TM1 Slides 202324
TM1 Slides 202324
TM1 Slides 202324
Managerial Economics’
𝑝𝑞
𝐴 → 𝐵: Δ𝑝𝑞 > 0
𝐴 → 𝐶: Δ𝑛 > 0
𝐴 → 𝐸: Δ𝑀 < 0 and 𝑄 normal good
𝐸
•𝐴 𝐶
𝑑 %Δ𝑄𝑑 𝑑𝑄𝑑 𝑝𝑦
➢ Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand: 𝜀𝑞,𝑦 = =
%Δ𝑝𝑦 𝑑𝑝𝑦 𝑄𝑑
𝑑 > 0: goods 𝑞 and 𝑦 are substitutes
✓ 𝜀𝑞,𝑦
✓
𝑑 = 0: goods 𝑞 and 𝑦 are independent
𝜀𝑞,𝑦
✓
𝑑 < 0: goods 𝑞 and 𝑦 are complements
𝜀𝑞,𝑦
𝑑 %Δ𝑄𝑑 𝑑𝑄𝑑 𝑀
➢ Income Elasticity of Demand: 𝜀𝑀 = =
%Δ𝑀 𝑑𝑀 𝑄𝑑
𝑑
✓ 𝜀𝑀 > 1: 𝑞 is a luxury good
𝑑
✓ 0 < 𝜀𝑀 < 1: 𝑞 is a necessity good
𝑑
✓ 𝜀𝑀 < 0: 𝑞 is an inferior good
The Market of Goods and Services: Demand Elasticities (Arc Estimates)
➢ Own-Price Elasticity of Demand:
𝑑 𝑑 𝑑 𝑝 1 + 𝑝 2 Τ2
%Δ𝑄 𝑄2 − 𝑄 1 𝑞 𝑞
𝜀𝑞𝑑 = = ∗
%Δ𝑝𝑞 𝑝𝑞2 − 𝑝𝑞1 𝑄1𝑑 + 𝑄2𝑑 Τ2
where 𝑞𝑘𝑑 is the quantity demanded per month (in ths), 𝑝𝑘 is the price
of its product (in €), 𝐴𝑘 its advertising expenses (in ths €), 𝑀 the per
capita disposable income (in ths €) and 𝑝𝑏 the price of the product of
BJ Corp. (also in €). Using these, please answer the following:
0 𝑄
Equilibrium in a Perfectly Competitive Market
𝑝𝑞
𝑝𝑞1 : 𝑄1𝑑 − 𝑄1𝑠 < 0 → Δ𝑝𝑞 < 0
𝑝𝑞2 : 𝑄2𝑑 − 𝑄2𝑠 > 0 → Δ𝑝𝑞 > 0
𝑝𝑞∗ : 𝑄 𝑑 − 𝑄 𝑠 = 0 → Δ𝑝𝑞 = 0 𝑄𝑠
𝑝𝑞1
𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐴
𝑝𝑞2
𝑄𝑑
0 𝑄1𝑑 𝑄2𝑠 𝑄∗ 𝑄2𝑑 𝑄1𝑠 𝑄
Equilibrium in a Perfectly Competitive Market: Comparative Statics
𝑝𝑞 𝑄1𝑠
𝑄0𝑠
𝐵
𝑝𝑞1
𝐴
𝑝𝑞∗
𝐶
𝑝𝑞2
0 𝑄2 𝑄1 𝑄∗ 𝑄1𝑑 𝑄0𝑑 𝑄
Firm Technology: Production Function
𝑄 The production
𝑀𝑃𝐿 = 0 function is the
technical relationship
𝑀𝑃𝐿 = 𝐴𝑃𝐿 𝑇𝑃 between the amount
of inputs used to
produce a good and
𝑀𝑃𝐿 < 𝐴𝑃𝐿 the amount of the
(region of decreasing
returns to scale) good produced.
