FTGuide To Bond and Money Markets
FTGuide To Bond and Money Markets
FTGuide To Bond and Money Markets
BOND AND
much fun as making money in the financial
markets. As a wealthy investor in his early
50s, Glen now spends most of his time
Curious about financial markets in the modern MARKETS
running his own equity portfolio (see www. economy?
MONEY
glen-arnold-investments.co.uk) and a property The Financial Times Guide to Bond and Money
development company from his offi ce in the Then this is the book for you. Markets is a practical and easy-to-follow
heart of rural Leicestershire. introduction to the global wholesale financial
markets. Bestselling author Glen Arnold shows
Glen is the author of the investing classics
The Great Investors, The Financial Times
Guide to Value Investing, The Financial Times
Guide to Investing and Get Started in Shares. The Financial Times Guide to Bond and Money Markets is your
MARKETS you how bond and money markets work, where
they are located, and explains their impact on
everyday life.
definitive introduction to the financial marketplace. This book The Financial Times Guide to Bond and Money
He wrote the market-leading university
textbooks Corporate Financial Management, provides an authoritative and comprehensive guide to the workings GLEN ARNOLD Markets includes:
Modern Financial Markets and Institutions and of the modern financial system. It will help you understand key
• An overview of bond and money markets
Essentials of Corporate Financial Management. bond and money market terms and will demystify the different
types of markets, explaining the role of money market instruments • Government, international and corporate
He is also the author of three definitive books bonds
and revealing how fluctuations in the marketplace can affect your
on finance written for the professional market: • Interbank and Eurocurrency markets
own money strategies.
The Financial Times Handbook of Corporate • Treasury bills and commercial paper
Finance, The Financial Times Guide to the The Financial Times Guide to Bond and Money Markets:
Financial Markets and The Financial Times • Repurchase agreements and certifi cates
of deposits
Guide to Banking. All of these books are • Provides an easy-to-follow guide to bond and money markets
available from Financial Times Publishing. • Bills of exchange and banker’s acceptances
• Helps you understand the various markets and their functions
• Financial concepts and mathematics
• Explains in-depth finance theory and mathematical structures • Bond and money market securities valuation
• Features comprehensive graphs and real case studies from the • Central banking influences on interest rates
Financial Times
ARNOLD
FINANCE
Visit our website at
www.pearson-books.com
GLEN ARNOLD
PART 1
AN OVERVIEW 1
PART 2
BOND MARKETS 27
2 Government bonds 29
PART 3
MONEY MARKETS 237
PART 4
VALUING BONDS AND MONEY MARKET
INSTRUMENTS 309
PART 5
SOME VARIATIONS ON A BOND THEME 381
15 Securitisation 383
Index 460
Glen Arnold, PhD, has held positions of Professor of Investment and Professor
of Corporate Finance, but came to the conclusion that academic life was not
nearly as much fun as making money in the financial markets. As a wealthy
investor in his early 50s, Glen now spends most of his time running his own
portfolio (www.glen-arnold-investments.co.uk) and a property development
company from his office in the heart of rural Leicestershire. He is happy to
share his ideas with fellow enthusiasts and so writes a regular Deep Value Shares
newsletter on the investment website ADVFN.
Glen is the author of the number one best-selling investment book The
Financial Times Guide to Investing as well as the investing classics The Financial
Times Guide to Value Investing, The Great Investors and Get Started in Shares. He
wrote the market-leading university textbooks Corporate Financial Management,
Modern Financial Markets and Institutions and Essentials of Corporate Financial
Management. He is also the author of three definitive books on finance: The
Financial Times Guide to Banking, The Financial Times Handbook of Corporate
Finance and The Financial Times Guide to the Financial Markets. All these books
are available from Pearson Education.
This book is a simple, easy-to-follow guide to bond and money markets, which
assumes no prior knowledge of finance. The emphasis is on gaining an under-
standing of the underlying concepts in the first half of the book, the impor-
tance of these markets and ideas in the practical world of finance. Later I
introduce those elements of quantitative finance that are absolutely essential.
This way, I hope, the essence of this technical subject is explained without
bamboozling the reader with an overload of mathematics.
It explains:
● the vital role of money market instruments, ranging from commercial paper
to interbank lending
● the valuation of these securities and how value changes as interest rates
change.
● University students needing more depth on bond and money markets than
is provided by their main course texts.
● Those curious minds who realise they need to understand the financial mar-
kets to comprehend the modern economy.
● Private investors who might consider putting some of their savings in these
markets.
Glen Arnold
The production team at Pearson did a great job of turning a raw manuscript
into a book. I would like to thank Lisa Robinson, Melanie Carter, Vivienne
Church, Jen Halford and Kelly Miller.
Publisher’s acknowledgements
We are grateful to the following for permission to reproduce copyright material:
Table 2.11 courtesy of FTSE Group; tables 2.5, 2.6, 2.7, 3.1, 3.2, 3.5, 5.3, 5.4,
7.2, 7.3 and 11.2 courtesy of Thomson Reuters; table 9.6 courtesy of Moody’s
Investors Service; table 9.7 courtesy of Standard & Poor’s; table 10.1 courtesy of
Euro Repo Index.
Figures 3.3, 3.4 and 3.5 courtesy of Agence France Trésor; figure 3.6 courtesy of
Bundesrepublik Deutschland Finanzagentur; figures 4.6 and 4.7 courtesy of
www.advfn.com; figure 8.2 courtesy of the European Central Bank; figures
15.3, 15.5, 15.6 and 15.7 courtesy of the European Covered Bond Council.
All Financial Times articles © The Financial Times Limited. All Rights Reserved,
except Article 7.2, printed courtesy of Andrew Macdowall.
In some instances we have been unable to trace the owners of copyright material,
and we would appreciate any information that would enable us to do so.
Bond and money markets are vital parts of the global financial infrastructure.
They provide financing requirements for, and are essential to, the daily finan-
cial management of governments as well as thousands of corporations and
financial institutions. They also provide alternative sources of investment
returns for savers. A country’s economic strength will be reflected in the value
placed by the financial markets on its government-issued borrowing instru-
ments. Similarly, the financial strength of a corporation or a bank is indicated
by the rates of return it has to offer to borrow in the bond or money markets.
The difference between bond markets and money markets is a time or maturity
issue. The term to maturity (or simply term or maturity or tenor) is the
length of time remaining until the borrower pays the stated amount to the
lender who owns the bond or money market instrument. Generally, money
market instruments have maturity dates of one year or less, and bond markets
deal in instruments with maturities in excess of one year.
As you can see from the extract from the annual accounts of the giant drinks
company Diageo (Table 1.1), a firm requires good understanding of a great
many different debt instruments to carry out the efficient management of its
financing requirements, and it is crucial that this aspect of running a firm is
expertly executed. The debt instruments employed by Diageo are typical of
those used by large corporations, ranging from a simple bank overdraft to the
more esoteric hedging instruments, and may be in different currencies and
have different maturity dates. At this stage the titles of these instruments are
going to seem confusing jargon, but by the end of the book you will have a
sound understanding of terms such as commercial paper, medium-term notes
and interest rate hedging.
To keep track of all its financial instrument obligations and to ensure that a
company has sufficient finance for its needs throughout a year at the lowest
cost is a skilful undertaking and requires a complete understanding of the
Table 1.1
complexities of the bond and money markets. If a firm can achieve efficient
management of its financing requirements, its customers may also benefit
through lower prices. If a firm mismanages its financing, and has to pay
exorbitant interest rates on the money it needs to borrow, then these ineffi-
ciencies may well result in higher consumer prices or company liquidation.
Then, in Chapters 15 and 16, we examine some of the more unusual securities
that have evolved from the markets, such as bonds where the interest paid to
investors depends on monthly mortgage payments from thousands of home
owners, or the trading of agreements to notionally deposit money and notion-
ally receive interest at a future date.
Bonds
The concept of governments, companies and other institutions borrowing
funds to invest in long-term projects and operations is a straightforward one,
yet in today’s sophisticated capital markets, with their wide variety of financial
instruments and forms of debt, the borrowing and lending decision can be
bewildering. Is the domestic bond market or the Eurobond market the better
choice? On what terms, fixed- or floating-rate interest, with collateral or
unsecured? And what about high-yield bonds or convertibles? The variety of
methods of providing long-term finance is almost infinite.
1
Also called the debtor or borrower.
The secondary markets are sometimes very liquid; that is, those organisations
lending their surpluses to borrowers by buying bonds are able to get at their
capital (turn it into cash) by selling quickly to other investors without the risk
of reducing the price significantly, and the transaction costs of releasing the
cash are low. But most corporate bonds have pretty poor liquidity, with most
primary market investors buying them and then holding until maturity,
resulting in very few secondary market trades.
when they are first issued is generally between 5 and 30 years, but it should be
noted that a bond is classified during its life according to the time remaining
to maturity, not the maturity when it was issued, so a 30-year bond which has
only 4 years left until it matures, is a short.
A number of firms have issued bonds with a longer than usual maturity date –
IBM and Reliance of India have issued 100-year bonds, as have Coca-Cola and
Walt Disney (Disney’s was known as the ‘Sleeping Beauty bond’). There are
even some 1,000-year bonds in existence – Canadian Pacific Corporation is
paying a dividend of 4% on a 1,000-year bond issued in 1883 by the Toronto
Grey and Bruce Railway and due to be repaid in 2883.
Offsetting these plus points are the facts that bond holders do not (usually) share
in the increase in value created by an extraordinarily successful business, and
there is an absence of any voting control over the management of the company.
For a company, bonds offer the advantage of long-term borrowing, often with
a constant interest rate for, say, 15 years; the original lenders cannot withdraw
the capital they lent from the company or increase the interest rate (this is the
most common case, but, given the potential for innovation here, there are
bonds that allow these things). An overdraft may have a variable interest rate
and can be withdrawn at short notice, leaving the company in need of finance.
It also has to be renewed, maybe every six months, and there is a real danger
that the lender will refuse to ‘roll over’ (continue) the debt at a future renewal
date, or may demand a much higher interest rate to continue the lending.
Term loans from banks are often more difficult to obtain in the size required by
larger companies, and they frequently cost more over the lifetime of the loan.
Of course, bank overdrafts and loans have the advantage that they are available
even to the smallest firms, whereas the bond market is generally open for large
firms only.
Fixed-interest securities
Bonds are often referred to collectively as fixed-interest securities. Most
bonds are indeed fixed rate, offering regular coupon amounts agreed at the
outset, but some are variable, with the interest rising or falling every few
months depending on a benchmark interest rate (e.g. Libor, the London
Interbank Offered Rate – discussed in Chapter 8). Other bonds vary the interest
paid for a particular three or six months depending on all sorts of factors, e.g.
the rate of inflation or the price of copper. Nevertheless they are all lumped
together as fixed interest to contrast these types of loan instrument with equit-
ies that do not carry a promise of a return.
Fluctuating values
The value of a bond – the price at which it is trading between investors on the
secondary market – may fluctuate considerably during its life, and this value
reflects the changes in the prevailing interest rate. Bonds are usually issued, but
not always, with a nominal value of £100 or $1,000 (or €1,000, etc.). They
may have any nominal value, but typical ‘lots’ are 100, 1,000, 10,000 and
50,000 of, say, pounds, euros or dollars. A five-year £100 bond issued with a
coupon of 5% means that it will pay £5 per year, which is 5% of its nominal
value of £100. After five years have expired, the issuer will have made five
payments of the £5 coupon to the current holder, or ten of £2.50 if it pays
semi-annual (every six months) interest, and the eventual holder receives the
nominal value of £100 at the end of the term.
If, during those five years, the interest rate that investors demand for bonds of
a similar risk class and time to maturity rises, the market value of the bond will
fall to compensate for its coupon rate of only 5%, so that its rate of return
reflects the prevailing interest rate.
throughout its life. However, this is unlikely to be the case, as the value of a
bond will fluctuate throughout its life to take into account the prevailing rate
of interest. Interest rates may change daily and the value of bonds changes
accordingly. If interest rates on alternative, equally risky bonds rise to 6%
when the bond has three years left to maturity, the bond will be a less attractive
investment were it still to be offered for sale at £100. It is offering the following
deal: in one year receive £5, in two years another £5, and in three years £100
plus the final £5 coupon, i.e. 5% at a time when other bonds offer 6% for the
same risk and maturity.
For investors to obtain the current going rate of 6%, the bond must offer
secondary market traders £5 per year plus a capital gain over the next three
years. This will occur if the price of the bond drops to £97.327 (take this
on trust for now, you will be able to calculate this yourself after reading
Chapter 13). At this price, investors gain £2.673 by buying at £97.327 and
receiving £100 on maturity three years later.
The capital gain is worth £2.673 ÷ £97.327 = 2.746% over three years, or
0.915% per year. Add that to the coupon of £5 per year on an investment that cost
£97.327, which in percentage terms works out at 5.137% per year, £5 ÷ £97.327
= 5.137%, and you obtain (approximately) the 6% that investors in bonds of
this risk class and maturity are now requiring. These are rough calculations
to give you the gist, precision comes in Chapter 13 – then you’ll see how the
overall rate of return does work out at exactly 6% once we take into account the
timing of compounding (interest received on the interest in the three years).
So the bond selling in the secondary market is rather like a bank account that
offers the following deal: you put £97.327 into the bank account and the bank
pays you 6% interest per year. Each year you withdraw £5. At the end of three
years your bank account contains £100. However, while a bank account might
produce this type of deal if you agree to hold your money there for the full
three years, the bond has the advantage that you can choose to sell the bond
to another investor at any point during the three years.
Conversely, if general interest rates that investors are now accepting for this
risk class fall to 2% when the bond has three years to maturity, then it will
seem an attractive investment at £100, because it is offering a better rate of
interest than is current, and its price will rise to £108.652. Investors are accept-
ing a capital loss of £8.652 over the three years but being compensated with
three lots of £5.
In both these cases, the bond will still be worth its face value (£100) at the end
of its life.
Bonds come in all shapes and sizes, from UK government bonds to Chinese
company bonds. Of this vast volume of $90 million million bonds3 outstanding
2
Included in the BIS figures for domestic bonds are a small fraction of money market
instruments.
3
This includes all currencies, even though they are summed in US dollars.
(not yet redeemed – the capital has not been repaid), about $70 trillion are
issued in the domestic bond markets of countries, that is issued within
the country in its currency by resident issuers, under the jurisdiction of the
authorities there. In addition to these domestic bonds there are another $20
trillion of bonds issued outside the domestic markets on the international
bond markets. These are issued outside the market where the borrower resides.
These can either be outside the jurisdiction of the country in whose currency
the bond is denominated – thus a bond denominated in pounds sterling
but issued in Switzerland is outside of the control of London regulators and
government (a Eurobond) – or issued by foreigners in a country’s currency in
and under the rules of that country (a foreign bond).
shows some large ups and downs over a ten-year period. As we saw in the
example of the 5% coupon bond, if the rates of return investors demand
from bonds in the future rise, then the price of the bond can fall, sometimes
dramatically as in the case of 2013. Thus there are years when bond prices fall
by a larger percentage than the percentage coupon rate, resulting in an overall
negative return for the year for an investor who buys at the beginning of the
year and sells at the end.
It might be difficult to discern from this figure, with it being only for a ten-year
period and one subject to a severe shock in 2008, that it is generally the case
that bond returns are less volatile than share returns. This is better illustrated
in Figure 1.3, which shows the returns on UK government bonds (gilts) over
each of the years from 1900 to 2013. These are not interest rates that the
government paid, rather they are the combination of the cash coupon received
Figure 1.3 UK annual real gilt returns 1900–2013, percentage (real means after
excluding inflation)
Source: Data from Barclays Equity Gilt Study 2014
as a percentage of the secondary market price at the start of the year, plus the
capital gain or loss in the secondary market over 365 days for bonds with 15 or
20 years to run before the government redeems them.
Note that there are many years where the return was negative. However, a
comparison with the equity markets’ returns shows that government bond
returns were far less volatile than equity returns – see Figure 1.4. Shares quite
often show annual returns up and down more than 15%; bonds show this
relatively infrequently.
Governments issue bonds to finance the gap between what they raise in taxes
and what they spend. Bonds from strong nations, such as the UK, the USA or
Germany, are considered (almost) risk free with regard to the likelihood of the
issuer not paying coupons and/or the principal, or breaching some other con-
dition in the agreement, i.e. default risk, and so give relatively low rates of
return because of their small risk factor. If a country is in economic trouble,
with high levels of borrowing, investors may become nervous that they will
not receive their coupon payments and the return of the principal, and there-
fore be less willing to hold these bonds unless they offer higher interest rates.
This happened to Greece, Spain, Portugal and Ireland in 2011, causing their
bonds to be deemed a riskier investment and investors to require higher rates
of interest to invest in them.
Bond issuance
Financial institutions, usually an investment bank, may assist a firm to issue
bonds. This is known as underwriting and they generally guarantee to the
issuer that the entire issue will be sold. They then try to sell the bonds to investors,
taking the risk that they may not be able to sell the whole issue. Alternatively
they may act as a distribution agent for the issuer, trying to sell on a best-
efforts basis, but not guaranteeing the sale. A third possibility is that the
investment bank organises a private placement where one or more large
financial institutions are lined up to receive the whole of a forthcoming bond
issue. Companies, by paying commission to the financial institutions, benefit
from both their professional experience and skill in selling issues of bonds and
their reputation with investing institutions.
Credit ratings
To assist investors in assessing the likelihood of a borrower defaulting there are
teams of analysts working for credit rating companies who look into the
detail of the strengths and weaknesses of the borrower and give a rating to its
creditworthiness – a triple-A, AAA, Aaa rating means that the borrower is very
unlikely to default. Lower ratings, single-A, B, C or D, indicate that there is
progressively more risk of default. Details about credit ratings and the agencies
that issue them are in Chapter 5.
issue, whereas a bank may not be in a position to offer the total amount
required. When a company issues bonds, it has some control over what cove-
nants or restrictions are placed on the issue. Covenants are conditions with
which the bond issuer must comply (such as limiting the amount of debt a
company can take on).
Securitised bonds are issued by an entity separate from the owner of the cash
flow and therefore can have a separate credit rating which may well be a higher
rating than the company/bank as a whole is given. Thus, for example, a bank
might set up a separate company which receives monthly income from 1,000
house mortgage payers. This separate company issues bonds secured against
the mortgage rights it holds, and the bond interest is paid out of the mortgage
receipts from 1,000 households. The interest on these bonds may be fixed at
the time of issue or floating relative to a benchmark interest rate such as Libor,
a standard rate of interest for loans.
Covered bonds are secured on the cash flows from mortgages, public sector
loans or other loan receipts, but the assets (e.g. 1,000 mortgage rights) remain
on the balance sheet of the issuer, usually a bank or financial institution, which
retains control over them. Thus the covered bond holder has the security of
both the assigned assets, e.g. the cash inflows from 1,000 mortgages, and the
promise from the issuing firm to make good any shortfall if the securitised
assets are not sufficient. Covered bonds usually are perceived as very low risk
due to the reliability of the assets they can draw on.
can be called back for redemption at any time is obviously not something
bond holders favour without offsetting compensation, especially when the
bond price would otherwise have risen significantly above the par value.
● Usually bonds are set up with a bullet structure, where regular payments
made reflect the interest only and the whole of the principal amount (face
value) is repaid at maturity. Balloon interest means that the coupons paid
on a long-term bond rise over time. Thus bonds issued to finance the con-
struction of a wind turbine field might pay low coupons in the early years
when income is poor and expenses high, but then, after the first three years,
the coupons grow larger.
● Principal is the amount that will be repaid on maturity, typically £100,
£1,000 or $1,000. It has various names: face value, par value, face amount,
redemption value or maturity value.
● Coupon rate is the amount of interest paid per year expressed as a percent-
age of the principal. Typically it is paid twice a year, or semi-annually, but it
could be paid more or less frequently than this. It is also known as interest
rate, dividend or nominal rate.
● Zero coupon is when a bond does not pay interest/coupon payments, but
is redeemed for face value at maturity. The return that an investor receives
on these bonds is achieved by buying the bonds at a discounted price
which is less than face value. So a five-year zero coupon bond that will be
redeemed at £100 might be selling at £60 today. Using the discounted
purchase price and the time to redemption, it is possible to work out the
annual yield during the life of the bond, which in this case works out at
10.76% (see Chapter 13 for the calculations).
● Convertible bonds can be converted at the insistence of the holder into
shares or other securities of the issuing company, usually equity shares.
● Floating-rate notes (FRNs) (also called variable-rate notes) have a variable
coupon reset on a regular basis, usually every three or six months, in relation
to a benchmark or reference rate. The typical term for an FRN is about
5–12 years.
● Bond funds are collective investment vehicles which enable small/retail
investors as well as major financial institutions to invest in a broad portfolio
of bonds. Some are listed on stock markets, others are traded over the
counter in tailor-made deals.
Money markets
Money markets are a source of short-term finance for governments, corpora-
tions and other organisations. There are times when these organisations are in
need of funds for merely a day, a week or the next three months. They thus
need a place where they can borrow to make up a shortfall; the money markets
fulfil this role. Banks are an alternative source of short-term finance, but in
many cases the money markets are cheaper and involve less hassle.
At other times an organisation may have surplus funds and instead of keeping
that money as cash or in current accounts at banks, earning little or no interest,
it chooses to lend it out to those needing short-term funds by purchasing
money market instruments from them.
(Note that while most money market securities are issued at a discount, this is
not true of all of them. Certificates of deposit and interbank deposits (banks
lending for short periods to each other), for example, are issued at their face
value and then redeemed at a higher value.)
The discount and rate of interest (yield) earned are dependent on the risk
level and the maturity of the instrument. The maturity is the length of
time between issue of the instrument (start of borrowing) and the time it is
redeemed when money due is paid (original maturity), or the length of time
between when a security is priced or purchased in the secondary market and
the date of redemption (current maturity). The maturity length can vary
from overnight (borrowing for just 24 hours) to 3 months to 1 year (or more,
occasionally). Interest is measured in percentage points, which are further
divided into basis points (bps). One basis point equals 1/100 of a percentage
point.
● Repurchase agreements (repos) are a way of borrowing for a few days using
a sale and repurchase agreement in which securities (e.g. government
bonds) are sold for cash at an agreed price with a promise to buy back the
securities at a specified (higher) price at a future date. The interest on the
agreement is the difference between the initial sale price and the agreed
buy-back, and because the agreements are usually collateralised (secured)
by government-backed securities such as Treasury bills, the interest rate is
lower than a typical unsecured loan from a bank. If the borrower defaults
on its obligations to buy back on maturity the lender can hold on to or
sell the securities. Banks and other financial institutions use repos very
regularly to borrow money from each other. Companies do use the repo
markets, but much less frequently than the banks. (There is more on repos
in Chapter 10.)
Italy and Germany, where individual federal states issue them regularly.
There are also many bill issues by companies close to governments, e.g.
the French railway, SNCF, or the German postal service, Deutsche
Bundespost.
● Certificates of deposit (CDs) are issued by banks when funds are deposited
with them by other banks, corporations, individuals or investment compa-
nies. The certificates state that a deposit has been made (a time deposit) and
that at the maturity date the bank will pay a sum higher than that originally
deposited. The maturities are typically one to four months and can be nego-
tiable or non-negotiable. (You can find more on this in Chapter 10.) There
is a penalty on the saver withdrawing the money before the maturity date
(they are term securities). A company with surplus cash can put it into a
negotiable CD knowing that if its situation changes and it needs extra cash,
it can sell the CD for cash in a secondary market.
● Bills of exchange and banker’s acceptances are commercial financial
instruments, often linked to international trade (exports), which enable
corporations to obtain credit or raise money and to trade with corporations
at low risk of financial inconvenience or loss. Once issued, they may be
traded on the secondary markets. (There is more on these instruments in
Chapter 11.)
following a hurricane. These markets are also used by central banks to influence
interest rates charged throughout the economy – for example, changing base
rates at banks through the central bank conducting repo deals in the market
will have a knock-on effect on mortgage rates or business loan rates.
In the modern era, rather than having one or a few market locations or
buildings in which money market instruments are bought and sold, we have
organisations arranging deals over the telephone and then completing them
electronically. The process of bringing buyers and sellers together is assisted by
the many brokers and dealers who tend to operate from the trading rooms
of the big banks and specialist trading houses – they regularly trade money
market securities in lots worth tens of millions of pounds, dollars, etc. Some
of them act as market makers, maintaining an inventory of securities and
advertising prices at which they will sell and, slightly lower, prices at which
they will buy. By providing these middle-man services they assist the players
in the market to quickly find a counterparty willing to trade, thus enhancing
liquidity. They are said to be traders in STIR products, that is short-term
interest rate products.
Some of the trades are simply private deals with legal obligations to be enforced
by each side, but some are conducted through a central clearing house, with
each party responsible for reporting the deal to the clearing house, which set-
tles the deal by debiting the account of the buyer and crediting the account of
the seller. The clearing house then holds the security on behalf of the buyer.
The risk of a counterparty reneging on the deal (counterparty risk) is reduced
by trading through a clearing house because the clearing house itself usually
becomes a guarantor to each party.
Case study
Vodafone
You can get some idea of the importance of money markets to companies from
Table 1.2 showing investment amounts taken from Vodafone’s annual reports.
Vodafone keeps a large amount of cash and cash equivalents in reserve: over
£7 billion in 2013. Cash equivalents are not quite cash but they are so liquid that
they are near-cash (near-money or quasi-money). They are financial assets that
can easily be sold to raise cash, or which are due to pay back their capital value
in a few days, with low risk regarding the amount of cash they will release. These
are mostly money market instruments.
Vodafone keeps such a large quantity of money available in this highly liquid and
low-risk form so that it can supply its various business units with the cash they
need for day-to-day operations or for regular investment projects. Also, it is useful
to have readily accessible money to be able to take advantage of investment
opportunities as they fleetingly appear (e.g. the purchase of a company).
Alternatively, the cash and near-cash is there because the company has recently
had a major inflow – perhaps it sold a division or has had bumper profits – and it
has not yet allocated the money to its final uses, such as paying billions in divid-
ends to shareholders, launching a new product, buying another company or simply
paying a tax bill. In the meantime that money might as well be earning Vodafone
some interest, so the money that is surplus to the immediate needs of Vodafone’s
various business units is gathered together and temporarily lent to other organisa-
tions in the money markets.
Vodafone also uses the money markets to borrow money. For example, at 2013
year-end it had more than £4 billion owing to purchasers of its commercial paper.
This was borrowed (and had to be repaid) in sterling, US dollars, euros and
Japanese yen. But this is not the half of it. Vodafone had arrangements with banks
to borrow via commercial paper as much as US$15 billion and £5 billion at any one
time. The banks committing to this deal will generally make arrangements for other
investors to supply this finance if Vodafone wishes to borrow this way to meet
short-term liquidity requirements at any point in the year.
Table 1.2 Money market holdings and cash taken from Vodafone’s annual
reports, 2008–2013
Cash and cash equivalents 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008
£m £m £m £m £m £m
Cash at bank and in hand 1,396 2,762 896 745 811 451
Money market funds 3,494 3,190 5,015 3,678 3,419 477
Repurchase agreements 2,550 600 – – 648 478
Commercial paper – – – – – 293
Short term securitised investments 183 586 – – – –
Other – – 341 – – –
Cash and cash equivalents as 7,623 7,138 6,252 4,423 4,878 1,699
presented in the balance sheet
(statement of financial position)
Corporations may also deposit money in money market funds to obtain good
rates of interest through professional management of the fund. They also value
being able to withdraw their money from the fund without the need to deal
with the selling of the underlying securities in the secondary markets – in most
cases investors in money market funds can gain access to their money within
hours: ‘same-day’ access. It is also possible to put in place a sweep facility so
that money is automatically transferred from a bank account (paying little
interest) if it exceeds a stated balance to a money market account (paying more
interest) and vice versa – this can be done at the end of each day.
With much of the rest of the financial sector, money markets went through
a crisis in 2008. A money market fund, Reserve Primary Fund, had invested a
substantial proportion of its funds in Lehman Brothers’ short-term debt. When
Lehman Brothers went bust the fund was unable to return to investors the
amount they had paid into it. This ‘breaking of the buck’ is a great sin in the
money market world – all money market funds are supposed to be incredibly
safe. What made it worse was the subsequent freezing-up of credit markets:
investors in funds could not withdraw their money at short notice as per the
agreement. The market became illiquid because the money market funds could
not find buyers for the securities they held and so could not raise cash at the
moment when a high proportion of their investors clamoured to withdraw cash.
However, there were howls of protest that the loss of interest on 3% of the fund
was too much to bear at a time when money market funds were struggling to
make even a 0.1% return in a year for investors because interest rates were so
low – see Article 1.1. In 2015 the politicians decided to abandon the 3% buffer
rule. Instead they insist that most CNAV funds switch to a ‘low-volatility
NAV’, which means they can only hold money market instruments which
mature within 90 days. The other 10% of CNAV are allowed to escape this rule
if they are aimed purely at ‘retail’ investors or if they invest 99.5% of their
assets in government debt. (In the article, ‘AUM’ is assets under management
– the amount they are investing for others.)
In July 2014 the regulator in the US, the Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC), gained the power to force some CNAV funds to scrap their fixed
$1-a-share price structure, permitting the fund to continue even if the under-
lying money market investments, e.g. commercial paper, add up to less than
$1 per share. This applies to funds invested in corporate debt and municipal
(local authority) debt. Those that buy only federal government debt or are sold
only to retail investors are exempt, so they stay as CNAV funds.
Article 1.1
‘If the regulation comes in as proposed we expect a 30% or higher decline of AUM
because of the likely switch to “variable net asset values” by most managers,’ said
Yaron Ernst, a managing director of global managed investments at Moody’s.
Money market funds, which act as reservoirs of easy-to-access cash, are a crucial
source of short-term financing for banks and companies worldwide. They are used
by corporates and others to diversify short-term cash holdings and are widely
perceived as low risk.
‘We are overwhelmingly invested in senior bank debt of less than three months’
maturity . . . the default risk on those assets is almost non-existent according to
long-term studies,’ said Martin Curran, a senior portfolio manager at Royal Bank
of Scotland. ‘With variable net asset values a corporate cash manager puts £1 into
a MMF to pay his bills, but it might not repay £1 the day after – he can’t afford to be
in that position, and particularly if he’s managing millions of them.’
In the US, the Securities and Exchange Commission has proposed limiting
investors’ ability to withdraw their cash from money market funds during times of
market stress, and is currently weighing whether this idea is better than a floating
NAV, or whether it can combine the two. The changes would only affect part of the
industry. The SEC plans to exempt funds that invest only in super-safe government
securities, and those targeted at retail investors, who are seen as less likely to start
a run on a fund.
The gloomy Moody’s prognosis comes as low interest rates, which squeeze funds’
already wafer-thin margins, have led to declines in assets under management for
many funds.
‘Fees have already been waived for more than a year by most MMF managers,
which reflects the stress on the industry’s business model,’ said Mr Ernst.
Euro-denominated money market funds shed €127bn of assets between June 2011–
13 according to Moody’s figures. HSBC estimates that the US industry has seen
assets decline from $4tn in 2009 to about $2.7tn.
Regulators say they want to bolster money market funds and avoid a run on
the market in the event of a financial crisis, which would lead to global finance
freezing up.
Source: Thompson, C. and Foley, S. (2013) Money funds at risk of big drop in assets,
Financial Times, 21 November.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
If the national currency is unstable or weak for whatever reason the govern-
ment may be able to issue bonds denominated in a foreign hard currency,
usually the US dollar. This makes them more attractive to investors because
they are viewed as less risky than domestic currency bonds because the
government is committed to paying interest and principal in, say, the US
dollar, regardless of inflation or exchange rate movement in that country.
Bonds issued by a government either in the country’s own currency or in
another currency are usually known as sovereign bonds.
Following the round of financial crises, most governments have had to issue
more bonds to permit deficit spending (i.e. not raising enough in taxes to
cover outgoings to boost the economy). Statistics from The Economist from
a range of countries show the enormous amount of debt some countries
1
Foreign currency reserves or foreign exchange reserves (FOREX reserves or FX reserves)
are held by the national central bank or other monetary authority. They usually consist of a
range of hard foreign currency and bonds issued by other governments (popular usage of the
term usually also includes gold reserves, shares and the ability to draw money from the IMF).
These are saved to reduce the risk of not being able to pay off international debt obligations, thus
increasing the confidence of overseas creditors that the country will not default. They also allow
the purchase of the domestic currency, thus influencing monetary policy and exchange rates.
owe – see Figure 2.2. For every person in Italy, the government owes more
than $39,000. It is even worse in Japan, where the government owes over
$98,000 per person. In both cases the debt is mostly bought domestically
rather than lent by foreigners, and so the risk of a foreign lenders’ strike or
a major outflow of interest payments is less worrisome. Nevertheless, that is
an awful lot of borrowing.
Bonds issued by reputable governments are the most secure (least risky) in the
world because they are very aware of the need to maintain a good reputation
for paying their debts on time. Furthermore, for countries able to issue in their
own currencies, should there be a cash flow difficulty, they are able to print
more money or to raise taxes, to ensure they have the means to pay the bonds’
coupons or the bonds’ redemption value. But if money creation is taken
too far, raised inflation may be the result, putting off potential lenders in that
currency.
We first look at the UK government bond market to get a feel for the
workings of these markets and then, in Chapter 3, consider the US, French,
German, Japanese, Chinese and emerging (underdeveloped) government
bond markets.
Figure 2.2 Total public debt for a selection of countries: total amount outstanding
in $USbn
UK gilts
In most years, in common with other countries in the world, the British
government does not raise enough in taxes to cover its expenditure –
see Figure 2.3, which shows the amount the UK public sector (central and
local government) had to borrow between 2000 and 2014 to make up this
deficit and to maintain stability and restore confidence. Note the significant
rise following the 2008 financial crisis as the government borrowed to cover
falling tax receipts, boost aggregate demand and bail out the banks.
Figure 2.3 UK public sector (central and local government) net borrowing 2000–2014
(the difference between expenditure and revenue)
Source: ONS Public Sector Finances, March 2014 www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_360531.pdf
UK government bonds are called gilts because in the old days they were very
attractive certificates with gold-leaf edges (gilt-edged securities). Lending to
the UK government by buying gilts is one of the safest forms of lending in the
world; the risk of the UK government failing to pay is inconceivably small –
it has never done so, although a few doubts did creep in following the high
government spending during 2010–2011 when the volume of gilts outstand-
ing grew enormously – see Figure 2.4. There are so many gilts held by investors
and financial institutions that they equal more than 75% of the amount of
output that UK citizens produce in one year (GDP).
Figure 2.4 The amount of UK government gilts in issue up to 2014 and gross
issuance (includes gilts sold to replace maturing gilts being redeemed)
Source: Debt Management Office www.DMO.gov.uk
Issuing gilts
The UK government issues most gilts through auction via the Debt
Management Office (DMO) and each issue receives a unique identification
number, an ISIN (International Securities Identification Number). Gilts are
issued with a par (face) value of £100. This is the amount guaranteed to be paid
on maturity to the holder, who may or may not be the original purchaser.
Their maturity can be 5, 10, 30, 40, 50 and recently 55 years, and during the
time to maturity they pay a twice-yearly coupon, the amount of which reflects
the current and expected future rates of interest at the time of issue.
Most are conventional bonds, but since 1981 gilts have been issued which
offset the effect of inflation; the coupons and principal paid on these are linked
to the Retail Prices Index (RPI) over the life of the bond and are known as
index-linked gilts. Table 2.1 gives examples of conventional and index-linked
gilts.
In March 2014 there were 72 gilts in issue with a total outstanding value
(including inflation uplift for index-linked gilts) of about £1.4 trillion and of
varying maturities – see Figure 2.5. The maturity of a gilt is measured by the
remaining time left to redemption.
Table 2.1 Examples of two gilts, the 4¼% Treasury Gilt 2039 and the 2½%
Index-linked Treasury Stock 2024
£100 × 4¼% ÷ 2. Thus Those issued in The gilt will mature in 2039 The ISIN is a
£2.125 will be paid on recent years are at which time the final unique number
set dates at 6 monthly called Treasury coupon and the par value identifying
intervals to the gilt holder Stocks or of £100 will be paid to each gilt
Treasury Gilts the holder
£100 × 2½% ÷ 2. Those issued in The gilt will mature in 2024 The ISIN is a
Thus £1.25 plus an recent years are at which time the final unique number
increase to take inflation called Treasury coupon and the par value identifying
into account will be paid Stocks or of £100 plus an increase each gilt
on set dates at 6 monthly Treasury Gilts to take inflation into
intervals to the gilt holder account will be paid to
the holder
Source: www.DMO.gov.uk
● index-linked various
change in the RPI. The RPI is published monthly by the Office for National
Statistics and measures the change in price of a representative basket of
retail goods and services.
● Eight undated older gilts issued between 1853 and 1946 with no redemption
date. They pay their coupons in perpetuity, but can be redeemed at the dis-
cretion of the government – see Article 2.1. Most pay semi-annual coupons
but some pay interest each quarter. Their nominal value is £2.6 billion.
● More than 170 STRIPS of gilts (discussed later in this chapter).
Article 2.1
Source: Moore, E. (2014) UK to repay tranche of perpetual war loans, Financial Times, 31 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
When gilts are sold by the government with a nominal value of £100, only the
20 Gilt-edged Market Makers (GEMMs)2 can submit competitive bids at the
auction. They may do this for themselves or for their clients. For conventional
gilts, all those who bid above the minimum needed to sell the bonds pay the
price they bid (a multiple price auction). For index-linked gilts the pricing
at the conclusion of the auction is different: all bidders pay the same lowest
accepted price rather than each paying the price at which they bid (a uniform
price auction).3 In return for exclusive access to auctions GEMMs must commit
2
GEMMs are a group of commercial banks/financial institutions/brokers, the number of
which has varied between 20 and 30, and at the time of writing is 20.
3
The index-linked market has fewer similar gilts already trading in the secondary market
to allow investors to gauge where to pitch their bid, therefore they face the danger of over-
pricing if they have to pay the price they offer. This ‘winner’s curse’ problem is off-putting
to investors and so to attract them, the DMO prices all index-linked bonds at a level that
will sell the bonds – even if a particular investor bids a very high price it will pay the same
as the other successful bidders. The conventional gilt market is much more liquid, with
many more comparators for bidders to gauge where to pitch their bids, and so the winner’s
curse disincentive does not have much of an impact, thus the DMO can get away with
charging higher prices to some buyers.
As well as GEMMs submitting competitive bids at the auction, they can take
up the post-auction option facility (PAOF), which enables successful bidders
to acquire up to an extra 10% of their allocation at the average accepted (strike)
price at conventional auctions and at the single clearing (strike) price at index-
linked auctions.
Following an auction GEMMs can trade in the secondary market directly with
investors, making available advertised prices between 8am and 5pm every
business day in all those gilts in which they are recognised as market maker.
They quote two prices: the bid price is the price at which they will buy, the
offer price is their selling price. The difference between the bid price and
the offer price is known as the dealer’s spread, i.e. their potential profit. They
are also able to trade gilts anonymously with each other through interdealer
brokers (IDBs), who act as intermediaries for GEMMs. IDBs are required to
post deals done on their screens for all other GEMMs to see. Below is the list of
GEMMs and interdealer brokers at the time of writing.
Table 2.2 shows details for the gilts issued over a one-month period. Note a
strange phenomenon in 2014: index-linked issues could be sold at a yield of
less than zero before taking into account the inflation uplift, e.g. while the ‘⅛%
Index-linked Treasury Gilt 2019’ has a nominal coupon yield of positive one-
eighth of 1% per year, it sold at a price of £105.83. The capital loss of £5.83 over
the five years (because it will be redeemed at £100 (plus inflation)) means that
the yield will be negative 0.918% per annum before inflation uplift. This is an
indication that investors were so desperate to invest in ‘safe-haven’ assets with
both high default protection and some inflation protection that they accepted
returns guaranteeing a real-terms reduction of capital value. Bid to cover ratio
means the amount investors offered to buy relative to the amount offered for sale.
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
Investors wishing to bid for more than £500,000 nominal in a competitive bid
must submit their bids through a GEMM stating the price they wish to pay. If
4
A piece of bureaucracy designed to exclude money launderers and other financial criminals.
Application forms are available from the DMO. The approval process takes a few days.
the bid is below the price required to sell the gilts available they will receive no
bonds, or only a proportion of those bid for.
Mini-tenders also take place between the major auctions. They are smaller
issues which supplement the main auction sales, and are designed to tap into
emerging pockets of demand for particular gilts.
Supplementary issues
If a gilt already in issue is ‘supplemented’ (more issued) it keeps the same
ISIN number – see Table 2.3, where we can see the details of a 3¾% Treasury
Gilt with a redemption date of 2021, issued originally on 18 March 2011 with
an initial issuance of £2.75 billion and paying a coupon of £3.75 annually
in two equal semi-annual payments made on fixed dates six months apart;
with gilt GB00B4RMG977 these payments are on 7 March and 7 September
each year.
Since it was first sold, the government raised more money with this gilt, ending
up with a total issuance of nearly £28 billion. The purchase (market) price of a
gilt varies, depending on the coupon offered, the general level of interest rates
in the markets, dealers’ perception of future interest rates, and present and
expected inflation rates. For gilt GB00B4RMG977 the initial price was £100.80
and the subsequent prices varied between £98.91 and £114.49. At maturity it
will be worth £100 and as a gilt approaches maturity its price will become ever
nearer to its par value.
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
From the clean price (the price of the gilt excluding any accrued interest since
the last coupon was paid – see later in the chapter) and yield at issue we can
gain an impression of how the prevailing rate of interest for securities with a
similar risk and maturity changed over the period March 2011 to January 2012,
falling 157 basis points. Indeed, interest rates usually change daily, even if usually
by very small amounts.
* ‘Monetary Financial Institutions’ replaced the ‘Banks’ and ‘Building Societies’ categories in January 2011
and excludes Bank of England holdings.
Source: DMO, Quarterly Review January–March 2014 www.dmo.gov.uk/documentview.aspx?docname=
publications/quarterly/jan-mar14.pdf&page=Quarterly_Review
Article 2.2 discusses the operations of the DMO, with particular reference to
the necessity to sell gilts to overseas investors.
Article 2.2
‘I think that since the crisis, I have gone out to Asia at least once a year,’ says
Robert Stheeman. ‘That didn’t happen before – [I] barely travelled. But the investor
base is more diverse now.’
The UK’s unprecedented need to borrow hundreds of billions of pounds from the
markets since the financial crisis has pushed Mr Stheeman, a 54-year-old former
investment banker, into the limelight over the past few years. As chief executive of
the UK’s Debt Management Office he is charged with ensuring the country is able
to borrow as much as it needs at the lowest rate possible.
The UK’s centuries-old system of raising funds by selling bonds – known as gilts
after the gilded edges of the old paper certificates – has created one of the most
liquid markets in the world.
International investors are now the largest holders of UK debt, with £413bn – just
under a third of the total – as of December. Keeping those investors engaged is not
simply a matter of air miles, and the job is made more challenging by the fact that
the UK does not know exactly who its overseas investors are.
Many of the central banks and sovereign wealth funds that now buy large volumes of
gilts do so through nominee accounts, which do not reveal the underlying investor.
‘We have an idea who they are,’ he says. ‘Although they don’t like to show their hand.’
Composed and fond of answering a question with the aid of a chart, Mr Stheeman
personifies the stability he wants investors to associate with the market. But he
acknowledges substantial changes in the past decade.
In 2004–5, the country raised £50bn through gilts sales. Six years later, at the peak
of the crisis in 2009, the UK had to convince the markets to absorb gilts worth
£228bn. This financial year, it plans to raise £127bn.
The rise of overseas investors has also necessitated a change of strategy. Pension
funds and insurance companies face liabilities in the future and want long-term
investments. Overseas buyers prefer short-term investments. The result is that the
number of short-dated bonds issued by the UK has grown rapidly since 2008.
‘One concept I try to convey to [the government] is that we can’t force people to buy
our debt,’ says Mr Stheeman. ‘What we can do is to put in place a framework that
makes it attractive to invest in.’
There have been occasions since the crisis began when the allure of gilts seemed
under threat. Following the introduction of the Bank of England’s gilt purchasing
programme – known as Quantitative Easing – a bond auction drew fewer bids than
expected for the first time in years. A few years later, credit rating agencies
stripped the UK of its triple A grade, citing sluggish economic growth.
Despite these stumbling blocks, demand has remained strong as investors have
sought the relative haven of UK government debt.
➨
What he is certain about is that the UK’s need to raise very large amounts of money
will remain for years to come.
‘The debt stock has increased so dramatically that it cannot go back to pre-crisis
levels for a long time,’ he says. ‘Not for a generation.’
Gilts remain the main way in which the UK government finances the shortfall
between what it spends and what it receives in tax revenues, and borrowing costs
have been falling steadily since the 1980s when they exceeded 16%. Yields are
expected to rise when the BoE finally raises interest rates above 0.5%.
Source: Moore, E. (2014) Hard times force UK seller of gilts on a globe-trotting journey,
Financial Times, 21 May.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Accounting for the capital loss over the next five years: the investor pays
£120 but will receive only £100 at maturity, a loss of £4 per year over the
five years, or as a percentage of what the investor pays £4/£120 × 100 = 3.33%
per year. The yield to maturity, YTM (redemption yield), is approximately
● If a dated gilt is trading below £100 the purchaser will receive a capital
gain between purchase and redemption and so the YTM is greater than the
current yield.
● If a dated gilt is selling at more than £100 a capital loss will be made if held
to maturity and so the YTM is below the current yield.
Of course, these capital gains and losses are based on the assumption that the
investor buys the gilt and then holds it to maturity. In reality many investors
sell their bonds a few days or months after purchase, in which case they may
make capital gains or losses dependent not on what the government pays on
maturity but on the market price another investor is prepared to offer. This, in
turn, depends on general economic conditions, in particular projected general
inflation over the life of the gilt: investors will not buy a gilt offering a 5%
redemption yield over five years if future inflation is expected to be signific-
antly higher than this.
As we have seen, bond prices and yields move in opposite directions. If our
five-year gilt purchased for £120 offering a coupon of 10% with an approx-
imate redemption yield of 5% is trading in an environment where general
interest rates for that risk level rise to 6% because of an increase in inflation
expectations, investors will no longer be interested in buying this gilt for £120,
because at this price it yields only 5%. Demand will fall, resulting in a price
reduction until the bond yields 6% – the bond’s market value will then be
£116.85 (see calculation method in Chapter 13). A rise in yield goes hand in
hand with a fall in price.
Quotes
Tables 2.5, 2.6 and 2.7, from the Financial Times, show the ‘mid-prices’ half
way between the bid and the offer prices of the government-approved dealers,
GEMMs.
Table 2.5 Gilts – UK cash market on 9 June 2014 – conventional gilts, maturity terms
under 15 years
www.ft.com/gilts
Jun 9 Price £ Day’s W’ks Int Red Day’s W’ks Mth’s Year 52 Week Amnt Last Interest
M02_ARNO1799_01_SE_C02.indd 48
chng chng yield yield chng chng chng chng £m xd date due
High Low
Tr 4.75pc’30 ............ 119.83 –0.45 –0.32 3.95 3.19 +0.03 +0.07 +0.02 +0.34 126.11 115.50 28,716 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 4.25pc’32 ............ 113.35 –0.45 –0.33 3.73 3.26 +0.03 +0.07 +0.02 +0.30 118.75 109.05 34,598 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
PART 2 BOND MARKETS
Tr 4.5pc’34 .............. 117.01 –0.48 –0.37 3.83 3.34 +0.03 +0.07 +0.02 +0.26 122.28 112.57 25,501 26/02 7 Mar/Sep
Tr 4.25pc’36 ............ 113.37 –0.49 –0.38 3.73 3.38 +0.03 +0.06 +0.03 +0.24 118.17 108.92 25,952 26/02 7 Mar/Sep
Tr 4.75pc’38 ............ 122.49 –0.54 –0.43 3.86 3.39 +0.03 +0.06 +0.03 +0.20 127.24 117.68 24,601 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 4.25pc’39 ............ 113.94 –0.51 –0.41 3.71 3.42 +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.18 117.87 109.28 19,280 26/02 7 Mar/Sep
Tr 4.5pc’42 .............. 119.28 –0.56 –0.45 3.76 3.43 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.14 123.05 114.24 26,001 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 3.25pc’44 ............ 95.86 –0.49 –0.39 3.37 3.48 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.10 98.22 90.69 23,778 13/01 22 Jan/Jul
Tr 4.25pc’46 ............ 115.63 –0.59 –0.49 3.66 3.45 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.09 118.71 109.84 20,873 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 4.25pc’49 ............ 116.75 –0.62 –0.54 3.62 3.43 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.05 120.05 110.52 19,301 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 3.75pc’52 ............ 106.49 –0.59 –0.51 3.50 3.44 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.03 109.48 100.30 19,761 13/01 22 Jan/Jul
Tr 4.25pc’55 ............ 118.68 –0.66 –0.56 3.56 3.41 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.02 122.22 111.43 23,416 28/05 7 Jun/Dec
Tr 4pc’60 ................. 113.86 –0.67 –0.57 3.49 3.40 +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.01 117.49 106.48 18,764 13/01 22 Jan/Jul
Undated
Cons 4pc ................* 97.09 –0.62 –0.53 4.09 4.12‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.04 +0.01 99.91 90.45 257 22/01 1 Feb/Aug
War Ln 3.5pc ........... 83.57 –0.52 –0.45 4.16 4.19‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.10 85.52 77.76 1,938 21/05 1 Jun/Dec
Cn 3.5pc’61 Aft .......* 81.43 –0.49 –0.42 – 4.30‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.10 83.84 77.71 17 23/03 1 Apr/Oct
Tr 3pc’66 Aft ...........* 68.36 –0.41 –0.35 4.36 4.39‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.10 70.42 64.91 40 26/03 5 Apr/Oct
Cons 2.5pc .............* 58.57 –0.36 –0.31 4.24 4.27‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.10 60.43 55.54 177 26/03 5 Ja/Ap/Jul/Oc
Tr 2.5pc ..................* 59.69 –0.37 –0.32 4.16 4.19‡ +0.03 +0.05 +0.03 +0.10 61.59 56.64 287 23/03 1 Apr/Oct
7/7/15 8:47 AM
2 GOVERNMENT BONDS 49
of the gilt to maturity will receive the yield that was obtainable at the time
of purchase.
Redemption yields for gilts are quoted daily online by the Debt Management
Office at www.dmo.gov.uk. Other sources of information on prices, and on
the gilts market generally, are websites, e.g. www.bloomberg.com, www.
fixedincomeinvestor.co.uk, www.hl.co.uk, www.londonstockexchange.com,
www.selftrade.co.uk, www.iii.co.uk and www.fitchratings.com.
Institutional investors in bonds deal directly with the GEMMs (the primary
dealers). Non-institutional investors can buy or sell gilts through brokers, who
contact the GEMMs, dealing on the telephone or online. They need to state the
nominal value of the gilts they want to deal and whether they want to trade at
best (the best price currently in the market) or with a limit on the price they
are prepared to pay (or sell for). High street banks, some building societies,
independent financial advisers and even some solicitors and accountants will
buy or sell gilts for clients.
The settlement day, the date on which transfer of gilt and payment occur, is
usually the next business day after the trade is conducted (T+1), although
other settlement dates may be negotiated between the buyer/seller and the
GEMM. The CREST system run by Euroclear organises the transfer between
investors and maintains records of ownership transferred in the secondary
market, usually an electronic record rather than paper certificates. (Euroclear
also does this for another 30 bond markets internationally.)
Retail investors can also buy and sell gilts in the primary and secondary markets
via the DMO’s Gilt Purchase and Sales Service using Computershare (www-uk.
computershare.com). It is first necessary to fill in forms to become an Approved
Group of Investors member. The investor is not able to specify the price or a
maximum/minimum price at which the purchase/sale of gilts is to be made.
Since 2010 retail investors have been able to buy and sell gilts and other
bonds through the London Stock Exchange’s electronic Order book for Retail
Bonds (ORB) where lots can be very small (minimum £1) and the costs of
trading are relatively low. The London Stock Exchange authorises dedicated
market makers to state bid/offer prices (some are GEMMs). Buyers and sellers
are able to set limits on the prices they are willing to pay/accept or simply
ask a broker to trade at the current market price. Small investors can now
see ORB gilt prices on free financial websites (e.g. www.advfn.com, www.
londonstockexchange.com).
Other ways for small investors to gain exposure to the gilt (and/or corporate
bond) market is to buy units in a unit trust or shares in an investment trust that
specialises in the type of bonds they are interested in. They gain professional
management and diversification but will pay fees (sometimes more than 1%
per year, which is a lot as a proportion of the annual interest on gilts of, say, 3%
or 4%). Exchange traded funds are another alternative. Collective bond funds
such as these are discussed in The Financial Times Guide to Investing (Glen
Arnold, 2014, Pearson).
Taxation on gilts
The investor’s tax bracket influences the return they receive. Currently there
are four tax brackets applying to a person’s marginal taxable income and
capital gains. The interest on gilts is taxed but the capital gains are not, thus
higher-rate tax payers are better off if they select gilts with a greater proportion
of the total return coming from capital gains rather than coupons. The
Financial Times provides a helpful table (Table 2.8) showing the best value
gilts in terms of after-tax returns in the four tax brackets. Note that the ‘GRY’
(gross redemption yield) shown here is actually a yield calculated after the
deduction of tax. So, for example, looking at other databases on 13 June 2014,
the gross redemption yield (before tax deduction) for the Treasury 1.75% 2022
is 2.62%, whereas in the so-called ‘GRY’ shown in Table 2.8 it is 1.68% for the
40% tax bracket investor and 1.59% for the 45% tax bracket investor. Again
note the way in which the prices of index-linked bonds were pushed so high
in 2014 that they all provide a negative return after tax and assuming inflation
of 3%.
Non Taxpayers
20% Taxpayers
40% Taxpayers
45% Taxpayers
Best performing bonds are selected on highest yield for each marginal tax rate based on closing mid price.
Gilts exclude double-dated and rump issues. Prices quoted as £ per £100 nominal. For Inflation-linked gilts:
year-on-year inflation.
