The Emerging Conception of The Policy Sciences
The Emerging Conception of The Policy Sciences
The Emerging Conception of The Policy Sciences
ABSTRACT
The policy sciences may be conceived as knowledge of the policy process and of the relevance of
knowledge in the process. Professional careers in the theoretical branches of policy analysis have
been typically academic and include professors of political science, jurisprudence, political
economy, and public administration. One novelty of recent decades has been the prodigious
multiplication of policy careers having little direct contact with traditional policy theory, though
grounded in some specialized knowledge of the physical, biological, or cultural sciences. New
specialties have arisen that affect the procedures of the policy making process itself, such as the
handling of computerized information.
Whatever their origin policy scientists appear to be converging toward a distinctive outlook.
Contextuality calls for a cognitive map of the whole social process in reference to which each
specific activity is considered. Problem orientation includes five intellectual tasks: goal
clarification; trend description; analysis of conditions; projection of future developments;
invention, evaluation and selection of alternatives. There is also a distinctive synthesis of
technique, guided by principles of content and procedure.
A distinctive identity image is evolving in which the role of the mediator-integrator among
men of knowledge and between knowledge and action is becoming more explicit.
Policy science careers have come into existence with little fanfare a n d little awareness
o f a n identity in c o m m o n or of a distinctive o u t l o o k or synthesis of skills. We are,
somewhat belatedly, engaged in appraising these developments and proposing future
lines of growth. Hence our current interest in the emerging conception of the policy
sciences. As a working f o r m u l a I describe the policy sciences as concerned with two
separable though entwined frames of reference: knowledge o f the policy process;
knowledge in the process.1
o
"~w
-'~ ~ ~ ~
o~= o~
o~.~
~
o ~ ~
o . ~~
~~ o ~'~
o
9
~:~._ ~ ~
~ztO
~
o ~ '~ . . . ~ ~ .
o ~ ~
- - 0
~.-
i
o
cD ~ o
~o
-o k;
2 .o
r~
~ ~ . ~
- t t~t g o
oo
~.~
0
o
"8
3 For partial exemplifications see the studies in public order, chiefly published at The Yale University
Press, directed by Myres S. McDougal and Harold D. Lasswell, and including treatises on the
international law of war, space, sea resources, propaganda, treaty interpretation, etc., by the senior
authors and, among others, Florentino P. Feliciano, William T. Burke, Ivan A. Vlassic, Douglas
M. Johnston, B. F. Murty, James C. Miller.
Policy Sciences 1 (1970), 3-14
10 Harold D. Lasswell
higher gross national product); well-being (i.e., a lowered incidence of disease);
skill (i.e., higher levels of mathematical know-how); affection (i.e., reduced private
quarrels); respect (i.e., decreased discrimination against individual merit); rectitude
(i.e., increased concern for and responsible service of common welfare).
A short list of value categories (such as the eight mentioned here) can be used by
any one policy analyst to refer to all the events in any social context, and therefore to
serve as a means of calibrating equivalencies of reference in the whole-referring
language of any other analyst. (Among the many terms that are at least partial
equivalencies of "values" are "preferences," "needs," "desires," "drives," or "ends.")
Conceiving of the social process as a value shaping and sharing process yields
several advantages to a policy analyst. It permits easy focus either on the aggregate
situation or on the position of particular participants. It directs attention to aggregate
or particular gross or net outcome flows over a selected time period. This practice is
well established in the description of wealth, since we are accustomed to operationalize
the term and to speak of gross and net income changes through time; and also to
summarize gross and net wealth statuses at specified time intervals. We also sum up
investment flows and consumption flows. When claims to wealth are used as base
values to increase wealth as a scope value during a given period, it is investment;
when claims are used for other value outcomes than investment, the process is
consumption (well-being, respect, and so on).
It is less well established but analytically important to use value analysis as a
technique of describing all value shaping and sharing processes. Consider power, or
the giving or receiving of support in important decisions (the outcomes that are
expected to be and in fact are enforceable if necessary by imposing severe deprivations
on challengers). We refer to gross and net power changes in the predispositions and
resources available to the public order of a nation-state, or to a participating group
or individual; similarly, for gross and net shift in power status from the beginning to
the end of a period. Moreover, power may be used as a base for later power (the
parallel to investment) or used for other values (the parallel to consumption).
Parallel distinctions can be made for the other values (in our list, they are enlighten-
ment, well-being, skill, affection, respect, rectitude).4
For the sake of finer comparisons "institutional" terms are required. They are
defined as patterns relatively specialized to the shaping and sharing of a category of
values. The double-reference technique--of locating outcome events and of identifying
subpatterns--is a means of expediting comparative studies. It facilitates the task of
describing the significance of any institutional detail or configuration of detail. For
instance, policy analysis may be concerned with appraising the impact of institutions
primarily specialized to each value process, but having repercussions on every sector.
