Microeconomics
Microeconomics
Microeconomics
Compiled by:
Md. Mahfuzur Rahman
Assistant Professor (Economics)
School of Business
Bangladesh Open University
School of Business
BANGLADESH OPEN UNIVERSITY
MICROECONOMICS
1
Contents
Unit 1: Introduction
Lesson 1: Nature and Methodology of Economics
Lesson 2: The Basic Problems of an Economy
Unit 7: Monopoly
Lesson 1: Nature of Monopoly Market and AR and MR Curves in Monopoly Market
Lesson 2: Price and Output Determination under Monopoly: Equilibrium of Monopolist
Lesson 3: Monopoly Power, Regulating the Monopoly and the Comparison between Competitive and
Monopoly Markets
2
Unit 1: INTRODUCTION
Highlights
3
Lesson 1: Nature and Methodology of Economics
Lesson Objectives
Nature of Economics
Economics is a social science which deals with economic activities of people. People have
unlimited wants, but the resources required to satisfy these wants are limited. Scarcity of
resources in the presence of unlimited wants gives rise to all economic activities. If the resources
were not scarce, there would not be any economic activity at all. With unlimited resources, a
person could get as much as he would like to have without any work. Economics is rightly called
the study of the allocation of resources for satisfying human wants.
Since people cannot satisfy all wants with limited resources, they have to choose the most and
urgent ones from unlimited wants. A person may feel the wants for food, color television, and a
host of other items, but he must meet his want for food before anything. The choice problem
arises also because a resource has alternative uses. For example, a piece of land can be used for
growing paddy or it can be used for building a market on it or it can be put to any other use its
owner thinks most profitable. Once its owner has put it to one use, it cannot be used for other
purposes. The best use of a resource can be assured by utilizing it to meet the most urgent and
important wants. The definition of Economics is based on the fundamental concepts of unlimited
wants, limited resources, the choice problem, and alternative uses of resources. Professor L.
Robbins defines economics as, "Economics is the science which studies human behavior as a
relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.''
Methodology of Economics
Economics is a science in the sense that it employs scientific methods of acquiring and
disseminating knowledge. There is, however, a sharp distinction between the methods of
acquiring knowledge used in economics and those used in natural sciences like physics,
chemistry, etc. The natural sciences conduct controlled experiments with inanimate matters and
4
animals in laboratories whereas, Economics experiments with human being who cannot be
subjected to such controlled experiments. Moreover, randomness is a latent feature of human
behavior. The science of Economics formalized the systematic pattern of economic behavior of a
person, if any, despite the wide fluctuations in his behavior. Nevertheless, Economics uses
scientific methods of acquiring knowledge. Broadly speaking, there are two methods of
gathering knowledge, viz., deductive and inductive methods. Let us now determine which of the
two methods is used in Economics.
It should be noted that much of economic analysis are positive. A few topics in economics,
however, are normative in nature. Finally, we can think of another type of economic analysis
known as the Art of economics. It discusses the methods of applying the knowledge obtained in
Positive Economics to achieve the goals determined in Normative Economics. Suppose, we have
decided to achieve a particular type of distribution of income in the economy given the way the
economy works, how can we obtain the specified pattern of distribution of income? The art of
Economics provides answers to this type of questions.
5
markets for products, markets for inputs are a few examples of microeconomic topics. Not only
microeconomics discusses the behavior of the smallest independent decision units, but also
discusses the interactions emerging among different economic agents.
Macroeconomics deals with aggregate variables facing an economy. Gross national product
(GNP), aggregate employment level, the general price level, the growth rate of the economy,
etc., are few examples of macroeconomic topics. The macroeconomic topics are quite distinct
from the microeconomic topics. For example, Macroeconomics shows how the equilibrium
levels of income and consumption of the economy are determined, whereas Microeconomics
determines the utility maximizing levels of commodities of a consumer. Microeconomics
discusses the determination of relative prices of the commodities and services and
Macroeconomics discusses the determination of general price level in the economy.
The assumptions of the two branches of economics are, of course, different. Microeconomics
assumes prices of other commodities and services to remain fixed when it explains the
determination of price of one commodity. Macroeconomics, on the other hand, assumes that the
relative prices have already been determined when it explains the determination of the general
price level. In some cases, the boundaries of Microeconomics and Macroeconomics are
overlapping. For example, one topic of Microeconomics is general equilibrium analysis which
shows the simultaneous equilibrium of all consumers and production firms in the economy. On
the other hand, Macroeconomics analyzes separately the determinants and functioning of bond
market, labor market, etc.
Finally, it is observed that the values of Macroeconomic variables are not equal to sums of
values of microeconomic variables. The study of Macroeconomics will not be necessary and
interesting if macroeconomic variables can be created by adding microeconomic variables. It
can, however, be asserted that the two types of variables are quite distinct. Consider, for
example, the case of transfer payments to a person, who wins a lottery award of forty lakh taka.
There is no doubt that the income of the person has increased, but national income has not
increased due to the increment in personal income. In other words, national income does not
reflect the increment in personal income in this case.
Review Questions
1. What is Economics? Is Economics a normative or positive science? Illustrate your answer.
2. Distinguish Microeconomics from Macroeconomics. What are the uses and limitations of
Microeconomic theories?
7
The idea of opportunity cost can be explained with the help of an opportunity cost curve,
alternatively known as production possibility curve. Suppose, a hypothetical economy can
produce only two commodities: guns and paddy, by using all its resources. The production
possibilities of the economy are shown in Figure-1.1. We measure the quantity of food in million
metric tons along the vertical axis and the number of guns in millions along the horizontal axis.
A
Food
C
F
D
G
E
H
0
B
Guns
Figure 1.1: Production Possibility Curve
Initially, the economy is at point A producing OA quantity of food and no guns. Perhaps both the
people and the government of the economy express their dissatisfaction in having no guns and
would like to produce FC guns by sacrificing AF quantity of food. In other words, the
opportunity cost of FC guns is AF quantity of food. Some resources previously used in
producing food were released and shifted to the production of guns. Consequently, the
production of food fell when the economy stands to produce a small number of guns.
Suppose the new military ruler of the country wants more guns. The economy moves to D from
C gaining GD guns at the cost of GC tons of food. Similarly, to obtain HE additional units of
guns, the economy has to sacrifice DH units of food. It can be easily seen that the amount of
sacrifice of food for each extra unit of gun is rising gradually. In economic terminology, this
phenomenon is known as increasing marginal opportunity cost or increasing marginal cost in
brief. There is, of course, an economic explanation for increasing marginal cost. When the
economy was producing a large amount of food and a small number of guns initially, some of the
resources used in food production were indeed more suitable to gun production. The resources
having comparative advantage in gun production were released for gun production when the
economy started to produce more guns. As a result, the opportunity cost of producing guns was
low initially. As the economy increased the production level of guns further, some of the
resources having comparative advantage in food production had then to be shifted to gun
production. Consequently, the opportunity cost of producing guns increased with increase level
of gun production. Needless to say, the phenomenon of increasing marginal cost makes the
production possibility curve concave to the origin.
8
It should be noted that the production possibility curve shows efficient production levels. At each
point on the production possibility curve, the economy produces the two commodities as much
as possible with given resources. Take, for example, the production level shown by H in Figure
1.1, which is clearly inefficient. Using the given resources, production level can be pushed to D
which shows increased quantity of food with no change in the production level of guns. Or, it
can be shifted to E where production of guns increases, whereas production of food remains
fixed. Production of both commodities will increase if the production shifts to any point between
D and E.
Now that we have explained the concept of opportunity cost and illustrated the derivation of
production possibility curve which entails opportunity cost. We can use the production
possibility curve for explaining the problem denoted by the word 'what?'. The production
possibility curve shows the different bundles of two commodities, food and gun, that can be
produced utilizing all the available resources in the economy. For example, the country can
produce the combination shown by C or the combination shown by D in Figure 1.2. Combination
C signifies F1 tons of food and G1 units of guns. Similarly, combination D shows F2 tons of food
and G2 units of guns.
A
Food
C •M
F1
F2 D
0 G1 G2 B
Guns
Figure 1.2: Production Possibility Curve
Each point on the curve AB shows a specific combination of two commodities. The country
chooses one and only one combination from the set of many combinations on the curve AB. It
cannot choose more than one combination on the curve. Similarly, it cannot choose the point M,
which it cannot produce with the given resources. It would not choose any point below the
production possibility curve because production at such a point would entail inefficiency in
production. The word 'what?' refers to the problem of choosing one specific combination of the
two commodities from a large number of combinations lying on the efficient production frontier
AB.
9
The Problem of Selecting Method of Production: 'How?'
The abbreviated question 'how?' refers to the problem of the choice of the method of producing
the selected commodities. There are different methods of producing the predetermined quantities
of a number of commodities and services. For example, there are labor intensive and capital
intensive methods of production. Normally, production of a commodity or service requires all
inputs of production. The quantities put in the production of a commodity may be changed,
because, one input may be substituted another depending on the relative prices of two inputs.
A
Capital
K1 C
K2 D
0 L1 L2
Labor
Method of producing commodity is called labor intensive when more labor and less capital is
used in the production process of that commodity. Input intensity of a commodity can also be
defined in relative terms. Gun is said to be more capital intensive than food when the ratio of
capital to labor in gun production is larger than the corresponding capital labor-ratio of food
production. It should be noted that the method of production depends on technology of
production and prevailing input price.
Figure 1.3 explains the nature of the second problem denoted by the term 'how?'. Here, we
introduce the concept of equal product curve, alternatively known as iso-quant. An equal product
curve shows the different combinations of two inputs, which produce a given quantity of output.
The curve AB in Figure 1.3 is an equal product curve. The vertical axis of Figure 1.3 measures
capital and the horizontal axis measures labor. Combination C with OK1 units of capital and OL1
units of labor can produce as much of the commodity as the combination D with OK2 amount of
capital and OL2 amount of labor can produce. Input allocation at C, however, implies a capital
intensive method of production, because, at C production of the commodity requires more capital
than labor. Similarly, combination D implies a labor intensive method of production. Each point
on the curve AB implies a distinct capital labor ratio, and hence, a distinct production process of
the commodity in question. The choice problem indicated by the word 'how?' refers to the
problem of choosing one of several methods of production shown along different points of an
equal product curve.
10
The Problem of Distribution: 'For Whom?'
The third problem of an economic society as abbreviated by the phrase 'for whom?' refers to the problem of
distribution of the produced commodities and services among the consumers. An economy may be endowed with
many natural and non-natural resources so that it can produce a large volume of goods and services. The people of
the economy might still face problems in meeting their wants for daily necessities if most of the produced
commodities and services go to the consumption of a small section of the people. Most least
developed countries (LDCs) face the problems of both inadequate resources and distribution of
income. In Bangladesh, small portion of population are rich, and one of the reasons is that their
forefathers were rich and these people have much more than they would like to have. Majority of
the people live below the poverty line. The big question is: should we ignore it and endure with
the existing distribution of income as happily as ever? We also face the problem of physically
crippled and mentally retarded persons who are unable to work. Should these persons be left
uncared and allowed to starve to death? The central authority of an economy often faces these
types of questions. The problem expressed by the phrase 'for whom?' refers to the problem of
selecting a widely accepted criterion of distributing income among hundreds of millions of
people living in the country.
Review Questions
14
Unit 2: DEMAND AND SUPPLY
Highlights
Law of Demand
Individual Demand Curve
Market Demand Curve
Law of Supply
Individual Supply Curve
Market Supply
Market Equilibrium and Disequilibrium
15
Lesson 1: Theory of Demand
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
define the concept of demand;
explain the main influences on demand;
explain law of demand;
draw demand curve from demand schedule; and
describe the relation between individual and market demand.
Wants
Wants are the unlimited desires or wishes that people have for goods and services. Every person
wants to get more and more of goods and services. A person who has a bicycle likes to get a
motorcycle. When he/she gets a motorcycle, she/he wants to have a private car, and so on. Wants
are always unlimited. In these circumstances, a question arises: can people meet all of their
wants? The answer is NO. Why? Because, resources are limited.
Need
Need for a commodity refers to the necessity of the commodity to sustain life. For example, if
you tell your friend that you need three tickets for watching a movie if the price is Tk. 30.00 per
ticket, it would be easy for your friend to disagree with your statement. She/he could argue that
you did not need any movie tickets because watching movie was not necessary to sustain life.
But if you say that you want three movie tickets, then it's all right - it cannot be disputed. You
can rightly say that you need a glass of water to quench your thirst. In this lesson, we are
concerned with wants, not needs because, demand reflects only wants.
Demand
You have seen earlier that all of our wants cannot be satisfied due to the limited availability of
resources. Only a few numbers of wants are affordable. Demand reflects the decision about
which wants are to satisfy. That is, the affordable wants are considered as demand. So we will
say the consumer has demand for commodity X if (if and only if) the following things are true:
The consumer has want for commodity X, i.e., commodity X has the ability to meet the
desire of the consumer.
The consumer is willing to have it.
The consumer has sufficient purchasing power to buy the commodity.
Quantity Demanded
The quantity demanded of a good or service is the amount that people are willing and able to
purchase at each price in a series of possible prices during a specified period of time. Three
important things are to be noticed when someone thinks about quantity demanded:
16
Quantity demanded is a desired quantity- not necessarily the same amount as the people
actually bought. Quantity demanded may be a different amount than people actually succeed
in purchasing. If sufficient quantities are not available, the amount people wish to purchase
may exceed the amount they actually do purchase. To avoid confusion, we could use quantity
demanded to refer to desired purchase and quantity exchanged to refer to actual purchase.
The word "Desired" does not refer to idle dreams or future possibilities but to effective
demands, that is, to the amounts people are willing to buy given the price they must pay for
the commodity. For persons willing to spend Tk. 500 this year on a commodity whose price
is Tk. 100 per unit, the quantity demanded is 5 units even though they would prefer to
consume much more if only they did not have to pay for it.
Quantity demanded refers to a continuous flow of purchase. It must, therefore, be expressed
as so much per period of time: 1 thousand bananas per day, 7 thousand per week, or 100
thousand per year. If you were told, for example, that the quantity of computers demanded (at
current prices) in Bangladesh was 50,000, this would mean nothing. Because you were not
told the period of time involved.
17
Income: Other things remaining the same, when income increases, consumers buy more of most
of the goods, and when income decreases, they buy less of most of the goods.
Tastes: Tastes are an individual's attitudes toward goods and services. For example, a pop music
fanatic has a much greater taste for tapes than does a tune-deaf workaholic. As a consequence,
even if they have the same incomes, their demand for tapes will be very different.
Population: If the population of the country increases, the quantity demand of a good increases
even though the price of the commodity remains unchanged.
Other unrelated goods: If price of a good decreases, you will get more money to spend on
books or any other goods or services. On the other hand, if other unrelated goods are not
available, then you will have more money to spend on the commodity.
Expectations : Expectations have influence on consumer decisions. If someone expects that the
price of Sony TV will be decreased within the next few days, she/he will be reluctant to buy a
TV set at the moment. If you think that you are going to get a personal computer with more
facilities and same price after a few days, would you decide to buy a computer at this moment?
Certainly not.
Therefore, due to the expectations about future price, quality, etc. of a product, the demand for
the product varies.
Now, think yourself. What is the most important determinant of quantity demanded? Certainly,
price of the commodity. Let's know about the relationship between price and demand.
}
Prices of related goods
Average income of the consumers
Tastes
Prices of unrelated goods Other things
Expectations about future price
Population
18
On What Basis Does the Price-Demand Relationship (or the Law of Demand) Rest?
There are several levels of analysis on which to argue the case:
Firstly, our common sense says that people ordinarily do buy more of a product at a low price
than they do at a high price. A high price discourages consumers from buying, and a low price
encourages them to buy. Businesses, for example, Bata, Arong, etc. declare "Sale" sometimes in
the year. At that time the products are sold at low prices. Lots of people gather in the sales
centers. Within a short period their inventories are exhausted. This evidence makes our belief in
the law of demand consistent.
Secondly, after a given period of time, each buyer of a product will get less satisfaction or utility
from each successive unit of a product. The second piece of "biscuit" will yield less satisfaction
to the consumer than the first one and the third will still add less satisfaction or utility than the
second. As consumption is subject to diminishing marginal utility (see Lesson 2 of Unit 4) -
consuming successive units of a particular product yields less and less additional satisfaction,
consumers will agree to buy additional units of the product if its price is reduced.
Thirdly, the law of demand also can be explained in terms of income and substitution effects.
The substitution effect indicates that the lower price of a good, other things remaining the same,
the consumers get the incentive to substitute the cheaper good for goods relatively expensive.
Consumers tend to substitute cheap products for dear products.
The income effect suggests, at a lower price, other things remaining the same, a consumer can
afford more of the good without giving up other goods. In other words, a decline in the price of a
product will increase the purchasing power of the consumer enabling her/him to buy more of the
product than before. A higher price will have the higher opposite effect. For example, a decline
in the price of beef will increase the purchasing power of consumer enabling her/him to buy
more beef (the income effect). At a lower price, beef is more attractive and is substituted for
mutton, chicken, and fish (the substitution effect). The income and substitution effects combine
to make consumers able and willing to buy more of a product at a lower price than at a higher
price.
How Can the Relationship between Quantity Demand and Price be Portrayed?
Two methods are usually used to do that:
19
Table 2.1: Demand schedule for biscuits (hypothetical data)
Price per kg (Tk.) Quantity demanded
(kg per week)
Pt Qt
A 10 100
B 15 80
C 20 60
D 30 40
E 60 20
In Table 2.1, we see that as the price of biscuit increases, the quantity demanded for biscuits
decreases. That is, there is an inverse relationship between the quantity demanded for biscuit and
its own price.
Second method: Demand curve or willingness and ability to pay curve
The relationship between quantity demanded and price can be shown by drawing a graph. If we
plot the information given in Table 2.1 in a graph, we get demand curve. Figure 2.1 shows a
demand curve which represents the points corresponding to price-quantity pairs of Table 2.1.
In Figure 2.1, DD is the demand curve for biscuit. Each point on the DD curve refers to the
quantity demanded for biscuit at a particular price. We see that with the uise of price of biscuit,
quantity demand for biscuit decreases along the DD curve.
20
Pt
D
60 E
50
40
Price
D
30
20 C
B
10 A
D
0 Qt
20 40 60 80 100
Quantity
Figure 2.1: Demand Curve for Biscuit
Normally, demand curves are downward sloping i.e., the relationship between quantity
demand and price is inverse. According to the law of demand, people buy more at a low price
than at a high price, which is reflected in the downward slope of the demand curve.
The term demand refers to the entire relationship between price and quantity. However, a
single point on a demand curve refers to the quantity demanded at a particular price. For
example, at point C in Figure 2.1, we see that 60 kg of biscuits is demanded at a price of Tk.
20.00 per kg
The slope of the demand curve changes if the pattern of the relationship between price and
quantity demanded changes.
The position of a demand curve changes if the ceteris paribus assumption is violated, i.e., if
other things, such as tastes, income, price of related goods, expectation, etc. change.
What is the Advantage of Graphing the Demand Schedule?
We see that in both Table 2.1 and Figure 2.1 contain exactly the same data and reflect the same
relationship between price and quantity demanded. However, an added advantage lies with
graphing that we can represent clearly a given relationship in which case the law of demand is
shown more simply than that of tabular or verbal presentation. A single curve on a graph, if
understood, is simpler to state and manipulate than tables and lengthy verbal descriptions.
Especially, in economic analysis, graphs are invaluable tools. They permit clear expression and
handling of complex relationships.
Change in the Quantity Demanded Vs. Change in Demand
From the above discussion, you have learnt that quantity demanded refers to a particular point on
a demand curve, whereas demand refers to the entire relationship between price and quantity as
shown by the whole demand curve. Therefore, if the own price of a commodity changes (i.e.,
rises/falls), the quantity demanded of that commodity changes along the demand curve; the
position of the demand curve does not change. This is called the movement along the demand
curve (see Figure 2.3). On the other hand, if factors other than price (i.e., tastes, income,
21
population, expectation, etc.) change, the demand changes, which is reflected by the change in
the location of the demand curve, i.e., the demand curve shifts (see Figure 2.2 below). Hence, the
determinants other than the commodity's own price are called demand shifters. The chart below
shows the reasons and consequence of the change in the quantity demanded and the change in
demand for a commodity:
Consequences
Change in Change in What happens with the demand curve?
Possible causes quantity demand
demanded
Own price Rise Decreases Downward movement along the demand curve
fall increases Upward movement along the demand curve
Price of Rise Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
substitute fall decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
Price of Rise Decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
complement fall Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
Income Increase Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
decrease decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
Population Increase Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
decrease decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
Expectation Rise Decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
about future fall Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
price
Taste Increase Increase Outward shift of the demand curve
decrease decrease Inward shift of the demand curve
Therefore, if the own price of a commodity changes, the quantity demanded changes but demand
doesn't change i.e., the demand curves doesn't shift. However, if the factors other than
commodity's own price change, the demand does change and the demand curve shifts. Since the
demand curve shifts, at any price the quantity demanded will also be different from the previous
amount. For example, if the average income of the people increases by 10%, price remaining
same, the demand for biscuits will be more than before. Table 2.2 shows the change in demand.
Table 2.2: Changes in Demand (hypothetical data)
Price Quantity demanded Quantity demanded
(Tk. per kg) (kg per week) (kg Per week)
Average household income = Average household income = Tk. 1,500
Tk. 1,000
10 100 110
15 80 90
20 60 70
30 40 60
60 20 30
22
In Column 2 of Table 2.2, the quantities of biscuits demanded at different prices are shown
(same as Table 2.1). But in Column 3, the quantity demanded for biscuits is higher than before at
each price, though the prices are the same. The reason is the increase of average income level.
People are now willing to buy more of the commodity (since biscuit is a normal good; for detail
see Lesson 3 of Unit 3) because their purchasing power is now higher than before. Graphically,
the change in demand is shown by the outward shift of the demand curve, from DD1 to DD2 in
Pt
D
D
60
50
40
Price
30
20
D2
10 D1
0 Qt
20 40 60 80 100 120
Quantity
Figure 2.2: Shift of the demand curve
Figure 2.2.
In Figure 2.2, the initial location of the demand curve was DD1. Due to the increase in income,
the demand curve has been shifted to the right, from DD1 to DD2. Conversely, due to a decrease
in average household income, the demand curve shifts to the left from the initial position. Notice
that due to change in income, people now buy more amount of biscuit at the same price. At price
of Tk. 30.00, people now buy 60 kg biscuits which is 20 kg higher than the initial purchase (40
kg).
Similarly, if any other determinant (except the commodity's own price) of demand is changed,
the demand will be changed causing the demand curve to shift. For detail please see Chart 2.1.
23
When the own price of the commodity changes, the quantity demanded of the commodity is
Pt
D
60 E
50
40
Price
30 D
20 C
10 D1
0 Qt
20 40 60 80 100
Quantity
Figure 2.3: Movement along the demand curve
changed and thus a movement along the demand curve occurs. For example, along the demand
curve DD1 in Figure 2.3, a rise in the price of biscuit produces a decrease in the quantity
demanded of biscuit and fall in the price produces an increase in the quantity demanded of
biscuit. The arrows on the demand curve represent the movements along the demand curve. Due
to the fall in the price of biscuit from Tk. 60.00 to Tk. 30.00, the quantity demanded has been
increased by 20 kg, from 20 kg to 40 kg This situation is shown by the movement from point E
to point D along the DD 1 curve. Conversely, in the case of a rise in price, the consumer moves
from point C to point D. In this case, point C is assumed to be the initial point.
Therefore, when any determinant of demand other than commodity's own price changes which
increases the quantity people plan to buy, then demand curve shifts rightward (from DD1 to DD2
in Figure 2.2) and demand increases. Conversely, if any determinant of demand other than its
own price changes that reduces the quantity people plan to buy, the demand curve shifts leftward
and demand decreases. On the other hand, if the commodity's own price changes, the quantity
demanded changes and the consumer moves from one point to another point along the same
demand curve.
Exceptions to the Law of Demand
The law of demand does not apply to the following cases:
Expectations regarding future prices. When consumers expect a continuous increase in the
price of a durable commodity, they buy more of it despite the increase in its price. They do so
with a view to avoiding the pinch of a still higher price in future. Similarly, when consumers
anticipate a considerable decrease in the price in future, they postpone their purchases and
wait for the price to fall to the expected level rather than buy the commodity when its price
initially falls. Such decisions of the consumers are contrary to the law of demand.