GRY = Gross Redemption Yield. Data compiled on: May 30th 2014
Source: Barclays plc
prices (flat prices) – that is, quoted without taking account of any accrued
interest. However, the buyer will pay the clean price plus the accrued interest
value (called the dirty price or full price or invoice price or full accrual
price) and will receive all of the next coupon. So, if you buy a gilt four months
before the next coupon is due, you would pay the clean price, say £101, plus
60 days’ accrued interest, i.e. two months of accrued coupon since the last
was paid. The accrued interest for a bond that pays coupons every six months
is calculated by taking the annual coupon and dividing it by two to obtain
the half-yearly coupon. This number is then multiplied by the fraction of the
half-year that has already passed. So, if the bond pays an annual coupon of 7%
and is currently quoted at a clean price of £101, the dirty price is:5
Dirty price
= clean price
Index-linked gilts
There is a danger with conventional gilts – inflation risk. Say, for example, that
you, along with the rest of the gilt-buying community, think that inflation over
the next ten years will average 2.5%. As a result you buy ten-year gilts that have
a redemption yield of 4.8%, giving a comfortable real income over and above
the expected cost-of-living increases. However, two years later inflation starts
to take off (oil prices quadruple, or the government goes on a spending spree).
Now investors reckon that inflation will average 6% over the following eight
years. As a result your gilt yield will fail to maintain your capital in real terms.
5
Note that the ‘actual number of days since last coupon payment’ is to the settlement day,
when the buyer actually takes possession of the bond (the day of the deal is usually one day
before settlement day).
Suppose inflation is 4% over the first year of the bond’s life. The payout on
maturity would rise to £104. However, this inflation-linked uplift happens
every year (more specifically, the uplift for inflation occurs every six months).
So, if over the ten years the inflation measure has risen by 60%, the payout on
the bond is £160. This means that you can buy just as many goods and services
at the end with the capital sum as at the beginning of the bond’s life (if you
paid £100). Furthermore, the coupon rate also rises through the years if infla-
tion is positive. So after the inflation experience in the first year, the coupons
for the first six months of the second year go up by 4%, (£0.25 ÷ 2) × (1 + 0.04)
to £0.13. The situation is slightly more complicated than this in that the infla-
tion figures used are those for three months preceding the relevant coupon
dates, but this example illustrates the principle.6
Any future rises in inflation lead to further growth in the coupon, so that the
last coupon will be 60% larger than the initial coupon rate if inflation over
the ten years accumulates to 60%, paying £0.40 per £100 nominal.
6
For bonds issued prior to July 2005 the lag is eight months.
current price and coupon?7 ‘Value stock’ means the volume in issue expressed
in the local currency, e.g. the UK 2.5% 2016 has £7.9 billion in issue.
Inflation-linked bond issues are taking off across Europe – see Article 2.3.
Article 2.3
7
This is far from an agreed scientific way of estimating the market’s expectations of future
inflation. Many other factors play a role in pushing yields on gilts up or down – for example,
pension funds may increase their buying of linkers (index-linked bonds) to better match
their liabilities, thereby encouraging higher prices and lowering yields.
On Wednesday, France issued its largest inflation-linked bond since the financial
crisis began, selling €3.5bn of 15-year debt. France is the exception within
inflation-linked bond issuers because it sells bonds tied to the Europe-wide measure
of goods and services as well as one connected to domestic inflation.
Clearly inflation in Europe is extremely low but there is a lot of discussion in
the markets about whether it will stay that way and the strength of appetite for
inflation-linked bonds shows that not all investors think it will.
The latest inflation-tied debt issuance, which was sold via BNP Paribas, Crédit
Agricole, HSBC, Nomura and Société Générale, was notable for the level of interest
it drew from UK and domestic investors, said one banker. The bond was priced to
yield 20 basis points more than the country’s existing inflation-linked note which
matures in July 2027.
Inflation-linked bonds have performed poorly for investors in recent years, as
global inflation stayed low. However, they are seen as a hedge against the possibility
of inflation increases.
‘Demand is high for inflation protection at these levels,’ said Jonathan Gibbs, a
fund manager at Standard Life Investments. ‘Investors with liabilities linked to
inflation, such as pension funds, will be using the opportunity to buy into these
bonds.’
In May, Spain issued its first inflation-linked bond, which attracted orders of more
than €20bn. Last week Germany added €1bn to its existing inflation-linked bond
due to mature in 2023.
Source: Moore, E. (2014) Europe on track to sell record amounts of inflation-linked debt,
Financial Times, 12 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
STRIPS
Some conventional gilts, following issuance by the government and trading
on the secondary market, can be stripped. A gilt STRIPS (the letters stand for
Separate Trading of Registered Interest and Principal Securities) occurs
when the gilt is separated from its coupons and the gilt and its coupons all
become zero coupon bonds. Thus a five-year gilt could become eleven separate
zero coupon bonds, each with its own ISIN, one for each six-monthly coupon
plus the original bond. Twenty-nine gilts have been stripped, resulting in
164 separately traded instruments, and the STRIPS have a value of around
£1.8 billion. They are traded at a discount to their redemption value and once
stripped can be reconstituted. Only GEMMs can strip gilts.
The motivation for stripping is that investing institutions might offer a higher
price because they can obtain the exact maturity profile and interest rate they
are looking for. The problem with conventional coupon-paying bonds is that
long-term buy-and-hold investors have to reinvest the money paid as a coupon,
say half way to maturity. What reinvestment interest rate might you get three
or four years down the line? It might be more or less than the yield to maturity
that you originally bought into, which distorts the overall return received.
With STRIPS the rate of return is fixed for the full term because there is only
one payout. Table 2.10 shows some of the STRIPS available – details are
updated daily on the DMO website. Of course, the clean and the dirty market
prices are the same because there are no payments made each six months,
therefore no coupon interest is accruing day by day.
Article 2.4
Source: Moore, E. and Hale, T. (2014) UK sukuk bond sale attracts £2bn in orders,
Financial Times, 25 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Fixed-interest indices
The FTSE (owned by the London Stock Exchange) creates indices for a variety
of securities. The ‘FTSE Actuaries UK Gilts Index Series’ provides an indication
of returns on bonds of various classes over time. Table 2.11 shows the perfor-
mance over one month and one year of collections of bonds, e.g. a representa-
tive group of twelve bonds with less than five years to maturity. The column
labelled ‘Total return’ includes both interest payments that the bond accrues
Real yield Jun 16 Dur yrs Jun 13 Yr ago Jun 16 Dur yrs Jun 13 Yr ago
FTSE is making a number of enhancements to the FTSE Actuaries UK Gilts Index Series which are effective from 28 April 2014.
Please see the FTSE website for more details: www.markets.ft.com
Source: FTSE Group
and the payments that have actually been made which are reinvested in the
index as well as capital gain or loss. The base value for the total return index is
a figure that was set years ago, equal to the total market value of the group of
gilts at the base (starting) date divided by the starting index value at that date
(often 100) but which is subsequently adjusted to allow for changes in the
constituents of the group and the nominal amounts of the constituent gilts.
The table also shows the average yield to maturity currently available to a
buyer of this group of gilts. The price indices, in the second column, labelled
‘Jun 16’ (the day of the download), is an arithmetically weighted index based
on the dirty price and weighted by the nominal amount outstanding (it does
not allow for that part of the return from coupons).
The ‘real yield’ (after deduction of inflation) for the index-linked securities
(final section) is shown for bonds with a variety of maturities and is based on
different assumptions with regard to future inflation.8 ‘Dur yrs’ is the length of
the duration in years, a measure related to price volatility of the collection
of bonds (see Chapter 13).
8
A greater range of real yields based on assumptions of future annual inflation rates of 0%,
3%, 5% and 10% can be seen at www.ftse.com.
The Financial Times website also has a table displaying the spreads on
ten-year benchmark bonds. That is, the number of percentage points of gross
redemption yield above the ten-year German government bond (Bund) and
above the ten-year US government bond (Treasury bond or T-bond) offered
on a ten-year government bond from another country. Thus, Table 3.2 shows
an investor in New Zealand government bonds (denominated in NZ$) will
receive 3.06% per year more than an investor in German bonds (in euros)
and 1.83% more than an investor in US bonds (in US$). The additional yield
may compensate for greater anticipated inflation, greater perceived risk (such
as exchange rate change risk) or other factors, e.g. the relative tendency for
central banks to push down ten-year bond yields through their quantitative
easing programmes (buying bonds, pushing up their prices and lowering their
yields – see Chapter 16).
Table 3.2 Government bonds – spreads over ten-year bonds and US Treasuries
Article 3.1
China remained the biggest investor of US government bonds but pared back its
holdings by $21bn to $1.28tn between May and June. Japan, the second-biggest
investor, cut its holdings by $20bn to $1.08tn.
Total outflows of $66.9bn surpassed the $59bn seen in November 2008, just after the
collapse of Lehman Brothers which sparked the global financial crisis.
Source: Alloway, T. and Rodrigues, V. (2013) Foreign investors dump Treasuries at record
pace, Financial Times, 15 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
The US Public Debt stood at nearly $17.5 trillion in February 2014. But about
$5 trillion of that was accounted for by one area of government owing another
area of government money, thus the net amount (owing external investors)
was around $12.5 trillion. Nearly $12 trillion of Treasury-issued marketable
securities are held by outside investors, including notes, bills, bonds and
TIPS (explained on page 67) – see Figure 3.2. Most of the rest is owned by
government-managed trust funds and savings bonds.
Treasury bills (T-bills) range in maturity from 1 day to 52 weeks, with 4-week
(28 days), 13-week (91 days) and 26-week (182 days) bills being the most
common. They are sold at a discount to par value by auction every week, except
for the 52-week bills which are auctioned every 4 weeks. They are zero coupon
securities, i.e. they do not pay a dividend; any gain for an investor results from
the difference between the purchase price and the selling price.
Treasury notes have a coupon payable every six months. They have a maturity
of two, three, five, seven or ten years and are sold at roughly monthly intervals.
Notes are sold in increments of $100. The minimum purchase is $100.
Treasury bonds are auctioned every few months, have maturities greater than
10 years (usually 30 years) and pay interest twice per year. Bonds are sold in
increments of $100. The minimum purchase is $100. Notes and bonds are
referred to collectively as Treasury coupon securities.
thus raising the coupon by the CPI. At maturity the investor will receive the
final principal amount including adjustment for ten years of inflation. To
protect against deflation the holder receives at maturity the adjusted principal
or the original principal, whichever is greater.
Article 3.2
The issue at stake partly revolves around the manner in which the Treasury sells
government debt. In the past this was done in a straightforward way: bonds carried
fixed interest rates, and most of these were either short-term bills or 10-year ones.
Until recently US officials saw little reason to change this approach as demand was
sky high.
But now a business-as-usual course is starting to look dangerously complacent.
Never mind the fact that the US debt pile has doubled to $17tn in the past decade;
and ignore recent fiscal fights and the threat of a new debt-ceiling showdown.
The other challenge haunting the Treasury is the maturity profile of the debt.
In the past three decades this maturity has averaged 58 months, meaning it must be
renewed almost every five years. During the financial crisis it declined to four years
– half the average maturity of most European countries. That produced one oft-
ignored benefit: because the Fed has kept rates ultra-low, total interest costs have
not risen as fast as total debt. Just like a homeowner on a floating mortgage, low
rates have meant low monthly interest payments for the Treasury. Indeed, interest
payments now represent 6% of federal outlays; two decades ago it was 15%.
But this benefit comes with a sting that mortgage borrowers know well: if rates
increase, interest payments could balloon. And if investors panic about inflation,
higher rates or fiscal sustainability, that squeeze could be more intense.
The good news is that the Treasury is aware of this danger, and trying to prepare. In
recent months it has had success in raising the average maturity profile by selling
more long-term bonds. This stands at 66.7 months, and officials say that by 2020 it
could reach 80.
Treasury officials are also trying to help the market absorb future rate rises by
offering a more flexible range of instruments. This week’s experiment with floaters
is one move. However, the Treasury is also selling inflation-protected bonds and
officials are getting more proactive about asking large investors – including Asian
buyers – what moves will keep them purchasing Treasuries. In March 2014 there
were 32 bills being traded, 219 Notes, 64 Bonds, 38 TIPS and 321 STRIPS. Treasuries
interest payments are exempt from local and state taxes, but not from federal
income taxes.
Source: Tett, G. (2014) Why Uncle Sam needs some novel sweeteners for its bonds,
Financial Times, 31 January.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
US STRIPS
Treasury STRIPS are similar to UK STRIPS, sold at a discount with maturities
of 9 months to 30 years. US government notes and bonds may be converted
to STRIPS by financial institutions and government securities brokers and
dealers, who create STRIPS after purchasing the non-stripped notes or bonds.
They then ask the Federal Reserve (US central bank) to record the separation
of coupons and face value with separate number identifiers on its computer
system. The individual coupons and principal can then be traded as zero
coupon securities by dealers. The minimum face amount needed to strip a
fixed-principal note or bond or a TIP is $100 and any par amount to be stripped
above $100 must be in a multiple of $100. STRIPS may be reconstituted – this
might be worthwhile if the package of zero coupon STRIPS is selling in the
market at less than the complete Treasury security.
Secondary market
US government bills, notes and bonds are traded in an active and liquid
secondary market (in an over-the-counter market rather than on a formal
exchange), with dealers posting bid (buying) and ask (selling) prices, and
trades conducted over the telephone or by electronic communication. The
central actors in the secondary market are the primary dealers (largest banks
and brokerages in New York, Tokyo and London), which often act as market
makers. Notes and bonds usually trade in $1,000 denominations. Settlement
normally takes place one business day after a trade. Primary dealers also trade
with each other directly or through interdealer brokers who match up buyers
and sellers, usually with the advantage of anonymity for the participants.
Retail investors buy or sell through banks and brokerage firms.
Prices for notes and bonds are quoted as a combination of whole dollars and
as a fraction of a dollar. This may be in decimal terms, i.e. a fraction of 100, but
more often the fraction used is 1/32nd of a dollar. Thus a US Treasury bond price
has two parts: (1) the handle, that is, the main number (the first), and (2) the
32nds, that is, the number expressed as a fraction of 32. This can be confusing
because a decimal point might be used to separate the handle from the 32nds,
despite the fact that the number that follows is not a fraction of 100 but of 32.
Table 3.3 shows the prices of US Treasury notes and bonds of varying
maturities on 27 March 2014. The price for a $1,000 five-year note consists
of (a) 99 and (b) 19¾ of 32. (Thankfully our numbers are separated by a dash
rather than a decimal point.) To convert into a percentage to determine the
dollar amount for the bond we first divide 19¾ by 32. This equals 0.6171875.
We then add that amount to 99 (the handle), which equals 99.6171875. So,
99–19¾ equals 99.6171875% of the par value. If the par is $1,000, then the
price is $996.171875.
This price, which is slightly lower than the face value, demonstrates that the
current interest rates (market yields) are higher than the coupon yield of 1.625%,
$1.625 per $100. Often notes and bond prices are quoted just with a yield
figure, as it is then possible to work out what the market price would be.
(These calculations are explained in Chapter 13.) Some very active issues may
be quoted in 64ths of a point – in this case a + sign is added to the 32nds.
Some traders/writers use even more convoluted and confusing conventions
and fractions. It is definitely a weird system, time honoured, but weird.
French bonds
The French Treasury, Agence France Trésor (AFT), is responsible for borrow-
ing to finance the public debt – for 2013 this figure was €169 billion. With
this added to the total, France owed investors a sum equal to more than 90%
of annual output. Most of this was raised by selling medium- and long-term
securities. AFT sells by auction on fixed dates government bonds with a face
value of €1 and a minimum bid of €1 million. Any institution affiliated to
Euroclear France1 and holding an account with the Banque de France (the
central bank) is eligible to bid at the auctions, and they are able to sell the
securities on to retail investors. Bids are made and the Treasury accepts the bids
from the highest downwards until the target amount is achieved. Bidders pay
varying prices according to their bids. The bonds issued are as follows:
BTFs (bons du Trésor à taux fixe et à intérêts précomptés) are government bills
with which the government covers its short-term cash position fluctuations.
They have a maturity of one year or less and are auctioned every Monday.
1
A system for settling trades in securities: the simultaneous transfer of cash to the seller for
payment and securities to the buyer. It also performs the functions of safekeeping and asset
servicing (‘custody’) of these securities.
BTANs (bons du Trésor à intérêts annuels) are auctioned on the third Thursday
of each month and are two- to five-year bonds with a fixed annual rate of
interest. Since the 1st of January 2013, new benchmark securities created on
medium-term (maturities of two and five years) are issued under the form of
OAT (Obligation Assimilable du Trésor), as it is the case for long-term secu-
rities (10 years and more). The specific name of BTAN for medium-term
securities has indeed no more the utility it had originally. Existing BTAN
continue to be tapped in order to maintain their liquidity.
OATs (obligations assimilables du Trésor) are auctioned on the first Thursday
of each month and range in maturity from 7 to 50 years. They are mostly fixed
rate, but some have floating rates, pegged to the TEC 10, an index of long-term
government bond yields; these are called TEC 10 OATs (because the yield on
a bond with close to ten years to redemption is used). There are some index-
linked bonds, linked either to the domestic consumer price index, OATi, or
to the eurozone price index, OAT€i. Once issued OATs may be supplemented
by further issues. Interest is paid once per year. OATs may be STRIPS.
Figure 3.4 French government bond maturity dates. Securities issued during the first
quarter of 2014 and total issuance
Source: Agence France Trésor, Monthly Bulletin, May 2014 www.aft.gouv.fr/documents/%7BC3BAF1F0-F068-
4305-821D-B8B2BF4F9AF6%7D/publication/attachments/23525.pdf
In 2014 the total of these bonds in issue was over €1.4 trillion – see Figures 3.3
and 3.4. Primary dealers commit to market making in OATs in an OTC market.
Note that the majority of French debt is held by non-residents – see Figure 3.5.
German bonds
In Germany, the German Finance Agency, Bundesrepublik Deutschland
Finanzagentur (BDF), is tasked with managing German government debt.
During 2014 it planned to issue securities totalling €205 billion – see Table 3.4.
Schaetze 2Y 25.4% 52
Bobl 5Y 23.4% 48
Bund 10Y 26.3% 54
Bund 30Y 3.4% 7
Capital market 78.5% 161
Bubill 6M 10.7% 22
Bubill 12M 10.7% 22
Money market 21.5% 44
The BDF sells via pre-announced auctions arranged by the Bundesbank, the
German central bank, with 6-month, 12 -month, 2-, 5-, 10- and 30-year matur-
ities, with a nominal value of €1 and a minimum bid of €1 million. Only the
37 members of the Bietergruppe Bundesemissionen (Bund Issuance Auction
Group) can place bids at the auctions. Bids may be competitive or non-
competitive. Competitive bids are made as a percentage of the nominal
price and successful bidders pay the actual price bid, with bids being accepted
from the highest downwards. Non-competitive bids are settled at the weighted
average price of accepted bids. A detailed auction timetable is available from
the BDF (www.deutsche-finanzagentur.de). The bills are discount securities
and the bonds pay interest once per year.
During the darkest days of the eurozone financial crisis investors were so
concerned about default risk that they were willing to pay very high prices
for government bonds from those countries perceived to be safest. They did
this to such an extent that the yield fell to below zero (the capital loss over the
holding period outweighed the coupon income). Then with deflation came
widespread holding of negative yield bonds – see Article 3.3.
Article 3.3
But then comes the bond market. Here, history suggests that prices have entered
into new and undiscovered territory. But because that territory is so new, history
has few precedents to help predict what might happen next.
This week’s publication of the annual Barclays equity-gilt study demonstrated that
UK gilts have outperformed stocks over the past 25 years – a remarkable outcome
that implies that bonds’ outperformance cannot be sustained. Over the longer
term, as Neil Collins details elsewhere in these pages, equities have comfortably
outperformed.
But by the standards of government bonds, UK gilts are not that impressive.
Negative yields, meaning that investors are in effect paying the government for the
privilege of looking after their money, are now available on bonds from Germany
and Switzerland. This sounds crazy. Why would anyone do this?
In fact, negative yields can be explained by a number of factors. First, there is the
fear of deflation. If you think the buying power of money will decline, it makes
sense to buy a bond whose value will also decline.
Second, there is second-guessing the actions of central banks. If they will be buying
at whatever price, then buy bonds, even at a negative yield, and sell to them later.
The European Central Bank is about to launch into indefinite bond purchases, and
the Bank of Japan is in the midst of a continuing bond-buying campaign. They can
print money so they can be relied on to buy.
Third, there are demographics. As populations age, so it makes sense for more
people to buy bonds that provide an income in retirement, and for more pension
funds to buy them so that they can afford to make guarantees for the future. This
is particularly true when governments change regulations to force them to do so,
thereby arguably forcing them to lend cheap to the state.
Fourth, there is supply. There are fewer safe assets than there used to be. US
mortgage-backed debt is, naturally, no longer considered to be in that category; the
number of corporations with the top triple-A credit rating is also now negligible;
and government bonds issued by peripheral eurozone countries are now regarded
as very risky.
Hence, naturally enough, the few truly safe assets that are left become even more
valuable – to the point where investors will even accept a negative yield.
Finally there is demand. Foreign exchange reserve managers have steadily bought
bonds, particularly Treasuries, as insurance against crises. China’s huge build-up
of Treasury bonds, which arguably kept rates artificially low, was dubbed a ‘savings
glut’ as long as a decade ago. Now, the eurozone’s huge and growing trade surplus
should deepen that savings glut – and force bond yields down.
In the short term, it is eminently possible for bonds’ price rise to continue, even
though they have reached a historic extreme. The experience of last year, when
substantially nobody was ready for bond yields to pivot downwards once again,
makes that clear.
Richard Batley, economist at Lombard Street Research, points out that the
money coming from the ECB and the Bank of Japan will be more than enough to
➨
counteract any decline in the balance sheet of the Federal Reserve, according to
their announced plans.
But investors may have learnt the wrong lesson from 2014. Yes, bond yields can
continue to fall, and even go negative. But that does not mean that they can never
reverse.
Demographics have helped bonds (and equities) for the past three decades, and are
in the process of reversing in the western world and even in China. Once there
are fewer savers as a proportion of the population, and more people gradually
selling bonds as they live into their retirement, so this will be a big headwind for
bond prices. And at some point, central banks will stop offering their support, even
if that point is still in the future.
And the pain when they do could be considerable. Investors have grown accustomed
to low or even negative interest rates, and have developed a range of securities to
act as a proxy for the safe income-producers that government bonds used to be.
Look at the growth of real estate or infrastructure investing, for example, or the
popularity of high-yielding dividend stocks.
All of these assets would be affected if and when the bond market finally turns.
And the steady exit of banks from fixed-income markets, under pressure from
regulators, means that they would not be there to ease the process as bonds finally
turn. There have been a few indicators in the past two years that the bond market
is vulnerable to short and sharp turns – such as the ‘taper tantrum’ in spring 2014,
when yields rose, or last October’s ‘flash crash’, when they fell.
The chief warning of the Barclays study, even though history provides so few pre-
cedents, is that the bond market must turn at some point, and that when it does
that turn could be violent.
Source: Authers, J. (2015) Investors be warned: the bond market must turn some time,
Financial Times, 27 February.
© The Financial Times Limited 2015. All Rights Reserved.
Japanese bonds
The Japanese Ministry of Finance issues Japanese government bonds ( JGBs),
paying interest semi-annually. In March 2014, the Japanese government had
outstanding debt of ¥1,025 trillion ($10 trillion). Medium- and long-term bonds
made up nearly 80% of this. Auctions take place regularly (usually monthly)
according to a published calendar. Maturities on JGBs can be 2, 5, 10, 20, 30
or 40 years. Inflation-indexed JGBs are also issued for 10-year maturities and
floating-rate JGBs for 15-year maturities. Japanese institutions purchase the
majority (about 70%) of these bonds (see Figure 3.7), but retail investors are
able to purchase 3-, 5- and 10-year bonds.
● ¥10,000 for JGBs for retail investors (3-year fixed rate, 5-year fixed rate,
10-year floating rate)
● ¥50,000 for 2-, 5-, 10-, 20-, 30- and 40-year
Many JGBs are traded in the over-the-counter secondary market, but trade has
been severely constrained by the impact of the enormous quantity of buying
by the central bank – see Article 3.4. Foreign investors are encouraged, but still
hold less than 10%. A few are traded on the Tokyo Stock Exchange and other
exchanges. The average time to maturity of bonds and T-bills combined is
seven and a half years – see Figure 3.8.
Article 3.4
Credit Suisse has already calculated that, if the bank keeps buying bonds at its
current rate, it will hold nearly 40% of all outstanding five to 10-year JGBs by
next March – nearly double its current share.
Source: McLannahan, B. (2014) Kuroda always looks on the bright side, but reality is dark,
Financial Times, 11 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Chinese bonds
China’s government bond market was established in 1950, but that experiment
by the Communist Party was closed down in 1958. With the economic reforms
of the 1980s the Chinese bond market was re-established and is now one of
the largest in the world, having grown exponentially during the 21st century.
Unlike most debt markets the Chinese one is generally closed to foreign issuers,
investors and intermediaries, except for investments via qualified foreign
institutional investors (QFIIs), which are a select few foreign financial institu-
tions allowed to invest in the Chinese securities market. Even then, they can
do so only up to their quota limit.
The amount of bonds (government plus corporate) outstanding at the end of
2013 was over Rmb 35 trillion (about £3.4 trillion) – see Article 3.5.
The bond market is split into three roughly equal portions: (1) government
bonds consisting of Treasury bonds and bills, savings bonds and local govern-
ment bonds, and central government bonds; (2) policy bank bonds, issued
by the Agricultural Development Bank of China, China Development Bank
and Export–Import Bank of China; and (3) corporate bonds, most of which
are issued by state-owned enterprises and a few private corporate entities and
financial institutions (they also issue medium-term notes, commercial paper).
There are two main types of government bonds traded in China:
● Treasury bonds – these have maturities up to 50 years. They are issued at
auctions with no set pattern of issuance
● financial bonds – these are issued by banks and financial institutions and are
heavily backed by government-owned or controlled institutions. They are
traded in the interbank markets.
Wary of foreign investment and control, most domestic debt is still purchased
by state-owned or state-controlled financial institutions, thus concentrating
risk in quasi-government-owned institutions instead of spreading it among
many investors. The secondary market is very thin.
Article 3.5
Since the days of Marco Polo, China has been stuck with the label of the world’s
largest untapped market.
At roughly $4tn, China’s domestic bond market is the world’s fourth largest, and
far larger than the Shanghai equity market’s $2.4tn. It is also growing about 30%
a year.
Yet for global investors, Chinese credit has been almost entirely off limits, with
opportunities limited to relatively small offshore markets – whether in US dollars
or renminbi – where a small number of mainland companies have chosen to borrow.
But change is afoot as financial reforms crack open the door to domestic Chinese
bonds.
‘As the market opens up, it’s going to become one of the most important capital
markets in the world,’ says Geoff Lunt, Asian fixed-income product specialist at
HSBC asset management.
Singapore on Tuesday joined London and Hong Kong as financial centres where
investors can apply for quotas under China’s renminbi qualified foreign institu-
tional investor scheme. Holders of RQFII licences can use renminbi that they hold
offshore to invest directly in domestic Chinese assets, from bonds to stocks to
money market funds.
The recent expansion of RQFII – totalling Rmb400bn ($65bn) but of which just
Rmb130bn has been allocated – is the latest step in Beijing’s broad, long-term
goal of improving access to China’s domestic financial markets. A sister pro-
gramme denominated in US dollars has also been expanded to attract more foreign
investment.
HSBC, which in July became the first big international bank to get an RQFII
licence, says it plans to use its licence to launch funds targeting China’s domestic
bond market. Central banks are also getting in on the act as they look to diversify
their holdings away from the US dollar. In April, the Reserve Bank of Australia said
it planned to invest about 5% of its reserves in Chinese government debt.
‘Liquidity is better onshore, and the yield pickup is also higher. That’s why a lot of
central banks have got their own quotas to place funds onshore’, says Jack Chang,
chief executive of ICBC Asia asset management. His company, whose clients include
central banks and sovereign wealth funds, plans to make its first investment in
onshore fixed income later this month.
➨
However, few are expecting the swift demise of the offshore – or ‘dim sum’ – bond
market, which is subject to international legal and regulatory standards and offers
much simpler tax and repatriation rules for those seeking to exit investments.
Source: Noble, J. (2013) China bond market emerges from the shadows, Financial Times,
23 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Emerging markets
Less well-developed economy governments may issue bonds in their domestic
currency or in the major hard currencies such as the dollar or the euro.
Table 3.5 shows a sample of government bonds from emerging countries for
which the coupons and principal will be paid in dollars or euros (there are also
a couple of high-yield corporate bonds for Bertin and Kazkommerts). Credit
ratings from Standard & Poor’s, ‘S’, Moody’s, ‘M’, and Fitch, ‘F’, are discussed
Kazkommerts Int 02/17 6.88 B Caa1 B 99.88 6.91 0.03 –0.47 6.86
Emerging US$
Bulgaria 01/15 8.25 BBB− Baa2 BBB− 104.00 1.21 –0.03 0.37 1.14
Peru 02/15 9.88 BBB+ Baa2 BBB+ 105.59 0.95 0.41 –0.01 0.88
Brazil 03/15 7.88 BBB− Baa2 BBB 104.76 1.18 0.03 0.05 1.07
Mexico 09/16 11.38 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 123.27 0.86 –0.05 –0.10 0.39
Philippines 01/19 9.88 BBB Baa3 BBB− 132.51 2.34 0.00 –0.02 0.65
Brazil 01/20 12.75 BBB− Baa2 BBB 150.12 2.94 – –0.35 1.23
Colombia 02/20 11.75 BBB Baa3 BBB 144.23 3.18 –0.01 0.02 1.48
Russia 03/30 7.50 BBB− Baa1 BBB 115.25 4.32 0.16 –0.21 2.63
Mexico 08/31 8.30 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 143.20 4.62 0.00 0.06 2.02
Indonesia 02/37 6.63 BB+ Baa3 BBB− 113.25 5.59 – 0.10 2.11
Emerging Euro
Brazil 02/15 7.38 BBB− Baa2 BBB 103.89 1.10 0.10 0.08 1.08
Poland 02/16 3.63 A− A2 A− 105.63 0.15 –0.18 –0.34 0.12
Turkey 03/16 5.00 NR Baa3 BBB− 105.40 1.74 0.05 0.16 1.71
Mexico 02/20 5.50 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 121.02 1.59 0.04 –0.12 1.03
US$ denominated bonds NY closer; all other London close. * S – Standard & Poor’s, M – Moody's, F – Fitch.
Source: Thomson Reuters
in Chapter 5. Note the additional yield that must be offered on these bonds
(‘Spread vs US’) compared with what the US government has to pay despite
the currency of coupons and principal both being US dollars. This is due to the
extra risk of default.
Frequently, these bonds are issued under UK or US law to reassure lenders that
should default occur there will be greater protection than under the issuer’s
law. The benefit of this was shown in the case of Greece’s default in 2012 – the
majority of its sovereign debt was issued under local law and those holders
were forced to accept 74% losses in a ‘bond exchange’ (meaning they swapped
the original bonds for lower-value ones). The minority holding the few governed
under English law were repaid at par. Mind you, it is not always that easy. Take
the case of Argentina’s bonds, issued under US law. They defaulted in 2001.
Following a deal with most of the bond holders (they got about 35 cents on
the dollar) the country refused to pay anything to those who did not agree
to the reduction (24% of the holders). The ‘holdouts’ (mostly hedge funds)
fought in US courts for years and won a number of judgments – an Argentine
ship was seized in Ghana at one point; the president is reluctant to fly abroad
in her plane in case it is seized – which in 2014 resulted in a ruling that they
should receive full payment including interest – see Article 3.6.
Article 3.6
North Korea’s defaulted debt exists in a sort of twilight state, paying no interest but
invested in by those who believe that the country cannot remain severed from the
wider world forever. No payout on the loans is in sight, but prices on the securitised
loan certificates have moved between 60 cents on the dollar to less than 10 cents
over the years, depending on news from the country and indications about the
future of sanctions.
Now the battle between Argentina and investors who hold the country’s defaulted
bonds has reawakened interest in markets such as those North Korean certificates,
part of a small and illiquid world of hyper-exotic distressed debt.
If the ‘hold out’ hedge fund investors receive the money that New York judge
Thomas Griesa says is due to them, they could stand to profit not only from the
discount at which they purchased the bonds but on unpaid interest due since
the default.
So-called past due interest can be the source of spectacular gains to investors
patient enough to wait for it.
When Iraq defaulted on sovereign bonds in the 1980s, borrowed in part to fund a
war with Iran, the unpaid interest spanned over two decades before the country
restructured its debt in 2006. Vietnam repaid past interest on loans that had traded
at less than 5 cents on the dollar in the 1990s when it rejoined capital markets and
Liberian debt, which also traded at less than 5 cents in the 1990s, was settled at
close to six times that when it was restructured.
The prospect of harvesting these sort of returns is why some investors will consider
buying non-performing debt from the tiny island of Nauru in the South Pacific,
currently trading at 5 cents on the dollar, or debt issued by Sudan before civil war
split the country north to south.
Exotic frontier debt is in vogue right now. Debut sovereign bonds issued by
Rwanda and Kenya have attracted unexpected levels of interest from investors
keen for yield. That has caused concern in some quarters.
‘There is an increasing lack of awareness about the illiquidity and implicit risk
taken by investors as they move down the curve looking for yield in this zero
interest world,’ says Sam Vecht at BlackRock Frontiers investment trust.
But others say that long-term investment in defaulted sovereign debt is not neces-
sarily the one-sided risk it might sound. The prospect of low-cost funding has also
put pressure on countries such as Argentina to resolve outstanding debts if they
are to tap global capital markets.
‘There is a big difference between a country and a corporation defaulting because
the country won’t disappear,’ says Christopher Wyke, emerging market debt product
manager at Schroders.
One of the markets long considered ripe for turnaround is Cuba, which defaulted
on its debt in 1986. This year prices in the secondary market for the discounted debt
rose from 6 cents on the dollar to 9 cents. Experts say unpaid due interest could far
exceed the sums demanded by investors in Argentinian debt.
➨
‘Opportunities [in distressed debt] will usually arise from a credit event such as
the lifting of an embargo,’ says Julian Adams, chief executive of investment fund
Adelante. ‘But this market is shrinking as countries embrace capital markets and
must sort out their older debts.’
Source: Moore, E. (2014) Argentina row triggers interest in defaulted debt, Financial Times,
2 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Article 3.7
Around half of all government debt defaults now trigger creditor lawsuits and
in countries such as Congo, Ecuador, Iraq, Peru and Poland, small numbers of
private investors have refused to take part in government plans to restructure
unaffordable debt, holding out for full repayment.
Additional reporting by Robin Harding.
Source: Moore, E. (2014) New framework for sovereign defaults, Financial Times,
28 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Article 3.8
Original sin is pernicious. Borrowing in foreign currencies can both trigger and
exacerbate financial and economic crises. When a country’s debts are denominated
in foreign currencies, it forces policy makers to keep exchange rates pegged or
heavily managed. If the rate buckles, the authorities have to burn through valuable
reserves and raise interest rates to protect the value of the local currency – even in
the midst of a recession if necessary.
Almost inevitably, the peg breaks, the local currency tumbles, the foreign currency-
denominated debt burden becomes too great and a destructive government default
ensues.
Spurred by these crises, emerging market policy makers have spent the past decade
getting their finances in order. Crucially, they have nurtured and developed domestic
bond markets denominated in local currencies.
‘We saw with our own eyes how hard [the Asian financial crisis in 1998] hit our
neighbours, and how harshly the IMF treated them – far worse than it is treating
the eurozone,’ Cesar Purisima, the Philippine finance minister, told the Financial
Times. ‘We learnt lessons from that.’
The changes across emerging markets are eye-catching. The domestic Mexican peso
bond market, for example, exploded from about $28bn in US dollar terms in 1996 to
$445bn in late 2011. South Korea’s bond market surged fivefold to $1.1tn over the
same period, while Poland’s zloty market grew sevenfold to $203bn.
It has been a gradual process. Local institutional investor bases have often had
to be started from scratch through reforms that encourage domestic pension and
insurance industries to take root. Above all, inflation – the nemesis of bond investors
but a perennial problem in emerging markets – had to be tamed.
‘When I started trading, emerging markets were the wild west,’ recalls Sergio Trigo
Paz, head of emerging market debt at BlackRock. ‘Local markets were considered
no-man’s land, even domestically, due to hyperinflation.’
Kenneth Rogoff and Carmen Reinhart have shown that the share of domestic debt
to total government debts in emerging markets declined gradually from a peak
of about 80% in the 1950s to a low of about 40% in the early 1990s. But by 2010 the
percentage had climbed sharply back to more than 60%. In fact, experts now say
domestic debt levels could return to those highs of the 1950s.
‘There were very large local bond markets before, but high inflation pretty much
wiped them out,’ says Mr Rogoff, an economics professor at Harvard. ‘Things are
changing. Developing countries have been very keen to rebalance their borrowing
away from foreign markets.’
The financial crisis reinforced this trend. Domestic bond sales now account for the
vast majority of government borrowing in the developing world, perhaps as much
as 90% of it in 2012.
International investors have become increasingly infatuated by the economic pro-
spects for the developing world and have piled into local bond markets in recent
years. From less than $150bn in March 2009, foreign holdings of local currency
emerging market bonds climbed to well over $500bn last year.
➨
The rating agencies have also cheered the rise of local bond markets and have
rewarded developing countries with better grades. ‘One of the key reasons for the
improvement in emerging market resilience and robustness – and the increase in
their ratings – is the changing make-up of their debt,’ says David Riley, head of
sovereign ratings at Fitch Ratings.
Although positive, more vibrant local bond markets do not completely inoculate
countries from crises. Deep local markets can even act as a temptation for govern-
ments to borrow excessively. Once they do, many countries have in the past found
it easier simply to inflate the debts away – throttling local bond markets in the
process. Some have simply defaulted. For example, Russia’s short-term debt market
allowed it to delay its inevitable default in 1998, but exacerbated the ensuing chaos.
Local bond markets are also of little help if a country has a current account deficit.
Countries that import more than they export need foreign currency inflows to
make up the difference, whether through borrowing or overseas investment. Even
governments with healthy budget surpluses can run into trouble if the current
account is negative.
It also remains tricky to sell longer-term bonds locally. While some have managed to
lengthen the ‘duration’ of their markets, even some of the more advanced emerging
economies struggle to sell bonds with a maturity longer than 10 years.
‘Original sin is receding for some countries, but mostly for the advanced ones,’ says
Marie Cavanaugh, managing director and member of the sovereign ratings com-
mittee at Standard & Poor’s. ‘Poorer, less developed emerging economies are often
still very dependent on foreign capital.’
Of the almost $10tn worth of locally denominated debts tallied by BofA, almost
two-thirds are in Brazil, China and South Korea. Many smaller countries have
found it harder to nurture local markets.
In fact, the IMF has started to become concerned that the current eagerness of
investors to lend to emerging economies could lead some of these smaller states to
forget the hard-learnt lessons of the past and borrow too much in dollars.
Countries such as Zambia and Mongolia have been identified as being at particular
risk of reviving the bane of original sin. Mongolia late last year sold a $1.5bn bond
– equal to a fifth of its annual economic output in a single offering.
Some fund managers also fret that emerging market companies could become
future sources of instability, after selling record amounts of dollar-denominated
corporate bonds in recent years.
Professors Hausmann and Eichengreen agree that original sin is a less pressing
problem than in the past, but argue that improvements are the result of a drastic
curtailment of dollar borrowing – not a rise in international investor participation
on local bond markets. Indeed, these days some countries have imposed barriers to
keep foreign investors out of their markets, rather than enticing them in. Capital
inflows can cause currencies to appreciate, making a country less competitive.
Foreign investors are often more fickle than local ones, and sharp outflows can
unsettle local markets.
➨
Nonetheless, the rise of domestic bond markets has proved a tremendously positive
development not just for emerging economies but also for the wider international
financial system. Rather than being sources of instability – as was often the case in
the past – many emerging markets are now self-funding carthorses for the global
economy.
The progress of the past decade is already striking. As long as policy makers do not
forget the lessons of past crises, local bond markets are likely to continue to gain in
size, vibrancy and importance, experts say.
Africa has underdeveloped local bond markets, but even here many of its
countries are now welcomed in the international dollar-denominated market
– see Article 3.9.
Article 3.9
David Cowan, Africa economist at Citigroup, adds that east African nations would
also benefit from investors’ interest in diversifying their exposure from countries
➨
such as Nigeria, Ghana and Gabon. ‘There is strong appetite to diversify from the
west African sovereign bond story, which is mostly linked to oil,’ he says.
The JPMorgan Nexgem Africa index, which tracks the bond market in the region,
is yielding 7.3%, up from a low-point in January of 5.3%. Still, interest rates for
sovereign issuers in sub-Saharan Africa remain well below the most recent peak of
14% set during the global financial crisis in 2008.
Zambia’s debut last year marked the top for the sub-Saharan market, raising $750m
at a yield of 5.6%. But since then other countries have paid higher yields: Ghana
paid an interest rate of 7.85% in June, and Nigeria paid 6.6%.
But he warns that many investors attracted by ‘a bit of euphoria in the market’
but who are not familiar with Africa are easily wrong footed. Insparo did not join
in the rush for Rwanda’s debut $400m bond, which launched earlier this year and
has already fallen significantly. He says Rwanda’s small, aid-dependent economy is
at too early a stage of development to warrant a bond. Still, Mr Hanif says Kenya
and Tanzania instead present ‘great stories’ with more mature economies that offer
‘sustainable growth’ and Insparo expects to participate in both bonds.
‘In March this year I was online requesting [offers] for investors. I was looking for
$500m but it was oversubscribed to $2.5bn,’ he says, adding: ‘We already have very
good investors who are actually waiting for [the bond] opportunity.’
Source: Blas, J. and Manson, K. (2013) Sub-Saharan bond rush spreads east to Kenya and
Tanzania, Financial Times, 3 September.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Clearly, many emerging markets are for the bravest of investors, but it can pay
off if you buy at high yields and then the generality of investors become less
afraid, start buying, pushing up the bond price and lowering yields, as they did
with Irish and Belarusian debt following their crises. But there is brave and
there is foolhardy – see Article 3.10.
Article 3.10
developed-market credit. Even so, investors are beginning to buy these bonds with
ever less discrimination.
A brave investor may also argue that fundamentals favour the Iraqi bond. The
country sells lots of oil. But 6.7%? EM bond risks may not seem so high when risk
has become favoured everywhere. That is not the same as riskless.
Source: Lex column (2014) EM bonds: are you nuts?, Financial Times, 11 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Local authority/municipal/quasi-state/
agency bonds
Local authority, municipal, quasi-state and agency bonds are issued by
governments and organisations at a sub-national level, such as a county, city
or state. They pay a rate of interest and are repayable on a specific future date,
similar in fact to Treasury bonds. They are sometimes called semi-sovereigns
or sub-sovereigns. They are an important means of raising money to finance
developments, buildings or expansion by the local authority or agency. They
are riskier than government bonds (the issuers cannot print their own money
as governments might) as from time to time cities, counties, etc. do go bust and
fail to pay their debts. However, many issuers, particularly in Europe and the
US, obtain bond insurance from a private insurance group with a top credit
rating, guaranteeing that the bond will be serviced on time. This can boost an
issue’s credit rating, as its rating will then be based on the insurer’s credit
rating, which reduces the interest rate the sub- sovereigns pay.
In the UK, local authority bonds or quasi-state bonds are out of favour at
the moment, although Transport for London issued a 25-year bond in 2006,
and in 2012–2013 raised £1.6 billion with four bond issues with maturities
ranging from 5 to 33 years. There has been talk of issuing a ‘Brummie’ bond
(by Birmingham City Council), but this has yet to be finalised. In July 2013
the city of Leeds raised more than £100 million with an oversubscribed bond
issued to finance a social housing project.
US municipals
Municipal bonds (‘munis’, pronounced mew-knees) are issued by state and
local government departments and special districts. Much of the infrastructure
Figure 3.9 State and local government debt in the US over time
Source: Data from Financial Accounts of the United States, June 2013
in the US has been and still is financed by municipal bonds, the first of which
was issued in 1812. These bonds have proved to be a valuable source of finance
for local communities.
Some municipal bond issuers have made bad investment decisions and
have gone bust, notably those issued by Orange County, California, in 1994,
where the county treasurer lost more than $1.5 billion; by Jefferson County,
Alabama, in 2011, which went bankrupt owing $4.2 billion; and by the city
of Detroit, Michigan, the former hub of the US motor industry, which in
2013 went down owing $18 billion. Investors who bought bonds where
the issuer has gone bankrupt face losing some or all of their investment.
Despite these few well-publicised defaults, overwhelmingly municipal bonds
provide a valuable service to their communities and their investors with very
few problems.
The German Länder (federal states) are also large issuers, with more than
€350 billion of bonds outstanding in 2014, about the same as the Netherlands.
There are also quasi-state organisations issuing bonds in Europe. In France,
Société Nationale des Chemins de Fer Français (SNCF, the state-owned French
railway operator), and in Germany, Deutsche Bahn (DB, the state-owned German
railway company), are just some of the institutions that have issued bonds.
Sweden and Finland both run schemes where local communities join together
to issue bonds to raise finance. By keeping the schemes local, the risk is reduced
so that the bonds receive higher credit ratings. Article 3.11 discusses some local
authority bonds.
Article 3.11
Investor appetite for public sector debt has become intense, says George Richardson,
head of capital markets at the World Bank Treasury.
In the UK, local authorities are hoping to kick start a market in municipal bonds to
take advantage of low global borrowing rates by creating central agencies.
The UK’s Local Government Association has said that creating an agency able to
issue debt on behalf of councils could save them more than £1bn in borrowing
costs.
More than £4.5m has so far been raised to create the Local Capital Finance
Company, and the organisers say they hope to raise the first bond by March or
April 2015.
Bankers say the success of municipal bond agencies in Nordic countries, Switzerland,
Italy and now France, bodes well.
In Sweden, Kommuninvest raises sums that standalone councils would not be able
to do, something UK councils will be aware of. Launched in the late 1980s, by the
end of last year Kommuninvest’s total lending had reached $28bn.
And in the US, the vast municipal bond market, which reached $3.7tn by the end
of last year, is an established source of saving for households.
Source: Moore, E. (2014) Local authorities turn to capital markets, Financial Times,
30 September.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Agencies
Agencies (government-sponsored enterprises, GSEs) are set up to fulfil a
public purpose and while the debt they issue is not always explicitly guaranteed
by the government, there is a strong implication or assumption that the state
will step in to make good any shortfall. In the US, a handful of organisations
(quasi-governmental) dominate the agency bond market, including the Federal
Home Loan Bank System (FHLBS), the Federal National Mortgage Association
(Fannie Mae), the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac),2
Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) and the Student Loan Marketing Association
(Sallie Mae).
2
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were taken over by the US government in 2008 to save them
from failure after the mortgage crisis.
Most companies at some time need to borrow large sums of money to finance
their operations, and it is vital that they try to do so to their best advantage, e.g.
at the lowest cost, with an optimum mix in terms of maturity dates and with
an acceptable pattern of cash outflows.
If a company finds that it needs extra debt capital to operate successfully, one
of the ways it can source the capital is by issuing corporate bonds. These bonds
are simply IOUs issued by the company and bought by investors who, in return
for lending the company their money, receive interest payments (usually) and
payment of the principal amount at a set time. In general, corporate bonds
offer a higher rate of return than reputable government bonds but as you
might expect, this comes with a greater degree of risk of failure to pay what was
agreed. Having said that, because many governments are less reputable than
some companies within the country, corporate borrowing can be at lower rates
of return than that of their governments. Corporate bonds are generally issued
with a coupon (usually taxable) paying a set amount annually or semi-annually,
and their yield is calculated in the same way as government bonds. Most
corporate bonds are medium to long dated and are rarely more than 20 years.
Corporate bonds can be a very useful way for companies to raise money with-
out issuing equity, which brings the possibility of losing a degree of control
over the company, or accepting the constraints imposed by bank lenders.
Issuance depends on investors and corporate managers having confidence
in the economy and in the prospects for the specific company as well as the
interest rate level. Investor appetite for corporate bonds ebbs and flows, as does
managerial confidence in the benefits of additional debt. Sometimes, as in
August 2013, there is great economic uncertainty and a considerable drop in
the amount being issued – see Article 4.1.
Article 4.1
Source: Atkins, R. (2013) Global corporate bond issuance at lowest level in five years,
Financial Times, 25 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Trading of bonds
While the government bond markets in developed economies are very liquid,
with single government bond issues raising billions and with thousands of
investors trading in the market, by contrast corporate bond market activity can
be very low. Companies may raise merely millions of pounds/dollars in an
issue, and most investors buy and hold to maturity rather than trade in and
out. Some companies issue bonds on a regular basis, every few months or years,
each with its own coupon and terms, thus there might be a dozen bonds
for one company and tens of thousands of different corporate issues in the
secondary market place. The wide range reduces the market depth for any one
issue. This means that an investor might not be able to buy or sell particular
bonds because there is none being traded – see Article 4.2.
Article 4.2
are trading. They join an elite group of liquid corporate bonds. Most issues are not
so easy to buy and sell.
In fact, of the 30,000 investment-grade corporate bonds trading in the US alone, only
20 trade more than ten times a day, according to MarketAxess. The proportion of
the market that turns over in a year has slipped below 75%. The situation in muni-
cipal bonds, issued by state and local governments, is even worse.
And that means it is not so easy for a bond investor to be sure of the price she
will have to pay if she puts in an order, or end up receiving if she tells her broker
to sell.
At an industry forum earlier this month, the independent financial adviser Ric
Edelman went as far as to claim investors were, in effect, being ‘lied to . . . We
understand why that happens, that no deceit is intended, but they are shocked to
discover what they thought was $105 was in fact $98 and don’t know that until they
have sold. We have huge education and disclosure problems within the industry.’
The issue is getting scrutinised by regulators in the US and Europe like never
before. Technological advances bring the tantalising prospect of more liquidity and
there is already more transparency on price, at least after bonds have traded.
But the US Securities and Exchange Commission for one is sceptical that the bene-
fits are flowing through to retail investors. They fear that the opacity of the market
allows big dealers to take advantage by taking big mark-ups on trades.
The agency is considering demanding more transparency in corporate and muni-
cipal bond trading, although it has to weigh concerns that new rules could be
detrimental to some big players in the market.
As for investors being able to see a price for their specific bond before they trade,
that is a harder problem to crack. Traditionally, there has been no substitute to
brokers calling round the trading desks of Wall Street to ask what a specific lot of
bonds will fetch.
Source: Foley, S. (2013) Battle is on to make bonds more transparent, Financial Times,
1 May.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Some corporate bonds are sufficiently liquid to trade on the London Stock
Exchange and other exchanges in Europe, Asia or the Americas and may also
be traded on electronic communication networks (ECNs), which facilitate
trading outside stock exchanges, but the vast majority of trading occurs in the
over-the-counter market directly between an investor and a bond dealer.
Bond dealers stand ready to quote bid and offer prices depending on whether
the investor wants to buy or sell. Fund managers, or brokers acting for inves-
tors, will have to contact a number of these dealers by telephone to get quote
prices. The bid–offer spreads are generally higher than for equities – even large
company bonds can have a spread of 15%, but most are less than this.
costs. Many such platforms are now operating but they still account for only
1% of trades. Investors are irritated by the splitting of such trades between
numerous venues, mostly run by an investment bank with its own agenda (single-
dealer systems) and would prefer to see one dominant platform (multi-dealer
platform) emerge, run in a way that would benefit them. Concern has been
expressed that platform providers are using data from the trading venue to
inform their own team of traders and market makers – this knowledge might
be used against investors. Market makers in the OTC market appear to be
somewhat reluctant to shift from one-to-one trades with high spreads allowing
them to pocket the difference between bid and offer prices to a computer system
doing cheaper automatic trades – turkeys not voting for Christmas, I guess.
Article 4.3
Coming forward to fill this gap are electronic trading platforms such as MarketAxess,
Bonds.com, BondDesk, and TradingScreen. While attracting growing volumes, for
the most part, trading on these platforms involves so-called ‘odd lots’ or small
trades of older bond issues.
At least, that was the case until trading activity in Dell bonds on several platforms
surged earlier this year. For one electronic platform, Bonds.com, the heightened
activity in Dell bonds that helped its daily market share jump fivefold to around
10% was a watershed and points to a future solution. ‘It shows the model works,
really well, or one like it could,’ says Thomas Thees, chief executive at Bonds.com.
He says the industry needs to reach a consensus around one trading venue. The
dilemma for the industry is that an already fragmented bond market, comprised of
thousands of individual bond issues, requires a common solution, not an ecosystem
of competing electronic trading platforms. As a host of venues and initiatives by
dealers are fighting for leadership, investors have yet to throw their weight behind
one of them.
But at some point the investor community needs to take the lead. ‘The buyside has
to be very engaged and involved with getting out in front of the liquidity issue,
rather than sitting back and waiting for a solution,’ says Chris Rice, global head of
trading at State Street Global Advisors. ‘We need to take control of our destiny and
start supporting emerging bond trading venues.’
Some dealers say efforts to build electronic corporate bond trading platforms have
had to start slowly. Electronic trading can help banks reduce costs in their
bond-trading businesses, by automating trades and eliminating expensive staff, but
the trade-off is greater price transparency and potentially smaller profits per trade.
Banks are reluctant to give up their profitable ‘high-touch’ dealing in the bonds
before they absolutely have to, some dealers say privately. Still, many banks have
been experimenting with their own platforms, including Goldman Sachs, Morgan
Stanley and UBS.
For many large bond investors, the use of single dealer platforms is limited, given
that the dealer selects the bonds being transacted and can also gain an insight into
what investors are doing.
Source: Mackenzie, M., McCrum, D. and Alloway, T. (2013) Electronic trading to muscle in
on corporate debt, Financial Times, 3 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Because most corporate bond market trading is a private matter between the
dealer and its customer in the OTC market it is difficult to obtain prices of recent
trades; they are not shown in the Financial Times, for example. Some websites
provide prices and other details on a few dozen corporate bonds, for example
www.fixedincomeinvestor.co.uk, www.hl.co.uk, www.selftrade.co.uk, http://
finra-markets.morningstar.com/BondCenter/Default.jsp.
Having said that the main bond market is a wholesale one, I need to add that
there is another regulated market in London. In 2010 the London Stock
Exchange (LSE, www.londonstockexchange.com) launched the Order Book
for Retail Bonds (ORB), which offers retail investors the opportunity to trade
a number of gilts, corporate bonds and international bonds, where lots are
often £100 or £1,000, with a typical initial minimum investment of £2,000,
and the costs of trading are relatively low.