𝑇𝑃 = 𝑓 𝐿
𝑇𝑃 𝐿
𝐴𝑃𝐿 =
𝐿
𝑑𝑇𝑃 𝐿
𝑀𝑃𝐿 =
𝑀𝑃𝐿 > 𝐴𝑃𝐿 𝑑𝐿
(region of increasing
returns to scale)
0 𝐿1 𝐿2 𝐿
Firm Technology: Short-run Cost Function
➢ The cost function is an economic relationship between the cost
and the level of output produced.
0 𝑄1 𝑄 2 𝑄 3 𝑄
Firm Technology: Average Cost, Marginal Cost, and Cost Elasticity
in the Long-run
𝐿𝑀𝐶, 𝐿𝐴𝐶
𝐿𝑀𝐶 𝑄
𝐿𝐴𝐶 𝑄
𝐴
𝑚𝑖𝑛 𝐿𝐴𝐶 In the long-run, the
quantities of all inputs
can be adjusted. Thus,
the cost is variable.
𝜀<1 𝜀>1
𝒅𝑻𝑪 𝑸 𝑸
Cost elasticity: the % change in 𝑻𝑪 due to an 1% change in 𝑸 (obtained as 𝜺 = )
𝒅𝑸 𝑻𝑪 𝑸
Firm Technology: The Duality between
Production and Cost Functions
➢ The production and the cost function provide exactly the same
information about the underlying technology.
a) When the production increases at an increasing (decreasing) rate the
cost increases at a decreasing (increasing) rate.
b) When 𝑀𝑃 > < 𝐴𝑃, then 𝑀𝐶 < > 𝐴𝐶.
c) When production takes place at the region of increasing (decreasing)
returns the cost elasticity is below (above) 1; when production takes
place at constant returns to scale, the cost elasticity equals 1.
In addition,
d) The 𝑀𝑃 curve cuts the 𝐴𝑃 curve from above at the input level where
𝐴𝑃 receives its maximum value.
e) The 𝑀𝐶 curve cuts the 𝐴𝐶 curve from below at the level of 𝑄 where
𝐴𝐶 receives its minimum value.
Different Market Structure: Basic Characteristics
company has negligible market share that cannot change the whole
structure.
✓ Homogeneous product: Consumers will not incur additional costs
✓ Perfect information.
✓ No transaction costs.
𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒
𝑀𝑅 𝑞 = 𝐴𝑅 𝑞 = 𝑝𝑞
𝑄0𝑑
0 𝑄
Managerial Decisions in Perfectly Competitive Markets:
Short-run Equilibrium of an Individual Firm
𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐
𝑆𝑀𝐶 = 𝑞 𝑠 𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶
𝑆𝐴𝑉𝐶
𝜋>0 𝐵
𝑝𝑞1 𝜋=0
𝜋<0
𝐴 If 𝑝𝑞∗ > 𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶 → 𝜋 > 0
𝑝𝑞0 If 𝑝𝑞∗ = 𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶 → 𝜋 = 0
𝑠ℎ𝑢𝑡 𝑑𝑜𝑤𝑛 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒
If 𝑆𝐴𝑉𝐶 ≤ 𝑝𝑞∗ < 𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶 → 𝜋 < 0
If 𝑝𝑞∗ < 𝑆𝐴𝑉𝐶 → firm exit
0 𝑞0 𝑞1 𝑞
Managerial Decisions in Perfectly Competitive Markets:
