Tax Theory and Tax Base
Tax Theory and Tax Base
Tax Theory and Tax Base
Abstract. The wide gap between tax theory and tax practice may be traced
back, among other things, to the focus in tax theory on the level and optimal
structure of tax rates, assuming that tax bases are consistently defined, precisely
measurable and readily and uniformly assessable. This approach overlooks the
variances between tax design, tax law, tax impact, tax incidence and tax perception.
The effects of taxes on efficiency and equity depend not just on the tax‐rate sched‐
ule adopted but also on differences in tax treatments resulting from the definition,
measurement and assessment of tax bases. The Italian experience in the field of
income taxation shows the extent to which the definition, measurement and as‐
sessment of tax bases matter. Many problems associated with defining, measuring
and assessing tax bases, which the personal nature and high progressivity of income
tax had contributed to highlighting and accentuating, remain still unresolved and
require further research of a better understanding of the rationale, causes and
effects of many differentiated tax treatments.
*
University of Rome "La Sapienza", e‐mail: antonio.pedone@uniroma1.it.
1
1. This year, the theme of the 20th Annual Conference of the Italian Public
Economics Society (Siep) is the economics of taxation, an area in which there is a
very wide gap, particularly in Italy, between theoretical and econometric analysis,
on the one hand, and the reality of tax policy and practice, on the other.
It could be that the observed divide between tax theory and practice is only
apparent and that Keynes' general remarks1 regarding the unwitting influence, for
better or for worse, of the ideas of economists, apply in this case.
It may be that the traditional Italian tendency, noted by Buchanan2, of focusing
attention on theoretical aspects whilst neglecting issues of tax reform, is still
widespread and prevalent among scholars in the field of public finance.
It might perhaps be that, on the one hand, the growing specialisation and
refinement of the theoretical and empirical analysis of various aspects of the
economics of taxation and, on the other, continuous changes in an increasingly
complex economic and social reality, make it difficult for tax theorists and tax
practitioners to communicate with each other (even though a frank exchange of
opinions could perhaps prove useful to both).
Yet it could also be that, as in other fields of theoretical and applied economic
research, analytical models and econometric estimates provide ambiguous findings
and mixed results, whilst tax practitioners expect unequivocal and practicable
propositions.
1
"The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are
wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else.
Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are
usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air,
are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back". (Keynes 1936, 383).
Obviously, Keynes was not referring to the statements of some of the Finance Ministers of recent
years, though his remarks nevertheless seem very apt.
2
"With rare exceptions, the Italians have not been greatly interested in fiscal reforms [...]. No
reforming spirit has guided the Italians. This has made their arguments seem sterile and devoid of
normative content". (Buchanan 1960, 34 and 72).
2
The fact is, however, that a gap between theory and practice does exist – and
quite a wide one at that. In taxation theory, the focus is on the level and optimal
structure of tax rates, assuming that tax bases are consistently defined, precisely
measurable and readily and uniformly assessable.
In reality, when moving from theoretical models to the concrete application of
any form of taxation deemed optimal, it is almost always the case that the effects
produced in terms of efficiency, equity and other significant economic variables are
different from the effects anticipated on the basis of the theoretical model. The
more that certain constraints vary and are subject to change from the way they are
formulated in the theoretical model, the greater the difference between the
theoretical and practical effects.
Each of these constraints – namely, the prevailing social and economic
structure, the degree of international integration, institutional set‐ups, the manner
in which the tax administration is organised, and the attitudes and behaviours of
taxpayers – may be approximated by a set of indicators that are more or less
representative depending on the availability of data and experiences to draw on.
Their relative importance also varies in different circumstances, as do the ways in
which they interact. These constraints are often ignored or inadequately considered
in many current analyses, which assume the existence of well‐defined and
consistently and uniformly measurable and assessable tax bases, thus focusing
research efforts on optimal tax‐rate schedules.
However, it is my belief that the discrepancy between the anticipated
theoretical effects and the actual effects produced is not only the result of the
application of tax‐rate schedules that differ from those suggested by theory, but the
consequence, above all, of differences in the definition, measurement and
assessment of tax bases. These differences depend on the abovementioned five
groups of constraints and changes in them – in other words, on their actual
3
configuration and development in a given country during a given period of time. As
a result, tax‐related analyses and proposals that do not take these factors into
account and are based solely on findings drawn from inevitably aggregated and
simplified theoretical models can be misleading.