Corporates are able to issue bonds on ORB in sizes smaller (from only £25 mil-
lion) than on the wholesale markets, where issues are usually £250 million
plus. Issuers must apply and be accepted by both (1) the United Kingdom
Listing Authority (UKLA), part of the financial services industry regulator, the
Financial Conduct Authority (FCA), and (2) the LSE. Trading is facilitated by
competing market makers advertising bid and offer prices on the LSE system
during the trading day, 8am to 4.30pm. Retail investors can buy through a
stockbroker, wealth manager or other regulated intermediary. Since 2010, com-
panies on ORB have raised more than £4 billion with 42 new issues. Table 4.1
presents some of the issues, showing the amounts raised.
Table 4.1 Some bonds available to retail investors on the London Stock Exchange’s
Order Book for Retail Bonds market
Figures 4.1 to 4.5 show the secondary bond price movements for some well-
known companies.
Case study
Tesco Bank (‘Personal Finance’) bond
We now look at a bond issue on ORB in more detail: Tesco Bank’s 8.5-year 5%
Sterling Fixed Rate Bond issued in May 2012 and due to be redeemed at £100
on 21 November 2020. However, it may be redeemed (at 100% of face value),
purchased or cancelled by Tesco Bank before then. This may happen if the tax
rules change to make Tesco Bank pay more, or in the case of default. Interest is
paid on 21 May and 21 November each year.
When first issued the minimum purchase was a mere £2,000 and the issue price
was 100% of the face value. Barclays Bank and Investec Bank both helped with
the sale of the bonds in the primary market. They were book-runners (organisers
of the issue) who received in fees 0.75% of the amount raised (0.75% of £200
million, i.e. £1.5 million), of which two-thirds was passed on to eight distributors,
stockbrokers who sold the bonds to investors. Barclays Bank and Investec Bank
subsequently acted as market makers in the secondary market. Many free financial
websites display information about the bond and the trading prices in the second-
ary market – an example is shown in Figure 4.6, taken from www.ADVFN.com.
Trades are settled after two business days (T+2).
Figure 4.7 shows the price movements of Tesco Bank’s bond during its first two
years.
Not all the bonds issued in ORB are borrowing with the same level of safety
because they may not have the backup from the strongest part of a group of com-
panies under the same ownership – see Article 4.4.
Article 4.4
Source: Johnson, S. (2013) Concerns mount over UK retail bond issues, Financial Times,
18 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Mini bonds
There is another class of bonds targeted at retail investors, but these do not
have a secondary market. They have been dubbed mini-bonds (mini-retail or
self-issued bonds) and are issued in very small amounts by small companies
– see Article 4.5 for some examples. With these bonds lenders are committed
for the full term (usually 3–5 years), to a small, usually non-stock market-
quoted firm, with less open accounting than quoted firms. The marketing and
information material has not been vetted by the FCA. The covenants placed
on the bond to reduce lender risk tend to be much lighter than those of
normal bonds. The interest rates offered on the bonds described in Article 4.5
are greater than those on ORB due to the additional liquidity and default
risk. They also suffer from not being eligible for inclusion in retail investors’
tax shelters such as self-invested personal pensions and not being covered
by the regulators’ Financial Services Compensation Scheme should something
go wrong.
Article 4.5
But this market is ‘archaic’ and ripe for disruption, said Luke Lang, one of
Crowdcube’s founders. Rather than paying fees, which it says usually total more
than £100,000, Crowdcube charges companies 5% of the total raised once the target
has been met.
‘We’re trying to cut out some of the fat from the City of London,’ said Mr Lang.
‘With mini-bonds, fees from financial advisers, lawyers, compliance and marketing
companies can rack up pretty quickly.’
While attracting high-yield investors, the bonds have also drawn scrutiny. Critics
point out that there is no secondary market, and the bonds are unsecured – meaning
that investors rank behind secured investors in the case of a default.
‘Some of the conventions of the institutional market have been thrown out the
window, but those conventions are there for a reason,’ said James Tomlins, a
high-yield bond portfolio manager at M&G.
He added that the products represent a ‘new area of capital’ and that the use of the
word bond may be inappropriate. ‘You’ve got linguistic arbitrage here,’ he said.
‘You’ve got equity-like downside with bond-like upside.’
Previously, companies such as Crowdcube have targeted equity investors looking
to benefit from the profit potential of small but fast-growing companies. In issuing
bonds, crowdfunding companies hope to diversify their investment offerings and
attract companies with the cash flow available to service fixed income debt.
While the average size of an equity issuance on Crowdcube is £200,000, retail bonds
are all expected to raise at least £1m. The company says it is currently in talks with
companies – including ‘household name brands’ – over future bond issuances, some
of which may reach a price of up to £15m.
Source: Hale, T. (2014) ‘Crowdfunding’ muscles in on the bond market, Financial Times,
24 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Infinite variation
Corporate bonds come in an infinite variety of forms in many different curren-
cies and maturities, with the most common currencies being the US dollar and
the euro.
FRNs pay an interest rate that is linked to a benchmark rate – such as the Libor.
The issuer will pay, say, 70 basis points (0.7 of a percentage point) over the
‘reference index’ of Libor. The coupon might be set for the first six months at
the time of issue, after which it is adjusted every six months, so if Libor was 3%,
the FRN would pay 3.7% for that particular six months. The most common
reference rates are three-month or six-month Libor. Interest rates may be
linked to a variety of other benchmark rates, such as the Fed Funds rate, muni-
cipal and mortgage interest rate indexes, a particular money market rate or the
rate of inflation. The interest rate may be fixed daily, weekly, monthly, etc.
In 2013 concern about rises in interest rates led to an upsurge in the number of
FRNs being issued – see Article 4.6.
Article 4.6
Source: Thompson, C. and Atkins, R. (2013) Floating rate bond issuance jumps in Europe,
Financial Times, 29 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
FRNs may come with additional features such as a floor, which means that the
coupon can fall but there is a minimum beyond which it cannot go, and caps,
which permit a rise in the coupon with the underlying benchmark only up to
a point, there is a maximum. If there is both a floor and a cap the bond is said
to be a collared FRN.
FRNs will trade at par value on each of the coupon reset days. But if interest
rates rise between reset days they will trade slightly below par because investors
can now obtain the higher rates on alternative bonds and so are less willing to
hold the FRNs unless the price falls commensurately. If rates fall then FRNs will
trade at slightly above par until the next reset day.
Callable bonds
The issuer retains the right but not the obligation to redeem these bonds before
maturity at a set price which is usually a little more than the par price, say
$1,050 instead of $1,000 (the difference is the call premium). In return for
this privilege, the bond will pay a higher coupon. If interest rates fall, it would
be advantageous for the company to call in its bonds, redeem them and
issue new replacement bonds with a lower coupon, thus reducing their cost
of borrowing.
For investors the attraction of a higher coupon rate on callable bonds is some-
what offset by the risk that, should interest rates fall, the value of a callable
bond may also fall or at least fail to rise due to the threat of being called at a
low price relative to a similar non-callable bond, contrary to the behaviour of
normal bonds where value rises if interest rates fall. This is called price com-
pression risk. Callable bonds also suffer from reinvestment risk – see page 133.
Article 4.7
Louis Dreyfus Commodities, one of the world’s top food commodities traders, last
September tapped the public capital markets for the first time in its 160-year his-
tory, raising $350m in a perpetual bond.
The perpetual bond, which international accounting rules count as equity, will
strengthen the balance sheet of Trafigura without diluting existing shareholders.
Claude Dauphin, chief executive and one of the founders of the group, owns less
than 20% while more than 500 senior employees control the rest.
‘We want to get the long-term liquidity while maintaining our credit standing,’
Pierre Lorinet, Trafigura chief financial officer, said in an interview. ‘[The per-
petual bond] provides us with long-term money [with an] equity treatment.’
The bond will be listed on the Singapore Exchange, forcing Trafigura to release
publicly semi-annual accounts for the first time. Until now the company has only
released financial information to a small group of investors and bankers.
The new sources of financing in the Swiss commodities industry are partly driven
by a change in the business model of the trading houses.
Companies have moved away from their traditional role as middleman – selling
and buying commodities in a business of large volumes but razor-thin margins –
increasingly to become vertically integrated groups, with interest spanning pro-
duction, logistics, trading and processing.
The new areas, such as investing in oil refineries, require long-term capital that the
trading houses in the past did not need. Some trading houses have not opened their
equity to outsiders, but are seeking bond investors.
Source: Blas, J. and Farchy, J. (2013) Trafigura raises $500m with perpetual bond,
Financial Times, 10 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Puttable bonds
The holder has the right but not the obligation to demand early redemption of
the bonds on a set date or dates. The benefit to purchasers is that if interest
rates rise, they can cash in their bonds and reinvest in another investment
offering a higher rate of interest. The disadvantage is a slightly lower rate of
return in the first place.
Bonds secured through a fixed charge often have legal provisions in the debt
agreement that allow the issuer to dispose of a proportion of the property or
plant (such as a crane or fleet of cars) used as collateral, but when they do so
they must make provision for the redemption of a proportion of the fixed-
charge bonds. These are known as release of property clauses. The usual rule
is that these bonds are retired at par value, but some agreements allow a
redemption price other than par.
A floating charge means that the debt is secured by a general charge on all the
assets of the corporation, or a class of the firm’s assets such as inventory or
receivables (debtors). In this case the company has a high degree of freedom to
use its assets as it wishes, such as sell them or rent them out, until it commits a
default which ‘crystallises’ the floating charge, i.e. the floating charge is converted
to a fixed charge over the assets which it covers at that time. If this happens an
administrative receiver or administrator will be appointed with powers to
manage the business, to either pay the debt through income generation, or
dispose of the assets followed by distribution of the proceeds to creditors, or
sell the entire business as a going concern.
Similar collateral charges to the floating charge are the floating lien in the US
and a few other places, and the commercial pledge in many European countries.
The terms bond, debenture and loan stock are often used loosely and inter-
changeably, and the dividing line between debentures and loan stock is a fuzzy
one. As a general rule debentures are secured with collateral and loan stock is
unsecured, but there are examples that do not fit this classification. If liquidation
occurs, the unsecured loan stock holders rank beneath the debenture holders.
However, in the US and some other countries the definitions are somewhat
different and this can be confusing. Here a debenture is a long-term unsecured
bond and so the holders become general creditors who can only claim assets
not otherwise pledged. In the US the secured form of bond is referred to as a
mortgage bond and unsecured shorter-dated issues (less than ten years) are
called notes. US subordinated debentures, as well as being unsecured, are
further back in the queue for a cash distribution in the event of the company
failing to pay its debts than both mortgage bonds/debentures and regular
US-style debentures. They carry higher interest rates to compensate and are
often classified as junk bonds (see Chapters 5 and 6).
● Limits on the dividend level. Lenders are opposed to money brought into the
firm by borrowing at one end and then being taken away by shareholders in
dividend payments at the other. An excessive withdrawal of shareholders’
funds may unbalance the financial structure and weaken future cash flows
required to pay bond holders.
● Limits on the disposal of assets. The retention of certain assets, for example
property and land, may be essential to reduce the lenders’ risk. Disposal of
assets covenants often allows a cumulative total of up to, say, 30% of the
gross assets of the firms, but no more.
● Financial ratios. A typical covenant here concerns the interest cover, for
example: ‘The annual profit should remain four times as great as the overall
annual interest charge.’ Other restrictions might be placed on working cap-
ital ratio levels (the extent to which current assets exceed current liabilities)
and the debt to net assets ratio (a gearing ratio covenant) may require
that the total borrowing of the firm may not exceed a stated percentage of
net worth (share capital and reserves) of, say, 100%.
● Cross default covenant. The trustee has permission to put all loans into
default if the borrower defaults on a single loan.
While negative covenants cannot ensure completely risk-free lending they can
influence the behaviour of the managerial team so as to reduce the risk of
default. They can also provide the management team with an early warning
signal to take action. The lender’s risk can be further reduced by obtaining
guarantees from third parties (for example, guaranteed loan stock). The guar-
antor is typically the parent company of the issuer.
The trustee, responsible to bond holders, will inform them if the firm has failed
to fulfil its obligation under the trust deed and may initiate legal action against
the firm. If the firm has to go through a reorganisation of its finances, admin-
istration or liquidation, the trustee will continue to act on behalf of the bond
holders.
agent to undertake the paying agent’s role. The fiscal agent is appointed
by and is the representative of the issuer, in contrast to the trustee’s role as the
representative of the lenders. Nevertheless, the fiscal agent must not act in
a harmful way toward the bond holders. As well as payments it performs a
number of administrative tasks such as sending information on the bond/
issuer to the holders.
A registrar or transfer agent keeps a record of bond ownership and notes all
changes of ownership. A listing agent is required only if the bond is listed on
a stock exchange such as in London or Luxembourg. The listing agent keeps
the stock exchange informed and ensures required documents are delivered
to the exchange. In the UK the listing agent must be authorised to act in that
capacity by the FCA.
Repayments
The principal on most bonds is paid entirely at maturity. However, some
bonds, e.g. callable bonds, can be repaid before the final redemption date.
Another alternative is for the company to issue bonds with a range of dates for
redemption; so a bond dated 2024–2027 would allow a company the flexibility
to repay a part of the principal over the course of four years. This may help
prevent ‘a crisis at maturity’ by avoiding a large cash outflow at a singular
redemption. A range of dates is also useful if machinery subject to deprecia-
tion, e.g. a ship, is used as collateral because the amount owed declines as the
asset backing declines in value. When there are many maturity dates the bonds
are referred to as serial bonds.
Another way of redeeming bonds is for the issuing firm to buy outstanding
bonds by offering the holder a sum higher than or equal to the amount ori-
ginally paid. A firm is also able to purchase bonds on the open market.
Sinking fund
The most trusted corporates are able to sell bonds without the need to be
specific about how the debt will be repaid – the implication is that they will be
redeemed using general income flowing from operations or by the issue of
more bonds or bank borrowing. Borrowers with lower credit ratings may need
to state specific provisions for principal repayment to reduce investor anxiety
about the safety of their money.
Bonds might be selected randomly through a lottery for early redemption. The
alternative is the pro rata method with which all bond holders are treated
equally, thus they all might be required to retire 10% of their holdings if the
issuer decides to reduce the bonds outstanding by 10%.
Because a bond with a sinking fund provision is less risky for the investor, as
there is money being set aside, there is a push down on the rate of return
offered. However, offsetting this for the investor are the negative effects of not
knowing when or how many bonds will be retired.
Event risk
Some adverse event may occur which devalues the bond, e.g. a natural disaster
wipes out company profits and damages the ability of the company to pay its
obligations. Or an issuer is merged with another firm and the debt burden
increases significantly, causing a credit downgrade and lower bond prices.
Article 4.8
Source: Lex column (2013) LBOs and bonds: animal antidote, Financial Times, 26 February.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Article 4.9
Although fund managers aim to ensure investors can buy or sell their fund hold-
ings on any day, there is concern they would be unable to sell enough bonds to meet
redemption requests in a tough market environment, leaving investors stranded.
Source: Dunkley, E. (2014) Watchdog sounds alarm over corporate bond funds, Financial
Times, 29 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Reinvestment risk
This is the risk arising from the need to reinvest money received from a
bond investment. For example, some issuers retain the right to redeem
bonds at their insistence; bonds thus called may then leave investors
struggling to find a replacement investment offering a similar rate of interest.
Another example: coupons received are likely to be reinvested in other bonds,
but the rate of return then available may be lower than when the bond was
first issued.
Call risk
There are three downsides for the lender when a bond agreement allows
the issuer to buy them back from the holder before the normal redemption
date:
1 Uncertainty regarding the cash flow from the investment because it is not
known whether a call will be enacted.
2 Calls are likely to be exercised if interest rates fall, thus the investor faces
reinvestment risk, i.e. buying other bonds at a lower yield.
3 A call provision will limit the capital appreciation potential of the bond
because the price may not rise much above the price at which it could be
called.
Supply risk
A company may issue further bonds of the same type, which could result in an
over-supply in the market and the price falling.
Tax risk
A government might change its tax policy to the detriment of corporate bond
holders.
Sector risk
Investors become unwilling to buy bonds in a certain sector (e.g. those issued
by banks) regardless of the merits of an individual borrower, thus bond prices
fall even for sound issuers.
Political risk
Bond values may be adversely affected by civil unrest, nationalisation of assets,
inflation, government interference in markets, coups or dictatorships.
The process might begin with competing banks offering their services to the
corporate. They will indicate the price/yield at which they think the bonds
can be sold together with the size of their fees. The issuer will consider these
factors along with the bank’s reputation and standing. The bank that wins the
mandate for the issue will be termed the lead underwriter, lead manager or
book-runner. The lead underwriter will then usually team up with a number
of other banks to simultaneously offer the bonds to the market. This syndicate
often comprises banks from many countries. A co-lead manager(s) might be
appointed to help sell the bonds in particular countries, where the lead man-
ager does not have large client bases.
The usual method is the fixed-price re-offer. The investment bank syndicate
agrees a fixed price and a fixed commission. It also agrees the quantity each
member is to take to offer to the market at the agreed price. In this way the lead
manager avoids the problem of some syndicate members selling the bonds at
a low price in the grey market just to shift the bonds (‘dumping’). The grey
market is the buying and selling of bonds before they have officially arrived on
the market – they are traded on investors’ anticipation of their allocation. The
obligation to stick to a fixed price means that the lead manager does not
have to step in to support the price by buying back the bonds. After the first
settlement date in the secondary market the restriction on syndicate members’
selling prices is lifted.
In a bought deal the issuer is offered a package: a fixed price for a fixed quan-
tity bought by the lead manager or managing group (not a syndicate). The
issuer then has a few hours to decide whether to accept. If accepted the lead
manager then either buys the whole issue to distribute to other investors or
sells portions to other banks for distribution to investors – placement of the
bonds. In anticipation of issuer acceptance many of the bonds will usually
have been pre-placed with institutional investors (pension funds, insurance
companies, etc.) before the bid was made. Obviously, bought deals are con-
ducted by lead managers with large capital bases and with high placement
ability; they might be left holding (‘wearing’) the bonds if they cannot find
buyers, thus tying up capital and damaging their reputation for accurately
assessing market demand, pricing and marketing bonds.
Most corporate bonds are underwritten by an investment bank(s) on a firm
commitment basis, meaning that the issuer is guaranteed a certain amount
from the sale. However, some are best-efforts offerings where the bank(s) does
not guarantee a firm price to the issuer, merely agreeing to act as a placing
or distribution agent. A fee will be paid for this service. The downside of
best-efforts issues is that investors are aware that the investment bank(s) has
not committed any of its own funds and so they are usually unwilling to pay a
price as high as they might with a firm fixed-price commitment from the lead
underwriter.
The lead manager (often in cooperation with other syndicate members) will
help the issuer prepare the prospectus to be presented to potential investors,
detailing the issue and explaining the company and its finances. It will also
deal with the legal issues and other documentation, using either an in-house
legal team or an external one.
Fees as a percentage of funds raised for underwriting (agreeing to buy those not
sold to the public) and selling bonds tend to be greater for longer maturities
and for those lower down the credit rating scale, but smaller for large issues
given the economies of scale. Fees will rise if the issue is more exotic (unusual
and/or complex) rather than straight vanilla, but are typically in the range
0.25–0.75% of the par value. The issuer will also have to factor in their own
time and that of their accountants, legal advisers, etc.
When pricing a bond the lead manager often focuses on a benchmark bond
currently trading in the market with the same maturity as the new issue and
uses that as a reference. The new bond might be priced as so-many basis points
of spread over or under the benchmark.
Private placements
In private placements an investment bank(s) uses its contacts to find finan-
cial institutions willing to purchase the whole issue between them, usually
no more than ten in the group. This allows the issuing company to develop a
closer relationship with a tight-knit group of investors, first gaining under-
standing of the business and later communicating progress, perhaps opening
the possibility of raising more at a later date. Private placings also avoid the
cost of obtaining and maintaining a credit rating for publicly traded bonds and
the costs of additional disclosure.
In the US, where this market is very strong, privately placed bonds are un-
registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission, with minimal dis-
closure required, and so can be resold only to large, financially sophisticated
investors; they are therefore not available to retail investors. Most privately
placed bonds are 144a securities, meaning that they are exempt from SEC
registration under Section 144a of the 1990 Securities Law. Private placement
costs much less than a public offering because the issuer does not have to
comply with generally accepted accounting principles and because marketing
to only a handful of investing institutions is cheaper. A detailed prospectus
Article 4.10
Source: Bolger, A. (2014) Thirst for funds lifts appeal of private placements, Financial
Times, 24 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Despite the progress made in Europe, even today European companies often
choose to issue privately placed bonds on the other side of the Atlantic where
there is a well-established clientele, infrastructure, regulation and procedures
– see Article 4.11.
Article 4.11
But a working group led by the International Capital Market Association has
launched a voluntary guide for common market standards and best practices
which it says are essential for the development of a pan-European market.
‘The guide will be a big help in communicating with and within midsized corpor-
ates about an alternative source of finance,’ says Colin Tyler, chief executive of
the Association of Corporate Treasurers. ‘For potential midsized issuers that have
not used private placements before, it will give confidence that there are clear
paths to issuing – it is not venturing into Wild West territory.’
Private placements are medium- to long-term senior debt obligations – in bond or
loan format – issued privately by companies to a small group of investors. The
private placement market typically provides fixed-rate financing of between three
and 15 years, most commonly for seven to 10 years.
With private placement deals providing longer maturities than many bank loans,
this helps to release companies from the burden of refinancing bank debt every
couple of years.
Calum Macphail, head of private placements at M&G Investments, one of the
largest European investors in private placements, says the guide provides com-
panies interested in exploring this market an understanding of the process, who
was involved and information potential investors would require.
‘As the financing landscape changes as banks de-lever, natural sources of longer-
term finance, namely pension funds and institutional investors, are filling this
gap,’ he says. ‘Pension funds are attracted to the characteristics of private place-
ments – strong, stable cash flows and covenant protections similar to a loan.’
In addition to diversification and stronger documentation compared with public
bonds, he says investors will also benefit from an illiquidity premium which could
provide an enhanced yield as well as regular income over the medium to long term.
The popularity of private placements has accelerated since the onset of the finan-
cial crisis, with markets in countries such as France and Germany providing bor-
rowers with a local solution.
ICMA, which represents institutions across the international capital markets, says
demand for private placements is set to increase as the EU’s approximately 200,000
midsized companies look to diversify their sources of funding away from the tradi-
tional bank loan market, and view private placements both as an alternative and
as an intermediate step towards the listed bond markets.
The guide builds on existing practices and documents used in the European bond
and loan markets, especially a charter developed by the Euro PP Working Group, a
French financial industry initiative. It is expected costs will be lowered by promot-
ing the use of recently standardised documentation.
Daniel Godfrey, chief executive of the Investment Association, says common mar-
ket standards for European private placement transactions will remove a signifi-
cant barrier to the development of the private placement market in the UK and
Europe.
➨
‘Our members are major investors in UK businesses and, having worked closely
with members and government on the proposed withholding tax exemption for
privately placed debt in the UK, in December 2014, we were able to announce that
five institutions intend to make investments of around £9bn in private placements
and other direct lending to UK companies,’ he said.
The French and German domestic private placement markets issued approximately
€15bn of debt in 2013 in addition to a further $15.3bn raised by European companies
in the $60bn US private placement market.
Standard & Poor’s estimates €2.7tn of debt will need to be refinanced by midsized
companies between now and 2018, at a time when banks continue to retreat from
long term lending markets.
As well as trade bodies, the pan-European private placement initiative has received
strong support from government officials in the UK and France, as it is closely
aligned with the European Commission’s goal of bringing about a capital markets
union, on which a green paper is expected this week.
Welcoming the guide, Fabio Panetta, deputy governor of the Bank of Italy, said: ‘It
is a useful tool for developing a European private placement market for corporate
debt and, consequently, for broadening and diversifying sources of funding to the
European economy.’
Source: Bolger, A. (2015) Midsized issuers welcome funding scheme, Financial Times,
16 February.
© The Financial Times Limited 2015. All Rights Reserved.
● Pre-launch and launch. The lead manager appoints the trustee or fiscal agent,
the principal paying agent, the other members of the syndicate, and pre-
pares the prospectus and other documents. The lead manager or co-lead
managers will discuss with the issuer and potential investors the specifica-
tions, such as size of issue, coupon and price. As discussion progresses these
will be ‘firmed up’. A book-building public promotion period might span
two weeks (‘pre-selling the bonds’). Within that, a roadshow and a series of
conference calls might take four days with, say, 10 to 100 attendees per
meeting in different cities across the country.
● Announcement day. It is only on the announcement day that the issue is for-
mally announced (a press notification is usual), including the decision on
the maturity and coupon rate or range of coupon rates. The lead manager
formally invites the prospective syndicate members to participate, telling
them the timetable and their obligations. On the pricing day, the price
of the bond relative to par (say £99.85 if the par is £100) is agreed by the
borrower and the syndicate group.
● Offering day/signing day. The bonds are formally offered the day after the
pricing day. The borrower and managing group sign the agreement on the
specifications. The size of the allotments to syndicate members is announced
by the lead manager. Signing usually occurs between two days and one week
before closing and can take place at a meeting or, more frequently these
days, by fax or email.
● Closing. The trust deed or fiscal agency agreement are signed, the bond is
created and investors pay for the bonds they have purchased.
● Listing.For listed bonds the relevant documentation must be delivered to
the listing authority (e.g. in Britain it is the UKLA, part of the FCA) and
the stock exchange.
Auction issue
In an auction issue the cost of management fees is bypassed because the issuer
goes to investors directly asking for price and quantity bids for prospective
bonds with specified maturity and coupon. The disadvantage is that the
expertise of the lead manager and others in the syndicate is forgone with
regard to market knowledge, contacts, reputation, etc. Thus auction issues are
for high-quality, well-known borrowers only.
0.571% to 12%. About two-thirds of Ford’s bonds have the same credit rating,
Baa3 from Moody’s and BBB− from Standard & Poor’s and Fitch, and recent
sales prices vary from $41 to $202.375.
Disney has 26 bonds listed, including its famous Sleeping Beauty bond, a
100-year bond issued in 1993 paying a coupon of 7.55% on par (the yield
to redemption was 4.071% at the time of writing). This bond is continuously
callable and of the initial offering of $300 million, $99 million has been
redeemed. It is rated single-A. According to Morningstar, the investment
research centre, the Ford Motor Co had $7.7 billion of outstanding bonds and
Walt Disney had $13.3 billion in 2014, illustrating how important the bond
markets are for funding their operations.
Many non-US companies issue US$ bonds in both the public debt market and
the private placement market because they are more attractive to investors
than bonds issued in a not-so-strong currency. Increasingly, with globalisation
corporate bonds are issued all over the world, so a UK company might issue
bonds in Japan denominated in yen or dollars because it is transacting business
there.
Asia
Bond issuance in China is booming as corporates tap the markets rather than
automatically source borrowed funds from banks. The big issuers are the state-
owned enterprises, ranging from the oil company Sinopec to China National
Nuclear. But there are many private companies tapping into markets offering
good interest rates. Alongside the greater issuance has been the growth in sec-
ondary market trading with institutions and retail investors enthusiastic about
adding fixed-income securities to their portfolios in what is now a reasonably
liquid market. China is beginning to realise the importance of overseas invest-
ment in its domestic markets, and has paved the way for renminbi-qualified
foreign institutional investors (RQFIIs) to invest their foreign-held renminbi in
Chinese corporate (and government) bonds.
Domestic pension funds and other institutions in many Asian countries are
keen to obtain assets denominated in their own currencies and so welcome
further growth of their corporate bond markets – see Article 4.12. Pension
funds are particularly interested in bonds of a longer maturity providing a
better match to their pension liabilities than short-maturity issues. From
the companies’ perspective, they benefit from the stability that comes with
locking in fixed-rate money for a decade or more.
Article 4.12
Source: Flood, C. (2014) Asian credit markets expand at record pace, Financial Times,
27 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Bond indices
A bond index provides information, such as price movements and returns over
a period for a particular category of bond, e.g. an average for 100 or so corpor-
ate bonds denominated in euros or a few dozen inflation-linked bonds across
the world. Among other uses they allow investors to compare their bond port-
folio performance against a benchmark. The main indices are managed by
Markit (the iBoxx indices) and FTSE. Leading investment banks supply bid and
ask (offer) prices through the trading day to these organisations, which then
compile the indices.
In Table 4.2, an example of the bond indices table from the Financial Times, the
first column shows whether the bonds are denominated in sterling, dollars or
euros, the second column shows the number of bonds included in the index.
The final column does not indicate the yield to maturity but the return to an
investor who bought one year ago, including capital gains and losses, if they
sold now. These index suppliers produce many more indices than those shown
in Table 4.2 – see www.markit.com and www.ftse.co.uk for the other indices
and much more analytical data, such as average yield and duration.
BOND INDICES
M04_ARNO1799_01_SE_C04.indd 146
Index Day’s Month’s Year Return Return
change change change 1 month 1 year
FTSE Jul 8
Sterling Corporate (£) 66 108.63 0.45 –0.05 1.54 0.35 6.72
Euro Corporate (€) 304 109.28 0.12 0.39 3.08 0.64 6.59
Euro Emerging Mkts (€) 7 96.09 0.13 0.14 2.70 0.50 7.83
Eurozone Gov’t Bond 260 109.94 0.07 0.24 5.58 0.50 9.18
7/7/15 8:47 AM
CHAPTER 5
CREDIT RATINGS
FOR BONDS
Time was when a country’s financial credibility was measured by the amount
of gold in its vaults. Modern life has overtaken precious metal’s capacity to
underpin the credit standing of countries, or that of companies or individuals.
Nowadays we often rely on some independent outside body to be an
‘impartial’ judge of each borrower’s standing, and so the credit rating industry
was established.
Borrowers pay to have their bonds rated by the CRAs. Standard & Poor’s,
Moody’s and Fitch Ratings are the three most important credit rating com-
panies, but there are also many less well-known CRAs in North America (e.g.
Kroll Bond Rating Agency, DBRS and Morningstar) and in other countries,
including Dagong from China.
Standard & Poor’s was founded in 1860 by Henry Varnum Poor to give infor-
mation about US railroad companies, but did not assign ratings to corporate
bonds until 1922. Moody’s was established in 1900 by John Moody to give
statistics on US bonds and shares, providing its first credit rating in 1909. Fitch
was founded in 1913 by John Knowles Fitch to provide financial statistics to
help the US investment industry and began rating in 1924. Dagong is a relative
newcomer, founded in 1994.
The ratings that CRAs give to countries, sovereign ratings, can vary – see
Table 5.2. A notch is a one-stage move on the rating scale, e.g. moving from
A− to BBB+. The UK lost its AAA rating with some of the CRAs in 2013, due to
concern about future financial stability. S&P downgraded the US to AA+ in
2011 after the prolonged political wranglings over the US government debt
level, and the Chinese agency, Dagong, caused controversy by downgrading
the US rating by several notches, from AAA to A−, in 2013 when the US
government could not agree on its financial policy (again, arguments in
Congress over the debt ceiling) and came dangerously close to being unable
to meet the payments due on its bonds. The Chinese are concerned about
the US debt burden as they are the biggest holders of US Treasury securities, at
$1.3 trillion:
For a long time the U.S. government maintains its solvency by repaying
its old debts through raising new debts, which constantly aggravates the
vulnerability of the federal government’s solvency. Hence the government
is still approaching the verge of default crisis, a situation that cannot be
substantially alleviated in the foreseeable future.
Table 5.1 Credit rating systems for long-term debt (more than one year)
Investment grade
Highest credit
Aaa AAA AAA Highest quality, minimal credit risk AAA
quality
A1 A+ A+
A+
High credit
A2 A A Upper medium grade, low credit risk A
quality
A−
A3 A− A−
B1 B+ B+
B+
Relatively low
B2 B B Speculative, high credit risk B
credit quality
B–
B3 B− B−
Low credit
Caa CCC+ Poor standing, very high credit risk CCC
quality
When the rating agencies disagree we have a split rating – as you can see, this
occurs quite often. The rating and re-rating of bonds is followed with great
interest by borrowers and lenders and can give rise to some heated argument.
Italians were very upset in 2014 when S&P was accused of taking insufficient
account of the country’s qualities – see Article 5.1.
Article 5.1
Source: Foley, S. and Dinmore, G. (2014) Italy accuses S&P of not getting ‘la dolce vita’,
Financial Times, 4 February.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
The rating agencies are constantly reviewing countries to detect reasons for
thinking that default risk has improved or deteriorated. As Article 5.2 shows, in
the years following the financial crisis there were some dramatic changes, with
Europe declining and developing countries prospering.
Article 5.2
before the crisis that a third would be on negative outlook, you would have right-
fully thought that was pretty bad, but it has stabilised. Relative to where we were,
things have certainly improved.’
Any turnround in European credit ratings will be slow, however. Mr Kraemer at
S&P points out that when Sweden and Finland lost their triple A status in the early
1990s, it was a decade before it was regained.
Similarly, France and the UK are unlikely to see a quick return to triple A status,
warns Mr McCormack. ‘We have suggested that debt ratios need to come down in
a more meaningful way – there has to be a track record of fiscal adjustment.’
Ratings in emerging markets over the past year have improved in Asia, central and
eastern Europe and the Caribbean. But African, Middle East and Latin American
Source: Atkins, R. and Fray, K. (2014) Turning point for European debt ratings, Financial
Times, 31 March.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
While corporate borrowers’ credit ratings are generally of great concern to them,
because those with lower ratings tend to have higher costs, some companies
are fairly sanguine, particularly if they regard the CRAs as using unreasonable
methods and they can persuade finance providers of their point of view – see
Article 5.3 for the example of Rio Tinto.
Article 5.3
Source: Wilson, J. and Hume, N. (2013) Rio Tinto’s Sam Walsh questions credit rating
groups’ relevance, Financial Times, 11 December.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Article 5.4
option but to buy Microsoft products. The consumer profile for the companies is
slightly different.’
He adds: ‘Apple’s credit profile is tied to the company’s ability to keep up with
innovations and maintain its unique corporate culture. The rapid rise and fall of
new products demonstrates these sectors are particularly prone to transforma-
tional changes that could lead to shifts in market leadership.’
Fitch said the company would likely fall in the high single ‘A’ rating category,
based on the inherent business risk of consumer-centric hardware companies.
‘Consumer product companies such as Sony, Nokia, and Motorola Mobility have
proven the risks related to ever-changing consumer tastes, low switching costs,
and a highly competitive environment,’ said James Rizzo at Fitch. ‘Each has his-
torically had a dominant market position and strong financial metrics, only to
falter over a relatively short period of time.’
‘Apple’s better diversification and the stickiness of its iTunes ecosystem clearly
make it a stronger credit that would likely be at the highest end of the ‘A’ category,’
said Mr Rizzo.
While there is a one notch difference in ratings between Apple and Microsoft,
investors appear less discerning based on the pricing of recent bond issues by both
companies. Apple’s blockbuster bond issue priced very close to where Microsoft’s
much smaller $1.95bn offering of five-, 10-, and 30-year debt was sold last week.
While Microsoft sold $1bn of 10-year debt at 70 basis points over Treasury yields,
Apple’s $5.5bn issue arrived at 75 bps over benchmark government debt. There was
a difference of 10 basis points in pricing between their 30-year bonds.
Source: Mackenzie, M. and Rodrigues, V. (2013) Microsoft beats Apple in the credit ratings
league, Financial Times, 1 May.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
● plans for further cash raising, equity or bonds; how receptive might the
markets be; will the changes unbalance the capital structure, creating risk?
● how sensible the dividend policy is
● any worries over the legal structure of the group, such as subsidiaries in
overseas companies borrowing, government controls on moving money
across borders
● contingent liabilities, e.g. pensions, legal liabilities, environmental
● taxation powers
● contingent liabilities
As well as specific bond ratings the CRAs provide issuer ratings to firms and
other organisations, which are assessments of the creditworthiness of the
whole entity. The vast majority of ratings, however, apply to a particular
security issue by the firm. Ratings on some securities may have a higher rating
than the issuing company as a whole because the specific security is secured on
a very reliable asset.
If a bond does not have a rating, it could simply mean that the borrower
has chosen not to pay for one, rather than implying anything untoward or
sinister. Indeed, some bonds are sold on a name recognition basis, that is, the
issuer has such a good reputation with lenders accepting that their financial
standing is such that there is a very low likelihood of default and they do not
require a formal credit rating. However, ‘unrated’ is often used to mean poorer
default risk.
Article 5.5
Other prominent unrated deals so far this year include Sodexo, the French caterer,
which borrowed $1.1bn in January, ProSiebenSat, the German broadcaster, which
borrowed $828m in April, and CGG, an Irish support services group, which raised
$750m in March.
However, unrated bond issues remain relatively rare, given many investors are
limited to buying certain grades, and most prefer the transparency that a rating
confers. They have accounted for about 10% of the European corporate bond
market in recent years.
Unrated bonds also tend to be smaller and less liquid than rated debt. Half such
bonds issued over the past three years were for less than $250m. The companies
therefore have to pay lenders a premium to the yields at which they would
normally expect to issue.
But Rupert Lewis, a debt syndicate banker at BNP Paribas, says that the extra
cost of issuing unrated debt has come down over the last couple of years from
approximately 100 basis points to 50bp – or potentially less, depending on the
company.
‘It’s a horses for courses market,’ he says. ‘They tend to be companies that don’t
issue that often and therefore don’t want to go through the workload and costs of
getting and maintaining a credit rating for infrequent borrowing. Without a rating
they don’t go in indices, so a large amount of investors cannot buy, but despite that
the cost has definitely come down.’
Jean-Marc Mercier, global head of debt syndicate at HSBC, says: ‘A lot of companies
don’t want to take on the cost, work and management time involved with obtaining
a rating – particularly family-controlled companies.’
However, unrated bonds have also been issued by large companies such as SAP, the
German software group, which has borrowed several billions of euros via such
bonds. Household names that have used the market and subsequently acquired
ratings include the Dutch brewer Heineken and Thomas Cook, the UK travel group.
The rating agency Fitch says some household names have been able to take
advantage of their higher profiles among retail investors to issue unrated bonds.
These include Skanska, the Swedish engineering group; Finnair in Finland; Air
France-KLM; and Sixt, the German-based car rental group.
Mike Dunning at Fitch says: ‘UK companies can also access the US private
placement market to raise funds on an unrated basis – which is easier than going
through the full bond rating process.’
The agency says that a sizeable proportion of the larger issues of unrated bonds
display credit profiles that could be classified as investment, or near-investment
grade. This is in spite of a significant level of opportunistic issuance by smaller,
non-eurozone domiciled corporates.
‘The European institutional bond market is generally receptive to the first, oppor-
tunistic, unrated bond from a new issuer, but increasingly looks for a rating if
repeat visits, particularly for smaller issuers, are contemplated,’ says Tom
Chruszcz, an analyst with Fitch.
➨
Source: Bolger, A. and Wigglesworth, R. (2014) ‘Dash for trash’ lifts unrated debt sales,
Financial Times, 19 May.
© The Financial times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
A rating decision generally takes a few weeks and is made by a rating committee
assessing the evidence, rather than by an individual. The committee notifies
the issuer of the rating and the rationale behind it.
The agencies are also available to carry out credit analysis as a service to lenders.
They thus produce unsolicited company analysis and credit ratings without
necessarily gaining the cooperation of the issuing company (or country).
Post-rating
There is generally a high degree of ongoing interaction between a corporate
and its CRA following bond issuance; the relationship is akin to that between
a company and its longstanding bank, with a high degree of transparency.
In addition to the agency gleaning information through dialogue with the
company it will continue to scan publicly available sources. Its monitoring
(ratings review) in the months and years following is focused on develop-
ments that could alter the original rating. Issues might arise that lead to
an upgrade or a downgrade. These are called rating actions. A press release
disseminates a change of rating.
The CRAs not only give countries/companies/bonds a credit rating, they also
give an outlook, an assessment of what the credit rating is likely to be in the
future over the intermediate to longer term: ‘positive’ indicates that the rating
might be raised, ‘stable’ means not likely to change, ‘negative’ means it may
be lowered, ‘developing’ means it may be raised or lowered. This can be
influenced by many things, such as political unrest (e.g. Egypt), natural
disasters (e.g. earthquake in Japan and New Zealand) or economic instability
(e.g. Ireland, Spain, Greece and Portugal in 2010–2012). But note, outlooks are
not necessarily a precursor to ratings changes, just possibilities.
Ranking
In the event of financial failure of a company (liquidation/bankruptcy), the
ranking (‘priority’) order for bonds is:
1 Senior secured debt holders will be paid first. An example of this would be a
mortgage loan secured on the mortgaged asset.
2 Senior unsecured debt is paid next, if any money is left. This is debt consist-
ing of loans which are not secured on an asset(s), but it is stated in the trust
deed that they will be near the front of the queue for payouts of annual
coupons and of proceeds from liquidation. After this group has been paid
the subordinated bond holders may receive nothing.
3 Senior subordinated debt – high-yield or junk bonds, secured or unsecured.
4 Subordinated debt is the last type of debt to be paid out after all other
creditors.
The situation becomes more complicated when group companies are forced
into liquidation. For example, it is possible for senior debt issued by the
holding company to be subordinated to debt issued by a subsidiary (senior or
junior) if the subsidiary’s lenders have legal access to assets of the subsidiary.
The variety of insolvency regimes across Europe, with different rules on bond
priorities following insolvency, is thought to have inhibited bond market
growth relative to that in the single system across the US – see Article 5.6.
Article 5.6
Michael Dakin, a partner at the law firm Clifford Chance, likens the recent sell-off
of high-yield bonds to ‘blowing the froth off the cappuccino’. But he predicts a
‘flood’ of selling when the currently ‘ludicrously low’ level of company defaults
moves back closer to its historic average.
One potential problem is that US investors are used to dealing with corporate re-
organisations conducted under the Chapter 11 procedure, which applies in all
states, and is subject to the US bankruptcy code, providing for valuations of the
debtor’s assets and ranking of competing claims.
Source: Bolger, A. (2014) Europe looks for common default process, Financial Times,
11 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Bond credit ratings are available direct from rating agency websites,
www.standardandpoors.com, www.moodys.com, and www.fitchratings.com.
Note the higher variation in the price, yield and spread of the high-yield
bonds, compared with investment-grade bonds.
Aug 7 Red date Coupon Ratings Bid price Bid yield Day’s chge Mth’s chge Spread vs
yield yield Govts
S* M* F*
US $
BNP Paribas 06/15 4.80 BBB+ Baa2 A 103.28 0.98 0.03 –1.13 0.89
M05_ARNO1799_01_SE_C05.indd 166
GE Capital 01/16 5.00 AA+ A1 0 106.09 0.64 –0.02 –0.08 0.55
Erste Euro Lux 02/16 5.00 A– 0 0 104.24 2.11 –0.03 –0.17 1.65
Credit Suisse USA 03/16 5.38 A A1 A 107.24 0.89 – –0.05 0.28
SPI E&G Aust 09/16 5.75 A– A3 A– 107.50 2.07 –0.04 –0.08 1.63
Abu Dhabi Nt En 10/17 6.17 A– A3 0 113.54 1.79 0.01 –0.05 0.73
Swire Pacific 04/18 6.25 A– A3 A– 114.04 2.26 –0.07 –0.06 1.38
PART 2 BOND MARKETS
7/7/15 8:48 AM
Table 5.4 High-yield and emerging market bonds, 7 August 2014
Aug 7 Red date Coupon Ratings Bid price Bid yield Day’s Mth’s Spread
chge yield chge yield vs US
S* M* F*
M05_ARNO1799_01_SE_C05.indd 167
High Yield US$
Bertin 10/16 10.25 BB Ba3 0 113.06 3.85 0.03 0.14 3.26
Emerging US$
Bulgaria 01/15 8.25 BBB– Baa2 BBB– 102.75 1.72 0.68 0.39 1.68
Peru 02/15 9.88 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 104.31 0.92 0.00 –0.37 0.87
Brazil 03/15 7.88 BBB– Baa2 BBB 103.78 1.20 –0.03 –0.10 1.16
Mexico 09/16 11.38 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 121.25 1.12 – 0.27 0.66
Philippines 01/19 9.88 BBB Baa3 BBB– 131.48 2.34 –0.05 –0.04 0.72
Brazil 01/20 12.75 BBB– Baa2 BBB 148.20 3.05 0.17 0.12 1.41
Colombia 02/20 11.75 BBB Baa2 BBB 143.64 3.11 0.03 0.06 1.51
Russia 03/30 7.50 BBB– Baa1 BBB 111.50 4.98 0.25 0.72 3.35
Mexico 08/31 8.30 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 147.38 4.33 –0.03 –0.13 1.91
Indonesia 02/37 6.63 BB+ Baa3 BBB– 112.88 5.61 0.19 –0.15 2.37
Emerging Euro
Brazil 02/15 7.38 BBB– Baa2 BBB 103.05 0.95 –0.25 0.06 0.92
Poland 02/16 3.63 A– A2 A– 104.73 0.40 –0.01 0.11 0.40
Turkey 03/16 5.00 NR Baa3 BBB– 105.50 1.39 0.04 –0.11 1.38
Mexico 02/20 5.50 BBB+ A3 BBB+ 120.85 1.53 0.02 –0.04 1.14
5 CREDIT RATINGS FOR BONDS
US $ denominated bonds NY close; all other London close. S* – Standard & Poor’s, M* – Moody’s, F* – Fitch.
Source: Thomson Reuters
167
7/7/15 8:48 AM
168 PART 2 BOND MARKETS
Crisis of confidence
CRAs advance the argument that their ratings are mere opinions and are thus
protected under free speech laws. They have no contract with the investing
institutions, nor do they have a fiduciary duty to them, so say the agencies.
Thus they can publish an opinion without being liable for mistakes or mislead-
ing statements.
There have been some serious legal challenges to the CRAs’ claim that
an ‘opinion’ should not lead to claims of carelessness or negligence if their
judgement turns out to be wrong. Article 5.7 shows the state of the law in
Australia, which will probably have an impact on other jurisdictions: CRAs
have a duty of care to investors, not just their paymasters, the issuers.
Article 5.7
The ruling by the Federal Court of Australia in a case that also involved ABN Amro,
which is now owned by Royal Bank of Scotland, paves the way for similar court actions
elsewhere from investors who lost billions of dollars during the financial crisis.
John Ahern, a partner at law firm Jones Day, said the judgment augured ill for
rating agencies. ‘The position that the court took is logically the conclusion that
courts in other jurisdictions could arrive at, given [there is] a good deal of similar-
ity in the principles of negligence – at least in common law jurisdictions.’
S&P originally lost the Australian case in November 2012, when the court issued a
scathing ruling that the rating agency was ‘misleading’ and ‘deceptive’ when it
awarded a AAA credit rating to a complex debt instrument.
The judgment was the first time a court found a credit-rating agency liable for
losses incurred by investors on financial products, which it had erroneously
awarded a gilt-edged credit rating. It also said that rating agencies have a duty of
care to investors.
The court found that the notes were sold to local councils in Australia on the basis
that the AAA rating was based on reasonable grounds, and as the result of an exer-
cise in reasonable care and skill, while neither was true.
‘S&P also knew them not to be true when they were made,’ concluded the original
ruling.
Local councils lost tens of millions of dollars on the collateralised debt instruments
when the financial crisis struck.
ABN AMRO, which created the toxic products, and Local Government Financial
Services, which sold them to councils, also engaged in misleading and deceptive
conduct, according to the original court judgment.
The dismissal of the appeal by Judge Peter Jacobson is a setback for S&P, which is
fighting multiple legal actions in the US and Europe related to claims it issued
misleading credit ratings before the 2008 financial crisis.
Source: Smyth, J. and Fleming, S. (2014) S&P loses Australia appeal over misleading
investors, Financial Times, 6 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Regulators around the world have tried to keep closer tabs on the CRAs in
recent years. The European Union set up a new regulator, the European
Securities and Markets Authority, in part to scrutinise the CRAs’ conduct.
The Federal Reserve and the Securities and Exchange Commission in the US
tightened regulation, e.g. by prohibiting the agencies from also advising the
issuers (for a fee) on how to structure a bond issue to obtain a favourable rating.
The fear was that the CRAs would lower standards in order to generate business
for their consultancy wing. In addition, the agency’s fee negotiator (for the
rating exercise) has to be someone who is not involved in the rating assess-
ment. Also, more disclosure on how ratings are determined, and disclosure of
historical ratings performance, are required. One of the tools regulators are
Article 5.8
In the aftermath of the crisis, when subprime mortgage securitisations turned out
to be anything but the pristine investments that their triple-A credit ratings
implied, regulators rushed to reform the agencies hired to evaluate such securities.
At the top of their list was encouraging the agencies to be more vocal about their
competitors’ ratings by publishing their own unsolicited opinions. To do so, they
created a special website for issuers to share deal data, so that competing agencies
could evaluate securitised products they were not formally hired to rate.
The idea was to help expose spurious ratings and encourage smaller agencies that
might help challenge the dominance of ‘the big three’ – Fitch Ratings, Moody’s and
Standard & Poor’s.
Fitch’s criticism of Wells Fargo Commercial Mortgage Trust 2014-Tish, which
includes a $210m loan secured by the Westin Hotel, is the most recent example of
a rating agency publishing an unsolicited commentary. ‘Fitch believes a number
of recently issued large loan transactions have debt levels that are inconsistent
with the ratings assigned,’ the agency’s analysts wrote in the commentary.
Larger credit rating agencies, in particular Fitch, have been among the most
prolific when it comes to issuing unsolicited opinions. Smaller groups such as Kroll
and Morningstar have not published any unsolicited ratings or commentaries,
according to their respective spokespeople.
‘We believe that [publishing unsolicited commentaries] will enhance our credibility
with investors and they will encourage issuers to use Fitch more frequently,’ says
Kevin Duignan, global head of securitisation and covered bonds at Fitch. ‘We think
that’s healthy.’
But, while the competition between rating agencies to issue unsolicited opinions
has heated up, it appears to have had little impact on the behaviour of investors
or issuers, say market participants. ‘They [the rating agencies] have been sidelined
by US regulation so they could be just fighting each other in a shrinking market.
I would expect some laundry cleaning in public,’ said a securitisation banker.
Indeed, there are rumblings of a return of ratings shopping – the pre-crisis practice
where issuers would sound out rating agencies for their initial feedback on a deal,
and then hire the agency that offered the best possible designation.
When Moody’s criticised a residential mortgage-backed security in 2011, for
instance, the company that created the deal simply decided to use Fitch’s ratings
instead. ‘The sponsor disagreed with Moody’s preliminary assessment of the risks
attributable to the mortgage loans,’ the prospectus for the deal read.
Fitch says it was asked to provide initial feedback on the CMBS backed by the
Westin loan and determined that it would have rated the safest slice of the deal AA,
and would not have rated some of the riskier pieces of the deal at all. S&P and
Morningstar rated the top slice of the deal triple-A. Says Mr Duignan: ‘Unsolicited
commentaries may not be the best solution but they are a far better solution than
remaining silent.’
Source: Alloway, T. and Thompson, C. (2014) Doubts raised over rating agency reform,
Financial Times, 11 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
A major debate is whether the investing institutions rather than the borrowers
should pay for ratings. After all, they would be the beneficiaries of a more
robust examination of the likelihood of default without the, supposed, taint-
ing of the potential conflict of interest arising from the examinee paying – a
case of he who pays the piper calling the tune, it is alleged. The CRAs retort that
they live and die by their reputations; they cannot be seen to be anything less
than objective and impartial. Also, with lenders paying, they might decide
not to publicise the rating they pay for; lack of public information could result
in distortion of trading in the market or duplication of rating assessments.
Egan-Jones is an example of a CRA paid by bond investors, but remains a
minnow, with 95–97% of ratings conducted by S&P, Moody’s or Fitch. Despite
this dominance, new rating agencies are springing up to challenge the big
three – see Article 5.9.
Article 5.9
Source: Jenkins, P. (2013) Scope Ratings aims to shake up hegemony, Financial Times,
15 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
AAA 0 0 0 0 0 0
AA+ 0 0 0 0 0 0
AA 0 0 0.11 0.28 0.46 0.36
AA− 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.21
A+ 0 0.1 0.2 0.27 0.4 0.89
A 0.06 0.25 0.45 0.69 0.94 2.05
A− 0.17 0.31 0.46 0.57 0.74 2.53
BBB+ 0.13 0.28 0.51 0.82 1.16 2.39
BBB 0.09 0.64 1.29 1.97 2.58 4.79
BBB− 0.39 1.14 1.89 2.66 3.6 7.54
BB+ 0.92 2.62 4.17 5.71 7.13 10.15
BB 0.79 2.84 4.55 6.36 7.69 13.78
BB− 1.59 2.6 4.08 5.08 6.01 9.19
B+ 1.01 3.65 6.08 7.83 9.04 10.12
B 2.28 5.11 8.2 11.52 14.24 13.97
B− 2.63 4.92 6.16 7.42 9.19 10.19
CCC to C 23.51 31.48 34.96 37.01 39.58 39.54
Investment grade 0.11 0.35 0.61 0.88 1.17 2.27
Speculative grade 2.88 5.33 7.38 9.16 10.7 13.38
All corporate finance 0.73 1.43 2.04 2.59 3.07 4.07
Source: Data from Fitch – Credit Market Research Report
www.fitchratings.com/web_content/nrsro/nav/NRSRO_Exhibit-1.pdf
default rates between the ratings. After five years only 0.46% of AA bonds had
defaulted, whereas 14.24% of B bonds had defaulted.
1
Hickman, W.B. (1958) ‘Corporate bond quality and investor experience’, National Bureau
of Economic Research, 14, Princeton.
Article 6.1
Heavy buying has pushed down the average yield on triple C rated bonds to 7.75%
from 9.80% a year ago, significantly cutting the compensation that investors
receive for the higher risk of default.
Michael Collins, a senior investment officer for Prudential Fixed Income, said the
risk-return equation involving very low rated bonds is now ‘asymmetric’.
‘Investors are not being fully compensated for holding some of these bonds.’
The demand for yield has become the big driver of investor behaviour as they
downplay high valuations for junk bonds.
The gamble for investors is that as long as the Fed keeps on trying to suppress
interest rates, and as long as corporate default rates – currently 2.3% per year –
remain below historical norms, the prospect of losses is limited.
But the risks are twofold: a general rise in rates could cause investors to abandon
risky overpriced assets, while weaker economic growth or falling lending stand-
ards could cause a spike in defaults.
‘Easy money has pushed investors to take more and more risk,’ said Sabur Moini,
a high-yield bond portfolio manager at Payden & Rygel.
‘A severe downturn in the US economy and a freeze in the high-yield market is a
potential big risk. But investors can make the argument that, from a perspective
on margins and cash flow, the average company is healthier now than it was five
years ago.’
