD, for example, has embraced complexity theory to make sense of the dynamics of economic
systems The focus has, however, been mostly on financial markets, and less on market competition.
5 We take issue with the fact that the endogeneity of competition/market structure is often omitted in the discus-
sions of the welfare consequences of innovation/market power. This endogeneity means that there is a limit to what
can be achieved through a focus on market structure, and a danger that competition policy that is focused on lowering
concentration levels could actually harm innovation.
1170 N. Petit and D.J. Teece
2.1 Definitions
Static competition describes a situation in which firms compete for existing rents. In static com-
petition, firms supply close to perfect substitute products. Rivalry results in short-term price
decreases, cost-cutting, including wage reductions.
Dynamic competition, on the other hand, describes a situation in which firms compete for
future rents. In dynamic competition, firms use innovation to introduce new products, processes,
and services. Rivalry results in product differentiation, recombination, integration, diversifica-
tion, or platformization. It is a type of competition animated not by firms that compete head-on
with similar products but by heterogeneous competitors, complementors, suppliers, and cus-
tomers, using innovation to bring forth new products and processes. Such competition improves
long-term factor productivity, raises consumer welfare, and supports higher wages.
effective at improving consumer welfare than is static competition. He analogized static ver-
sus dynamic competition to the difference between bombardment and forcing a door. Dynamic
competition is so much more important that:
it becomes a matter of comparative indifference whether competition in the ordinary sense func-
tions more or less promptly; the powerful lever that in the long run expands output and brings
down prices is in any case made of other stuff.
6 The Austrian School was founded by Menger (1871) in the 19th century.
7 Although Bork found perfect competition to be a “defective policy goal”, and advocated in favor of a productive
efficiency friendly policy (High, 1984).
1172 N. Petit and D.J. Teece
theory has produced multiple efficiency and inefficiency possibility theorems, without however
supplying clear policy guidance to real-world decision-makers. And when economics have tried to
be more empirical, innovation has been measured by proxies like patent counts and R&D expen-
diture, which give at best crude insights and occasional clues about the complexity of processes
involved in innovation-led dynamic competition.
Notwithstanding these shortcomings, no policymaker would disagree with the statement that
innovation brings competition. Yet, despite its obvious importance, dynamic competition is not
embraced as widely in practice as is static competition. One reason for this neglect is instrumental.
It is harder to measure dynamic than static competition. Innovation often does not show up
… in the world of high technology there is high uncertainty and supercharged competition…
waves of new product introductions are frequently accompanied by premium prices initially,
followed by rapid price declines… antitrust economics and the industrial organization literature
manifests a limited understanding of the nature of competition in high-technology industries,
where competition is driven by innovation. Among the public policy (and economic) issues that
have not been well explored are the evolutionary processes at work, [and] the nature of the
sources of economic rent…8
Today, Schumpeterian and Austrian perspectives that embrace deep uncertainty are recognized
as highly relevant to the competitive activity of the tech sector. The widely popular “lean startup”
model (Ries, 2011) emphasizes this basic point. Perhaps, a reexamination of the historical
marginalization of dynamic competition is needed.
Antitrust enforcement has historically focused on static [rather] than dynamic analysis… for
a number of reasons. First the antitrust community… both lawyers and economists…have far
greater familiarity and comfort with static analysis rather than dynamic analysis. Second, there
is less incentive for parties to take the time to develop arguments based on dynamic analysis.
Third, there’s the perception – right or wrong – that dynamic analysis is less well developed and
less measurable than static analysis.
Almost a decade later, commissioner Christine Wilson of the US Federal Trade Commission
lamented again that frameworks that incorporated dynamic competition had been neglected
noting that:
the economic literature also acknowledges that innovation over the long run will deliver very
large consumer welfare gains.
Finally, about 5 years ago, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
stressed that “the methodology of competition authorities should move from a focus on static
economic theory does not offer a prediction about the effects of competition on innovation
that is robust to all of these markets and technological conditions. Instead, there are many
predictions….