Short-run Equilibrium of a Perfectly Competitive Industry
𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐1 𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐2 𝑝𝑞
𝑄𝑑 𝑞1𝑠
𝑆𝑀𝐶2 = 𝑞2𝑠
𝑆𝑀𝐶1 = 𝑞1𝑠
𝑄 𝑠 = 𝑞1𝑠 + 𝑞2𝑠
𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶2
𝑆𝐴𝑇𝐶1
𝑐20 𝐸
𝐵 𝑝𝑞∗
𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐴
𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐷 𝑆𝐴𝑉𝐶2
𝑐10 𝑆𝐴𝑉𝐶1
𝐶
𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐 𝑝𝑞
𝑀𝐶𝑖
𝑦 𝑄1𝑑 𝑄0𝑠 𝑄1𝑠
𝑄0𝑑 𝐶
𝑝𝑞1 𝐷
𝑦
𝐴𝐶𝑖
𝜋𝑖
𝐵 𝐸 𝑠
𝑄𝐿𝑅
𝐴
𝑝𝑞0
0 𝑞0 𝑞1 𝑞 0 𝑄 0 𝑄1 𝑄2 𝑄
(Individual firm equilibrium) (Industry Equilibrium)
Welfare Measures in a Perfectly Competitive Market (Consumers’
Surplus (CS) , Producers’ Surplus (PS), and Total Market Welfare (W))
• Marginal Willingness to Pay at 𝑸 (𝑴𝑾𝑷(𝑸)): The
𝑝𝑞 maximum amount consumers are willing to pay
for an additional unit when 𝑄 is already available
𝐵 in the market. It is given by the vertical distance
𝑄𝑠 from the demand function to the 𝑄 axis (e.g.,
𝑴𝑾𝑷 𝑸𝟐 = 𝑲𝑸𝟐 ).
𝐶𝑆
𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐴 Welfare level generated by a
perfectly competitive market:
𝑃𝑆 𝑾 = 𝑪𝑺 + 𝑷𝑺
𝑄𝑑
0 𝑄1 𝑄2 𝑄∗ 𝑄
More Comparative Statics: (a) The Effect of a Tax
𝐶𝑆0 = 𝐸𝐴𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐶𝑆1 = 𝐸𝐶𝑝𝑞2
𝑃𝑆0 = 𝐴𝑂𝑝𝑞∗ 𝑃𝑆1 = 𝐵𝑂𝑝𝑞1
𝑝𝑞 𝑄0𝑠
𝑇 = 𝐵𝐶𝑝𝑞2 𝑝𝑞1
𝐸 Δ𝑊 = −𝐴𝐵𝐶
𝑝𝑞2 𝐶
𝐴
𝑝𝑞∗
𝐵
𝑝𝑞1
𝑡 (%) 𝑄0𝑑
𝑄1𝑑
0 𝑄1 𝑄∗ 𝑄
More Comparative Statics: (b) Effect of a Production Quota
𝐶𝑆0 = 𝐸𝐴𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐶𝑆1 = 𝐸𝐵𝑝𝑞2
𝑝𝑞
𝑃𝑆0 = 𝑂𝐴𝑝𝑞∗ 𝑃𝑆1 = 𝑂𝐶𝑝𝑞1 + 𝑝𝑞1 𝐶𝐵𝑝𝑞2
𝐸 Δ𝑊 = −𝐴𝐵𝐶 𝑄𝑠
𝑝𝑞2 𝐵
𝐴
𝑝𝑞∗
𝑝𝑞1 𝐶
𝑄𝑑
0 𝑚𝑎𝑥 𝑄 𝑄∗ 𝑄
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #1
Suppose that the demand and supply curves of coffee beans are given from
the following equations:
𝑄 𝑑 = 800 − 8𝑝𝑞 and 𝑄 𝑠 = 200 + 4𝑝𝑞
where 𝑄 𝑑 and 𝑄 𝑠 are the quantities demanded and supplied per month in
kgs and 𝑝𝑞 the price of coffee beans in €. Please answer the following:
−50
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #1
2. Calculate the price demand and supply elasticities corresponding to the
market equilibrium.
𝑑𝑄𝑑
Answer: From the supply and demand functions we get = −8 and
𝑑𝑝𝑞
𝑑𝑄𝑠
= 4. Using the equilibrium price and quantity and the elasticity
𝑑𝑝𝑞
𝑑𝑄𝑑 𝑝𝑞∗ 50 𝑑𝑄𝑠 𝑝𝑞∗ 50
formula we obtain: = −8 × = −1 and =4× = 0.5.