Total returns on this tier of the junk bond market have been higher than nearly all
fixed-income asset classes this year and now stand at 11.6%, according to Barclays
data.
That compares with returns of 5.9% on junk bonds as a whole and a negative return
of 2.2% on investment grade corporate debt.
While top tier corporate bonds are rated on the basis of an investor being repaid
their principle with interest, the assumption behind junk debt is that the company
could at some point default on its obligations.
Source: Rodrigues, V. (2013) Triple C bond sales hit record high, Financial Times,
15 November.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
One of the major attractions of this form of finance for the investor is that it
often comes with equity warrants or share options attached, which can be
used to obtain shares in the firm – this is known as an equity kicker. These
may be triggered by an event taking place, such as the firm joining the stock
market. They give the right but not the obligation to buy shares at a fixed price
in the future. If this is at, say, £1 per share and the firm performs well, resulting
in the share rising to, say, £5, the warrant or option holders can make high
returns.
Bonds with high-risk and high-return characteristics may well have started as
apparently safe investments but have now become more risky (fallen angels)
– see Article 6.2 for an example – or they may be bonds issued specifically
to provide higher-risk financial instruments for investors who are looking
for a higher return and are willing to accept the accompanying higher risk
(original-issue high-yield bonds). This latter type began its rise to promin-
ence in the US in the 1980s and is now a market with more than $130 billion
issued per year. The rise of the US junk bond market meant that no business was
safe from the threat of takeover, however large – see Box 6.1 on Michael
Milken.
Article 6.2
Source: Thompson. J. (2014) Moody’s cuts Sony rating to junk, Financial Times, 27 January.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Box 6.1
At the investment banking firm Drexel Burnham Lambert, Milken was able to
persuade a large body of institutional investors to supply finance to the junk bond
market as well as provide a service to corporations wishing to grow through the
use of junk bonds. Small firms were able to raise billions of dollars to take over large
US corporations. Many of these issuers of junk bonds had debt ratios of 90% and
above – for every $1 of share capital, $9 was borrowed. These gearing levels con-
cerned many in the financial markets. It was thought that companies were pushing
their luck too far and indeed many did collapse under the weight of their debt.
The market was dealt a particularly severe blow when Michael Milken was convicted,
sent to jail and ordered to pay $600 million in fines. Drexel was also convicted,
paid $650 million in fines and filed for bankruptcy in 1990.
The junk bond market was in a sorry state in the early 1990s, with high levels of
default and few new issues. However, it did not take long for the market to recover.
Senior lenders to a firm (e.g. banks and bond holders) usually impose limits on
the senior debt to equity ratio. However, subordinated debt might be accept-
able to senior bond holders and equity holders alike. Thus, junk bonds are a
form of finance that permits the firm to move beyond what is normally consid-
ered an acceptable debt:equity ratio (financial gearing, leverage levels). This
might be useful for rapid company expansion.
Junk bond borrowing usually leads to high debt levels, resulting in a high
fixed-cost imposition on the firm. This can be a dangerous way of financing
expansion and therefore the use of these types of finance has been criticised.
Yet some commentators have praised the way in which high gearing and large
annual interest payments have focused the minds of managers and engen-
dered extraordinary performance. Also, without this finance, many takeovers,
buyouts and financial restructurings could not take place.
1
For equity valuation you could consult Arnold, G. (2014) The Financial Times Guide to
Investing, 3rd edition, or, for more depth, the university textbook, Arnold, G. (2013)
Corporate Financial Management, 5th edition.
As a result high-yield bonds are, in general, far more volatile than investment-
grade bonds, going up and down depending on expectations concerning the
company’s survival, strength and profitability. In 2009, for example, investors
were very risk averse, requiring yields of more than 20% for a typical euro
high-yield bond; in 2014 they lent ‘high-yield’ for less than a 5% return per
year, perceiving company business risk to be relatively low, lured by low recent
default rates and factoring in low inflation expectations.
Article 6.3
so there is a “lower for longer” feeling about interest rates. Where is the place in
the world where you least expect interest rates to rise? It has got to be Europe.’
The high-yield market is also being driven by more fundamental shifts, such as
the need for European corporates to tap the bond markets for finance as capital-
constrained banks shrink their balance sheets by refusing to renew loans to
traditional customers.
Fraser Lundie, of Hermes Credit’s global high-yield bond fund, says 33% of
European high-yield bonds have come over the past year from companies that were
first-time issuers, whereas in the US the comparable figure was 5%.
‘It shows you where the US market is, and where the European market is going,’ he
says.
Mitch Reznick, at Hermes Credit, says that the size of the European high-yield
sector has trebled since 2008. The sector has also been boosted by ‘fallen angels’ –
companies that have slipped below investment grade – and a recent influx of small
companies.
Moody’s, the rating agency, says there has also been a flurry of small companies
issuing high-yield bonds for the first time, with six companies, each with core
annual earnings (earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation) of
less than $50m, raising a total of about $2bn.
Moody’s adds: ‘It is encouraging to see the success of these small companies in
issuing bonds at the bottom of the ratings spectrum. However, it remains to be seen
if this is a temporary consequence of investors’ search for yield, that will diminish
as interest rates rise.’
Increasingly, corporates are borrowing more, for longer and cheaper, which can
often mean poor value for the bond investor on the other side of that trade.
Paul Smith, corporate bond fund manager at Premier Asset Management, believes
that ‘For corporate issuers this can be an opportunity to lock in fixed-rate, long-
term capital before rates start to rise . . . which can often mean poor value for the
bond investor on the other side of that trade, although defaults will remain low for
the near-term.’
Ms Johnson sees potential dangers in bonds rated BB or Ba1 – the top end of the
high-yield market.
‘BB looks overbought, since it has been backed by investors who are not really high-
yield people, and could exit quickly. But single B and CCC bonds still offer 9% yields.
You’ve got to do your homework, but selectively there are still good opportunities.’
At Hermes, Mr Lundie argues that any shift in sentiment that spooks investors in
BB-rated bonds will also hit lower-rated issues. Part of his strategy is to focus on
bonds that have been issued in the past 12 months and now trade below face value.
He says: ‘High-yield bonds usually offer change-of-control put options that allow
investors to redeem at more than face value. This “optionality” further improves
the potential for returns from investing in bonds below face value.’
Source: Bolger, A. (2013) European bonds hit a sweet spot, Financial Times, 31 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
For bonds higher up the rating ladder the normal covenants are often put in
place to provide early warning signs of distress or threats to the collateral back-
ing, for example:
● the property assets of the issuer must remain greater than the debt
If these are breached the lenders can request cash or a debt restructuring, where
they gain a powerful negotiating position. Covenant light legal structures
eliminate many of these safeguards. A further erosion of the lender’s position
is the shrinkage of the call protection: while there is typically a six-year non-
call period on standard bonds, this can be reduced to three years or less on
covenant light bonds. Critics point out that the absence of key covenants
makes them dangerous for the lenders – the lack of meaningful covenants
results in prudence going out of the window – see Article 6.4.
Companies have also increasingly been making use of payment in kind (PIK)
toggle notes where payments due to lenders can, at the option of the issuer, be
rolled over into a further debt; lenders can be paid with more debt (more PIK
toggle notes or other payments in kind such as equity) rather than cash. The
interest paid in additional notes is set at a higher rate than the cash interest
rate. During boom times for bonds when lenders are searching for higher yield,
which usually happens following a period of subdued default levels, these
instruments become a popular way for companies to finance leveraged buy-
outs. This exuberance was present in the run-up to the 2008 crisis and again in
Article 6.4
A group of banks including Goldman Sachs and Nomura have agreed to lend nearly
€1bn to the private equity-backed company without requesting the typical creditor
protections attached to highly indebted borrowers. It is one of the largest ‘covenant
light’ financings arranged for a European company this year.
The loan package, which the banks are marketing on both sides of the Atlantic,
highlights the way that credit markets have become more accommodating of
European companies, as institutional investors snap up riskier debt securities and
abandon protective clauses in their hunt for yields.
But volumes are also picking up in the region. Nearly €8bn in euro-denominated
loans of this type were issued last year. Dollar-denominated covenant light loans to
US and European companies reached a record $260bn in 2013, or 57% of the total
volume, and 69% more than in 2007.
‘Covenants are being dropped, lenders’ arranging fees are going down, interest
margins are going down, the amount of debt you can borrow is going up – it’s a
great time to be a borrower,’ says William Allen, a partner at Marlborough,
London-based debt adviser. ‘There simply isn’t enough paper to satisfy investors’
demand and European investors wanting to invest in European loans are having to
accept increasingly loose terms.’
Ceva’s financing, which will comprise a euro tranche and a dollar tranche, has
features that became common at the peak of the credit bubble in 2007. The com-
pany, which has taken the unusual step of issuing a new financing before starting
a competitive process to sell a stake, will not have to comply with debt-to-earning
ratios every quarter during the entire seven-year maturity of the loan.
It will not have to pay down any principal amount before the very end, and will be
able to roll over interest payments into debt instead of paying them for about a
quarter of the package (in a so-called ‘payment in kind’ debt). ‘It’s a dream for
Ceva,’ a person close to the deal said.
It’s not a dream for the debt holders, however, according to Jon Moulton, the
British veteran private equity executive. ‘Cov-lites are pretty dangerous pieces of
paper for those who advance the loan.’
➨
Ceva’s creditors will not be able to request a debt restructuring or a cash injection
from the company’s shareholders in case its creditworthiness deteriorates. This is
despite the fact that Ceva’s total debt will equal up to 7.5 times its earnings before
interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation, a level reminiscent of the leveraged
buyout boom.
Buoyant credit markets are also translating into higher amounts of debt in LBOs,
which have increased in Europe and in the US to near the 2007 all time highs of six
times ebitda on average, according to S&P.
While the Bank of England and the European Central Bank have not yet raised the
alarm, they are starting to take an interest in the matter, in the wake of the US
regulators, including the Federal Reserve, being concerned about ‘deteriorating
underwriting practices’.
‘Private equity is its own worst enemy when it comes to leverage,’ said Neil
MacDougall, managing partner of Silverfleet, a London-based private equity group.
‘As an industry, we’ll just use it to maximise prices.’
Source: Chassany, A.-S. (2014) Loan terms eased in search for yield, Financial Times,
23 March.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
2013–2014 when investment-grade debt gave very low interest rates. PIKs can
give yields in double figures, but that ‘yield’ may be in the form of more bonds
– see Article 6.5.
Article 6.5
The esoteric debt structures last gained prominence during the leveraged buyout
boom that defined the 2006–2007 credit bubble, and their return has raised concerns
that markets could once again be overheating.
PIK note issuance has taken off in the past month, with deals from luxury retailer
Neiman Marcus, drive-through burger joint Checkers & Rally’s, and Ancestry.com,
pushing the amount sold so far this year to $9.2bn, according to S&P LCD
[Leveraged Commentary and Data]. That is the highest volume since 2008, when
$13.4bn worth of PIK notes were sold.
A wave of junk-rated borrowers, including Michaels Stores, the chain of arts and
crafts shops, and CommScope, a maker of communications cable equipment, have
also included PIK structures as part of new bond deals earlier this year.
PIK-toggles were widely criticised for fuelling the bubble in cheap credit before the
crisis. About 32% of the companies that issued PIK bonds during the bubble era
defaulted at some point from 2008 to mid-2013, according to Moody’s, although the
rating agency says the outlook for today’s issuers is less bleak.
‘PIK structures are back,’ said Lenny Ajzenman, senior vice-president at Moody’s.
‘It has become easier for companies to issue such notes given lower borrowing costs
and use the proceeds to fund dividend payments to shareholders. And with the low
yields in debt markets, investors are snapping up all these notes.’
Bankers say the intense demand for higher-yielding bonds and loans has made
selling such assets much easier in recent years.
Source: Rodrigues, V. and Alloway, T. (2013) Pre-crisis debt products make comeback,
Financial Times, 22 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
PIKs relieve the company of making cash payments, but regularly add to the
amount of debt, which can then become excessive and cause problems, as it
did for the fashion company New Look – see Article 6.6.
Article 6.6
The cash raised will be used to pay off half of the £746m in payment-in-kind notes
that accounted for the bulk of the private equity-owned retailer’s £1.1bn net debt.
The remaining PIK notes were due to mature in 2015, but will now not do so until
2018, giving vital breathing space to new chief executive Anders Kristiansen, who
took over the business late last year.
New Look, owned by private equity groups Apax and Permira, will pay a coupon of
12% on the new payment-in-kind notes, compared to 9% plus Libor the retailer had
paid previously.
‘People were expecting the keys to be handed over to the payment-in-kind holders
in 2015,’ said one person familiar with the situation. The £425m left over from the
bond will – along with some of the group’s cash – refinance the retailer’s remaining
senior debt.
The move comes three years after New Look scrapped a planned £650m IPO as
potential investors raised questions about the low-cost fashion retailer’s debt.
Annual interest costs on the debt, which came to slightly more than £100m in 2012,
have since hindered the group’s profitability.
New Look, founded in 1969, has more than 1,000 stores globally. In 2012, it had
revenues of £1.5bn and adjusted earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and
amortisation of £198m. Late last year, New Look was forced to beat off suggestions
that it was close to going into administration and wrote to suppliers to reassure
them of its financial strength.
Source: Robinson, D. and Chassany, A.-S. (2013) New Look launches £800m bond to grasp
debt nettle, Financial Times, 26 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Hybrid securities
Convertible bonds
Convertible bonds (or convertible loan stocks, or converts, or CBs), like
other hybrids, combine a debt security element and an equity element.
Convertible bonds carry a rate of interest in the same way as ordinary bonds,
but they also give the holder the right to exchange the bonds at some stage in
the future into ordinary shares according to some prearranged formula.2 The
owner of these bonds is not obliged to exercise this right of conversion and so
the bonds may continue until redemption as an interest-bearing instrument.
2
Alternatively they may be convertible into preference (preferred) shares.
They are not particularly popular in the UK, but in the US and some other parts
of the world they form a significant percentage of securities, and issuance has
risen as investors seek the better returns that may come from the link to equity
– see Article 6.7.
Article 6.7
Those bets have paid off, at least compared with pure fixed-income investments.
Convertible bonds have returned 12.8% this year, compared with 3.2% for high
yield and a loss of 3% for investment grade debt.
The strong demand has prompted companies to take advantage of the instruments
as a source of cheap and flexible financing. Companies around the world raised
$48bn in the first half of the year.
And it is not just the traditional unrated companies in the technology or bio-
technology sector – which struggle to get normal bond market funding – that are
Source: Stothard, M. and Massoudi, A. (2013) Rate rise fears spark boom in convertible
bonds, Financial Times, 19 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
The conversion price can vary from as little as 10% to over 65% greater than
the share price at the date of the bond issuance. So, if a £100 bond offered the
right to convert to 40 ordinary shares, the conversion price would be £2.50
(that is £100 ÷ 40), which, if the market price of the shares is £2.20, would be a
conversion premium of 30p divided by £2.20, which equals 13.6%. The right
to convert may be for a specific date or several specific dates over, say, a four-
year period, or any time between two dates. The company may have the option
to redeem the bonds before maturity.
Case study
Ford Motor Co
The Ford Motor Co issued 30-year convertible bonds in 2006, raising $4.5 billion.
The bonds were sold at a premium of 25% above the share price at the time of
$7.36. That is, the conversion price was at $9.20 per share. The bonds will mature
in 2036 if they have not been converted before this and were issued at a par value
of $1,000. The coupon was set at 4.25%. They are non-callable for the first ten
years. From this information we can calculate the conversion ratio:
Each bond carries the right to convert to 108.6957 shares, which is equivalent to
paying $9.20 for each share at the $1,000 par value of the bond.
In November 2010 Ford, desperate to reduce its corporate debt and try to regain
a better credit rating (move up to investment grade), after having had its commer-
cial paper downgraded in 2005, persuaded holders of $1.9 billion of convertibles
(this issue together with some other convertibles due for redemption in 2016) to
swap debt for shares in the company. Ford gave the holders of the 2036 convert-
ibles 108.6957 shares plus a cash payment equal to $190 for every $1,000 in
principal amount, along with accrued and unpaid interest.
Box 6.2
Conversion price
This gives the price of each ordinary share obtainable by exchanging a convertible
bond:
Conversion premium
This gives the difference between the conversion price and the market share price,
expressed as a percentage:
The length of time to maturity affects the conversion premium: the longer it is, the
greater likelihood the share will rise above the conversion price and therefore the
more an investor will pay for the option to convert.
Conversion value
This is the value of a convertible bond if it were converted into ordinary shares at
the current share price:
A convertible bond has two values forming lower bounds through which it
should not fall: (1) it must sell for more than its conversion value, otherwise an
arbitrageur could buy bonds and immediately convert them to shares, selling
the shares, making a quick low-risk profit; (2) the value as a straight bond
(ignoring the conversion option) (see Chapter 13 for such valuations). When
the share price is low, the straight bond value is the effective lower bound, with
the conversion option having little impact. When the share price is high, the
bond’s price is overwhelming driven by the conversion value.
To illustrate convertible bond price movements consider the Ford bond selling
at $1,000, which can be converted to 108.6957 shares at $9.20 per share when
shares are currently trading at $7.36:
1 If you bought shares and then they double to $14.72 you would make 100%
return.
2 If, instead, you bought a convertible for $1,000 and shares double your
return will be 60% (the convertible rises to 108.6957 × $14.72 = $1,600). The
lower return than in (1) is due to you effectively paying $9.20 per share
rather than $7.36. In reality, the value of the convertible would be slightly
higher than this because it will tend to trade at a slight premium to its con-
version value (it still has the safety feature of the straight debt, and a timing
option on the conversion).
3 Conversely, if the share price falls, say, to $5 and you made a pure share
investment, you will be down by 32%, that is $2.36/$7.36. The conversion
value on the bond falls from $800 to $5 × 108.6957 = $543.4785.
4 However, its price does not go down that low because the minimum price is
the greater of its conversion value or its value as straight debt. Assuming the
value of comparable straight debt is $750 given current yields to redemption
in the bond markets, the convertible will fall by a maximum of only 25%.
Again, it is very likely to trade at more than this, a premium to its straight
value, because the conversion right is still in place, even though conversion
has become a more distant prospect. Thus a convertible offers the benefit of
a reduced downside risk compared with equity, but also a reduced upside
potential because the premium per share is paid.
5 Of course, if the share price is constant but market-determined redemption
yields rise, then the value of the convertible will fall, as will its floor, being
determined by its value as straight debt.
6 If the credit rating of Ford deteriorates, then the convertible price will fall, as
will the straight-debt floor level.
If the share price rises above the conversion price, investors may choose to
exercise the option to convert if they anticipate that the share price will at least
be maintained and the dividend yield is higher than the convertible bond
yield. If the share price rise is seen to be temporary, the investor may wish to
hold on to the bond. If the share price remains below the conversion price, the
value of the convertible will be the same as a straight bond at maturity.
Article 6.8
Source: Hammond, E. (2013) Great Portland strikes with convertible bond, Financial Times,
3 September.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
4 Fewer restrictive covenants. The directors have greater operating and financial
flexibility than they would with a secured debenture. Investors accept that
a convertible is a hybrid between debt and equity finance and do not tend
to ask for high-level security (they are usually unsecured and subordinated)
or strong restrictions on managerial action or insist on strict financial ratio
boundaries. Many Silicon Valley companies with little more than a web
portal and a brand have used convertibles because of the absence of a need
to provide collateral or stick to asset:borrowing ratios.
5 Underpriced shares. A company that wishes to raise equity finance over the
medium term, but judges that the stock market is temporarily underpricing
its shares, may turn to convertible bonds. If the firm does perform as the
managers expect and the share price rises, the convertible will be exchanged
for equity.
6 Cheap way to issue shares. Managers tend to favour convertibles as an inex-
pensive way to issue ‘delayed’ equity. Equity is raised at a later date without
the high costs of rights issues, etc.
7 Available finance when straight debt and equity are not available. Some firms
locked out of the equity markets (e.g. because of poor recent performance)
and the straight debt markets (because of high levels of indebtedness) may
still be able to raise money in the convertible market. Rating agencies treat
them as part bond, part equity, usually half-and-half,3 thus their issue does
not impact leverage levels as much as vanilla debt for assessments such as
default ratings, making downgrades less likely.
Note that a bond’s conversion price will be adjusted for corporate actions such
as share splits (say doubling the number of shares by simply giving existing
shareholders one extra share for each one currently held), rights issues (share-
holders buying more shares from the firm) and stock dividends (shares issued
as an alternative to a cash dividend).
Some variations
A variation on the convertible idea is to have rising conversion prices, e.g. £3
in the first three years, £4 for the next five years, and so on. These are known as
step-up convertibles. Obviously, with these the bond converts to fewer shares
over time. Another variation is the zero coupon convertible bond, issued at a
discount to par value. Going further we can have the zero coupon convertible
bond, which is both issued and redeemed at par, i.e. there is no capital gain to
make up for the lack of coupons (a par-priced zero coupon convertible). Here
the investor is expecting the equity value to rise, but has an element of capital
protection through the issuer’s promise to repay at par. Yet another possibility
is a variable-coupon bond, which can be converted into a fixed-interest rate
bond – useful if you can judge when interest rates have reached a peak because
you can convert and lock in high interest rates.
The bonds sold may give the right to conversion into shares not of the issuers
but of another company held by the issuer. Note that the term exchangeable
bond is probably more appropriate in these cases.
3
But sub-investment-grade issuers often do not qualify for the 50% equity treatment.
a specified value for a specified amount of time. The coco market really got
going in the mid-2000s when a number of, particularly US, companies issued
bonds which were convertible into shares only once the share price moved
beyond a threshold (set even higher than the strike price for the convertible).
This type is known as an upside contingent bond.
Also issued were downside contingent bonds which convert if a low thresh-
old is breached. This downside idea was extended following the financial crisis.
Banks needed to raise more reserve capital (the gap between what they owe
and what they own) as a buffer against running into difficulties. Banks tend
to run with tiny amounts of equity put into the business by the ultimate risk
takers, the shareholders. They might put up, say, 3% of the amount that the
bank owes to depositors and other creditors. If it loses more than 3% by, say,
making bad loans, then it will owe more than its assets, i.e. be insolvent.
The regulators insisted on a programme of gradual beefing-up of equity
buffers. Most banks have done this by selling more shares through, say, a rights
issue or by retaining more profit in the business rather than paying dividends.
However, some bankers thought they did not want to continue increasing the
amount of equity capital in the business and looked for alternatives. The main
instrument they adopted was the contingent convertible. Some banks opted
for the downside contingent bond, which forces the holder to convert to
shares automatically if the equity as a percentage of bank assets falls below a
pre-determined level (note: the holder has no choice). This boosts the buffer of
capital that will be subject to total loss if the bank has to be liquidated, thus
providing greater protection for depositors and other creditors to the bank.
In the jargon: it boosted the bank’s ‘Tier One capital’, reducing the odds of it
falling below the regulatory amount. (See Arnold, G. (2014) The Financial
Times Guide to Banking for more on bank solvency buffers.)
Some banks issued another type of bond to help cope with losses. The total
writedown bond (sudden death bond, total loss bond or wipeout coco) is
written off completely if the contingency occurs. Thus the bank eliminates a
portion of its debts and improves its leverage ratios. This is usually triggered by
the equity capital buffers falling below a trigger level approved by the country’s
financial regulator.
Because of the risks involved of losing the income from the original bond, or
losing the amount invested entirely, cocos pay a higher rate of return, up to 8%
at a time when interest rates in much of the world are less than 1%, and so hold
considerable attraction to investors – see Articles 6.9 and 6.10.
Article 6.9
As regulators encourage banks to hold more capital where investors would take
losses if a bank defaults, cocos are seen as a relatively quick fix when it comes to
bolstering tier one capital ratios.
Tier one capital, a key regulatory measure of financial health, is considered the
safest portion of a bank’s capital and traditionally comprises common equity and
retained earnings.
There have been two types of coco to date: those which convert into equity when a
bank’s capital ratio falls below a pre-agreed trigger and those which are written off
entirely.
‘The bank doesn’t have to default to trigger these cocos . . . the point is they can
push losses on to bondholders and provide capital while the bank is still a going
concern,’ says Jenna Barnard at Henderson.
Such criticism has not deterred the banks, particularly as demand has been buoyed
by wealthy Asians who can snap up cocos with borrowed money, bolstering their
returns.
Year to date global coco issuance stands at $8.5bn from eight deals, a record num-
ber, according to figures from Dealogic, all from European banks.
Keith Skeoch, chief executive of UK life company Standard Life, describes wipeout
cocos as ‘death-spiral bonds’. However, he says they have a role where ‘there is a
desperate need, particularly in the banking sector, for the provision of loss absorb-
ing capital’.
Barclays issued a $3bn death spiral coco last November and followed it up with
another $1bn issue in April. They yielded 7.6% and 7.7% respectively.
Earlier this month Credit Suisse issued its own $2.5bn wipeout coco, which yielded
6.5%, that followed a $1bn issue from Belgium’s KBC with an interest rate of
8%.
➨
The Swiss bank said similar issues would follow, not least as it seeks to lock in
historically low interest rates and take advantage of investors’ hunger for rela-
tively high-yielding instruments.
It is why even coco critics, such as Ms Barnard, admit the asset class ‘will become
quite hard to ignore’.
Other banks are choosing to plot a middle path.
Société Générale is preparing what it refers to as a ‘write-down, write-up’ hybrid
bond in which investors would take losses if the bank’s tier one capital falls below
5.1%. However, if the bank recovers, bondholders would begin to get their money
back.
‘It’s not exactly a coco but it has a writedown mechanism . . . if the trigger is
reached only a proportion will be written down, depending on where the capital
ratio of the bank stands,’ says Stéphane Landon, Société Générale’s head of asset
and liability management. ‘If the bank gets better this amount can be reinstated
and so the bond can be reinstated.’
In the US, a more restrictive definition of regulatory capital effectively prevents US
banks from including cocos in their tier one buffers.
US regulators are said to have been scarred by their experience during the financial
crisis with other types of hybrid bank instruments combining equity and debt char-
acteristics. Many of these hybrid products failed to absorb bank losses during the
financial crisis.
Source: Thompson, C. and Alloway, T. (2013) ‘Sudden death’ bank bonds on the increase,
Financial Times, 29 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Article 6.10
The UK’s Financial Conduct Authority earlier this month announced a ban on
retail investors buying cocos, which now constitute a €45bn market according to
RBS, albeit one dominated by institutions and hedge funds.
➨
Some see the sell-off as restoring a measure of sobriety to what had become an
increasingly frenzied market whose gyrations were exacerbated in part due to fast-
money investors selling-out at the first sign of trouble.
The sell-off comes on the back of frantic coco buying. In May average yields hit a
record low of 5.54%, while Deutsche Bank reported about €25bn of orders for its
maiden €1.5bn coco, underlining investor willingness to shoulder more risk in their
hunt for higher-yielding bank assets.
‘When I see cocos at 5.5% I personally don’t think I’m getting paid for the risks,’
says Jorge Martin Ceron, a portfolio manager at Lombard Odier.
The bond’s conversion mechanism – which can allow for coupon cancellations even
while the bank is a ‘going concern’ and potentially paying dividends to shareholders
– remains untested. Coco supporters point out that European banks’ continued
deleveraging and recent capital raising has made the prospect of outright conver-
sion, if not coupon cancellations, increasingly unlikely. But the wider market fall-
out highlights the asset’s exposure to ‘tail-risks’, or unforeseen events.
Regulatory incentives remain for banks to tap the coco market, not least because
they offer a cheaper way of raising capital than issuing equity. ‘For banks, using cocos
is still a very cost effective way to fill your capital bucket,’ says Mr Weinberger [head
of capital markets engineering at Société Générale].
Source: Thompson, C. (2014) Coco sell-off unveils high-yield bargains, Financial Times,
14 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Catastrophe bonds
These are issued by insurance companies. If no major catastrophe, e.g. earth-
quake in California, occurs they pay coupons and a redemption amount at the
end of their lives, usually around three years. If the specified catastrophe does
occur before maturity the principal and further coupons are ‘forgiven’ by the
holders: they get no more money from the insurance company. Thus the
insurance company has passed on some of the risk – see Article 6.11.
Article 6.11
costly disasters – those expected to occur less frequently than once in 50 years –
strike.
Even Hurricane Sandy, which caused almost $70bn worth of damage when it struck
the US east coast in 2012, left the bondholders unscathed. Only about a dozen of the
bonds – equating to less than 2% of the sums at risk – have ever incurred any losses.
Source: Gray, A. (2014) Cat bond investors show their limits, Financial Times, 1 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
This chapter focuses on ways of raising money by selling bonds outside of the
issuer’s home currency. This may be done by issuing bonds in another country
under the regulatory constraints of that country (foreign bonds) or may be
done outside of the jurisdiction of any country, with no interference from
national regulators or tax authorities (Eurobonds). It may also be done by
setting up an ongoing programme of issuance of a number of medium-term
bonds/notes through an arrangement with an investment bank(s) acting as a
manager helping the sale of bonds every few weeks in the amounts, currency
and type that suit the borrower at that time. Finally, the chapter discusses
the principles behind the rapidly growing market in Islamic bonds; still less
than 30 years old, this market is now worth well over $230 billion.
● Foreign bonds are issued in the domestic currency of the country where the
bond is issued by a non-resident, and are usually given a name that relates
to the country of the currency of issue, e.g. Samurai bonds are issued in
Japan in yen by a non-resident issuer.
● Eurobonds are bonds issued outside the jurisdiction of the currency of issue,
e.g. a Eurodollar bond is issued outside the US and so the US authorities have
no control over this market.
The term global bond is used where bonds are issued simultaneously in differ-
ent countries by large companies trading internationally or by sovereign entities.
These may be issued and traded in the foreign bond markets of one or more
countries, and/or the Eurobond market, and/or in the domestic market of the
issuer. Thus, they may be issued and trade in many different currencies.
The majority of international bonds are issued in US dollars or euros, with the
euro now having overtaken the dollar – of all the international bonds out-
standing 45% are denominated in euros and 36% in dollars. Note that most of
those denominated in euros are not under the jurisdiction of any eurozone
country (they are Eurobonds), with most of their trading taking place in finan-
cial centres outside of the continent, such as London. While only 9% of inter-
national bonds are issued in sterling, London is the major centre for secondary
trading, responsible for more than 70% of Eurobond trades.
Foreign bonds
Foreign bonds are given names relevant to the country where they are issued
and regulated, for example in Canada bonds issued by non-Canadian companies
denominated in Canadian dollars are known as Maple bonds and the interest
and capital payments are in CAD. Other foreign bonds from around the world
issued by non-domestic entities in the domestic market include:
Yankee bonds (US), dollar bonds issued in the US by a non-US issuer
Bulldog bonds (UK), sterling bonds issued in the UK by a non-UK issuer
Rembrandt bonds (the Netherlands)
Matador bonds (Spain)
Panda bonds (China)
Kangaroo or Matilda bonds (Australia)
Kiwi bonds (New Zealand).
Many deeply furrowed brows can be seen in financial circles when trying to
come up with nicknames for new types of foreign bonds – see Article 7.1.
Article 7.1
Source: Crabtree, J. (2014) The rise of the . . . Masala bond?, Financial Times, 10 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
For investors, foreign bonds carry the disadvantage of being subject to cur-
rency fluctuation. For example, a £100,000 foreign bond bought by a US
investor when the exchange rate was $1.60 to the £ would cost $62,500. Three
years later, the bond reaches maturity and the investor receives back the par
value of £100,000, but now the exchange rate is $1.85 to the £, so he receives
only $54,054 and makes a capital loss.
Another disadvantage for investors is that foreign bonds are traded on foreign
markets where investors do not have the same degree of protection as they
would in their own domestic market. Political unrest or disputes could cause
investors to lose control of their foreign investments as the foreign govern-
ment could ban all payments on externally raised finance. Not infrequently
investors in foreign bonds have found their coupon payments subjected to an
extra withholding tax imposed by the country where the bonds are issued.
Article 7.2
‘We expect good results on yields, meaning Bulgaria gets cheap financing,’
Goranov said early this month.
The money raised will be used to help bridge a fiscal deficit that the government
expects to come in at 3% of GDP this year. It will also finance the rollover of a
€1.5bn loan it used to finance last year’s deficit, which was increased by the need to
guarantee deposits and recapitalise banks following the collapse of Corporate
Commercial Bank (KTB or Corpbank) and a run on another domestic lender.
The loan was syndicated by Citi, HSBC and the Bulgarian units of Société Générale
and UniCredit, which will also arrange the first foreign bond issue this year.
The 6.9bn lev bonds will increase Bulgaria’s public debt to 28.4% of GDP this year,
Reuters reported, from 18% in 2013.
While this is still one of the lowest levels in the European Union, observers have
mixed views on Bulgaria’s creditworthiness. GDP growth is expected to come in at
under 1% this year, according to a recent forecast by the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development, though the Economist Intelligence Unit expects
a respectable average of 3% between 2015 and 2019.
‘Bulgaria’s banking crisis and the chronic political instability which has been
plaguing the country of late have taken their toll on the country’s creditworthiness,’
says Nicholas Spiro of consultancy Spiro Sovereign Strategy. ‘Many of Bulgaria’s
underlying weaknesses have been exposed over the past several months even
though the country’s low level of public indebtedness sets it apart from some of its
more fiscally challenged CEE peers. Growth remains lacklustre and the budget
deficit has deteriorated significantly over the past year – albeit from a relatively
strong position.’
While quantitative easing from the European Central Bank will provide a liquidity
boost that somewhat offsets the US Federal Reserve’s monetary tightening, Spiro
does not expect this to boost demand for Bulgarian sovereign debt considerably.
‘A huge burst of monetary stimulus from one of the world’s leading central
banks is inevitably positive for emerging-market assets. But Bulgarian yields were
already at exceptionally low levels to start with, offering little carry for investors
– not least given the mounting risks in the country and the relatively illiquid
nature of the market.’
In December, Fitch affirmed Bulgaria’s foreign and local currency ratings at
investment-grade BBB − and BBB, respectively, with a stable outlook. The agency
noted the stabilisation of the banking sector and the government’s efforts to
reduce its deficit, as well as downside risks from the eurozone and the crisis in
Ukraine. However, the same month, Standard & Poor’s cut the country’s sovereign
credit rating to junk.
There are grounds for optimism. A snap election last October brought an unwieldy
four-party coalition to power, including two groupings that are themselves awkward
alliances of smaller parties. But a pro-reform government source told beyondbrics
the administration’s progress was a case of ‘so far, so good’.
➨
‘There are no major cracks in the government, and none in sight,’ the person said.
‘Some reforms are already under way in health, justice and education, without any
sign of social discontent.’
There were also tentatively positive signs on the chaotic and indebted energy
sector, with a ‘major focus’ on improving energy security, while in the banking
system, ECB supervision and a move towards the eurozone (the lev is already
pegged to the euro in a currency board arrangement) were part of the government’s
programme.
Still, there is much work to be done – and all with an economy that is both sluggish
and vulnerable.
‘The governing coalition, although composed of four rather different parties, has
already demonstrated that it can deliver,’ says Daniel Smilov, programme director
at the Centre for Liberal Strategies, a Sofia think-tank. ‘Bulgaria’s position on the
South Stream project and the start of judicial reforms are positive signs. Thus far,
the government has handled the banking situation well – what remains to be done
is a thorough investigation of responsibility for the Corpbank collapse. As for the
energy sector, concrete actions have not been taken yet, and the government has
still not announced a detailed plan for tackling the problems.’
Source: MacDowall, A. (2014) Bulgaria lines up 3.5bn bond issues as crises ease, Financial
Times, 29 January.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Because foreign bonds are regulated by the domestic authority of the country
where the bond is issued the rules can be demanding and an encumbrance to
companies seeking to act quickly and at low cost. Some regulatory authorities
have also been criticised for stifling innovation in the financial markets. The
growth of the less restricted Eurobond market, where the bonds are not under
the jurisdiction of the country of issue, has put the once dominant foreign
bond market in the shade.
Eurobonds
Let’s get one misunderstanding out of the way: Eurobonds are not connected
with the euro currency. They were in existence decades before Europe thought
of creating the euro – the first Eurobond issue was in 1963 on the Luxembourg
stock exchange, with the $15 million Eurodollar issue by Autostrade, the
Italian motorway company.
The term ‘euro’ in Eurodollar and Eurobond does not mean European. The name
‘Eurodollar’ came about when the former Soviet Union transferred dollars
from New York to a French bank at the height of the cold war in 1957. The
cable address just happened to be EUROBANK and the money transferred
became Eurodollars – dollars beyond the reach of US tax and government
restrictions. Bonds issued outside of the US in Eurodollars were called
Eurodollar bonds, but they are often referred to simply as Eurobonds.
Eurobonds are issued all over the world – see Article 7.3 for examples.
Article 7.3
Source: Rintoul, F. (2013) Sub-Saharan market: high yields fire appetite for African
Eurobonds, Financial Times, 3 November.
© Andrew Macdowall.
Eurobonds are distinct from euro bonds – euro bonds are bonds denominated
in euros and issued in the eurozone countries. Of course, there have been
euro-denominated Eurobonds issued outside the jurisdiction of the authorities
in the euro area; these are euro-Eurobonds.
Eurobonds can be described as ‘external bonds’, but the more precise defini-
tion of ‘bonds sold outside the jurisdiction of the country of the currency in
which the bond is denominated’ is more descriptive. So, for example, the UK
financial regulators have little influence over Eurobonds issued in Luxembourg
and denominated in sterling (known as Eurosterling bonds), even though the
transactions (for example interest and capital payments) are in sterling.
UK, the world centre for Eurobonds, is sticking to its tax exemption, making it
difficult for other jurisdictions to tax this source of income – this stateless
money will flow to where it is most advantageous to lenders and borrowers,
thus any tax rules in one or a few countries only will be bypassed.
Eurobonds are also bearer bonds, so holders do not have to disclose their
identity. All that is required to receive interest and capital is for the holder to
have possession of the bond. Originally this meant physically held bonds, but
today many bearer bonds are held in a central depository so that trading and
post-trade settlement can take place electronically – a paperless system. The
clearing organisations (e.g. Euroclear or Clearstream) ‘present’ the bonds for
coupon payment on the appropriate dates. The anonymity from the govern-
ment authorities makes tax avoidance even easier. In contrast, domestic bonds
are usually registered, allowing companies and governments to identify the
owners and ensure that taxes are paid.
The market grew modestly through the 1970s and then at a rapid rate in the
1980s. By then the Eurodollar bonds had been joined by bonds denominated
in a wide variety of currencies. The market was stimulated not only by the tax
and anonymity benefits, which brought a lower cost of finance than for
domestic and foreign bonds, but also by the increasing demand from transna-
tional companies and governments needing large sums in alternative currencies
and with the potential for innovatory characteristics. The Eurobond market
was further boosted by the recycling of dollars from the oil-exporting coun-
tries, which generated vast amounts of dollars needing an investment home,
and by other countries not wanting to keep dollar assets in the US, e.g. Iran,
and by American companies choosing not to send profits to head office
because of the high tax rates if they did so. Apple, for example, had more than
$150 billion held outside of the US in 2014, while eBay said it faced a tax
charge of $3 billion on $9 billion of foreign earnings it was bringing back to the
US that it had been storing offshore.
In 1979 less than $20 billion worth of international bonds were issued in a
variety of currencies. By the end of 2013 the rate of new issuance had grown to
about $900 billion, with a total amount outstanding of about $23,500 billion
(these were mostly Eurobonds, but some were foreign bonds) – see Figure 7.1.
Figure 7.1 International bond and note (including foreign bonds) outstanding,
December 2013
Source: Data from BIS Quarterly Review, March 2014 www.bis.org
Even though the majority of Eurobond trading takes place through London,
sterling trades are not as important as USD and EUR trades, and what is
more, it tends to be large US and other foreign banks located in London that
dominate the market. While American issuers are the largest, they account for
less than one-seventh of all the issues because the issuing organisations are
dispersed all over the world – see Figure 7.3.
Since the financial crisis Eurobonds have become increasingly important for
financing European businesses, the growth in the market assisted by reduced
appetite in banks for business lending and the ability to sell across the eurozone
– see Article 7.4.
Article 7.4
Paving the possible way ahead has been the rapid development of corporate bond
markets in the world’s emerging economies. During the past quarter, emerging-
market companies obtained three times as much funding from the bond markets as
from bank syndicates, the biggest gap in at least a decade.
Additional reporting by Rachel Sanderson.
Source: Atkins, R. and Stothard, M. (2013) Eurobonds: a change of gear, Financial Times,
30 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Types of Eurobonds
The Eurobond market is innovative in producing bonds with all sorts of coupon
payment and capital repayment arrangements, for example the currency of
the coupon changes half way through the life of the bond, or the interest rate
switches from fixed to floating rate at some point. We cannot go into detail
here on the rich variety but merely categorise the bonds into broad types.
1 Straight fixed-rate bond
The coupon remains the same over the life of the bond. These are usually paid
annually, in contrast to domestic bond semi-annual coupons. The redemption
of these bonds is usually made with a ‘bullet’ repayment at maturity.
2 Equity related
These take two forms:
a Bonds with warrants attached
An equity warrant, for example, would give the right, but not the obliga-
tion, to purchase shares. There are also warrants for commodities such as
gold or oil, and for the right to buy additional bonds from the same issuer
at the same price and yield as the host bond. Warrants are detachable from
the host bond and are securities in their own right, unlike convertibles.
b Convertibles
The bondholder has the right (but not the obligation) to convert the
bond into ordinary shares at a pre-set price (see Chapter 6).
3 Floating-rate notes (FRNs)
These have variable coupons reset on a regular basis, usually every three
or six months, in relation to a reference rate, such as Libor. The size of the
spread over Libor reflects the perceived risk of the issuer. The typical term for
a Eurobond FRN is about 5–12 years, but some companies, particularly
banks, favour issuing perpetual, or undated, FRNs.
5 Dual-currency bonds
These bonds pay the coupon in one currency but are redeemed in a different
currency. The redemption currency is usually the US dollar and the coupon
payments are often made in a currency which offers the issuer the chance of
a lower rate of borrowing.
Within these broad categories all kinds of ‘bells and whistles’ (features) can be
attached to the bonds, for example reverse floaters – the coupon declines as
benchmark interest rate, say Libor, rises – and capped bonds – the interest rate
cannot rise above a certain level. Many bonds have call back features under
which the issuer has the right, but not the obligation, to buy the bond back
after a period of time has elapsed, say five years, at a price specified when the
bond was issued. This might be at the par value but is usually slightly higher.
Because there are real disadvantages for investors, bonds with call features offer
higher interest rates. Issuers like call features because a significant price rise for
the bond implies that current market interest rates are considerably less than
the coupon rate on the bond. They can buy back the original bonds and issue
new bonds at a lower yield. Also some bonds place tight covenant restrictions
on the firm so it is useful to be able to buy them back and issue less restrictive
bonds in their place. Finally, exercising the call may permit the corporate to
adjust its financial leverage by reducing its debt. A Eurobond may also have a
‘put’ feature (see Chapter 4).
Issuance
The majority of Eurobonds (more than 80%) are rated AAA or AA, although
some are issued rated below BBB−. Denominations are usually $1,000, $5,000,
$10,000, $50,000 or $100,000 (or similar large sums in the currency of issue –
known as 1,000, 5,000 or 50,000 lots or pieces). Details of some international
bonds are shown in Tables 7.2 and 7.3 taken from FT.com. The issue process
leading to this point is described in Chapter 4. Note the large volume of money
raised in this market in one week (selected at random).
US Dollars
Euros
Swiss Francs
Bond issue details are online at ft.com/bondissues. Final terms, non-callable unless stated.
Spreads relate to German govt bonds unless stated.
Source: Thomson Reuters
Secondary market
Eurobonds are traded on the secondary market through intermediaries acting
as market makers. Some bonds are listed on the London, Dublin, Luxembourg,
Channel Islands or other stock exchanges around the world. Listing enables
some institutions to invest that would otherwise be prohibited. Despite this,
the market is primarily an over-the-counter one. Most deals are conducted
using the telephone, computers, telex and fax, but there are a number of
electronic platforms. The extent to which electronic platforms will replace
telephone dealing is as yet unclear. It is not possible to go to a central source
for price information. Most issues rarely trade; those that do are generally pri-
vate transactions between investor and bond dealer and there is no obligation
to inform the public about the deal.
M07_ARNO1799_01_SE_C07.indd 222
US Dollars
American Water Capital Corp 200 01-12-2042 4.3 99.589 BofA Merrill/RBC CM/RBS/TD Securities
American Water Capital Corp 300 01-03-2025 3.4 99.857 RBS/BofA Merrill Lynch/RBC CM/TD Securities
Burlington Northern 700 01-09-2024 3.4 99.771 Citi/BofA Merrill Lynch/Goldman Sachs
Burlington Northern 800 01-09-2044 4.55 99.446 Citi/BofA Merrill Lynch/Goldman Sachs
CBS Corp 550 15-08-2044 4.9 98.639 CS/Deutsche Bk/BofAML/RBS/UBS/BNPP/Mizuho/SMBC Nikko
CBS Corp 600 15-08-2019 2.3 99.696 CS/Deutsche Bk/BofAML/RBS/UBS/BNPP/Mizuho/SMBC Nikko
CBS Corp 600 15-08-2024 3.7 99.76 CS/Deutsche Bk/BofAML/RBS/UBS/BNPP/Mizuho/SMBC Nikko
China Constr Bark 750 20-08-2024 4.25 99.577 ANZ/BofAML/CCB International/Citi/DeutscheBank/HSBC/UBS
Consumers Energy 250 31-08-2064 4.35 99.137 Scotia Capital/Barclays/RBCCM/SuntrustRobinsonHumphrey/WFC
Consumers Energy 250 31-08-2024 3.125 99.898 Scotia Capital/Barclays/RBCCM/SuntrustRobinsonHumphrey/WFC
Gulfport Energy Corp 300 01-11-2020 7.75 106 Credit Suisse
Minerva Luxembourg 200 31-01-2023 7.75 100 *Banco BTG Pactual/HSBC/ItauBBA/BofA Merrill Lynch/Santander*
PRICOA Global Funding I 500 18-08-2017 1.35 99.93 *Citi/Credit Suisse/JP Morgan/Wells Fargo*
UBS AG Stamford 1250 14-08-2017 1.375 99.678 UBS Investment Bank
UBS AG Stamford 2500 14-08-2019 2.375 99.836 UBS Investment Bank
World Bank 100 28-08-2019 1.7 100.000 Morgan Stanley
Euros
7/7/15 8:48 AM
Sterling
Swiss Francs
M07_ARNO1799_01_SE_C07.indd 223
Credit Suisse 370 18-08-2015 FRN 100.000 3mL+22bps Credit Suisse
Credit Suisse 155 19-08-2016 FRN 100.000 3mL+27bps Credit Suisse
Municipality Finance 150 17-09-2024 0.75 101.328 Credit Suisse
Total 800 29-08-2024 1 100.584 UBS
WellsFargo 250 30-09-2020 0.625 100.456 Credit Suisse/UBS
WellsFargo 250 03-09-2024 1.25 100.513 Credit Suisse/UBS
Australian Dollars
Norwegian Krone
Swedish Krona
Bond issue details are online at ft.com/bondissues. Final terms, non-callable unless stated. Spreads relate to German govt bonds unless stated.
Source: Thomson Reuters
7/7/15 8:48 AM
224 PART 2 BOND MARKETS
Advantages Drawbacks
1 Large loans for long periods are available. 1 Only for the largest companies – minimum
realistic issue size is about £100m – and
only those with good ‘name recognition’
(widely regarded as creditworthy) or good
credit rating.
2 Often cheaper than domestic bonds. 2 Because interest and capital are often paid
The finance provider receives the interest in a foreign currency there is a risk that
without tax deduction and retains anonymity exchange rate movements mean more of
from the tax authorities and therefore the home currency is required to buy the
supplies cheaper finance. Economies foreign currency than was anticipated.
of scale also reduce costs. Also a wider
investor base can be tapped than in the
domestic market.
3 Ability to hedge interest rate and exchange 3 The secondary market can be illiquid.
rate risk. For example, a Canadian
corporation buying assets in Europe
(such as a company) may finance the
asset by taking on a Eurobond liability
in euros, thus reducing variability in net
value (in Canadian dollars) when the
C$/€ exchange rate moves.
An MTN programme stretching over many years can be established with one
set of legal documents. Then, numerous notes can be issued under the pro-
gramme in future years. Such a programme allows greater certainty that the
firm will be able to issue an MTN when it needs the finance and allows issuers
to bypass the costly and time-consuming documentation associated with each
stand-alone note/bond. The programme can allow for bonds of various qual-
ities, maturities, currencies or type of interest (fixed or floating). Over the years
the market can be tapped into at short notice in the most suitable form at that
time, e.g. US dollars rather than pounds, or redemption in three years rather
than in two. It is possible to sell in small amounts, e.g. $5 million, and on a
continuous basis, regularly dripping bonds into the market. The banks
organising the MTN programme charge a commitment fee on any available
funds authorised by the programme but not used. Management fees will also
be payable to the syndication of banks organising the MTN facility.
Vodafone’s MTN programme is one of the most varied I have come across. If
you download an annual report you will find a list of over two dozen MTNs
in issue, with a wide variety of currencies, maturities and coupon payment
intervals (see Vodafone’s Notes to the accounts). It has two MTN programmes:
a €30 billion medium-term note (EMTN) programme and what is called a
‘US shelf programme’. The US shelf programme (shelf registration or shelf
offering or shelf prospectus) is one where there is a single prospectus approved
by the Securities and Exchange Commission at the outset under which numerous
MTNs can be issued in subsequent years. For each issue the borrower must file
a short statement pointing out material changes in its business and finances
since the shelf prospectus was filed.
Sukuk (the plural form of the Arabic word sakk, meaning legal document or
certificate, from which the word cheque is derived) are bonds which conform
to sharia law, which forbids interest income, or riba. However, Islam does
encourage entrepreneurial activity and the sharing of risk through equity
shares.
There was always a question mark over the ability of modern finance to com-
ply with Islamic sharia law, which not only prohibits the charging or paying of
interest but insists that real assets underlie all financial transactions. Money
alone should not create a profit and finance should serve the real economy, not
just the financial one. Ways have been found to participate in the financial
world while still keeping to sharia law, although certain Islamic scholars
oppose some of the instruments created.
Whereas conventional bonds are promises to pay interest and principal, sukuk
represent part ownership of tangible assets, businesses or investments, so the
returns are generated by some sort of share of the gain (or loss) made and the
risk is shared.
Currently, there is some confusion over whether investors can always seize
the underlying assets in the event of default on sukuk or whether the assets
are merely placed in a sukuk structure to comply with sharia law. Lawyers
and bankers say that the latter is the case, with most sukuk being, in reality,
unsecured instruments. They differentiate between ‘asset-backed’ and ‘asset-
based’ sukuk:
● Asset-backed: there is a true sale between the originator and the SPV that
issues the sukuk, and sukuk holders own the underlying asset and do not
have recourse to the originator in the event of a payment shortfall. The
value of the assets owned by the SPV, and thence the sukuk holders, may
vary over time. The majority of sukuk issues are not asset backed.
● Asset-based: these are closer to conventional debt in that they hand inves-
tors ownership of the cash flows but not the assets themselves; the sukuk
holders have recourse to the originator if there is a payment shortfall.
There is no overarching regulator for Islamic finance but the rulings of the
AAOIFI are most widely followed in the Gulf. In Malaysia and other parts of
Asia other guidelines are adopted.
At the beginning of 2013 3,875 sukuk had been issued, 223 international and
3,652 domestic, with a total issuance value of $473 billion. The most common
types of sukuk are:
● Bai’ Bithaman Ajil – the issuer sells an asset(s) to investors with the promise
that it will buy the asset back at a predetermined price which allows for a
profit to the finance provider(s). Payment is on a deferred or instalment
basis over a pre-agreed period. The assets generally comprise land, buildings,
vehicles and equipment.
● Ijarah – one of the most common sukuk types, this is a leasing contract, for
well-defined assets, in which the lessee can gain benefit from the use of
equipment or other asset in return for regular lease payments providing a
return to sukuk holders. Some types permit legal title to be passed to the user
after the end of the lease, others do not. The ijarah contract is a binding con-
tract which neither party may terminate or alter without the other’s consent.
● Istisna’a – this is the financing of manufacturing, assembly or construction
capacity by arranging money to be transferred from the finance providers
prior to production. Payment is made at an agreed price for something that
does not yet exist in a lump sum or in instalments. The finance providers
may sell the asset once created. It is not necessary that the seller itself is the
manufacturer, merely that it causes the manufacture to take place. The item
must be described in detail and construction must fit the specifications.
Istisna’a is invalid for an existing asset or for natural things such as corn or
animals.
● Mudarabah – this is for when a partnership between two parties is formed.
One party acts as capital provider(s), giving a specific amount of capital to
another person, a named entrepreneur, to make use of the capital given for
the benefit of the business. Profits are shared according to a pre-arranged
ratio. Losses are borne by the finance providers.
● Murabaha – this a fixed-income bond for the purchase of an asset such as
property or a vehicle, with a fixed rate of profit for the finance providers
determined by a fixed profit margin. The asset acts as collateral until the
contract is settled. It is similar to rent-to-own arrangements, with sukuk
holders as owners and creditors until all required payments are made.
The first sukuk (a Bai Bithaman Ajil) was issued in 1990 in Malaysia by Shell
and denominated in the Malaysian currency, ringgit. International sukuk were
introduced in 2001 with the $100 million sovereign ijarah issue by the Central
Bank of Bahrain, and the market has grown rapidly since then, albeit with a
blip as a result of the 2008 global crisis – see Figures 7.4 and 7.5. It is estimated
by the International Islamic Financial Market (IIFM) that there is more than
$230 billion ($191 billion of domestic and $45 billion of international) sukuk
outstanding, and this figure is expected to increase rapidly.
Malaysia takes the lion’s share of the domestic market, with nearly 80% of the
world total, and has 12% of the international market. United Arab Emirates
dominates the international market with 44%, followed by Saudi Arabia with
13%, and then Malaysia. The UK and Luxembourg are important European
Figure 7.5 Amount of sukuk issued each year from 2001 to 2012
Source: Data from IIFM, sukuk issuance database
centres for Islamic finance. In the UK there are more than 20 banks providing
this service and numerous professionals skilled and experienced in its complex
details. To April 2015 more than US$38 billion had been raised through 53
issues of sukuk on the London Stock Exchange. See Article 7.5 for a discussion
on the competition between financial centres for Islamic finance.