24
Prestigious Goods. The law does not apply to the commodities which serve as a status
symbol, enhance social prestige or display wealth and richness, e.g., gold, precious stones,
rare paintings and antiques, etc. Rich people buy such goods mainly because their prices are
high.
Giffen Goods. An exception to this law is also the classic case of Giffen Goods named after
Robert Giffen (1837-1910). A Giffen Good does not mean any specific commodity. It may
be any commodity much cheaper than its substitutes, consumed mostly by the poor
households claiming a large part of their incomes. If price of such a good increases (price of
its substitute remaining constant), its demand increases instead of decreasing. For instance,
let us suppose that the monthly minimum consumption of food grains by a poor household
includes 20 kg of wheat (an inferior good) at the rate of Tk. 10 per kg and 5 kg of flour (a
superior good) at Tk. 20.00 per kg It spends a fixed amount of Tk. 300.00 on these items.
Now, if price of wheat increases to Tk 13 per kg, the household will be forced to reduce the
consumption of flour by 3 kg and increase that of wheat by the same quantity in order to
meet its minimum monthly consumption requirement within Tk. 300.00. Obviously, the
household's demand for wheat increases from 20 to 23 kg per month despite increase in its
price.
Individual and Market Demand
In the previous sections, we have discussed the things related to the individual demand curve and
that time we have assumed just one consumer. Certainly, the choices by individuals are the basis
of the theory of demand. But the market demand is of primary interest to managers.
Fortunately, the transition from the individual to the market demand schedule is possible. Market
demand curve can easily be derived by summing the quantity demanded by each consumer at
various prices. The aggregation process is not more difficult than simple arithmetic. If there are
just three consumers in the market, it would be easy to determine the total quantities demanded
(or market demand) at each price. This is shown in Table 2.4.
Table 2.4 : Market demand for biscuit, three buyers (hypothetical data)
Quantity demanded Total quantity
Price First buyer Second buyer Third buyer Demanded/ Market demand (kg
(Tk.. per kg) (kg per week) (kg per week) (kg per week) per week)
10 30 35 35 110
15 25 25 25 75
20 15 20 20 55
30 10 15 15 40
40 5 10 10 25
If we plot the data of Table 2.4 in graph, we get the market demand curve as a horizontal summation of
the individual demand curves. Figure 2.4 shows this.
25
Pt Pt Pt Pt
Buyer 1 Buyer 2 60 Buyer 3 60 Market demand
60 60 d
d d D
40 40
Price
40 40
20 20 20 20
d2 d3 D
d1 Qt
0 0 0 0
10 20 30 40 20 40 60 80 100 110
10 20 30 40 10 20 30 40
Quantity Quantity Quantity Quantity
Figure 2.4: Market demand curve derived from the individual demand curves
In Figure 2.4, market demand curve is drawn from the individual demand curves. In the figure,
we see that at price Tk. 20.00, the demand for biscuit from buyer 1, buyer 2, and buyer 3 are 15
kg, 20 kg, and 20 kg per week, respectively. The market demand at this price is 55 kg (=15 + 20
+ 20). Similarly, we can see that at each price, the market demand for biscuit is the summation of
the quantity demanded by individual buyers at that price.
What Does Happen With the Derivation of the Market Demand Curve if More Than Three Buyers
are in the Market?
Competition, of course, entails many more than three buyers in the market. So to avoid a lengthy
aggregation process, suppose there are 100 buyers of biscuit in the market, each of whom
chooses to buy the same amount at each of the various prices as our original consumer does.
Thus we can determine total or market demand by multiplying the quantity-demanded data of
Table 2.1 by 100, as in Table 2.5. Curve DD1 in Figure 2.5 indicates this market demand curve
for the 100 buyers.
Table 2.5: Market demand for biscuits, 100 buyers (hypothetical data)
Price per kg (Tk.) Quantity demanded No. of buyers Total quantity
Pt (kg per week) in the market demanded/market
Qt demand
('000 kg per week)
10 100 100 = 10
15 80 100 =8
20 60 100 =6
30 40 100 =4
60 20 100 =2
26
Points on the DD1 curve represent the price-quantity data of Table 2.5. In the figure, we see that as the
price of biscuit falls the market demand for biscuit increases because, all the individuals are now
Pt
D
D
60 D
50
40
Price
30
D2
20
10
D1
D3 Qt
0
2 4 6 8 10 12
Quantity ('000 kg)
Figure 2.5: Market demand for biscuit, 100 buyers.
buying more biscuits than before. Lower price induced the buyers to buy more.
27
Review Questions
1. (a) What is demand? How does it differ from need, want and desire?
(b) Distinguish between demand and quantity demanded.
2. State the law of demand and show it through a demand schedule and a demand curve. what
are the exceptions to the law of demand?
3. Explain demand schedule, demand curve and demand function. Derive curve from the
demand function Q=50-10 P.
4. (a) What is implied by the downward sloping characteristic of a demand curve?
(b) Is a downward demand curve consistent with the utility-maximizing rule? Explain.
5. (a) Define an increase in demand- A decrease in demand.
(b) Illustrate each on a diagram.
6. (a) What factors are held constant when drawing a given demand curve?
(b) What happens when one or more of these factors change?
(c) How does increase in income, other factors remaining the same, affect the demand for
necessities, comforts and luxuries?
7. (a) What is market demand?
(b) What are the determinants of market demand?
8. State whether the following changes increase or decrease the current demand for new
American-made cars, and explain why. Also illustrate each on a diagram.
(a) An increase in the price of Japanese cars.
(b) A decrease in money incomes.
(c) Consumers expect lower U.S car prices in the future.
28
Lesson 2: Theory of Supply
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
define the concept of supply;
explain the law of supply;
describe supply schedule;
draw supply curve from supply schedule;
describe the relationship between individual and market supply curve;
tell the determinants of supply; and
explain the difference between quantity supplied and supply.
What is Supply?
Supply is a schedule which shows the amounts of a product a producer is willing and able to
produce and make available for sale at each price in a series of possible prices during a specified
period. The amount the firms are willing to sell (desired sales) may not be the same as the
amount they succeed in selling. Desired sales many not be equal to the actual sales.
Since desired purchases do not have to equal desired sales, different terms (quantity demanded
and quantity supplied) are needed to describe the two separate amounts. But, as the quantity
actually purchased must be the same amount as the quantity actually sold, both can be described
by a single term quantity exchanged.
29
The goals of the firm: Normally, the firm is assumed to have the single goal of profit
maximization. Firms might, however, have other goals either in addition to or as substitutes for
profit maximization. If the firm worries about risk, it will pursue safer lines of activity even
though they promise lower probable profits. If the firm values seize, it may produce and sell
more than the profit-maximizing quantities. If it worries about its image in society, it may avoid
highly profitable activities (such as the production of opium) when there is major public
disapproval. However, as long as the firm prefers more profits to less, it will respond to changes
in the possibilities of alternative lines of actions. A change in the emphasis that firms give to
other goals will change the willingness to supply the quantity at given price and hence, the level
of profitability will be changed.
Expected Future Price: Assume, the price of paddy will rise just after four months. What will
happen with the supply of paddy presently? Since paddy can be stored for couple of months and
the return from selling paddy will be higher than it is in the present, producers will offer a
smaller quantity of paddy for sale now and so the current supply of paddy decreases. Here,
producers substitute over time. Similarly, if the price of paddy is expected to fall in the future,
the return from selling it at present is high as against what is expected. So, again producers
substitute over time. They offer more paddy for sale before its price is expected to fall, so the
current supply of paddy increases.
The state of technology: Invention of new technologies that enable the producers to produce
their commodity at lower cost (use of less factors of production or cheaper factors of
production), which increases their profits at any given price of the commodity, and they increase
supply. For example, the invention of transistors and silicon chips has revolutionized production
in television, high-fidelity equipment, computers, and guidance-control systems.
Number of suppliers: Other things remaining the same, the larger the number of firms
supplying a commodity, the larger is the supply of the commodity.
Taxes and subsidies: Producers treat most taxes as costs. Therefore, an increase in sales or
property taxes will increase costs and reduce supply. On the other hand, subsidies are reverse of
taxes. If the government subsidizes the production of a good, it in effect lowers cost and
increases supply.
Let's now look at the relationship between commodity's own price and the quantity supplied.
The Relationship between Price and Quantity Supplied: Law of Supply
In the previous section, you have learnt the determinants of quantity supplied. If all other factors
remain constant, there exists a relationship between commodity's own price and quantity
supplied. This relationship is called the law of supply.
The law of supply simply states:
Others things remaining the same, the higher the price of a commodity, the higher the quantity
supplied and vice versa.
Why does the higher price lead to greater quantity supplied?
It is because of increasing opportunity cost. The opportunity cost of the commodity increases as
the quantity produced increases. So, if the price of commodity is high, only then producers are
willing to incur the higher opportunity cost and increase production.
30
Does supply always increase with the rise in price?
NO.
How can the relationship between quantity supplied and price be portrayed?
In Table 2.6, we see that as the price of biscuit increases, the quantity supplied of biscuits
increases. That is, there is a positive relationship between the quantity supplied of biscuits and its
own price.
Second method: Supply curve
The relationship between quantity supplied and price can be shown by drawing a graph. If we
plot the information given in Table 2.6 in a graph, we get the supply curve. Figure 2.6 shows a
supply curve which represents the points corresponding to price-quantity pairs of Table 2.6.
In Figure 2.6, SS is the supply curve of biscuit. Each point on the SS curve refers to the quantity
supplied of biscuit at a particular price. We see that as price of biscuit rises, the quantity supplied
of biscuit increases along the SS curve.
31
Pt
60 S
E
50
40
Price
D
30
C
20
B
A
10
S
0 QtS
20 40 60 80 100
Quantity supplied
Figure 2.6: Supply curve of biscuit
Properties of a Supply Curve
Supply curve shows the relationship between quantity supplied of a good and its own price
assuming that other things remain the same.
Normally, supply curves are upward sloping i.e., the relationship between quantity supplied
and price is direct. The law of supply shows producers’ supply more at a high price than at a
low price as is reflected in the upward slope of the supply curve.
The term supply refers to the entire relationship between price and quantity. However, a
single point on a supply curve refers to the quantity supplied at a particular price. For
example, at point C in Figure 2.6, we see that 60 kg of biscuits are supplied at a price of Tk.
20.00 per kg
The slope of the supply curve changes if the pattern of the relationship between price and
quantity supplied changes.
The position of a supply curve changes if the ceteris paribus assumption is violated, i.e., if
other things, such as price of other goods produced, prices of factors of production, the goals
of the firm, expected future price, the state of technology, number of suppliers, taxes and
subsidies, etc. change.
Distinguish between Supply and Quantity Supplied
We have seen in the previous lesson that there is a difference between the concepts demand and
quantity demanded. Similarly, to avoid confusion, we should know the difference between
supply and quantity supplied.
Supply refers to the entire relationship between quantity supplied and price while a single point
on the supply curve refers to the quantity supplied at that price.
Distinction between Change in the Quantity Supplied and Change in Supply
From the above discussion, you have learnt that quantity supplied refers to a particular point on a
supply curve, whereas supply refers to the entire relationship between price and quantity as
32
shown by the whole supply curve. Therefore, if the own price of a commodity changes (i.e.,
rises/falls), the quantity supplied of that commodity changes along the supply curve; the position
of the supply curve does not change. This is called the movement along the supply curve (see
Figure 2.8). On the other hand, if factors other than price (i.e., price of other goods produced,
prices of factors of production, the goals of the firm, expected future price, the state of
technology, number of suppliers, taxes and subsidies, etc.) change, supply changes, which is
reflected by the change in the location of the supply curve, i.e., the supply curve shifts (see
Figure 2.7 below). Hence, the determinants other than the commodity's own price are called
supply shifters. The chart below shows the reasons and consequence of the change in the quantity
supplied and the change in supply of a commodity:
Chart 2.2: Consequences of the changes in the determinants of quantity supplied
Consequences
Change Change in What happens with the supply curve?
Possible causes in supply
quantity
supplied
Own price Rise Increases Upward movement along the supply curve
Fall Decreases Downward movement along the supply curve
Price of Rise Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
substitute in Fall Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
production
Price of Rise Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
complement Fall Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
in production
Price of Rise Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
factors of Fall Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
production
Expected Increase Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
future price Decrease Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
State of New Increase Rightward shift of the demand curve
technology invention
Backward Decrease Leftward shift of the demand curve
trend
Taxes Rise Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
Fall Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
Subsidies Increase Increase Rightward shift of the supply curve
Decrease Decrease Leftward shift of the supply curve
Number of Increase Increase Rightward shift of the demand curve
suppliers Decrease decrease Leftward shift of the demand curve
Therefore, if the own price of a commodity changes, the quantity supplied changes but supply
doesn't changes, i.e., the supply curve doesn't shift. However, if the factors other than the
commodity's own price changes, then supply does change and the supply curve shifts. Since the
supply curve shifts, at any price, the quantity supplied will also be different from the previous
amount. For example, if the government initiates subsidy to biscuit production, price remaining
the same, the quantity supplied will be more than before. Table 2.7 shows the change in supply.
33
Table 2.7: Changes in supply (hypothetical data)
Price Quantity supplied Quantity supplied
(Tk. per kg) (kg per week) (kg per week)
Without subsidy With subsidy of Tk.2 per kg
10 20 40
15 40 50
20 60 70
30 80 90
60 100 110
In Column 2 of Table 2.7, the quantity of biscuits supplied at different prices is shown (same as
Table 2.6). But in Column 3, the quantity supplied of biscuits is higher than before at each price,
through the prices are the same. What's the reason? As subsidy is provided with biscuit
production, it lowers the cost of producing biscuit. As a result, bakers are now willing to produce
more biscuits because, producing biscuit is now more profitable than before. Graphically, the
change in supply is shown by the rightward shift of the supply curve, from SS1 to SS2 in Figure
Pt
S3
S1 S2
60
50
40
Price
30
20
S
10
S S
0 QtS
20 40 60 80 100 110
Quantity supplied
Figure 2.7: Shift of the supply curve
2.7. ??
In Figure 2.7, the initial location of the supply curve was SS1. Due to the initiation of subsidy to
biscuit production, the supply curve has been shifted to the right, from SS1 to SS2. Conversely,
due to the imposition of taxes, the supply curve shifts to the left from the initial position, from
SS1 to SS3. Notice that due to the initiation of subsidy, more biscuits come out in the market at
the same price. At price of Tk. 20.00, bakers now supply 70 kg biscuit which is 10 kg higher
than the initial supply (60 kg).
Similarly, if any other determinant (except the commodity's own price) of supply is changed,
then supply will be changed causing the supply curve to shift. For detail please see Chart 2.2.
34
When the own price of the commodity changes, the quantity supplied of the commodity is
changed and thus a movement along the supply curve occurs. For example, along the supply
curve SS in Figure 2.8, a rise in the price of biscuit produces an increase in the quantity supplied
of biscuit and fall in the price produces a decrease in the quantity supplied of biscuit. The arrows
Pt
S
60 E
50
Price
40
D
30
C
20
B
A
10
S
0 QtS
20 40 60 80 100
Quantity supplied
Figure 2.8: Movement along the supply curve
on the supply curve represent the movements along the supply curve. Due to the fall in the price
of biscuit from Tk. 60.00 to Tk. 30.00, the quantity supplied has been decreased by 20 kg, from
100 kg to 80 kg This has been shown by the movement from Point E to Point D along the SS
curve. Conversely, in the case of rise in price, the producer moves from Point C to Point D. In
this case, Point C is assumed to be the initial point. Therefore, when any determinant of supply
other than commodity's own price changes which increases the quantity supplied, then supply
curve shifts rightward (from SS1 to SS2 in Figure 2.7) and supply increases. Conversely, if any
determinant of supply other than its own price changes that reduces the quantity people plan to
buy, the supply curve shifts leftward and supply decreases. On the other hand, if the commodity's
own price changes, the quantity supplied changes and the consumer moves from one point to
another point along the same supply curve.
Market Supply
By adding up the quantity each supplier is willing and able to offer at every price, we can get the
market supply. In brief, the market supply is just the summary of the supply intention of all
producers. Assume that there are 100 sellers in the market having the same supply schedules. So,
the market supply schedule can be found as in Table 2.8.
35
Table 2.8: Market supply of biscuit, 100 sellers (hypothetical data)
Price per kg Quantity supplied Number of sellers Total quantity
(Tk.) (kg per week) In the market supplied/market supply
Pt QtS ('000 kg per week)
10 20 100 =2
15 40 100 =4
20 60 100 =6
30 80 100 =8
60 100 100 = 10
In Figure 2.9, SS1 is the market supply of biscuit. As the price of biscuit increases, the supply of biscuit
Pt S3
S1 S2
60
50
40
Price
30
20
S
10
S S
0 QtS
2 4 6 8 10 12
Quantity supplied ('000 kg)
Figure 2.9: Market supply of biscuit, 100 sellers.
in the market increases because all the bakers are now producing more biscuits than before.
Lower price induces the buyers to buy more.
Let's now know the determinants of market supply.
Determinants of Market Supply
The basic determinants of market supply are as:
Review Questions
1. (a) What is supply?
(b) Distinguish between supply and quantity supplied.
(c) What are the determinants of supply?
3. Explain supply schedule, supply curve and supply function. Derive the supply curve from
the supply function Q=30 + 5P.
4. (a) What factors are held constant when drawing a given supply curve?
(b) What happens when one or more of these factors change?
37
Lesson 3: Price Determination: Equilibrium of Demand and Supply
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
explain the process of price determination in a market;
explain the concepts of equilibrium and disequilibrium in market; and
describe the difference among equilibrium price, demand price and supply price.
Introduction
In last two lessons, demand and supply have been considered separately. You learnt from the
previous lessons how demand and supply respond to the change in price and other determinants.
Moreover, you learnt that demand schedule/curve shows the quantities people desire and are able
to buy at different prices. But one question was not solved. Can the consumers always buy the
quantity exactly they desire at any price? The answer is 'No'. Then why do they fail to meet their
desire, i.e., what makes the difference between desired and actual purchase?
Similarly, the supply schedule/curve shows the quantity of goods producers desire and able to
supply at different prices. But the question arises: can the producers always sell the amount
exactly they desire to sell? The answer is again 'No'. So, why do they fail to meet their desire,
e.g., what makes the difference between desired and actual sale?
So, in the case of demand as well as supply, the desired quantity is not always identical to the
actual quantity. The reason is: the amount of goods people want to buy at a given price, the
suppliers do not want to supply exactly that amount at the same price; in other words, the amount
of goods the suppliers desire to supply at a given price is not the same as the amount the
consumers are interested to buy at that price.
But what is the price at which the desired and actual quantities become identical, i.e., at what
price the suppliers will supply exactly the same amount of goods that the consumers desire to
buy - no goods will remain unsold? There will be no excess demand or excess supply in the
market. In this lesson, we will discuss how and when this golden situation comes.
Price Determination
In a free market, where no outside forces other than commodity's own price are considered to
influence supply decisions and buying decisions, adjustments in price coordinate the devices of
buyers and sellers. Here price is treated as a regulator. The price of a good regulates the
quantities demanded and supplied. If the price is too high, the quantity supplied exceeds the
quantity demanded. If the price is too low, the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied.
There is one price, and only one price, at which the quantity demanded equals the quantity
supplied - that price is called equilibrium price (or market price).
38
What is "Equilibrium"?
Equilibrium is a situation in which the opposing forces are in balance. So, equilibrium in market
occurs when the price is such that the opposing forces of the plans of buyers and sellers balance
each other, e.g., in equilibrium situation, the price is such that the quantity demanded equals
quantity supplied where there is no surplus or shortage. So, the equilibrium price is called the
market-clearing price.
Now, let's see graphically, how the market-clearing price or equilibrium price is established.
Figure 2.10 shows the equilibrium that occurs at the intersection of market demand and market
supply curves. In the figure, Point E is the equilibrium point. The equilibrium price is Tk. 20.00
and the equilibrium quantity is 6,000 kg of biscuits.
Pt
D
60
S1
50
40
Price
Surplus
30
E
20
10 S D1
Shortage
0 QtD,QtS
2 4 6 8 10
Quantity ('000 kg)
Figure 2.10: Equilibrium in market
At point E, the market demand curve intersects market supply curve. Hence, there is no surplus
or shortage at this point. At any price level other than Tk. 20.00, the market is in disequilibrium.
We see that at the price of Tk. 30.00, market supply of biscuit exceeds market demand by 4,000
kg - there is an excess supply or surplus in the market. Similarly, at price of Tk. 10.00, market
demand for biscuit exceeds market supply by 4,000 kg- there is an excess demand or shortage in
the market. But the disequilibrium situations are not long-lived. They disappear through market
mechanism. In the case of excess demand, the producers want to supply less than the buyers'
desire. The tendency for buyers to offer, and sellers to ask for, higher prices crates upward
pressure on price. Price rises till the equilibrium occurs again.
Similarly, in the case of excess supply in market, e.g., the producers wants to supply more than
the consumers' or buyers' desire, the tendency for buyers to offer, and sellers to ask for, lower
prices creates a downward pressure on price. Price falls till the equilibrium occurs again. Table
2.9 below summarizes these events:
39
Table 2.9: Equilibrium in the market
Quantity supplied Quantity
Price ('000 kg Per week) demanded
( Tk. per kg) QtS ('000 kg Per
week)
QtD
10 2 Excess demand/market 10
shortage (QtS< QtD)
15 4 8
20 6 Equilibrium(QtS = QtD) 6
30 8 Excess supply/market 4
surplus (QtS > QtD)
60 10 2
Pt
D
D
60
S1
50
Price (Tk. Per kg)
40
E2
30
E1
20 D2
10
S D1
0 QtD,QtS
2 4 6 8 10
Quantity ('000 kg)
Figure 2.11: The effects of a change in Demand
40
change in demand on the equilibrium price and quantity. The figure shows that the original
equilibrium price is Tk. 20.00 per kg of biscuit, and the quantity is 6,000 kg biscuit a week.
When demand increases, the demand curve shifts rightwards, from DD1 to DD2 in Figure 2.11.
The equilibrium price rises to Tk.30.00 a kg of biscuit and the equilibrium quantity increases to
8,000 kg of biscuit, which corresponds to the new equilibrium Point E2. The effects will be
reverse if demand decreases, i.e., the demand curve shifts leftward.
On the other hand, if the supply curve shifts rightward, then equilibrium price of the commodity
decreases and the equilibrium quantity increases as in Figure 2.12. The effect will be reverse if
the supply curve shifts leftward.
Pt
D
60 S1
50 S2
40
Price
30
E1
20 E2
10 S D1
S
0 QtD,QtS
2 4 6 8 10
Quantity ('000 kg)
Figure 2.12: Effect of a change in supply on equilibrium position
In Figure 2.12, we see that due to the rightward shift of the supply curve, new equilibrium
position has been established at Point E2. At E 2, the price of the commodity is lower and the
quantity exchanged is higher than those at the initial equilibrium point E1.
In the cases described by Figure 2.11 and Figure 2.12, only demand curve or supply curve was
assumed to be shifted. There we haven't explained the case where both supply and demand
curves shift simultaneously.
41
What Will Happen If Both Demand Curve and Supply Curve Shift?
If they shift in the same direction and same extent, the equilibrium price will not be changed, but
the equilibrium quantity will be changed as in Panel A of Figure 2.13.
Pt Panel A
Pt
60 D 60 Panel B
D D D
50 S1 50 S1
S2
40 40
S2
Price
30 30
E1 E2 E1 E2
20 D2 20
D2
10 S D1 10 S
D1
S S
0 0 QtD,QtS
2 4 6 8 10 2 4 6 8 10
Quantity ('000 kg) Quantity ('000 kg)
Figure 2.13: Effect of a change in both supply and demand
In Figure 2.13, we see that the supply curve has been shifted rightward from SS1 to SS2 and at
the same time, the demand curve has been shifted outward from DD1 to DD2. The extent of
change in both demand and supply is the same. We see that at the new equilibrium point E 2, the
equilibrium price is the same as that at the initial equilibrium Point E1, but the quantity
exchanged has been increased. If the extent of change in both demand and supply is not the
same, both equilibrium price and quantity exchanged are changed. Panel B of Figure 2.13 shows
that.