𝑑𝑝𝑞 𝑄∗ 400 𝑑𝑝𝑞 𝑄∗ 400
3. Assume that a tax 𝑡 = 15€ is levied on the producers. Find the after tax
market equilibrium and calculate the incidence of a tax (the percentage
of a tax passed on to consumers as a price increase).
𝑓
Answer: After tax coffee bean producers receive 𝑝𝑞 = 𝑝𝑞∗ − 15. Hence,
800 − 8𝑝𝑞∗ = 200 + 4 × 𝑝𝑞∗ − 15 ⇒ 𝑝𝑞∗ = 55€. Using the demand
function we get 𝑄 𝑑 = 800 − 8 × 55 ⟹ 𝑄 ∗ = 360kgs. Then using supply
𝜀𝑞𝑠
and demand elasticities we can calculate tax incidence from 𝑖 = =
𝜀𝑞𝑠 −𝜀𝑞𝑑
0.5 1 𝑑𝑝𝑞 55−50 1
= 3 or 𝑖 = = = 3 (see the graph).
0.5+1 𝑑𝑡 15
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #1
Inverse Supply Function:
𝑝𝑞 𝑄1𝑠 1 𝑠
𝑝𝑞 = −35 + 𝑄1
4
100 𝑠
𝑄 = 0 → 𝑝𝑞 = −35
𝑝𝑞 = 0 → 𝑄 𝑠 = 140
𝑄0𝑠
55
50
40
𝑄𝑑
0 𝑄
140 200 360 400 800
−35
−50
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #1
4. What would be the effect of a subsidy 𝑠 = 30€ per kg given to coffee bean
producers by the government in the market equilibrium? Calculate
consumer's and producer's surplus and the loss in the social welfare
𝑓
Answer: After subsidy coffee bean farms receive 𝑝𝑞 = 𝑝𝑞∗ + 30. Hence,
800 − 8𝑝𝑞∗ = 200 + 4 × 𝑝𝑞∗ + 30 ⇒ 𝑝𝑞∗ = 40€. Using the demand
function we get 𝑄 𝑑 = 800 − 8 × 40 ⟹ 𝑄 ∗ = 480kgs.
1
Consumer’s surplus after the subsidy would be 𝐶𝑆𝑆 = 2 × 100 − 40 ×
480 = 14,400. Accordingly, coffee bean producers will enjoy a surplus
1 1
𝑃𝑆𝑆 = × 70 − −50 × 480 − × 0 − −50 × 200 = 23,800.
2 2
70 𝑄1𝑠
50
40
𝑄𝑑
0 𝑄
200 320 400 480 800
−50
−80
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #2
Suppose Bella's Birkenstocks produces sandals in the perfectly competitive
sandal market. It's total cost of production both in the short-run and the
long-run is 𝑆𝑇𝐶, 𝐿𝑇𝐶 = 64 + 𝑞 2 . Please answer the following:
6. In the short run there are 19 other sandal producers, each with the same
costs as Bella. What is industry output at a price of 32€?
Answer: Since firms are identical, then everyone will produce the same
quantity at the equilibrium. Hence, 𝑄 = 20 × 𝑞 ⇒ 𝑄 = 20 × 16 = 320.
7. What is the industry short-run supply curve?
𝑝
Answer: Industry supply is 𝑄 = 20 × 𝑞 ⇒ 𝑄 = 20 × 2 = 10𝑝.
Perfectly Competitive Markets: Example #2
8. If the sandal industry is a constant cost industry in the long run, what is
the long run price and quantity?