Article 7.5
entrepôt for global finance in the 21st century. Bolstering Islamic finance is an import-
ant aspect of this, especially if, as the government hopes, it triggers an accompanying
wave of investment from appreciative Muslim countries and financiers.
The UK is stepping into a crowded field, however. The biggest Islamic finance
markets are Malaysia, Iran and Saudi Arabia. But Iran is in effect cut off from the
rest of the industry by international sanctions and different sharia interpretations,
leaving the other two centres as the leading powerhouses.
Saudi Arabia and Malaysia have the size and depth to act as regional centres of
gravity for the Middle East and Asia, and aspirations to lead the global industry.
Then there are established offshore hubs, led by Bahrain – one of the industry’s
pioneers – but with ambitious Dubai increasingly asserting itself. Bahrain has a
head start, but Dubai has already stolen its crown as the Middle East’s financial
centre and hopes to become the capital of the emerging ‘Islamic economy’ as well.
London is the leading western centre but Luxembourg, Hong Kong and South
Africa are now competing with the UK to become the first non-Islamic country to
issue a sovereign sukuk to make themselves stand out.
➨
Essentially, bankers, lawyers and clerics who are well versed in Islam’s financial
tenets work together to use one or a combination of permissible concepts in sharia
to get around bans on fixed interest rates and pure monetary speculation. They also
need to fulfil injunctions for real assets to back transactions and for profit-and-loss
sharing investments.
Still, the industry has its detractors. Some Muslim critics feel it is merely a means
to give conventional finance a veneer of sharia, following the letter of Islamic law
rather than its spirit.
Critics charge that the industry fails in the area that some proponents like to hold
up as its prime selling point: Islam’s injunction for profit-and-loss sharing equity
investments, rather than usurious debt. In practice, however, Islamic finance often
deviates little from its conventional counterpart.
Some proponents feel that Islamic finance has occasionally compromised its
principles in its efforts to grow. That has led to periodic pushback from the ‘sharia
scholars’, the specialist clerics who act as guardians of the industry’s religious
foundations.
In 2007 Sheikh Muhammad Taqi Usmani, one of the most distinguished sharia
scholars, indicated that some prominent sukuk structures strayed too far from the
spirit of Islamic law. Briefly, ‘a cold sweat broke out across the industry’, recalls
Harris Irfan of EIIB-Rasmala, an Islamic investment bank, but standards were
quickly tightened and growth was revived.
Many Muslims are simply agnostic on Islamic finance. Despite high hopes,
Islamic retail banking has failed to take off in the UK, for example. Even in Egypt,
a populous bastion of the Muslim world, the industry has failed to establish firm
roots.
Source: Wigglesworth, R. (2014) Islamic finance: by the book, Financial Times, 25 May.
© Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
As well as Shell, Tesco and Toyota have both issued ringgit sukuk (both
musharakah) in Malaysia. In a further development in November 2009,
General Electric (GE) became the first large western corporation to expand its
investor base into this arena with the issuance of its $500 million ijarah sukuk.
The assets underlying this sukuk are GE’s interests in aircraft and rental pay-
ments from aircraft leasing. The London Shard building was partly financed
with sharia-compliant funds. As the importance of Islamic finance grows, it is
thought that more European and US companies will enter this market and tap
the vast investment resources available. The UK government raised £200 million
by issuing a sukuk in 2014, hoping that this would be a catalyst for corporates
to follow suit. Being the first western country to do so has helped to reinforce
London’s position as the dominant western hub for Islamic finance. As well as
Islamic banks it already has Islamic insurance, murabaha for commodities,
mortgages, car loans and a secondary market for sukuk. Many other countries
are expected to issue their first sukuk soon – see Article 7.6.
Article 7.6
Source: Blas, J. (2014) South Africa to issue maiden sukuk, Financial Times, 28 August.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
There is no secondary trading in the interbank market; the loans are non-
negotiable – thus a lender for, say, three months cannot sell the right to
receive interest and capital from the borrower to another organisation after,
say, 15 days. The lender has to wait until the end of the agreed loan period to
recover the money. If a bank needs funds, it simply ceases to deposit money
with other banks or borrows in the market.
1
Apart from interest rates being very low due to central bank intervention, banks did
not want to encourage large deposits from other banks because this would increase the
amount they need to retain as equity reserves. See Chapter 16 for more on bank reserve
requirements.
The loans in this market are not secured with collateral. However, the rate of
interest is relatively low because those accepting deposits (borrowers) are respect-
able and safe banks. The interest rate charged to the safest banks creates the
benchmark (reference) interest rate, e.g. Libor – explained below. Banks with
lower respectability and safety will have to pay more than the benchmark rates
set by the safest institutions.
Interest rates
In the financial pages of serious newspapers you will find a bewildering variety
of interest rates quoted from all over the world. Following is an explanation of
some of the terms in common use.
Libor
Libor or LIBOR, the London InterBank Offered Rate, is the most commonly
used benchmark rate, in particular the three-month Libor rate, which is the
interest rate for one bank lending to another (very safe) bank for a fixed
three-month period. Obviously these lending deals are private arrangements
between the two banks concerned, but we can get a feel for the rates being
charged by surveying the leading banks involved in these markets. This is done
every trading day. Libor, and other such benchmark interest rates, are crucial
to an economy and its citizens, as benchmark rates are used to set rates for loans,
mortgages, savings accounts, etc. It is therefore imperative that confidence in
the validity of benchmark rates is maintained. A small change in a benchmark
rate has the ability to affect millions of financial products, from one person’s
small hire purchase loan on a washing machine to a corporate’s billion dollar
loan for expansion. London’s historical and current preeminent position in
the financial world has seen Libor used as a benchmark interest rate not only
in the UK but also in many other countries, where an interest rate might be
quoted as Libor plus a few basis points, with universal comprehension of
what this means.
Until 2013 the official Libor rates were calculated by Thomson Reuters for
the British Banking Association (BBA) by asking a panel of 23 UK and inter-
national banks at what rates they could borrow money in unsecured loans of
various maturities. The size of the panel for a particular currency varied from 7
(e.g. New Zealand dollar) to 18 (e.g. US dollar). For sterling it was (and is) 16.
Contributor banks were (and still are) asked to base their Libor submissions on
the question:
At what rate could you borrow funds, were you to do so by asking for
and then accepting interbank offers in a reasonable market size just prior
to 11 am?
The rates from the submitting banks were ranked in order from the highest
to the lowest and the average of only the middle two quartiles was taken,
i.e. with 16 submitting, the top four and bottom four quoted each day were
removed and then the middle eight rates were averaged to calculate Libor.
The Libor figures appeared on millions of computer screens around the world
each day at midday (now around 11.45am).
For over two decades the BBA produced Libor interest rates for borrowing
in ten currencies with a range of 15 maturities from overnight (borrowing for
24 hours) to 12 months quoted for each currency, producing 150 rates each
business day, even though many of them might be based on actual loans only
occasionally. The rates are expressed as an annual rate even though the loans
may be for only one day, a few days or weeks, e.g. if an overnight sterling rate
from a contributor bank is given as 2.00000%, this does not indicate that a
contributing bank would expect to pay 2% interest on the value of an over-
night loan. Instead, it means that it would expect to pay 2% divided by 365.
Following the Libor scandal (see below) it was decided that there was not
enough data to keep calculating 150 benchmarks and those rarely used were
open to manipulation; for some, such as 9-month sterling, a big bank may do
50 borrowing deals per year, but nevertheless had to submit a new estimate
every day. The less frequently used currencies/maturities have been dropped,
resulting in a more manageable 35 rates per day, 7 maturities in 5 currencies.
The data shown in Table 8.2 is for those currencies and maturities that are
currently available.
Because the Libor rate is calculated in different currencies, its influence is spread
worldwide, and is particularly used in dollar lending outside the US. In all, Libor
is used to price around £200 trillion of financial products; for comparison, the
output of all UK citizens in one year (GDP) is around £1.5 trillion. Remarkably,
about 90% of US commercial and mortgage loans are thought to be linked to
the Libor rates, usually 2–3% over Libor.
Libor scandal
The fact that Libor was not necessarily based on actual transactions because
there were simply not enough lending transactions in each of the currencies/
maturities every day meant that a bank was asked to ‘estimate’ or to ‘predict
accurately’ the correct rate for currencies or maturities based on its knowledge
of its credit and liquidity risk profile. The inability to base many Libors on
recorded loans gave all the leeway needed for unscrupulous bankers to mani-
pulate the reported rate to further their own ends. This led to the now infamous
Libor scandal and fines imposed on the banks involved amounting to billions.
Up to 20 banks and a number of brokers are involved in investigations in
Europe, America and Asia.
There were two main elements to the manipulative behaviour. First, the value
of billions of pounds/dollars’ worth of derivatives is determined by the level of
Libor. If derivative traders could persuade those in their bank (and in some
of the other banks) who had responsibility to submit daily Libor rates to
change the submission slightly, they could make a fortune on the movements
in derivatives. With the huge values involved in derivative trading, a differ-
ence of a few pips (one-hundredth of 1%) had the potential to make (or lose)
huge amounts of money. From 2005 on (and perhaps earlier) rate submitters
were regularly cajoled, bribed and leant on to do the derivative guys a favour
– and some senior bankers encouraged this. It was an international game,
with many interlocking personal relationships in the very small world of rate
submitters and derivatives traders located in the major financial centres.
Within this web, an alternative way of making money illegally using derivatives
was for traders to receive advanced word on which direction rates would move.
It wasn’t just banks; some interdealer brokers, who facilitate derivative trades
between banks, also came under investigation for coordinating manipulation.
Second, following the financial crisis of 2007–2008, banks did not want to
appear weak. A clear sign of weakness, and therefore seeming to be a higher
risk, is for a bank to admit that it has to borrow from other banks at high inter-
est rates. Thus, the rate submitters were leant on to ‘lowball’ their submissions
to make the banks appear healthier than they really were. Admittedly, there
was so little confidence in banks generally at that time that actual tangible
interbank lending became very thin, if not completely shut down, and so sub-
mitters frequently had to fall back on their judgement of what they might have
to pay to borrow ‘were you to do so’. They were caught out by email records
showing that, far from merely using good judgement about what rate the bank
might have to pay, they were deliberately underestimating borrowing rates to
fool outsiders – they falsified.
An insider’s view
In the tight-knit world of interest rate derivatives and Libor submissions, the
bankers know each other by first name, regularly phoning, texting, messaging
and emailing. They were ridiculed in the press as crass money-obsessed shallow
people. Their confidence and bonuses knew no bounds at a time when millions
suffered in a recession created by greedy bankers, an image that was not helped
by the email correspondence made public, for example:
● ‘Dude, I owe you big time! Come over one day after work and I’m opening a
bottle of Bollinger.’ In response to a manipulation of USD Libor.
● ‘When I write a book about this business your name will be written in golden
letters.’
● ‘If you keep the 6s [the six-month yen Libor rate] unchanged today . . . I need
you to keep it as low as possible . . . if you do that . . . I’ll pay you . . . I’m a man
of my word.’
● ‘It’s just amazing how Libor-fixing can make you that much money or lose it if
opposite. It’s a cartel now in London.’
The response from bank leadership was interesting. Here is a quote from
The Economist:2
Risibly, Bob Diamond, [Barclays] chief executive, who resigned on July 3rd
as a result of the scandal, retorted in a memo to staff that ‘on the majority
of days, no requests were made at all’ to manipulate the rate. This was rather
like an adulterer saying that he was faithful on most days.’
2
‘Briefing: The LIBOR scandal.’ The Economist, 7 July 2012, 25–27.
Article 8.1
Source: Masters, B., Binham, C. and Scannell, K. (2012) Daily fix that spiralled out of control,
Financial Times, 19 December.
© The Financial Times Limited 2012. All Rights Reserved.
ICE began its role on 1 February 2014 and issued its first ICE Libor rates on
3 February – see Article 8.2. Note the determination to move away from rates
based on theoretical loans to actual lending agreements.
Article 8.2
The US derivatives exchange has also appointed André Villeneuve, a senior City
executive, as chairman of the ICE subsidiary that will collate and monitor the data
submitted by banks.
The handover of administration to ICE from the British Bankers’ Association
will mark the first steps to rehabilitate the benchmark, which has been tarnished
after allegations it has been manipulated by banks around the world. More than
€2bn has been collected in fines by regulators after a string of financial institutions,
including RBS, UBS and Barclays settled charges.
ICE has been in line to run the process since its purchase of NYSE Liffe, the London
derivatives exchange, in November. NYSE won the contract to replace the BBA
last year. It plans to move calculation of the benchmark away from the theoretical
price quotes submitted by banks to a fixing based on real transactions.
However, ICE said there would be no immediate change to the calculation of Libor.
The group is currently moving the technology platform from a NYSE-owned system
to one overseen by ICE.
The IBA continues to administer Libor in much the same way as the BBA, with
a panel of banks submitting seven different maturity rates for five currencies:
the US dollar (USD), the British pound (GBP), the euro (EUR), the Swiss franc
(CHF) and the Japanese yen (JPY). The highest and lowest 25% of submissions
are removed and the remainder averaged to give each rate. This trimming of
the top and bottom quartiles allows for the exclusion of outliers (potentially
freakishly extreme numbers) from the final calculation.
The submitting banks for each currency are shown in Table 8.3. IBA asks the
panel banks to inform Thomson Reuters of the rates they might be asked for
if they were to borrow using the same question that the BBA employed. The
rates are published and distributed by the ICE Benchmark Administration.
The www.global-rates.com website, run for IBA, shows Libor rates updated
daily at around 6pm (CET) so that those of us without the expensive computer
systems showing the 11.45am postings can also see the rates.
The current system tries to place more emphasis on actual market transactions,
but frequently this is not possible due to lack of lending that day for that
particular maturity and currency, especially problematic in times of market
turmoil. Then the IBA allows the submitters to use ‘qualitative criteria’ and
‘expert judgement’ to estimate the rate they would be charged should they
Santander UK plc ✴ ✴
UBS AG ✴ ✴ ✴ ✴ ✴
borrow. ICE would like to move to a system that also takes into account
interest rates in the commercial paper and certificates of deposits markets – see
Article 8.3. There are voices saying that the compromise of allowing estimates
alongside actual rates is not going far enough, that all submissions should be
on actual deals – see Article 8.4. Other prominent people such as regulators
ponder whether it is best to move towards two systems running in parallel, and
this is something which the new administrator, ICE Benchmarks Limited,
and the FCA will have to resolve.
Article 8.3
Source: Stafford, P. (2014) Intercontinental Exchange unveils plans for Libor reform,
Financial Times, 20 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Article 8.4
Regulators are keen to ensure that benchmarks are rooted in real market trans-
actions rather than just bank submissions which, since the Libor scandal, are seen
as susceptible to manipulation.
‘None of the administrators has completed an analysis of methodologies to provide
a basis for deciding whether the submissions are anchored in that market,’ Iosco
said.
The group gave administrators until the end of the year to set out concrete steps to
address this issue.
Iosco’s report comes shortly after Intercontinental Exchange, which took over
the administration of Libor this year, began asking banks for internal transaction
data and also started testing a new system to collect and validate rates the banks
submit.
Major reference interest rates such as Libor, Euribor and Tibor should be ‘to the
greatest extent possible’ based on actual trade data, the Financial Stability Board
said in an additional report on Tuesday.
The FSB also called on market participants to investigate the feasibility of develop-
ing alternative, fully transaction-data based reference rates.
Source: Schäfer, D. (2014) Regulators warn on Libor reform, Financial Times, 22 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Now that Libor is no longer calculated for the Australian dollar (nor NZ or
Canadian dollars or Danish and Swedish krona) the Australians have decided
to obtain interbank rates from market transactions – see Article 8.5. Bank bills
are discussed in Chapter 11.
Article 8.5
‘Building on the advantage of BBSW being based on a traded market, AFMA pro-
poses to bypass the panel requirement by adopting a process to extract these rates
directly from trading venues – brokers and electronic markets. This proposal has
the support of market participants,’ it said in a statement.
The BBSW is the Australian equivalent of the scandal-plagued London InterBank
Offered Rate (Libor) and is used to set interest payments on floating rate securities,
derivatives and Australian dollar-denominated loans.
The decision to take rates directly from the market, rather than from submissions,
comes after two more banks – Citigroup and HSBC – said they would no longer
contribute to the BBSW panel. JPMorgan and UBS withdrew earlier this year.
Banks are quitting rate-setting panels around the world because of tougher scrutiny
and a rise in compliance costs brought about by the Libor scandal.
Banks which contribute to the process in the UK will be required to corroborate their
submissions and appoint a specific person to take charge of compliance with the
new rules.
Australia’s BBSW rate differs from Libor in that panellists are asked for the actual
rates they observe in the market rather than an indicative quote.
Source: Hume, N. (2013) Australia to use market prices for Libor, Financial Times,
27 March.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Article 8.6
Source: Schäfer, D. (2013) UBS joins exodus from Euribor panel, Financial Times, 19 March.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Eonia
Eonia or EONIA (Euro OverNight Index Average) is the effective overnight
rate for the euro, a ‘one-day Euribor’. It is computed as a weighted average of
all overnight unsecured lending transactions in the interbank market initiated
within the European Union and European Free Trade Association (EFTA) coun-
tries by the same 26 panel banks as for Euribor. It is calculated by the European
Central Bank. Figure 8.2 and Article 8.7 illustrate the dramatic effect of the
financial crisis and the long recession on Eonia, with policy makers pushing
down interest rates: before 2008 Eonia remained in the range of 2–6%, today it
hovers just above zero.
Article 8.7
Source: Thompson, C. and Moore, E. (2014) Eurozone borrowing costs hit record low,
Financial Times, 12 August.
© The Financial Times 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Fed funds interest rate – borrowing in the US – and the overnight US dollar
Libor rate – borrowing in the UK – are usually very close to each other because
they are near-perfect substitutes. If they were not close then a bank could make
a profit borrowing in one overnight market and depositing the money in
another. If the US dollar Libor rate is significantly higher, banks needing to
borrow will tend to do so in the Fed funds market and the increased demand
will push up interest rates here, while the absence of demand will encourage
lower rates in the US dollar Libor market. Having said that, they are not perfect
substitutes: the Fed funds rate tends to be slightly lower than US dollar Libor
because of the greater safety in the US with the Federal Reserve overseeing and
backing up the debt market, including deposit insurance. Thus the arbitrage
opportunity is really about the risk premium in London over the Fed funds
rate, but the risk premium is usually pretty small.
The Federal Reserve created vast amounts of new money by buying about
$3 trillion of bonds over the five years to 2014. It funded this by creating
bank reserves. Now that banks have plenty of reserves, interbank lending has
reduced dramatically. This has distorted the Fed funds rate and interrupted
the normal mechanism for adjusting interest rates through central bank inter-
vention (discussed further in Chapter 16). Article 8.8 considers the possibility
of using other measures of short-term dollar borrowing as benchmarks.
Article 8.8
Source: Harding, R. (2014) Fed explores overhaul of key rate, Financial Times, 10 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
The US prime rate is the short-term interest rate US banks charge their
best corporate customers. An average is taken from the largest US banks – the
most well known is the prime rate calculated by The Wall Street Journal. In
approximate terms it is around 3% more than the Fed funds rate. It is used as
a benchmark for other loans, e.g. consumer credit loan interest rates are often
set at so-many basis points above the prime rate, as are credit cards, home
equity loans and lines of credit and auto loans. Many small business loans are
also indexed to the prime rate.
Eurocurrency
Eurocurrency has a large part to play in the interbank market as well as other
lending/borrowing markets. The terms Eurocurrency, Eurodollar, Euroyen,
Euroswissfrancs, etc. have nothing to do with the actual euro currency.
Their name simply means that the currency is deposited and lent outside the
jurisdiction of the country that issued the currency. For example, an Australian
company might make a deposit in yen in a German bank; this would be a
3
Just to confuse everybody, traders in this market often refer to all types of Eurocurrency,
from Eurosterling to Euroyen, as Eurodollars, and do not reserve the term for US dollars.
Eurocredit is used for the market in medium- and long-term loans in the
Euromarkets, with lending rates usually linked to (a few basis points above)
the Libor rates. Loans greater than six months normally have interest rates
that are reset every three or six months depending on the Libor rate then pre-
vailing for, say, three-month lending. So a corporate borrower with a two-year
loan that starts off paying three-month Libor plus 150 basis points when
three-month Libor is 3% pays 4.5%. This is expressed as an annual rate – the
borrower will pay only one-quarter of this for three months. If, at the start of
the next three months, the three-month Libor rate has moved to 3.45%, the
corporate will pay 4.95% (annual rate) for three months. Interest on deposits
of more than one year is likely to be paid on an annual or six-monthly basis.
● The finance available in these markets can be at a lower cost in both trans-
action costs and rates of return offered. There are economies of scale due
to the wholesale nature of the market. The absence of withholding tax on
interest and anonymity encourage lenders to offer lower rates.
● There are fewer rules and regulations, such as needing to obtain official
authorisation to issue or needing to queue to issue, leading to speed,
innovation and lower costs.
● There may be the ability to hedge foreign currency movements. For example,
if a firm has assets denominated in a foreign currency it can be advantageous
to also have liabilities in that same currency to reduce the adverse impact of
exchange rate movements.
● The borrowing needs of some firms are simply too large for their domestic
markets to supply. To avoid being hampered in expansion plans, large firms
can turn to the international market in finance.
The Eurocurrency market allows countries and corporations to lend and borrow
funds worldwide, picking the financial institution which is the most suitable
regardless of geographic position. While the world economy is thriving, this
works well. However, some spectacular problems were highlighted in 2008.
For example, Iceland’s financial institutions found themselves in trouble after
much of their borrowing in the international debt markets suddenly dried up.
The Eurodollar market has become so deep and broad that it now sets interest
rates back in the mother country of the dollar. A very large proportion of
US domestic commercial loans and commercial paper interest rates are set at
a certain number of basis points above US dollar Libor rates determined by
banks operating out of London.
Treasury bills
Throughout the world, government agencies issue Treasury bills (T-bills or
Treasury notes).1 They do not pay a coupon; the return investors receive is the
difference between the purchase price and the selling/redemption price – they
trade at a discount to their face value, and the discount reflects the current rate
of interest on similar securities. They are negotiable securities, which means
that they can easily be traded in the secondary market and thus easily liqui-
dated to release cash. They can be one of the most risk-free forms of investing
(if you are lending to financially stable governments), but pay a lower return
for this reason. T-bills form by far the largest part of the money markets and are
generally issued at auction through a national government agency.
UK Treasury bills
In the UK Treasury bills were first issued by the Bank of England in the early
1700s, when the UK adopted the concept of money as an amount written
on a piece of paper, rather than a piece of metal with intrinsic value. They are
now issued at weekly tenders by the Debt Management Office (DMO) with a
face value or par value of £100 and are sold with a maturity date of one month
(approximately 28 days), three months (approximately 91 days), six months
(approximately 182 days) or twelve months (up to 364 days).2 At each tender,
the DMO publishes the type and amount of bills to be offered the following
week. Bills are initially sold by competitive tender to cash management
1
In Germany and Austria, a Treasury bill is called a Schatzwechsel; in Russia a Gosudarstvennoe
Kratkosrochnoe Obyazatelstvo (GKO); and in France and Canada a Bons du Trésor.
2
In theory 12-month bills can be issued, but to date none has yet been offered for sale.
Table 9.1 shows the results from the four sales of Treasury bills which took
place weekly during March 2014, on the 7th, 14th, 21st and 28th. Note that
the issues occurred every few days as the government borrowed more money
or simply replaced maturing debt. Table 9.2 shows the Financial Times tender
results table for the three-month T-bills on 14 and 21 March 2014.
Tenders are held by the DMO on the last business day of each week (i.e. usually
on Fridays), for settlement (paid for) on the following business day, usually
Monday. The redemption date is the day when the face value of the bill (£100)
will be paid to the holder. The T-bills issued at tenders mature on the first busi-
ness day of the week. The nominal amount is the total amount of the face
value of the bills offered at the tender (not what was actually paid for them).
Table 9.1 DMO Treasury bill tender results, 1 March 2014 to 31 March 2014
1 month
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 07-Apr-14 2,000 2.21 0.393578 99.969817
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 14-Apr-14 2,000 3.30 0.364505 99.972046
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 22-Apr-14 2,000 1.85 0.381211 99.969721
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 28-Apr-14 2,000 1.62 0.407344 99.968761
3 months
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 09-Jun-14 1,500 2.64 0.363186 99.909534
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 16-Jun-14 2,000 3.09 0.379104 99.905573
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 23-Jun-14 2,000 1.95 0.390464 99.902746
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 30-Jun-14 2,000 1.51 0.421457 99.895035
6 months
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 08-Sep-14 1,500 2.87 0.409168 99.796392
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 15-Sep-14 1,500 3.23 0.394030 99.803910
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 22-Sep-14 1,500 2.17 0.400866 99.800515
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 29-Sep-14 1,500 1.70 0.422876 99.789585
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
Table 9.2 UK three-month Treasury bill tender results in the Financial Times
Highest acpt yield 0.4180% 0.3850% Offer at next tender £2000m £2000m
About allocated 88.10% 75.95% Highest acpt yield 28 days 0.4170% 0.3650%
The bid to cover ratio is the ratio of the amount that was actually bid to the
amount of T-bills offered; if the number is greater than 1 it shows that there
were more bids than the amount on offer. Although extremely rare it is not
unknown for an offer to be undersubscribed3 – it is a sign of lack of confidence
in the government’s financial situation and/or indigestion in a market faced
with an exceptionally high volume of government borrowing.
Treasury bills in March 2014 yielded a rate as low as 0.364505% for one month
T-bills, 0.363186% for 3M T-bills and 0.394030% for 6M T-bills (Table 9.1). The
average price is the average of the price handed over by bidders for bills which
will pay the holders of the bills £100 in one month, three months or six
months.
3
This has happened only twice for UK Treasury bills, both times in 2008, with a six-month
bill offered for sale in October and a three-month bill offered for sale in May.
The DMO published results for the tender on the 21 March for the 23 June
bill are shown in Table 9.3. From this it can be noted that the bill was over-
tendered by a factor of 1.95, i.e. the amount on offer was £2 billion (at face
value), there were actual bids offered totalling nearly £4 billion and about 88%
of the bidders achieved the highest yield of 0.418%.
During the life of the bill, its value fluctuates daily as it is traded between inves-
tors – see Table 9.4, which gives the daily March and April 2014 figures for this
particular bill. The yield shown is the (annual) return that a purchaser in the
secondary market will achieve between purchase date and maturity date. Note:
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
Table 9.4 Daily trading prices for Treasury bill GB00B7P4VP73, 21 March to 16 April
2014
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
the price gravitates towards par value as the day of maturity draws nearer
because on redemption day, 23 June 2014, the holder will receive the face
value of £100.
4
Not yet fully developed economies.
US Treasury bills
US Treasury bills are sold by Treasury Direct (www.treasurydirect.gov), which
is part of the US Department of the Treasury. They range in maturity from a
few days to 52 weeks, with 4-week (28 days), 13-week (91 days) and 26-week
(182 days) bills being the most common. They are sold at a discount to par
value by auction every week, except for the 52-week bills which are auctioned
every 4 weeks. The buyers include securities’ houses, banks, institutional
investors and private investors. The bidders can bid for the bills in two ways
(they have to choose one route or the other at the outset):
Source: www.treasurydirect.gov
All bidders, competitive and non-competitive, receive the same discount rate,
and therefore the same yield, as the highest accepted bid and so pay the same
amount for their bills (contrasting with UK bills, where bidders pay the
amount at which they tendered).
Individuals may bid and the minimum purchase is a lowly $100, unlike in the
UK where the minimum bid is £500,000 and individuals may not bid them-
selves but hold UK Treasury bills only through one of the approved bidders.
Table 9.5 gives the results of US T-bill auctions held during March 2014. US
T-bill interest is calculated on an actual/360 annual basis.
Commercial paper
Commercial paper (CP) is an unsecured short-term instrument of debt, issued
primarily by corporations, banks and other financial institutions to help meet
the financing requirements of their accounts receivable (debtors), inventories
(stock) and other short-term cash needs, but can also be issued by municipali-
ties. The issue and purchase of commercial paper is one means by which the
largest commercial organisations can avoid paying a bank intermediary a mid-
dleman fee for linking borrower and lender, e.g. corporations can avoid taking
out loans from a bank and go direct to the financial market lenders.
Called ‘paper’ because originally the promissory note was written on a piece of
paper, CP is now more usually dealt with electronically, but is still a promise to
pay the holder the designated sum on the designated date. Buyers include
money market funds, investment firms, mutual funds, insurance companies,
pension funds, governments and banks. Also corporations with temporary
surpluses of cash are able to put that money to use by lending it directly to
other commercial firms at a higher effective rate of interest than they might
have received by depositing the funds in a bank. Investors in CP often buy it
from dealers, which are usually banks. Settlement (actual transfer) is normally
the same day as the deal is struck (known as T+0).
5
A small amount of commercial paper is issued with interest payments, but this is rare.
Large and frequent borrowers may pay issuance costs of merely one or two
basis points. Some companies, such as General Electric, are such frequent issuers
of CP that they employ in-house teams to do the selling – direct placement.
Other issuers ask dealers (usually employed by investment banks) to either buy
the issue with the expectation of selling it on (firm commitment underwrit-
ing) or use ‘their best endeavours’ to find lenders. These two methods are
dealer-directed offers.
Demand is very limited for lower-rated issues. Even moving from Prime-1 to
Prime-2 means much greater difficulty in finding lenders – see Article 9.1.
P-1 Issuers (or supporting institutions) rated Prime-1 have a superior ability to repay
short-term debt obligations.
P-2 Issuers (or supporting institutions) rated Prime-2 have a strong ability to repay short-
term debt obligations.
P-3 Issuers (or supporting institutions) rated Prime-3 have an acceptable ability to repay
short-term obligations.
NP Issuers (or supporting institutions) rated Not Prime do not fall within any of the Prime
rating categories.
Source: www.moodys.com/researchdocumentcontentpage.aspx?docid=PBC_79004
Category Definition
D A short-term obligation rated ‘D’ is in payment default. The ‘D’ rating category
is used when payments on an obligation are not made on the date due,
unless Standard & Poor’s believes that such payments will be made within
any stated grace period. However, any stated grace period longer than five
business days will be treated as five business days. The ‘D’ rating also will be
used upon the filing of a bankruptcy petition or the taking of a similar action if
payments on an obligation are jeopardized.
Source: www.standardandpoors.com/spf/general/
RatingsDirect_Commentary_979212_06_22_2012_12_42_54.pdf
In some countries using credit rating agencies to rate CP is rare, with investors
buying paper on the basis of the strength of the name of the organisation
issuing it – only the largest, most well known and trusted can issue in these
places.
Article 9.1
Source: Lex column (2014) ADP: commercial success, Financial Times, 21 April.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
via a money market fund: the fund buys a range of CP issues (and other instru-
ments) and so, while it is committed to hold each CP to maturity, because it is
well diversified, with many securities maturing every day, it is able to pay out
to money market fund investors when they demand it. The Federal Reserve
Board posts the current rates being paid on US commercial paper by non-
financial and financial firms on its website – see Table 9.8.
Table 9.8 US Federal Reserve Federal funds rate and examples of commercial paper
rates in August 2014, per cent annualised
Federal funds (effective) 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.09 0.07 0.09 0.09 0.09
Commercial paper
Non-financial
Financial
If there is a time when it is difficult to sell the paper to the banks then the
borrower can turn to those banks that have signed up to be underwriters of the
facility to buy the issue, or, depending on the deal, borrow from the bank or
banks in the syndicate. Underwriters take a fee for these guarantees. Most of
the time they do not have to do anything, but occasionally, often when the
market is troubled, they have to step in.
Some people draw a distinction between an NIF and an RUF: with an RUF the
underwriting banks agree to provide loans should the CP/MTN issue fail, but
under an NIF they could either lend or purchase the outstanding CP or notes.
However, these definitions do not seem to be rigidly applied.
By allowing borrowers the choice at each point of borrowing of either drawing
a loan from the bank(s) at an agreed spread over Libor or selling CP/MTN
through banks, the borrower gets the best of both worlds: a bank loan (com-
mitted bank facility) fallback, or access to the financial markets in corporate
debt instruments. Which is chosen depends on interest rates at the time. One-
off fees are payable for arrangement and annual fees for bank participation
(actual lending) and commitment (standing ready to lend).
An insider’s view
Opus plc agrees a £300 million NIF with a bank for six years. This lead bank asks other
banks to join the syndicate. Opus obtains a credit rating for commercial paper that
it might issue. Opus can repay funds drawn down under the NIF at will, without penalty.
Opus decides it would like to borrow £150 million starting in eight days for a six-month
period. It tells the lead bank that it would like either to take a six-month loan at the
rate stated in the NIF loan agreement, which is Libor + 95bp, or to issue CP to a
predetermined syndicate of banks and dealers at the rate currently being offered
by that dealer group. Currently, six-month Libor is 1.4%, thus the loan will cost 2.35%
(annual rate) for six months. The lead bank comes back with the CP interest rate
of 2.56%, so Opus decides to exercise its right under the NIF to borrow the £150
million from the banks. For the remaining five and a half years Opus will have the
right to repay and then take out fresh loans or issue fresh CPs as the need arises.
Really well-known creditworthy issuers can opt to avoid the cost of maintain-
ing the backstop option of access to these loans (arrangement and participa-
tion fees) and simply rely on their ability to periodically attract lenders in the
CP market under the NIF framework, but they still pay for swinglines and
backup. That is, to obtain a credit rating CP issuers must have unused credit
lines from banks to provide liquidity in the event of an interruption to the CP
market preventing rolling over (the issue of new CP as old ones mature).
Swinglines are bank commitments to provide same-day credit facilities to
cover a few days of the CP maturities. Backup lines, sometimes uncommitted,
are available for the longer maturities. There is a variety of liquidity backups
that can be acceptable for this purpose, including cash and securities, but most
CP issuers rely on credit lines from banks.
At least that was the theory, but many conduits and their parent banks disap-
peared or nearly blew up in 2008 when they could not roll over the ABCP as
they were accustomed to doing. When the financial crisis occurred many of these
cash flows dried up, causing major problems for both issuers and holders of CP.
Rolling over CP became difficult, confidence in this market plummeted and com-
panies found it nearly impossible to obtain the CP funding on which they relied.
The commercial paper market can be very influential in corporate life. For
example, in 2005, Standard & Poor’s downgraded the commercial paper
Eurocommercial paper
Eurocommercial paper (Euro-CP) is paper that is issued and placed outside
the jurisdiction of the country in whose currency it is denominated. So an
American corporation might issue commercial paper denominated in Japanese
yen outside of the control of the Japanese authorities and this is classified as
Eurocommercial paper. The most common denominations are the euro, US
dollar and GB pound, and the main place of issue is London.
Because the agreements provide collateral backup for the lender, most often in
the form of government-backed securities such as Treasury bills, the interest rate
is lower than on a typical unsecured loan from a bank. If the borrower defaults
on its obligations to buy back on maturity the lender can hold on to or sell the
securities they bought in the first leg of the repo. In the absence of such a
default if a coupon is payable on bonds during the term of the repo the original
owner receives it, maintaining the same economic exposure to the security as
though the economic ownership had not been sold. Thus, despite legal title to
the securities being transferred, economic benefits and market risk are retained,
so if the price of the security falls in the market it is the original owner who
suffers the capital loss.
Repos have the advantage that they can be tailor-made to suit circumstances
– the maturity can be any number of days and the amount fully variable,
whereas many other forms of lending via financial securities tend to be for
specific amounts and periods of time.
Repos are used very regularly by banks and other financial institutions to
borrow large amounts of money from each other. Secured lending, such as
repo lending, increased in volume following the financial crisis as more banks,
etc. became reluctant to participate in unsecured lending, deeming it too risky.
Companies do use the repo markets, but much less frequently than the banks
do. This market is also manipulated by central banks to manage their mone-
tary policy and maintain stability in their economy (see Chapter 16).
The term for repos is usually between 1 and 14 days, but can be up to a year,
and occasionally there is no end date, an open repo. Overnight repos are the
most common type, where the repurchase takes place the next day. Repos are
useful for institutions holding large quantities of money market securities
such as T-bills. They can gain access to liquidity through the repo for a few
days while maintaining a high level of inventory in short-term securities.
Example 10.1
Repurchase agreement
A high street bank has the need to borrow £26 million for 14 days. It agrees to sell
a portfolio of its financial assets, in this case government bonds, to a lender for £26
million. An agreement is drawn up (a repo) by which the bank agrees to repurchase
the portfolio 14 days later for £26,005,285.48. The extra amount of £5,285.48
represents the repo rate of interest (an annual rate of 0.53%) on £26 million over
14 days.1 The sterling market day count basis is actual/365.
1
The formula for this calculation can be found in Chapter 14.
Example 10.2
Reverse repo
A bank has £45 million of spare cash for one day. A reverse repo agreement is
drawn up, by which the bank agrees to buy £45 million of government securities
from a borrower and sell them back the next day for £45,000,517.81. The extra
amount of £517.81 represents overnight interest on £45 million at an annual rate
of 0.42%.2
Repo deals are usually individually negotiated between the two parties
(bilateral repos) and are therefore designed to suit the length of time of
borrowing and the amount for each of them, thus there is usually little need
for redemption before the agreed date. However, if circumstances change
and the lender needs the money quickly it might be possible to arrange an
off-setting reverse repo transaction.
Traditionally banks formed the largest group of borrowers in the repo markets,
but now, as Article 10.1 makes clear, hedge funds, property funds and mutual
funds have overtaken them.
2
The formula for this calculation can be found in Chapter 14.
Article 10.1
Source: Alloway, T. (2014) Big investors replace banks in $4.2tn repo market, Financial Times,
29 May.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Special collateral repos, ‘specials’, are used extensively in the financial mar-
kets. Here the lender designates a particular security as the only acceptable
collateral. Dealers and others lend money on special collateral repos in order to
borrow specific securities needed to deliver against short sales. Superficially,
this sounds the same as a specific repo. The key difference is that a special has
a repo interest rate that is lower than the GC repo rate. Also there is exceptional
specific demand in the cash market for those particular bonds trading ‘on spe-
cial’. Clearly, not all repo rates with a precisely defined agreed security are
below the GC repo rate. Such issues could be called ‘specifics’ but should not be
called ‘specials’.
To be clear: specials are often used to cover short sales where a dealer sells secur-
ities it does not own but still needs to deliver. It then must obtain the desig-
nated securities through a repo – a stock-driven transaction. It might be so
keen to obtain the securities that it will hand over cash for them, expecting
little extra cash on the second leg in the repo. The interest rate on a special
collateral RP is commonly called a specials rate.
From the perspective of the institution that happens to be holding the desig-
nated securities, it can gain from temporarily selling them through a repo. This
may make sense even if it has no need to borrow money at that time. For exam-
ple, if the specials rate is 1% per annum, money could be borrowed at this rate
using the securities as collateral. This money can then be lent out in the GC
repo market. If the interest rate here is 1.4% then a profit can be achieved on
the interest rate difference.
There are times when the supply of particular securities is limited. Then the
specials rate for the security may be significantly below the general collateral
rate. When interest rates are very low, as in 2014 in the eurozone, the repo
interest can be negative: the cash transferred in the second leg is less than that
in the first.
Benchmarks
In the UK a benchmark for interest charged on repos with a maturity one day
later is arrived at daily by the WMBA by consulting a group of interdealer
brokers on the rates being charged in the market place with lenders and
borrowers who use brokers to transact. The rate is called RONIA or Ronia,
the Repurchase Overnight Index Average. This overnight funding rate is the
weighted average rate to four decimal places of all secured sterling overnight
cash transactions brokered in London by contributing WMBA member firms
between midnight and 4.15pm with all counterparties regardless of deal size.
The weighting is according to the principal amount of deposits which were
taken on that day. The gilts bought and repurchased for these deals are deliv-
ered via the settlement system called CREST. The borrowing member has gilts
on its account to the required value delivered automatically to the CREST
account of the money lender. Some advocates believe that Ronia has the poten-
tial to take over from the interbank rate in providing the ‘risk-free’ interest
benchmark – after all, it has collateral backup whereas Libor does not, and
it is based on actual transactions.
Source: www.repofundsrate.com/overview.htm#
showing average repo rates combining general collateral and specific collateral
trades. Note that average interest rates are below zero for three indices. In other
words, for a proportion of these deals market participants are willing to pay
interest on money they lend. The market makers and other dealers are using
the repo market to borrow bonds that are in strong demand in the cash market
(and therefore sometimes scarce) in order to fulfil delivery commitments on
sales of those bonds in the cash market.
The STOXX® GC Pooling index is a benchmark for secured euro lending trans-
actions and binding quotations that take place on the Eurex Repo GC Pooling
Market. These range from overnight to 12-month terms. Eurex Repo also
organises a Swiss Franc Repo Market for financial institutions to borrow and
lend in the interbank repo market. A wide range of high-quality fixed-income
securities apart from government bonds and bills is accepted by the market
participants with terms from intraday up to 12 months.
In America, the Depository Trust and Clearing Corporation DTCC GCF Repo
Indices track the average daily interest rate paid for the most-traded repo con-
tracts for the sale and repurchase of (1) US Treasury bills, (2) federal agency
securities and (3) mortgage-backed securities (MBS) issued by Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac. Table 10.2 shows the extraordinarily low rates on 9 September
2014 – less than 0.1% per annum. Figure 10.1 tracks how US repo rates changed
over a year – the lowest line is for the strongest collateral, Treasury bonds and
bills, the middle line is for federal agency securities and the highest line is for
mortgage-backed securities. Figure 10.2 displays the amount borrowed: bil-
lions every day. The interest on dollar repos is based on actual number of days
of the deal divided into a 360-day year.
In the US, the Federal Reserve of New York section known as The Desk uses
repos and reverse repos for monetary policy, adding or draining reserves of
Table 10.2 US repo rates as reported by the Depository Trust and Clearing
Corporation for 9 September 2014
cash to and from the banking system. Repos and reverse repos are arranged by
auction among the 21 primary dealers and the 49 reverse repo counterparties
approved by the Fed, all of them respected banking/broking institutions. Both
primary dealers and reverse repo counterparties must have substantial assets.
In 2014 the Fed embarked on greater intervention in the repo market so that it
could influence short-term interest rates as the economic recovery took hold
– see Article 10.2.
Article 10.2
When official short-term rates are eventually pushed higher, the Fed plans to use
the RRP to drain cash from the financial system via short-term loans of Treasuries
from its huge balance sheet.
Robert Grossman, managing director at Fitch, said the change in the Fed’s pre-
sence in the repo market had been dramatic and that the central bank could use
RRP to significantly escalate its role.
Source: Alloway, T. and Mackenzie, M. (2014) New York Federal Reserve takes on key role in
repo market, Financial Times, 19 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Haircuts
Although the securities bought and sold are considered relatively safe collat-
eral for the lender of the cash, there is always the danger that the price of the
bills, etc. might fluctuate during the period of the agreement to the detriment
of the buyer who is committed to a pre-agreed selling price. The buyer might
also be exposed to illiquidity risk and counterparty risk related to the securities
bought. Therefore it is common practice to impose a haircut on the collateral,
where the seller receives the amount of cash secured on the collateral less a
margin (over-collateralisation). If the haircut were 2%, the seller of a £200 mil-
lion repo would receive £196,000,000 cash in return for £200 million worth of
securities. The repo interest is only applied to the lesser amount.
Another way of looking at this is that if a bank wanted to own £200 million of
gilts it would only be necessary to find £4 million of cash. The other £196 mil-
lion could be borrowed in the repo market by using the £200 million of gilts as
security.
Article 10.3 discusses some new rules on minimum haircuts. If the market
value of the collateral drops by a larger amount or percentage than an agreed
threshold during the term, the lender might be entitled to variation margin.
This is a call for extra cash or collateral to be handed over.
Article 10.3
The FSB now wants a minimum 1.5% ‘haircut’ for corporate bonds with a maturity
of between one and five years, up from 1% before, and a 6% haircut for equities,
instead of 4% previously. The latter would mean that a borrower would have to
post $106 of equity collateral for a $100 loan.
The FSB also set out non-numerical standards aimed at tackling the risk that hair-
cuts get whittled away in benign market conditions. Mark Carney, chairman of the
FSB and Bank of England governor, said the rules marked a ‘big step forward’ in
the global shadow banking agenda.
Daniel Tarullo, chairman of the FSB Standing Committee on Supervisory and
Regulatory Co-operation, added: ‘Securities financing transactions such as repos
are important funding tools for a wide range of market participants, including non-
bank financial firms.
‘The implementation of the numerical haircut floors on securities financing trans-
actions will reduce the build-up of excessive leverage and liquidity risk by non-
banks during peaks in the credit and economic cycle.’
The FSB stressed that market participants should continue to set higher haircuts
than the official requirements where prudent. The FSB said firms had expected
only a ‘minimal’ impact on market volume from its proposals.
The FSB added that the haircut floors could in future be raised and lowered as part
of efforts to lean against fluctuations in the financial cycle, but that this would
require further work.
The repo market has already been under pressure from new rules that make it
more expensive for banks to broker the transactions or undertake their own repo
borrowing. While many in the market concede that runs in the repo market were a
prime cause of Lehman Brothers’ collapse in 2008, they also warn that limiting the
repo market could affect liquidity in a long list of financial assets.
Source: Fleming, S. and Alloway, T. (2014) Terms laid down for taming shadow bank risk,
Financial Times, 14 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Tri-party repo
Many repo markets are based on bilateral deals between borrower and lender.
But a common form in the US is the tri-party repo (TPR), where an interme-
diary, a custodian, acts for both seller and purchaser and undertakes all admin-
istrative tasks. There are two custodian banks, Bank of New York Mellon and
JPMorgan, which help to administer a repo agreement between two parties.
Lenders place money with the custodian bank, which in turn lends it through
a repo to another institution. Such a model functions well when liquid assets
such as Treasuries are being used, as this type of collateral can easily be sold.
During the credit boom, which peaked in the first half of 2007, the type of
collateral being pledged for cash in repo transactions steadily migrated away
from Treasuries and towards other assets such as private label mortgages, cor-
porate bonds and equities. This reflected the drive by investors to boost their
returns, gaining higher interest when lending against poorer quality collateral.
Tri-party was very popular with investment banks as it allowed them to finance
their balance sheets with short-term funding. However, as soon as market sen-
timent turned negative on lower-quality or more complex assets, investors
that had funded these repo agreements began to pull their money out. That
sparked a run on the investment banks. The vulnerabilities of this system were
highlighted with the near-failure of Bear Stearns six months before Lehman’s
demise. Article 10.4 illustrates the concerns of US authorities about the TPR
market.
Article 10.4
‘This is a process that’s providing credit from one part of the market to another,’
said Martin Hansen, senior director at Fitch Ratings. ‘But the issue is that at one
end of this chain of credit you have risk averse, short-term lenders. If they have
concerns, then that can create ripple effects along the rest of the chain and beyond.’
Fitch estimates that the use of interest rate-sensitive securities such as US
Treasuries and other US government-backed securities as collateral in the tri-party
repo market fell $187bn between May and July, after the Fed began talking about
winding down its emergency economic support. That suggests sell-offs in the repo
market remain an issue more than five years after the crisis.
‘The risk is that once a dealer [bank] goes under, money funds have to liquidate the
securities they hold and a money fund may not have the expertise to liquidate large
amounts of securities,’ said Scott Skyrm, a former repo broker.
The New York Fed has overseen reform of the tri-party repo market in recent years,
with a heavy focus on the role played by the two custodian banks that incur daily
counterparty risk, JPMorgan Chase and Bank of New York Mellon.
While dependence on so-called ‘intraday credit’ from the two banks, along with
poor liquidity and credit risk management practices by the banks, has largely been
addressed, the spectre of fire sales remains an issue for regulators.
Regulators also point to a lack of data concerning the bilateral repo market, which
operates in a similar way but without custodians. Estimates of the market’s size
vary from about $3tn to $5tn, and a report from the Office of Financial Research this
week warned of ‘data gaps’ in securities lending and repo markets.
Friday’s meeting organised by the New York Fed will bring together academics,
market participants and other regulators. Speakers are expected to discuss ways of
setting up ‘a process for orderly liquidation’ of repo collateral.
Source: Mackenzie, M. and Alloway, T. (2013) Repo ‘fire sale’ risk worries regulators,
Financial Times, 2 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Whereas in the UK, US and many other developed countries repo rates are
currently low, typically between 0% and 1%, in other parts of the world the
rate can be considerably higher. The rates reflect the risk element, anticipated
current and future degree of inflation, and the credit rating in each country –
see Figure 10.3.
The sell/buy-back
Some countries, such as Italy, never developed, or were slow to develop, the
legal frameworks, IT systems and settlement systems for repo transactions. The
sell/buy-back was created instead, which is very similar to a repo but involves
an outright cash sale of bonds, and a separate agreement to buy back the bonds
at a forward date. Coupon payments during the term are paid first to the buyer
and only given to the original owner on termination.
short-term CDs also occasionally pay variable interest rates, e.g. the interest on
a 6-month CD changes every 30 days depending on interbank interest rates.
Those dated for over one year have interest paid annually, or sometimes semi-
annually; they may also pay a variable rate of interest, with the rate altered,
say, each year, based on the rates on a benchmark rate, e.g. Libor.
Lot sizes are generally $100,000 to $1,000,000 in the US for the main wholesale
market, with similar sized lots in the eurozone, Japan and other countries. In
the US, however, CDs are frequently bought by retail investors in denomina-
tions that can go as low as $100. Individuals generally buy non-negotiable
CDs because the minimum denomination for a negotiable CD is $100,000
(also termed a jumbo CD). Most retail-focused CDs are guaranteed by the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) for up to $250,000 per depositor,
meaning that if the issuing bank does not redeem them this government-
sponsored agency will. For US CDs the interest is calculated on an actual/360
basis, with the interest generally paid at maturity.
Quotations
CDs are quoted in the trading markets on a yield to maturity basis. So, if a
deposit of £100,000 is made and a CD is handed over which states that after
one-quarter of the year the holder will receive £100,500, the yield to maturity
is £500 divided by £100,000 multiplied by 4 to annualise it. Thus the annual
rate of interest is 2%. (See Chapter 14 for more on CD calculations.)
Many CDs issued today lack a paper certificate, which, given that ‘certificate’
is in the title, seems a little oxymoronic. These ‘dematerialised’ CDs are held
as electronic book entries only. Euroclear operates a book entry system in
London. Here CDs are issued and transferred using Delivery Versus Payment
(DVP), meaning that the electronic transfer of ownership in the secondary
market is at the same time as payment.
Eurocurrency CDs
As well as domestic currency CDs there are Eurocurrency certificates of
deposit, Euro-CDs, outside the jurisdiction of the authorities of the currency
of denomination. Standard Eurocurrency deposits (not CDs) have fixed
maturities – say seven days – and you cannot get at that money until the seven
days have passed. By issuing Eurodollar CDs banks are able to offer an advan-
tage if those CDs are negotiable, by allowing depositors to sell the CDs to other
investors before maturity. Those issued by a bank with a high credit standing
are likely to have greater liquidity. Eurodollar CDs tend to offer higher yields
than CDs issued in dollars in the US because the American-based CDs have the
backing of the Federal Reserve regulatory environment for banks, making
them safer for investors.
Bills of exchange and banker’s acceptances are instruments that are particu-
larly useful in helping to oil the wheels of international commerce. They enable
corporations to obtain credit from suppliers or raise money, and also to trade
with foreign corporations at low risk of financial inconvenience or loss. An
illustration of the risk problem is provided in the following example.
Example 11.1
The international trade problem
Tractors UK has found a firm in South Africa that wishes to buy £12 million worth
of its tractors. Tractors UK cannot simply send its tractors to South Africa in the
hope that the payment will be sent, nor can the South African firm send £12 million
in the hope that the tractors will be sent. The two companies do not know each
other well enough to trust that the transaction will be carried out correctly on
each side. The solution is to use a bill of exchange or a banker’s acceptance, which
will provide a legally enforceable promise of payment of £12 million to Tractors UK,
which can send the tractors off to South Africa, knowing with a high degree of
certainty that payment will be made.
Bills of exchange
Bills of exchange have been used to smooth the progress of overseas trade for
a long time. Known to have been used by the Babylonians, Egyptians, Greeks
and Romans, the bill of exchange appeared in its present form during the
13th century among the Lombards of northern Italy who engaged in wide-
spread foreign trading. These instruments became particularly useful in the
burgeoning international trade of the 19th and 20th centuries.
At this point the bill of exchange may be forwarded to and accepted by the
customer, which means that the customer signs a promise to pay the stated
amount and currency on the due date (a time draft). The due date is usually
90 days later, but 30-, 60- or 180-day bills of exchange are not uncommon.
However, note that some bills of exchange are sight drafts (‘documents
against payment’ drafts), payable on demand immediately.
More usual is for the bill first to be sent to the exporter’s bank, which, in turn,
sends the draft and the documents to a bank in the importer’s country with
which the exporter’s bank has an ongoing relationship. This correspondent
bank will be instructed to get the draft signed, that is, accepted, by the
importer, or to receive payment in the case of a sight draft. Then the corres-
pondent bank will hand over the bill of lading documents permitting the
importer to claim the goods. With payment on a sight draft the correspondent
bank will transfer the funds received from the importer to the exporter’s bank,
which will credit the exporter’s account. Fees will be charged for facilitating
these transactions. With time bills the exporter will receive a promise to pay in,
say, 90 days.
The banks have reduced the risk for the exporter by ensuring that the goods
are not released to the importer until money or a promise is in place. Also, for
the time draft, there is a legal acknowledgement that a debt exists, facilitating
easier access to the legal systems in the event of non-payment.
As well as the benefit of a potential credit period before paying on a time draft,
risk for the importer is reduced because payment will be made only if the goods
are present and correct with all the documentation.
Despite the simplification of Figure 11.1, many bills of exchange do not remain
in the hands of the discounter until maturity but are traded a number of times
before then.
Bills of exchange are normally used only for large transactions (> £100,000).
The effective interest rate charged by the discounter is usually a competitive
150–400 basis points over interbank lending rates (e.g. Libor). The holder of
the bill usually has recourse to both of the commercial companies: if the
customer does not pay then the seller will be called upon to make good the debt.
This overhanging credit risk for the exporter can sometimes be transferred (to,
say, a bank) by buying credit insurance. If the bill is guaranteed by another
bank or the importer has a very high credit standing it may not carry recourse
rights for the holder to force the exporter to pay.