4 See Harold D. Lasswell and Allan R. Holmberg, "Toward a General Theory of Directed Value
Accumulation and Institutional Development," in Ralph Braibanti, Political and Administrative
Development (Duke Univ. Press, Durham, N.C., 1969); Bruce M. Russett, Hayward R. Alker, Jr.,
Karl W. Deutsch, Harold D. Lasswell, Worm Handbook of Political and Social Indicators (New
Haven, Yale Univ. Press, 1964); C. L. Taylor (ed.), Aggregate Data Analysis; Political and Social
Indicators in Cross-national Research (International Social Science Council, No. 10, Paris and The
Hague, Mouton & Co., 1968).
Policy Sciences 1 (1970), 3-14
The Emerging Conception of the Policy Sciences 11
Consider wealth institutions, such as private capitalism, socialism, consumers'
cooperation. They can be compared in terms of income, wealth, or consumption levels.
Consider power institutions: it is relevant to compare systems of popular, oligarchic,
and monocratic rule in terms of their consequences for power and other values.
Similar comparisons can be considered for the many institutional arrangements of
the other value-institution sectors and for the component elements of a given
institution, such as the degree of specialization of participants, their perspectives,
their detailed situational features, strategic (and tactical) devices, outcome routines
and effects.
Distinctive Identity
The distinctive outlook and synthesizing techniques of modern policy analysts are
interwoven with the evolution of a distinctive identity image. The conception of the
policy sciences is at once a by-product of an emerging image and a contributor to its
further clarification.
The contemporary policy scientist perceives himself as an integrator of knowledge
and action, hence as a specialist in eliciting and giving effect to all the rationality of
which individuals and groups are capable at any given time. He is a mediator between
those who specialize in specific areas of knowledge and those who make the commit-
ments in public and private life (the public and civic order). He is continually
challenged to improve his theory of the policy process itself, and therefore to perform
a crucial role, especially at the intelligence and appraisal phases of policy.
In achieving the new identity it has been necessary to overcome the image of a
second class man of knowledge and a second class man of action, and to perceive that
the integrative role of the policy scientist is indispensable to the security and advance-
ment of a world civilization of science-based technology. The scientist or scholar who
becomes the mediator between the social environment and his colleagues is a target
of ambivalent sentiment on the part of colleagues and the larger environment; and
privately he often shares the ambivalence. Fellow specialists may think of him as a
careerist, as a man who tries to substitute power for serious achievement. Presently
they regard him as an ex-scientist or ex-scholar. The larger environment is not certain
how to categorize a man who stands for knowledge and is nevertheless a man of
affairs. As a man of affairs the Dean or the President or the Association Secretary or
the consultant seems half-hearted. He is not necessarily a standard brand politician
who runs for office or manages a party machine. He is sufficiently intellectual to arouse
some inferiority feelings among men of affairs; and he is enough of a man of affairs to
introduce a note of constraint in the intellectual community. He is perceived as
" h a l f man, half brain."
Both the intellectual community and the community at large are beginning to
acknowledge the indispensable place of the integrator, mediator, and go-between.
However, the appropriate image is still semidefined. Perspectives are in flux.
And indeed this somewhat confused, contradictory image is not out of harmony
Policy Sciences 1 (1970), 3-14
14 Harold D. Lasswell
with the present state of transition. The basic uncertainty is "whose side is he o n ? "
Presumably policy scientists as a whole can be analogized to one of the traditional
practitioners of the mediating role, the lawyer. The lawyer is "for hire"; hence he is
permitted to serve the presumptively guilty as well as the presumptively innocent. But
there are limits on his freedom. He is, after all, an officer of the court, which gives
him a semiofficial capacity. There are limits on the strategies that the counselor is
permitted to use on behalf of a client, and it is perhaps vaguely perceived that public
policy goals are served by giving everyone who is involved in a public controversy an
expert who can say whatever there is to say on his behalf. Obviously, this may bring
to the focus of attention of the community decisionmaker data that would otherwise
be neglected. Hence it may serve rationality.
But who is served by the man of knowledge, especially by the intermediaries
between specialists and the social environment ? The answer is not difficult: at first the
knowledge mediators seek to serve themselves. Hence they serve the rich if the rich
want to buy knowledge. They serve the powerful if the powerful want to buy the
know-how for weapons. But this is not all. Many of them hope to serve a broader
range of interests. They want to persuade the rich and powerful to support the
knowledge that will heal the sick and improve the position of the socially deprived
in every category.
Since the policy sciences are concerned with the aggregate as well as the individual
value pattern, they are responsible for perfecting the tools required to appraise the
consequences of all groups and institutions. This includes all specialists in knowledge
and all institutions of knowledge. Hence policy scientists must ask: is it the function
of men of knowledge to take initiatives on behalf of all man ? Or only to serve the rich
and powerful? Or shall they try to become the rich and powerful? And if they do,
will they serve themselves or will they serve man ?
The identity problems of the contemporary policy scientist are as complex as those
of any element in society. But the principles already developed for the examination of
the self-in-context contain the seeds of solution. Such at least is the opportunity of
the new schools and programs existing or in prospect for the emerging profession.