Similarly, we can see what happens to the equilibrium price and quantity when supply and
demand change in opposite directions.
42
Review Questions
1. (a) Define equilibrium price.
(b) If actual price is above the equilibrium, what will force it down?
(c) If actual price is below the equilibrium, what will force it up?
2. (a) Plot the corresponding demand and supply curves from the figures below, showing
equilibrium price and quantity.
Price Quantity Quantity Supplied
Demanded
$100 10 50
80 20 40
60 30 30
40 40 20
20 50 10
(b) If price was $100, would there be a surplus or a shortage? How much?
(c) If price was $20, would there be a surplus or a shortage? How much?
3. State how the stipulated changes in each of the following demand shifters would change
the equilibrium price and quantity of new US cars? Assume all other shifters remain
constant except the one under consideration:
(a) An increase in money income of the car-buying public. Assume new cars are a
superior good.
(b) A decrease in the price of foreign cars, a substitute for US cars.
(c) Consumers expect less unemployment in the near future.
(d) Consumers tastes shift in the direction of European styling.
(e) Population increases.
4. State how the stipulated changes in the following supply shifters change the equilibrium
price and quantities of personal computers. Assume all other shifters remain constant
except the one under consideration:
(a) A decrease in the price of typewriters - an alternative product that can be produced.
(b) A decrease in the price of silicon chips.
(c) Producers expect prices to be lower next year.
(d) Advances are made in electronics technology.
(e) There is a decrease in the number of manufacturers of this product.
5. (a) Is it possible for the equilibrium price of a good or service to change Without a change
in the equilibrium quantity exchanged in the market? Explain.
(b) Is it possible for the equilibrium quantity of a good or service to changes without a
change in the equilibrium market price? Explain.
43
Unit 3: ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND
Highlights
Price Elasticity of Demand;
Point and Arc Elasticity;
Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand;
Income Elasticity of Demand;
Determinants of Income Elasticity of Demand;
Cross Elasticity of Demand and Its Determinants;
What Is Elasticity?
Elasticity is the ratio which measures the responsiveness or sensitiveness of a dependent variable
to the changes in any of the independent variables. Specifically, the term elasticity refers to the
percentage change in dependent variable divided by the percentage change in independent
variable. That is,
Percentage change in Y % Y % Y % Y
Elasticity of Y .......... ....
Percentage change in X %X 1 % X 2 % X n
or we can calculate the elasticity of Y with respect to each of the X's, which is called partial
Percentage change in Y % Y
Elasticity of Y with respect to X 1
Percentage change in X 1 % X 1
elasticity, as follows:
Now let's think about the elasticity of demand.
Elasticity of Demand
Percentage change in Y % Y
Elasticity of Y with respect to X 2
Percentage change in X 2 % X 2
Percentage change in Y % Y
Elasticity of Y with respect to X n
Percentage change in X n % X n
The elasticity of demand is the measure of responsiveness of demand for a commodity to the
changes in any of its determinants. We studied in the previous lessons that the determinants of
Q XD f ( P X , M , P y , Pz , etc. )
demand are the commodity's own price, income, price of related goods (substitutes and
complements), and consumers expectations regarding future price, i.e.,
Here, QXD = Quantity demanded of commodity X
PX = Price of commodity X
M = Money income of the consumer
PY = Price of the substitute, X and Y are substitutes to each other
PZ = Price of the complement, X and Z are complements to each other
Therefore, we can calculate the elasticity of demand with respect to each of the determinants.
When we calculate the responsiveness of demand to the change in commodity's own price, then
we call it price elasticity of demand. If we calculate the elasticity of demand with respect to the
change in consumer's money income, we call it income elasticity of demand. If we calculate the
elasticity of demand with respect to the change in the price of any related goods (substitutes or
complements), we call it cross elasticity of demand.
Now let's start with price elasticity of demand.
Price Elasticity of Demand
If the price of a commodity changes, then do consumers change their attitude in buying that
commodity?
The answer may be one of the following three:
45
They do not change their attitude;
They slightly change their attitude;
They change their attitude drastically.
How much consumers respond to the price changes are measured by price elasticity of demand.
In other words, the response of consumers to a change in price is measured by the price elasticity
of demand. Specifically, the price elasticity of demand refers to the percentage change in
quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in price. That is, the price elasticity of
and % QD
X = QOX 100, where Q OX = Original Quantity
QX
Q X / Q OX Q X PXO
E PD .
PX / PXO PX Q XO
As we know from the demand law that one of the changes (QX or Px ) in the elasticity formula
will be negative. As a result, the sign of the elasticity coefficient will be negative. For
convenience, we ignore the sign of the elasticity formula.
At the moment, some questions may arise in your mind:
(a) Why are percentages used rather than absolute amounts in measuring consumer
responsiveness?
The answer is two- fold:
If we use absolute changes, our impression of buyer responsiveness will be arbitrarily
affected by the choice of units. For example, the price of product X falls from Tk. 5 to Tk. 3,
and consumers increase their purchases from 70 to 100 kg, it appears that consumers are
quite sensitive to price changes, and, therefore, that demand is elastic. After all, a price
change of 'two' has caused a change in the amount demanded of 'thirty'. But by charging the
monetary unit from taka to paisa, we find a price change of 'two hundred' causes a quantity
46
change of 'forty', giving the impression of inelasticity. Using percentage changes avoids this
problem. The given price decline is 33 per cent whether measured in term of taka (Tk. 2 / Tk.
5) or paisa (200 p / 500 p). Therefore, elasticity is a unit-free measure.
The other reason for using percentage is that we can more meaningfully compare consumer
responsiveness to changes in the prices of different products. It makes little sense to compare
the effects on quantity demanded of a Tk. 1 increase in the price of a Tk. 10,000 washing
machine with a Tk. 1 increase in the price of a Tk. 1 shaving blade. Here the price of washing
machine is rising by .0001 per cent while the blade price is up by 100 per cent! If the price of
both products were increased by 1 percent - Tk. 100 for the washing machine and 1 p for the
blade - we would obtain a sensible comparison of consumer sensitivity to the price changes.
(b) Why should we ignore the 'minus sign' in the price elasticity of demand formula?
We know from the downward sloping demand curve that price and quantity demanded are
inversely related (demand law). This means that the price elasticity coefficient of demand will
always yield a negative number. For example, if price declines, then quantity demanded will
increase. This means that the numerator in our formula positive and denominator negative,
yielding a negative coefficient. Conversely, for an increase in price, the coefficient will also be
negative.
This negative sign is usually ignored and it is simply presented the absolute value of the
elasticity coefficient to avoid an ambiguity which might otherwise arise. It can be confusing to
say that an elasticity coefficient of '- 4' is greater than one of '- 2', this possible confusion is
avoided when we say a coefficient of 4 indicates greater elasticity than one of 2. Hence, we
ignore the minus sign in the coefficient of price elasticity of demand and merely show the
absolute value. However, the noted ambiguity does not arise with supply because price and
quantity are positively related.
(b) Does elasticity coefficient give the same message as the slope of demand curve gives?
Elasticity coefficient certainly does not give the same message as that of the slope of demand
curve. Slope depends on the units in which we measure the price and quantities. This is why, if
we want to compare two demand curves, we can't do that simply by their slopes. Also, we often
need to compare the demand curves for different goods and services. For example, when
deciding by how much to change the tax rates, the government needs to compare the demand for
oil and the demand for tobacco. Which is more responsive to price? Which can be taxed at an
even higher rate without decreasing the tax revenue? Comparing the slope of the demand curve
for oil with the slope of the demand curve for tobacco has no meaning because oil is measured in
gallons and tobacco in pounds- completely unrelated units.
In this case, for meaningful comparison, we should have a measure of responsiveness that is
independent of the units of measurement of prices and quantities. Elasticity is such a measure.
On the other hand, at every point on a straight line demand curve, the slope is the same. But the
elasticity coefficient varies from one point to another point on the straight line demand curve.
(d) Is elasticity of demand the ratio of percentage changes or proportionate changes?
Elasticity is the ratio of the percentage change in the quantity demanded to the percentage
change in the price. It is also, equivalently, the proportionate change in the quantity demanded by
the proportionate change in the price. This can be shown as follows:
47
Percentage change in quantity demanded = %Q Q 100
Q
Q
Q Proportion ate change in quantity demanded
P Proportion ate change in price
P
Therefore, elasticity is the ratio of percentage changes, which ultimately stands as a ratio of proportionate
changes after the cancellation of the 100s.
48
Arc Elasticity
The formula used to computing arc elasticity is,
Q X / Q OX
Q X PXO
EP .
PX / PXO PX Q OX
Graphically, arc elasticity is the measure of elasticity of demand between two finite points on a
demand curve. For example, in Figure 3.1, the measure of elasticity between points A and B is
arc elasticity.
Let's assume that the original price and quantity (at Point A) are Tk. 30 and 20 units,
PX
40 D
30
A
Price
10
B
D
0 QX
20 40 60 80 100
Quantity
Figure 3.1: Arc elasticity
respectively. If we move from Point A to B along the demand curve DD, price will fall and
consequently, the quantity demanded will be increased. That is:
Px = 30 - 10 = 20
Qx = 20 - 70 = - 50
Therefore, the elasticity between Point A and B (moving from A to B) will be as follows:
o
E P D Qx . Pxo
Px Qx
50 30
3.75
20 20
49
The elastically coefficient 3.75 indicates that as a result of a 1 percent decrease in the price of X
the demand for the commodity X is increased by 3.75 per cent.
We have seen that the elasticity coefficient 3.75 indicates the elasticity of the portion of the
demand curve between Points A and B. Is this result true for either direction or change in price?
That means, will we get the same elasticity coefficient (3.75) if we start from Point B to A on the
demand curve? Let's check it.
Original price and quantity at Point B are Pxo = 10 and Q ox = 80, respectively.
Px = 30 - 10 = 20, Qx = 20 - 70 = -50
Now, putting the values into the elasticity formula, we get elasticity between Point B and A as:
o
Q x Px
E P D . o
Px Q x
-50 10
.
= 20 70
5
.35
= 14
Therefore, the elasticity coefficient computed for the same portion of the demanded curve varies
in respect to the direction of the change in price, which indicates a serious problem with
computation of the elasticity coefficient using the above formula.
To resolve this problem, economists suggested some modifications in the elasticity formula:
Using lower values of price and quantity demanded: By using lower values of price and
quantity demanded instead of their original values ( Pxo , Q ox ) the problem arising due to the
change in the direction of price change may be avoided. The formula will be:
PX PXl
E PD .......... .......... .......... ..1
Q X Q lX
Where l denotes lower value.
1
From our example, for measuring elasticity between Points A and B in Figure 3.1, we find Px
1
=10 (lower one of the two prices), QX = 20 (the lower one of the two quantities), Px = 20, Qx =
50.
By substituting these values in Equation (1), we get:
50 10
E PD 1.25
20 20
This method, however, violates the rule of computing percentage change, because, the choice of
the lower values of P and Q is arbitrary. Thus this method is devoid of any logic.
50
Using average value of price and quantity: In this method, the average of the upper and lower
values of P and Q are used. The formula then stands as:
Qx . Px Px / 2
u l
EP
Px Qlx Qux / 2
Q x P xave
. ave
Px Qx
u l
x x x
Q . Pl Pu
Px Qx Qx …………………………(2)
Where u, l are upper and lower values, respectively. 2's are cancelled by each other. 'Ave' means
'average'.
Putting the values from our example of Figure 3.1 into Equation 2 we get:
50 30 10 50.40 10
E PD 1.11
20 20 70 20.90 9
This method measures the elasticity at the mid-point of the chord that connects the Points A and
B on the demand curve defined by the initial and new price levels (Figure 3.1).
The elasticity coefficient just computed (1.11) is not true for the whole range of price-quantity
combinations between Points A and B (see Figure 3.1). It does not resolve the problem that
arises due to the change in the direction of the price. It gives only the mean of the elasticities
between the two points.
However, this method is widely used, conventionally, to calculate arc elasticity.
It should be clear that this measure of the arc elasticity is an approximation of the true elasticity
of the section AB of the demand curve, which is used when we know only the two Points A and
B from the demand curve, but not the intermediate ones. Clearly the more convex to the origin
the demand curve, the poorer the linear approximation attained by the arc elasticity formula.
Point Elasticity
If the changes in price are infinitesimally small, we use the point elasticity of demand as a
measure of the responsiveness of demand. The point elasticity of demand is defined as the
percentage change in the quantity demanded resulting from an infinitesimally small change in
prices. Symbolically, we may write the formula of point elasticity as follows:
dQ x dPx
Ep
Qx Px
dQ x Px
. ........................... (3)
dPx Q x
51
In this formula, the first part, dQ x is reciprocal of the slope of the demand curve. So, the slope is
dPx
the part of the elasticity formula. But it is not the only part : The ratio Px/Qx is invalid as well.
Example: Suppose, a linear demand curve is:
Qx = b0 - b1 Px
By differentiating we get,
dQ x
b 1 . Substituting this value into the elasticity formula (Equation-3), we obtain:
dPx
Ep = b1 . Px
Qx
This implies that the elasticity changes at the various points of the linear demand curve (why?).
In this case, since the changes are very small, the directions of price changes do not affect the
elasticity coefficient. If we calculate elasticity considering either direction of price changes, the
result will be almost the same.
Graphically, the point elasticity of a linear demand curve is shown by the ratio of the segments of
the line to the right and to the left of the particular point. That means:
Right or lower part of the particular point
Ep = ------------------------------------------------------
Left or upper part of the particular point
For example, in Figure 3.2, the elasticity of the linear demand curve DD' at Point F is the ratio
FD'
FD
PX
D
Price
P1 F
P2 F'
E
D'
0 QX
Q1 Q2
Quantity
Figure 3.2: Point elasticity
52
Proof :
From Figure 3.2 we see that
P = P1P2 =EF
Q = Q1Q2 =EF'
If changes in P and Q are considered as infinitesimally small, then P dP and Q dQ.
Thus, substituting in the formula for the point elasticity, we obtain:
E F Q1 D Q1 D
EF FQ1 OP1
Q1 D OP1 Q1 D
EP
OP1 OQ1 OQ1
From the figure, we can also see that the triangles FEF' and FQ1D' are similar (because each
corresponding angle is equal). Hence, ??
Thus??
Q1 D P1 F OQ1
OP1 FD FD
Q1 D F D
OQ1 FD
Q D FD
EP 1
OQ1 FD
coefficients at different points on a demand curve. Let's first deal with the linear demand curve.
53
Point elasticities of a linear demand curve: See the Figure 3.3. DD' is a straight-line or linear
demand curve.
PX
D EP
EP>1
Price
EP=1
M
EP<1
0
EP 0 QX
D'
Quantity
Figure 3.3: Point elasticities at point on a straight line
At mid-point, M, of the demand curve the EP = 1. At any point right of M the EP < 1 and at any
point left of M the EP >1. At Point D the EP , while at Point D' the EP0. So, the range of
values of the elasticity are: 0 EP . Let's now know the explanation of different elasticity
coefficients and about the shape of the corresponding demand curves presented as below:
54
PX PX PX
D
Price
Price
Price
D
0 QX 0 EP = 1 0 EP =
EP = 0
Quantity Quantity Quantity
Point elasticities of a non-linear demand curve: The elasticity at a point (say A) on a non-
linear demand curve can be computed in the following way:
Firstly, draw a tangent to the demand curve at Point A.
Secondly, divide the segment of the tangent to the right of A by the segment to the left of A.
Then you will get the elasticity coefficient of the demand curve at Point A.
This is shown in Figure 3.7.
PX
B
Price
A
0 QX
C
Quantity
Figure 3.7: Point elasticity of a non-linear demand curve
At Point A the EP = AC/ AB. Similarly, we can find the elasticity at any other point on the demand curve.
55
Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
What factors make demand for a commodity more elastic or less elastic? Why are people price-
sensitive (e > 1) with some goods and not (e < 1) with others? To find answers to these
questions, we have to go back to the demand curve itself. The elasticity of demand is computed
between points on a given demand curve. Hence, the price elasticity of demanded is influenced
by all the determinants of demand. Anyway, there are no iron-clad generalizations concerning
determinants of the elasticity of demand. The following factors, however, are worth noting:
Nature of the Goods (Luxuries versus Necessities): Necessities, such as food stuffs are price
inelastic, meaning they are not very responsive to change in prices. For example, the quantity of
rice demanded does not decline much when the price of rice rises. This happens because people
do not reduce their consumption of rice even if the price is very high. People cannot live without
rice. Therefore, rise in price cannot influence the demand for necessities very much.
In contrast, any luxury goods, such as air conditioner, decoration item, etc. are price elastic,
meaning they are very responsive to changes in prices. People can postpone the consumption of
luxury goods when their prices rise.
Availability of Close Substitutes: This is a critical determinant of price elasticity of demand. If
consumers can easily get a good substitute Y for a product X, they will switch readily to Y if the
price of X rises. Thus the closer the substitutes for X that are available, the more elastic its
demand will be. For example, the demand for a particular brand of toothpaste is quite elastic;
because another brand will work just as well. If the price of Close-Up toothpaste rises, people
will switch readily to any other brands such as Pepsodent, Colgate, etc. Here an important thing
should be remembered that availability of close substitutes depend on how narrowly or broadly
the commodity is defined. If we define a commodity narrowly (such as Close-Up toothpaste),
many substitutes are available for that commodity. So, the elasticity of demand for that
commodity is high. On the other hand, if the commodity is broadly defined (such as toothpaste),
as not many substitutes for that commodity are available and thus the elasticity of the demand for
that commodity is low. Similarly, the elasticity of demand for meat in general is low, but the
elasticity of demand for beef, lamb, or chicken is high. The elasticity of demand for personal
computers is low, but the elasticity of demand for a Compaq, Dell, Intel or IBM is high.
Therefore, the demand for narrowly defined commodity is more elastic than the demand for
more broadly defined commodities.
Fraction of the Income Absorbed: Other things remaining the same, the higher the proportion of
income spent on a good, the more elastic the demand for it. If only a small fraction of income is
spent on a good, then a change in its price has little impact on the consumer's overall budget. In
contrast, even a small rise in the price of a good that commands a large part of a consumer's
budget induces the consumer to make a radical reappraisal of expenditures.
For example, think about the elasticity of demand for textbooks and chewing gum. If price of
textbooks doubles (rises by 100%), there will be a big decrease in the quantity of textbooks
bought. Thus, students will share and photocopy the textbook instead of buying new ones. If the
price of chewing gum doubles, also a 100% increase, there will be no change in the quantity of
gum demanded. Why is the difference? It is because, textbooks take a large portion of the budget
while gum takes only a tiny portion.
56
Evidence (1989) shows that in Tanzania, a poor African nation where average income is 3.3% of
that in the United States and where 62% of income is spent on food, the price elasticity of
demand for food is 0.77. In contrast, in the United States, where 12 percent of income is spent on
food, the elasticity of demand for food is 0.12.
Time: The demand for many products is more elastic in the long-run than in the short-run. When
the price of a product rises, it takes time to find and experiment with other products to see if they
are acceptable. Consumers may not immediately reduce their purchases very much when the
price of chicken rises by 10 percent, but in time they may shift to beef or fish. Therefore, since
consumers do not reduce the demand for a commodity (for example, chicken) immediately after
the rise in its price, the demand for that commodity is inelastic in the short-run. But if the price
of chicken remains high for a long time, then consumers switch to any convenient (or less costly)
substitutes for chicken (for example, beef, fish, etc.), which makes the demand for chicken
elastic in the long-run.
Alternative uses of a commodity: The more the alternative uses of a commodity the highly elastic
is the demand for it. For example, if the price of milk falls, the demand for milk will increase
more than the proportionate fall in its price, because milk can be used in different purposes such
as in making curds, ghees, butter, sweets, etc. Therefore, the demand for milk is highly elastic.
57
decrease in price results in an increase in total revenue, the demand is elastic- this can be named
as total revenue test.
By employing this test, we can most easily infer whether demand is elastic or inelastic. In this
test, we have to observe what happens to total revenue, total expenditures from the buyer's view
point when the product price changes.
Income Elasticity of Demand
We know from Lesson 1 of Unit 2 about the impact of income changes on demand for a good.
Now we will know how the demand for a particular good change as income grows? The answer
depends on the income elasticity of demand for the good. The income elasticity of demand is a
measure of the responsiveness of demand to a change in income, other things remaining the
same. It is calculated by using the following formula:
As price elasticity, income elasticity can be expressed in either arc or point terms. Arc income
elasticity is used when relatively long changes in income are considered and is defined as:
av e
Q X Y
E Y . av e
Y Q X
Where Y = Y0 - Y1
QX = YX 0 - YX
QX Y'Y''
EY . ' ''
Y QX QX
Q'X Q''X
Qave
X
2
' ''
ave Y Y
Y
2
Q' = Initial quantity
Q" = Changed quantity
Y' = Initial income
Y" = Changed income
On the other hand, if the change in income is small or if income elasticity at a particular income
level is to be determined, a point elasticity is appropriate.
In this case,
Q X dQ X
Lim Y 0
Y dY
58
So, the income elasticity formula stands as follows:
dQX . Y
EY
dY QX
Nature of the Commodity and Income Elasticity
Income elasticity of demand can be positive or negative and falls into the following interesting
ranges:
Positive
Income Income Income
elastic inelastic elasticity
Quantity demanded
Negative
Income
elasticity
0
0 0 m
Income Income Income
(a) EY >1 (c) EY <0
(b) 0<EY<1
The three cases cited above can be illustrated by diagrams. Figure 3.11 does it.
59
Part (a) shows an income elasticity that is greater than 1, i.e., as income increases, quantity
demanded increases, but the quantity demanded increases faster than income.
Part (b) shows an income elasticity of demand that is between zero and 1. In this case, the
quantity demanded increases as income increases, but income increases faster than the quantity
demanded.
Part (c) shows an income elasticity of demand that eventually becomes negative. In this case, the
quantity demanded increases as income increases until it reaches a maximum at income m. After
that point, as income continues to increase, the quantity demanded declines. Up to the income m,
the income elasticity of demand is positive but less than 1. After income m, the income elasticity
of demand is negative.
The low-income people normally buys bicycles, potatoes, and rice. Up to a level of income, they
increase buying of these commodities as income increases. But as income goes above the Point
m, consumers replace these goods with superior alternatives. For example, a motorcycle replaces
bicycle; fruit, vegetables, and meat begin to appear in a diet that was heavy in rice or potato.
Engel's Law
Ernst Engel, a German statistician, proposed this law in the nineteenth century.
60
Main theme of the Law: The percentage of income spent on food decreases as incomes
increases, i.e., the income elasticity of demand for food is less than unity and greater than zero
(0<EY < 1).
To conclude this expenditure pattern, Engel studied the consumption patterns of a large number
of households. Later, many other researchers have been confirmed his findings repeatedly.
Implication of Engel's Law: During the period of economic prosperity, farmers may not
prosper as much as people in other occupations. The reason is that if expenditures on food do not
keep pace with increase in gross domestic product, farm incomes may not increase as rapidly as
incomes in general. However, this tendency has partially offset by the rapid increase in farm
productivity in the recent years.
61
Review Questions
1. (a) Explain the following concepts separately
(i) Price-elasticity of demand
(ii) Income-elasticity of demand
(iii) Price-elasticity of supply
(iv) Cross elasticity of demand
(b) What are the uses of these concepts of elasticity in the analysis of the market.
2. (a) Explain the concepts of arc and point elasticity of a demand curve for a commodity.
(b) What is the problem in using the arc elasticity? How can this problem be resolved?
3. Explain the concept of price elasticity of demand and the relationship between price
elasticity, average revenue and marginal revenue.
(ii) Prove that in the case of two straight line demand curves, with the same point of origin
on the price axis, at any given point, elasticity is the same in spite of their different
slopes.
(b) If two straight line demand curves intersect each other, which of them will have higher
elasticity of demand at point of intersection?
Price 100 80 60 40 20 0
(Tk.)