Answer: Long-run equilibrium is where 𝐿𝑀𝐶 = 𝑝, and since 𝑝 = 𝐿𝐴𝐶, the
long-run equilibrium is given by 𝐿𝑀𝐶 = 𝐿𝐴𝐶. Given the long-run total
𝐿𝑇𝐶 64 𝜕𝐿𝑇𝐶
cost function 𝐿𝐴𝐶 = 𝑞
= 𝑞
+ 𝑞 and 𝐿𝑀𝐶 = 𝜕𝑞
= 2𝑞. Hence, 𝐿𝐴𝐶 =
64 64
𝐿𝑀𝐶 ⇒ + 𝑞 = 2𝑞 ⇒ 𝑞 = 8. From 𝑝 = 𝐿𝐴𝐶 we get that: 𝑝 = + 8⇒𝑝=
𝑞 8
16.
9. How many firms are there in the industry? Assume that the demand for
sandals is 𝑄 𝑑 = 640 − 10𝑝.
𝑄𝑑
Answer: The number of firms in the industry are 𝑛 = 𝑞
. The long-run
equilibrium quantity will be 𝑄 𝑑 = 640 − 10𝑝 = 640 − 10 × 16 = 480.
𝑄𝑑 480
Therefore, 𝑛 = 𝑞
= 8
= 60.
Barriers to Entry and Market Power: Definitions
➢ In some markets there are barriers preventing free entry and exit for
individual firms due to:
✓ economies of scale and scope
✓ government intervention
✓ essential inputs
✓ brand loyalties
✓ consumer’s lock-in
✓ network externalities
✓ significant sunk costs
➢ When strong barriers exist, firms can raise price above 𝑀𝐶 𝑄 earning
economic profits even in the long-run.
➢ In these cases, firms posses a degree of market power facing a
downward sloping demand curve.
𝑝𝑞 −𝑀𝐶 𝑄 1
➢ Lerner Index of market power: 𝐿𝐼 = =−
𝑝𝑞 𝜀𝑞𝑑
(note: in oligopolistic markets 𝐿𝐼 is different)
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Market
Characteristics
𝐷 = 𝐴𝑅 𝑞 = 𝑝𝑞 > 𝑀𝑅
𝑀𝑅
0 𝑄
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Market Equilibrium
∗
𝜋𝑚
𝑐∗ 𝐶
𝐴
𝐷 = 𝐴𝑅
𝑀𝑅
0 𝑄∗ 𝑄
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Welfare Effects
𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐
𝑀𝐶 = 𝐴𝐶 = 𝑐 ∗ 𝑊𝑚 = 𝑐 ∗ 𝐸𝐵𝐴
𝐸
𝑊𝑐 = 𝑐 ∗ 𝐸𝐶
𝐷𝑊𝐿 = 𝑊𝑚 − 𝑊𝑐 = −𝐴𝐵𝐶
𝐶𝑆 𝐵
𝑝𝑞∗
𝜋
𝐷𝑊𝐿
𝐶
𝑐∗ 𝑀𝐶 = 𝐴𝐶
𝐴
𝐷 = 𝐴𝑅
𝑀𝑅
0 𝑄∗ 𝑄
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Perfect Price Discrimination
𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐
For each unit, a consumer pays her (his) 𝑴𝑾𝑷. At the
𝐾 market equilibrium (𝑸𝒄 ), the aggregate consumer surplus
𝐶 is zero and the social welfare equals the firm’s profit.
𝑝𝑞1
𝐸
𝑝𝑞2
𝐵
𝑝𝑞𝑚
𝐹
𝑝𝑞4
𝐺
𝑝𝑞5
𝑎 𝑏 𝑐 𝑑 𝑒 𝐾
𝑝𝑞𝑐 𝑀𝐶 = 𝐴𝐶
𝐴
0 𝑄1 𝑄2 𝑄𝑚 𝑄4 𝑄5 𝑄𝑐 𝑄
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Non Linear Pricing
A. Two-Part Pricing:
Consider an amusement park, where the consumer pays an entrance fee
and a price per attraction. The higher the number of attractions a
consumer chooses, the lower the unit price.