Banker’s acceptances
A banker’s acceptance, also known as an acceptance credit, is a time draft,
which is a document stating the signatory will pay an amount at a future
date, say in 90 days. Say, for example, that an importer buys goods from an
exporter with an agreement to pay in three months. Instead of sending the
bill to the importer, the exporter is instructed to send the document, which
states that the signatory will pay a sum of money, at a set date in the future,
to the importer’s bank. This is ‘accepted’ by the importer’s bank rather than
by a customer. Simultaneously the importer makes a commitment to pay the
accepting bank the relevant sum at the maturity date of the bill.
The exporter does not have to wait three months to receive cash despite the
importer’s bank not paying out for 90 days. This is because it is possible to sell
this right to investors in the discount market long before the three months are
up. This bank commitment to pay the holder of the banker’s acceptance allows
it to be sold with more credibility in the money markets to, say, another bank
(a discounter) by the exporter after receiving it from an importing company’s
bank. So, say, the acceptance states that €1 million will be paid to the holder
on 1 August. It could be sold to an investor (perhaps another bank) in the
discount market for €980,000 on 15 June. The importer is obliged to reimburse
the bank €1 million (and pay fees) on 1 August; on that date the purchaser
of the acceptance credit collects €1 million from the bank that signed the
acceptance, making a €20,000 return over six weeks.
Not all banker’s acceptances relate to overseas trade. Many are simply a way of
raising money for a firm. The company in need of finance may ask its bank
to create a banker’s acceptance and hand it over. Then the company can sell
it in the discount market at a time when it needs to raise some cash. They are
very useful for companies expanding into new markets where their name is not
known and therefore their creditworthiness is also unknown; they can take
advantage of the superior creditworthiness of the bank issuing the acceptance,
which guarantees that payment will be made.
1 The bank charges acceptance commission for adding its name to the
acceptance.
2 The difference between the face value of the acceptance and the discount
price, which is the effective interest rate.
3 Dealers take a small cut as they connect firms that want to sell with com-
panies that wish to invest in banker’s acceptances.
These costs are relatively low compared with overdraft costs. However, this
facility is available only in hundreds of thousands of pounds, euros, etc. and
then only to the most creditworthy of companies. Figure 11.2 summarises the
acceptance credit sequence for an export deal.
1 Banker’s acceptance drafted and sent by an exporting company (or its bank)
demanding payment for goods sent to an importer’s bank. Importer makes
arrangements with its bank to help it. Acceptance commission paid to the
bank by importer.
2 The bank accepts the promise to pay a sum at a stated future date.
3 The banker’s acceptance may be sold by the exporter at a discount.
4 The discounter pays cash for the banker’s acceptance.
5 The bank pays the final holder of the banker’s acceptance the due sum.
6 The importer pays to the bank the banker’s acceptance due sum.
Example 11.2
The use of a banker’s acceptance
A Dutch company buys €3.5 million of goods from a firm in Japan; it promises to
pay for the goods in 60 days’ time. The Dutch company asks its bank to accept the
banker’s acceptance. Once the bank has stamped ‘accepted’ on the document,
it becomes a negotiable (sellable) instrument. The exporter receives the banker’s
acceptance. After 15 days, the Japanese company decides it needs some extra
short-term finance and sells the acceptance at a discount of 0.60%, receiving
€3,479,000. The exporter has been paid by banker’s acceptance immediately the
goods have been despatched. It can also shield itself from the risk of exchange
rates shifting over the next 60 days by discounting the acceptance immediately,
receiving euros and then converting these to yen. And, of course, the exporter is
not exposed to the credit risk of the importer because it has the guarantee from
the importer’s bank.
Case study
HSBC Canada’s banker’s acceptance service
HSBC Canada advertises banker’s acceptances (BAs) as a good way of raising
money for businesses. Here is a page from its website:
➨
BAs may provide your business with a lower cost borrowing alternative
Most of the rates shown have already been described, but the ‘SDR int rate’
needs some explanation. Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) are a composite
currency created in 1969 by the IMF to act as an international reserve currency
to supplement IMF member countries’ official reserves. Weak IMF members can
sell SDRs to financially strong members, effectively borrowing money from
them via the IMF. The SDR rate of interest is decided weekly and is a weighted
Table 11.1 Market interest rates for 12 September 2014, all annualised rates
US$ Libor* 0.09060 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.15360 0.23410 0.33090 0.58220
Euro Libor* –0.05929 –0.042 –0.033 –0.054 0.00071 0.05000 0.14000 0.29929
£ Libor* 0.47500 – 0.003 0.004 0.50438 0.56025 0.69875 1.04744
Swiss Fr Libor* –0.00600 –0.002 – –0.009 –0.00400 0.00500 0.05140 0.15500
Yen Libor* 0.04571 –0.001 –0.009 –0.009 0.08357 0.11786 0.17071 0.32071
Canada Libor* – – – – – – – –
Euro Euribor – – – – 0.01 0.08 0.19 0.35
Sterling CDs – – – – 0.55 0.77 0.75 1.10
US$ CDs – – – – 0.00 0.11 0.17 0.42
Euro CDs – – – – –0.10 –0.05 0.06 0.23
US o'night repo 0.08 0.010 –0.060 –0.020
Fed Funds eff 0.09 – – –
US 3m Bills 0.02 –0.005 –0.010 –0.015
SDR int rate 0.05 – –0.020 –0.030
EONIA –0.024 –0.036 –0.018 –0.043
EURONIA –0.0362 0.046 0.002 0.005
RONIA 0.4904 –0.013 0.027 0.036
SONIA 0.4316 0.003 0.002 0.006
LA7 Day Notice 0.35%–0.30%
Over night One One Three Six One
Week month months months year
* Libor rates come from ICE (see www.theice.com) and are fixed at 11am UK time. Other data sources:
US$, Euro & CDs: dealers; SDR int rate: IMF; EONIA: ECB; EURONIA, RONIA & SONIA: WMBA. LA7 days
notice: Tradition (UK).
Source: Data from Financial Times http://markets.ft.com/RESEARCH/markets/DataArchiveFetchReport?Category=BR&Type=
MNY&Date=09/12/2014
average of the rate charged on money market securities in the currencies that
make up the SDR basket. This currency basket is currently based on four key
international currencies: the euro, the Japanese yen, pound sterling and the
US dollar. There are 188 members of the IMF and on joining each member
is allocated a quota of SDRs according to its relative position in the global
economy.
The FT also publishes in the ‘Companies and Markets’ section a table showing
US, eurozone, UK, Japanese and Swiss official interest rates – see Table 11.2.
These are the rates strongly influenced by central bank policy makers, such
as the US Federal Reserve trying to manage monetary conditions (more on this
in Chapter 16).
Figures 11.3 and 11.4 show comparative interest rates from the UK and the US
over a 30-year period. A number of observations can be made about the
interest rate on different money market instruments:
● Generally, investors require extra return for longer lending periods because
of the extra risk involved, so overnight rates will normally be less than rates
on longer-term instruments (although this is not always the case). Notice
in Figure 11.4 US six-month T-bill rates are slightly higher than those for
three-month T-bill lending.
● The creditworthiness of the borrowing institution has a strong influence
on the rate of interest charged. The rate offered by reputable national
● Money market interest rates with similar terms to maturity stay close
together and move up or down with quite a high degree of correlation over
time. These rates are all low risk and all short term, thus there is a reasonable
amount of substitutability between them for potential lenders. So if interest
rates in, say, the CD market fell abnormally below that in, say, the com-
mercial paper market, those banks needing to attract deposits might have
difficulty doing so because potential lenders will put more money in the
CP market. The banks will have to raise CD interest rates to attract deposits
while the commercial paper borrowers will find they can lower rates – thus
some degree of convergence takes place.
● Short-term interest rates can be lowered by central banks intervening in the
markets when they judge that the economy is in need of a boost. You can see
this sort of action in the figures in the years after the shock of the dot.com
bust at the turn of the millennium and following the financial crisis of
2007–2008.
The figure of 5.06% may be regarded here as the risk-free return (RFR), the
interest rate that is sufficient to induce investment assuming no uncertainty
about cash flows. Investors tend to view lending to highly reputable govern-
ments through the purchase of bills as the nearest they are going to get to risk-
free investing because these institutions have an almost unlimited ability to
raise income from taxes or to create money with minimal likelihood of default.
This applies only if the country has a reputation for good financial manage-
ment – Greece had a troublesome 2011–15; between 2011 and 2014 bonds
from Spain, Portugal and Ireland were also thought to be risky investments.
When investors doubt the soundness of government finances, this has the
effect of pushing up the interest rates governments have to pay to allow for the
risk of default (non-payment) way beyond the normal RFR accorded a reputa-
ble eurozone government, such as Germany.
The RFR forms the bedrock for time value of money calculations as the pure
time value and the expected inflation rate affect all investments equally.
Whether the investment is in property, bonds, shares or a factory, if expected
inflation rises from 3% to 5% then the investor’s required return on all invest-
ments will increase by 2%.
In the case of Mrs Ann Investor, the risk premium pushes up the total return
required to, say, 10%, thus giving full compensation for all three elements of
the time value of money.
The interest rates quoted in the financial markets are (theoretically) sufficiently
high to compensate for all three elements – whether investors sometimes
over- or under-price bonds, etc. and thus yields are pushed irrationally low or
high is a different matter.
The nominal rate of interest is the rate quoted by lenders and includes the
inflation element. The real rate of interest removes inflation.
its own sake and so only those techniques of direct relevance to the subject
matter of this book are covered.
When there are time delays between receipts and payments of financial sums
we need to make use of the concepts of simple and compound interest.
Simple interest
Example 12.1
Suppose that a sum of £10 is deposited in a bank account that pays 12% per
annum. At the end of year 1 the investor has £11.20 in the account. That is:
F = P(1 + i )
where F = Future value (or terminal value), P = Present value, i = Interest rate.
The initial sum, called the principal, is multiplied by the interest rate to give
the annual return. At the end of five years:
F = P(1 + in)
Note from the example that the 12% return is a constant amount each
year. Interest is not earned on the interest already accumulated from previous
years.
Compound interest
The more usual situation in the real world is for interest to be paid on the sum
that accumulates – whether or not that sum comes from the principal or from
the interest received in previous periods.
Example 12.2
An investment of £10 is made at an interest rate of 12% with the interest being
compounded. In one year the capital will grow by 12% to £11.20. In the second year
the capital will grow by 12%, but this time the growth will be on the accumulated
value of £11.20 and thus will amount to an extra £1.34. At the end of two years:
F = P(1 + i )(1 + i )
F = 11.20(1 + i )
F = 11.20(1 + 0.12)
F = 12.544
Alternatively,
F = P(1 + i )2
F = 10(1 + 0.12)2
F = 12.544
While these calculations are not overly difficult, they can become cumbersome
and time consuming, requiring the use of a calculator and accurate pressing of
buttons. It is common practice to use tables for the solution. Table 12.1 shows
an extract from Appendix I to this chapter, which gives the future value of
£1 invested at a number of different interest rates and for alternative numbers
of years.
This gives the results we have worked out above. From the second row of the
table in Table 12.1 we can read that £1 invested for two years at 12% amounts
to £1.2544. Thus, the investment of £10 provides a future capital sum 1.2544 times
the original amount:
£10 × 1.2544 = £12.544
and from the fifth row, the investment of £10 after five years provides a future
capital sum 1.7623 times the original amount:
£10 × 1.7623 = £17.623
Year 1 2 5 12 15
The interest on the accumulated interest over five years is therefore the differ-
ence between the total arising from simple interest and that from compound
interest:
£17.62 − £16.00 = £1.62
Present values
There are many occasions when you are given the future sums and need to find
out what those future sums are worth in present-value terms today. For exam-
ple, you wish to know how much you would have to put aside today that will
accumulate, with compounded interest, to a defined sum in the future; or you
are given the choice between receiving £200 in five years or £100 now and wish
to know which is the better option, given anticipated interest rates; or a bond
gives a return of £1 million in three years for an outlay of £800,000 now and
you need to establish whether this is the best use of the £800,000. By means of
a discount calculation, a sum of money to be received in the future is given a
monetary value today.
Example 12.3
If we anticipate the receipt of £17.62 in five years’ time we can determine its
present value. Rearrangement of the compound interest formula, and assuming a
discount (interest) rate of 12%, gives:
F 1
P= or P = F ×
(1 + i ) n (1 + i ) n
£17.62
P= = £10
(1 + 0.12)5
1 5 10 12 15 17
Alternatively, as before, we can use discount tables – see Appendix II, which gives
the present value of £1, an extract from which is shown in Table 12.2. The factor
needed to discount £1 receivable in five years when the discount rate is 12% is
1 1
0.5674. This is the element, = 0.5674.
(1 + i ) n (1 + 0.12)5
Examining the present value of £1 in Table 12.2 you can see that as the
discount rate increases, the present value goes down. Also, the further into the
future the money is to be received, the less valuable it is in today’s terms.
Distant cash flows discounted at a high rate have a small present value; for
instance, £1,000 receivable in 20 years when the discount rate is 17% has
a present value of £43.30 (£1,000 × 0.0433). Viewed from another angle, if
you invested £43.30 for 20 years it would accumulate to £1,000 if interest
compounds at 17%.
Since:
F = P(1 + i )n
F
= (1 + i ) n
P
Second, take the root to the power n of both sides and subtract 1 from each
side:
1/ n
n
F ⎛F⎞
i= − 1 or i = ⎜ ⎟ −1
P ⎝ P⎠
Example 12.4
In the case of a five-year investment requiring an outlay of £10 and having a future
value of £17.62 the rate of return is:
1/ 5
5
17.62 ⎛ 17.62 ⎞
i= − 1 = 0.12, or 12% or i = ⎜ − 1 = 0.12, or 12%
10 ⎝ 10 ⎟⎠
The rate of interest being offered by the bond mentioned above is:
5 £10, 000
i= − 1 = 0.04564, or 4.564%
£8, 000
A more straightforward alternative is to use the future value table (Appendix I),
an extract of which is shown in Table 12.1. In our example, if the return on £10
is £17.62, then the return on £1 worth of investment over five years is:
17.62
= 1.762
10
In the body of the future value table look at the year 5 row for a future value
of 1.762.
Annuities
In financial calculations, quite often there is not just one payment at the end
of a certain number of years, there can be a series of identical payments made
over a period of years. For instance:
● individuals can buy, from savings plan companies, the right to receive a
number of identical payments over a number of years
● a business might invest in a project which, it is estimated, will give regular
cash inflows over a period of years
● a typical house mortgage is an annuity.
Example 12.5
For a regular payment of £10 per year for five years, when the interest rate is 12%,
we can calculate the present value of the annuity (P) by three methods.
Method 1
A A A A A
P= + + + +
(1 + i ) (1 + i )2 (1 + i )3 (1 + i )4 (1 + i )5
10 10 10 10 10
P= + + + + = £36.048
(1 + 0.12) (1 + 0.12)2 (1 + 0.12)3 (1 + 0.12)4 (1 + 0.12)5
Method 2
Using the derived formula:
⎡ 1 ⎤
1− ⎢ n ⎥
P= ⎣ (1 + i ) ⎦ × A
i
⎡ 1 ⎤
1− ⎢ 5 ⎥
P= ⎣ (1 + 0.12) ⎦ × 10 = 3.6048 × £10 = £36.048
0.12
Year 1 5 10 12 15
Method 3
It is useful to understand Methods 1 and 2, but the calculations can be prolonged.
Method 3 is recommended, where the relevant figures are looked up using the
‘present value of an annuity’ table. Table 12.3 is an extract from the more complete
annuity table in Appendix III. Here we simply look along the year 5 row and 12% column
to find the figure of 3.6048. This is the present value of five future annual receipts
of £1. Therefore we multiply by £10:
Perpetuities
Some contracts run indefinitely and there is no end to a series of identical
payments. Certain government securities do not have an end date; that is, the
amount paid when the bond was purchased by the lender will never be repaid,
only interest payments are made. For example, the UK government issued
consolidated stocks many years ago which may never be redeemed.
A
P=
i
10
P= = £83.33
0.12
It is very important to note that in order to use this formula we are assuming
that the first payment arises 365 days after the time at which we are standing
(the present time or time zero).
Example 12.6
If you put £10 in a bank account earning 12% per annum then your return after one
year is:
10(1 + 0.12) = £11.20
Daily compounding:
10(1 + [0.12/365])365 = £11.2747
Example 12.7
If £10 is deposited in a bank account that compounds interest quarterly and the
nominal return per year is 12%, how much will be in the account after eight years?
10(1 + [0.12/4])4×8 = £25.75
Continuous compounding
If the compounding frequency is taken to the limit we say that there is
continuous compounding. When the number of compounding periods
approaches infinity the future value is found by F = Pein where e is the value
of the exponential function. This is set as 2.71828 (to five decimal places, as
shown on a scientific calculator).1
So, the future value of £10 deposited in a bank paying 12% nominal compounded
continuously after eight years is:
10 × 2.718280.12×8 = £26.12
If m is the monthly interest or discount rate and i is the annual compound rate,
then over 12 months:
(1 + m)12 = 1 + i
So
i = (1 + m)12 − 1
(1 + d )365 = 1 + i
So
i = (1 + d )365 − 1
Thus, if a credit card company charges 1.5% per month, the annual compound
rate, i, is:
i = [(1 + 0.015)12 − 1] × 100 = 19.56%
1
The number ‘e’ is a special number discovered by mathematicians, a mathematical constant.
It is the ‘natural’ exponential because it arises naturally in science and maths, similar to the
way pi arises naturally in geometry. It is on most calculators.
If you want to find the monthly rate when you are given the annual com-
pound rate:
m = (1 + i )1/12 − 1 or m = 12 ( 1 + i ) − 1
If you want to find the daily rate when you are given the annual compound
rate:
d = (1 + i)1/365 − 1
Or
d= 365
(1 + i ) − 1
£37.92 365
bey = × × 100 = 0.304193%
£50, 000 91
An alternative outcome might be that every three months you take your money
(principal plus interest) and reinvest in the same deal at the same rate. Thus
you can get interest on the accumulated interest as well as on the principal. If
you reinvested the principal and accumulated interest every three months at
this quarterly rate of return for a year you would receive:
4
⎛ 0.00304193 ⎞
£50, 000 × ⎜ 1 + ⎟⎠ = £50,152.27
⎝ 4
The compound rate of return is slightly more than the simple annualised rate
of return of 0.304193%:
4
⎛ 0.00304193 ⎞
⎜⎝ 1 + 4 ⎟⎠ − 1 = 0.003045402 or 0.3045402%
Note that this is not entirely accurate because there are more than 4 × 91 days
in a year, so if you want to be really precise, a further small adjustment is
necessary:
1 Simple annualised bey. This is the one most practitioners and books refer to
and it is fine for comparing the rate offered on one money market security
with another of the same time to maturity.
2 (What I’ll call) compound annualised bey, but many people only use (1).
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 325
Future value of £1 at compound interest
F = P(1 + i ) n
Interest rate
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Periods (n) 1 1.0100 1.0200 1.0300 1.0400 1.0500 1.0600 1.0700 1.0800 1.0900 1.1000 1.1100 1.1200 1.1300 1.1400 1.1500 1
2 1.0201 1.0404 1.0609 1.0816 1.1025 1.1236 1.1449 1.1664 1.1881 1.2100 1.2321 1.2544 1.2769 1.2996 1.3225 2
3 1.0303 1.0612 1.0927 1.1249 1.1576 1.1910 1.2250 1.2597 1.2950 1.3310 1.3676 1.4049 1.4429 1.4815 1.5209 3
4 1.0406 1.0824 1.1255 1.1699 1.2155 1.2625 1.3108 1.3605 1.4116 1.4641 1.5181 1.5735 1.6305 1.6890 1.7490 4
5 1.0510 1.1041 1.1593 1.2167 1.2763 1.3382 1.4026 1.4693 1.5386 1.6105 1.6851 1.7623 1.8424 1.9254 2.0114 5
6 1.0615 1.1262 1.1941 1.2653 1.3401 1.4185 1.5007 1.5869 1.6771 1.7716 1.8704 1.9738 2.0820 2.1950 2.3131 6
7 1.0721 1.1487 1.2299 1.3159 1.4071 1.5036 1.6058 1.7138 1.8280 1.9487 2.0762 2.2107 2.3526 2.5023 2.6600 7
8 1.0829 1.1717 1.2668 1.3686 1.4775 1.5938 1.7182 1.8509 1.9926 2.1436 2.3045 2.4760 2.6584 2.8526 3.0590 8
9 1.0937 1.1951 1.3048 1.4233 1.5513 1.6895 1.8385 1.9990 2.1719 2.3579 2.5580 2.7731 3.0040 3.2519 3.5179 9
10 1.1046 1.2190 1.3439 1.4802 1.6289 1.7908 1.9672 2.1589 2.3674 2.5937 2.8394 3.1058 3.3946 3.7072 4.0456 10
11 1.1157 1.2434 1.3842 1.5395 1.7103 1.8983 2.1049 2.3316 2.5804 2.8531 3.1518 3.4785 3.8359 4.2262 4.6524 11
12 1.1268 1.2682 1.4258 1.6010 1.7959 2.0122 2.2522 2.5182 2.8127 3.1384 3.4985 3.8960 4.3345 4.8179 5.3503 12
13 1.1381 1.2936 1.4685 1.6651 1.8856 2.1329 2.4098 2.7196 3.0658 3.4523 3.8833 4.3635 4.8980 5.4924 6.1528 13
14 1.1495 1.3195 1.5126 1.7317 1.9799 2.2609 2.5785 2.9372 3.3417 3.7975 4.3104 4.8871 5.5348 6.2613 7.0757 14
15 1.1610 1.3459 1.5580 1.8009 2.0789 2.3966 2.7590 3.1722 3.6425 4.1772 4.7846 5.4736 6.2543 7.1379 8.1371 15
16 1.1726 1.3728 1.6047 1.8730 2.1829 2.5404 2.9522 3.4259 3.9703 4.5950 5.3109 6.1304 7.0673 8.1372 9.3576 16
17 1.1843 1.4002 1.6528 1.9479 2.2920 2.6928 3.1588 3.7000 4.3276 5.0545 5.8951 6.8660 7.9861 9.2765 10.7613 17
18 1.1961 1.4282 1.7024 2.0258 2.4066 2.8543 3.3799 3.9960 4.7171 5.5599 6.5436 7.6900 9.0243 10.5752 12.3755 18
19 1.2081 1.4568 1.7535 2.1068 2.5270 3.0256 3.6165 4.3157 5.1417 6.1159 7.2633 8.6128 10.1974 12.0557 14.2318 19
20 1.2202 1.4859 1.8061 2.1911 2.6533 3.2071 3.8697 4.6610 5.6044 6.7275 8.0623 9.6463 11.5231 13.7435 16.3665 20
12 FINANCIAL CONCEPTS AND MATHEMATICS
25 1.2824 1.6406 2.0938 2.6658 3.3864 4.2919 5.4274 6.8485 8.6231 10.8347 13.5855 17.0001 21.2305 26.4619 32.9190 25
325
7/7/15 8:49 AM
326
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 326
16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30
Periods (n) 1 1.1600 1.1700 1.1800 1.1900 1.2000 1.2100 1.2200 1.2300 1.2400 1.2500 1.2600 1.2700 1.2800 1.2900 1.3000 1
2 1.3456 1.3689 1.3924 1.4161 1.4400 1.4641 1.4884 1.5129 1.5376 1.5625 1.5876 1.6129 1.6384 1.6641 1.6900 2
3 1.5609 1.6016 1.6430 1.6852 1.7280 1.7716 1.8158 1.8609 1.9066 1.9531 2.0004 2.0484 2.0972 2.1467 2.1970 3
4 1.8106 1.8739 1.9388 2.0053 2.0736 2.1436 2.2153 2.2889 2.3642 2.4414 2.5205 2.6014 2.6844 2.7692 2.8561 4
5 2.1003 2.1924 2.2878 2.3864 2.4883 2.5937 2.7027 2.8153 2.9316 3.0518 3.1758 3.3038 3.4360 3.5723 3.7129 5
6 2.4364 2.5652 2.6996 2.8398 2.9860 3.1384 3.2973 3.4628 3.6352 3.8147 4.0015 4.1959 4.3980 4.6083 4.8268 6
7 2.8262 3.0012 3.1855 3.3793 3.5832 3.7975 4.0227 4.2593 4.5077 4.7684 5.0419 5.3288 5.6295 5.9447 6.2749 7
8 3.2784 3.5115 3.7589 4.0214 4.2998 4.5950 4.9077 5.2389 5.5895 5.9605 6.3528 6.7675 7.2058 7.6686 8.1573 8
9 3.8030 4.1084 4.4355 4.7854 5.1598 5.5599 5.9874 6.4439 6.9310 7.4506 8.0045 8.5948 9.2234 9.8925 10.6045 9
10 4.4114 4.8068 5.2338 5.6947 6.1917 6.7275 7.3046 7.9259 8.5944 9.3132 10.0857 10.9153 11.8059 12.7614 13.7858 10
11 5.1173 5.6240 6.1759 6.7767 7.4301 8.1403 8.9117 9.7489 10.6571 11.6415 12.7080 13.8625 15.1116 16.4622 17.9216 11
12 5.9360 6.5801 7.2876 8.0642 8.9161 9.8497 10.8722 11.9912 13.2148 14.5519 16.0120 17.6053 19.3428 21.2362 23.2981 12
13 6.8858 7.6987 8.5994 9.5964 10.6993 11.9182 13.2641 14.7491 16.3863 18.1899 20.1752 22.3588 24.7588 27.3947 30.2875 13
14 7.9875 9.0075 10.1472 11.4198 12.8392 14.4210 16.1822 18.1414 20.3191 22.7374 25.4207 28.3957 31.6913 35.3391 39.3738 14
15 9.2655 10.5387 11.9737 13.5895 15.4070 17.4494 19.7423 22.3140 25.1956 28.4217 32.0301 36.0625 40.5648 45.5875 51.1859 15
16 10.7480 12.3303 14.1290 16.1715 18.4884 21.1138 24.0856 27.4462 31.2426 35.5271 40.3579 45.7994 51.9230 58.8079 66.5417 16
17 12.4677 14.4265 16.6722 19.2441 22.1861 25.5477 29.3844 33.7588 38.7408 44.4089 50.8510 58.1652 66.4614 75.8621 86.5042 17
18 14.4625 16.8790 19.6733 22.9005 26.6233 30.9127 35.8490 41.5233 48.0386 55.5112 64.0722 73.8698 85.0706 97.8622 112.4554 18
19 16.7765 19.7484 23.2144 27.2516 31.9480 37.4043 43.7358 51.0737 59.5679 69.3889 80.7310 93.8147 108.8904 126.2422 146.1920 19
20 19.4608 23.1056 27.3930 32.4294 38.3376 45.2593 53.3576 62.8206 73.8641 86.7362 101.7211 119.1446 139.3797 162.8524 190.0496 20
25 40.8742 50.6578 62.6686 77.3881 95.3962 117.3909 144.2101 176.8593 216.5420 264.6978 323.0454 393.6344 478.9049 581.7585 705.6410 25
PART 4 VALUING BONDS AND MONEY MARKET INSTRUMENTS
7/7/15 8:49 AM
Appendix II
Present value of £1 at compound interest
1
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 327
(1 + i ) n
Interest rate (i )
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Periods (n) 1 0.9901 0.9804 0.9709 0.9615 0.9524 0.9434 0.9346 0.9259 0.9174 0.9091 0.9009 0.8929 0.8850 0.8772 0.8696 1
2 0.9803 0.9612 0.9426 0.9246 0.9070 0.8900 0.8734 0.8573 0.8417 0.8264 0.8116 0.7972 0.7831 0.7695 0.7561 2
3 0.9706 0.9423 0.9151 0.8890 0.8638 0.8396 0.8163 0.7938 0.7722 0.7513 0.7312 0.7118 0.6931 0.6750 0.6575 3
4 0.9610 0.9238 0.8885 0.8548 0.8227 0.7921 0.7629 0.7350 0.7084 0.6830 0.6587 0.6355 0.6133 0.5921 0.5718 4
5 0.9515 0.9057 0.8626 0.8219 0.7835 0.7473 0.7130 0.6806 0.6499 0.6209 0.5935 0.5674 0.5428 0.5194 0.4972 5
6 0.9420 0.8880 0.8375 0.7903 0.7462 0.7050 0.6663 0.6302 0.5963 0.5645 0.5346 0.5066 0.4803 0.4556 0.4323 6
7 0.9327 0.8706 0.8131 0.7599 0.7107 0.6651 0.6227 0.5835 0.5470 0.5132 0.4817 0.4523 0.4251 0.3996 0.3759 7
8 0.9235 0.8535 0.7894 0.7307 0.6768 0.6274 0.5820 0.5403 0.5019 0.4665 0.4339 0.4039 0.3762 0.3506 0.3269 8
9 0.9143 0.8368 0.7664 0.7026 0.6446 0.5919 0.5439 0.5002 0.4604 0.4241 0.3909 0.3606 0.3329 0.3075 0.2843 9
10 0.9053 0.8203 0.7441 0.6756 0.6139 0.5584 0.5083 0.4632 0.4224 0.3855 0.3522 0.3220 0.2946 0.2697 0.2472 10
11 0.8963 0.8043 0.7224 0.6496 0.5847 0.5268 0.4751 0.4289 0.3875 0.3505 0.3173 0.2875 0.2607 0.2366 0.2149 11
12 0.8874 0.7885 0.7014 0.6246 0.5568 0.4970 0.4440 0.3971 0.3555 0.3186 0.2858 0.2567 0.2307 0.2076 0.1869 12
13 0.8787 0.7730 0.6810 0.6006 0.5303 0.4688 0.4150 0.3677 0.3262 0.2897 0.2575 0.2292 0.2042 0.1821 0.1625 13
14 0.8700 0.7579 0.6611 0.5775 0.5051 0.4423 0.3878 0.3405 0.2992 0.2633 0.2320 0.2046 0.1807 0.1597 0.1413 14
15 0.8613 0.7430 0.6419 0.5553 0.4810 0.4173 0.3624 0.3152 0.2745 0.2394 0.2090 0.1827 0.1599 0.1401 0.1229 15
16 0.8528 0.7284 0.6232 0.5339 0.4581 0.3936 0.3387 0.2919 0.2519 0.2176 0.1883 0.1631 0.1415 0.1229 0.1069 16
17 0.8444 0.7142 0.6050 0.5134 0.4363 0.3714 0.3166 0.2703 0.2311 0.1978 0.1696 0.1456 0.1252 0.1078 0.0929 17
18 0.8360 0.7002 0.5874 0.4936 0.4155 0.3503 0.2959 0.2502 0.2120 0.1799 0.1528 0.1300 0.1108 0.0946 0.0808 18
19 0.8277 0.6864 0.5703 0.4746 0.3957 0.3305 0.2765 0.2317 0.1945 0.1635 0.1377 0.1161 0.0981 0.0829 0.0703 19
20 0.8195 0.6730 0.5537 0.4564 0.3769 0.3118 0.2584 0.2145 0.1784 0.1486 0.1240 0.1037 0.0868 0.0728 0.0611 20
25 0.7795 0.6095 0.4776 0.3751 0.2953 0.2330 0.1842 0.1460 0.1160 0.0923 0.0736 0.0588 0.0471 0.0378 0.0304 25
30 0.7419 0.5521 0.4120 0.3083 0.2314 0.1741 0.1314 0.0994 0.0754 0.0573 0.0437 0.0334 0.0256 0.0196 0.0151 30
12 FINANCIAL CONCEPTS AND MATHEMATICS
35 0.7059 0.5000 0.3554 0.2534 0.1813 0.1301 0.0937 0.0676 0.0490 0.0356 0.0259 0.0189 0.0139 0.0102 0.0075 35
40 0.6717 0.4529 0.3066 0.2083 0.1420 0.0972 0.0668 0.0460 0.0318 0.0221 0.0154 0.0107 0.0075 0.0053 0.0037 40
45 0.6391 0.4102 0.2644 0.1712 0.1113 0.0727 0.0476 0.0313 0.0207 0.0137 0.0091 0.0061 0.0041 0.0027 0.0019 45
50 0.6080 0.3715 0.2281 0.1407 0.0872 0.0543 0.0339 0.0213 0.0134 0.0085 0.0054 0.0035 0.0022 0.0014 0.0009 50
327
7/7/15 8:49 AM
328
16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30
Periods (n) 1 0.8621 0.8547 0.8475 0.8403 0.8333 0.8264 0.8197 0.8130 0.8065 0.8000 0.7937 0.7874 0.7812 0.7752 0.7692 1
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 328
2 0.7432 0.7305 0.7182 0.7062 0.6944 0.6830 0.6719 0.6610 0.6504 0.6400 0.6299 0.6200 0.6104 0.6009 0.5917 2
3 0.6407 0.6244 0.6086 0.5934 0.5787 0.5645 0.5507 0.5374 0.5245 0.5120 0.4999 0.4882 0.4768 0.4658 0.4552 3
4 0.5523 0.5337 0.5158 0.4987 0.4823 0.4665 0.4514 0.4369 0.4230 0.4096 0.3968 0.3844 0.3725 0.3611 0.3501 4
5 0.4761 0.4561 0.4371 0.4190 0.4019 0.3855 0.3700 0.3552 0.3411 0.3277 0.3149 0.3027 0.2910 0.2799 0.2693 5
6 0.4104 0.3898 0.3704 0.3521 0.3349 0.3186 0.3033 0.2888 0.2751 0.2621 0.2499 0.2383 0.2274 0.2170 0.2072 6
7 0.3538 0.3332 0.3139 0.2959 0.2791 0.2633 0.2486 0.2348 0.2218 0.2097 0.1983 0.1877 0.1776 0.1682 0.1594 7
8 0.3050 0.2848 0.2660 0.2487 0.2326 0.2176 0.2038 0.1909 0.1789 0.1678 0.1574 0.1478 0.1388 0.1304 0.1226 8
9 0.2630 0.2434 0.2255 0.2090 0.1938 0.1799 0.1670 0.1552 0.1443 0.1342 0.1249 0.1164 0.1084 0.1011 0.0943 9
10 0.2267 0.2080 0.1911 0.1756 0.1615 0.1486 0.1369 0.1262 0.1164 0.1074 0.0992 0.0916 0.0847 0.0784 0.0725 10
11 0.1954 0.1778 0.1619 0.1476 0.1346 0.1228 0.1122 0.1026 0.0938 0.0859 0.0787 0.0721 0.0662 0.0607 0.0558 11
12 0.1685 0.1520 0.1372 0.1240 0.1122 0.1015 0.0920 0.0834 0.0757 0.0687 0.0625 0.0568 0.0517 0.0471 0.0429 12
13 0.1452 0.1299 0.1163 0.1042 0.0935 0.0839 0.0754 0.0678 0.0610 0.0550 0.0496 0.0447 0.0404 0.0365 0.0330 13
14 0.1252 0.1110 0.0985 0.0876 0.0779 0.0693 0.0618 0.0551 0.0492 0.0440 0.0393 0.0352 0.0316 0.0283 0.0254 14
15 0.1079 0.0949 0.0835 0.0736 0.0649 0.0573 0.0507 0.0448 0.0397 0.0352 0.0312 0.0277 0.0247 0.0219 0.0195 15
16 0.0930 0.0811 0.0708 0.0618 0.0541 0.0474 0.0415 0.0364 0.0320 0.0281 0.0248 0.0218 0.0193 0.0170 0.0150 16
17 0.0802 0.0693 0.0600 0.0520 0.0451 0.0391 0.0340 0.0296 0.0258 0.0225 0.0197 0.0172 0.0150 0.0132 0.0116 17
18 0.0691 0.0592 0.0508 0.0437 0.0376 0.0323 0.0279 0.0241 0.0208 0.0180 0.0156 0.0135 0.0118 0.0102 0.0089 18
19 0.0596 0.0506 0.0431 0.0367 0.0313 0.0267 0.0229 0.0196 0.0168 0.0144 0.0124 0.0107 0.0092 0.0079 0.0068 19
20 0.0514 0.0433 0.0365 0.0308 0.0261 0.0221 0.0187 0.0159 0.0135 0.0115 0.0098 0.0084 0.0072 0.0061 0.0053 20
25 0.0245 0.0197 0.0160 0.0129 0.0105 0.0085 0.0069 0.0057 0.0046 0.0038 0.0031 0.0025 0.0021 0.0017 0.0014 25
30 0.0116 0.0090 0.0070 0.0054 0.0042 0.0033 0.0026 0.0020 0.0016 0.0012 0.0010 0.0008 0.0006 0.0005 0.0004 30
35 0.0055 0.0041 0.0030 0.0023 0.0017 0.0013 0.0009 0.0007 0.0005 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 35
40 0.0026 0.0019 0.0013 0.0010 0.0007 0.0005 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 40
PART 4 VALUING BONDS AND MONEY MARKET INSTRUMENTS
45 0.0013 0.0009 0.0006 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 45
50 0.0006 0.0004 0.0003 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 50
7/7/15 8:49 AM
Appendix III
Present value of an annuity of £1 at compound interest
⎡ 1 ⎤
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 329
1− ⎢ n ⎥
P= ⎣ (1 + i ) ⎦ × A
i
Interest rate (i )
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
Periods (n) 1 0.9901 0.9804 0.9709 0.9615 0.9524 0.9434 0.9346 0.9259 0.9174 0.9091 0.9009 0.8929 0.8850 0.8772 0.8696 1
2 1.9704 1.9416 1.9135 1.8861 1.8594 1.8334 1.8080 1.7833 1.7591 1.7355 1.7125 1.6901 1.6681 1.6467 1.6257 2
3 2.9410 2.8839 2.8286 2.7751 2.7232 2.6730 2.6243 2.5771 2.5313 2.4869 2.4437 2.4018 2.3612 2.3216 2.2832 3
4 3.9020 3.8077 3.7171 3.6299 3.5460 3.4651 3.3872 3.3121 3.2397 3.1699 3.1024 3.0373 2.9745 2.9137 2.8550 4
5 4.8534 4.7135 4.5797 4.4518 4.3295 4.2124 4.1002 3.9927 3.8897 3.7908 3.6959 3.6048 3.5172 3.4331 3.3522 5
6 5.7955 5.6014 5.4172 5.2421 5.0757 4.9173 4.7665 4.6229 4.4859 4.3553 4.2305 4.1114 3.9975 3.8887 3.7845 6
7 6.7282 6.4720 6.2303 6.0021 5.7864 5.5824 5.3893 5.2064 5.0330 4.8684 4.7122 4.5638 4.4226 4.2883 4.1604 7
8 7.6517 7.3255 7.0197 6.7327 6.4632 6.2098 5.9713 5.7466 5.5348 5.3349 5.1461 4.9676 4.7988 4.6389 4.4873 8
9 8.5660 8.1622 7.7861 7.4353 7.1078 6.8017 6.5152 6.2469 5.9952 5.7590 5.5370 5.3282 5.1317 4.9464 4.7716 9
10 9.4713 8.9826 8.5302 8.1109 7.7217 7.3601 7.0236 6.7101 6.4177 6.1446 5.8892 5.6502 5.4262 5.2161 5.0188 10
11 10.3676 9.7868 9.2526 8.7605 8.3064 7.8869 7.4987 7.1390 6.8052 6.4951 6.2065 5.9377 5.6869 5.4527 5.2337 11
12 11.2551 10.5753 9.9540 9.3851 8.8633 8.3838 7.9427 7.5361 7.1607 6.8137 6.4924 6.1944 5.9176 5.6603 5.4206 12
13 12.1337 11.3484 10.6350 9.9856 9.3936 8.8527 8.3577 7.9038 7.4869 7.1034 6.7499 6.4235 6.1218 5.8424 5.5831 13
14 13.0037 12.1062 11.2961 10.5631 9.8986 9.2950 8.7455 8.2442 7.7862 7.3667 6.9819 6.6282 6.3025 6.0021 5.7245 14
15 13.8651 12.8493 11.9379 11.1184 10.3797 9.7122 9.1079 8.5595 8.0607 7.6061 7.1909 6.8109 6.4624 6.1422 5.8474 15
16 14.7179 13.5777 12.5611 11.6523 10.8378 10.1059 9.4466 8.8514 8.3126 7.8237 7.3792 6.9740 6.6039 6.2651 5.9542 16
17 15.5623 14.2919 13.1661 12.1657 11.2741 10.4773 9.7632 9.1216 8.5436 8.0216 7.5488 7.1196 6.7291 6.3729 6.0472 17
18 16.3983 14.9920 13.7535 12.6593 11.6896 10.8276 10.0591 9.3719 8.7556 8.2014 7.7016 7.2497 6.8399 6.4674 6.1280 18
19 17.2260 15.6785 14.3238 13.1339 12.0853 11.1581 10.3356 9.6036 8.9501 8.3649 7.8393 7.3658 6.9380 6.5504 6.1982 19
20 18.0456 16.3514 14.8775 13.5903 12.4622 11.4699 10.5940 9.8181 9.1285 8.5136 7.9633 7.4694 7.0248 6.6231 6.2593 20
25 22.0232 19.5235 17.4131 15.6221 14.0939 12.7834 11.6536 10.6748 9.8226 9.0770 8.4217 7.8431 7.3300 6.8729 6.4641 25
30 25.8077 22.3965 19.6004 17.2920 15.3725 13.7648 12.4090 11.2578 10.2737 9.4269 8.6938 8.0552 7.4957 7.0027 6.5660 30
12 FINANCIAL CONCEPTS AND MATHEMATICS
35 29.4086 24.9986 21.4872 18.6646 16.3742 14.4982 12.9477 11.6546 10.5668 9.6442 8.8552 8.1755 7.5856 7.0700 6.6166 35
40 32.8347 27.3555 23.1148 19.7928 17.1591 15.0463 13.3317 11.9246 10.7574 9.7791 8.9511 8.2438 7.6344 7.1050 6.6418 40
45 36.0945 29.4902 24.5187 20.7200 17.7741 15.4558 13.6055 12.1084 10.8812 9.8628 9.0079 8.2825 7.6609 7.1232 6.6543 45
50 39.1961 31.4236 25.7298 21.4822 18.2559 15.7619 13.8007 12.2335 10.9617 9.9148 9.0417 8.3045 7.6752 7.1327 6.6605 50
329
7/7/15 8:49 AM
330
16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 330
Periods (n) 1 0.8621 0.8547 0.8475 0.8403 0.8333 0.8264 0.8197 0.8130 0.8065 0.8000 0.7937 0.7874 0.7812 0.7752 0.7692 1
2 1.6052 1.5852 1.5656 1.5465 1.5278 1.5095 1.4915 1.4740 1.4568 1.4400 1.4235 1.4074 1.3916 1.3761 1.3609 2
3 2.2459 2.2096 2.1743 2.1399 2.1065 2.0739 2.0422 2.0114 1.9813 1.9520 1.9234 1.8956 1.8684 1.8420 1.8161 3
4 2.7982 2.7432 2.6901 2.6386 2.5887 2.5404 2.4936 2.4483 2.4043 2.3616 2.3202 2.2800 2.2410 2.2031 2.1662 4
5 3.2743 3.1993 3.1272 3.0576 2.9906 2.9260 2.8636 2.8035 2.7454 2.6893 2.6351 2.5827 2.5320 2.4830 2.4356 5
6 3.6847 3.5892 3.4976 3.4098 3.3255 3.2446 3.1669 3.0923 3.0205 2.9514 2.8850 2.8210 2.7594 2.7000 2.6427 6
7 4.0386 3.9224 3.8115 3.7057 3.6046 3.5079 3.4155 3.3270 3.2423 3.1611 3.0833 3.0087 2.9370 2.8682 2.8021 7
8 4.3436 4.2072 4.0776 3.9544 3.8372 3.7256 3.6193 3.5179 3.4212 3.3289 3.2407 3.1564 3.0758 2.9986 2.9247 8
9 4.6065 4.4506 4.3030 4.1633 4.0310 3.9054 3.7863 3.6731 3.5655 3.4631 3.3657 3.2728 3.1842 3.0997 3.0190 9
10 4.8332 4.6586 4.4941 4.3389 4.1925 4.0541 3.9232 3.7993 3.6819 3.5705 3.4648 3.3644 3.2689 3.1781 3.0915 10
11 5.0286 4.8364 4.6560 4.4865 4.3271 4.1769 4.0354 3.9018 3.7757 3.6564 3.5435 3.4365 3.3351 3.2388 3.1473 11
12 5.1971 4.9884 4.7932 4.6105 4.4392 4.2784 4.1274 3.9852 3.8514 3.7251 3.6059 3.4933 3.3868 3.2859 3.1903 12
13 5.3423 5.1183 4.9095 4.7147 4.5327 4.3624 4.2028 4.0530 3.9124 3.7801 3.6555 3.5381 3.4272 3.3224 3.2233 13
14 5.4675 5.2293 5.0081 4.8023 4.6106 4.4317 4.2646 4.1082 3.9616 3.8241 3.6949 3.5733 3.4587 3.3507 3.2487 14
15 5.5755 5.3242 5.0916 4.8759 4.6755 4.4890 4.3152 4.1530 4.0013 3.8593 3.7261 3.6010 3.4834 3.3726 3.2682 15
16 5.6685 5.4053 5.1624 4.9377 4.7296 4.5364 4.3567 4.1894 4.0333 3.8874 3.7509 3.6228 3.5026 3.3896 3.2832 16
17 5.7487 5.4746 5.2223 4.9897 4.7746 4.5755 4.3908 4.2190 4.0591 3.9099 3.7705 3.6400 3.5177 3.4028 3.2948 17
18 5.8178 5.5339 5.2732 5.0333 4.8122 4.6079 4.4187 4.2431 4.0799 3.9279 3.7861 3.6536 3.5294 3.4130 3.3037 18
19 5.8775 5.5845 5.3162 5.0700 4.8435 4.6346 4.4415 4.2627 4.0967 3.9424 3.7985 3.6642 3.5386 3.4210 3.3105 19
20 5.9288 5.6278 5.3527 5.1009 4.8696 4.6567 4.4603 4.2786 4.1103 3.9539 3.8083 3.6726 3.5458 3.4271 3.3158 20
25 6.0971 5.7662 5.4669 5.1951 4.9476 4.7213 4.5139 4.3232 4.1474 3.9849 3.8342 3.6943 3.5640 3.4423 3.3286 25
30 6.1772 5.8294 5.5168 5.2347 4.9789 4.7463 4.5338 4.3391 4.1601 3.9950 3.8424 3.7009 3.5693 3.4466 3.3321 30
35 6.2153 5.8582 5.5386 5.2512 4.9915 4.7559 4.5411 4.3447 4.1644 3.9984 3.8450 3.7028 3.5708 3.4478 3.3330 35
40 6.2335 5.8713 5.5482 5.2582 4.9966 4.7596 4.5439 4.3467 4.1659 3.9995 3.8458 3.7034 3.5712 3.4481 3.3332 40
45 6.2421 5.8773 5.5523 5.2611 4.9986 4.7610 4.5449 4.3474 4.1664 3.9998 3.8460 3.7036 3.5714 3.4482 3.3333 45
PART 4 VALUING BONDS AND MONEY MARKET INSTRUMENTS
50 6.2463 5.8801 5.5541 5.2623 4.9995 4.7616 4.5452 4.3477 4.1666 3.9999 3.8461 3.7037 3.5714 3.4483 3.3333 50
7/7/15 8:49 AM
Appendix IV
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 331
Future value of an annuity of £1 at compound interest
Interest rate (i )
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 12 14 16 18 20 25 30 35
Periods (n) 1 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000
2 2.0100 2.0200 2.0300 2.0400 2.0500 2.0600 2.0700 2.0800 2.0900 2.1000 2.1200 2.1400 2.1600 2.1800 2.2000 2.2500 2.3000 2.3500
3 3.0301 3.0604 3.0909 3.1216 3.1525 3.1836 3.2149 3.2464 3.2781 3.3100 3.3744 3.4396 3.5056 3.5724 3.6400 3.8125 3.9900 4.1725
4 4.0604 4.1216 4.1836 4.2465 4.3101 4.3746 4.4399 4.5061 4.5731 4.6410 4.7793 4.9211 5.0665 5.2154 5.3680 5.7656 6.1870 6.6329
5 5.1010 5.2040 5.3091 5.4163 5.5256 5.6371 5.7507 5.8666 5.9847 6.1051 6.3528 6.6101 6.8771 7.1542 7.4416 8.2070 9.0431 9.9544
6 6.1520 6.3081 6.4684 6.6330 6.8019 6.9753 7.1533 7.3359 7.5233 7.7156 8.1152 8.5355 8.9775 9.4420 9.9299 11.2588 12.7560 14.4834
7 7.2135 7.4343 7.6625 7.8983 8.1420 8.3938 8.6540 8.9228 9.2004 9.4872 10.0890 10.7305 11.4139 12.1415 12.9159 15.0735 17.5828 20.4919
8 8.2857 8.5830 8.8923 9.2142 9.5491 9.8975 10.2598 10.6366 11.0285 11.4359 12.2997 13.2328 14.2401 15.3270 16.4991 19.8419 23.8577 28.6640
9 9.3685 9.7546 10.1591 10.5828 11.0266 11.4913 11.9780 12.4876 13.0210 13.5795 14.7757 16.0853 17.5185 19.0859 20.7989 25.8023 32.0150 39.6964
10 10.4622 10.9497 11.4639 12.0061 12.5779 13.1808 13.8164 14.4866 15.1929 15.9374 17.5487 19.3373 21.3215 23.5213 25.9587 33.2529 42.6195 54.5902
11 11.5668 12.1687 12.8078 13.4864 14.2068 14.9716 15.7836 16.6455 17.5603 18.5312 20.6546 23.0445 25.7329 28.7551 32.1504 42.5661 56.4053 74.6967
12 12.6825 13.4121 14.1920 15.0258 15.9171 16.8699 17.8885 18.9771 20.1407 21.3843 24.1331 27.2707 30.8502 34.9311 39.5805 54.2077 74.3270 101.841
13 13.8093 14.6803 15.6178 16.6268 17.7130 18.8821 20.1406 21.4953 22.9534 24.5227 28.0291 32.0887 36.7862 42.2187 48.4966 68.7596 97.6250 138.485
14 14.9474 15.9739 17.0863 18.2919 19.5986 21.0151 22.5505 24.2149 26.0192 27.9750 32.3926 37.5811 43.6720 50.8180 59.1959 86.9495 127.913 187.954
15 16.0969 17.2934 18.5989 20.0236 21.5786 23.2760 25.1290 27.1521 29.3609 31.7725 37.2797 43.8424 51.6595 60.9653 72.0351 109.687 167.286 254.738
16 17.2579 18.6393 20.1569 21.8245 23.6575 25.6725 27.8881 30.3243 33.0034 35.9497 42.7533 50.9804 60.9250 72.9390 87.4421 138.109 218.472 344.897
17 18.4304 20.0121 21.7616 23.6975 25.8404 28.2129 30.8402 33.7502 36.9737 40.5447 48.8837 59.1176 71.6730 87.0680 105.931 173.636 285.014 466.611
18 19.6147 21.4123 23.4144 25.6454 28.1324 30.9057 33.9990 37.4502 41.3013 45.5992 55.7497 68.3941 84.1407 103.740 128.117 218.045 371.518 630.925
19 20.8109 22.8406 25.1169 27.6712 30.5390 33.7600 37.3790 41.4463 46.0185 51.1591 63.4397 78.9692 98.6032 123.414 154.740 273.556 483.973 852.748
20 22.0190 24.2974 26.8704 29.7781 33.0660 36.7856 40.9955 45.7620 51.1601 57.2750 72.0524 91.0249 115.380 146.628 186.688 342.945 630.165 1152.21
25 28.2432 32.0303 36.4593 41.6459 47.7271 54.8645 63.2490 73.1059 84.7009 98.3471 133.334 181.871 249.214 342.603 471.981 1054.79 2348.80 5176.50
30 34.7849 40.5681 47.5754 56.0849 66.4388 79.0582 94.4608 113.283 136.308 164.494 241.333 356.787 530.312 790.948 1181.88 3227.17 8729.99 23221.6
12 FINANCIAL CONCEPTS AND MATHEMATICS
331
7/7/15 8:49 AM
M12_ARNO1799_01_SE_C12.indd 332 7/7/15 8:49 AM
CHAPTER 13
BOND VALUATION
Bonds, particularly those that are traded in liquid secondary markets, are
priced according to supply and demand, and their prices can be volatile. The
main influence is the general level of interest rates for securities of a similar risk
level and length of time to maturity. As a bond approaches its maturity date,
its market value grows closer to its nominal value, the amount that will be paid
at maturity. This is known as the pull to par, pull to maturity or pull to
redemption.
Irredeemable bonds
Take the case of a €1,000 irredeemable bond with an annual coupon of 8%.
This financial asset offers to any potential purchaser a regular and fixed €80 per
year in perpetuity (i.e. 8% of the par value of €1,000), but the actual price of
the bond will fluctuate in response to the prevailing rate of interest. When the
bond was issued, general interest rates for this risk class may well have been 8%
and so the bond may have been sold at €1,000. However, interest rates change
over time and the €80 coupon may not remain sufficient to maintain the bond
price at €1,000.
Suppose that the current rate of interest is now 10%. Investors will no longer
be willing to pay €1,000 for an instrument that yields only €80 per year. The
current market value of the bond will fall to €800 – the current value of the
irredeemable bond is given by dividing the coupon rate by the current rate of
interest, €80/0.10. This is the maximum amount needed to pay for similar
bonds given the current interest rate of 10%. We say that the bond is trading at
a ‘discount’ to its nominal value because it is trading below €1,000.
If the coupon rate is more than the current market interest rate, the bond price
will be greater than the nominal (par) value. Thus, if market rates are 6%,
the irredeemable bond will be priced at €1,333.33 (€80/0.06). We say that it is
trading at a ‘premium’ to its nominal value, i.e. at more than €1,000.
The formula relating the price of an irredeemable bond, the coupon and the
market rate of interest is:
C
PD =
kD
C = nominal annual income (the coupon rate × nominal (par) value of the
bond)
kD = market discount rate, the annual return required on bonds of similar risk
and characteristics.
Also:
I
VD =
kD
We may wish to establish the market rate of interest represented by the market
price of the bond. For example, if an irredeemable bond offers an annual coupon
of 9.5% and is currently trading at £87.50, with the next coupon due in one
year, the rate of return is:
C £9.5
kD = = × 100 = 10.86%
PD £87.5
Note this formula can be used only if the next coupon is payable one year
from the time of valuation. If there are coupons before then they need to be
discounted separately, adding to the overall value.