62
Unit 4: CONSUMER BEHAVIOR
Highlights
Definition of Utility
Different Approaches to the Measurement of Utility
Total and Marginal Utility
Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility
Indifference Curves and Budget Line
Theory of Revealed Preference
Technologies Used for Content Delivery
BOUTUBE
BOULMS
WebTV
Web Radio
Mobile Technology with Micro SD Card
LP+Office365
BTV Program
Bangladesh Betar Program
Lesson 1: Introduction
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
understand consumer behavior ;
define the concept of utility; and
say about the measurability of utility.
Introduction
We discussed the concept of demand and the law of demand in the previous unit. There we saw
that demand has an important effect on the price of a good. But we didn't analyze what exactly
shapes a person's demand? In this unit, we will examine the household or consumer behavior and
its influence on demand. In this regard, we will try to find the answers to the following
questions: How does a consumer decide how much of the commodity she/he should buy at a
given price? Why she/he buys more of some commodities when their prices fall? Why she/he
doesn't change his consumption of some items even if their prices go up? Why the prices of some
items are so out of proportion to their total benefits? Lesson 1 of this unit will discuss some
important concepts used in the analysis of consumer behavior, Lesson 2, and Lesson 3 will
discuss Cardinalist approach and Ordinalist approaches to consumer behavior, respectively. Let's
take the lessons sequentially.
63
The Consumer
Commonly, we think that a consumer is one who consumes or uses a commodity. Here, it doesn't
matter whether the consumer is a qualified or an unqualified person. However, in Economics, the
term consumer refers to a person or entity with the following qualifications:
Rational behavior: The consumer is a rational being. She/he tries to spend her/his money income
so as to derive the greatest amount of satisfaction, or utility, from it. Consumers want to
maximize the total utility.
Clear-cut preferences: The consumer has rather clear-cut preferences for different goods and
services that are available in the market. She/he can guess about the utility she/he will get from
the consumption of the additional units of various products what might purchase.
Budget constraint: The consumer has limited money income. Because, a consumer supplies
limited amounts of human and property resources to businesses, the money income received will
be limited.
Perfect competition: Perfect competition exists on the demand and supply side of the market, i.e.,
the product prices are not affected by the amount of specific goods which the individual
consumer buys.
Ordinalist approach:
-indifference-curves approach
utility
The Cadinalist School held the views that utility can be measured. But how can it be measured?
What units can it be measured in? Various suggestions have been made for the measurement of
the utility. Some economists have suggested that utility can be measured in monetary units while
others suggested the measurement of utility in subjective units, called utils.
On the contrary, the Ordinalist School postulated that utility is not measurable, but is an ordinal
magnitude. The consumer need not know the units of utility she/he gets from the commodities to
make her/his choice. It is sufficient for him if he is able to rank the various baskets of goods
according to the satisfaction that each bundle gives him.
65
In this lesson, we are not going to discuss the approaches to the analysis of consumer behavior,
i.e., the Cardinalist approach and the Ordinalist approach, in detail. We will thoroughly examine
them in the following lessons.
Review Questions
1. What is meant by the term 'consumer'? Write down the characteristics of a consumer.
2. What is utility? Is it measurable? Describe different approaches to the measurement of utility.
Introduction
Classical and neo-classical economists including Gossen (1854) of Germany, William Stanly
Jevons (1871) of England, Leon Walras (1874) of France and Karl Menger of Austria held views
that utility is quantitatively or cardinally measurable entity. It can be measured like any other
entities, such as temperature, height, weight, and length. But what exactly is utility and in what
units can we measure it? Starting with the answer to this question, this lesson will discuss the
different concepts of utility, such as marginal utility, total utility, and the concept of consumer
surplus.
How Can We Measure Utility?
Utility is an abstract concept. It cannot be observed or touched anyway. That's why, the
measuring units of this entity are arbitrary. Just like temperature, utility can be measured in
arbitrary units. Let's know how temperature is measured, that will help us understand how the
measurability of utility in arbitrary units is justifiable:
Temperature is an abstract concept. We cannot observe it - only we can feel it. However, we can
observe water turning to steam if it is hot enough or turning to ice if it is cold enough. And we
can construct an instrument, called thermometer, that can help us predict when such changes will
occur. The scale on the thermometer is what we call temperature. But the units in which we
measure temperature are arbitrary. For example, we can accurately predict that when a Celsius
thermometer shows a temperature of 0, water will turn to ice. But the units of measurement do
not matter because this same event also occurs when a Fahrenheit thermometer shows a
temperature of 320.
66
In the above example, we have seen that temperature helps us to make predictions about physical
phenomena. In the same way utility helps us make predictions about consumption choices.
However, utility theory is not as precise as the theory that helps us to predict when water will
turn to ice or steam.
From the above discussion, one thing is now clear to us that utility is measurable, though it is not
so precise as other measurements. But it is still unclear how to measure utility, i.e., in what units
we can measure the utility we get from the consumption of a commodity?
About a hundred years ago, economists thought utility as an indicator of the pleasure a person
gets from the consumption of some set of goods, and they thought that utility could be measured
directly in some psychological units called utils, after somehow reading the consumer's mind.
But it was an impossible task to guess the satisfaction one gets from consuming a commodity.
Can you say how many utils did you get from the last cricket match you saw at the Bangabandhu
National Stadium? Probably your answer is NO, because you have no idea what util is. The same
thing would happen to anyone else.
But if you are asked: how many Shingara would you give up to get the ticket to watch that
cricket match? Now you can answer this question confidently, for example, five Shingaras.
Remember that still you don't know how many utils you got from watching the cricket match.
But you do know that your satisfaction from the cricket match is more than the satisfaction from
a piece of Shingara. In this case, Shingaras, rather than utils, become the unit of measurement.
We can say that the utility you derived from the cricket match is five Singagas. Actually, this
indirect way of measuring utility is the basis of the Cardinalist theory of consumer behavior. In
the early twentieth century, economists used this indirect way of measuring utility to analyze the
consumer behavior.
We can measure utility derived from a commodity (like a ticket for watching cricket match) in
terms of any other commodity (such as Shingara, Samucha, money, etc.) we are willing to give
up for it. In our discussion, we will use the commodity which is the simplest and commonly used
as a medium of exchange- that is, MONEY- to measure utility.
Thus we can define the utility of a commodity to a consumer as the amount of money she/he is
willing to give up for it. For example, suppose Modhu decides to buy one Chicken Patty by Tk.
10.00, she will not buy any Chicken Patty if the price is higher than 10.00 taka. Then the utility
of one piece of Chicken Patty is Tk. 10.00 - the maximum amount of money she is willing to pay
to have it. If she wants to buy five pieces of Chicken Patty and is willing to pay Tk.30.00 at a
maximum, then the total utility of five pieces of Chicken Patty to her is Tk. 30.00. Here one
thing is noticeable that though Modhu is willing to pay Tk. 10.00 for one piece of Chicken Patty,
she is willing to spend Tk. 30.00 only - not Tk. 50.00 = 5 @Tk. 10.00 - for five pieces of
Chicken Patty. This happens because she is willing to pay less for each additional piece of
Chicken Patty, which indicates that she gets lower utility from additional unit. The utility derived
from an additional piece of Chicken Patty is called marginal utility. Marginal utility and Total
utility are two related concepts. Let's now see how these concepts are related.
67
Total and Marginal Utility
Total utility refers to the amount of satisfaction from consumer's entire consumption of a
commodity. In the example cited earlier, the utilities Modhu derives from the 1st, 2nd, 3rd, 4th, and
5th pieces of Chicken Patty are Tk. 10.00, Tk. 9.00, Tk. 7.00, Tk. 4.00 and Tk. 0.00, respectively.
Therefore, the total utility derived from five pieces of Chicken Patty is Tk.30.00 = Tk. 10.00 +
Tk. 9.00 + Tk. 7.00 + Tk. 4.00 + Tk. 0.00.
On the contrary, marginal utility is the amount of utility a consumer derives from consuming the
last, i.e., marginal, unit of a commodity. In other words, marginal utility can be defined as the
amount of utility a consumer derives from the consumption of an additional unit of the
commodity. Marginal utility can also be defined as the change in the total utility resulting from
the change in the consumption- that is,
MR = TU/C
Here, MR = marginal utility, TU = change in total utility and C = change in consumption.
Recall our example of Chicken Patty consumption. Modhu gets the utility of Tk.10.00 from the
first piece of Chicken Patty. When she takes the second one, she gets the utility of Tk. 9.00. This
additional utility is called marginal utility. When she takes the third one, her marginal utility
becomes Tk. 7.00. For the fifth one, she is not willing to pay any money, i.e., the marginal utility
is zero.
Table 4.1 helps clarify the distinction between marginal and total utility and shows how the two
are related. First two columns show how much total utility Modhu derives from various
quantities of Chicken Patty. For example, one Chicken Patty is worth Tk.10.00 to her, two
Chicken Patties are worth Tk.19.00, in total, to her and so on.
68
The marginal utility is the difference between any two successive total utility figures, which is
shown in the third column of the Table 4.1. For example, if Modhu already consumed three
pieces of Chicken Patty which are worth Tk.26.00 to her, consumption of an extra piece of
Chicken Patty makes her total utility Tk.30.00. Thus her marginal utility is the difference
between the two, i.e., Tk.4.00 (= Tk. 30.00 - Tk. 26.00). If we plot the data of Table 4.1 into the
graph, we get total and marginal utility curves. Figure 4.1 portrayed the total utility and the
marginal utility curves in the same plot area.
M
30
TU
20
Total and Marginal utility
10
MU
1 2 3 4 5
Quantity of Patty
In Figure 4.1, the TU curve indicates the total utility Modhu derives from Chicken Patties at
different consumption levels. We see that the total utility curve is upward up to a level of
consumption (Point M), which means that the more patties Modhu consumes, the more total
utility she gets up to a certain level of consumption. Notice that the total utility curve is rising but
at a diminishing rate (Why?- see the law of diminishing marginal utility). We see the MU
(Marginal Utility) curve lying just under the TU curve in the same plot area. The downward
sloping MU curve tells us that as she incases her consumption, the amount of utility Modhu gets
from each extra piece of Patty decreases.
Therefore, if we summarize the message given in Figure 4.1, we get the following characteristics
of total and marginal utility, which tells us how total and marginal utility are related:
Up to a certain level of consumption, total utility increases as the consumption increases.
Marginal utility is decreasing with the increase in consumption.
Total utility increases till marginal utility is positive, but at a diminishing rate.
When marginal utility becomes zero, then total utility is the maximum.
Total utility decreases if marginal utility becomes negative.
69
The area under the marginal utility curve indicates the total utility derived from various
pieces of Patty.
In the previous discussion, we have learnt that marginal utility diminishes as the consumer
increases her consumption of Chicken Patty. This very nature of marginal utility is described by
the law of diminishing marginal utility. Let's know the law in detail.
Assumptions
The assumptions upon which this law is based are as follows:
Given time period: Units of the commodity are consumed in a given time period. The time
period must be appropriate. If you drink ten cans of cold drinks during the whole day, the idea of
diminishing marginal utility will not hold. However, if you are asked to drink all of the cans in
two hours of time, then the idea of diminishing marginal utility makes sense.
Continual consumption: The units of the commodity are consumed continually, but the time
interval between the consumption of two units of the commodity must be appropriately short.
Normal behavior of the consumer: The mental condition of the consumer remains normal during
the period of consumption of the commodity. She/he has a hierarchy of uses to which she/he will
put a particular commodity. All of these uses are valuable, but some are more valuable than
others.
Standard units of the commodity: The units of the commodity must be standard, i.e., a can of
cold drinks, a glass of juice, a cone of ice-cream, a cup of tea, a pair of shoes, etc. If the units are
excessively small or large, the law may not hold.
Consumption of other commodities is given: During the consumption of the commodity, the
consumption of all other commodities remains constant.
The behavior of the sea-fish connoisseurs is not abnormal. Generally speaking, as we consume
more and more of a commodity, even the most favorite one, we become bored with it and our
satisfaction from additional units of it diminishes. Indeed, this phenomenon of diminishing is so
nearly universal that economists have fashioned a law around it which is called the law of
diminishing utility.
Note that this law does not say that we won't like the third or fourth piece of a commodity; it just
says we won't like them as much as the ones we have already consumed.
Graphically, the law of diminishing marginal utility has been illustrated in Figure 4.1. The
downward sloping MU curve in the figure indicates that the marginal utility derived from each
extra piece of Chicken Patty diminishes as the consumption of it increases.
71
Review Questions
1. (a) What is marginal utility?
(b) What is the law of diminishing marginal utility?
(c) What evidence is there to suggest that diminishing marginal utility exists?
(d) Calculate the marginal utilities of additional glasses of orange juice from the following
figures:
MU Price
Steak dinner 100 $10
Fish dinner 75 5
5. Let's say that the combination of food that maximizes your satisfaction for lunch consists of
one cheeseburger, one slice of apple pie, and one cup of coffee. According to the marginal-
utility-over-price approach to making consumer decisions, you should continue to consume
this mix of foods for lunch the rest of your life. True or false? Explain.
6. It is a common practice in restaurants for customers to be given as much coffee as they
desire free of charge when they purchase a meal. Under these circumstances, what is the
marginal utility of the last cup of coffee; that is, what should be the marginal utility of the
last unit consumed of goods received 'free'.
72
Lesson 3: Ordinal Utility Theory - Indifference Curve
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
describe the basic difference between the ordinalist theory and cardinalist theory;
explain the indifference curve;
explain the budget line;
Introduction
At the end of the previous lesson, we learnt that there are some basic weaknesses in the
Cardinalist approach. The main weakness in the Cardinalist approach is the assumption of
cardinal utility. In the Cardinalist approach, the taste or satisfaction or utility derived from the
consumption of a commodity can be measured objectively. In Table 4.1, we saw that the
marginal utility Modhu got from the first piece of Patty was Tk. 10.00, while the second piece of
Patty had the marginal utility of Tk.9.00. Now, the question is: can we really be so specific about
our tastes? Is it reasonable to say that you got the marginal utility of Tk.10.00 from the
consumption of the first can of Virgin? Should we calculate a psychological entity, like utility,
arithmetically?
Till early twentieth century, the above questions were left unanswered. In 1906, Vilfredo Pareto
first opposed the idea of cardinal utility and initiated the idea of ordinal utility to consumer
behavior analysis. Later Eugene E. Slutsky, W.E. Johnson, A.L. Bowley, John R. Hicks, and
R.G.D. Allen systematically developed the ordinal utility theory as a powerful tool of consumer
behavior analysis. There are several theories which are based on the concept of ordinal utility.
For example, the indifference curves analysis, theory of revealed preference, etc.
This lesson presents the indifference curve analysis of consumer behavior. Let's first know
something about the concept of ordinal utility.
Commodities Ranks
Patty 3
Shingara 2
Orange 1
Therefore, the ordinal utility is the expression of the consumer's preference for one commodity
over another or one basket of goods over another, but not a numerical figure of utility derived
73
from different commodities or baskets. In this case, it is assumed that the utility derived from the
consumption of various commodities cannot be measured in quantities, but the consumer can
rank her/his preferences according to the satisfaction of each commodity or basket. For example,
you can say that you prefer Orange to Shingara, but it is extremely doubtful if you say that the
utility you will receive from Orange and Shingara is Tk.10.00 and Tk.5.00, respectively.
So, ordinal utility analysis is a more advanced explanation of consumer behavior than cardinal
utility analysis.
Let's now discuss indifference curve analysis which is based on the ordinal utility concept.
Indifference curves
curve analysis
Budget lines
Let's first discuss the assumptions underlying the indifference curve analysis. Later, we will
discuss indifference curves and budget lines in detail.
Assumptions
The indifference curve analysis of consumer's behavior is based on the following assumptions:
Rationality: The consumer is rational - she/he aims at the maximization of her/his utility, given
her/his income and market prices. She/he has full knowledge of all relevant information.
Ordinal utility: The consumer can rank her/his preferences according to the satisfaction of each
basket. She/he doesn't need to care the arithmetic calculation of utility or satisfaction. Only
ordinal measurement of utility is required.
Diminishing marginal rate of substitution: The slope of the indifference curve is called the
marginal rate of substitution of the commodities. The indifference curve analysis is based on the
axiom of diminishing marginal rate of substitution.
74
Total utility depends on the quantities consumed: The total utility depends on the quantities of
the commodities consumed. That is,
U f ( q1 , q1 ,....., q x , q y ,....., qn )
Consistency of choice: The consumer is consistent in her/his choice, which means if the
consumer once chooses Bundle A over Bundle B, she/he will not choose B over A in another
period if both bundles are available to her/him. Symbolically, the assumption of consistency may
be written as follows:
If A > B, then B A
In Table 4.2, five combinations of Orange and Patty have been shown. Combination-a contains
12 pieces of Orange and 2 pieces of Patty, combination-b contains 7 pieces of Orange and 4
pieces of Patty, combinaton-c contains 4 pieces of Orange and 6 pieces of Patty, and so on. We
see that the quantity figures are not the same in all the combinations. If a combination contains
75
more Oranges, it has to contain less Patty. This is necessary, because all the combinations should
yield the consumer the same satisfaction. Note that as the combinations include more of Patties,
the quantity of Oranges in the combinations becomes lower. That means, the consumer has to
give up Oranges for getting more Patties to keep her satisfaction same. So, there is a substitution
between the two commodities. But what is about the rate of substitution? Does she always give
up or substitute the same amount of Oranges for every extra piece of Patty? Look at Table 4.4.
When Modhu moves from combination-a to combination-b, she substitutes 2 pieces of Patty for
5 pieces of Orange; if she moves further, i.e., from combination-b to combination-c, she
substitutes same amount of Patty (2 pieces of Patty) for 3 pieces of Orange; and so on. Therefore,
the rate of substitution of each extra piece of Patty (marginal rate of substitution) diminishes.
This is shown in Table 4.5.
Table 4.3: Marginal rate of substitution (hypothetical data)
Combinations
a 12 2
b 7 5 (=12-7) 4 2 (= 4-2) 2.5
c 4 3 (= 7-4) 6 2 (= 6-4) 1.5
d 2 2 (= 4-2) 8 2 (= 8-6) 1.0
e 1 1 (= 2-1) 10 2 (= 10-8) 0.5
In Table 4.3, it is shown that for every extra 2 pieces of Patty the consumer is not willing to give
up the same quantity of Oranges - her willingness to giving up Oranges becomes lower as she
gets more of Patties. This means, her attraction toward Patty reduces as she gets more of it.
Column-6 of the table shows the diminishing marginal rate of substitution of Patty for Orange.
Indifference curve: Plotting the data given in Table 4.4 we get the indifferent curve of the
consumer. Figure 4.4 shows it.
In the above figure, IC indicates the indifference curve. Any point on the indifference curve
indicates a combination of two commodities - Orange and Patty. At all the points, the consumer
is indifferent, i.e., throughout this curve the consumer's utility or satisfaction is the same. That's
why, indifference curve is also called Iso-utility or Equal-utility curve.
14
a
12
Quantity of Orange
10
8 b
6
c
4
d
2 e
IC
0
2 4 6 8 10 76
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.4: Indifference curve of Modhu
Indifference map
An indifference map is the collection of all indifference curves which rank the preferences of the
consumer. As we move out from the origin, each successive indifference curve entails a higher
level of utility. That means, combinations of goods lying on a higher indifference curve yield
higher level of satisfaction and are preferred. Figure 4.5 shows an indifference map.
Quantity of Orange
IC3
IC2
IC1
0
Quantity of Patty
Downward sloping: The indifference curve is downward sloping, which implies that: the two
commodities can be substituted for each other; and if quantity of one commodity decreases,
quantity of the other commodity must increase if the consumer has to stay at the same level of
satisfaction. Technically, the slope of the indifference curve is called the Marginal Rate of
Substitution (MRS), because it shows the rate, at the margin, at which the consumer will
substitute one good for the other to remain equally satisfied.
Convex to the origin: Downward slope is the necessary, not sufficient, property of the
indifference curve. As viewed from the origin, a downward sloping curve can be concave
(bowed outward) or convex (bowed inward). The indifference curve is convex to the origin,
which means that slope of the indifference curve, the marginal rate of substitution, diminishes as
we move down the curve. The diminishing slope of the indifference curve means the willingness
to substitute one commodity (orange) for the other (Patty) diminishes as one moves down the
curve.
77
Indifference curves do not intersect nor be tangent to one another: By definition, we know that
along an indifference curve the consumer's satisfaction remains the same. If indifference curves
intersect, the point of their intersection would imply two different levels of satisfaction, which is
impossible.
Upper indifference curves represent higher level of satisfaction than the lower ones: The further
away from the origin an indifference curve lies, the higher the level of utility it denotes. Bundles
of commodities on an upper indifference contain a larger quantity of one or both of the
commodities than the lower indifference curve. Thus bundles of commodities on a higher
indifference curve are more preferred by the rational consumer.
Budget Line: What the Consumer Can Afford
In the previous section, we learnt that an indifference curve shows such combinations of
commodities from which the consumer gets the same level of satisfaction. In that case, we
haven't considered any constraint. Is the consumer able to consume any combination she/he
prefers? Certainly the answer is NO. Why? Because her/his income is limited. Thus which
bundle or combination of the commodities the consumer can afford depends on her/his income
and the prices of the commodities.
A budget line shows such combinations of two commodities which the consumer can afford,
given her/his money income and prices of the commodities. Table 4.6 shows the combinations of
Orange and Patty which the consumer can purchase when her/his money income is Tk.36.00,
price of Orange is Tk.3.00 and price of Patty is Tk.4.00.
Table 4.6: Combinations of Orange and Patty attainable with an income of Tk.36.00 (hypothetical
data)
Quantity of Quantity of Expenditure on Expenditure Total
Orange Patty Orange on Patty Expenditure
Combinations
a 12 0 3 12 = 36 40=0 36 + 0 = 36
b 8 3 3 8 = 24 4 3 = 12 24 + 12 = 36
c 4 6 3 4 = 12 4 6 = 24 12 + 48 = 36
d 0 9 30=0 4 9 = 36 0 + 36 = 36
In the table above, four combinations are shown such as combination-a{12 pieces of Orange and
0 piece of Patty}, combination-b{ 8 pieces of Orange and 3 pieces of Patty}, combination-c{ 4
pieces of Orange and 6 pieces of Patty} and combination-d{0 piece of Orange and 9 pieces of
Patty}. Each of the combinations can be purchased with Tk.36.00 of money income.
Algebraically, we can write the income constraint, in the case of two commodities, as follows:
Assigning successive values to Qor ( M, Por and Ppa remain the same), we may find the
corresponding values of Qpa . Thus, if Qor = 0 (that is, if the consumer spends all her/his income
on Patty), then the consumer can buy M/Ppa units of Patty. Similarly, if Qpa = 0 ( that is, if the
consumer spends all her/his income on Orange), then the consumer can buy M/Por units of
Orange. These results are shown in Figure 4.8 by Points A and B. If we join these points with a
line, we obtain the budget line. Budget line is also called as price line. In the above figure, AB is
the budget line. Any point on or under the budget line indicates the combination of Orange and
Patty which is affordable to the consumer, but the points on the north-east area of the budget
line indicate such combinations which are out of the purchasing capacity of the consumer. Thus
the south-west area of the budget line is feasibility area and the north-east area of the budget line
is non-feasibility area. We can geometrically calculate the slope of the budget line as follows:
Point A: M/Por=12
12
Budget line
Quantity of Orange
3
Point B: M/Ppa =9
0 3 6 9 12
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.6: Budget line (representing the data in table 4.1)
OA M / Por Ppa
OB M / Ppa Por
So, we can draw the budget line easily if we know the prices of the commodities and the money
income of the consumer. Let's consider the prices and money income assumed in Table 4.6. We
find:
These two results are shown in Figure 4.8 by Points A and B. If we join these points with a line,
we obtain the budget line, AB. Points on the budget line represents the combinations of Orange
and Patty which can be purchased with Tk.36.00. All the combinations in Table 4.6 fall on the
budget line. Thus, without plotting the data in Table 4.6 budget line can be derived if we have
the information about the prices of the commodities and the money income of the consumer.
Properties of budget line
Budget line has the following basic properties:
Downward sloping: Budget line is downward sloping, which implies that: the two commodities
can be substituted for each other; and if quantity of one commodity decreases, quantity of other
commodity must increase if the consumer has to spend all of her/his money income. Technically,
the slope of the budget line is the ratio of the prices of the commodities: Ppa /Por.
