Corruption: Delving Into The Muddy Water Through The Lens of Islam
Corruption: Delving Into The Muddy Water Through The Lens of Islam
Corruption: Delving Into The Muddy Water Through The Lens of Islam
www.emeraldinsight.com/1359-0790.htm
Through the
Corruption: delving into lens of Islam
the muddy water through
the lens of Islam
139
Siti Faridah Abdul Jabbar
School of Accounting, Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia, Bangi, Malaysia
Abstract
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to examine corruption from the perspective of Islam.
Design/methodology/approach – The paper takes the form of a critical analysis of the primary
sources of Islamic law and extant literature.
Findings – In Islam, corruption is vehemently condemned; the meaning and scope of corruption is
wide; and Islamic internal constraint is a significant tool against corruption.
Practical implications – The paper suggests a manner by which Muslim countries may effectively
combat corruption.
Originality/value – This paper contributes to a discourse on corruption from an Islamic perspective,
which is currently lacking.
Keywords Corruption, Islam
Paper type Viewpoint
Introduction
A significant number of Muslim countries occupy the bottom of the Transparency
International Corruption Perceptions Index[1]. While at the one end there may be some
who hastily put the blame on religious influence for this predicament, at the other there
may be others who try to empathise with the misfortune by linking it to factors such as
lower income and educational levels of the majority of the Muslim population[2]. While
it is not the aim of this paper to uphold or refute any of the sentiments, it does, however,
begin by examining Islam’s stance on corruption. Next, it analyses the meaning and
scope of corruption in Islam and finally discusses the significant role that Islam can
play in combating corruption.
Conclusion
Corruption is fervidly forbidden in Islam. There are numerous verses in the Qur’an and
innumerable Sunnah of the Prophet Muhammad which condemn corruption. The fight
against corruption is, thus, obligatory upon all Muslims. The meaning and scope of
corruption is very wide in Islam. Any act that flouts the principle of justice and
causes harm to mankind, other creatures and the environment is corruption. Islam can
play a significant role in the fight against corruption. Its central value of equitable
distribution of income, resources and wealth coupled with the principle of strict
accountability would significantly support the external constraints such as education,
law and institutional infrastructures in combating corruption.
Notes
1. Transparency International is a global non-governmental coalition against corruption and
scores countries each year on how corrupt their public sectors are perceived to be through
its corruption perceptions index (CPI). The CPI is determined through “the informed
views of analysts, businesspeople and experts in countries around the world”
JFC (Transparency International) and measured in the scale of 0 to 10. 0 is the highest level of
corruption and 10 the lowest. A higher value indicates a more honest and less corrupt
20,2 country. The CPI is employed by many as the standard indicator of the extent of corruption
in a country.
2. Although the following studies are not directly linked to the statement above, see
La Porta et al. (1999) who find that countries with higher Catholic or Muslim populations
144 tend to have higher corruption and Samanta et al. (2010) who present that a country becomes
less corrupt when the percentage of Islamic population goes up. For a succinct yet
comprehensive discourse on various other determinants of corruption (Pellegrini and
Gerlagh, 2008).
3. A corrupt act such as embezzlement (sarigah) has been categorised as hudud by the Qur’an
and Sunnah that would entail in a fixed penalty which cannot be reduced, augmented or
annulled by man. Corrupt acts that have not been specifically categorised as hudud may be
categorised as ta’zir by the State, which is also given the discretion to determine the
punishment for the acts after having taken cognisance of the requirements of the Qur’an and
Sunnah ( Jabbar, 2010).
4. See, for example, a Hadith where the Prophet Muhammad was reported to have said: “ [. . .] to
earn a lawful livelihood is an obligatory duty [. . .]” (Hadith Baihaqi).
5. Hadith Bukhari and Muslim.
6. Narrated by Ahmed, Al-Bazaz and Al-Tabarani.
7. Hadith Muslim.
8. Hadith Bukhari.
9. http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/anticorrupt/corruptn/cor02.htm
10. For a further discussion on “justice” in Islam (Rosen, 2000).
11. The duty to protect the environment may be derived, among others, from Surah Ar-Rahman
(55), verses 5-9 of the Qur’an, which is translated thus: “the sun and the moon run on their
fixed courses by precise calculation. And the stars and trees both prostrate. And the heaven
He has raised high and He has set up the balance. That you not transgress the balance. And
observe the weight in equity and do not make the balance deficient”.
12. For example, Surah Al-Baqarah (2), verse 188 which is translated thus: “and do not consume
one another’s property unjustly nor give bribery to the rulers so that they might aid you to
consume a portion of the property of others sinfully, while you know [it is unlawful]”.
13. For example, Surah Hud (11), verse 85 which is translated thus: “and O my people, give full
measure and weight in justice and do not deprive the people of their due and do not commit
abuse on the earth, spreading corruption”.