I will seek here to demonstrate the basis for this assertion, briefly running
through certain aspects of the Italian experience with regard to comprehensive
progressive personal income tax (Cppit), although the same reasoning could be
applied to other taxes such as consumption taxes. The reference made to the Italian
experience is only by way of example. It is not intended as a description much less
an appraisal of that experience, but rather solely as a means of drawing attention to
several points which highlight the importance of defining, measuring and assessing
tax bases (in this case, "income") in analysing relationships and the gap existing
between tax theory and tax policy.
2. In very simplified terms, the gap between tax theory and tax practice may be
traced back to variances between ideal taxation (tax design), legally‐imposed
taxation (tax law), the effective impact of taxation (in other words, who is formally
liable to pay the tax: tax impact), the effective incidence of taxation (namely, who
ultimately bears the tax: tax incidence) and perceived taxation (or tax perception).
By clarifying the issues raised by each of these phases and the relationships between
them, it is possible to gain an idea of the extent to which theoretical indications and
concrete applications of a given form of taxation coincide or deviate, and to
compare the effects anticipated by the theoretical model (in terms of revenue yield,
efficiency, equity, income, stabilisation and growth) and the effects that are actually
generated in a specific economic and institutional system of a given country during a
given period of time. Before examining how, in the Italian case, these various phases
and the transition from one phase to the next has been influenced by the varying
4
degree of priority accorded to different objectives and the varying stringency of the
different constraints, it is worth mentioning a few general issues that arise during
each phase when the tax base in question is "income".
Even at a theoretical level, there is no uniform approach to the choice of a tax
base that is "income‐based". The three income formulations generally referred to –
namely, in Lindahl's terminology, income as produce, income as earnings and
income as consumption or expenditure – can each include different components
depending on the timeframe and on the accounting standards and face‐value
inflation‐adjustment criteria adopted3. Moreover, once again at the theoretical
level, "it is possible to arrive at alternative definitions of scientific importance which
should be kept quite separate"4.
The distinction that it is advisable to maintain between the different theoretical
definitions of income that may be used (and are used in models) as a tax base for
"income tax", should also be accompanied by an awareness of the "remarkable
difference between the meaning (or meanings) of income, as the notion appears to
the economic theorist, and the meaning which is given to it, which indeed has to be
given to it, when income is considered as an object of taxation"5.
It is not my intention here to enter into the debate regarding the most
appropriate or optimum theoretical definition of "income" to adopt as the base for a
comprehensive progressive personal income tax6, partly because the proposals put
3
For a clear analysis of these issues, with particular reference to the most widely‐used concept of "income" for tax
purposes (namely, income as earnings) and certain aspects of the Italian system, see Longobardi (2009). An attempt to
link the evolution of the Italian tax system as well as tax reforms introduced in other industrialised nations with
developments in the field of optimal income taxation theory can be found in Artoni, Micheletto and Zanardi (2007).
4
Lindahl 1933, 399. Lindahl examines four concepts of income: the three recalled here as well as income as
interest. It should be noted that in relation to income as earnings as the ideal basic reference model (in the Haigh‐
Simons version), of many modern personal income taxation systems (including those in the US and Italy), he "observes
that "this concept [,..] hardly provides an ideal solution of the problem of how to arrive at a concept of income that
will be both tenable theoretically and practically useful at the same time". (Lindahl 1933,405)
5
Hicks 1981, 73. Naturally, Hicks adds that although the meanings of income for theoretical and taxation purposes
are different, they are nevertheless connected. He also recalls that from the inception of English income tax, it was a
firmly held principle that "incomes of different sorts had to be reached in different ways".
6
This is a debate which at times has been quite heated, as in the crowded controversy over the so‐called "double
taxation of savings" or, for instance, the criticisms levelled (by the most well‐known supporter of the definition of
5
forward in relation to the tax base for income tax have always, and to a greater
extent in recent times, been mixed or "hybrid" in nature. It is enough to assume that
some definition of income, whether pure or hybrid, has been formulated and
adopted as the theoretical term of reference of a Cppit to be levied in a given
context.
income as earnings) at the proposals put forward by Irving Fisher (one of the most noted proponents of the definition
of income as consumption) in his paper "Income in Theory and Income Taxation in Practice". (Simons 1938, 225 sqq.)