In particular, both the Schumpeterian and the Arrow hypotheses are highly stylized and not
particularly relevant to real-world circumstances. Take Arrow’s model if monopolists will not
give up their current revenue (i.e., cannibalize their rent), it leaves the door wide open for new
entrants. To be sure, one should be alert to “dirty tricks” by an incumbent monopolist. But some
form of contestability should help save the day. Similarly, the Schumpeter risk-based requirement
for investment in R&D and innovation is overturned once an assumption is introduced that
investments from multiproduct firms or venture capitalists are available, which it is in most
modern economies.
Technology opportunities are another variable of importance that is not in Arrow or Schum-
peter. Schumpeter talked about “perennial gales of creative destruction.” Technological opportu-
nity (which can flow from developments in science and in enabling technologies) may shed light
14 See e.g., Klepper and Graddy (1990), Utterback and Suárez (1993), and Malerba and Orsenigo (1996).
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1175
Apple, moved successfully from a single product strategy (selling the Apple I PC) to sell a “broader
range of products,” with a “market wide emphasis”.
Christensen’s model of innovation has caught the attention of many executives and some aca-
demics. His “Disruption” model is outlined in the “Innovator’s Dilemma” (1997). He sought
to answer two main questions: (i) why is durable competition advantage so difficult to maintain
and (ii) is innovation really as unpredictable as the data suggests. His model was built from close
observation of the disk drive, mechanical excavators, and integrated steel industries.
Management plays a key role in Christensen’s model. The dilemma he saw was that “the
logical, competent decisions of management that are critical to the success of their companies are
Disruption technologies bring to a market a very different value proposition… generally dis-
ruptive technologies underperform established products in mainstream markets. But they have
other features that a few (and generally new) customers value. Products based on disrup-
tive technology are typically cheaper, simpler, smaller, and frequently more convenient to
use (PXViii)
Christensen noted that some companies tend to offer customers more than they wish to pay
for. This overkill opens opportunities for new entrants to enter with lower price and quality
products and then improves their performance a manner that undermines the incumbent.
There are two important takeaways that can be derived from Christensen’s popular model of
disruption. The first we credit to Thiel and Masters (2014: 56–57):
The act of creation is far more important… Indeed, if your company can be summed up by its
opposition to already existing firms, it cannot be completely new.
15 Schumpeter put more emphasis than Christensen does on the explosive power of entrepreneurialism. New tech-
nological phenomena are born of dynamic innovation-driven competition. As we have emphasized competition is fueled
not by static price-based rivalry, even though price for unit of performance may be lower even with no innovation (due
to efficiency). Thus a lightbulb was more expensive than a candle, but even the first lightbulbs were orders of magnitude
brighter (10× candlepower) than the candles they replaced.
16 Sometimes, incumbents can actually set the rules of the game by investing in predatory innovation (Schrepel,
2018), that is the “alteration of one or more technical elements of a product to limit or eliminate competition”.
1176 N. Petit and D.J. Teece
process.”17 These models and others like them can no longer continue to be ignored. A more
robust theory of the innovating firm is needed to guide competition economics and competition
policy.
decides, or not, to develop, maintain, and improve them.18 This distinguishes them from ordi-
nary capabilities, which can be readily bought and taught—most often, they are the skills learned
at business and engineering schools—in support of greater efficiency.
Now, just how and why some firms develop dynamic capabilities compared to others remains
somewhat enigmatic. The micro-analytics of these decisions are not well explained by economic
theory or by any other theory for that matter. Moreover, the dynamic capabilities framework has
not yet been extensively employed to account for the success, and failure, of firms in the digital
economy. An effort to remedy this situation is commenced in the next section.
18 We are not suggesting that this is an explicit board action item. However, the culture, tone, and ownership a
firm chooses has strong implications for dynamic capabilities.
19 These dynamic coordination issues are very different from the rent extraction of concern in the economics liter-
ature on innovation. In Farrell and Katz (2000), for example, a monopolist may extract so much rent from the firms
selling a competitively supplied complement that their innovation is suboptimal even from the monopolist’s perspective.