M
A Por
Quantity of Orange
Budget line
M
Ppa
0 B
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.7: Slope of the budget line: Ppa /Por 0
Position of the budget line: Position of the budget line is determined by two types of data: the
prices of the commodities and consumer's disposable income.
80
Income change: If the income of the consumer increases, the budget line shifts outward parallely.
The reason is simply that say, 33 per cent increase in available income, if entirely spent on two
goods in question, would permit the consumer to purchase exactly 33 per cent more of either
commodity. Conversely, if the income decreases by 33 per cent, then the consumer's purchase of
either goods is decreased by 33 per cent. In this case, the budget line shifts inward in parallel
way. Figure 4.10 shows both the cases.
16
14
12
10
Quantity of Orange
8 Income = Tk.48.00
6
4
Income = Tk.36.00
2
0 Income = Tk.24.00
3 6 9 12
Quantity of Pattis
Figure 4.8: The effect of income changes on the budget line
Price change: If the price of one or both of the commodities is changed, the budget line will
swing. To explain the nature of the swing we can consider the following cases:
Case-1: Price of only one commodity changes. If the price of only one commodity changes, one
end of the budget line swings away from the initial position. For example, in Figure 4.11(A), the
initial position of the budget line is indicated by the bold line. The initial prices of Orange and
Patty are Tk.3.00 and Tk.4.00, respectively. Now, if the price of Patty rises to Tk.4.00 while the
price of Orange remains fixed, the end of the budget line on the Patty axis (i.e., horizontal axis)
10
8
Price of Patty = Tk.3.00
6
4 Price of Patty = Tk.4.00
2
0 Price of Patty = Tk.6.00
3 6 9 12 15
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.9(A): The effect of price changes on the budget line.
will swing toward the origin. This is shown by the dotted line in Figure 4.11(A). But in the case
of fall in the price of Patty (from Tk.4.00 to Tk.3.00), the effect will be reverse. The right most
budget line in Figure 4.11(A) shows that. Similarly, we can see the effect of the changes in the
price of Orange assuming that the price of Patty is fixed. Figure 4.11(B) shows that.
81
In Figure 4.11(B), The bold line indicates the initial position of the budget line, when the prices
of Orange and Patty are Tk.3.00 and Tk.4.00 respectively. If the price of Orange rises, the price
18
16 POrange changes; PPatty constant
14
12
Quantity of Orange
10
8 Price of Orange = Tk.2.00
6
4 Price of Orange = Tk.3.00
2
0 Price of Orange = Tk.6.00
3 6 9 12 15
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.10(B): The effect of price changes on the budget line
of Patty remaining the same, the end of the budget line on the Orange axis (vertical axis) swings
inward, which is shown by the dotted line in Figure 4.11(B). But in the case of a fall in the price
of Orange, the effect will be reverse, i.e., the upper end of the budget line swings outward, which
is shown by the right most line in Figure 4.11(B).
In conclusion, we can say that if the price of a particular commodity changes, the respective end
of the budget line swings. If price falls, it swings outward and if price rises, it swings inward.
Case-2: Price of both commodities change. If the prices of both commodities are changed
simultaneously, then it becomes more complex to discuss their effect on budget line. However,
keeping the effect of individual price changes on the budget line in mind, we can see how the
budget line shifts or rotates. If the prices change in opposite direction, the budget line rotates as
in Figure 4.11(C). For example, if the price of Orange falls and the price of Patty rises
18 Prices change in opposite direction
16
14 Price of Orange = Tk.2.00
12
Quantity of Orange
3 6 9 12 15
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.11(C): The effect of price changes on the budget line
simultaneously, the budget line will rotate clockwise, which is shown by the steepest line in
Figure 4.11(C). On the other hand, if the price of Orange rises and the price of Patty falls, then
the budget line rotates anti-clockwise, which is shown by the dotted line in Figure 4.11(C). The
bold line in the figure indicates the initial position of the budget line.
82
If the prices change in the same direction, the budget line shifts. Figure 4.11(D) shows it. For
18 Prices change in opposite direction
16
14 Price of Orange = Tk.2.00
12
Quantity of Orange
3 6 9 12 15
Quantity of Patty
Figure 4.11(D): The effect of price changes on the budget line
example, if both prices fall, the budget line shifts outward (steepest line in the figure), while the
rise in both prices causes the budget line shift inward entirely (dotted line in the figure).
83
Review Questions
1. Explain the concept of ordinal utility. What are the assumptions in ordering consumer
preference?
2. What is an indifference curve? What are the main properties of indifference curve? What
will be the shape of indifference curve if one of the two goods is a free commodity?
3. Why are the indifference curves convex to the point of origin?
4. What is marginal rate of substitution? Why does the MRS diminish along the indifference
curve?
5. Draw indifference curves for the following pairs of products and explain why you have
drawn them in a certain shape:
(a) paper and pencils.
(b) pens and pencils.
6. How do you depict the indifference preference map for (a) good and a bad, (b) a bad and a
bad?
7. What is the shape of an indifference curve between a good and another good over same
range of consumption and a bad thereafter.
8. Suppose there are two commodities each of which cause a reduction in total utility beyond
a certain rate of consumption. What would be the shape of a typical indifference curve?
9. What is the shape of indifference curve when one of the two good is a normal good and
the other a neutral?
10. Show with the help of indifference curves that price effect is a combination of income and
substitution effects.
11. Derive a demand curve with the help of indifference curves.
12. What is the difference between the price consumption curve and the conventional demand
curve? Derive a demand curve with the help of price consumption curve.
84
Unit 5: PRODUCTION, COST AND SUPPLY
Highlights
Defining the Concept of Production
Total, Marginal and Average Product Curves
Short-run and Long-run Product Curves
Total, Marginal Cost and Average Cost Curves
Short-run and Long-run Cost Curves
Laws of Returns
Meaning of Production
In popular language, the term production is used to mean creation of a new commodity or a
service. In Economics, production means creation of new utility. The law of indestructibility of
matters in physics states that human beings cannot create or destroy matters. She/he can only
change the shape of matters so that these transformed matters satisfy human wants. In other
words, a human being creates new utility by rendering her/his services. Suppose a person gets a
piece of wood, free of cost, from her/his friend. As long as the piece of wood lies unused in his
courtyard, it will not be a production activity. The person hires a carpenter who puts her/his
services on the piece of wood to change it to an item of furniture.
85
The carpenter creates new utility by changing the piece of the wood to the shape of a furniture
item. Thus, the carpenter produces a commodity which satisfies human wants. There are four
factors of production - land, labor, capital, and entrepreneur. The owners of land, labor, and
capital and the entrepreneur get rent, wages, interest income and profit respectively as their
remunerations. The entrepreneur organizes the production activities. She/he buys a piece of land,
hires the workers and borrow the necessary capital from the financial institutions for investing in
her/his production firm. Her/his ultimate objective is to maximize her/his profit which can be
defined as the difference between total revenue and total cost. A production firm generally
consists of a few production plants; each production plant in turn consists of one production unit
with one big furnace, machinery and equipments. The collection of all firms producing one
commodity is called an industry. For example, the sugar industry in Bangladesh consists of all
production firms engaged in producing sugar.
Production Function
A production function is a technical relationship between the inputs of production and output of
the firm; the relationship is such that the level of output depends on the levels of inputs used, not
vice versa. A production function is traditionally expressed by the following equation:
Q = f(K,L)
where,
Q = the level of output
f = the symbol of relationship, which is determined by the production engineers.
K = the amount of capital
L = the amount of labor
86
Symbolically, a short-run production function can be expressed as follows:
Y = f (K0, L)
Where,
K0 means fixed level of capital.
Suppose there are two factors of production, capital (K) and labor (L). Also suppose capital is
fixed in the short-run. We are interested to examine how total, average, and marginal product
curves would be affected if we keep increasing the level of labor input. The following diagram
shows the behavior of total, average, and marginal product curves in the short-run.
A3
TPL
MPL A2
APL TPL
A1
APL
O L
L1 L2 L3
MPL
Figure 5.1: Total, average and marginal product curve in the short-run
In Figure 5.1, we measure productivity along the vertical axis, and quantity of labor along the
horizontal axis. The TP curve in the diagram shows how total product behaves if we increase the
quantity of labor keeping the quantity of other factors fixed in the short-run. It is evident that
total product increases at an increasing rate initially. It starts increasing at a decreasing rate after
point L1 along the horizontal axis and after A1 along the TP curve. Total product becomes the
maximum when OL3 amount of labor is used. Then it starts diminishing. Marginal product
increases as long as total product increases at an increasing rate. Marginal product becomes the
maximum at the inflection point where total product starts increasing at a decreasing rate.
Marginal product becomes zero when total product is the maximum. Marginal product remains
negative as long as total product diminishes. Average product increases initially up to point L2
along the horizontal axis and up to point A2 along the TP curve. It begins to fall after OL2
amount of labor. It should be noted that average product can never be zero or negative.
It is evident from the table that we change all factors of production keeping the ratio of capital
(K) to labor (L) always equal to half. From step 1 to step 2, we double both the factors, capital
and labor. Total product however, becomes more than double. It is a case of increasing returns to
scale. From step 2 to step 3, total output and the two inputs increase at the same rate - all double
in step 3. We have constant returns to scale here. From step 3 to step 4, total product becomes
less than double though the inputs double in step 4. The final case shows decreasing returns to
scale. It should be noted that production functions showing any kind of returns to scale are
known as homogeneous production functions. We must use equal product curves in order to
show returns to scale diagrammatically. At the end of this lesson returns to scale will be shown
by equal product curves.
88
Equal Product Curves and Budget Lines
Equal Product Curve
An equal product curve is the locus of different combinations of two inputs that can produce a
give level of output. It should be noted that an equal product curve is very much similar to an
indifference curve. An indifference curve consists of different combinations of two commodities.
An indifference curve represents the same level of satisfaction at all points on it; an equal
product curve shows the same level of output at all points on it. There is one difference between
two: the given level of satisfaction cannot be quantified in the case of indifference curve whereas
the given level of output can be quantified in the case of an equal product curve. The following
figure shows an equal product curve.
K
Capital
K1 A1
K2
A2
Q = 20
0 L1 L2 L
Labor
Figure 5.2: Equal product curve
In Figure 5.2, we measure quantity of capital (K) along the vertical axis and the quantity of labor
(L) along the horizontal axis. Q = 20 is an equal product curve showing the different
combinations of two inputs capable of producing 20 units of output. For example, both
combination A1 with OK1 units of capital and OL1 units of labor and combination A2 with OK2
units of capital and OL2 units of labor can produce 20 units of output. The other points on Q = 20
are also capable of producing 20 units of output.
Characteristics of Equal Product Curve
Equal product curves possess characteristics similar to those of indifference curves. These are
cited below:
Equal product curves are downward sloping;
Equal product curves are convex to the origin;
Two equal product curves cannot intersect each other; and
A higher level of equal product curve indicates higher level of output.
Let's now discuss the concept of budget line in production analysis.
89
Budget Line or Iso-Cost Line
A budget line in production analysis shows the different combinations of two inputs that a firm
owner can buy with a given amount of money and given prices of two inputs. Figure 5.3 shows a
budget line with capital measured along the vertical axis and labor along the horizontal axis.
K
Capital
K1 C
K2
D
0 L1 L2 L
Labor
Figure 5.3: Budget line or Iso-Cost Line
The combination C with OK1 of capital of OL1 of labor costs as much as the combination D with
OK2 of capital and OL2 of labor. All other points on the budget line cause the firm owner to
spend the same amount of money.
90
K
Capital
C M
A
N
K* E
Q
P EQ = 20
O L* B D L
Labor
Her/his minimum cost is given by the budget line CD. She/he would like to go to budget line
AB, but she/he cannot produce 20 units of output by going to budget line AB. Thus, geometric
condition for minimum cost is that at the least cost combination, the equal product curve must be
tangent with the budget line. We can formalize the necessary and sufficient conditions for cost
minimization as follows:
Necessary Condition
PL/PK = MPL/MPK
Where,
PL = Price of labor input
PK = Price of capital input
MPL = Marginal productivity of labor
MPK = Marginal productivity of capital
Sufficient Condition
At the least cost combination, the equal product curve must be convex to the origin.
We can illustrate the concepts of returns to scale with the help of least cost combinations of
factors. Figure 5.5 explains three kinds of returns to scale.
91
K
A4
A3
T
K4 A2 E4
Capital
Q4 =100
K3 E3
Q3 =75
A1
K2 E2
Q2 =50
K1 E1
Q1 =20
B1 B2 B3 B4
L
O L1 L2 L3 L4
Labor
Figure 5.5: Returns to scale
We measure capital along the vertical axis and labor, along the horizontal axis. In Figure 5.5, we
have four budget lines A1B 1, A2B2, A3B 3 and A4 B4 which result from increased budgets of the
entrepreneur with prices of two inputs remaining the same. We also notice four least cost
combinations of factors in the diagram. These are E1, E2, E3 and E 4. By joining the least cost
combinations, we get a curve like OT in Figure 5.5. This curve is called the expansion path,
because it shows the inputs utilization levels when an entrepreneur wants to expand its
production levels keeping the inputs ratio the same. It should be noted that the expansion path is
a straight line in the case of a homogeneous production function. It is evident from Figure 5.5
that the following distances have the same length in the diagram.
OE1 = E 1E2 = E2E 3 = E 3E4
This implies that if the producer doubles both the inputs, she/he comes to the least cost
combination E2 from the earlier least cost combination E1. The level of output, however, more
than doubles at E2 because E2 is on the equal product curve Q2 showing 50 units of output. At E1,
the producer used to produce 20 units of output. In other words, the movement from E1 to E2
shows increasing returns to scale if the two inputs are doubled and as a result the increase in
output is the same as the initial output, the situation is called constant returns to scale. In Figure
5.5, movement from E2 to E 3 indicates constant returns to scale to the producer. Similarly, if the
inputs are doubled and as a result the increase in total output is 1.5 times of the initial output, the
situation is called decreasing returns to scale, the movement from E 3 to E 4 in Figure 5.5 indicates
decreasing returns to scale.
92
Review Questions
1. Explain the relationship between the average cost and marginal cost curves.
2. Explain the behavior of cost curves in short-run. Show the relationship between marginal
cost, average variable cost, average total cost.
3. Suppose a cost function is given as C = 135 + 75Q - 15Q2 + Q3. There are a cost schedule
showing total cost, marginal cost, marginal cost, average cost and average variable cost.
Draw the cost curves on the basis of cost data obtained from the cost function.
4. (a) What is production?
(b) In each of the following activities, identify what is being produced and the major
inputs:
(1) Baking a cake
(2) Attending college
(3) Eating
(4) Sleeping
5. (a) What is production function? Distinguish between short-run and long
run production functions.
(b) Write down the characteristics of equal product curves.
(c) What is budget line or iso-cost curve?
(d) Explain the least cost combination of factors.
6. What is expansion path? Explain it graphically.
7. What is marginal physical product of labor? In what units MPL is measured in production
of:
(a) Wheat
(b) Haircuts
(c) Houses
(d) Dental services
93
Lesson 2: Short-run and Long-run Cost Curves
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
derive the different short-run cost curves;
state the nature of different short-run average cost curves;
derive the different long-run cost curves; and
state the nature of different long-run cost curves.
94
In Figure 5.6, we measure output level along the horizontal axis and different types of cost along
STC
STC, TFC,TVC
D
A
B C TVC
E
TFC
Q
O Q1
Output
Figure 5.6: Different types of short-run cost curves
the vertical axis. The horizontal line marked TFC shows that total fixed cost does not depend on
the level of output; it is fixed at all levels of output. The curve STC shows how short-run total
costs increase with the level of output. The gap between short-run total cost (STC) and total
fixed cost (TFC) measures the total variable cost (TVC) of production. It can easily be seen from
the figure that both STC and TVC increase at a decreasing rate initially when output level
increases, and then both increase at an ??? here that the shape of STC derives from the shape of Commented [H1]: See
the short-run total product curve; the shape of STC is just the opposite of the shape of the short-
run total product curve. We know that the short-run total product curve increases at an increasing
rate and then it increases at a decreasing rate.
If we divide short-run total cost (STC), total variable cost (TVC), and total fixed cost (TFC) by
the level of output, we obtain short-run average total cost SATC, short-run avarage variable cost
(SAVC) and short-run average fixed cost (SAFC) respectively. The relations are shown below:
SATC = STC/Q
SAVC = TVC/Q
SAFC = TFC/Q
SATC = STC/Q = (TVC+TFC)/Q = TVC/Q + TFC/Q = SAVC + SAFC
Short-run marginal cost is defined as the change in short-run total cost due to one unit change in
output.
SMC = STC/ Q = TVC/Q
Alternatively, the average cost curves can be derived geometrically from the STC and TFC
curves. First, we find the values of SAC, SAVC, SAFC, and SMC at a particular level of output
like Q1 along the horizontal axis. Then we find these values at all levels of output. Finally, by
plotting these values, we get the different types of average cost curves. For example, we are
interested in finding the values of SAC, SAVC, SAFC, and SMC at output level Q1 in Figure 5.6.
SATC at Q 1 is found by dividing total cost, Q1 A, by the level of output, Q1. SAFC is equal to
total fixed cost, Q1 E, divided by the level of output, Q1. Finally, SMC is calculated as the value
of the slope of the tangent at point A, which is equal to DC divided by BC.
95
Nature of Short-run Average Cost Curves
Short-run average total cost SATC is the sum of short-run average fixed cost (SAFC) and short-
run average variable cost (SAVC).
SATC = SAFC + SAVC
SAFC declines continuously when the level of output increases, because the quotient TFC/Q
falls continuously with increasing units of output. SAFC is a rectangular hyperbola approaching
both axes asymptotically. SAVC is normally U-shaped, falling initially as output level increases.
It reaches a minimum value at a certain level of output and starts rising after that.
SAVC is found to be the reciprocal of average productivity of labor if we assume that price of
labor does not depend on the level of employment. We know that the average productivity curve
is inverted U-shaped in the short-run. Hence the SAVC curve is U-shaped in the short-run.
Second, in the short-run certain inputs are fixed. Each fixed input needs a certain number of
labor force for its optimum utilization. We assume that the number of labor force applied to each
fixed input in the short-run increases gradually starting from zero. Initially, a small number of
labor input is applied to the fixed input. Average productivity is, therefore, low and short-run
average variable cost is high at the initial stage. Average productivity of labor starts rising as the
number of labor input increases. As a result, SAVC starts falling. As the number of variable
input, labor, keeps increasing, average productivity of labor becomes maximum when the fixed
inputs are put to optimum their utilization. Corresponding to this point of labor employment,
SAVC becomes the minimum. If we increase the number of labor force beyond the optimum
utilization point, average and marginal productivity of labor start falling due to mismanagement
and chaotic conditions prevailing in the firm. Consequently, SAVC starts rising after the
optimum utilization points of the fixed inputs. This ends the explanation of the U-shape of
SAVC.
96
SAFC is greater than the rate of rise of SAVC. After some units of output, the rate of rise of
SAVC becomes greater than the rate of fall of SAFC.
From that point, rise in SAVC offsets the fall in SAFC. As a result, SATC starts rising with the
increase in the level of output.
The preceding discussion explains why SATC is also U-shaped. Like SATC, short-run marginal
cost (SMC) curve is also U-shaped. SMC derives its shape from the shape of short-run marginal
productivity curve. The following equation shows how SMC and marginal productivity (MPL)
are related to each other.
SMC = STC/ Q = (L.PL)/Q = PL/(Q/L) = PL/MPL
If we assume PL to be fixed regardless of the level of employment, we find SMC to be the
reciprocal of MPL. Since MPL curve is inverted U-shaped, SMC curve will be U-shaped.
Now let's explain how short-run marginal cost (SMC) curve is related to SAFC, SAVC and
SATC curves.
SMC SMC
SATCS
AVC SATC
SAFC
SAVC
SAFC
Q
O Q1 Q2 Q3
97
falling initially to Q1 level of output and then starts rising. The SMC curve cuts the SAVC and
SAC curves at their minimum points corresponding to Q 2 and Q3 levels of output, respectively.
T1
Q Q
O Q1 Q2 O
In Figure 5.8, we showed three STC curves for three plants. If the entrepreneur wants to produce
Q1 level of output, she/he can use one of the three production plants. Her/his total cost of
production is Q1U with plant-1, Q1 S with plant-2 and Q1 T with plant-3. Her/his minimum total
cost is Q1T 1 with plant-3. By joining minimum cost points like T1 and T2, we obtain the long-run
total cost curve (LTC) which starts from the origin as shown in Figure 5.9. Like STC, LTC also
increases at a decreasing rate initially and then it increases at an increasing rate.
98
In Figure 5.10, we measure short-run costs along the vertical axis and level of output along the
SMC3 SMC5
SAC SMC1
E6 SATC5
SMC
SATC1 E11 LAC
LAC
E1 E2 SMC2
SMC4
SATC2 E7
SATC4
E8 SATC3 E10
E3
E9 E4 E5
Q
0 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5
Figure 5.10: Derivation of long-run average cost curve (LAC)
horizontal axis. In this diagram, we show five short-run average total cost (SATC) curves, each
representing one production plant. The SATC curves have been numbered according to the
number of production plants. Suppose the producer produces Q1 level of output with production
plant-1. The producer wants to increase his production level to Q2, which he can produce using
his old plant-1 or using the new plant-2. Her/his average cost of production is Q2E 2 in plant-1
and Q2E3 in plant-2. He/she will use plant-2 since his average cost of producing Q2 level of
output is lower in plant-2 (Q2E3 <Q2E2). Similarly, she/he will produce Q3 level of output using
plant-3. Her/his average cost of production of Q4 level of output will be lower if she/he uses
plant-4 instead using plant-3 (Q4E5 <Q4E 6). She/he will use plant-5 for producing Q5 level of
output. By joining the points of minimum average cost like E1, E3, E 4, E5, and E7, we get the
long-run average cost (LAC) curve. It is easily seen that the long-run average cost of production
will be minimum if the producer produces Q3 level of output using plant-3. The plant giving rise
to long-run minimum average cost is known as the optimum plant, which is plant-3 in Figure
5.10. We also notice that LAC is tangent to the SATC curves in their falling portions to the left
of the optimum plant. LAC is tangent to the SATC curves in their rising portions to the right of
the optimum plant. In the long-run minimum cost level of output Q3, the LAC curve is tangent to
the SATC curve at its minimum point. It should be noted here that like SATC, LAC curve is also
U-shaped, though it is flatter than the SATC curve. Unlike the LAC curve, the long-run marginal
cost curve is not the envelope of the short-run marginal cost (SMC) curves. We know that there
is a short-run marginal cost curve corresponding to each short-run average cost curve. We find
the short-run marginal cost of each level of output produced in the long- run. We obtain the long-
run marginal cost (LMC) curve by joining the points showing short-run marginal cost of
producing the different levels of output in the long- run. For example, the short-run marginal cost
is Q1E8 for Q1, Q2E9 for Q2, Q3E4 for Q3, Q4E 10 for Q4 and Q5E11 for Q5 level of output. We
99
obtain the LMC curve by joining the points like E8, E9,E4, E10 and E11. In Figure 5.11, we show
both the LAC and LMC curves derived in Figure 5.10.
We observe that LMC is less than LAC as long as LAC continues to fall. LMC is equal to LAC at the
minimum point of LAC curve LMC is greater than LAC as long as LAC continues to rise.
LAC
LMC
LMC
LAC
0 Q
Q3
100
Review Questions
1. Derive different short-run cost curves? Is there any relation among them?
2. Explain the different nature of short-run cost curves.
3. Derive the long-run cost curves and explain their natures.
4. How is the long-run average cost curve derived from the short-run average cost curves?
The long-run average cost curve joins the minimum points on the short-run average cost
curves. Do you agree?
5. How are internal and external economies related to long-run average cost curves?
101
Lesson 3: Laws of Returns
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
explain returns to variable proportions;
explain returns to scale; and
compare laws of variable proportions with returns to scale.
Introduction
In Lesson 1 of this unit, we have discussed the basic concepts and tools of analysis used in the
exposition of production theory. There we briefly explained the returns to variable proportions
and the returns to scale. The laws related to the returns to variable proportions and the returns to
scale are called the laws of returns. In this lesson, we will discuss the laws in detail. There are
two kinds of laws of returns:
Laws of returns
Law of variable proportions
In Lesson 1 of this unit, you learnt that Production is a function of both capital and labor. It is,
however, possible for a firm to increase production by holding capital constant and employing
more and more of labor. This is actually true in the short-run, because the supply of capital is
inelastic in the short-run.