6
legislative amendments and regulatory innovations, which become increasingly
more complex, difficult and costly to manage for tax authorities and taxpayers.
In moving from tax design to tax law, the theoretical concepts of income are
broken down and mixed together in a vast array of legislation, from which it is no
longer possible to distil any clearly identifiable and consistent common guiding
principles. Legislative output aimed at combating the continual development of new
forms of avoidance transactions grows ever larger and more detailed. Added to this,
rather than as an alternative, recourse is also had to general "substance‐over‐form"
rules, such as those requiring verification of the actual nature and economic content
(or economic substance) of such transactions, regardless of how they are framed
formally. These are rules that are complex to interpret and difficult to apply for tax
officials that are not always adequately trained and skilled. Their application may
require the assistance and opinion of economists (as has occurred for some time
now in the antitrust field) and a willingness on their part to talk and cooperate with
legal professionals who use different language, methods and principles.
As the muddle of legislation grows increasingly confused, resort to courts of
law and judicial interpretation become unavoidable in many cases and play a role
that is no longer negligible in the very definition of the nature and scope of tax
bases7.
In many countries, recent decades have seen repeated calls and several reform
proposals for the simplification of tax laws, the reduction of Dtts and a widening of
the tax base. The results have, however, been modest and temporary in nature,
because tax law is influenced by factors that have only been partially examined and
which greatly contribute to its further complication by increasing the resort to Dtts.
These factors include: the characteristics of the decision‐making process with
respect to tax legislation and the role played in that process by bureaucrats, political
7
This has been true for a long time at the level of individual national States (with reference to the definition of
taxable income under the old Italian system, cf. Berliri 1949), but it has become increasingly important even at the
supranational level: see, in this regard, the role played in recent years by the European Court of Justice.
7
parties, parliamentary bodies and rules, and organised interest groups; the objective
complexity and the continual transformation of the economic and financial
situation; and the use of Dtts as a means of obtaining consensus and exploiting
political rents8. In Italy too, occasional efforts to restore neutrality, including within
specific categories of income (for instance, between various types of investment
income or between various types of business income), or horizontal equity between
specific categories of workers (for instance, between those receiving income from
employment and those who are self‐employed), have essentially been in vain and, in
some cases, counterproductive. The tax laws that resulted from such attempts have
often been even more complicated than those that previously existed.
4. Regardless of how complicated tax laws may be, they also need to be applied
by tax officials and taxpayers (often with the assistance of tax advisors). The phase
involving enforcement of tax laws by authorities and the more or less willing and full
compliance by taxpayers is another crucial stage where the gap between tax theory
and practice tends to become wider9.
Indeed, the Dtts provided for by law are, in turn, applied in a manner that is not
uniform but rather differentiated according to the different assessment methods
employed and depending on the behaviour of tax officials, taxpayers and tax judges.
The extent and methods of implementation of tax laws (and the Dtts they provide
for) are influenced by numerous factors that have been the subject of a wide body
of literature which examines: the resources, competences, organisation, procedures
and incentives of tax officials; the effectiveness of the penalty system and litigation
8
In commenting on the American reform of .1986 that had substantially and surprisingly reduced tax rates and
broadened the tax base, thereby greatly reducing the number of Dtts, Buchanan recalls that he had predicted, on the
basis of a typical public choice model, that American Congress would soon revert to increasing tax rates on the
broadened tax base and would then reintroduce many Dtts (that is, that it would "[start] reselling the rents"). Indeed,
this is precisely what happened. (Buchanan and Musgrave 2000, 86‐87)
9
With respect to the problems of managing a Cppit extended to apply to high number of taxpayers, see Pedone
1984. In relation to the factors that in recent years have exacerbated these problems, making the application of tax
laws even more differentiated and arbitrary, see Aaron and Slemrod 2004.
8
proceedings; and the strategic behaviours of taxpayers and the role of their tax
advisors. I do not intend to recall here, not even by way of summary, the problems
identified and the solutions proposed and adopted in respect of each of these
aspects. What is of interest here is to note that the various solutions formulated in
theory or adopted in practice to address each of these issues involves Dtts that
become evident when examining who effectively pays (though not necessarily
ultimately bears) the taxes in question.