20 The firm MIPS Computer Systems encountered this with its failed attempt to promote their Advanced Comput-
ing Environment (ACE) to compete with Sun’s Scalable Processor Architecture (SPARC). MIPS set up alliances with
Compaq, DEC, Silicon Graphics, and other firms to pursue a RISC-based computing standard. However, soon after
DEC and Compaq announced that they were going to reduce their commitment to ACE, the alliance fell apart because
MIPS could not pick up the slack in some of the upstream activities. It failed both to develop competencies in key
aspects of the technology and to create a common expectation for the alliance (Gomes-Casseres, 1994).
1178 N. Petit and D.J. Teece
Orchestrations and (data) integration are particularly relevant to the digital economy. Today,
cospecialized assets, resources, and data are the building blocks of digital firms (Teece, forthcom-
ing). Building and assembling cospecialized assets and data inside the firm (rather than accessing
them through a skein of contracts) is not done primarily to guard against opportunism and recon-
tracting hazards. Instead, effective coordination of assets, resources, and data is important but
difficult to achieve through the price system. Existing property institutions do not enable efficient
opportunities for trade and economic exchange because information knowledge is a “fugitive
resource” (Arrow, 1996) subject to low appropriability and intellectual property (“IP”) protec-
tion. For example, there may simply be no viable business model for licensing certain types of
3.3 The way forward for a refined theory of firm-level competitive advantage in
the digital economy
In order to refine our understanding of the source of competitive advantage in the digital economy,
we propose the hypothesis that strong dynamic capabilities are a leading cause of the success and
failures of Big Tech firms Stated differently, the strength of a firm’s dynamic capabilities explains
the durability and diversification of some Big Tech firms and the stumbles of others.
To understand Big Tech firms’ dynamic capabilities, one needs to look closely inside the black
box, so as to pay attention to internal assets, resources, and data. More particularly, the economic
analyst should look for distinctive technical and human capital inputs. This requires models that
do not treat technology as fungible and in which “management matters”.23
In the digital economy, we believe that dynamic competition requires firms to have superior
capabilities to (i) astutely orchestrate big data, (ii) deploy artificial intelligence-driven operating
models, (iii) act entrepreneurially, while (iv) eschewing bureaucratic decision making.
21 Achieving such alignment through internalization goes beyond what Barnard (1938) has suggested as the
functions of the executive—which he sees in achieving cooperative adaptation.
22 Langlois (1992) defines dynamic transaction costs as “the costs of persuading, negotiating, coordinating and
teaching outside suppliers” (113).
23 See Bloom et al. (2007).
24 This section draws in part from Baden-Fuller et al. (forthcoming).
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1179
a product involving fixed, or near-fixed, proportions (or what Leontief called “production pro-
cesses”), it sometimes produces ancillary products/services that may have positive value, no value,
or negative value (as with effluents).
Netflix, for example, saw customer data as an inevitable byproduct of managing its DVD rental
business. However, that customer data over time formed the basis of its predictive algorithm
that became its core competitive advantage. Likewise, Amazon initially developed, in the 2000
timeframe, cloud computing as an ancillary software support function for itself and third-party
merchants (e.g., Target, Marks and Spencer). To more fully utilize the excess capacity it created
to meet peak demand, it began providing services to others, and AWS is now a very profitable
and grow it without a high quotient of what we call dynamic capabilities…which itself requires
entrepreneurial management.
Schumpeter considered that entrepreneurs are the main agents of “creative destruction.”
They are, as he powerfully wrote, the “pivot on which everything turn” (McCraw, 2007: 7).