14. For example, Surah Al-Qasas (28), verse 4 which is translated thus: “indeed, Pharaoh exalted
himself in the land and made its people into factions, oppressing a sector among them,
slaughtering their [newborn] sons and keeping their females alive. Indeed, he was of the
corrupters”.
15. In a study based on interviews conducted with tax payers in Taiwan, 94 percent of them
admitted to bribing public officials to be lenient in assessing their taxes (Chu, 1990).
16. Mauro (1998) finds that corruption reduces government spending on education in a
cross-section of countries.
17. Smith et al. (2003) present that some developing countries have high levels of political
corruption, which reduces effective funding levels and distorts priorities, thus, affecting the
success of conservation projects.
18. Other impacts of corruption include lower level of investment (Wei, 2000; Habib and Through the
Zurawicki, 2002; Samanta and Breslin, 2007; Podobnik et al., 2008); adverse effect on business
(Bliss and Di Tella, 1997; Johnson et al., 2000; Anderson and Marcouiller, 2002; Beck et al., lens of Islam
2005); adverse effect on financial market (Fisman, 1991); negative effect on human capital
(Murphy et al., 1991); erodes belief in the political system (Seligson, 2002); and decline in foreign
aid (Mauro, 1997). Although there had been arguments that corruption may not necessarily be
bad and may, in fact, “grease the squeaking wheels of a rigid administration” or “grease the
wheels of commerce” by, among others, removing obstructionist bureaucratic behaviour that 145
stifle efficient investment and reducing transaction cost and the cost of capital (Leff, 1964;
Lui, 1985; Kaufmann and Wei, 1999; Ehrlich and Lui, 1999), these efficiency-enhancing
theoretical views of corruption, however, had been brushed aside on the basis that they lack
empirical support and have largely fallen out of favour (Iqbal and Lewis, 2002; Aidt, 2003).
19. Ahmad (1999). Individuals without any sense of the strict accountability “will be tempted to
engage in corruption when the size of their corrupt gain is greater than the penalty if caught
times the probability of being caught” (Klitgaard, 1998).
References
Abuarqub, M. (2009), Islamic Imperatives to Curb Corruption and Promote Sustainable
Development, Islamic Relief Worldwide, Birmingham.
Ahmad, M. (1999), Business Ethics in Islam, Kitab Bhavan, New Delhi.
Ahmad, Z. (1991), Islam, Poverty and Income Distribution, Islamic Foundation, Leicester.
Aidt, T.S. (2003), “Economic analysis of corruption: a survey”, Economic Journal, Vol. 113,
November, pp. F632-F652.
Anderson, J.E. and Marcouiller, D. (2002), “Insecurity and the pattern of trade: an empirical
investigation”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84 No. 2, p. 342.
Andersson, S. and Heywood, P.M. (2009), “The politics of perception: use and abuse of Transparency
International’s approach to measuring corruption”, Political Studies, Vol. 57 No. 4, p. 746.
Asian Development Bank (1998), Anticorruption Policy, Asian Development Bank,
Mandaluyong City.
Beck, T., Demirgüçkunt, A. and Maksimovic, V. (2005), “Financial and legal constraints to
growth: does firm size matter?”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 60 No. 1, p. 137.
Bliss, C. and Di Tella, R. (1997), “Does competition kill corruption?”, Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 105 No. 5, p. 1001.
Brown, E. and Cloke, J. (2011), “Critical perspectives on corruption: an overview”, Critical
Perspectives on International Business, Vol. 7 No. 2, p. 116.
Chu, C.Y. (1990), “A model of income tax evasion with venal tax officials – the case of Taiwan”,
Public Finance, Vol. 45 No. 3, p. 392.
Ehrlich, I. and Lui, F. (1999), “Bureaucratic corruption and endogenous economic growth”,
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107 No. 6, p. 270.
Er, M. (2008), “Corruption from the Islamic perspective: some recommendations for the MENA
region”, International Journal of Islamic and Middle Eastern Finance and Management,
Vol. 1 No. 1, p. 31.
Fisman, R. (1991), “Estimating the value of political connections”, American Economic Review,
Vol. 94 No. 4, p. 1095.
Friedman, E., Johnsonb, S., Kaufmann, D. and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (2000), “Dodging the grabbing
hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries”, Journal of Public Economics,
Vol. 76 No. 3, p. 459.
JFC Gray, C.W. and Kaufman, D. (1998), “Corruption and development”, Finance & Development,
Vol. 35 No. 1, p. 7.
20,2
Graycar, A. and Villa, D. (2011), “The loss of governance capacity through corruption”,
Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions, Vol. 24
No. 3, pp. 419-438.
Gupta, A. (1995), “Blurred boundaries: the discourse of corruption, the culture of politics, and the
146 imagined state”, American Ethnologist, Vol. 22 No. 2, p. 375.
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H. and Alonso-Terme, R. (1998), “Does corruption affect income inequality
and poverty?”, IMF Working Paper, Washington, DC, May.
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2002), “Corruption and foreign direct investment”, Journal of
International Business Studies, Vol. 33 No. 2, p. 291.