It is still a matter of debate as to whether, in order to assess their effects, it is
better to consider the impact of legally‐imposed tax rates or effective (average and
marginal) tax rates, and how the latter should and could be calculated. For our
purposes, it is enough to note that referring to one or the other produces very
different results depending on the various characteristics of individual types of
income‐producing activity and taxpayers. In many cases, effective tax rates
represent average values, whose aggregated trends can conceal the non‐uniform –
and sometimes conflicting – patterns of individual components in terms of tax
impact.
Turning to consider effective tax in terms of incidence (rather than impact), it
becomes necessary to introduce specific assumptions about shifting the tax paid by
the taxpayer. Alongside uniform zero or total tax‐shifting, frequently used for their
explanatory simplicity in many models, the assumption of a differentiated shifting of
tax levied on even a "simple" tax base (such as wages, or income from work as a
whole) "gives rise to a redistribution of income tax that is difficult to grasp and is
certainly not referable to any reasonable criteria of justice"10.
Finally, it should be recalled that taxes with the same incidence can be
perceived differently and that it is tax perception, often in conjunction with the
perception of other aspects of public action, that influences the behaviour of
10
Steve 1984, 285.
9
taxpayers and their views on the "fairness" of a tax11. Moreover, the perceived
justice and acceptability of income taxes depends in large measure on the extent
and characteristics of Dtts, which reflect differentiations linked to the definition,
measurement and assessment of the various types of income, as we will see when
we examine certain aspects of the Italian experience in this field.
11
The perception of a tax may militate against the adoption of a tax that is "optimal" from a strictly economic
point of view. This is, for instance, the case with respect to tax on land rent in the Ricardo model, in which "the
taxation of rent does not influence the maximum equilibrium rate of growth or the other equilibrium values of the
system, because scarce resources have the properties of non‐basic products; moreover, among the institutional
factors influencing the rate of accumulation and growth in the R‐model, a reduction in the amount of a given pre‐tax
rent plays no role, because it is assumed that all rents are spent in unproductive consumption. So, one would expect
that, since the taxation of rent does not affect the equilibrium values of the system and does not influence the process
of actual economic growth, it should have been strongly recommended by Ricardo. But this is not the case" (Pedone,
1969, 80). One of the possible reasons that might explain Ricardo's position is that a tax on land rent could be
perceived as a violation of the "natural" right of ownership and lead to a widespread acceptance of the possibility of
also impinging on other natural rights.
12
Goode 1976, 17.
10
patterns, based on some form of utility sacrifice principle. Indeed, at least in the
United States, the country where formal progressivity of personal income tax
reached its highest levels (at the beginning of the 1950s, the marginal tax rate was
94%), this approach to progressivity was adopted rather than relying on abstract
principles as it was deemed the most effective means to reduce the inequalities that
are inevitably created in a market economy. Despite being aware of the disincentive
effects created (to be reduced to a minimum without compromising progressivity
vis‐a‐vis individuals), this approach to reducing inequalities was still viewed as the
least damaging to the functioning of a market economy compared to other forms of
public intervention, such as protectionism or public ownership13.
However, in order to function and "be equalized, a progressive income tax
must be related to the taxpayer's total net income from all sources, and individual
income components must be measured in a uniform manner for all income
categories" (italics added)14. This proposition was reiterated by the most staunch
defender of Cppit: "The effective degree of progression of the income tax depends
on the comprehensiveness of the tax base as well as on the tax rates"15. Yet, as
noted, the measures proposed and adopted to widen the tax base, by determining
its various components in a uniform manner, have not proved successful.
Thus it was that alongside the evident original difficulties, linked to the
different measurement and assessment of tax bases and to Dtts introduced to
mitigate the disincentive effects, further difficulties emerged as a result of increased
international integration and changes in technology and in production structures. In
order to counter the disincentive effects of high marginal tax rates and the distortive
effects of the proliferation of Dtts, formal progressivity was considerably reduced
13
The position in favour of a high level of progressivity, despite an awareness of its disincentive effects (to be
reduced to a minimum), is clearly set out in Simons 1950.
