Chapter11 Stock Valuation and Risk
Chapter11 Stock Valuation and Risk
E(W)=pW1+ (1-p)W2=0.6*150.000+0.4*80.000=122.000
σ2 = E[W-E(W)]2=p[W1-E(W)]2+(1-p) [W2-E(W)]2 =
= 0.6*(150.000-122.000)2+0.4(80.000-122.000)2 =
= 1.176.000.000
The standard deviation, σ, which is the square root of the variance, is therefore, 34.292,86.
• The standard deviation of the payoff is large, much larger than the expected profit of 22.000.
Whether the expected profit is large enough to justify such risk depends on the alternative portfolios.
• Let us suppose that Treasury bills (bonds) are one alternative to the risky portfolio. Suppose that at
the time of the decision, a one-year T-bill offers a rate of return of 5%; 100.000 can be invested to
yield a sure profit of 5.000. We can now draw the decision tree.
• Earlier we showed the expected profit on the prospect to be 22.000. Therefore, the expected marginal,
or incremental, profit of the risky portfolio over investing in safe T-bills is 22.000-5.000=17.000,
meaning that one can earn a risk premium of 17.000 as compensation for the risk of the investment.
U=E(r) – 0.005A σ2
Where U is the utility value and A is an index of the investor’s risk aversion. The factor of 0.005 is a
scaling convention that allows us to express the expected return and standard deviation, as percentages
rather than decimals.
• For example, recall the earlier investment problem, choosing between portfolio with an expected return
of 22% and a standard deviation 34% and T-bill providing a risk-free return of 5%.
• Even for A=3, a moderate risk-aversion parameter, the risky portfolio’s utility value is U=E(r) – 0.005A
σ2=22-0.005*3*342=4.66% which is slightly lower than the 5% of the T-bill.
• In this case one would reject the portfolio in favor of T-bill. If the investor where less risk averse, for
example A=2, then U= U=E(r) – 0.005A σ2=22-0.005*2*342=10.44%, higher than the risk-free rate,
leading her to adopt the prospect.
• We can depict the individual’s trade-off between risk and return by plotting the characteristics of
potential investment portfolios.
• Portfolio P with expected return E(rp) and standard deviation σp, is preferred by any risk-averse investor
to any portfolio in quadrant IV because it has an expected return equal to or greater than any portfolio in
that quadrant and a standard deviation equal to or smaller than any portfolio in that quadrant.
Conversely, any portfolio in quadrant I is preferable to portfolio P because its expected return is equal to
or greater than P’s and its standard deviation is equal to or smaller than P’s.
• This is the mean-standard deviation, or equivalently, the Mean-Variance (M-V) criterion.
It can be stated as:
A dominates B if
E(rA)≥ E(rB)
σ A≤ σ B
and at least one inequality is strict.
2.1 Market The Opportunity Set with N Risky Assets
Equilibrium:
CAPM
1. Investors are risk-averse individuals who maximize the expected utility of their wealth.
2. Investors are price takers and have homogeneous expectations about asset returns that have a
joint normal distribution.
3. There exists a risk-free asset such that investors may borrow or lend unlimited amounts at a risk-
free rate.
4. The quantities of assets are fixed. Also, all assets are marketable and perfectly divisible.
5. Asset markets are frictionless, and information is costless and simultaneously available to all
investors. All Assets are divisible and tradable.
6. There are no market imperfections such as taxes, regulations, or restrictions on short selling.
Implications :
Since markets are frictionless, the borrowing rate equals the lending rate (=risk free rate), and we are
able to develop a linear efficient set.
Since investors have homogeneous beliefs. They all make decisions based on an identical opportunity
set (IMI’). In other words, no one can be fooled because everyone has the same information at the same
time.
Since all investors maximize the expected utility of their end-of-period wealth, the model is implicitly
a one-period model.
Two-fund separation Theorem and Capital market line (CML):
• If investors have homogeneous beliefs, then they all have the same linear efficient set called the
capital market line (CML)
෪𝑝)=aE(𝑅
E(𝑅 ෪𝑖 )+(1-a)E(𝑅෪
𝑚) (eq. 1)
(eq. 3)
(eq. 4)
• In equilibrium, the market portfolio already has the value weight, wi percent, invested in the risky asset I.