Haque, N. and Sahay, R. (1996), “Do government wage cuts close budget deficits? Costs of
corruption”, IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 43, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC,
p. 754, December.
Iqbal, Z. and Lewis, M.K. (2002), “Governance and corruption: can Islamic societies and the West
learn from each other?”, The American Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, Vol. 19 No. 2, p. 1.
Jabbar, S.F.A. (2010), “Financial crimes: prohibition in Islam and prevention by the Shari’a
Supervisory Board of Islamic financial institutions”, Journal of Financial Crime, Vol. 17
No. 3, p. 287.
Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., McMillan, J. and Woodruff, C. (2000), “Why do firms hide? Bribes and
unofficial activity after communism”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76 No. 3, p. 495.
Kaufmann, D. and Wei, S.J. (1999), “Does ‘grease money’ speed up the wheels of commerce?”,
NBER Working Paper 7093, April.
Klitgaard, R. (1998), “Strategies against corruption”, Foro Iberoamericano sobre el Combate a la
Corrupción (1998 Jun. 15-16: Santa Cruz de la Sierra) CLAD; Agencia Española de
Cooperación Internacional.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1999), “The quality of government”,
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, Vol. 15, pp. 222-279.
Leff, N.H. (1964), “Economic development through bureaucratic corruption”, The American
Behavior Scientist, Vol. 8, p. 8.
Lui, F. (1985), “An equilibrium queuing model of bribery”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93,
p. 760.
Mannan, M.A. (1982), Why is Islamic Economics Important? Seven Reasons for Believing,
King Abdulaziz University, Jeddah.
Mauro, P. (1997), “Why worry about corruption?”, Economic Issues No. 6, International Monetary
Fund, Washington, DC.
Mauro, P. (1998), “Corruption and the composition of government expenditure”, Journal of Public
Economics, Vol. 69 No. 2, p. 263.
Mo, P.H. (2001), “Corruption and economic growth”, Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 29
No. 1, p. 66.
Murphy, K.M., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1991), “The allocation of talent: implications for
growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, p. 503.
Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R. (2008), “Causes of corruption: a survey of cross-country analyses
and extended results”, Econ. Gov., Vol. 9 No. 245.
Podobnik, B., Shao, J., Njavro, D., Ivanov, P.C. and Stanley, H.E. (2008), “Influence of corruption Through the
on economic growth rate and foreign investment”, The European Physical Journal B,
Vol. 63, p. 547. lens of Islam
Polzer, T. (2001), “Corruption: deconstructing the World Bank discourse”, DESTIN Working
Paper 01-18, London School of Economics, London.
Ravallion, M. and Chen, S. (1997), “What can new survey data tell us about recent changes in
distribution and poverty?”, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 11 No. 2, p. 357. 147
Rider, B.A.K. (2007), “Recovering the proceeds of corruption”, Journal of Money Laundering
Control, Vol. 10 No. 1, p. 5.
Rosen, L. (2000), The Justice of Islam, OUP, New York, NY.
Samanta, S., Pleskov, I. and Zadeh, A.H.M. (2010), “Religion as a determinant of corruption:
comparative evidence from OPEC and OECD countries”, International Journal of
Management, Vol. 2 Nos 3/Part 2, p. 728.
Samanta, S.K. and Breslin, T. (2007), “Corruption and economic performance in several African
countries: an analysis”, Asian-African Journal of Economics and Econometrics, Vol. 7
No. 417.
Seligson, M.A. (2002), “The impact of corruption on regime legitimacy: a comparative study of
four Latin American countries”, Journal of Politics, Vol. 64 No. 2, p. 408.
Sexton, S. and Hildyard, N. (2008), “Sustaining corruption legal challenges in a hostile political
environment when corruption investigations have not been sustained: insights from
‘the BAE case’”, Brown, E. and Cloke, J. (2011), “Critical perspectives on corruption:
an overview”, Critical Perspectives on International Business, Vol. 7 No. 2, p. 116.
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1993), “Corruption”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108,
p. 599.
Smith, R.J., Muir, R.D.J., Walpole, M.J., Balmford, A. and Leader-Williams, N. (2003), “Governance
and the loss of biodiversity”, Nature, Vol. 426, pp. 67-70.
Tanzi, V. and Davoodi, H. (1997), “Corruption, public investment, and growth”, IMF Working
Paper 97/139, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Wei, S.J. (2000), “How taxing is corruption on international investors?”, Review of Economics and
Statistics, Vol. 82 No. 1, p. 1.
Whyte, D. (2007), “Hire an American! Tyranny and corruption in occupied Iraq”, Social Justice,
Vol. 35 No. 4, p. 153.
Further reading
Transparency International (2012), available at: www.transparency.org (accessed
October 10, 2012).
World Bank (2012), available at: http://www1.worldbank.org/publicsector/anticorrupt/corruptn/
cor02.htm (accessed October 7, 2012).