102
When production is carried out with capital as a fixed factor and labor as a variable factor, or
when more and more of labor is used with a fixed amount of capital, capital-labor proportions
change. The change in factor proportions causes a change in output at a certain rate. The
relationship between the changing factor proportions and the output is generalized in the forms
of certain laws of production which are called the laws of variable proportions.
Main theme of the law
The law of variable proportions can be stated as follows:
If more and more of a variable input is applied to a fixed input, the total output initially
increases at an increasing rate, but beyond a certain level of output, it increases at a diminishing
rate. More precisely, if some factors are held constant and more and more units of a variable
factor are employed, the marginal product of the variable factor initially increases, then
decreases and eventually turns negative.
Therefore, the law of variable proportions refers to three regions of production: increasing
returns, diminishing returns and negative returns. These are discussed below with a table and
also with figure.
103
Given the production technology, the size of the capital, the fixed factor, is given.
300-
250-
200- TP
150-
100-
50-
0
50-
100-
AP L
Labor
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
MPL
It is indivisible. Therefore, a certain minimum labor is required to make the optimum use of the
capital. If a smaller number of workers are used, capital remains underutilised. This under-
utilisation of the fixed factor, capital, causes the firm come out with returns at an increasing rate
as it increases the employment of the variable factor, labor. Let us suppose that optimum capital-
labor combination is 1:5. That is, one unit of capital is optimally used with 5 workers. Under this
condition, if less than 5 workers are employed, the plant or machine would remain under-
utilised. When more and more workers are added, utilisation of machine increases and also the
productivity of additional workers. Another reason for increase in labor productivity is that,
employment of additional workers leads to advantages of division of labor, until optimum
capital-labor combination is reached.
104
Technical reasons: As mentioned earlier, employing more labor beyond the optimum capital-
labor combination means substituting another. In our case here, this limit is given by MPL =
0. Any addition of labor beyond this limit leads to overcrowding, lower availability of tools
and equipments which causes fall in total production. Besides, use of more and more labor
results in excessive exploitation of capital. This reduces its contribution to production. For
example, use of excessive labor on a piece of land reduces its fertility. That is why, the law
of diminishing returns is more applicable to agriculture.
Managerial reasons: Overcrowding gives labor an opportunity to shift work responsibility to
others. Instead of cooperating with each other, they come in each other' way. With excess
labor, it becomes increasingly difficult to fix accountability. Labor can therefore avoid the
work.
The Laws of Returns to Scale
In the previous paragraphs, we have discussed production with one variable input (labor),
holding the other input (capital) constant. Here we will discuss input-output relationships under
the condition that all the inputs (labor and capital) are proportionately and simultaneously
changed. When all the inputs are proportionately increased, the scale of production, the size of
the firm increases. The laws that pertain to the input-output relationships under the condtion of
changing scale of production are called the Laws of Returns of Scale. The laws of returns to
scale are a long-term phenomenon.
In the long-run, supplies of both labor and capital are elastic. Therefore, the firms can employ
more of both labor and capital to increase their production. In this section, the question that we
will answer is: how does total output behave when all the inputs are proportionately changed?
When all the inputs are proportionately increased, there are technically three possible ways in
which total output may increase. For example, if all the inputs are doubled, the resulting output
may more than double, double and grow less than double. This kind of output behavior gives
three kinds of returns to scale as given below:
If increase in output is more than proportional to the increase in inputs, it means increasing
return to scale.
If increase in output is proportional to increase in inputs, it gives constant returns to scale.
If increase in output is less than proportional to the increase in inputs, it gives decreasing
returns to scale.
105
Increasing Returns to Scale
As stated above, the law of increasing returns to scale implies that output increases more than
proportionately to the increase in inputs. For example, when inputs increase by 50% output
increases by more than 50%; when inputs are increased by 100%; output increases by more than
100% and so on. This kind of returns to change in scale is illustrated in Figure 5.13. Isoquants
EQ1 and EQ2 represent two different levels of production, 20 units, 50 units, respectively.
Product line OA shows the relationship between inputs and output. For instance, movement from
point a to b denotes doubling the inputs, labor, and capital. As Figure 5.13 shows, input
combination increases from K + L to 2K + 2L. The movement from a to b also indicates increase
in output from 20 units to 50 units. This means that when inputs are doubled output has more
than doubled. This reveals increasing returns to scale.
A
Capital
Product line
b
2K
EQ2=50
a
K
EQ1=20
0 L
L 2L
Labor
Figure 5.13: Increasing returns to scale
A
Capital
Product line
b
2K
EQ2=40
a
K
EQ1=20
0 L
L 2L
Labor
Figure 5.14: Constant returns to scale
The constant returns to scale are also attributable to the limits of the economies of scale. With the
expansion in the scale of production, economies arise from such factors as indivisibility of
certain factors, greater possibility of specialization of capital and labor, use of labor-saving
techniques of production, etc. But there is a limit to the economies of scale. When economies of
scale disappear and diseconomies are yet to begin, the returns to scale becomes constant. The
diseconomies arise mainly because of decreasing efficiency of management and scarcity of
certain inputs.
107
The constant returns to scale are said to occur also in productive activities in which factors of
production are perfectly divisible.
A
Capital
Product line
b
2K
EQ2=30
a
K
EQ1=20
0 L
L 2L
Labor
Figure 5.15: Decreasing returns to scale
108
Comparison between the Law of Variable Proportions and Returns to Scale
The basic difference between the law of returns to a variable factor and the law of returns to
scale lies in the assumptions and conditions on which these laws are based.
The law of returns to a variable factor allows only one input to vary, holding all other inputs
constant, whereas in the case of the law of returns to scale all the inputs are variable.
The law of returns to a variable factor is a short-run phenomenon, because, supply of capital
in the short-run is inelastic. On the contrary, the law of returns to scale is a long-run
phenomenon, because, supply of all the inputs in the long-run is elastic and more and more of
their quantities can be employed.
Review Questions
1. What is meant by the laws of returns? Why is this law associated with one variable input?
2. What is the law of diminishing returns? Why it is called the law of variable proportions?
3. Discuss the law of variable proportions. What are the causes of diminishing returns?
4. Draw diagrams to show firms' average product, marginal product and total product curves
in the short period. How do these curves depict the law of variable proportions?
5. State and explain returns to scale using suitable iso-product diagrams.
6. Show returns to scale with the help of iso-product map.
7. Show increasing, constant and diminishing returns to scale with the help of iso-product
diagrams.
8. Distinguish between the law of variable proportions and returns to scale. Enumerate the
factors that cause decreasing returns to scale.
109
Unit 6: PERFECT COMPETITION
Highlights
Introduction
A firm owner, popularly known as factory owner, may have different motives when she/he
organizes production activities. For example, she/he may be interested in increasing her/his
social status as an industrialist. In Economics, however, profit maximization is identified as the
sole motive for undertaking production activities. Profit is the difference between total revenue
and total cost of production, both depending on the nature of market. Total revenue is equal to
the product of price of the commodity and quantity of the commodity sold. The price which a
seller can charge its buyers for his commodity depends on the nature of market. Total cost of
production depends, among others, on the prices of inputs of production which in turn are
determined by the forces of input market. Total cost of production also depends on the
productivity of inputs. The important point is that profit of an entrepreneur depends on the nature
of both product market and input market. A study of market structure is, therefore, important to
realize the price and output determination process. Economists conceptualize two broad
categories of market structures: perfect competition and imperfect competition. In this unit, we
undertake the study of the ideal form of market structure which is called perfect competition.
110
Characteristics of Perfect Competition
The economists' concept of perfect competition is quite opposite of the businessmen's concept of
competition. Businessmen would describe the market for tooth paste as highly competitive
indicating the rigorous competition among the few brands of tooth paste in the market. This type
of market is quite distinct from what the economist calls perfect competition. The concept of
perfect competition in Economics is entirely impersonal. The economists always refer to large
number of buyers and sellers in perfect competition so that no one seller or no one buyer can
exert a perceptible influence on the market price. The market price is determined at the level
where aggregate demand from all consumers of the product just equals the aggregate supply of
the product from all sellers. Perfect competition is better known as the market of price takers as
opposed to the market of price makers. Both the buyers and sellers in perfect competition are
price takers. A price taker is a firm or consumer who sells or buys at the given price. If the price
of Aman rice is Tk. 16 per kg the next door grocer charges the same price of Tk. 16 for each
Kilogram of Aman rice sold when the consumer buys 100 kg or 1000 kg The seller does not give
any kind of price rebate whatever be the volume of the sale.
We now turn to a systematic description of the characteristics of perfect competition. It should be
noted at this point that all the characteristics of perfect competition ensure price-taking behavior
of firms and buyers.
Large number of buyers and sellers: Presence of many buyers and sellers in the market is the
most important feature of perfect competition. Because of a large number of buyers and sellers,
each buyer buys and each seller sells a very small fraction of total output sold in the market.
Consequently, no single seller or no single buyer can exert a perceptible effect on price. Not only
the buyers and the sellers are many in number, but also they are widely scattered all over the
country so that they find it difficult to organize themselves into groups. By forming groups or
associations, the buyers as a group can claim price rebate. Similarly, the sellers can raise the
price of the product by forming guilds of sellers. Because of multiplicity of numbers and lack of
concerted pressure, no single seller or no single buyer can exert a perceptible effect on the price
of the product. If a seller charges a higher price than her/his rivals, she/he looses customers.
Though a seller cannot sell at a price higher than the market price, why cannot he sell at a lower
price? He cannot sell at lower price because by doing so he incurs unnecessary loss - he can sell
all of his product at the market price.
Homogeneous product: All the firms in perfect competition produce and sell identical product.
Product of one firm cannot be distinguished from the product of another firm. If the product of
one firm can be differentiated from the product of other firms by any means, the said firm may
have some fixed customers who will be willing to pay even a higher price for their preferred
product. Since the product in perfect competition is homogeneous the question of paying a
different price for the product of any firm does not arise.
No barriers to entry or exit: Perfectly competitive firms face no barriers in moving into and
leaving the industry in three senses. Industry is a collection of all firms producing a
homogeneous product. A firm is production unit comprising one or more production plants
which is independent in decision making.
Firstly, firms from other industries or new firms can enter into the industry if existing firms make
supernormal profit. Similarly, some of the losing firms may leave the industry in the long-run.
Secondly, barriers to entry might arise due to economic reasons. New firms may be prevented
111
from entering into an industry due to the existence of patent laws and other legal barriers.
Economies of scale enjoyed by large firms prevent other firms from entering into the industry
because entry of new firms would cause average cost of production to rise and to drive away the
small firms. Cost of providing funds may be high for new firms due to imperfections in the
capital markets. These kinds of economic barriers may restrict entry or exit of firms. Thirdly,
barriers to entry or exit might arise from immobility of some specific factors of production or
when the resources are owned by one firm. It is assumed that such immobility of factors of
production or sole ownership of resources does not exist in perfect competition.
Complete information: The consumers, producers, and resource-owners are assumed to possess
prefect knowledge about prices and quality of the commodities and inputs. An ignorant
consumer may buy the product at a price higher than the market price. Similarly, the unaware
input-supplier may be offered a lower price than the market price of input. The profit
maximizing entrepreneur must be fully knowledgeable about both the prices of output and input.
The Average Revenue (AR) and Marginal Revenue (MR) Curves of a Competitive Firm
The total income or total revenue (TR) of a firm is equal to the product of the price of the
commodity and the number of units sold: TR = Pq. Conversely, the average income or average
revenue (AR) is calculated by dividing total revenue by the quantity of output sold: AR=TR/q.
Another related concept is marginal revenue which is defined as the change in total revenue
resulting from one unit change in output. For a better understanding of profit maximizing
behavior of a competitive firm, we need to examine what happens to total revenue (TR) when
quantity of output sold increases. The curve showing the relationship between total revenue and
the quantity of output sold is known as total revenue curve. Similarly, the average revenue curve
shows the relationship between AR and Q. Marginal revenue curve shows how marginal revenue
changes when quantity of output increases. Our next discussion focuses on the shapes of the TR,
AR and MR curves of a competitive firm.
It was mentioned earlier that a competitive firm is a price-taker. Its perception is that it can sell
any quantity of output at the given market price. This perception arises, because, the maximum
amount of output that an individual firm can produce and sell in the market using all of its
production capacity constitutes a very small fraction of aggregate output produced and sold in
the market. Consequently, the firm cannot exert any influence on the market price. The following
example clarifies this point:
Suppose, the amount of total annual sale of Pajam rice in Bangladesh at a price of Tk. 15 per kg
is ten thousand million kg A grocer or a farmer cannot charge a price higher than Tk. 15 per kg
for this brand of rice when a buyer buys 100 kg or 1000 kg or any other quantity the farmer can
sell. The individual firm charges the same price of Tk. 15 for any quantity of the product it can
sell. In other words, price or AR of the firm remains fixed at Tk. 15 when quantity of output of
sold increases. As a result, the AR curve of a competitive firm becomes a horizontal line at the
given market price. Panel A of Figure-6.1 shows the AR curve of a hypothetical competitive
firm. In this diagram, price or AR is measured along the vertical axis and quantity sold along the
horizontal axis. It can be seen from panel A of the Figure-6.1 that the price of the commodity is
Tk. 15 if the firm sells 100 kg or 1000 kg or any other quantity the firm can produce using 100%
of production capacity. One question still remains to be answered: How is the market price of
Tk. 15 determined? The answer is given in paned B of Figure 6.1. The units of measurements in
112
both the panels of Figure 6.1 are the same along the vertical axes but the units are not, however,
the same along the horizontal axes.
The units are 100 kg of rice along the horizontal axis of panel A and one billion kg of rice along
the horizontal axis of panel B. The DD and SS curves are aggregate demand curve for and
aggregate supply curve of the product respectively. It is shown in Panel B that the market price
of Tk. 15 is determined at the intersection point of the aggregate demand and supply curves. We
can conclude that the price determined in the market gives the horizontal price or AR curves of
the firm.
Panel B
Price
Panel A
D S
P = AR = MR
Tk. 15 Tk. 15
S D
O 1 10 Q
Quantity (in 100 kg) Quantity (in billion kg)
Having determined the shape of the AR curve, we now turn to the discussion of the shape of the
MR curve of a competitive firm. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue brought about
by sale of one additional unit of output. Since a competitive firm sells all units of output at the
same price, the additional total revenue from the sale of one extra unit becomes equal to price. If
the firm sells 100 units of output at a price of Tk. 15, the 101th unit is also sold at the same price
of Tk. 15. So that the additional revenue from the sale of that last unit of output also becomes Tk.
15. In other words, the MR curve of the firm coincides with the price curve or the AR curve of
the firm. This is why the horizontal AR curve in panel A of Figure 6.1 has been labeled as the P
= AR = MR curve.
Finally, we discuss the nature of the total revenue (TR) curve of a competitive firm. Since the
competitive firm can sell any quantity of its output at a constant price, its total revenue will
increase at a constant rate with the increase in the level of output. The result is that the total
revenue curve will be a straight line starting from the origin as shown in Figure 6.2.
113
TR
TR
B
Total revenue
A C
0 q1 q2
Quantity
In the figure we measure TR along the vertical axis and quantity of output along the horizontal
axis. The shape of the total revenue curve is important because it gives values of AR and MR at a
particular level of output of the firm. Average revenue at a particular level of output is given by
the slope value of a straight line joining the origin and the point at which a vertical line drawn
upward from that particular level of output intersects the TR curve. For example, AR at q 2 is
given by the slope of the line segment OB: AR=Bq2/Oq 2. To find MR between two levels of
output, we draw two vertical lines from the two levels of output to determine the points at which
these vertical lines intersect the TR curve. The slope value of the line segment between these two
intersection points gives the MR value. For example, MR between q 1 and q2 in Figure 6.2 is
given by the slope value of line segment AB : BC/AC.
Since line segment AB is a portion of line segment OB in Figure 6.2, both the line segments will
have the same slope value. We come back to the previous conclusion: for a competitive firm
both the AR and MR curves coincide with each other.
Review Questions
1. (a) What is a perfectly competitive firm?
(b) What are the two characteristics that give rise to such a firm?
2. (a) What is the shape of the demand curve facing a perfectly competitive firm?
(b) What is implied by such a demand curve?
3. What are the characteristics of perfect competition? Under what market conditions a firm is a
price taker?
4. Write a short note on AR and MR curves of a competitive firm.
114
Lesson 2: Equilibrium of a Competitive Firm
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
state when a competitive firm operates and when it shuts down in the short-run ;
explain the profit maximizing conditions of a firm;
state how a competitive firm determines its equilibrium level of output in the short-run; and
state how a competitive firm determines its profit and shut-down point in the short-run.
Once a firm has decided to keep its production line busy in the short-run, its next task is to
decide the profit maximizing level of output when P > SATC at all levels of output and to decide
the loss minimizing level of output when the minimum SAVC < P < SATC. The profit
115
maximizing or loss minimizing level of output is known as equilibrium level of output since the
firm cannot do better by producing any other quantity of output.
116
The Graphical Method with MR and MC curves
The graphical method of determining the profit maximizing level of output with the help of MR
and MC curves has been shown in Figure 6.3 with MR and MC measured along the vertical axis
and quantity of output along the horizontal axis.
SMC
MR SMC
AR
G
A B D F H AR=MR
C
E
Q
0 q1 q2 q3 q4 q* q5
Output
Figure 6.3: Profit maximization with MR and MC curves
Suppose, the market price of the commodity is P0 which the firm accepts as fixed. The horizontal
line at price P0 is virtually the AR = MR curve of the firm. The SMC curve shows the nature of
short-run marginal cost of the firm. Suppose, the firm's initial production level is q3. If the firm
decides to increase its output level to q 4, its MR becomes q 4D but its MC equals q 4E so that MR
exceeds MC. The firm makes supernormal profit of Tk. DE from the last unit of output and its
total profit increases. The firm increases its sale by one unit again to increase its total profit
further. The process of increasing output level continues until the firm produces output level q*
where MR = MC. The firm earns no profit from the last unit and total profit turns out to be
maximum at q*. If the firm increases output to q5, its MR falls short of MC. q5H < q5G. Profit
becomes negative for the last unit of output sold and the firm's total profit decreases from the
maximum level. If the initial output level were q5, the firm would reduce it q*, which is the profit
maximizing level of output in the figure. It is easily seen that at to q*, MR equals MC and MC is
increasing in the neighborhood. At q1, MR = MC but q1 is not the profit maximizing level of
output. An increase in the quantity of output from q1 to q2 leads to a fall in marginal cost from q1
A to q2B when MR remains fixed at the previous level of q1 A, i.e., q1 A=q 2B. Since the firm can
make a profit of Tk. BC by increasing its sale level from q1 to q2, q 1 cannot qualify as the profit
maximizing level of output. It is thus shown that MR = MC is only the necessary condition, not
the sufficient condition, of profit maximization. The sufficient condition requires that the MC
curve be increasing in the neighborhood of output level where MR = MC.
117
The Tabular Method
The process of determining the profit maximizing level of output can also be explained with the
help of a table similar to that given below. The first column of the table shows the units of
output. It is evident from the first column that the sale of the product is increasing by one unit
each time. The price of the product, which is also MR of the firm, is assumed to be Tk. 25 for all
units of output as shown in the second column. In the third column, we show MC which falls
from an initial high level and then starts rising from a minimum level. The fourth column gives
the amount of marginal profit obtained from successive marginal units of output. Satisfaction of
necessary condition of profit maximization, MR = MC, yields zero profit for the marginal unit at
the equilibrium point. Only the units before the marginal unit yield positive profits. Though we
notice zero profit for the second and 6th units, the second unit cannot be the equilibrium output
level. If output level is increased by one additional unit to 3 units, marginal cost decreases to Tk.
20 when MR remains at Tk. 25 so that the third unit brings profit of Tk. 5.
Table 6.1: Profit maximizing level of output of a competitive firm
Unit of output P=AR=MR MC(Tk.) Marginal Total profit
(Tk.) Profit (Tk.) (Tk.)
1st 25 31 -6 -6
2nd 25 25 0 -6
3rd 25 20 5 -1
4th 25 18 7 6
5th 25 23 2 8
6th 25 25 0 8
7th 25 34 -9 -1
8th 25 40 -15 -16
Similarly, a profit of Tk. 7 can be earned from the 4th unit. The firm will increase its output level
as long as it can earn a positive profit from sale of the last unit of output. At the sixth unit of
output, MR equals MC yielding zero profit. It can be easily seen from Table 6.1 that profit
becomes negative for output level beyond the sixth unit. Sixth unit of output becomes the profit
maximizing level of output where MR = MC. Moreover, MC is found to increase in the
neighborhood of the sixth unit of output. The fifth column of the table gives the amount of total
profit which is calculated by adding the marginal profits of previous units to the marginal profit
of the current unit. The maximum profit in this table is found to be Tk.8 at the sixth unit of
output.
118
The Graphical Method with TR and TC Curves
Another method of determining the equilibrium level of output uses the total revenue and total
cost curves. Figure-6.4 illustrates the use of these curves for finding the profit maximizing level
of output. The vertical axis measures TC and TR in taka and the horizontal axis measures the
level of output Q. The TR curve shows the changing pattern of total revenue of a competitive
TC
TR
TR
TC
Q
0 q1 q2 q* q3
Output
Figure 6.4: Profit maximization with TR and TC curves
firm and the TC curve shows the changing pattern of short-run total cost of a firm when output
level increases. Profit is the difference between TR and TC so that the gap between these two
curves measures total profit at different output levels. We observe that profit is negative up to q2,
positive between q2 and q3 and again negative after q3 level of output. The maximum profit is
obtained at output level q*.
At q*, a tangent drawn on the TC curve becomes parallel to the TR curve indicating that the
slope of the TC curve, which is MC, equals the slope of the TR curve, which is MR. Once again,
we find that MR equals MC at the profit maximizing level of output. Moreover, the TC curve is
found to be upward sloping and convex to the origin. The mathematical implication of upward
sloping and convex to the origin TC curve is that MC is positive and rising in the neighborhood
of equilibrium level of output. The slopes of the TC and TR curves, which are MC and MR
values respectively, are also found to be equal at q1, but this level of output maximizes loss, not
profit. At q1, the necessary condition of profit maximization is satisfied, but the sufficient
condition is not satisfied.
Determining Profit and the Shut-down Point
In the preceding analysis, our primary concern was related to determination of the profit
maximizing level of output. We discussed three equivalent methods of doing that and showed
how to find the maximum profit in each of three cases. Here, we demonstrate another method of
determining total profit with the help of short-run average total cost (SATC) and short-run
average variable cost (SAVC) curves. Before doing that we must distinguish between the
economists' definition of profit and the accountants' definition of profit. As we know, total profit
is the difference between total revenue and total cost. The economists incorporate the
opportunity cost of the entrepreneur as an item of total cost. The entrepreneur's opportunity cost
is the nominal value of all financial and fringe benefits she/he could earn in her/his next best
occupation. Instead of engaging himself full-time in organizing and managing the current firm,
119
the entrepreneur could work elsewhere in different capacities and earn some income as
remuneration for her/his work in his next best occupation. She/he forgoes this income when
she/he takes over as the entrepreneur of the current firm and the forgone income thus becomes
the opportunity cost of her/his current occupation. The accountants do not include this
opportunity cost in total cost of the firm, whereas the economists take this items of cost into
consideration. According to the economists, the firm is said to earn normal profit when total
revenue equals total cost inclusive of entrepreneur's opportunity cost. The firm earns
supernormal profit if total revenue exceeds total cost and incurs loss if total revenue becomes
less than total cost. A firm finds its short-run equilibrium level of output where the two
conditions of profit maximization are satisfied. At the equilibrium output level, the firm may find
itself in one of the five situations of profit. It may earn supernormal profit. or normal profit. It
may also incur loss which may be less than, equal to, or greater than total fixed cost. The five
situations of profit are demonstrated in five panels of Figure 6.5.
O q1 O q2
O q3 O q4
Panel E
SMC
SATC
A5 B5
SAVC
D5
C5
P5 AR5=MR5
E5
O q4
120
Figure 6.5: Five situations of profit
In each panel, we determine the equilibrium level of output of the competitive firm using the two
conditions of profit maximization, viz, (i) MR = MC; (ii) MC is increasing.