• Therefore, the percentage a in the above equations 3 and 4 is the excess demand for an individual risky
asset. But we know that in equilibrium the excess demand for any risky asset must be zero. Prices will
adjust until all assets are held by someone. Then, in the above equations if we set a=0 we can determine
the equilibrium price relationships at point M.
(eq. 5)
(eq. 6)
• The slope of the risk-free trade-off evaluated at point M, in market equilibrium, is :
(eq. 7)
• The final insight is to realize that the slope of the opportunity set IMI’ provided by the
relationship between the risk asset and the market portfolio at point M must also be equal to the
slope of the capital market line, Rf M.
෪𝑝)=aE(𝑅෪
E(𝑅 ෪
𝑚 )+(1-a)E(𝑅𝑓 ) (eq. 8)
෪𝑝) = aσm
σ(𝑅 (eq. 9)
• The slope of the capital market line is :
(eq. 10)
(eq. 11)
෪𝑖 ) we have :
• And solving for E(𝑅
(eq. 12)
• Investors can always diversify away all risk except the covariance of an asset with the market
portfolio. In other words, they can diversify away all risk except the risk of the economy as a
whole, which is inescapable (undiversifiable).
• Consequently, the only risk that investors will pay a premium to avoid is covariance risk.
• The total risk of individual asset can be partitioned into two parts-systematic risk, which is a
measure of how the asset covaries with the economy, and unsystematic risk, which is
independent of the economy:
The variance is total risk: it can be partitioned into systematic risk: b2j m2
and unsystematic risk : 2
It turns out that bj in the simple linear relationship between individual asset return and
market return is exactly the same as βj in the CAPM.
• One cannot compare the variance of return on a single asset with the variance for a well
diversified portfolio.
• The variance of the portfolio will almost always be smaller.
• The appropriate measure of risk for a single asset is beta, its covariance with the market divided
by the variance of the market. This risk is non-diversifiable, and is linearly related to the rate of
return of the asset required in equilibrium.
• The second property is that the measure of risk for individual assets is linearly additive when the
assets are combined into portfolios.
• If we put a% of our wealth into asset X and b% of our wealth into asset Y, then the beta of the
resulting portfolio is simply the weighted average of the betas of the individual securities:
N N N N N
Var(Rp)= w w =w (w )=w COV(R ,R )
i j ij i j ij i i p (eq. 16)
i =1 j =1 i =1 j =1 i =1
as the risk of security i in portfolio j. However, at the margin, the change in the contribution
of asset I to portfolio risk is simply : COV(Ri,Rp)
• Therefore, covariance risk is the appropriate definition of risk since it measures the change in
portfolio risk as we change the weighting of an individual asset in the portfolio
Example
Suppose you are the manager of an investment fund in a two-parameter economy. Given
that E(Rm)=0.16, Rf=0.08, and σm=0.20, would you recommend investment in a security
with an expected Rate of Return E(RJ)=0.12 and σjm=0.01?
Solutions – A
E(R j ) = R f + [E(R m ) − R f ] j
= .08 + (.16 − .08).25
E(R j ) = .10
where
jm .01
j = = = .25
2m (.2) 2
• Since the expected rate of return is greater than the required rate of return, investment in
the security would be advisable.
• Because it provides a quantifiable measure of risk for
individual assets, the CAPM is an extremely
2.3 Use of useful tool for valuing risky assets.
• We assume that we are dealing with a
CAPM for single time period. This assumption was built into the
derivation of the CAPM.
(eq. 17)
=[E(Rm)− R f ] 12
m (eq. 19)
• Substituting equation 17 into equation 19 we get :
• We can now interpret P0 as the equilibrium price of the risky asset. Rearranging the above
expression, we get :
E(Pe )
P0 =
1+ R f + jm (eq. 20)
• Which is often referred to as the risk-adjusted rate of return valuation formula. For assets with
• For that purpose we assume that the realized rate of return on any asset is equal to the expected rate
of return.
(eq. 34)
• Prices should be adjusted for all capital actions having an impact on the “raw” price in the
exchange – Some Examples are:
• Stock Splits
• Reverse Stock Splits
• Dividends
• Returns need to reflect the total return obtained from investors adjusting for all possible
capital actions and dividends (Usually this price is referred as a Total Return Index)
References:
• Jeff Madura, Financial Markets and Institutions, 12th edition, Cengage (JM), Chapter 11