Entrepreneurs identify “new things or the doing of things that are already being done in a new way
(innovation)” (Schumpeter, 1947: 151).30 They are not just inventors. Entrepreneurial activity
involves innovation, organization and management.31
As enormous volumes of digitized information become available, it is most important to under-
stand that the astute orchestration and management of data is critical to the long-term competitive
30 Schumpeter rightly added that the new thing “need not be spectacular or of historic importance”.
31 Economic evidence confirms that entrepreneurs play an outsized role in the fortunes of digital firms Empirical
economic studies have found that “many of the canonical superstar firms such as Google and Facebook employ relatively
few workers compared with their market capitalization, underscoring that their market value is based on intellectual
property and a cadre of highly skilled workers” (Autor et al., 2020). At a finer level, Athey and Luca discuss evidence
of large numbers of PhD economists joining the ranks of tech companies to work on business problems like working
with data; assessing and interpreting empirical relationships; understanding and designing markets and incentives; and
reading the environment and strategic interactions (Athey and Luca, 2019). If anything, job market trends suggest that
digital firms’ ability to hire talent and orchestrate it is key to survival in rapidly changing marketplaces.
32 All the more given that complexity arises from the fact that that limited datasets might also be sufficient for
small firms to enter in some applications markets. See Gómez-Losada and Duch-Brown (2019).
33 Michael Porter has developed a theory of strategy around conduct designed to impair competition. As Porter
(1981: 612) notes “public policy makers could use their knowledge of the sources of entry barriers to lower them,
whereas business strategists could use theirs to raise barriers.”
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1181
influence of dynamic competition in mainstream economics (and for the enduring prevalence
of the neoclassical tradition) is perhaps the lack of definitional precision. The economics liter-
ature on rents unfortunately has failed to disaggregate the sources of “rents” very well, and it
is therefore necessary to go back to basics. We do so by differentiating first between Ricardian,
Schumpeterian, and monopoly rents.
Ricardian rents reflect returns to assets whose supply is fixed over a finite time horizon and are
a function of permanent differences in the productivity or location of alternative assets difficult
to expand competences. Winter (1995) talks of scarcity rents.
Schumpeterian (entrepreneurial) rents reflect returns arising from the introduction by
Source of rents Rents consistent with: Short-term consumer welfare Long-term consumer welfare
√
Schumpeterian X √
Ricardian Maybe
Naked monopoly X X
A focus on long-run consumer welfare will protect/conduct that earns Schumpeterian rents
to draw forth continued investment in the ecosystem. Second, big is not bad, and dominance-
based intervention thresholds are inappropriate. Competition between platforms tends to reduce
winner take all outcomes. Moreover, industrial structure may be too fragmented, and most
small firms cannot afford the R&D and professional management that is needed to develop
commanding dynamic capabilities. Third, criteria are needed to distinguish (from a social wel-
fare perspective) between “undesirable” profits (monopoly) and “desirable” (Schumpeterian and
Ricardian) rents. For the reasons just explained, such performance indicators must complement
market structure analysis. The underlying idea is that high-performing firms that invest despite
deep uncertainty are unlikely to be the beneficiaries of naked monopoly rents. The best of all
in turn, tell us whether it is a “snatcher” or a “sticker” (Hicks, 1954).34 Sir John Hicks made
this distinction half a century ago (1954). Snatchers behave opportunistically, taking short-term
gains.
34 Hicks called a company that takes a quick profit a Snatcher; a company trying to develop a steady business was
a Sticker.
35 When firms are weak, there is a tendency to collude. The railroad cartels in the US in the depression years of the
1930s are a case in point.
36 One underappreciated point of the dynamic capabilities literature is that it considers that the bulk of activities
that make up an organization’s dynamic capabilities should not be outsourced, and should not be absorbed. This is
due to imperfect factor markets, the non-tradability of soft assets like value, culture and organizational experience, and
distinctive competences.