➢ The consumers are heterogeneous; they are of two types, A and B.
➢ The monopolist firm is aware of it, but it cannot tell whether a
particular consumer is of type A or of type B.
➢ To address this problem, it designs combinations of entrance fees
and prices in such a way as to extract the maximum possible surplus.
➢ The offered packages are subject to two type of constraints:
participation and incentive compatibility ones.
➢ The participation constraints ensure that each type of consumer
receives in equilibrium a non negative surplus.
➢ The incentive compatibility constraints ensure that each consumer
prefers the package designed for his type over the package designed
for the other type.
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Non Linear Pricing
B. Selling in Packages:
Firms often offer for sale packages containing at least two different
(mostly complementary) goods. This marketing strategy may turn out to
be profitable for the firm when consumers are heterogeneous and
preferences are negatively correlated.
Example: John and Anne are going to the cinema
➢ Before going to the movie they want to buy something to drink and
eat from the bar.
➢ The bar is selling only popcorn and diet Coke.
➢ John has a high valuation for popcorn whereas Anne has a high
valuation for diet Coke.
One potential strategy for the bar is to sell both goods as a package. If
selling in packages is not allowed, the bar may either set low prices and
sell both products to both consumers or set high prices and sell popcorn
to John and diet Coke to Anne (i.e., each product is purchased by the
consumer with the higher valuation for it).
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: 3rd Degree Price Discrimination
𝑑 𝑑
𝑚𝑎𝑥 𝜋 → 𝑀𝑅𝐺𝑅 = 𝑀𝑅𝑈𝐾 = 𝑀𝐶 𝑀𝐶 = 𝐴𝐶 = 𝑐 0 , 𝜀𝐺𝑅 ≠ 𝜀𝑈𝐾
𝑝𝐺𝑅 , 𝑐 𝑝𝑈𝐾 , 𝑐
∗ 𝐵
𝑝𝐺𝑅
∗ 𝐷
𝜋𝐺𝑅 𝑝𝑈𝐾
0
𝜋𝑈𝐾 𝑀𝐶 = 𝐴𝐶
𝑐
𝐴 𝐶
𝑄𝐺𝑅 𝑄𝑈𝐾
∗ ∗
𝑄𝐺𝑅 𝑀𝑅𝐺𝑅 𝑑
𝑄𝐺𝑅 = 𝐴𝑅𝐺𝑅 𝑄𝑈𝐾 𝑑
𝑀𝑅𝑈𝐾 𝑄𝑈𝐾 = 𝐴𝑅𝑈𝐾
𝑝𝐶𝐻 , 𝑐 𝑝𝑈𝑆𝐴 , 𝑐 𝑝𝑞 , 𝑐
𝑀𝐶𝑈𝑆𝐴
𝑀𝐶𝐶𝐻
𝐴𝐶𝐶𝐻 𝑀𝐶
𝐴𝐶𝑈𝑆𝐴
𝑝𝑞∗ 𝐸 𝐹 𝐵
𝜋𝐶𝐻 𝜋𝑈𝑆𝐴
𝑄𝑑
𝑝𝑞0 𝐴
𝐷 𝐶
𝑀𝑅
𝑄
𝑄𝐶𝐻 𝑄𝑈𝑆𝐴 𝑄𝐶𝐻 + 𝑄𝑈𝑆𝐴
𝑚𝑎𝑥 𝜋 → 𝑀𝐶𝐶𝐻 = 𝑀𝐶𝑈𝑆𝐴 = 𝑀𝑅
e.g., production of NIKE’s shoes in China and USA
With many plants: 𝑚𝑎𝑥 𝜋 → 𝑀𝐶1 = ⋯ = 𝑀𝐶𝑛 = 𝑀𝑅
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Example #1
Red Rose is a monopolist selling flowers in two villages, namely, Trenton and
Stenton. There are 100 individuals in Trenton, each with a demand function for
𝑝𝑇
flowers 𝑞𝑇 = 0.4 − 100. There are 500 individuals in Stenton, each with a demand
𝑝
function for flowers 𝑞𝑆 = 0.16 − 𝑆 . Red Rose’s cost function is 𝐶 𝑄 = 10𝑄,
500
where 𝑄 = 𝑄𝑇 + 𝑄𝑆 is the total volume of flowers sold.