Redeemable bonds
A purchaser of a redeemable bond buys two types of income promise: first
the coupon, second the redemption payment. The amount that an investor
will pay depends on the amount these income flows are presently worth when
discounted at the current rate of return required on that risk class of debt. The
relationships are expressed in the following formulae:
C1 C2 C3 C4 Cn Rn
PD = + + + + ... + +
1 + k D (1 + k D )2 (1 + k D )3 (1 + k D )4 1 + k D ) n (1 + k D ) n
(1
and:
I1 I2 I3 I4 In Rn*
VD = + + + + ... + +
1 + k D (1 + k D ) 2
(1 + k D ) 3
(1 + k D ) 4
1 + kD )
(1 n
(1 + k D ) n
where C1, C2, C3 and C4 = nominal interest per bond in years 1, 2, 3 and 4 up to
n years
Rn and R*n = redemption value of a single bond, and total redemption value of
all bonds in issue in year n, the redemption date or maturity date.
The following examples illustrate the valuation of a bond when the market
redemption yield is given.
Example 13.1
Blackaby plc issued a bond with a par value of £100 in September 2014, redeem-
able in September 2020 at par. The coupon is 8% payable annually in September.
Therefore:
● the bond has a par value of £100 but this may not be what investors will pay for it
● the annual cash payment will be £8 (8% of par)
● in September 2020, £100 will be handed over to the bond holder (in the
absence of default by the issuer).
The price investors will pay for this bond at the time of issue if the current market
rate of interest for a security in this risk class is 7% can be worked out as follows
(computers and financial calculators will perform the task quicker, but by doing it
the old-fashioned way you gain a greater understanding of what is going on inside
the ‘black box’ of the machine):
This bond also gives the holder £100 in six years from now. 100
= £66.63
We need to add the present value of this £100 to the (1 + 0.07)6
present value of all the coupons
PD = £104.77
Example 13.2
It is now three years later. What is the value of Blackaby’s bond in the secondary
market in September 2017 if market interest rates rise by 200 basis points (i.e.
for this risk class they rise to 9%)? (Assume the next coupon payment is in one
year.)
100
+ = £77.22
(1 + 0.09)3
PD = £97.47
Example 13.3
Bluebird plc issued a bond many years ago that is due for redemption at £100 par
in three years. The annual coupon is 6% (next one payable in one year) and the
market price is £91. The rate of return now offered in the market by this bond is
found by solving for kD:
C1 C2 C3 R3
PD = + + +
1 + k D (1 + k D )2 (1 + k D )3 (1 + k D )3
6 6 6 100
91 = + + +
1 + k D (1 + k D ) 2
(1 + k D ) 3
(1 + k D )3
We’ll solve this problem through iteration, i.e. trial and error, by trying one interest
rate after another on paper. First we will try 9%, as this seems roughly right given
the capital gain of around 3% per year over the three years (i.e. £9 overall) plus the
6% coupon.
1
If you would like a refresher on IRR and other discounted cash flow calculations consult
Chapter 2 of Arnold, G. (2012) Corporate Financial Management.
At an interest rate (kD) of 9%, the right side of the equation amounts to £92.41:
100
+ = £77.22
(1 + 0.09)3
PD = £92.41
This is more than the £91 on the left side of the equation, so we conclude that we
are not discounting the cash flows on the right side of the equation by a sufficiently
high rate of return. At an interest rate of 10% the right-hand side of the equation
amounts to £90.05:
100
+ = £75.13
(1 + 0.10)3
PD = £90.05
This is less than the £91 we are aiming at, so the internal rate of return lies some-
where between 9% and 10%. We can be more precise using linear interpolation:
We are trying to find the value of kD, where the cash flows are discounted at just
the right rate to equal the amount paid for the bond (£91). kD is 9% plus the fraction
formed by the difference between points ‘a’ and ‘b’, that is 92.41 − 91, divided by
the difference between points ‘a’ and ‘c’, that is 92.41 − 90.05, multiplied by the
number of percentage points between a and c, that is 10 − 9, one percentage
point:
92.41 − 91
k D = 9% + × (10 − 9) = 9.59%
92.41 − 90.05
Thus the cash flows offered on this bond represent an average annual rate of
return of 9.59% on a £91 investment if the bond is held to maturity and the coupon
payments are reinvested at 9.59% before then. This is the yield to maturity or YTM
discussed in the next section.
Excel offers formulae, IRR and NPV, for these calculations – see below:
A B C D E F G
3 Year zero 1 2 3
5 Coupon payments 6 6 6
8 −91 6 6 106
11
12
14
16
17 Current bond price (NPV) 102.72 100.00 97.38 94.85 92.41 90.05
Using the above figures, format a cell (in this case E10) in Excel as a percentage
and type in
=IRR(B8:E8)
and 9.59% will appear in cell E10.
To understand the sensitivity of bond prices to changes in the rate of return, type
into a cell (in this case B17)
=NPV(B15,$C8:$E8)
and 102.72 will appear in cell B17, which is the market price if the rate of return is
5%. (NPV is the net present value of all the cash inflows, ignoring the initial outflow
to buy the bond.) The figures for 6%, 7%, 8%, 9% and 10% can be worked out in
the same fashion, or by copying B17 and pasting in C17, D17, E17, F17 and G17.
Thus, for a holder of Bluebird’s bonds in Example 13.3 the current yield is:
£6
× 100 = 6.59%
£91
This is a gross yield. The after-tax yield will be influenced by the investor’s tax
position.
Net interest yield = Gross yield (1 − T )
At a time when interest rates are higher than 6.59% for that risk class it is obvi-
ous that any potential purchaser of Bluebird bonds will be looking for a return
other than from the coupon. That additional return comes in the form of a
capital gain over three years of £100 – £91 = £9. A rough estimate of this annual
gain is (9/91) ÷ 3 = 3.3% per year. When this is added to the current yield we
have an approximation to the second type of yield, the yield to maturity (the
redemption yield).
The yield to maturity of a bond is the discount rate such that the present value
of all the cash inflows from the bond (interest plus principal) is equal to the
bond’s current market price. The rough estimate of 9.89% (6.59% + 3.3%) has
not taken into account the precise timing of the investor’s income flows.
When this is adjusted for, the yield to maturity is 9.59% – the internal rate of
return calculated in Example 13.3.
2
Also known as the interest yield, flat yield, income yield, simple yield, annual yield and
running yield.
rates have risen over the holding period, the bond could well be worth less
than if market interest rates remained constant or declined. This will have a
depressing effect on the rate of return received even though coupons have
been paid during the time the bonds were owned – see Example 13.4.
Example 13.4
If an investor bought Bluebird’s three-year bonds at £91 and sells them one year
later when the rate of return on two-year bonds of this risk level in the market has
risen to 10%, instead of receiving the original 9.59% yield to maturity he/she will
achieve a rate of return of only 8.86% over the year of holding, as explained below:
After one year of holding there are only two cash inflows left owing to a buyer:
£6 to be received in one year and £106 to be received in two years (£6 coupon
plus £100 nominal value):
6 106
Market value of bond after 1 year = + = 93.06
1 + 0.1 (1 + 0.1)2
C + ( Pt +1 − Pt )
r= × 100
Pt
There is an interest element (C/Pt) plus a capital gain or loss ((Pt+1 – Pt)/Pt) element
to the rate of return:
6 + (93.06 − 91)
r= × 100 = 8.86%
91
Semi-annual interest
The example of Bluebird is based on the assumption of annual interest payments.
This makes initial understanding easier and reflects the reality for many types
of bond, particularly internationally traded bonds. However, many companies
and governments around the world issue domestic bonds with semi-annual
interest payments. The rate of return calculation on these bonds is slightly
more complicated.
Example 13.5
Redwing has an 11% bond outstanding that pays interest semi-annually. It will be
redeemed in two years at €100 and has a current market price of €96, with
the next interest payment due in six months. The yield to maturity on this bond is
calculated as follows:
Cash flows
Point in time (years) 0.5 1 1.5 2.0
Taking the capital gain (€100 − €96 over two years) as about 2% per year, the
IRR/2 would be roughly 5.5% plus 1%, 6.5% for six months. To obtain a more
accurate yield to maturity figure we need to solve for kD allowing for the semi-
annual compounding of interest received:
5.50 5.50 5.50 105.50
96 = + 2
+ 3
+ 4
kD ⎛ kD ⎞ ⎛ kD ⎞ ⎛ kD ⎞
1+ 1 + 1 + 1 +
2 ⎜⎝ 2 ⎟⎠ ⎜⎝ 2 ⎟⎠ ⎜⎝ 2 ⎟⎠
100
+ = €76.29
(1 + 0.07)4
PD = €94.92
100
+ = €79.209
(1 + 0.06)4
PD = €98.267
The IRR needs to be converted from a half-yearly cash flow basis to an annual
basis (an effective annual yield).
(1 + s)2 = (1 + i )
where s is the semi-annual rate and i is the annual rate, i.e. interest received at the
half year is compounded.
Thus:
(1 + s)2 – 1 = i
The yield to maturity is the return that would be received given the current
rate of coupon and market price, and assuming the bond is held until
maturity.
The rate of return is the rate that an investor actually receives between the
purchase and when their bond is sold before maturity, or on reaching
maturity.
Yield to maturity and rate of return are only the same if the time to maturity
is the same as the holding period.
Example 13.6
Assume that Tom has just bought four bonds. The maturity dates are 1 year from
now, 5 years from now, 10 years from now and 20 years from now. For the sake
of simplicity assume that all the bonds are trading in the secondary market at
€1,000, which is also their par values to be paid at maturity, and that they each
offer a yield to maturity of 6% (annual coupons are €60).
Tom is planning to sell all of the bonds in a year from now. The question is, what
rate of return will he receive if between now and then the yield to maturity that
investors demand in the secondary market on these bonds rises from 6% to 10%,
or falls to 2%? (Again, assume for the sake of simplicity that the yield to maturity of
10% or 2% is the same regardless of whether the bond has a short or a long time
until maturity – there is a ‘flat yield curve’ as discussed later.)
One-year bond
In the case of the one-year bond Tom does not have to sell in the secondary
market; the issuer redeems the bond at its par value of €1,000. Tom also receives
the coupon of €60, so the rate of return he gains is 6% (60/1000). This is the same
as the yield to maturity when he bought the bond.
Five-year bond
C + ( Pt +1 − Pt )
Rate of return over the one-year holding periood r = × 100
Pt
To calculate Pt+1:
Pt+1 = four annual coupons discounted to time t + 1 (€60 × annuity factor for four
years at 10%) plus the redemption amount discounted back to t + 1:
+ 1000 = €683.01
(1 + 0.10)4
Pt+1 = €873.20
60 + (873.20 − 1000)
Rate of return over one year r = × 100 = −6.7%
1000
So, while the yield to maturity at time t was 6%, the rate of return over the one-year
holding period was −6.7% because of the large capital loss on the bond.
It is even worse for the 10-year and 20-year bonds. If yields to maturity rise from
6% to 10% over the holding year then these bonds can be sold for only €769.64
and €665.40 at time t + 1:
Ten-year bond
C + ( Pt +1 − Pt )
Rate of return r = × 100
Pt
+
1000 = €424.10
(1 + 0.10)9
Pt+1 = €769.64
60 + (769.64 − 1000)
Rate of return over one year r = × 100 = −17%
1000
Twenty-year bond
C + ( Pt +1 − Pt )
Rate of return r = × 100
Pt
1000
+ = €163.51
(1 + 0.10)19
Pt+1 = €665.40
60 + (665.40 − 1000)
Rate of return over one year r = × 100 = −27.5%
1000
So far, poor Tom. Because interest rates have risen, the value of all his bonds
(except the one-year bond) has fallen and he ends up with a considerable capital
loss, €691.76 in total.
If, however, interest rates fall by 4% points to 2%, then Tom is in luck. Each of his
bonds (except the one-year bond) is worth far more, giving him a gain of €1105.93
on top of his coupon at the end of one year. The individual bond returns are shown
in Table 13.1, for both a rise in interest rates to 10% or a fall to 2%. An interest rate
change of 4% is quite dramatic; typically interest rates change by far smaller
amounts, but this example demonstrates the different volatility of bond prices and
how important it is to understand bond pricing.
Of course, if each of the bonds is held until maturity Tom will receive a 6% rate of
return on all of them, because they will then be redeemed at their par value.
Table 13.1 Rates of return on Tom’s bonds given market interest rate changes
and sale after one year
In general, rates of returns and prices for long-term bonds are more volatile
than they are for short-term bonds.
This means that if the investor has a time horizon of only a year or two,
long-term bonds may be seen as risky investments – even if they have very low
default risk, they have high interest rate risk. It is not uncommon for bonds to
lose or gain a significant percentage of their value in a year, even if they are
reputable government bonds. This is illustrated in Chapter 1 (Figure 1.3) by the
returns on UK gilts for every year going back to 1900. On many occasions an
investor who purchased bonds at the beginning of the year and sold at the end
lost more than 10%, despite receiving coupons.
Duration
To gain a measure of interest rate risk and volatility for a bond relative to
others, bond market participants often use duration. The duration3 metric is
a summary measure of how far into the future is the average date of the
cash flows to be received, when the cash flows are weighted by their size after
they have been discounted.
In other words,
the duration of a bond is the weighted average maturity time of all pay-
ments (coupons and principal) to be received from owning a bond, where
the weights are the discounted present values of the payments.
So, for zero coupon bonds the effective duration is the same as its actual term to
maturity – the ‘average’ maturity time is the same as the final payout, the only
cash flow received. A three-year zero coupon bond has a duration of three years.
For coupon-paying bonds the duration is shorter than the stated term to
maturity because as the years go by the investor receives income from the bond
which pushes the weighted average timing of income flows more towards the
start date than is the case on a zero coupon bond.
A three-year coupon-paying bond offering £7 per year (with the first in one
year from now) and £100 on maturity can be seen as having cash flows equal
to the following three zero coupon bonds:
A one-year zero coupon bond paying £7 in one year’s time
A two-year zero coupon bond paying £7 in two years’ time
A three-year zero coupon bond paying £107 in three years’ time
If the present yields to maturity for bonds of this risk class are also 7% then the
duration can be calculated – see Table 13.2 – where the present value
Ct
PV =
(1 + k D )t
3
Often referred to as Macaulay’s duration after Frederick Macaulay who formulated it in the
1930s.
As we might expect, the duration of 2.808 years is almost as much as the time
to maturity but it is lowered from the full three years because some of the income
is received before the end of three years. This three-year 7% coupon bond has
the same duration as a 2.808-year zero coupon bond also yielding 7%.
Holding other factors constant, the longer the term to maturity of a bond,
the longer its duration.
Article 13.1
Source: Rodrigues, V. (2014) Investors lap up ultra-long corporate bonds, Financial Times,
11 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Table 13.4 Calculating duration on a four-year 7% coupon bond when the yield to
maturity is 10%
Period
With the interest rate at 10%, duration has fallen from 3.6243 years to 3.603
years. This is because at the higher interest rate the more distant cash flows are
discounted more heavily and thus comprise a lower overall proportion of the
overall discounted cash flows – the nearer-term cash flows gain relative weight
as the duration reduces.
If interest rates rise, the duration falls (keeping everything else constant).
Article 13.2
Source: Rodrigues, V. and Mackenzie, M. (2013) Investors bet on junk bonds to outperform,
Financial Times, 30 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
Table 13.5 Calculating duration on a four-year 20% coupon bond when the yield to
maturity remains at 7%
Period
The bond with £20 coupons has a shorter duration, at 3.2547 years, than the
bond with the £7 coupon, at 3.6243 years, despite the yield to maturity and
time to maturity remaining the same. Thus we come to another rule:
The higher the coupon rate on the bond, the shorter the bond’s duration.
Answer:
0.01
Change in bond price ≈ −3.6243 × × 100 = −3.3
39%
1 + 0.07
Thus, for a 1 percentage point change in market interest rates this bond’s price
moves by roughly 3.39%. (Note that this formula can only be used for small
changes in yield to maturity of one percentage point or less, and even then it
is only an approximation. It slightly overestimates price declines and underes-
timates price increases – see convexity discussion later.) We can compare this
degree of sensitivity to interest rate changes with other bonds. Let us take the
four-year bond in Table 13.5 offering 20% coupons with YTM of 7%. It has a
duration of 3.2547 years.
0.01
Change in bond price ≈ −3.2547 × × 100 = −3.0
04%
1 + 0.07
Clearly, this bond carries less interest rate risk than the 7% coupon bond, as
its price changes by only 3.04% when yields change by 1 percentage point.
The lower duration and therefore lower interest rate risk, but same yield to
maturity, on the 20% coupon bond may induce an investor to switch invest-
ment funds from the more risky bond (7% coupon) to this less risky one.
Convexity
In the section discussing the effect of duration on interest rate risk we noted
that the formula, while roughly correct, produces errors for the influence of
interest rate changes on bond pricing. This is because it assumes a linear rela-
tionship between interest rate changes and bond price changes – this is shown
by the straight diagonal line in Figure 13.1. The exact valuation relationship
is curved, and the curvature around some interest rate level is measured by
convexity. The true relationship line is tangential to the straight line assump-
tion only at a zero interest rate change, i.e. it has the same slope, therefore
for very small interest rate changes the duration approach gives the true
answer. However, if we test large interest movements the true bond price
changes are different to that determined by the duration-based calculation
we used earlier.
Figure 13.1 The linear assumption for the relationship between bond price and YTM
This can be illustrated using the same example above, where we calculated a
change in bond price of −3.39% for a 1% increase in yield to maturity. We can
now calculate the actual change for an increase in 1%. At the interest rate of
7% the four-year bond was priced at £100. If interest rates rise to 8% then the
price changes to £96.6877:
bond price changes given the maturity and coupon rate to form a view of the
ball-park movements in various scenarios. Besides, modern computer systems
calculate duration and convexity automatically and display them on trading
screens.
For bond investors, high convexity is usually a desirable quality and so they
pay premiums to hold such bonds. This can be understood by examining
Figure 13.2. Two bonds are shown, each with the same duration at point ‘0’ (no
change in interest rate), but one has greater convexity. If interest rates increase,
the one with the greater convexity will experience a lower percentage decrease
in price than the bond with lower convexity. However, if rates decline, the high
convexity bond will have a greater uplift in value than the low convexity bond.
eurozone and Japanese governments.4 Note that default (and liquidity) risk
remains constant along one of the lines; the reason for the different rates is the
time to maturity of the bonds. Thus, a two-year US government bond has to
offer 0.57% whereas a ten-year bond offered by the same borrower gives 2.62%.
Note that the yield curve for the eurozone is only for the most creditworthy
governments who have adopted the euro (e.g. Germany). Less safe govern-
ments had to pay a lot more in 2014 as investors worried whether they would
default.
4
Using the benchmark yield curves as examples of the term structure of interest rates may
offend theoretical purity (because we should be using zero coupon, e.g. STRIPS, rather than
those with coupons that have to be reinvested before the redemption date – we do not
know the reinvestment rate), but they are handy approximate measures and help illustrate
this section.
Three main hypotheses have been advanced to explain the shape of the yield
curve (these are not mutually exclusive – all three can operate at the same time
to influence the curve):
Spot rates change over time. The market may have allowed Hype to issue
one-year bonds yielding 8% at a point in time in 2014 but a year later (time
2015) the one-year spot rate may have changed to become 10%. If investors
expect that one-year spot rates will become 10% at time 2015 they will have a
theoretical limit on the yield that they require from a two-year bond when
Figure 13.5 The term structure of interest rates for Hype plc at time 2014
viewed from time 2014. Imagine that an investor (lender) wishes to lend
£1,000 for a two-year period and is contemplating two alternative approaches:
1 Buy a one-year bond at a spot rate of 8%; after one year has passed the bond
will come to maturity. The released funds can then be invested in another
one-year bond at a spot rate of 10%, expected to be the going rate for bonds
of this risk class at time 2015.5
2 Buy a two-year bond at the spot rate at time 2014.
Under the first option the lender will have a sum of £1,188 at the end of two
years:
Given the anticipated change in one-year spot rates to 10% the investor will
buy the two-year bond only if it gives the same average annual yield over two
years as a series of one-year bonds (the first option). The annual interest
required will be:
£1,000 (1 + kD)2 = £1,188
k D = (1188
, / 1,000) − 1 = 0.08995, or 8.995%
which is the spot rate quoted for a two-year bond in 2014 in the second option.
Thus, it is the expectation of spot interest rates changing that determines the
shape of the yield curve according to the expectations hypothesis.
Now consider a downward-sloping yield curve where the spot rate on a one-
year instrument is 11% and the expectation is that one year from now spot
rates will fall to 8% for the one-year bonds. An investor considering a two-year
investment will obtain an annual yield (k) of 9.49% by investing in a series of
one-year bonds, viz:
5
I have simplified this to spot rates only. In reality investors in bonds can agree to buy a
bond one year (or more years) from now, a forward. The price of the forward purchase is
agreed now, thus traders can lock in the interest rate from that point on. This implied
forward rate can be interpreted as the market’s consensus of the spot rates in one year from
now.
or (1.08)(1.11) − 1 = 0.0949
With this expectation for movements in one-year spot rates, lenders will demand
an annual rate of return of 9.49% from two-year bonds of the same risk class.
Thus in circumstances where short-term spot interest rates are expected to fall,
the yield curve will be downward sloping.
Example 13.7
Spot rates
If the present spot rate for a one-year bond is 5% and for a two-year bond is 6.5%,
what is the expected one-year spot rate in a year’s time?
Answer
If the two-year rate is set to equal the rate on a series of one-year spot rates then:
(1 + 0.065)2
x= − 1 = 0.0802 or 8.02%
1 + 0.05
rates as they occur. The ten-year bond locks in a fixed rate for the full ten years
if held to maturity. Investors prefer short-term bonds so that they can benefit
from rising rates and so will accept a lower return on short-dated instruments.
A further factor is that in many bond markets there is a greater volume of trad-
ing for short-dated instruments than longer-dated ones, i.e. there is greater
liquidity, an increased speed and ease of the sale of an asset. In bond markets
where there is high liquidity for both short- and long-term bonds, the title
‘liquidity-preference theory’ seems incorrectly used because there is no prob-
lem of illiquidity for long-term bonds. For example, for government bonds,
sale in the secondary market is often as quick and easy as for short-term bonds.
In the bond markets where liquidity is fairly constant along the yield curve,
the premium for long-term bonds is generally compensation for the extra risk
of capital loss; ‘term premium’ might be a better title for the hypothesis.
If banks need to borrow large quantities quickly they will sell some of their
short-term instruments, increasing the supply on the market, so pushing
down the price and raising the yield. Meanwhile, pension funds may be flush
with cash and may buy large quantities of 20-year bonds, helping to temporar-
ily move yields downward at the long end of the market. At other times banks,
pension funds and the buying and selling pressures of a multitude of other
financial institutions will influence the supply and demand position in the
opposite direction. The point is that the players in the different parts of the
yield curve tend to be different. This hypothesis helps to explain the often
lumpy or humped yield curve.
Additional reading
Bodie, Z., Kane, A. and Marcus, A.J. (2014) Investments. McGraw-Hill.
Chisholm, A.M. (2009) An Introduction to International Capital Markets. 2nd
edition. John Wiley & Sons.
Choudry, M. (2010) An Introduction to Bond Markets. 4th edition. John Wiley &
Sons.
Fabozzi, F.J. (2012) Bond Markets, Analysis and Strategies. 8th edition. Prentice
Hall.
Veronesi, P. (2010) Fixed Income Securities. John Wiley & Sons.
Vast amounts of money in a wide variety of currencies are traded on the money
markets daily. Most of this huge volume of short-term instruments is traded
on a discount basis; there is no regular coupon payment, the instruments
are bought at a discount to their face value; any return for investors comes
from the difference between the price at which they were purchased and the
payout received when they reach maturity or are sold in the secondary market
before then.
There are two important considerations to take note of when undertaking any
calculations associated with money market securities:
If you wanted to compare a 5.5% interest quoted on a 365-day year basis with
another instrument calculated on the basis of a 360-day year, the calculation
would be:
⎛ 360 ⎞
Comparison interest rate = 5.5 × ⎜ = 5.4246
657%
⎝ 365 ⎟⎠
Difference £75,343
If the rate quoted is presented for a 360-day year then to compare with other
effective annual yield rates we need to adjust upwards. This time the comparison
rate is based on 365-days.
Let us assume the 360-day rate is 10%. To compare with other rates on a
365-day basis:
⎛ 365 ⎞
Comparison interest rate = 10.0 × ⎜ = 10.13
38889%
⎝ 360 ⎟⎠
The bond equivalent yield (also known as equivalent bond yield) is the yield
that is usually quoted in newspapers and it allows a comparison between
fixed-income securities whose payments are not annual and securities that
have annual yields. So a wide variety of debt instrument yields is expressed in
the same annual terms, whether they mature in a matter of days, have interest
paid every three months or have one yearly interest payment. The bey uses the
actual number of days in a year (365 or 366).
Example 14.1
Bond equivalent rate
Imagine a 12-month £100 UK Treasury bill was sold at a discount of 2%, i.e. at
£98, the purchase price or market price. We recognise that the investment made
is £98 and we gain £2 when it is redeemed in one year. Thus we know that the
true rate of return is slightly over 2%.
Given that there is a full year to maturity we know this is going to be the annual
rate:
100 − 98 365
bey = × × 100 = 2.04%
98 365
So although the bill was discounted at 2%, the actual return is more than this
because the investor did not pay the face value.
The discount yiel (bank-discount basis or discount rate) is the yield when using
the face value as the base rather than the actual amount invested by the buyer.
Discount yields are often calculated using a 360-day year count convention (e.g. in
US, German, Dutch, French and Italian T-bills), but the UK uses a 365-day year in
its calculations.
Example 14.2
Discount yield
For a UK T-bill issued at £98 when the face value is £100 and the time to maturity
is one year, when there are 365-days in the year:
Treasury bills
We shall use examples from the UK and US Treasury bills to explain how these
instruments are valued and how the returns on them are calculated.
Table 14.1 shows the results from the four sales of UK Treasury bills which took
place weekly during March 2014, on the 7th, 14th, 21st and 28th. As different
bidders pay different prices, a bill’s tender results are averaged. Each bidder
therefore must work out their own results to give them accurate information
about their investment.
Table 14.1 DMO Treasury bill tender results 1 March 2014 to 31 March 2014
1 month
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 07-Apr-14 2,000 2.21 0.393578% 99.969817
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 14-Apr-14 2,000 3.30 0.364505% 99.972046
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 22-Apr-14 2,000 1.85 0.381211% 99.969721
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 28-Apr-14 2,000 1.62 0.407344% 99.968761
3 months
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 09-Jun-14 1,500 2.64 0.363186% 99.909534
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 16-Jun-14 2,000 3.09 0.379104% 99.905573
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 23-Jun-14 2,000 1.95 0.390464% 99.902746
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 30-Jun-14 2,000 1.51 0.421457% 99.895035
6 months
07-Mar-14 10-Mar-14 08-Sep-14 1,500 2.87 0.409168% 99.796392
14-Mar-14 17-Mar-14 15-Sep-14 1,500 3.23 0.394030% 99.803910
21-Mar-14 24-Mar-14 22-Sep-14 1,500 2.17 0.400866% 99.800515
28-Mar-14 31-Mar-14 29-Sep-14 1,500 1.70 0.422876% 99.789585
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
Example 14.3
UK three-month Treasury bill
If we take the three-month Treasury bill sold at tender on 24 March at a discount
price of £99.902746, we can work out the discount yield (d), yield (bey) and
purchase price. Note that the time difference between the date of purchase and
redemption is only 91 days in this case and we must express these interest rates
in annual terms, so we multiply by 365/91.
Discount yield
( Face value – Purchase price) Days in year
d= × × 100 = annual rate
Face value Days to maturity
(100 − 99.902746) 365
d= × × 100 = 0.390085% per annum
100 91
Another example
You invest for three months and receive a ‘simple’ annual yield of 3%. This is an
annual rate that does not take into account compounding over the year – i.e.
interest received on interest, added after each quarter. With compounding the
effective annual rate is:
4 /1
⎡ 0.03 ⎤
⎢1 + ⎥ − 1 × 100 = 3.0339%
⎣ 4 / 1⎦
Thus, over a period of one year you receive an extra 0.0339% because after the
first three-month period you reinvest the maturity amount, including interest from
the first investment, in an identical investment for the next three of the remaining
nine months. And do the same after six months and nine months. Thus you
receive interest on interest received of 0.0339%. This is, of course, assuming
identical investments every three months. While this is unrealistic, at least the EAR
provides a gauge of the ‘true’ annual rate offered on short-term securities.
Purchase price
To calculate the price to be paid if the discount yield is 0.390085% we need to
start with the face value and take away the discount that applies when the term
is only one-quarter of the year or, more strictly, for 91/365th of the year.
The purchase price is the face value of 100 multiplied by 1 minus the discount
for this portion of the year:
⎡ ⎛ 0.00390085 × 91⎞ ⎤
Purchase price = 100 × ⎢1 − ⎜ ⎟⎠ ⎥ = £99.902746
⎢⎣ ⎝ 365 ⎥⎦
Note that the purchase price is often called the settlement amount. This is
because the bill is paid for on the settlement day rather than the transaction or
bargain day, which is usually one day earlier in the secondary market.
The results for the tender of this 24 March bill are in Table 14.2. The actual bids
from buyers varied from a yield (bey) of 0.33% to a high of 0.418% with an
average yield of 0.390464%.
A bidder tendering the lowest accepted yield, 0.33%, would have paid
£99.9177936 for their bills:
If:
Then:
Face value
Purchase price =
⎛ bey 91 ⎞
1+ ⎜ × ⎟⎠
⎝ 100 365
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
100
Purchase price = = £99.9177
7936
⎛ 0.33 91 ⎞
1+ ⎜ ×
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
And a bidder tendering the highest yield, 0.418%, would have paid
£99.89589479:
Face value
Purchase price =
⎛ bey 91 ⎞
1+ ⎜ ×
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
100
Purchase price = = £99.895
589479
⎛ 0.418 91 ⎞
1+ ⎜ ×
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
During the life of a bill, its value fluctuates daily as it is traded between
investors – see Table 14.3, which gives the daily March and April 2014 figures
for this particular bill.
Table 14.3 Data for Treasury bill GB00B7P4VP73, 21 March to 16 April 2014
Source: www.dmo.gov.uk
The price increases as the days to maturity decrease (all else remaining the
same) and on redemption day, in this case 23 June 2014, the holder will receive
the face value of £100. The yield in Table 14.3 is the (annual) return (bey) that
a purchaser in the secondary market will achieve between purchase date (the
settlement date is one day after the close of business transaction date) and
maturity date. We can check these figures, using 8 April as the purchase date:
US Treasury bills
While in many countries bills are bought in the primary market (from the
government) at the bidding price, in the US all bidders, competitive and
non-competitive, receive the same discount rate, and therefore the same yield,
as the highest accepted bid and so pay the same purchase price for their bills.
Table 14.4 gives the results of US T-bill auctions held during March 2014.
If we take the 26-week T-bill that was auctioned on 17 March 2014 below its
par value at $99.959556, we can work out the figures in Example 14.4.
Source: www.treasurydirect.gov
Example 14.4
US Treasury bill
For US short-term investments (less than one year) the day count is actual/360.
To calculate the discount yield, d, on the 26-week (182 days) US T-bill sold on
20 March 2014 at a discount price of $99.959556:
⎡ ⎛ 0.0008 × 182 ⎞ ⎤
Purchase price = 100 × ⎢1 − ⎜ ⎟⎠ ⎥ = £99
9.959556
⎢⎣ ⎝ 360 ⎥⎦
To calculate the bey from this bill, a 365-day (366 in a leap year) year is used
(because a 360-day year would underestimate the return):
The effective annual rate (over a 12-month investment period) assuming compound-
ing after reinvesting at day 182 with the same bey on this T-bill is:
365 /182
⎛ 0.00081143 ⎞
EAR = ⎜ 1 + − 1 = 0.08116%
⎝ 365/182 ⎟⎠
Commercial paper
After T-bills, commercial paper is the most common money market instrument.
It is a very popular way of raising money for large, well-regarded companies.
Example 14.5
Commercial paper
A dealer buys $2,000,000 worth of Eurodollar commercial paper from a company
requiring liquidity, with a 60-day maturity, at a discounted price of $1,994,874.
For Eurodollar (and most other Eurocurrency) deals interest is calculated using an
actual/360-day count convention (the same as in the US).
(2,000,000 − 1,994, 87
74) 360
= × × 100 = 1.5378% per annum
2,000,000 60
0 − 1,994,874) 365
(2, 000, 000
bey = × × 100 = 1.5632% per ann
num
1,994, 874 60
Repurchase agreements
Repurchase agreements (repos) and reverse repos are collateralised agreements
used mainly by banks to borrow from or lend to each other with cash that is
available for a short time (usually overnight or for a few days). Repo rates are
calculated for a variety of maturities.
Example 14.6
Repurchase agreement
A high street bank has the need to borrow £6 million for 14 days. It agrees to sell
a portfolio of its financial assets, in this case government bonds, to a lender for
£6 million. An agreement is drawn up (a repo) by which the bank agrees to repurchase
the portfolio (or an equivalent portfolio) 14 days later for £6,001,219.73. The extra
amount of £1,219.73 represents the interest on £6 million over 14 days at an
annual rate of 0.53%. Using an actual/365-day count convention, the calculation is:
Days to maturity
Interest = Selling price × Interest rate ×
Days in year
0.53 4
14
Interest = 6, 000, 000 × × = £1,219.73
100 365
Note that the agreement is to ‘sell’ securities and thereby borrow on a particular
date. The value date is when the transaction acquires value. This is not always
the same as the settlement date – when the amounts are actually transferred,
i.e. ‘settled’ or ‘cleared’ – because the value date may fall on a non-business day
such as a weekend.
Example 14.7
Repo bond equivalent yield
A financial institution borrows £26 million through a repo for 14 days. The difference
between the amounts in the first and second legs is £5,285.48, therefore the annual
rate of interest (bey) is:
5, 285.48 365
bey = × × 100 = 0.53%
26, 000, 000 14
In some markets, e.g. the US, the repo yield or repo rate of interest is calculated
based on a 360-day year:
Of course, this is not the bond equivalent yield, but merely the convention
used in some places to work out yields and prices of repurchases, strangely
enough. The repo rate is the one that will be most quoted in these markets,
so you need to remember that this is not even close to the true annualised
interest rate.
Example 14.8
Repo interest paid
A bank lends £45 million overnight at an annual bey rate of 0.42%. The actual
amount of interest is:
0.42 1
Amount of interest = 45, 000, 000 × × = £517.81
100 365
Example 14.9
A repo buy-back amount
A company owning £20 million worth of Treasury bills wishes to raise cash on
28 February and enters into an agreement to sell the bills and buy them back
in one week’s time. The agreed buy-back price would be £20 million plus the
accrued interest. The bond equivalent yield on 28 February for a one-week repo
is 0.52167%:
⎛ Days to maturity ⎞
Buy-back price = Selling price + ⎜ Selling price × Interest rate ×
⎝ Days in year ⎟⎠
⎛ 0.52167 7 ⎞
Buy-back price = 20, 000, 000 + ⎜ 20, 000, 000 × × = £20, 002, 000.93
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
This is not quite what happens in the markets because they impose ‘haircuts’.
Haircuts
Haircuts counteract the possibility of loss due to a drop in value of the securities
involved in a repo (and illiquidity and counterparty risk) by reducing the cash
received by the seller for a given quantity of collateral. The lender makes sure
that there is more collateral than the amount actually lent, also called margin
or over-collateralisation.
Example 14.10
A repo with a haircut
If a company has ownership of £20 million of gilts and wishes to raise money for
7 days through the repo market it can do so, but not all of the £20 million can be
borrowed. If a 0.95% haircut is imposed on £20 million, given a bond equivalent
yield of 0.52167%, the seller receives £19,810,000 in return for £20 million worth
of securities being sold in the first leg to the lender. Note that the repo interest is
only applied to the lesser amount.
The buyer (lender) pays out £19,810,000, but has securities worth £20 million, and
receives interest on the amount of cash actually lent. The buy-back price of a repo
with a haircut can then be calculated:
Buy-back price
⎡ Days to maturity ⎤
= Selling price + ⎢ ( Selling price − Haircut ) × Interest rate × ⎥
⎣ Days in year ⎦
Example 14.11
Certificate of deposit
A £75,000 CD is issued on 15 March for two months at 1.04% (expressed as
an annual rate, even though the money is deposited for a mere two months, often
called the coupon rate). Using an actual/365-day count, this means that the holder
will receive the following at maturity, including accumulated interest:
⎛ 1.04 61 ⎞
Value at maturity = 75, 000 + ⎜ 75, 000 × × = £75,130.36
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
If the CD is sold to another investor with 16 days left to maturity, its present value
(at the time of sale) if annual rates of interest on 16-day CDs are 1.04% is:
Value at maturity
Present value =
⎛ Interest Days to maturity ⎞
1+ ⎜ ×
⎝ 100 Days in year ⎟⎠
75,130.36
Present value = = £75, 096.12
⎛ 1.04 16 ⎞
1+ ⎜ ×
⎝ 100 365 ⎟⎠
Thus, the second holder of the CD will pay £75,096.12 now and receive
£75,130.36 from the holder if they keep it for another 16 days.
The annualised yield to maturity of this CD held for 16 days is:
For Eurocurrency CDs a 360-day year convention is used, thus the future value at
maturity is given by the following formula:
It is important to remember that the interest (coupon rate) quoted in these markets
is based on the 360-day convention and is not the same as the yield to maturity
based on a 365-day year.
Example 14.12
Eurocurrency CD
If the quoted rate based on a 360-day year is 3% for a CD with a present value of
$10 million with 92 days to maturity, the value at maturity is:
⎛ 3 92 ⎞
Value at maturity = $10m + ⎜ $10m × × = $10
0.076667m
⎝ 100 360 ⎟⎠
Bill of exchange
Bills of exchange are used by companies to facilitate trading by granting a
credit period to a customer. The customer signs a bill (accepts it) promising to
pay a sum of money to the seller at a set date.
Example 14.13
Bill of exchange
A customer has accepted a bill of exchange which commits it to pay £400,000 in
180 days. The supplier needs to raise cash immediately and so sells the bill to a discount
house or bank for £390,000. The discounter will, after 180 days, realise a profit of
£10,000 on a £390,000 asset. To calculate the effective rate of interest over 180 days:
Discount
Interest = × 100
Discounted price
10
0, 000
Interest = × 100 = 2.5641%
390, 000
To calculate the annual rate of interest, the bond equivalent yield, this equates to:
Discount Days in year
bey = × 100 ×
Discounted price Days to maturity
Through this arrangement the customer has the benefit of the goods on 180 days’
credit, the supplier has made a sale and immediately receives cash from the
discount house amounting to 97.4359% of the total due. The discounter, if it can
borrow its funds at less than 2.5641% over 180 days, turns in a healthy profit.
Banker’s acceptance
With banker’s acceptances it is a bank that takes on the liability to pay a sum
of money on a fixed date.
Example 14.14
The use of a banker’s acceptance
A German company purchases €8.5 million of goods from a Swiss company. It
draws up a document promising to pay for the goods in 90 days’ time, which its
bank accepts, that is, it is obliged to pay €8.5 million when it is due.
By stamping ‘accepted’ on the document, the document becomes more valuable
than if the promise to pay was given by the buying company only. Also it is a
negotiable (sellable) instrument.
Twenty days after the Swiss exporter receives the banker’s acceptance (BA) it
decides to sell it in the money market to raise some extra short-term finance. It is
sold at a discount of 0.95%. To calculate how much (the selling price) it receives:
Selling price = Face value − (Face value × Discount percentage)
⎛ 0.95 ⎞
Selling price = 8, 500, 000 − ⎜ 8, 500, 000 ×
⎝ 100 ⎟⎠
To calculate the annual rate of interest, the bond equivalent yield, which this is
costing them:
Discount amount Days in year
bey = × 100 ×
Discounted price Days to maturity
80, 750 36
65
bey = × 100 × = 5.0011%
8, 419, 250 70
The exporter can shield itself from the risk of exchange rates shifting over the
remaining 70 days until the BA pays out by discounting the acceptance, receiving
euros and then converting these to Swiss francs. And, of course, the exporter is
not exposed to the credit risk of the importer because it has the guarantee from
the importer’s bank.
Example 14.15
A US banker’s acceptance
If an institution sells a BA with a face value of $10 million when the rate of discount
is quoted at 3.05% based on a 360-day convention and the length of time to
maturity is 60 days, the amount to be received is:
⎛ Days to maturity ⎞
Selling price = Face value − ⎜ Face value × Discount percentage × ⎟⎠
⎝ 360
⎛ 3.05 60 ⎞
Selling price = 10, 000, 000 − ⎜ 10, 000, 000 × × = $9, 949,166.67
⎝ 100 360 ⎟⎠
In the strange world of modern finance you sometimes need to ask yourself
who ends up with your money when you pay your monthly mortgage, or your
credit card bill or the instalment payment on your car. In the old days you
would have found that it was the organisation from which you originally
borrowed and whose name is at the top of the monthly statement. Today
you cannot be so sure because there is now a thriving market in repackaged
debt – debt that is tied up in the bond markets.
Asset-backed securities
In this market a mortgage lender, for example, collects together a few
thousand of its mortgage ‘claims’ (the right of the lender to receive regular
interest and capital from the borrowers); it then sells those claims in a
collective package as bonds to other institutions, or participants in the market
generally. This permits the replacement of long-term illiquid assets with
immediate cash (improving liquidity and financial gearing), which can then
be used to generate more mortgages. It may also allow a profit on the difference
between the interest on the mortgages and the interest on the bonds. The
mortgages might be generating 6% interest, but the bonds secured on the cash
flow from the mortgages might pay a coupon of only 5%. The 5% is known as
the pass-through rate, the rate that is passed through to investors once fees
and commission have been deducted.
Rather than selling bonds in the mortgage company itself, a new company is
established, called a special purpose vehicle (SPV) or special purpose entity
(SPE). This new entity is then given the right to collect the cash flows from the
mortgages. It has to pay the mortgage company for this. To make this payment
it sells bonds secured against the assets of the SPV (e.g. mortgage claims). By
creating an SPV there is a separation of the creditworthiness of the assets
involved from the general creditworthiness of the parent company.
The sale of the financial claims can be either ‘non-recourse’, in which case
the buyer of the securitised bonds (the lender to the SPV) bears the risk of
non-payment by the mortgage holders, or ‘with recourse’ to the mortgage
lender should the mortgage payment fall short (with recourse the bonds might
be said to have ‘credit enhancement’).
Example 15.1
Car loan securitisation
GM Financial, the subsidiary of General Motors responsible for administering car loans,
which regularly securitises its loans, explains securitisation on its website. Notice
the recourse to GM if some customers do not pay – it suffers any ‘credit losses’:
Source: www.gmfinancial.com
Article 15.1
Deutsche Bank, Credit Suisse and JPMorgan are marketing the ‘Reo-to-rental’ after
securing a surprise triple-A rating from Moody’s, Morningstar and Kroll for the
bonds, which are backed by single-family rental properties owned by Blackstone.
Bankers involved in the solar panel deal had a tougher time convincing rating
agencies to evaluate the bonds, according to people familiar with the transaction,
after struggling to put together a deal for many months.
As talks with rating agencies about the potential deal deepened this year they hit
repeated structural snags. Rating agencies usually rely on historical data to judge
the risks of bonds defaulting. In the case of solar panel installations, such data is
lacking, making it difficult for the agencies to assess the probability of solar panel
lessors missing out on their payments.
Some bankers said that despite the risks of investing in a new asset class, the solar
bonds could attract interest from investors keen to place money into environmen-
tally friendly assets that can also generate decent returns.
‘There is a pool of capital that wants to invest in these types of assets,’ said one
banker at a large US investment bank. ‘People love to talk about clean technology
and renewables, because at some level most institutional investors want to invest
in things they can put in their annual report with glossy pictures.’
Solar panel companies will also be hoping that a successful sale of the bonds will
provide them with an additional source of capital to finance solar panel installations.
To date they have mostly relied on financing from big investment banks to help
fund their growth.
Why securitise?
Securitisation permits banks, etc. to focus on the aspects of the lending process
where they have a competitive edge. Some, for example, are better at originat-
ing loans than funding them, so they sell the loans they have created, raising
cash to originate more loans. Other motives include the need to change the
risk profile of the bank’s assets (e.g. reduce its exposure to the housing market)
or to reduce the need for reserve capital: if the loans are removed from the asset
side of the bank’s balance sheet it does not need to retain the same quantity of
reserves – the released reserve capital can then be used in more productive ways
(There is more on capital reserves in Chapter 16.)
home, car and student loan assets. There may be a pre-payment risk with
these because the bond holders do not know the proportion of borrowers
who will repay their loans earlier than expected. By repaying earlier than
expected the overall length of time to maturity of the pool of assets is
curtailed.
● Revolving structures. The asset pool is topped up with new assets as principal
is paid on older ones. In other words, when borrowers pay off their
debt principal, the SPV then has cash which can be used to buy, say,
more car loans, credit card debt, etc., but only if they fulfil key criteria
in terms of quality of the financial asset. Interest payments made by the
borrowers is regularly passed on to the SPV bond holders. The replacement
of maturing loans carries on in the revolving period, but when the
time comes for the amortisation period principal payments are paid to
bond holders either periodically or in a single lump sum (bullet or
slug methods).
● Master trust. Many batches of securitised bonds can be issued from the same
SPV. A large number of mortgages, say, are sold to the SPV, which act as the
collateral for a number of securitisations. ABS sold with this collateral back-
ing in a single trust have a variety of different maturities and redemptions.
The originator can replenish the asset pool by transferring new mortgages
of a comparable credit quality that meet certain pre-defined minimum
standards to the trust. Then additional series of ABS, identified by specific
dates, can be issued. Thus a recurring process is created with numerous
rounds of ABS (often called certificates) issues all backed by a single pool
of assets. This is particularly useful where the assets are receivables with
a short life, such as credit card receivables that may be paid off in a matter of
days or months by the credit card borrowers. New cardholder receivables
can take over from the old ones in providing cash flow and security for the
ABS. Some of the ABS issued under the master trust may be of lower credit
quality (offering high yields) than others.
Article 15.2
Investors were thereby freed from prepayment and extension risk and left only
with credit risk, and the impact of any bad loans would be cushioned by the size of
the whole giant mortgage pool.
Master trusts enabled the UK market to expand rapidly. Swathes of the bonds were
sold overseas because it was far easier to arrange currency swaps on paper with set
maturity dates than it would have been on a pass-through deal with its uncertain
quarterly payments.
Investors liked the apparent relative simplicity of the deals. By buying bonds
backed by a pool of known quality, they saved on the effort of analysing each deal
in great depth.
But the upshot of the simple front was the complexity that lurked behind the
master trust. ‘They have got many strong positives but one big negative, and that’s
the complexity,’ said one expert, summing up the industry’s dilemma.
‘Either we have a complex security or a simple-looking security backed by a
complex structure.’
Some investors favour the former. ‘Master trusts create concentration problems,’
says Chris Ames, head of asset-backed securities at Schroders. ‘If I own a 2005
bond and a 2006 bond from the same master trust, then I’ve simply doubled up my
exposure to the exact same pool of mortgages.
‘Furthermore, you lose a lot of information in a master trust pool. Because new
loans are added to the existing collateral pool when new bonds are issued, the
performance statistics of the older loans are diluted by the new loans.’
Steve Swallow, head of European asset-backed securities at CQS, the hedge fund,
believes investors are prepared – or should be – to do the extra work required to
analyse stand-alone deals.
‘Providing the investor community with a proposition that requires more diligence
and more consideration of risk can only be a good thing, and in the long term, the
transparency will encourage more investors into the market,’ he said.
Investors are unhappy at the way the structure leaves them at the mercy of the
lender’s treasury team, which can decide, under certain circumstances, not to
repay the bonds until their legal maturity date.
This is further into the future than the set maturity date and reflects the long-term
nature of mortgages.
In effect, this happened with Granite, where Northern Rock decided to no longer
support the trust with new mortgages and where it will instead simply pay out on
the existing bonds when the underlying mortgages are repaid.
‘Before the crisis, people took complexity for granted since what would get them
into trouble was so far-fetched, but now that’s actually happened with Granite,’
said one investor. ‘Everyone is comfortable with credit risk, but it’s really also
extension risk they’ve taken. It’s not always at the issuer’s discretion. They might
have to extend if certain things happen.’
Investor unhappiness does not appear to have yet held back the market.
➨
Last month’s £4bn ($6.5bn) deal from Lloyds was snapped up by investors who
returned this week to take £3.5bn of paper offered by Nationwide, a deal even more
notable because its Silverstone master trust was new to investors.
Bankers expect more deals to follow.
‘We’ve talked to the core investor base and most of them said we want “master
trusts”,’ said one banker on the Nationwide transaction.
David Basra, head of debt financing at Citigroup, argues that the UK structure is
safer for investors. He helped structure the first master trust for Bank of Scotland.
‘I’d argue that stand-alone pass-through transactions may expose investors to
greater credit risk, depending of course on which mortgages back their underlying
bonds,’ he said.
‘I think investors may find that they lose more over the cycle on some stand-alone
deals because there is a greater chance they’ll end up exposed to poorly under-
written risk.’
Source: Hughes, J. (2009) Recent deals signal market’s reopening in the same old style,
Financial Times, 29 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2009. All Rights Reserved.
Article 15.3
the SPEs can survive a bankruptcy of the umbrella group – and partly the fact
that the securities issued are often ‘wrapped’, or guaranteed, by highly-rated bond
insurers such as Ambac, FGIC or MBIA in return for a fee.
This is a complex and costly exercise, but can result in much cheaper debt. Once
established, a securitisation can be tapped again later if a business grows.
Sometimes securitisation is best suited to part of a business rather than the whole.
When applied to an entire business, as with Dunkin’ Brands or Domino’s, the new
financing typically replaces all traditional debt.
Rob Krugel, head of the esoteric asset-backed securities business at Lehman
Brothers, says: ‘Generally, the constituencies – rating agencies and bond insurers
– require that all pre-existing debt is refinanced. There is flexibility on a go-forward
basis to issue debt outside the securitisation as well as additional securitisation
debt. We generally find that securitisation is so efficient there’s no reason to issue
debt outside the structure.’
While a securitisation does involve financial constraints, they can be fewer and less
onerous than with traditional bank and bond debt. Managers would, for example,
have greater flexibility to pay dividends or buy back stock.
This reflects the fact that financiers in a securitisation look only to the specific
assets and cash flows held within the SPEs. But Eric Hedman, analyst at Standard
& Poor’s in New York, notes there can be a trade-off in terms of operational
flexibility. ‘Prior to the securitisation, Dunkin’ was an owner operator. Now, the
company is no longer the franchisor, there’s an SPE. Any new store agreement is
for the benefit of the securitisation.’ The company’s management also does not
have sole discretion over advertising spending, for example.
And the Dunkin’ Donuts brand is no longer owned by the company. ‘The sign on
the wall says “Copyright DD IP Holder LLC”. That’s a bankruptcy-remote SPE set
up for the benefit of noteholders [in the securitisation],’ Mr Hedman says.
This kind of shift might not suit all managers. But for some executives – particularly
those focused on maximising cash returns to shareholders – such considerations
can be outweighed by the financial benefits.
Private equity owners also like the fact that securitisations are ‘portable’ – they can
stay in place through a change of ownership. ‘That’s a big hook from the point of
view of sponsors,’ says John Miller, US head of financial sponsors at Lehman.
But Mr Yarbrough concedes that the structural demands of securitising their
entire business may not suit even the majority of companies. ‘I don’t know how
many businesses are really going to completely fit that model,’ he says. ‘But what
you will see is securitisation increasingly becoming a part of a financing solution.’
With the help of bond insurers, corporate securitisations can achieve triple-A or at
least investment grade ratings, even if the company concerned could not have done so.
This attracts the broadest possible range of investors, including pension funds and
fund managers at the most highly-rated end, and hedge funds lower down the cap-
ital structure.
➨
Mr Krugel says the magic is in the legal separation of the assets and the creation of
a tailored package for securitised investors. ‘You’re not fundamentally changing
the operational risk of the business, but you’re putting in place a lot of protections
in downside cases.’
He says it is also crucial that the SPEs are bankruptcy-remote. He points to the test
case of US car rental group Alamo National.
A securitised financing put in place before the group went bankrupt in 2001 sur-
vived the bankruptcy process, and was used for acquisition finance when the com-
pany was acquired by private equity firm Cerberus in 2003.
Source: Beales, R. (2007) Secularisation: it’s all a question of packaging, Financial Times,
25 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2007. All Rights Reserved.
Fannie and Freddie buy collections of mortgages from mortgage providers and
issue bonds backed by the security of these mortgages (mortgage bonds or
mortgage-backed securities (MBS)), thereby creating a secondary mortgage
market. They guarantee that the interest and principal on the MBS are paid,
thus the ultimate lenders have recourse to the GSE.
Now for some innovation: in the early 1990s new lenders emerged who were
willing to lend to people who did not qualify as prime borrowers. They would
often employ independent firms of mortgage brokers to persuade families to
take out a mortgage. The brokers received a commission for each one sold. The
number of sub-prime lenders grew significantly over the 12 years to 2005 and
the proportion of mortgages that were sub-prime rose to over 20%. The rise of
this market attracted the interest of the big names on Wall Street (e.g. Goldman
Sachs, Merrill Lynch, Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns and Morgan Stanley),
which bought up sub-prime lenders. These borrowers could be charged higher
interest rates than prime borrowers. They could also be charged large fees for
setting up the loan. The sub-prime market boomed. By 2005 the largest US
mortgage provider was the sub-prime lender Countrywide Financial, which
had grown fast from 1980s’ obscurity.
A key characteristic of the new lenders was that they lent at different interest rates
to different groups of mortgagees classified on the basis of statistical models
of likelihood of default. These relied heavily on the borrower’s credit score.
This score was calculated by examining a number of borrower characteristics,
the most important of which became the absence (or low incidence) of missed
or delayed payments on previous debts. The statisticians had discovered a high
correlation between credit scores and defaults on mortgages in the 1990s and
so it made sense to them to carry on with them in the 2000s. The problem
was that the statisticians had not fully taken on board the extent to which
mortgages in the 2000s were different to mortgages in the 1990s, particularly
at the sub-prime end of the market.
Many of the 2000s mortgages required much less documentation than in the
1990s. People were often not even required to prove their level of income; they
could just state their income. Nor was it necessary to pay for an independent
valuation of the house; borrowers could just state the value of the house.
Stated income loans were convenient for those without regular work, but
anyone with common sense can see the potential temptation to overstating
income to speculate on rising prices (they quickly became known as liar loans
on the street – a clue that the mathematicians could have picked up on if they
had taken time to glance up from the algebra).