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1185
The dynamic capabilities framework suggests that some classes of acquisitions are less prob-
lematic than others. Three rules of thumb can be drawn from the literature. One, and quite
counter-intuitively, the higher the degree of alignment between the merging firms, the greater
the scope for efficiencies to redeem an otherwise anticompetitive merger. This is because the
likelihood of successful dynamic capabilities absorption will be more important for firms who
have already developed a “path of learning”, than for firms who have closed it. Two, absorption
of dynamic capabilities is easier when the acquired firm is young. By contrast, older firms pos-
sess deep ingrained routines that are hardwired into the organization and difficult to transfer by
acquisition or agreement. Three, the risk of reduced competition by acquisition is lower when
5.1.2 Self-preferencing
Self-preferencing is a form of discrimination. In the standard case, a prominent platform that
administers interactions between two or more user groups gives preferential treatment to its
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1187
own applications, products or services in related areas. Prominent examples of alleged self-
preferencing in the digital economy include Apple consistently favoring its apps by displaying
them more prominently than similar apps in App Store search results and on the App Store
home page (Kotapati et al., 2020); Microsoft using its dominance over Windows to give Inter-
net Explorer a distribution advantage that other web browsers are unable to match (Buhr et al.,
2010); or Netflix tweaking its algorithm and user interface to display favorably its own shows
and reduce licensing costs to third-party suppliers of video content.
In the policy conversation, self-preferencing has been attacked on the ground that it places
upstream (or downstream) rivals at the mercy of anticompetitive exclusion by vertically inte-
5.2 Analytical tools, tests, and predictors for a dynamic competition paradigm
In this section, we sketch out tools relevant for analysis in digital industries. The likelihood of
error by courts and agencies under the current orthodoxy is indeed high given their limited toolkit
for understanding complex innovative environments. But it will also be high if they attempt
to apply the dynamic competition framework as such. The dynamic competition and dynamic
capabilities literatures are highly conceptual, and its implementation difficult. Capabilities are
organizationally embedded and hard to measure. The concrete application of dynamic capabili-
ties principles to competition policy development and execution thus requires additional effort to
convert abstract scholarly ideas into operational tests. As part of this task, we are also reminded
that it is good policy practice to strive for “information light” policies, that is policies that do
The existence of Amazon and its clear clout in the market rather strongly suggests the European
Commission missed the point: market control comes from aggregating customers; Google can’t
anymore restrict competition from sites that depend on Google than a car can restrict compe-
tition from a trailer it is towing. Winning online is not about functionality, but about what
app or website customers open of their own volition. In the case of shopping, that website is
increasingly Amazon, and now it is Google that is partnering with others in response.
Innovating Big Tech firms and competition policy 1189
not require information that cannot be made available to regulators (Tirole, 2014: 509). That
said, there are some available easy first steps.
product differentiation on choice variables like privacy (Petit, 2020). The EC market definition in
Google Android also leads to curious implications such as the idea that a merger between Apple
and Google in smartphone OS would be prima facie unproblematic, absent actual horizontal
overlaps.
The problems of static market definition might be mitigated by a revamped doctrine of
potential competition. We write “revamped” because the conventional assessment of potential
competition determines whether firms located in other markets or industries have incentives to
repurpose assets to compete deploying close-to-perfect substitute products with established firms.
In digital industries, firms compete by indirect entry (Bresnahan and Greenstein, 1999; Petit,
5.3 The law is further along than economic theory: doctrinal vs. operational
issues
Interestingly, our approach does not require foundational changes in antitrust/competition law.
(We note the relevance of Judge Hand’s thrust upon monopoly concept and his recognition of
the importance of superior skill, foresight and industry.) The problem is more with the eco-
nomics, less so the law. As Thomas Kuhn explained long ago, in science there is an inherent
conservatism around paradigm shifts. We believe that a paradigm shift from static to a more
wholesome dynamic competition is now required. The static model represents what Kuhn (Kuhn,
1962) calls “normal science” has outlived its usefulness and is now standing in the way of a deeper
understanding of competition in digital economies.
The dynamic competition framework we propose is not a critique of the law but a guide to
assessing the facts.44 In many ways, antitrust law, at least in the USA and increasingly in Europe,
allows for the introduction of considerations that relate to the capabilities of the enterprise in
evaluating Sections 1 and 2 cases as well as in merger review. We will advance the proposition
that on a “go forward” basis, the focus should not be a market power, but on anticompetitive
conduct, with a focus on naked exclusionary practices.