1. Suppose that price discrimination is possible. Find the equilibrium and the
price elasticities of demand in each village. Comment on your findings.
Answer: The aggregate demand function for Trenton is 𝑄𝑇 = 𝑞𝑇 × 100 = 40 −
𝑝𝑇 whereas that for Stenton is 𝑄𝑆 = 𝑞𝑆 × 500 = 80 − 𝑝𝑆 . Accordingly, the total
revenue functions are: 𝑇𝑅𝑇 = 𝑝𝑇 𝑄𝑇 × 𝑄𝑇 = 40𝑄𝑇 − 𝑄𝑇2 and 𝑇𝑅𝑆 = 𝑝𝑆 𝑄𝑆 ×
𝑄𝑆 = 80𝑄𝑆 − 𝑄𝑆2 . This implies that 𝑀𝑅𝑇 = 40 − 2𝑄𝑇 and 𝑀𝑅𝑆 = 80 − 2𝑄𝑆 . In
equilibrium, it holds 𝑀𝑅𝑇 = 𝑀𝑅𝑆 = 𝑀𝐶 = 10 .
Substituting from above and solving the resulting equations one gets 𝑄𝑇 =
15, 𝑄𝑆 = 35, 𝑝𝑇 = 25 and 𝑝𝑆 = 45. The price elasticities of demand are 𝜀𝑇𝑑 =
𝜕𝑄𝑇 𝑝𝑇 25 𝜕𝑄 𝑝 45
= −1 × 15 = −1.67 and 𝜀𝑆𝑑 = 𝜕𝑝𝑆 𝑄𝑆 = −1 × 35 = −1.29.
𝜕𝑝𝑇 𝑄𝑇 𝑆 𝑆
The results make economic sense; the higher price is charged in the market
where the elasticity of demand is lower.
Managerial Decisions for Monopolistic Firms: Example #1
2. Suppose that price discrimination is not possible. Find the new equilibrium.
Answer: The aggregate (two-markets) demand is 𝑄 = 𝑄𝑇 + 𝑄𝑆 = 120 − 2𝑝,
where 𝑝 is the common price. The respective marginal revenue function is
𝑀𝑅 = 60 − 𝑄, which when equated to the marginal cost 𝑀𝐶 = 10 yielding
𝑄 = 50 and 𝑝 = 35.
3. Compare Red Rose's profits, aggregate (village) consumer surpluses and total
welfare under both scenarios.
Answer: With the discriminatory price policy the firm's profit is 𝜋 =
15 × 25 + 35 × 45 − 10 × 50 = 1,450. Consumer surpluses are: 𝐶𝑆𝑇 =
0.5 × 40 − 25 × 15 = 112.5 and 𝐶𝑆𝑆 = 0.5 × 80 − 45 × 35 = 612.5 .
Therefore, the two-market consumer surplus is 𝐶𝑆 = 725 and the welfare
level is 𝑊 = 1,450 + 725 = 2,175.
With the non-discriminatory pricing the firm's profit is 𝜋 = 50 × 35 −
10 × 50 = 1,250. The consumer surplus in Trenton is 𝐶𝑆𝑇 = 0.5 × (40 −
35) × 5 = 12.5 and in Stenton is 𝐶𝑆𝑆 = 0.5 × 80 − 35 × 45 = 1,012.5. The
corresponding welfare level is 𝑊 = 1,250 + 12.5 + 1,012.5 = 2,275 (increases
by 100).