Another change was the help given with the deposit on the house. Whereas
traditionally households would have to find 10–20% of the house value as
a down payment, in the new era brokers could offer a second mortgage (called
a piggyback) which could be used as the deposit, so 100% of the value of the
house could be borrowed. Taking things a stage further, the UK’s Northern
Rock offered mortgages that were 125% of the value of the house.
A further change was the increasing use of mortgages that had very low
interest rates for the first two years (teaser rates), but after that they carried
rates significantly higher than normal – 600 basis points above Libor was
merely the average, many paid much more, i.e. well into double figures.
The more rational players in this market allowed for the qualitative changes
that had taken place in the housing markets in the noughties, rather than sim-
plistically using a mathematical model developed in the 1990s for estimating
default likelihood. Those wedded to quantified data in the statistical series had
difficulties adjusting to the new reality.
Originate-and-hold to originate-and-distribute
Traditionally, if a bank grants a mortgage it keeps it on its books until it is
repaid. This is called the originate-and-hold model. In this way banks have
every incentive to ensure that the mortgagee can repay and can help those
few who have temporary problems along the way. Fewer and fewer banks
kept mortgages on the books in the 2000s. They preferred the originate-
and-distribute model, selling them to other investors, usually through
securitisations. Alongside this development was the movement of investment
banks to use their own money to invest in securities rather than only provide
(lower-risk) advice and other fee-based activities.
Despite losing their lead the GSEs still participated. Apart from holding
hundreds of billions of dollars worth of MBS they had created, they also
bought more than $1,000 billion of MBS issued by the private firms. They felt
safe because they had put in place ‘safeguards’. First, if the loans were at more
than 80% of LTV they insisted on insurance being purchased from private
insurance firms that paid out in the event of default. Second, the credit rating
agencies had checked out the default likelihood on the private MBS they
bought and had concluded that they should be granted AAA status. What
could go wrong? Well, much of the insurance proved to be worthless as insur-
ance companies went bust, overwhelmed by the sub-prime losses, and credit
rating agencies looked foolish in granting high credit scores. Even they got
caught up in the rose-tinted vision of the time. (Or did they, as some people
suggest, have an incentive to rate excessively high? The debate rumbles on.)
The volume of mortgage payment defaults was too much for Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac and they had to be taken under government supervision in 2008
(they were too big to be allowed to fail) and government guarantees were put
in place to try to restore public confidence. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, along
with Ginnie Mae, still have an enormous slice of the ABS market – see Figure 15.2.
Thus, in the land of the free (markets) most mortgage bonds are guaranteed by
the government, squeezing out the private securitisation market and produc-
ing large profits. The flows of interest and principal payments for commercial
mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) shown in Figure 15.2 come from companies
paying off mortgages on commercial property (offices, factories, etc.).
European securitisation
The European asset-backed securities market is less than a quarter of the size of
the US market. It has always been smaller, but it faltered particularly badly
after the 2008 debacle. Also banks are currently not interested in increasing
volumes of lending and so do not need to securitise, especially when they can
borrow cheap money from the European Central Bank or the Bank of England
– see Article 15.4.
Article 15.4
The primary reason for the fall is simple: banks do not need the funding. After
volumes rose in the wake of the crisis – 2010 saw a nearly tenfold increase in ABS
issuance year-on-year to $30bn – they declined sharply in 2012 after the Bank of
England’s ‘funding for lending’ scheme (FLS), which offered banks cheaper fund-
ing than selling ABS on the open market.
‘Banks’ need for securitisation funding has been diminished,’ says Neal Shah at
Moody’s. ‘Banks have been deleveraging their balance sheets over the past few
years, and at the same time have had access to various forms of relatively cheap
liquidity, including FLS.’
Even as volumes shrank investor demand remained robust. The result is that
spreads – the amount of interest paid over the London Interbank Offered Rate –
have declined markedly.
‘Expectations of new issuance collapsed,’ says Dipesh Mehta, a research analyst at
Barclays. ‘Before FLS a senior tranche of a residential mortgage-backed security
priced at 150 basis points over Libor – now the same senior RMBS tranche is trading
at between 30–50 basis points over Libor.’
As the big high street banks cut back volumes, challenger banks such as Virgin
Money and Aldermore picked up some of the slack, albeit with smaller issues.
In 2010 smaller banks and building societies accounted for 5% of MBS issuance.
This year they account for two-thirds, according to research by RBS.
Source: Thompson, C. (2014) Banks shun packaged UK mortgage deals, Financial Times,
9 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
You can see in Article 15.5 that the US market has remained extremely strong,
with a blip in 2008. Investor confidence grew as it became clear in 2009–2010
that most pre-crisis securitised bonds, e.g. prime mortgage, car loan, credit card
securitisations and student loans, were performing as they were supposed to
through a recession. This led to high demand from insurance companies,
banks, hedge funds and pension funds.
Article 15.5
Nevertheless, there are critics who warn that the industry has yet to learn the
lessons of the crisis. Adam Ashcraft, head of credit risk management at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, warned at a conference last year: ‘We haven’t done
anything meaningful to prevent the securitisation market from doing what it
just did.’
Bankers are conscious the industry still needs to rebuild its reputation following
the excesses of the past.
Source: Alloway, T. (2014) Sliced and diced debt deals make roaring comeback, Financial
Times, 4 June.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
It is hoped that the European securitisation market can grow strongly, not least
because the European Central Bank and the Bank of England are helping to
promote a ‘high-quality’ packaged debt market – see Article 15.6.
Article 15.6
‘The ECB is taking a bet on the credit market, and by opening to mortgage-backed
purchases, especially the housing market, which has potentially powerful fiscal
implications for the eurozone area,’ says Carlo Altomonte, a professor at Bocconi
University.
The plan has powerful critics. Last week, Wolfgang Schäuble, Germany’s finance
minister, voiced his unease. ‘I am not particularly happy about the debate started
by the ECB about the purchase of securitisation products.’
The ECB and Bank of England consider a revival of the market as a way of trans-
forming European finance from a system based on bank loans to a US-style system
weighted more in favour of capital markets.
Europe’s bank dependence is stark: banks account for nearly 80% of corporate
loans compared with about 50% in the US. With a greater variety of non-bank
sources of finance, businesses’ access to credit is not solely tied to the fortunes of
their high street bank. Proponents of the plan point to the US programme of asset
purchases as evidence that it can work in Europe.
The US Federal Reserve has $1.7tn in mortgage-backed securities on its balance
sheet as a result of its buying programme since 2009, leading to a sharp rebound in
US ABS volumes. The ability to sell historic debts has given banks more lending
capacity. Commercial and industrial loans, for example, have risen by 45% to
$1.74tn since late 2010.
‘The key takeaway [from the US] is “build it and they will come”,’ says Jim Caron
at Morgan Stanley. ‘There were many questions about who would invest and would
it work. But once the government started to buy [MBS] it kick-started other forms
of lending and moved collateral away from banks to non-banks.’
There is also evidence that Europe’s inventory of ABS is in better condition than
that of the US, where default rates were much worse. Of more than 9,000 European
ABS notes issued during the past decade, only 2% have defaulted or are likely to
realise future losses, according to Moody’s Investors Service, compared with about
a fifth of US ABS.
Mr Draghi said the ECB would only buy products that were ‘simple, transparent
and real’.
The ECB could start with ABS backed by SME, consumer and car loans, of which
there is €300bn outstanding. Most existing ABS are held by banks as collateral
in exchange for ECB loans. If the ECB included all banks’ outstanding loans and
mortgages that could be feasibly packaged, the potential ABS could be €3tn.
Source: Thompson, C. and Jones, C. (2014) Asset-backed securities: back from disgrace,
Financial Times, 30 September.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Article 15.7
The subprime auto loan market is a case in point. Lured by the higher returns on
offer from investing in subprime auto ABS, investors have flocked to buy the securities.
Like other subprime auto lenders, Flagship has been able to grow its business by
tapping strong investor demand for subprime auto ABS. So strong is that demand
that Flagship has been marketing ABS with a ‘prefunding’ feature – in effect selling
securitised bundles of auto loans before the loans have even been made.
Such prefunding features were a hallmark of securitisation markets before the
crisis, when demand for residential mortgage-backed securities was so high that it
outstripped supply of new loans. Now a similar dynamic appears in play, prompting
concerns that investors’ relentless search for yield will once again end poorly.
There remains a lingering unease that investors are being herded into asset classes
that may not be adequately compensating them for the risks involved. Some are
already leveraging their portfolio and using derivatives to help amplify their
returns during a period of unprecedented low interest rates.
Source: Alloway, T. (2014) Rebound in sales of risky assets raises fears over quantitative
easing’s legacy, Financial Times, 27 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Covered bonds
Covered bonds are similar to the securitised asset-based bonds described
above, in that a specific group of assets, e.g. mortgage receivables, is used to
back up the claims of the bond holders. But covered bonds give investors
extra layers of protection compared with other types of ABS. First, only banks
are permitted to issue them and investors have full recourse to the bank’s
resources. This applies even for those issued through a special purpose vehicle
which on-lends the proceeds to the originating bank (either through a loan or
by buying its bonds). Thus if the covered bonds do not pay on time investors
can obtain payment from the bank that issued them, albeit indirectly, through
the SPV.
Furthermore, if the issuer goes bust, covered bond holders have priority claims
on the assets (mortgages, etc.) held in the cover asset pool. This is always a
segregated collection of financial assets, separate from the assets of the bank.
Covered bond holders rank above unsecured creditors of the bank in being
able to claim the assets in the pool. Thus covered bond holders are protected
from the failure of the bank because they have a group of ring-fenced assets
they can turn to, while, at the same time, if the bank is fine but the pool of
assets turns out to be a dud, investors can turn to the assets of the bank held
outside of the cover asset pool. In most jurisdictions the value of the assets in
the cover pool is required at all times to exceed the value of the covered bonds
by a prescribed amount: over-collateralisation – see Figure 15.3.
Figure 15.3 Legal minimum over-collateralisation levels for covered bonds in Europe
Source: European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org European Covered Bond Fact Book 2014,
European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org/Content/default.asp?PageID=501
covered bond holders at all times. Under this the bank is required to add
further assets to the cover pool to compensate for matured or defaulted assets
(e.g. house owner not paying his mortgage). This contrasts with most securitisa-
tions, where the sponsoring institution is not obliged to replace defaulted
assets, so the losses are borne by the bond investors.
On top of that protection, covered bonds can be issued only in strict legal and
supervisory settings. Supervision typically includes:
In most of the 29 countries with covered bond markets the monitor is a public
authority, e.g. the banking supervisory authority. In other countries the
issuing organisation (e.g. bank, SPV) appoints an external auditor (outside
its control) to regularly audit the cover pool, as well as an external trustee to
safeguard bond holders’ interests.
The financial assets held within the cover pool include loans and bonds. There
might also be derivatives designed to hedge interest rate and currency risk, but
equities, property and commodities cannot be included. The most common
pool asset is mortgage loans secured on residential or commercial property, but
in many countries there is a large market in covered bonds where the under-
lying assets are loans to public entities such as regional or local authorities.
Ship loans comes in a distant third.
Figure 15.4 shows the growth of this market, which in 2013 had more than
€2.5 trillion outstanding, with an increasing shift towards mortgage-backed
covered bonds and a decrease in the importance of public sector CBs.
We can see clearly from Figure 15.5 that the covered bond market is more
significant in some European countries than others. Germany takes nearly
20% of the outstanding covered bond market (its covered bonds are called
Pfandbriefe). Spain, Denmark and France all have around €350 billion out-
standing. The UK accounts for 5% (nearly €137 billion), while the US, with less
than 0.3% of the market, is only just getting going.
Figure 15.5 Outstanding covered bonds by country as well as change versus 2012 in
billions of euros
Source: European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org European Covered Bond Fact Book 2014,
European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org/Content/default.asp?PageID501
Figure 15.6 Covered bond and senior unsecured euro new issues by maturity, billions
of euros
Source: European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org European Covered Bond Fact Book 2014,
European Covered Bond Council http://ecbc.hypo.org/Content/default.asp?PageID=501
Some are short bonds, but most are medium-term bonds – see Figure 15.6.
Because of their high level of backing, covered bonds are usually given high
credit ratings (AAA) and are therefore a relatively low-cost way for financial
institutions to raise money. Having said that, the AAA rating is far from
automatic – see Article 15.8.
Article 15.8
‘Denmark is one of the biggest, most liquid, most transparent bond markets around
and Moody’s are picking on them,’ says Alan Boyce, chief executive of the Absalon
Project.
At the heart of the rating agency’s stance is its assertion that Danish covered bonds
– which pool together mortgages – are changing.
Where once the bonds were almost entirely composed of fixed-rate loans, now more
than half of outstanding Danish covered bonds – some DKr1,217bn ($231bn) worth
– are for financing adjustable-rate mortgage (Arm) loans, says Denmark’s central
bank.
But Danish banks have to reissue the bonds before the underlying loans expire,
creating a refinancing risk, according to Moody’s.
The interest rate that borrowers pay on their loan also changes every time the bond
is refinanced, meaning they may have to pay a higher rate if the rollover comes at
a time of financial stress for the issuing bank.
‘Typically, Arm loans mature after 20 to 30 years while the covered bonds mature
every one to three years,’ Moody’s says. ‘Hence there is refinancing risk and the
issuers’ dependence on regular market access to issue covered bonds has increased
with the growing volume of Arm loans.’
Covered bond issuers counter by arguing that unique features of the Danish
mortgage market mitigate risk. Mortgages are capped at 80% loan-to-value and
the bonds stay on bank balance sheets, aligning the interests of borrowers and the
issuing banks, says renowned financier Mr Soros.
Issuers say the debt has never defaulted – not even during Denmark’s early 19th
century bankruptcy – and also survived the 2008 financial crisis relatively well.
Denmark now has over DKr2,300bn in outstanding mortgage bonds, more than four
times the country’s government bond market.
But Moody’s says the refinancing risk for Danish covered bonds may still be up due
to the so-called ‘bail-in’ rules introduced for failed banks last year by Denmark’s
government.
The new rules allow banks to fail and impose losses on creditors and have raised
Danish banks’ funding costs in recent months.
Danske Bank, which issues covered bonds through its Realkredit Danmark business,
says it dropped Moody’s after the agency estimated it would have to surrender an
additional DKr32.5bn of collateral to maintain the triple A rating on its debt.
Smaller issuers say they will turn to other rating agencies such as Standard &
Poor’s or Fitch, according to Jan Knøsgaard, deputy director-general of the
Association of Danish Mortgage Banks. ‘The issuers can’t understand Moody’s
decision; they find it very mechanical and very different to the position of other
rating agencies,’ he adds.
Danish banks have started spreading their refinancing dates throughout the year
to limit the risk of big pressure points.
➨
Nykredit Realkredit, Denmark’s largest mortgage lender, says it will hive off its
funding for adjustable rate mortgages into a separate unit to protect the ratings on
its fixed-rate covered bonds. ‘The mortgage bonds have already traded back up
since the Moody’s announcement, and this is in an environment where everything
else in Europe has widened out,’ says Mr Boyce.
‘If Moody’s want to play hardball, they should look at some other European covered
bonds, things like German Public Pfandbriefe, which are stuffed with exposure to
eurozone peripherals but still retain their triple A ratings.’
Source: Alloway, T. (2011) Moody’s risk alert sparks covered bond dispute, Financial Times,
20 July.
© The Financial Times Limited 2011. All Rights Reserved.
The main investors in covered bonds are banks and investment funds, but
there are many others – see Figure 15.7.
Article 15.9
Source: Thompson, C., Sanderson, R. and Johnson, M. (2013) ‘Periphery’ bank bonds are
the comeback assets, Financial Times, 17 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
In the US, covered bonds make up a very small part of the bond universe
because the market has been hampered by a lack of legal framework for them
– see Article 15.10.
Article 15.10
But sales in the US of such bonds have slumped to $17bn so far this year. That is
down from $45bn in 2012 and $40bn in 2011, according to data from Dealogic.
The slower-than-expected march of covered bonds into the US is a disappointment
for the debt’s proponents, who still view the bonds as an elegant solution to the
problem of encouraging private investors into a mortgage market which is still
largely propped up by government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs).
Some in the market are now looking at alternative ways to make covered bonds
work in the US and give banks an opportunity to tap an alternative source of
financing, even without new legislation.
Source: Alloway, T. and Rodrigues, V. (2013) Sales of ultra-safe US covered bonds stall,
Financial Times, 14 October.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
We then need to tackle the constraints on that money creation, which come
largely from prudential self-restraint, with a helping hand from the central
banking authorities. Because a commercial bank knows it is sensible to keep a
proportion of the assets it owns in a highly liquid form, but at the same time
knows that it is tempting to lend long term to gain higher interest, there is
a tension within a bank on the quantity of money to hold in reserve. The
central bank can influence interest rates through its supply of cash reserves,
its interest rate on money borrowed from it, the level of interest it pays on
money deposited with it, and its purchases and sales of money market and
bond securities.
Following the 2008 financial crisis central banks significantly changed the way
in which they influence interest rates in the wider economy, not least through
quantitative easing. Thus we need to discuss both the ‘normal’ monetary
policy approaches and the more recent interventions.
to keep valuables safe. They’ve been dealing in gold for decades. You could
strike up a deal with them whereby they looked after your gold and silver for a
small fee.
The goldsmith gives you a written receipt. This piece of paper states the value
of the coins deposited. If you wanted to buy something in a shop you could
take your piece of paper to your goldsmith to receive coins to spend. But what
happened next led to the development of goldsmiths as banks. The shop keeper,
as likely as not, would deposit your coins with a goldsmith for safekeeping,
receiving a receipt in return. It did not take long for shopkeepers to realise that
a receipt from a reputable goldsmith was worth taking from a customer rather
than insisting on the usual merry-go-round of collecting coin and depositing
it again. The shopkeeper could simply accept the receipt and collect the coins
at a later date (or get them transferred to their account at the goldsmith). The
paper receipts increasingly became accepted as a form of money.
These private depositories of coin got a real boost when the rival depository,
the Royal Mint, on Tower Hill, was raided by Charles I at the start of the civil
war. He decided to ‘borrow’ the huge sum of £200,000. He later repaid, but the
damage was done, trust was gone. The goldsmiths not only had higher reputa-
tions but paid interest.
Fractional-reserve banking
Goldsmiths noticed that most of the deposited coins were never taken out. On
a typical day, or even a typical month, only a very small proportion of deposi-
tors turned up to demand their coins. So, reasoned the bankers, if for every
£100 deposited only around £20 would need to be kept in the vault to satisfy
those who turned up at the bank, why not lend out the other £80 and gain
some interest? Hence only a fraction of the money deposited is held in reserve:
fractional-reserve banking.
Money creation
Now we can move to another stage, we can actually create money. The borrowers
of the money from goldsmiths were usually content to take a piece of paper –
call it a bank note – instead of taking coins out of the bank. They could then
use that as currency to buy things. The goldsmith could just create these pieces
of paper off their own bat. Thus, a goldsmith-bank might have a total of, say,
£1,000 deposited, but hand out £500 of the coin as loans and issue another
£5,000 or £6,000 of new paper money to borrowers.
You can see the obvious danger here: depositors might all come at the same
time to demand their money – they want £1,000 back when there is only
£500 in the vault. Illiquidity! But what are the chances of a high proportion
of depositors wanting cash back at the same time? Minuscule, thought the
bankers, and so they carried on lending beyond their deposit base – and this
is what bankers do today. They create money out of thin air (just so long as
there is a deposit base on which to build) – see Figure 16.1. Initially there is
only £100, after seven actions there is £100 + £80 + £64 + £51.20 = £295.20 in
the economy.
This new money is actually debt. And it works only if people are willing to accept
bankers’ promissory notes. They do this because these notes are perceived as
being ‘payable on demand’. If you turned up at a bank you would have been
able to swap your notes for coins. Today UK notes still state ‘I promise to pay
the bearer on demand the sum of twenty pounds’. However, unlike in the 17th
century, if you went to collect from the Bank of England today you would only
get another note in exchange – we have moved right over to pure fiat money.
Paper money is called fiat money – it is money simply because it is declared
as such by a government to be legal tender. It is money without intrinsic
value other than the potential for others to trust it and accept it as money. To
be useful the notes issued then and now have to carry a legally enforceable
unconditional right to payment. Also, they should be negotiable – that is,
transferable – between people.
Of course, there is another danger: if you are working off a deposit base of
£1,000 and you lend £4,000, and then 30% of your borrowers are unable
to pay, you are bankrupt. This thought should limit the amount you lend
given your deposit base (a capital reserve is kept), but bankers occasionally
misjudge this.
A clearing house
But what if the payee banks with another goldsmith-bank? Then there had to
be a way of communicating between the two. At first this process would have
been laborious, as clerks from each bank would visit all the other banks to
exchange cheques and then settle between them, but in 1770 the London
bankers got together in one place (a tavern) to handle the cheques from many
banks. This eventually became the Bankers’ Clearing House in the early 19th
century. When the railways linked up the rest of the country in the 1840s the
cheque system really took off, linking up more than 150 banks.
During the Napoleonic wars the government was borrowing so much paper
money from the BoE that it ran out of gold to back the notes. The government
thus declared that the notes need no longer be convertible to gold. The result
of all this spending and the creation of so much fiat money was high inflation.
The lesson was learned: you need to limit the quantity of paper money.
There continued to be many small banks issuing bank notes. Many were
unsound, irresponsibly creating notes. In 1844 the BoE was emphasised as the
main issuer of notes. From then on, there were to be no new issuers of notes
and those whose issues lapsed, or that were taken over, forfeited their right
to issue. Other issuers gradually died out. The notes issued by the BoE were
mostly backed by its holdings of gold or silver bullion, but another £14 million
was permitted (equal to the BoE capital raised from shareholders). The backing
of gold (the gold standard) created a long period of price stability. However,
today in most countries currency notes are not backed by anything other than
a promise to pay – pure fiat systems.
In addition to the issue of notes and being banker to the government the BoE
took on roles such as being lender of last resort to the banking system and was
called on to stabilise the banking system in crises, which happened pretty
often.
Second, banks must protect themselves against the possibility of their assets
falling below liabilities (what the bank owes depositors and other creditors of
the bank). Such an eventuality would make a bank insolvent and unable to
carry on. This might happen, for instance, if, say, 10% of the loans it has made
to businesses go sour and are never repaid (as happened with HBOS following
the financial crisis). If a bank was to play it ultra-safe it would always hold
assets worth at least 20% more than its liabilities. This level of safety is being
called for by some experts in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis, but very few
banks come anywhere near that level; more typical levels are 3–5%.
This capital management is a much debated topic. The fundamentals are that
a bank starts out with some money put in by its owners to pay for buildings,
equipment, etc. Shareholders’ funds, obtained by the selling of shares in the
bank, have the advantage that the shareholders do not have the right to with-
draw their money from the company – it is permanent capital (although they
might sell their shares to other investors). As well as paying for the initial
set-up, shareholders’ capital provides a buffer acting as a safety margin against
the event of a significant number of the loans granted to borrowers going
wrong. The buffer is referred to as capital and loans made are assets of the
bank. Deposits (and other loans to the bank) are liabilities:
Total assets = Total liabilities + Capital
Cash reserves of 12% are unusually high, but useful for illustration. A more
normal figure is 1–3% of overall liabilities (not just deposit liabilities) held
in cash, but another 10% or so might be held in assets that can quickly be
converted to cash, such as very short-term loans to other banks, certificates of
deposit for money placed with other banks in tradable form and government
Treasury bills – these are termed near cash. The term for reserves that includes
near cash is liquid reserves.
To understand the working of a bank we will start with a very simple example
of a change in the cash held by a bank. Imagine that Mrs Rich deposits £1,000
of cash into her current account at the BarcSan Bank. This has affected the
bank’s balance sheet. It has an increase of cash, and therefore reserves, of
£1,000. This is an asset of the bank. At the same time it has increased its liabil-
ities because the bank owes Mrs Rich £1,000, which she can withdraw any
time. We can illustrate the changes by looking at that part of the balance sheet
that deals with this transaction. In the T-account below, the asset (cash) is
shown on the left and the increased liability is shown on the right.
Assets Liabilities
This increase in reserves could also have come about through Mrs Rich
paying in a £1,000 cheque drawn on an account at, say, HSBC. When BarcSan
receives the cheque it deposits it at the central bank, which then collects
£1,000 from HSBC’s account with the central bank and transfers it to BarcSan’s
account at the central bank, increasing its reserves. Remember: cash reserves
include both those held at the central bank and those in the bank vault, tills,
ATMs, etc.
Assets Liabilities
These reserves are not paying a high interest to BarcSan.1 What is even more
troubling is that the bank is providing an expensive service to Mrs Rich with
bank branch convenience, cheque books, statements, etc. This money has to
be put to use – at least as much of it as is prudent. One way of making a profit
1
Many central banks now do pay interest on those reserves deposited with them, but it can
be quite low. In May 2014 the US Federal Reserve paid 0.25% (annual rate), for example.
The BoE paid 0.5%.
is to lend most of the money. It does this by lending to a business for five years.
Thus the bank borrows on a short-term basis (instant access for Mrs Rich) and
lends long (five-year term loan). The bank decides to lend £880 because this
would allow it to maintain its required reserve ratio of 8% and its target excess
reserve of 4%.
Assets Liabilities
Assets Liabilities
To satisfy its own rule of 12% of current account deposits held as reserves it
needs only £1.2 billion but it currently has £2.1 billion (£800m + £1,300m). It
has a ‘spare’ £900 million. If there is a sudden rise in withdrawals from bank
accounts as people worry about the bank system collapsing and not being
able to repay its deposit liabilities (as with Northern Rock in 2007, or Cypriot
banks in 2013), this will have an impact on BarcSan. If £900 million of cash is
withdrawn from BarcSan, its balance changes to:
Assets Liabilities
The bank still has cash reserves above its target because 12% of £9,100 million
is £1,092 million (this apportioned as required reserves, 8% of £9,100m =
£728m, and excess reserves, 4% of £9,100m = £364m), but the bank has £1,200
million (required reserves of £728 million plus excess reserves of £472 million).
Because it started with plentiful reserves the public panic to withdraw funds
has not affected the other elements in BarcSan’s balance sheet.
Now take a different case, where BarcSan has already lent out any reserves
above its prudential level of 12% of deposits.
Assets Liabilities
Now imagine a financial panic: many depositors rush to the bank’s branches to
take out their money. In one day £900 million is withdrawn. At the end of the
day the balance sheet is looking far from healthy.
BarcSan’s balance sheet after £900 million is withdrawn (after the bank just met its
reserve target)
Assets Liabilities
Another day like that and it might be wiped out. It is required to hold 8% of
£9,100 million as reserves, £728 million, but now has only £300 million.
Where is it going to get the shortfall from? There are four possibilities.
1 Borrow from other banks and other organisations. The active markets in inter-
bank loans, repos, commercial paper or certificates of deposit could be use-
ful to raise the £428 million.
Assets Liabilities
However, given the cause of the crisis was a system-wide loss of confidence,
BarcSan may have difficulty raising money in these markets at this time.
This was a problem that beset many banks around the world in 2008, and
then many eurozone banks in Greece, Cyprus, Portugal and Spain in 2011–
2013. They had grown used to quickly obtaining cash to cover shortfalls
from other banks. But in the calamitous loss of confidence following the
sub-prime debacle and the eurozone crisis, banks simply stopped lending –
those that were caught with insufficient reserves failed or were bailed out by
governments.
2 Securities could be sold. Of the securities bought by a bank, most are traded in
very active markets where it is possible to sell a large quantity without mov-
ing the price. Let us assume that the bank sells £428 million of government
Treasury bills and bonds to move its reserves back to 8% of deposits.
Assets Liabilities
3 Borrowing from the central bank. One of the major duties of a central bank is
to act as lender of last resort. It stands ready to lend to banks that lack cash
reserves. However, it will do this at a high price only (high interest rate) to
deter banks from calling on it in trivial circumstances.2 If BarcSan borrows
the £428 million shortfall from the central bank to take it back to the regu-
lator’s minimum of 8%, its balance sheet now looks like this:
BarcSan’s balance sheet if it borrows £428 million from the central bank
Assets Liabilities
2
Interest charged by central banks is normally at penalty rates, but in 2014 many central
banks were charging very low rates to assist banks and encourage lending.
Assets Liabilities
Of course, there are a few more moves that need to be made if the bank wants
to reach its target of 12% reserves, rather than simply get to 8%, but after such
a crisis in the financial markets this may take a few years to achieve.
A difficult balance
A bank has a trade-off to manage. If it ties up a very high proportion of its
money in reserves it loses the opportunity to lend that money to gain a decent
return, but the managers can feel very safe, as they are unlikely to run out of
cash. Yet if it goes for maximum interest by lending the vast majority of the
money deposited long term, it could run out of cash. Thus it has to have
enough reserves to avoid one or more of the following costly actions to quickly
raise money: (a) borrowing from other banks; (b) selling securities; (c) borrow-
ing from the central bank; or (d) reducing its loans. Required and excess
reserves provide insurance against incurring liquidity problems due to deposit
outflows, but like all insurance it comes at a high price.
Assets Liabilities
Assets Liabilities
Assets Liabilities
3
This case illustrates a domino effect. The Cypriot banks ended up in trouble and unable to
pay their debts because a few years earlier they had bought a lot of bonds issued by Greek
banks. Then the eurozone ‘bailout’ of Greece was agreed, which resulted in default on the
Greek bank bonds – they lost 70% of their value. This wiped out a tremendous proportion
of assets from the Cypriot banks’ balance sheets.
Its capital to assets ratio has fallen to a less conservative 3.8% (£400m/
£10,400m), but this is a level that still affords some sense of safety for its pro-
viders of funds. (Some writers refer to the capital to assets ratio as the leverage
ratio, others take its inverse as the leverage ratio.)
Mercurial is insolvent. Its assets of £10,400 are less than the amount owed to
depositors.
Assets Liabilities
A course of action is to write to depositors to tell them that it cannot repay the
full amount that was deposited with the bank. They might panic, rush to the
branch to obtain what they are owed in full. More likely is for the regulator to
step in to close or rescue the bank. Occasionally the central bank organises a
rescue by a group of other banks – they, too, have an interest in maintaining
confidence in the banking system. In 2009 Royal Bank of Scotland and Lloyds
Banking Group, following the sudden destruction of balance sheet reserves
when the value of their loans and many securities turned out to be much less
than what was shown on the balance sheet, were rescued by the UK govern-
ment, which injected money into them by buying billions of new shares. This
was enough new capital to save them from destruction, but the banks are still
clawing their way back to health and still trying to rebuild capital reserves.
Given that both firms (in normal conditions) have the same profits and the
same assets, we have a ROA of £150m/£10,900m = 1.376%.4 This is a useful
measure of bank efficiency in terms of how much profit is generated per pound
of assets.
However, what shareholders are really interested in is the return for each
pound that they place in the business. Assuming that the capital figures in the
balance sheet are all provided by ordinary shareholders then the return on
equity (ROE) is:
£150m
For BarcSan: ROE = = 16.7%
£900m
£150m
For Mercurial: ROE = = 37.5%
£400m
Monetary policy
If the interest rates in an economy are held at a level that is too low then
inflation will start to take off. This can be disruptive to businesses in addition
to destroying people’s savings. It is especially problematic if inflation is high
and fluctuating. The resulting uncertainty about future price levels is likely
to inhibit economic growth, or, at the very least, penalise those who are not
protected against inflation. Unpredictability makes planning very difficult.
Yet if interest rates are set at an excessively high level this will inhibit business
activity, cause people to put off buying houses and reduce spending in the
4
This is at the top end of the usual range of ROAs for commercial banks.
shops, leading to a recession with massive job losses. Clearly a society needs
an organisation whose task it is to select the appropriate short-term interest
rate for the economic conditions it faces: neither too high nor too low. That
organisation is the central bank.5
Thus, one way to control money supply and interest rates is to use its special
powers to insist that each bank leaves a certain proportion of the amount it has
received as deposits from its customers (households, small businesses, etc.) at
the central bank. If a bank’s reserves at the central bank fall below the minimum
required then it has to top this up.
Many central banks, e.g. the Bank of England, some time ago moved from a
fixed daily level of reserves to target balances of reserves held at the central
bank on average over ‘maintenance periods’. In the case of the BoE the main-
tenance period ran from one meeting of the committee that sets interest rates
(the Monetary Policy Committee) to the next, usually one month. Smaller
banks may be exempt from the system.
A couple of years before the financial crisis the BoE removed its formal insist-
ence for banks to achieve targeted levels of reserves to be held with it. It had
a ‘voluntary’ system. However, when motivated by self-imposed prudential
liquidity levels and the need to settle payments with other commercial banks,
bankers want to hold reserves at the BoE.
5
Occasionally called a reserve bank or national bank or monetary authority.
6
Also called the cash reserve ratio.
Monetary base
The central bank has a liability – it accepted deposits from banks. Another liab-
ility of a central bank is what you see written on notes (or coins) that you have
in your wallet or purse; the central bank ‘promises to pay the bearer on demand
the sum of . . .’. As well as reserves at the central bank a typical commercial
bank will hold some of its assets in the form of vault cash in hand. Finally, the
economy has currency in circulation, that is, outside of banks. The combina-
tion of reserves and currency in circulation is the monetary base:
It is important to note that the sole supplier of reserves – notes and coins, and
balances at the central bank as liabilities of the central bank – is the central
bank.
Central banks can conduct monetary policy by changing the country’s mone-
tary base.
Example 16.1
Money creation – the deposit multiplier
Assume that all banks in a monetary system are required to keep 20% of deposits
as reserves. Bank A has $100 million of deposits from customers. Because it is
sticking to the reserve requirement, both required by the central bank and its own
prudential reserves policy, it lends out only $80 million and keeps $20 million as
cash or in its account with the central bank (assume no vault cash for simplicity).
Assets Liabilities
Now, if deposits in Bank A are increased by $5 million, the position changes (we’ll
look at where it got $5 million from in a minute – this is crucial). Deposits rise to
$105 million and reserves rise to $25 million as the additional $5 million is initially
held as reserves at the central bank.
Assets Liabilities
This means that the reserve ratio has risen to $25m ÷ $105m = 23.8%. The bank
earns no or little interest from reserves, so it will wish to reduce it back to 20% by
lending out the extra. The next balance sheet shows the amount of lending that
leaves a 20% reserve ratio, $84 million.
Assets Liabilities
Now let us bring in more banks. In lending an additional $4 million Bank A will have
an impact on the rest of the banking system. If the $4 million is lent to a company
and, initially at least, that company deposits the money in Bank B, then at the
central bank, Bank A’s account will be debited (reserves go down) and Bank B’s
account will be credited (reserves increase). Bank B will lend out 80% of the
amount, or $3.2 million, keeping $800,000 in reserves to maintain its 20% ratio of
reserves to deposits. The $3.2 million lent finds its way to Bank C, which, again,
holds 20% as reserves and lends the rest . . . and so on. At each stage 80% of the
deposit is lent out, increasing the deposits of other banks, encouraging them to lend.
The deposit multiplier is a reciprocal of the reserve ratio, which in this case =
1 ÷ 0.20 = 5. Following an injection of $5 million into the financial system,
the whole process ends when an additional $25 million of deposits have
been created; equilibrium has been reached again. Broad money grows by
$25 million.
Reality check: please note that the model is a simplification for illustrative
purposes. In reality, there might be leakages from the system due to money
flowing abroad, or people increasing currency holdings,7 or buying govern-
ment bonds rather than placing it in bank deposits. People and companies
might be so shocked by an economic downturn that instead of borrowing
more they repay old debt, thus working against the multiplier. Banks might
also be in such turmoil that they would rather reduce their loan book than
expand lending despite huge injections of deposits (they increase excess
reserves). But for now we’ll go along with the logic of the deposit or money
multiplier in ‘normal’ times, with an assumed mathematically pure relation-
ship between narrow and broad money.
The key point to remember is: the creator of the monetary base is the central
bank because it has a monopoly on the issuance of currency. If it has control
over this then it can influence the broader money supply (including deposits
at banks) through the reserves requirements. So, once the system has settled
down from the injection of a new deposit, it will be fairly stable – little money
creation or removal.
Here is the crucial bit about the source of the additional deposits of $5 million:
if it came from a customer who withdrew it from another bank then the
example is null and void because while Bank A benefits from the $5 million
deposit, the other bank, Bank X, sees a reduction in its reserves at the central
bank by an equal amount. It can now lend less than it could before because it
has to rebuild its reserves. Thus the stimulus effect of Bank A’s deposit is exactly
offset by the removal of money from the system by Bank X. If, however, the
7
If none of the extra reserves finds its way into currency then the example, assuming all else
equal, would be describing the money multiplier. However, the money multiplier is usu-
ally a much smaller number than the deposit multiplier because a significant proportion of
the new reserves finds its way into currency and this does not lead to multiple deposit
expansion.
$5 million came from the central bank purchasing Treasury bills from an
investor who then put the newly created cash received into his account with
Bank A, then we have new money coming into the system and we can expect
something like the multiplier effect shown above. The central bank is the only
player here that can create money out of thin air and pump it into the system
if the system is at equilibrium.
Thus, despite commercial banks’ ability to create money on the way to equilib-
rium, there is a limit to the amount that the system as a whole can go up to
because for every dollar, pound, euro, etc. created there has to be a fraction
held as a cash reserve. It is the central bank that controls the total volume of
monetary base (reserves at the central bank plus cash in circulation and at
deposit-taking institutions) and so the broader aggregates of money have an
upper limit. Small changes in the monetary base can have a large impact on the
amount of broad money in the system and so we often refer to the monetary
base as high-powered money.
Central banks have three major tools they use to increase or decrease the
money supply and interest rates:
To illustrate the creation of money by a central bank we can take Bank A’s bal-
ance sheet from the example above. The starting position is:
Assets Liabilities
The central bank wants to inject money into the financial system and lower
interest rates. It offers to buy billions of dollars of government securities. One
of the customers of Bank A sells $6 million of securities to the central bank. The
central bank sends money to the customer of Bank A who deposits the newly
created money (an electronic record rather than cash) in Bank A.8 Bank A adds
this $6 million to its reserve account at the central bank. Now Bank A’s balance
sheet looks like this:
Assets Liabilities
Bank A has a very high reserve level relative to its deposits, $27m ÷ $111m =
24.3%. The managers will want to employ the surplus money above that
needed to maintain the target reserve ratio (20%) to earn higher interest by
lending it. If banks are more willing to lend to businesses and individuals
because of the central bank intervention then interest rates are likely to fall,
along with new money flows into the financial system. If the central bank
wanted to raise interest rates by draining money from the system through
open market operations it would sell government securities to investors, which
reduces the amount held by banks in their reserve accounts at the central bank
or reduces vault cash. This would curb lending and raise interest rates.
Central banks tend to use Treasury securities to conduct open market opera-
tions because the secondary market in these securities is very liquid, there is a
8
In many financial systems there is a select group of security dealers (often a wing of the
major commercial and investment banks) with which the central bank buys and sells
government securities. It is these security dealers’ deposit accounts that are credited and
debited.
large volume of these securities held by dealers and investors, meaning that
the market can absorb a large number of buy and sell transactions. The main
method used is a repurchase agreement. The BoE generally uses repos with
an average maturity of one or two weeks, but will also target long-term
repos (3–12 months). The assets eligible for repo are gilts and sterling Treasury
bills, UK-government foreign currency debt, eligible bank and local authority
bills, and certain sterling bonds issued by supranational organisations and by
governments in the European Economic Area. Turkey uses the repo market –
see Article 16.1.
Article 16.1
Source: Dombey, D. (2014) Turkey’s central bank cuts rates despite mounting inflation,
Financial Times, 22 May.
© The Financial Times Limited 2014. All Rights Reserved.
Repos and reverse repos are, by their nature, temporary interventions because
the opposite transaction takes place on maturity, a few days after the first buy
or sell. There are times when the central bank wants to effect a more perman-
ent change in the money supply. Then it can go for an outright transaction, a
purchase or a sale (of government bills and bonds), that is not destined to be
reversed in a few days.
(An alternative way to increase the monetary base is for the central bank to
lend money to a commercial bank. The central bank simply credits the
commercial bank’s account with electronically created reserves. The amount
of monetary base is less controllable through this method than through
open market operations because the banks may or may not borrow, even if the
central bank offers enticing interest rates.)
Banks trade surplus reserves with each other. They always have an incentive
to lend – even if only for 24 hours – if they find themselves with too many
reserves. Each day there will be dozens of other banks that find themselves
temporarily below the reserve level they need and so they willingly borrow
in the market. The main target for central banks is usually the overnight
interest rate on loans of reserves from one bank to another. In the US this is
the Federal funds rate, in the eurozone it is the overnight repo rate in euros,
and in the UK it is the overnight sterling repo rate. Switzerland opts for the
Swiss franc Libor target rate. Soon after the official rate changes (typically the
same day) banks adjust their standard lending rates (‘base rate’ in the UK),
usually by the exact amount of the policy changes. This is transmitted through
money market rate changes, repos, interbank lending, etc. The impact on
longer-term interest rates can go either way when the short-term rates are
changed, depending on what the market perceives the future will bring in
terms of inflation and additional rises or falls in the overnight interest rate.
(A rise in the official rate could, for example, generate expectations of lower
future interest rates, in which case long rates might fall in response to a rise in
short-term rates.)
If we take the banking system as a whole, the demand for reserves falls as interest
rates rise. That is, the quantity of reserves demanded by banks (holding all else
constant) reduces if banks have a higher opportunity cost of keeping money in
the form of reserves; they would rather lend it out to clients to achieve higher
interest rates. This becomes more and more of a lost opportunity as rates in the
short-term interest rate markets rise. Bankers increasingly start to think that
they can economise on the excess reserves buffer if interest rates are high.
Thus, the demand curve for reserves, D, slopes downwards in Figure 16.2.
The central bank usually has a continuous programme of lending into the
general repo market and so there is a large quantity of money borrowed by
banks from the central bank at any one time. It is through the adjustment to
the amount of reserves outstanding that the central bank controls interest
rates. The supply curve for reserves, S, is the amount of reserves from the
central bank supplied through its open market operations (in more normal
times, at least). Equilibrium occurs where the demand for reserves equals the
quantity supplied. This occurs at an interest rate of A, providing the short-term
interest rate in the market.
Now imagine that the central bank wishes to lower interest rates. It does
this by increasing its purchases of government securities in the repo market,
providing a greater quantity of reserves. This pushes the supply curve in
Figure 16.3 from S1 to S2, and moves the equilibrium interest rate from A to B.
Obviously, if the central bank reduced its reserves outstanding to the banking
system by selling additional securities, the supply curve would move to the left
and the interest rate would rise.
So far we have discussed dynamic open market operations. That is, where
the central bank takes the initiative to change the level of reserves and the
monetary base within a reasonably static banking environment. However,
many times the environment is not static because there are a number of factors
changing demand for borrowed reserves, e.g. greater or lesser banker confid-
ence in the economy and thus the potential for low-risk lending. Thus, it
intervenes – a defensive open market operation – to offset the other factors
influencing reserves.
When the central bank wants to change short-term interest rates it can often
do so merely by announcing its new target rate and threatening to undertake
open market operations to achieve it rather than actually intervening. The
money market participants know that if they do not immediately move to the
new rate they will encounter difficulties. For example, if the central bank shifts
to target an interest rate lower than previously (i.e. it will lend on the repo
market at a new lower rate), then any bank wanting to borrow will be foolish
to borrow at a higher rate. Conversely, if the central bank announces a new
higher target rate, any bank wanting to lend will be foolish to accept a lower
rate than the central bank’s target because it stands ready to trade at its stated
rate. India targets the repo rate – see Article 16.2.
Article 16.2
Source: Kazmin, A. (2013) India cuts interest rate to revive growth, Financial Times,
19 March.
© The Financial Times Limited 2013. All Rights Reserved.
For banks in severe shock there is usually another facility, which is even more
expensive to borrow under. The BoE also has a discount window facility, which
is aimed at banks experiencing firm-specific or market-wide shock. Rather than
cash being borrowed from the BoE, the more usual form of borrowing is UK
government bonds, gilts, which are lent for up to 30 days (or 364 days for an
additional fee). The BoE hands over the gilts and receives in return less liquid
collateral in a repo-type deal. These less liquid securities are much more risky
than sovereign bonds, e.g. the collateral put up could be securitised bonds or a
portfolio of corporate bonds. Once it is in receipt of the gilts the borrowing
bank then obtains cash by lending them in the market – another repo. The
discount window facility borrowing is designed only to address short-term
liquidity shocks and the fees are set to ram home the extraordinary nature
of this type of help with reserves. The BoE states that ‘the fees are set to be
If the interest premium (above Bank Rate, Fed funds rate, etc.) charged in the
standing lending facility falls then an increasing number of banks will be
tempted to cut things fine on excess reserve levels, leading potentially to more
borrowing at the lending facility rate. If the premium rises then few banks will
borrow this way. Thus banks rein in their lending to customers for fear of
having to borrow themselves at punitive interest rates. The standing lending
facility rate acts as a back-stop for the open market target interest rate. The
money market rate will not rise above the standing lending facility rate so long
as the central bank remains willing to supply unlimited funds at the facility rate.
Figure 16.4 Standing lending facility availability changes the supply curve
relevant demand schedule for aggregate bank reserves then the horizontal
portion of the curve – bank borrowing from the central bank at the standing
lending facility rate – does not come into play. Banks will continue to borrow
and lend in the money markets but not from the central bank,9 and the
equilibrium interest rate remains at A. This is the case most of the time:
changes in the standing lending facility rate have no direct effect on the
market interest rate.
Now, consider the case where there has been a shock to the system and banks
increase their demand for reserves all the way along the curve – the demand
curve has shifted to the right, from D1 to D2 in Figure 16.5. Indeed, it has
shifted so much that banks now borrow from the central bank at the standing
lending facility rate to top up their reserves – see demand curve D2 intersecting
the supply curve at the standing lending facility rate at point M. Now, if the
central bank moves the lending facility rate up or down the point of intersec-
tion with the demand curve shifts and thus the market interest rates change. If
the central bank wanted to lower interest rates it could move the lending facil-
ity rate from, say, F to G, leading to increased borrowing from the central bank
and an increased money supply.
9
Unless, of course, it too happens to be one of the buyers or sellers in the normal market.
A few decades ago adjusting the standard lending facility/discount rate was
the main way in which many central banks effected monetary policy, but the
problem with this approach became increasingly apparent. It is difficult to
predict the quantity of lending facility/discount rate borrowing that will occur
if the lending facility/discount rate is raised or lowered, and so it is difficult
to accurately change the money supply. Today changes in this rate are used
to signal to the market that the central bank would like to see higher or lower
interest rates: a raising indicates that tighter monetary conditions are required
with higher interest rates throughout; lowering it indicates that looser, more
expansionary, monetary conditions are seen as necessary.
The main drawback to using changes in the reserve ratio, even in ‘normal
times’, is that it is difficult to make many frequent small adjustments because
to do so would be disruptive to the banking system (e.g. a sudden rise can cause
liquidity problems for banks with low excess reserves). Open market opera-
tions, however, can be used every day to cope with fluctuations in aggregate
monetary conditions. Article 16.3 discusses the lowering of reserves in China
to stimulate the economy.
Article 16.3
In depth
The central bank has tried to tread a fine line over the past year by providing a
targeted stimulus to support the slowing economy, without exacerbating financial
risks by unleashing a new credit binge like the one deployed in response to the 2008
financial crisis.
The central bank’s latest easing move followed a cut in benchmark interest rates in
November and a series of targeted easing measures last year, which included direct
loans worth more than $80bn to specific banks, and RRR cuts for small lenders.
In addition to Wednesday’s broad-based cut, the PBOC announced further targeted
cuts for so-called city commercial banks, whose loan books tilt towards small busi-
ness and the agricultural sector – two areas that have long complained of difficulty
obtaining credit.
In addition to responding to domestic conditions, economists say the PBOC’s move
is also a reaction to moves by central banks in other countries, including the recent
decision by the European Central Bank to pursue an ambitious programme of
quantitative easing.
‘Various countries are raising the stakes when it comes to monetary policy easing,’
said Cao Yang, an analyst at Shanghai Pudong Development Bank. ‘China’s RRR
cut is a move to keep pace.’
Source: Wildau, G. and McGee, P. (2015) Chinese shares fall despite bank reserve ratio cut,
Financial Times, 5 February.
© The Financial Times Limited 2015. All Rights Reserved.
To provide answers, examine the situation in Figure 16.6. The central bank
expects the aggregate demand curve to be as described by the solid demand
line, D2. However, the reality is that the authorities have only a vague idea of
where the demand schedule is. It might fluctuate up to the higher dashed line
or down to the lower one as, say, unexpected changes in deposit levels increase
or decrease commercial banks’ desire to hold excess reserves. Thus, if the cen-
tral bank rigidly maintains the supply schedule, S, the result could be that from
one day to the next overnight interest rates could be quite volatile, fluctuating
from, say, i1 to i3, as the demand curve moves left and right. Such a rapidly
shifting overnight rate can be disruptive.
The alternative approach is to target the overnight interest rate and to there-
fore fine-tune the supply of reserves to achieve the desired interest rate stability
– see Figure 16.7. Here the reserves demand curve fluctuations can be accom-
modated by the central bank response of quickly implementing open market
operations to pump in or drain reserves. If the D1 curve comes into play with
higher reserves demanded at each interest rate then the central bank can
increase supply to S3 by buying securities, achieving equilibrium at interest
rate, i. If demand for reserves is low, D3, then the central bank can move to
supply only S1, leaving equilibrium at i. It can do this by selling securities or
simply not supplying fresh reserves as repo positions come to an end. Thus, the
supply of reserves is determined by the commercial banks’ aggregate demand
for reserves, which is accommodated by the central bank through open market
operations in targeting the price of credit.
Interest rate targeting is generally preferred because the central bank can
quickly observe changes in the rate, whereas measuring aggregate quantities of
reserves involves a time lag. It can also intervene quickly to control the interest
rate, whereas reserves are not completely controllable. Also, central banks have
generally concluded that there is a closer link between interest rates and the
goal of the inflation level in the economy than that between monetary aggre-
gates and inflation. For these reasons central banks generally target short-term
interest rates.
Following the logic of targeting the overnight interest rate, some monetary
economists emphasise that it is the price of credit that determines the quantity
of broad money created by banks. So, rather than targeting a deposit multiplier
through altering the quantity of the monetary base in an assumed stable ratio
of broad money to narrow money, central banks set overnight interbank inter-
est rates, which affect other interest rates. The level of interest rates throughout
the economy (mortgages, deposit interest, etc.) creates the demand for broad
money – banks may become more or less willing to lend, borrowers become
more or less willing to borrow, pay down debt or spend, depending on the
interest rates. The impact on broad money then has an impact on the quantity
of base money demanded. Thus the demand for reserves is a consequence rather
than a cause of banks making loans and creating broad money. Commercial
bank decisions on the amount they make available for loans depends on
the perceived profitability of lending, which in turn depends on a number of
Quantitative easing
In extreme circumstances a central bank may find that interest rates have been
reduced to the lowest level they could go and yet still economic activity does
not pick up. People are so shocked by the crisis – increased chance of unem-
ployment, lower house prices, lower business profits – that they cut down their
consumption and investment regardless of being able to borrow at very low
interest rates. This happened in 2009–2014. Annualised short-term interest
rates in eurozone countries were less than 0.1%, in the UK they were 0.5% and
in the US they were between 0% and 0.25%. Clearly, low short-term interest
rates were not enough to get the economy moving, even with the additional
boost of government deficit spending to the extent that up to one-eighth of all
spending was from government borrowing.
is hoped that the new cash will be used to invest in other assets such as shares
pushing up equity issuance, prices and lowering required returns on these
assets, thus stimulating investment in companies.
In the UK the BoE bought so many bonds in 2009–2013 that it now owns
about one-third of all gilts, pushing ten-year yields at times to only 1.5%.
Between 2008 and 2014 the Fed bought more than $3.5 trillion bonds (mostly
mortgage-backed and government). However, central banks are increasingly
anxious about the consequences of ceasing quantitative easing – interest
rates might rebound dramatically and devastatingly. Some economists are
also worried that inflation might take off at some point given all the extra cash
floating about (optimists argue that the central bank can just sell the bonds
or wait until redemption to suck cash out of the system, others are not so
sure). Japan launched the most audacious quantitative easing plan in 2013:
$1.4 trillion in less than one year – see Article 16.4. Many suspect that bubbles
are being created in bond and other asset markets.
Article 16.4
With quantitative easing the central bank is creating large quantities of reserves
far beyond that needed to achieve its target interest rate. Not only this, but
the quantity of money goes up in large increments, so the supply curve is all
over the place – view the supply curve in Figure 16.8 as moving frequently left
to right and back again.
This could lead to uncertainty. To put a floor under the fluctuations the central
bank introduces a policy of paying its target Bank Rate of interest (0.5% in the
UK) to all reserves lodged by banks with it (even excess reserves). Because
commercial banks will not lend their surplus reserves to each other at rates
lower than can be obtained by depositing them at the central bank, this has the
effect of flattening the demand curve for reserves after the point where there
Figure 16.8 First change: extraordinary circumstances calls for quantitative easing
Figure 16.9 Second change: a floor system, where all bank reserves held at the
central bank are remunerated at Bank Rate (Fed Funds rate, etc.)
are sufficient reserves in the system for banks to manage their day-to-day
liquidity needs – see Figure 16.9.
This allows the central bank to supply unlimited amounts of reserves without
affecting the overnight interest rate – the supply curve can move but the over-
night interest rate stays at, say, 0.5%. The central bank establishes a bench-
mark short-term risk-free interest rate. This will influence the rates that
commercial banks are willing to charge or pay on short-term loans or borrow-
ings in the market.
We could, for completeness, also add the standing lending facility rate (0.75%
at the time of writing) to the diagram, which would create an upper boundary
for interest rates – see Figure 16.10. Commercial banks can borrow as much as
they want at this rate and so market interest rates for overnight money will not
go above this. Commercial banks will typically be unwilling to borrow in the
repo market on worse terms than those available from the central bank. Thus
short-term interest rates in the markets are collared within the range bounded
by the Bank Rate and the standing lending facility rate regardless of the extent
of high-powered money creation. In the UK the short-term interest rate is
unlikely to be lifted higher than the Bank Rate given the sheer quantity of
reserves sloshing about the banking system, where there are plenty of banks
willing to lend overnight to other banks at 0.5%. Collectively, banks would
need to come under severe strain for the upper limit of the corridor (0.75%) to
be tested.
Contact us today:
corporate.enquiries@pearson.com