Statutory antitrust law says nothing about the goal of antitrust being to lower prices. Rather,
the focus is on whether business behavior is anticompetitive. Merger law, for instance, does not
focus on the impact on price. The existing law requires one to look at competitive effects. Hence,
there is plenty of room in existing legal structures to bring in innovation, but too few choose to
do so, often because economists and lawyers are rather awkward when analyzing it, despite its
centrality to competition.
In Appalachian Coals, the US Supreme Court adopted a dynamic capabilities view of the com-
petitive process when it absolved a combination of 137 coal producers from Section 1 liability
on the ground that “The intelligent conduct of commerce through the acquisition of full infor-
mation of all relevant facts may properly be sought by the cooperation of those engaged in trade,
although stabilization of trade and more reasonable prices may be the result”.45 In United States
v Grinnell Corp, the US Supreme Court held that the basic standard for monopolization under
Section 2 requires proof of “the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished
Trinko also represents a profound change in the Supreme Court jurisprudence on microeco-
nomic competition. Specifically, Trinko represents the first Supreme Court case to break directly
with both the well-defended “structure-conduct-performance” and Chicago schools of economic
analysis, as well as the vaguely defined “post-Chicago” school of micro economic analysis… the
Supreme Court articulated a classical rivalrous process view of competition, as refined through
the core insights of the “Resource-Advantage” theory of competition, consistent with the 1890
enactment of the Sherman Act. In doing so, the court rejected the neoclassical construct of
“perfect competition” as a welfare ideal.
The US Supreme Court’s embracing of the resource-advantage theory is entirely consistent with
the capabilities framework we advance in this paper. An innovating firm’s exercise of dynamic
capabilities is, after all, a managerial model for achieving evolutionary marketplace fitness.
More generally, the Courts on both sides of the Atlantic increasingly reassess antitrust doc-
trine in light of progress in economic theory. In its 1992 Opinion in Eastman Kodak v Image
Technical Services, Inc, et al, the Supreme Court actually “instructed lower courts to judge par-
ties’ economic theories by how well they described ‘actual market behavior’.” There is no reason
to believe it cannot adapt to a dynamic capabilities and dynamic competition perspective on the
economics of digital markets. For example, in 2019, the Supreme Court came close to under-
standing the dynamic of ecosystems competition in Ohio, et al v American Express Company
when it relied on the economic theory of multisided markets to raise the burden of proof on
plaintiffs in vertical restraints cases involving transactions platforms like credit cards or online
commerce markets. And in its 2017 judgment in Intel v Commission, the Court of Justice of the
EU drew the correct conclusion of the consumer welfare paradigm when it held that dominant
firms can lawfully exclude less efficient rivals.
In the US, the Amex case has been criticized has a caricature of multisided market theory
(Melamed and Petit, 2019). But the idea underpinning the majority opinion in Amex makes
6. Conclusion
A new competition economics paradigm is needed. At a time where fiercely competitive diversified
firms represent a feature not a bug of the digital economy, a better diagnosis of the foundations of
long-term competitive advantage can reduce the risks of type I and type II errors in competition
cases and policy-making. Simplistic Chicagoan efficiency theorems and populistic antimonopoly
narratives fall way short of the mark.
Economist and legal experts must develop tools and models that operationalize the idea that
innovation drives competition as much as competition drives innovation. So far, the recognition
that advancing dynamic competition and supporting innovation benefits consumers has been
perfunctory in competition economics.
But there are reasons for optimism. The law, for a start, offers much leeway, and has
already begun to move in this direction. Moreover, a large body of research in evolutionary eco-
nomics, the behavioral theory of the firm, technology management, and strategic management
has emerged which can be readily exploited. In this paper, we have tried to derive some insights
from these studies in support of a framework, and a set of protocols, that can allow the incor-
poration of dynamic competition into the economics of competition policy. At the heart of our
framework is a new conceptualization of the firm. We replace standard production theory with
a Schumpeterian conception of the (innovating) firm which draws on the dynamic capabilities
framework.