In Panel A, equilibrium output is q1 at which per unit profit is E 1B1. Total profit at equilibrium
output level is E1B 1A1P 1. Suppose, the market price falls to p2 in panel B. The two conditions of
profit maximization are satisfied at E2 where price equals SATC yielding normal profit to the
firm. If market price goes down further to p3 in panel C, equilibrium output becomes q3
corresponding to equilibrium point E 3. The firm, however, incurs loss at E3, because, price q3E 3
falls short of short-run average total cost q3 B3. Per unit loss is B3 E3 and total loss is B3E3 A3P3.
We know that the gap between the SATC and SAVC curves gives a measure of SAFC, which is
B3D3 at equilibrium level of output. Multiplying B3D3 by quantity of equilibrium output q3, we
get total fixed cost equal to area C 3D3B3P3 which is greater than total loss B3E 3P3A3. Since the
firm's operating loss B3E 3P3 A3 is less than the shut-down loss, which is equal to total fixed cost
C3D3B 3P3, the firm keeps its production activities running. In Panel D, the market price falls to
the level of the minimum SAVC the firm incurs loss equal to total fixed cost P4E4B4A4 at
equilibrium output q4. The firm's total loss remains the same when it keeps operating it or it shuts
down. In panel E, the market price of the commodity dips down further and goes below the
minimum SAVC to P5. Equilibrium output now becomes q5 corresponding to equilibrium point
E5. The firm's total loss P 5E5B5 A5 will be greater than total fixed cost C5D5B5A5 if the firm
continues its production activities but this loss will be equal to total fixed cost if it shuts down.
The firm will, of course, shut down in such a situation.
D0 S0
SMC1 LMC S1
SAC 1
E0 E1 A
P0 P0
SAC2 LAC
A0 B0
A1 B1
B
P1 P1
E2
S0 D0
S1
O q0 q* q1 q O Q
(i) Each firm of the industry determines its equilibrium level of output according to the two
conditions of equilibrium.
(a) MR = SMC = LMC.
(b) Both SMC and LMC will be increasing.
(ii) The Price line in the long-run equilibrium of the firm will be tangent to the LAC curve at its
minimum point so that each firm earns only normal profit. This condition ensures that there
will be no tendency for the new firms to enter into and for the old firms to leave the
industry.
(iii) At the long-run equilibrium of the firm, market price will be determined such that the total
demand from all consumers for the commodity will just be equal to the total supply of the
commodity.
In Figure 6.6, these three conditions are met if the typical firm and hence each firm produces the
output level q* at the minimum point of the LAC curve and uses the optimum plant with the
short-run average cost curve SAC2. Here, the long-run price level P1 is equal to the minimum
LAC.
122
Review Questions
1. Explain the short-run equilibrium of a competitive firm. When would a competitive firm
close down its business in the short-run?
2. Show how under the condition of perfect competition in the long-run, the price of a
commodity equal to its average and marginal cost.
3. Write a short note on the relationship between firm’s short-run cost curves and supply curve.
4. Explain the long-run equilibrium of a competitive firm. Does a competitive firm incur loss in
the long-run?
123
Unit 7: MONOPOLY
Highlights
Nature of Monopoly
AR & MR curve in Monopoly Market
Equilibrium of a Monopolist
Comparison between Monopoly and Perfect Competition
Measures of Monopoly Power
Regulating the Monopoly.
124
consider Bangladesh Telegraph and Telephone (T&T) Board as a monopoly for telephone
services in the country. But in Bangladesh people use other devices of communication like FAX,
e-mail, courier service, etc., for fast and ensured passage of information. These devices of
communication serve as substitutes for telephone services, though these are not perfect
substitutes. Since it is very difficult to find a commodity without substitutes, pure monopoly
market as defined above is rare in the real world. Though each commodity must face competition
from its substitutes, the degree of substitutability varies among different pairs of commodities.
Two commodities may be close substitutes as in case of two tooth-paste brands or these
commodities may be distant substitutes like electric bulb and candle when used for lighting
rooms. Alternatively, the same two commodities, electric bulb, and candle may be close
substitutes when used for lighting. The degree of substitutability is also dependent on time. A
commodity might not have close substitutes at present, but such substitutes may eventually be
developed in future in response to higher price of the commodity charged by the monopolist. It
is, therefore, the degree of substitutability rather than availability of substitutes which should be
used as a criterion in the definition of monopoly market. Lack of precise measurement of degree
of substitutability between two commodities may give rise to subjectivity and value judgments in
the process of defining monopoly market in reality. The second element about ownership of
production enterprise can also be changed. Two or more producers can form a monopoly market
if they merge together to form a joint firm and act in concert to take price and output decisions
like a monopolist.
Now that we have defined a monopoly market, the next question that arises is why does a
monopoly market endure once it has been created? The answer is simple: A monopoly market
exists because barriers to entry into market prevent other firms from entering and competing with
the monopolist. These barriers to entry can take different forms.
Sometimes a firm might have sole ownership of an important input to a product, which makes
the firm the only producer and seller of the product. The barriers may be created by legal
authorities. In some cases, the government permits only one firm the right to produce and sell a
commodity or service. The license to run a restaurant in a railway station is an example of a local
monopoly created by legal authority. Another legal monopoly is patent, which is legal protection
of an innovation given out to a firm or a person for the time, energy, and merit expended on the
innovation. A patent allows the patent holder to be a monopoly in using the innovation. Patent is
given to encourage research and development activities. New firms cannot attain the level of
technological progress profitably utilized by the monopolist. Lack of advance technology acts as
a barrier to entry. Barriers to entry are also created by natural monopolist. A natural monopolist
enjoys economies of scale in the form of falling average and marginal costs with increase in the
level of output. These economies of scale disappear if monopoly is abolished and two more firms
share the market. As a result, the monopolist can drive away the potential competitors. Natural
monopolies occur in the case of production enterprises with very large amount of overhead costs
compared to minimal variable cost.
125
Nature of AR and MR Curves
Since there is one producer in monopoly market, the monopolist has enough power to exert
control over price or output. She/he is not a price taker like the competitive firm; rather she/he is
a price-maker. She/he can set the price of the commodity at any level she/he likes. She/he can
charge a higher price or she/he can be satisfied with a low price. Though the monopolist can set
the price, she/he cannot set simultaneously the quantity she/he will sell at the predetermined
price. The consumers are sovereign and it is to the consumers to decide how much output to
demand and consume at the given price. Normally the consumers are supposed to be guided by
the principle of equi-marginal utility which requires that marginal utility per taka spent on each
commodity be equal. Other things remaining the same, consumers demand and consume more at
a low price and less at a higher price. The monopolist cannot force the consumers to buy more at
a high price. Ultimately the monopolist finds that she/he can sell more if she/he sets a low price
and can sell less if she/he sets a high price. Alternatively, the monopolist can set the amount of
P
AR
P1
P2
0 q1 q2 q
her/his sale and leave the price to be determined by the consumers' preferences. This time, the
monopolist observes that the consumers are willing to pay a lower price at a higher level of sale
and a higher price at a lower level of sale. This means that the average revenue curve of the
monopolist, which is demand curve of the consumers, is a downward sloping curve. A typical
AR curve of the monopolist is shown in Figure 7.1 with AR or price measured along the vertical
axis and quantity sold or quantity demanded along the horizontal axis.
As it can be seen from the Figure, the monopolist can sell q1 if she/he sets the price at P1 and q2
if she/he sets the price at P2. The final result is that the AR or price always falls with increase in
the level of output sold.
Let's now discuss the shape of the MR curve in a monopoly market. In the case of perfect
competition, the firm can sell any amount of the commodity within its capacity at a constant
AR
MR
A
B C
126
MR AR
0 q1 q2 q
Figure 7.2: AR and MR curve of the monopolist
price. As a result, price equals marginal revenue for a competitive firm. The monopolist has to
reduce the price level if she/he wants to sell one extra unit. If she/he didn't want to sell the extra
unit, she/he could get the higher price for all previous units. Now that she/he sells one more unit,
she/he gets a lower price for all previous units as well as for the extra unit. The change in total
revenue from the sale of last unit or MR of the monopolist will be less than the price of the last
unit because she/he is getting a lower price on each of the previous units. In fact, MR will be
equal to price of the last unit minus the total loss due to a low price on all previous units. It
means that when AR falls with the increase in output sold, MR becomes less than AR at all
levels of output except at the starting point. We state an additional result without proving that the
MR curve always lies at mid- point between the price axis and the straight line AR curve.
Figure 7.2 shows the positions of the AR and MR curves of a monopolist. It shows that the MR
curve lies below the AR curve at all levels of output between O and q 1. After output q1, MR,
however, becomes negative whereas AR becomes negative after output q2. Draw a horizontal
line that interscts the MR and AR curves from point A on the vertical axis. It can be seen that AB
= BC, which shows that the MR curve lies halfway between the price axis and the AR curve. The
nature of the AR and MR curves and the relationship between them can also be explained with
the help of a table. Table 7.1 shows the values of AR = Price, TR and MR for a hypothetical
commodity of a monopolist.
Table 7.1: Relationship among AR, MR and TR
AR = Price Output = q TR = AR.q MR= TR/q
40 10 400
38 11 418 18
36 12 432 14
34 13 442 10
32 14 448 6
As we can see from Table 7.1, the monopolist's initial sale is 10 units of output at price of Tk. 40
yielding a total revenue of Tk. 400. To sell one more unit of the commodity, the monopolist has
to lower the price from Tk. 40 to Tk. 38. Total revenue now stands at Tk. 418 giving the
marginal revenue of Tk. 18. We find that marginal revenue is less than price Tk. 38 at which 11
units were sold. The monopolist lost Tk. 2 (Tk. 40 - Tk. 38) on each of the previous 10 units so
that her/his total loss on previous units amounts to Tk. 20 (10 Tk. 2). Deducting the loss of Tk.
20 from the price of Tk. 38 for the last unit, we get the marginal revenue of Tk. 18 (Tk. 38 - Tk.
20). We notice from the table that MR is less than AR = Price at all levels of output starting from
the 11th unit. For example, at 13 units of output, AR is Tk. 34, whereas MR is Tk. 10. Here, both
the AR and MR values are found to decrease with the increase in the quantity of output.
Moreover, the rate of decrease of MR is Tk. 4 which is two times Tk. 2, the rate of decrease of
AR. This is not a mere coincidence. The values of AR and q in Table-7.1 have been chosen such
that these values correspond to a straight line downward sloping AR curve. In the case of linear
AR curve, the rate of fall of MR is always double the rate of fall of AR. We can summarize the
results on the shapes of the AR and MR curves in a monopoly market as follows:
(i) Both the AR and MR curves are downward sloping;
(ii) The MR curve falls at a faster rate than the AR curve; and
(iii) In the case of a straight line AR curve, the rate of decrease of the MR curve is always
double the rate of decrease of the AR curve.
127
Relationship Among AR, MR, and Price Elasticity
We derive an equation that shows how AR, MR and price elasticity of demand are related with
each other. Figure 7.3 is used for this purpose.
AR
MR
A
B C
G
D
MR AR
0 q1 F q
128
AR
Therefore, EP =
AR MR
Rearranging we get,
1
MR = AR (1 - )
EP
From the above equation, we get the following results:
MR = 0 when EP = 1
MR > 0 when EP > 1
MR < 0 when EP < 1
Review Questions
1. (a) How does an imperfectly competitive firm differ from one that is perfectly
competitive?
(b) If an imperfectly competitive firm wishes to increase quantity sold, what must it do to
price?
2. What is monopoly and how does its definition depend on how the industry is defined?
3. Bangladesh Railway is generally given exclusive right to provide rail transportation
service throughout the country. Is Bangladesh Railway a monopolist? Explain.
4. (a) What is marginal revenue (MR) and why is MR less than price for a firm facing a
downward-sloping demand curve?
(b) Draw a demand curve facing a monopoly firm and its corresponding marginal
revenue curve. Do the same for a perfectly competitive firm.
5. Explain the sources of monopoly?
129
Lesson 2: Price and Output Determination under Monopoly: Equilibrium of
Monopolist
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
determine profit maximizing levels' of output and price in the short-run;
determine profit maximizing levels of output and price in the long-run;
why a monopolist does not have a supply curve; and
the rule of thumb for pricing in monopoly.
Panel A Panel B
SATC
SMC SMC
A1 SATC A2
P1 P2
C1
B1
E2
E1
MR AR MR AR
0 q1 q 0 q2 q
Panel C Panel D
SMC
SMC SATC
B4
SATC C4
B3 D4 SAVC
C3 G4
P3 A3 SAVC P4
D3 A4
G3
E3 E1
MR AR MR AR
0 q3 q 0 q4 q
The monopolist incurs a loss of B3A3 per unit of output and her/his total loss is P3A3B3C3. Since
the monopolist's total loss is less than her/his total fixed cost D3G3B3C3, it means the portion
D3G3 A3P 3 of his total fixed cost is being covered in the short-run. Since the monopolist's loss
becomes less when she/he runs the production firm than when she/he shuts down, it pays the
monopolist to keep the firm open in the short-run. In panel D of the figure, the loss minimizing
level of output q4 dictates a price level of q4 A4 which is even less than short-run average variable
cost (SAVC) of q4G4. The monopolist's total loss will be equal to total fixed cost when it shuts
down and it will be more than total fixed cost when it operates. Since the monopolist's total loss
131
becomes more when it operates than when it shuts down, he would certainly shut down her/his
plant in a situation depicted in panel D.
Long-run Equilibrium of the Monopolist
In the long-run, the monopolist can change her/his plant in order to increase her/his profit. The
monopolist does not run with any risk of losing profit due to entry of firms in the long-run.
Different types of barriers to entry successfully prevent new firms from entering the monopoly
market.
The monopolist tries to maximize her/his profit lying within the constraints of given demand and
cost conditions. Her/his choice of output and price levels change when these constraints change.
Depending on the nature of demand and cost conditions, the monopolist may make supernormal
profit or normal profit, but she/he will never incur a loss in the long-run. At the worst situation,
the monopolist may quit the production process in the long-run. Unlike the competitive firm, in
the long-run, the monopolist may not produce at the minimum point of LAC. The monopolist
may produce at the optimum plant or at less than optimum plant or at more than the optimum
plant. The long-run equilibrium of the monopolist is attained when the following two conditions
are met:
Panel A Panel B
SMC
LMC
SATC LAC
A1 SMC
P1 A2 LMC LAC
P2
SATC
B1
E1 B2
E2
MR AR AR
MR
0 q1 q 0 q2 q
Panel C
A3 LMC
P3
LAC
C3 E3
AR
B3
MR
0 q3 q
132
Necessary condition: SMC = LMC = MR < Price
Sufficient condition: LMC and hence SMC increases at the neighbourhood
The long-run equilibrium of the monopolist can be characterized by one of the three probable
situations shown in three panels of Figure 7.5.
In Panel A, the equilibrium point E1 gives rise to equilibrium output q1. At equilibrium level of
output, both price and long-run average cost are equal to q1 A1 so that the monopolist earns only
normal profit. The monopolist is, however, producing at less than the optimum plant in the long-
run. In panel B, the conditions of profit maximization are met at point E2, which is also the
minimum point of LAC. The firm is producing at the optimum plant in the long-run. At
equilibrium output q 2, price q2A2 is found to be greater than long-run average cost q2E2 so that
the monopolist earns supernormal profit equal to the area B2E2 A2P2. In panel C, profit
maximizing level of output is q3 corresponding to long-run equilibrium point E 3. It is easily seen
that the equilibrium output q 3 is produced by using a plant larger than the optimum plant. At q3,
price is q3A3 and long-run average cost is q3B3 yielding a total profit equal to area C3B3 A3P 3.
Examination of the three diagrams in Figure 7.5 reveals two facts about the monopolist. First, a
monopolist in the long-run equilibrium may use or may not use the optimum plant of production.
Second, in the long-run, the monopolist may earn normal profit or supernormal profit, but she/he
will never incur loss.
The Monopolist Does Not Have a Supply Curve
In perfect competitions, the firm is a price taker. The competitive firm tries to maximize its profit
by adjusting its output level to given price level which is determined at the intersection point of
the industry demand and supply curves. When the price level changes due to changes in demand
and supply conditions, the competitive firm also changes its output level to obtain maximum
profit in the changed situation. There is thus a relationship between price and quantity supplied
by a competitive firm, which is shown by the firm's supply curve. The monopolist is a price
maker. He can set one of the price and output levels and leave another to be determined by the
consumers' preferences. When demand conditions change, her/his profit maximizing level of
output may be different, but the price level may remain the same as before. Alternatively, shifts
in demand curves may lead to change in price with no change in output. Finally, changes in
demand may lead to changes in both price and output. In other words, there is lack of a definite
relationship between price and output of a monopolist. Figure-7.6 shows how shifts in AR and
MR curves give rise to the same price with
change in output or to the same output with change in price. In panel A, the initial average
revenue and marginal revenue curves are AR1 and MR1, respectively. With the straight line
MC
Panel A Panel B
P1
MC P2
E1 AR2
P1
E2 AR2 AR1
E1
AR1 MR2
MR1 MR2
MR1
0 q1 q2 0 q1
134
In perfect competition, price elasticity of demand is equal to infinity for a firm (EP = ). Hence,
we get price equal to marginal cost (P = MC) at the equilibrium level of output. In monopoly, the
AR curve is downward sloping so that price elasticity of demand is less than infinity (EP < ). In
that case price becomes equal to some multiple of marginal cost. In other words, price becomes
greater than marginal cost (P > MC) in a monopoly market.
Review Questions
1. Explain the equilibrium of a monopoly firm in the short-run. Is monopoly price always
higher than the competitive price?
2. Explain the equilibrium of a monopoly firm in the long-run.
3. How is pricing under monopoly different from that under perfect competition? Can a
monopoly firm fix any price for its product?
4. A monopoly firm may earn normal or abnormal profits or may even incur losses in the short-
run. Do you agree with this statement? Give reasons for your answer.
5. Why is monopoly considered socially undesirable?
6. Unlike a firm under perfect competition, a monopolist does not have a supply curve. Discuss.
7. Compare monopoly and perfect competition with regard to the following: price
(i) output
(ii) welfare
(iii) relationship between MC and price
135
Lesson 3: Monopoly Power, Regulating the Monopoly and the Comparison
Between Competitive and Monopoly Markets.
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
compare between competitive and monopoly markets;
state the measures of monopoly power; and
state how the monopoly can be regulated.
A
MC
Pm F
Ec
Pc M
Em
B
MR AR
0 qm qc q
Figure 7.11: Comparison between competitive and monopoly market
MR curves represent the average
the revenue and marginal revenue curves of the industry when we take the case of perfect
competition. Alternatively, the AR and MR curves represent the average revenue and marginal
revenue curves of the monopolist. Suppose, initially, the market was competitive. Since in
competitive equilibrium price equal marginal cost, the Point Ec in Figure 7.11 represents the
competitive equilibrium yielding competitive output qc and the competitive price Pc. Under
perfect competition, consumer's surplus is equal to the area of the triangle APcEc and producer's
surplus is equal to the area of the triangle BECPC. Now suppose the competitive market turns
into monopoly market for reasons not mentioned here. The equilibrium Point under monopoly
market becomes Em where the MC curves intersect the MR curve. Monopoly output and price
are qm and Pm, respectively. As we can see in the figure, the immediate effect of the
transformation of the competitive market into the monopoly market is a reduction in output and a
rise in price. Consumer's surplus decreases by an amount equal to the area of the trapezium
PmPcE cF of which the amount represented by the area of rectangle PmPcMF goes to the
monopolist in the form of higher price. There is a redistribution of income from the consumers to
136
the monopolist. the rectangle PmPc MF is a portion of the loss of consumer's surplus compensated
by the gain to the monopolist, but the loss shown by the area of the triangle FMEc is not
compensated. Due to reduction in output, the producer loses total revenue equal to the area of the
rectangle qm ME cqc of which the area of the trapezium qm EmEcqc represents savings in total cost
of the producer. The area of the triangle MEmEc is not compensated by savings in cost. Total loss
of the economy which cannot be compensated by any gain due to the emergence of a monopoly
market is equal to the area of the triangle FEmEc, which is known as the dead weight loss of the
monopoly. It is the presence of this deadweight loss of monopoly which instigates most of the
public opinions against monopoly. Even most economists publicly claim their dislike for
monopoly markets and would like the monopoly markets to be regulated by the government
authorities.
Regulation of Monopoly
A lower level of output sold at a higher price is the undesired effect of a monopoly market. A
monopoly market also gives rise to deadweight loss to society as well as a redistribution of
income in favor of the monopolist. The harmful effects of monopoly necessitate regulation of
137
monopolies taking the long-run equilibrium of the competitive firm as a benchmark. The three
features of long-run equilibrium of a firm under perfect competition are as follows:
1. Price equals marginal cost eliminating monopoly power,
2. The firm earns normal profit eliminating supernormal profit
3. The firm produces at the minimum LAC eliminating excess capacity.
Regulation of monopolies can take different forms depending on the relative positions of the
demand and cost conditions of the monopolist. It also depends on which of the two desired
features of the competitive equilibrium the authority wants to achieve through the regulation of
monopolies. We select three specific situations of relative positions of the demand and cost
conditions of the monopolist and examine how the desired features of the competitive
equilibrium can be attained. The three specific situations are as follows:
1. The AR curve intersects the MRC curve above the AC curve.
2. The AR curve intersects the MC curve below the AC curve.
3. The case of natural monopoly where both the AC and MC curves are downward sloping.
First Case: The intersection point of the AR and MC curves lies above AC.
138
We illustrate the first situation with the help of Figure 7.12 Em is the equilibrium point of the
profit maximizing monopolist whose output and price are qm and Pm respectively. Since AR>AC
at the equilibrium output qm, the monopolist is earning supernormal profit. The regulatory
P
MR
AC
MC
Pm A MC
E1
P1 AC
E2
P2 B
Em
E3 C
P3
D
MR AR
O q3 qm q2 q1 q4 F q5 C q
Figure 7.12: Regulation of monopoly
agency of the government can fix the price at p1 corresponding to Point E1 on the AR curve
where price equals marginal cost. The effective marginal revenue curve then becomes P1E1DF
with the discontinuous portion between E and D. The effective marginal revenue curve intersects
the MC curve at E1, which determines the output q1. Though the monopolist is still earning
supernormal profit at the regulated price P1, monopoly power has been reduced to zero form the
initial level of AEm/Pm. If the regulatory agent wants to eliminate supernormal profit, it can set
139
the price P2 corresponding to the Point where price equals average cost. The horizontal straight
line P 2E2B then becomes a portion of the effective marginal revenue curve which intersects the
MC curve at E2. The equilibrium output is q2 corresponding to the Point E2. Since the regulated
price P2 is equal to MC at E2, monopoly power is still zero, but supernormal profit has not been
eliminated altogether. Moreover, an excess demand for the commodity by an amount q2q4
develops at the regulated price p2. If price is regulated at further low levels, supernormal profit
decreases and excess demand for the commodity increases. If price is regulated at P3, equilibrium
occurs at E 3, the minimum Point of the average cost curve AC. Both the monopoly power and
supernormal profit of the firm disappear at equilibrium output q3, but excess demand for the
commodity increases to the level of q3q5. If price is set below P3, the level of minimum average
cost, the monopolist cannot break even and goes out of business. Regulation of monopoly should
be handled cautiously because excess demand for the commodity develops when price is set
below the level which eliminates monopoly power. There will be a tendency in the market to
evade such price regulations and the cost of monitoring price regulation may indeed be very
high.