What we have written here is neither heretical nor polemical. Dynamic competition is a natural
extension of traditional theories of competition. A trained competition eye will recognize the com-
mon thread between dynamic capabilities and policies against cartels that combat organizational
structures limiting the uncertainty of competition or stabilizing strategic positions.52
Considerable hard work has been done and core foundations are in place. However, we recog-
nize that we do not have all the answers. There is no handbook on dynamic competition available
for consultation by competition courts and agencies. That is not a reason to pull back. The direc-
tion of travel toward an innovation centric competition policy is clear. We believe that if just a
small group of the competition policy community would join us—and we would request a good
measure of the more junior members—then we can quickly forge a path ahead.
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank Ron Adner, John Blair, Charles Baden-Fuller, Connie Helfat,
Henry Kahwaty, Richard Nelson, Thibault Schrepel, George Soros, Giorgio Monti, David Stal-
librass, Doug Melamed and Bo Heiden for trenchant comments, observations, and relevant
discussions, Sam Palmisano, and Fernand Sarrat for important insights, and Charles Clarke,
Sara Guidi and Natalia Moreno Belloso for research assistance. The special issue editors and
several anonymous referees provided uncommon insights for which we are especially grateful.
Chesbrough, H. and D. J. Teece (1996), ‘When is virtual virtuous? Organizing for innovation,’ Harvard Business
Review, 74(1), 65–73.
Christensen, C. M. (1997), The Innovator’s Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail.
Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA.
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The nature of the firm,’ Economica, 4(16), 386–405.
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The problem of social cost,’ The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.
Coase, R. H. (1972), ‘Industrial organization: a proposal for research,’ in V.R. Fuchs (ed.), Economic Research:
Retrospect and Prospect, Volume 3, Policy Issues and Research Opportunities in Industrial Organization.
NBER: Cambridge, MA, pp. 59–73.
Hicks, J. (1935), ‘Annual survey of economic theory: the theory of monopoly,’ Econometrica, 3(1), 1–20.
Hicks, J. R. (1954), ‘The process of imperfect competition,’ Oxford Economic Papers, 6(1), 41–54.
High, J. (1984), ‘Bork’s paradox: static vs. dynamic efficiency in antitrust analysis,’ Contemporary Economic
Policy, 3(2), 21–34.
Holmström, B. and P. Milgrom (1994), ‘The firm as an incentive system,’ American Economic Review, 84,
972–991.
Hu, J. (2002), ‘Yahoo sheds Inktomi for new search technology,’ CNET, 12 January. https://www.cnet.
com/news/yahoo-sheds-inktomi-for-new-search-technology/.
Jacobides, M. G., T. Knudsen and M. Augier (2006), ‘Benefiting from innovation: value creation, value
Pleatsikas, C. and D. J. Teece (2001a), ‘New indicia for antitrust analysis in markets experiencing rapid innova-
tion,’ in J. Ellig (ed.) Dynamic Competition and Public Policy: Technology, Innovation, and Antitrust Issues.
Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, pp. 95–137.
Pleatsikas, C. and D. J. Teece (2001b), ‘The analysis of market definition and market power in regimes of rapid
“technological progress”,’ International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19(5), 665–693.
Porter, M. E. (1980), Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors. Free Press:
New York, NY.
Porter, M. E. (1981), ‘The contributions of industrial organization to strategic management,’ The Academy of
Management Review, 6, 609–620.
Teece, D. J. and M. Coleman (1998), ‘The meaning of monopoly: antitrust analysis in high-technology
industries,’ The Antitrust Bulletin, 43(3–4), 801–857.
Teece, D. J., G. Pisano and A. Shuen (1997), ‘Dynamic capabilities and strategic management,’ Strategic
Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.
Thiel, P. and B. Masters (2014), Zero to One. Notes on Startups, or How to Build the Future. Crown Business:
New York, NY.
Thompson, B. (2017), ‘Ends, means, and antitrust,’ Stratechery, 28 June. https://stratechery.com/2017/ends-
means-and-antitrust/.
Thompson, B. (2020), ‘The anti-Amazon alliance,’ Stratechery, 28 April. https://stratechery.com/2020/the-anti-