Second Case: The intersection Point of the AR and MC curves lies below AC
The situation mentioned above has been depicted in Figure 7.13. The price and output levels of
profit maximizing monopolist are found to be qm and pm respectively given by the equilibrium
Point Em . Since at the equilibrium level of output AR>AC, the monopolist is making
supernormal profit if the regulatory agency aims at abolishing supernormal profit here, it will set
the price at p1 corresponding to the Point B where average revenue equals average cost. At the
regulated price p1, the marginal revenue becomes p1BE 1CDFG of which the portion E1C is
discontinuous. The MC curve intersects the new marginal revenue curve at E1, which determines
MC
AC
Price, MC, AC
Pm A
P1 B H
P2 E2
E1
Em
MR
AR
C
O qm q1 D q2
F
Quantity
G
Figure 7.13: Regulation of monopoly
the equilibrium output q1. The equilibrium price level P1 is now equal to average cost q1B
yielding normal profit for the monopolist. Since at the equilibrium output q 1, marginal cost q1E 1
is less than price q1 B, monopoly power still exists though it has been reduced from the earlier
140
level. The price level can also be fixed at p2 corresponding to Point E 2 where marginal cost
equals price. The effective marginal revenue curve now becomes p2E2q2 FG which intersects the
MC curve at E2. The equilibrium output and price levels are now q2 and p2 respectively. Though
the monopoly power has been eliminated at the regulated price p2, price is less than average cost
by an amount E2H at output level q2. The monopolist incurs a loss and goes out of business in the
long-run if he is not supported financially by giving subsidies.
Third Case: Regulation of Natural Monopolies
The process of regulating natural monopolies has been explained with the help of Figure 7.9 in
the context of second degree price discrimination discussed in Lesson-3 of this unit. It was
shown in Figure 7.9 that regulating price at the level where average cost equals price could be a
feasible method of controlling natural monopolies.
We analyzed the mechanism of regulating monopoly under different demand and cost
conditions. It is almost impossible to achieve the twin goals of eliminating both monopoly power
and supernormal profit through price regulation. Suppose, cost of production is low so that the
intersection point of the average revenue and marginal cost curves lies above the average cost
curve. Fixing price at less than the competitive level of price being equal to marginal cost (P =
MC) results in excess demand for the commodity. The excess demand would put upward
pressure on the price jeopardizing the ultimate objective of price regulation. Implementing and
monitoring such price controls may be very much expensive. When cost of production is high so
that the intersection point of the average revenue and marginal cost curves lies below the average
cost curve, fixing price at the competitive level results in loss for the firm in the long-run.
Operating firms in such a situation necessitates the provision of subsidy. Controlling a monopoly
through price ceiling and then subsidizing it to compensate for the loss may seem paradoxical to
the lay public. Instead the firm may be brought under state ownership. Even the transfer of
ownership may not solve the problem of price being less than average cost under marginal cost
pricing. Giving subsidy to the state-owned firm may worsen the problem by creating wide spread
corruption and inefficiency in production and management. As a result, the amount of subsidy
increases gradually and the economy gets trapped into an irreversible culture of subsidy. Even a
private firm may suffer from the same problem, though the problem is not acute in this case. The
method of subsidizing the private and the state-owned firms cannot be justified on efficiency
grounds. Another method of avoiding the undesirable effects of monopoly is to resist the
formation of monopoly through anti-trust laws. Further, the existing monopolies can be
disintegrated and broken down into small-scale enterprises by passing laws.
Review Questions
1. (a) Compare the profit-maximizing price and quantity for a monopoly with the values in a
monopoly with the values in a perfectly competitive industry. Assume the same marginal
cost and demand for both.
141
(b) In attempting to maximize profits, do owners of a monopoly act differently than owners
of perfectly competitive firms? Explain.
2. How is pricing under monopoly different from that under perfect competition? Can a
monopoly firm fix any price for its product?
3. Explain the equilibrium of a monopoly firm in the short-run. Is monopoly price always
higher than the competitive price?
4. What is monopoly power? How it can be measured?
5. Why is it needed to regulate monopoly? Describe different cases of regulating monopolies.
6. Compare monopoly and perfect competition with regard to the following:
(a) Price
(b) Output
(c) Welfare
(d) Relationship between MC and price
142
Lesson 1: Monopolistic Competition
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
state the characteristics of monopolistic competition;
explain the short-run equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive firm;
explain the long-run equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive firm;
explain the concept of excess capacity that arises in monopolistic competition;
Panel A Panel B
SMC
SMC SATC
P1 A1 P2 A2
SATC
C1
B1 AR AR
E1 E2
MR MR
0 q1 0 q2
Panel C Panel D
SATC
SMC SATC SMC
B4 C4 SAVC
C3
B3 F4 D4
P3
A3 SAVC P4 A4
F3
D3 AR AR
E3 E4
MR MR
0 q3 0 q4
Figure 8.1:Panel A SMCEquilibrium
Short-Run
1 Panel
of Monopolistically B LMC
competitive firm
SMC1 SMC LAC
SMC SATC1
SATC
SATC1 A1
A1 P1
P1
SATC
Emc
C1
B1 AR
E1 AR
MR
AR1
MR
0 q1 MR1 0 qmc q1 qc
Figure 8.2 : Long-run equilibrium of a firm in monopolistic competition
normal profit. To see why it is so, we consider the case of a firm which makes supernormal profit
145
in the short-run as shown by Panel A of Figure 8.2. We assume identical cost and demand
conditions of all firms in the group, though their products are differentiated. Since each of the
firms in the group is making supernormal profit equal to the area B1C1A1P1 in Panel A, new
firms will enter the group and produce similar but differentiated products. As a result, the share
of each firm in total output of the group will fall as shown by the leftward shift of the AR and
MR curves in Panel A. The falling share of each firm will reduce the level of supernormal profit
and in an attempt to regain the previous level of supernormal profit, the firm will improve the
variety of the product. Such improvement and innovations entail some expenses which cause the
AC and MC curves to shift to the right. This process of shifting the demand and cost curves will
continue until the demand curve becomes tangent to the average cost curve at the falling portion
of the average cost curve. Supernormal profit will be totally eliminated and in the long-run each
monoplolistically competitive firm will only earn Bnormal profit. Similarly, if each firm incurs
loss in the short-run, some firms will leave the group enabling some of the existing firms to earn
normal profit. It should be noted that the firm will also try to minimize its cost of production in
the long-run by changing the production plant. In other words, each firm will be producing at
some point on the long-run average cost curve. We can summarize the following features of
long-run equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive firm:
In Panel B of Figure 8.2, we show the long-run equilibrium of the firm under monopolistic
competition. At equilibrium point Emc, LMC equals MR. Equilibrium output level is qmc at which
the LAC curve is tangent to AR. Since at qmc, LAC equals AR, the firm earns only normal profit.
qc-qmc=q1-qmc+ qc-q 1
At output qmc, the firm used the production plant with the short-run average cost curve SATC1.
The firm is producing at point A which is on the falling portion of SATC1 and is not producing at
B which is the minimum point of SATC1. The firm could use the lowest cost plant with the
short-run average cost curve SATC instead of using the plant with SATC1. The output range qc-
q1 then shows the portion of excess capacity that results due to the failure of the firm to use the
lowest cost plant in the long-run.
146
From the preceding discussion, the presence of excess capacity seems to be a measure of
inefficiency of monopolistically competitive market. Professor Chamberlin, one of the two
pioneers of the theory of monopolistic competition, opined that excess capacity reflects cost of
product diversity provided by monopolistic competition. He held the view that the consumers
benefit from having the opportunity to choose from a number of similar but differentiated
products. There are many brands of a commodity with different quality, style and appearance.
The benefits from this opportunity may well outweigh the cost of the opportunity measured by
excess capacity.
A
P1
B
E
MR AR
q
0 qmc qc
Figure 8.3: Perfect competition versus monopolistic competition
firms in the long-run drives the supernormal profit to zero. As we can see from Figure 8.3, the
long-run equilibrium of a competitive firm occurs at the minimum point of long-run average cost
curve whereas the long-run equilibrium of a firm under monopolistic competition occurs to the
left of the minimum point. The output segment qc-qmc measures excess capacity in monopolistic
competition. In long-run equilibrium of a monopolistically competitive firm price exceeds
marginal cost. It means that the firm enjoys some monopoly power and the consumers value the
benefits of additional output more than the cost of additional output. By restricting output to qmc,
the monopolistically competitive firm is depriving the consumers of this additional net benefit
shown by the shaded area AEB in Figure 8.3. This is, in fact, the deadweight loss that results
from the monopoly power of the monopolistically competitive firm.
The Sales and hence production of the firm increases to q2 from q1 after advertisements As we
Panel A Panel B
SMC
A2 SAC/
SAC/ P2
C1 E2
SAC C2 A1 B2 SAC
C2 P1
C1 B1 AR/
E1 MR MR/
AR
0 q1 q2 0 q1 q2
Figure 8.4: Effect of Advertisement Figure 8.5: Profit maximization with selling cost
can see from Figure 8.4, the average cost of production falls to C2 from C 1 due to economies of
scale involved with higher level of production. But these economies of scale may not always be
obtained. We illustrate the process of determining the profit maximizing level of selling cost by
Figure 8.5.
In Figure 8.5, the AR, MR, SAC and SMC curves show the demand and cost conditions of the
firm before advertising costs are incurred. Accordingly, the initial equilibrium point E 1
determines output q 1, price P 1 and a profit equal to area P1C 1B1A1. A given amount of
advertisement cost shifts the average revenue curve to AR1, the marginal curve to MR1 and the
average cost curve to SAC1. The marginal cost curve does not shift because the total
advertisement cost is treated as an item of total fixed cost. The new equilibrium point is E 2 which
gives rise to new output level q2 and a profit level equal to area P 2C2B 2A2. This figure shows the
effect of a fixed level of advertising expenditure on the price, output and profit of the firm. It is
difficult to show in this figure how the profit maximizing level of advertising cost is determined.
Instead we can provide a verbal explanation of the process of determining the optimum level of
selling cost. The monopolistic competitor can change the amount of fixed advertising cost and
see how much profit it brings for each level of advertising expenditure. The firm can adopt a trial
148
and error process for determining the profit maximizing level of selling cost. We should
remember that the AR, MR and SAC curves shift upward each time the entrepreneur changes the
level of selling cost and the extent of shift of these curves depends on the amount of change of
selling cost. We can, however, deduce the conditions for such an optimum level of advertising
expenditure. When the firm spends one taka on advertising, it increases the firm's sale level. To
meet the additional demand for its product, the firm needs to incur some expenses for producing
the additional output. It is natural to expect that at the profit maximizing level of advertising cost,
the additional taka spent on advertising plus the additional cost per unit of increased output
brought about by advertising cost should be equal to additional revenue per unit of increased
output. This condition can be put in an equation form :
Q Q
P 1 MC (1)
A A
where P = Price
Q = increased sale due to advertising
MC = Marginal cost
A = Change in advertising expenditure
PQ measures the change in total revenue brought about by additional advertising expenditure of
an amount A. MCQ shows the change in total production cost for additional output from
advertising. PQ/A then reflect the additional revenue per unit of taka spent on advertising.
MCQ/A shows the additional production cost per unit of increased output. The above
condition for profit maximizing level of advertising costs can be rearranged so that it can be used
in everyday business practice.
Q Q
P MC 1 2
A A
Q
or , P MC 1 3
A
The bracketed term on the left-hand side of Equation 4 can be called advertising elasticity of
demand. It shows the ratio of percentage change in quantity demanded to percentage change in
advertising expenditure. In previous chapter (P-MC)/P was found to be equal to inverse of
A E
AD 5
PQ EP
absolute value of price elasticity of demand. Using the notations EAD for advertising elasticity
and Ep for price elasticity, equation (4) can be rewritten as shown below:
149
Equation (5) says that to maximize profit from advertising, the expenditure on advertisement
should be chosen such that the ratio of advertising expenditure to total sale should be equal to the
ratio of advertising elasticity to price elasticity of demand. It is easy to collect information from a
monopolistic competition market, which can be used to estimate the relevant elasticity.
150
Review Questions
1. Discuss the characteristic features of monopolistic competition. How does it differ from
perfect competition?
2. What is monopolistic competition? What are the effects of product differentiation on:
(i) Firm's MR and AR curves; and
(ii) Firm's equilibrium
3. Discuss the equilibrium of a firm under monopolistic competition under the condition of
price competition among the firms.
4. How is the equilibrium of a firm affected under monopolistic competition where there is no
barrier to entry of new firms?
5. How is the long-run equilibrium of a firm under monopolistic competition affected by the
entry of new firms indulging in price competition?
6. (a) What are the characteristics that cause monopolistic competition?
(b) Give some examples of monopolistically competitive firms.
(c) How can two retail stores that sell the same brand of product be considered as selling
differentiated products?
7. Suppose by lowering its price from $1.20 to $1.15 per gallon, a service station can sell
15,000 gallons of gasoline per week as opposed to 10,000. Can we infer from these figures
that the marginal revenue of an extra gallon sold in this range of output is $1.15? Why or
why not? What is MR in this case?
8. Using the appropriate diagrams, illustrate the case where a monopolistically competitive
firm is making:
(a) pure profits
(b) just normal profits
(c) a loss
9. Describe the process of adjustment that would occur if a grocery store in an expanding
resort area is making pure profits.
10. What are the two ways in which pure profits are competed away in a monopolistically
competitive industry?
11. (a) Why do firms advertise?
(b) Would society be better off if advertising was banned? Explain.
12. How is the profit maximizing level of advertising expenditure decided?
13. Explain the excess capacity in monopolistic competition.
14. Compare:
a. perfect competition and monopolistic competition.
b. monopoly and monopolistic competition.
151
Lesson 2: Oligopoly
Lesson Objectives
After studying this lesson, you should be able to:
state the characteristics of oligopoly;
state the concept of Nash equilibrium;
state how price and output are determined in Cournot Model;
state why price remains rigid in the Kinked demand curve Model; and
state how Game theory can be applied in oligopoly market.
Characteristics of Oligopoly
In oligopoly, there are a few sellers so that in any decision it makes, each firm takes its rival's
reactions into account. Unlike the monopolistically competitive firms, the oligopolistic firms are
interdependent in decision making. The products produced by these firms may be homogenous
or differentiated. Often, the firms in an oligopoly market are large scale production enterprises
and a few firms account for all or most of total production. It may happen that some or all of the
oligopoly firms earn substantial amount of supernormal profit in the long-run because barriers to
entry prevents other firms from entering the market.
Making price and output decisions in oligopoly is very difficult because each firm may not know
precisely what other firms' reactions will be when it implements a decision about price and
output. Suppose, for example, a firm lowers its product's price. Its rivals may also lower their
prices so that the firm's sales will not increase significantly. Or, the rivals may keep their prices
fixed, consequently the firm's sales fall drastically. On the whole, the firm is not certain about the
possible consequences of its decision to reduce its product's price. A firm can only make guesses
about its rivals' reactions under different strategies or policies it adopts. But different firms may
make different assumptions about rivals' retaliatory actions depending on the size and financial
positions of the firms. This variation in assumptions about rivals' reactions is called conjectural
variation and any action undertaken in logical response to perceived reaction of the rivals' is
called strategic decision making. Since there is no commonly accepted assumption about rivals
reactions, there is no single model of price and output determination in oligopoly. Instead, a few
oligopoly models based on different assumptions about reactions of the rivals have been
developed to explain price and output determination in an oligopoly market.
We can classify these assumptions about reactions of the rivals into three broad groups and
discuss a few popular models from each group.
152
The Concept of Nash Equilibrium
Before discussing the different oligopolistic models, we mention one general principle
underlying oligopolistic equilibrium known as the Nash equilibrium. It is stated as follows:
Each firm is doing the best it can given what its competitors are doing
In the case of Nash equilibrium, one question then naturally arises. If a firm does the best it can
give what its competitors are doing, what does it assume that its competitors are doing? It is
natural to assume that the competitors are doing the best they can give what the firm is doing.
The concept of Nash equilibrium is pertinent for the equilibrium of an oligopolistic firm which
acts under a strategic consideration about the reactions of its rivals. This principle is not relevant
to pricing and output decisions made by the oligopolistic firms under formal and informal
agreements. The general principle of Nash equilibrium is different from general principle of
Non-Nash equilibrium used in the context of other market structure like perfect competitions,
monopoly, etc. In these markets, a firm does not have strategic considerations about the behavior
of other firms. The nature of equilibrium in absence of strategic considerations is stated as
follows:
A firm is doing its best it can do and has no reason to change its price and output. The firms in an
oligopoly market may operate in two situations. They may work in an environment of
uncertainty about reactions of rivals, though each firm may make a certain assumption about the
behavior of its competitors. Alternatively, these firms may cooperate with each other eliminating
all uncertainties about actions and reactions of the competing firm. The first situation may be
called the non-cooperation environment, and the second situation, the cooperation environment.
Some models have been developed for each situation. Next we discuss these models.
P
MC
MR
D(o)
E(o) D(q2)
MC1
E(2)
MR(q2) MR(o)
Q
q12 q10
Figure 8.5: Derivation of reaction function in Cournot Model
thus an inverse relationship between Firm 1's equilibrium output level and that of Firm 2.
Equilibrium output level and Firm 2's assumed output level, which is called the reaction function
of Firm 1. We can also obtain the reaction function of Firm 2 by reversing the derivation process.
In that case, we find the equilibrium output level of Firm 2 corresponding to different output
levels of Firm 1. Reaction function of one Firm shows the desired level of output of the Firm for
each of the different output levels of another Firm. Firm-1's decision to produce a given level of
output is based on its observation and assumption about Firm 2's output level, which may or may
E 154
not be true. If firm 1's assumption about Firm 2's output turns out to be true, then Firm 2's
q2
q2*
q21
q20
Reaction function of Firm 2
q1
0 q1*q11 q10 B D
Figure 8.6: Equilibrium in Cournot Model
assumption about Firm 1's output also turns out to be true. The two Firms assumptions about
each other are realized and equilibrium for both Firms is obtained at the intersection of the two
reaction functions. If the two Firms assumptions about each other prove to be wrong, equilibrium
is not attained and the two Firms keep changing their output level until expectations of both
about each other are realized. We have drawn the two reaction functions in Figure 8.6 where the
vertical and horizontal axes measure the output levels of Firm 1, (q2), and Firm 2,(q0). The
downward sloping straight lines AB and CD in the figure are the reaction functions of Firm 1
and Firm 2, respectively.
Suppose Firm 1 observes that Firm 2 is initially producing the output q20. According to Firm 1's
reacting function, the intended output of Firm 1 is q10 corresponding to Firm 2's output of q20.
But Firm 2's reaction function determines its output q 21 given output q 10 of Firm 1. Again the
reaction function of Firm 1 shows output q11 for Firm 1 corresponding to output q 21 of Firm 2.
This process of adjusting and readjusting output levels by two Firms continues until both Firms
reach the equilibrium point E where both Firms' expectations about each other come true. In the
end, Firm 1 produces output q1* and Firm 2 produces q2*. It is easily seen that the equilibrium in
Cournot Model is a Nash equilibrium mentioned earlier. This is because q 1* turns out to be the
profit-maximizing level of output for Firm 1 given Firm 2's output level q2* and q2* turns to be
the profit-maximizing level of output for Firm 2 given Firm 1's output level q 1*.
155
The Kinked Demand Curve Model
This model is based on the assumption that a rise in price is not matched by similar price rise by
other Firms whereas a fall in price is always followed by similar fall in prices by rivals. When a
Firm raises its price, other Firms do not raise their prices. The Firm then loses most of the
customers in the market. As a result, the portion of demand curve above the prevailing price
level becomes elastic. When the Firm lowers its price, other Firms will follow it. The sale of the
Firm then increases by a small amount. This makes the portion of the demand curve below the
current price level less elastic. The asymmetry in responses of other Firms to price changes gives
rise to a demand curve with two line segments having different price elasticity Such a demand
curve has been shown in Figure 8.7 where P0 is the prevailing price level. It is seen that the
B D0
MC1
A0 MC0
P0
C E1
E0
D
D1
q
O q0 F
Figure 8.7: Price rigidity in Kinked Demand Curve Model.
portion D 0A0 is more elastic and the portion A0D1 is less elastic. There is a kink at point A0. The
curve BCDF is the marginal revenue curve corresponding to demand curve D0A0D1. The
marginal revenue curve has a discontinuous segment between C and D. MC 0 is the initial
marginal cost curve of the Firm. The marginal cost curve MC0 intersects the marginal revenue
curve at E 0 giving rise to initial price level P0 and initial output level q0. Due to some external
reasons, the marginal cost curve shifts to MC1, which intersects the marginal revenue curve at E 1.
The new equilibrium point E 1 leads to the same price level P0 with no change in output level.
The kinked demand curve model thus explains why the price level remains rigid at the current
level in most cases. The problem with this model is that it cannot explain how the current price
was determined initially. It shows price rigidity without explaining the reason for such price
rigidity. Perhaps Game theory can provide some logical explanations for such price rigidity.
Game Theory
The main problem of an oligopolistic Firm is that it does not know what its rivals will do when it
takes any decision about price, product variety, selling cost and so on. Game theory suggests that
some kind of equilibrium solution for the Firm can be obtained in such an uncertain situation if
156
the Firm behaves according to some predetermined pattern. One such pattern is called game
theory with dominant strategy.
Dominant Strategy
The Game theory is traditionally explained with the help of a pay-off matrix which shows the
expected returns accruing from different strategies. Suppose, there are two Firms in a industry
producing a homogeneous product. Each of the two Firms is considering the possibility of
increasing its net profit through selling cost but it is unaware of the action taken by another Firm.
Each Firm then has two strategies viz., advertise and do not advertise. Since there are two Firms,
there will be four combinations of strategies by the two firms. The first number in each cell of
the following pay-off matrix shows the profit of Firm 1 and the second number the profit of Firm
2.
Pay-off Matrix 1
Firm 2
Do not
Advertise Advertise
Advertise 12,6 18,1
Firm 1 Do not 3, 12 8, 3
Advertise
There are two strategies for Firm 2. If Firm 2 advertises, Firm 1 makes a profit of Tk 12 if it
advertises and a profit of Tk. 3 if it does not advertise. So, the best strategy for Firm 1 is to
advertise when Firm 2 advertises. If Firm 2 does not advertise, Firm 1 earns Tk. 18 if it
advertises and Tk. 8 if it does not. So the best strategy for Firm 1 is to advertise when Firm 2
does not advertise. Firm 1's best strategy is to advertise under the two strategies of Firm 2.
Similarly, the best strategy of Firm 2 is to advertise under the two strategies of Firm 1. Both
Firms decide to advertise and Firm 1 earns a profit of Tk. 12 and Firm 2 earns a profit of Tk. 6.
A solution here exists because each Firm has a dominant strategy which is valid under two
strategies of another Firm. This may not be the case always. Suppose, we change the expected
returns in the bottom right-hand corner cell as shown below the pay-off matrix 2.
Pay-off Matrix 2
Firm 2
Do not
Advertise Advertise
Advertise 12, 6 18, 1
Firm 1 Do not 3,12 19, 13
Advertise
Firm 1 earns Tk. 12 if it advertises and Tk. 3 if it does not under the first strategy of Firm 2. So,
the best strategy of Firm 1 is to advertise when Firm 2 advertises. Firm 1 earns Tk. 18 if it
advertises and Tk. 19 if it does not advertise. So the best strategy of Firm 1 is to advertise when
Firm 2 advertises and not to advertise when Firm 2 does not advertise. Similarly, the best
strategy for Firm 2 is to advertise when Firm 1 advertises and not to advertise when Firm 1 does
157
not advertise. The second pay-off matrix is such that it does not yield any optimal strategy for
either of the Firms. Best strategy to one Firm depends on the strategy taken by another Firm.
There is no equilibrium solution here.
These examples of pay-off matrix show that application of Game theory in interdependent
decision making process of the oligopolistic Firms may sometimes yield an equilibrium solution.
At other times, Game theory cannot give any solution.
Review Questions
1. (a) What is an oligopoly?
(b) What characteristics are necessary to have an oligopoly?
2. Using the appropriate diagram, illustrate the profit-maximizing price and quantity for an
oligopoly.
3. State and explain the concept of Nash equilibrium.
4. Why is no single theory of oligopoly possible?
5. (a) Draw a kinked demand curve for a firm and identify the region on the corresponding
MR curve where a shift in the MC curve will not change the profit maximizing price
or quantity.
(b) Why is the upper portion of the kinked demand curve drawn to be more elastic than
the lower portion?
(c) In constructing the kinked demand curve, what is assumed about the profit-
maximizing behavior of competing firms?
6. What are the characteristic features of an oligopolistic industry. How does it differ from
monopolistic competition?
7. Explain Cournot's duopoly model and examine his solution to duopoly.
8. Discuss the game theory used to obtain the equilibrium solution of an oligopolistic firm.
158