14
Cosciani 1984, 40, who goes on to say: "The deviation from effective income of one or more components that
make up total income, whether attributable to the legal definition of income or to exemptions or total or partial
evasion, does not merely commensurately reduce the tax burden it is intended to alleviate, but also translates into tax
relief for other income that is subject to normal taxation rules" – in other words, into Dtts.
15
Pechman 1990, 9.
11
more or less across the board (as in the case of the Flat Tax or Dual Income Tax) and
a largely illusory attempt was made to significantly broaden the tax base by reducing
Dtts.
Hence, in Italy, just as in nearly all industrialised nations, personal income tax
continues to be the predominant source of government revenue, but the main
purposes that facilitated its widespread adoption in nearly all countries after the
Second World War (including the reduction of inequalities and automatic income
stabilisation) have – both in formal and, above all, practical terms – gradually
abated. The effectiveness of personal income tax has been greatly reduced and its
tax base is "very narrow, confined essentially to income from work and pensions"16.
Traditional issues, such as the use of averaging systems for fluctuating incomes, the
tax treatment of income accumulated over a number of years and paid as a lump
sum and forms of compensation for fiscal drag, may have lost their significance in
theoretical analysis but still merit some attention on a practical level. Detailed
analyses of tax‐rate schedules, also taking into account some forms of public family
support, or dealing with the extent of the redistributive effect, almost exclusively
refer to labour income and do not address the problem of overall inequalities that,
not just in Italy, are on the increase (in relation to which, perhaps it would be
worthwhile to come up with some new virtuous tax instead of the more extensive
direct public intervention measures that have been proposed).
The reduction of the level of progressivity has alleviated the inevitable
distortions linked to the personal nature of income tax, which requires a choice of
tax unit (such as individual income, family total income, or weighted family income).
Where there is a high level of progressivity, the choice of tax unit can have very
significant consequences on the labour market and the structure of consumption, as
well as on the pattern of interpersonal relationships and on social organisation. In
16
Visco in De Vincenti and Paladini 2008, XI.
12
practice, efforts to take into account the different sizes of families and the diverse
types of income earned by the various family members have led to an increase in
the number of Dtts linked to these aspects.
Although they have been alleviated by recent tendencies towards reducing
progressivity, the problems associated with defining, measuring and assessing tax
bases, which the personal nature and high progressivity of income taxes had
certainly contributed to highlighting and accentuating, remain unresolved. In fact, in
the case of taxes with rates that remain uniform and constant despite variation in
the size of tax bases, it becomes immediately evident that the differentiation in tax
treatment between different taxpayers or types of income‐producing activity does
not solely depend on disparities in tax rates, but also on differences in the definition,
measurement and assessment of tax bases. The significance of these issues emerges
clearly when the experience in Italy following the introduction of Cppit is
considered.
6. The tax reform that was adopted in Italy in 1973‐74 with the introduction of
Cppit (or Irpef, the acronym by which Italy's personal income tax is known) led to an
unprecedented transformation of the tax system ‐ a full‐blown "fiscal cataclysm"17.
During the thirty‐year period following the full implementation of the tax reform
between 1975 and 2005, the increase in the overall tax burden in Italy (including
social security contributions) was around three times higher than the average for
Oecd countries (16% of Gdp in Italy as opposed to 6%).
During the same period, fiscal pressure in the strict sense (that is, excluding
social security contributions) increased in Italy by 15 points compared to an increase
of little more than 3 points in the Oecd average and in the Eu‐19 member countries.
In other countries of the Group of 7, during the same period, fiscal pressure in the
17
Fuà and Rosini 1985, 9.
13
strict sense fell slightly in Germany, the United States and Canada, remained
essentially unchanged in the United Kingdom and rose a little in Japan and slightly
more in France18.
The increase in the tax burden in Italy over the last thirty years may thus be
considered as exceptional compared to the trend experienced in the majority of
other industrialised nations, and, in many cases, as constituting a countertrend. This
point should be kept in mind, even though to a large extent the increase saw Italy
closing the gap on the European and Oecd averages, which it has now decidedly
exceeded.
In addition to the intensity and speed of this increase in fiscal pressure, mainly
concentrated between 1975 and 1995, the means by which this increase was
brought about is worth noting, with around half of the extraordinary increase in the
overall tax take attributable to progressive personal income tax. In the case of Italy,
the increase in revenue from this tax in Gdp terms has, in the thirty years following
the reform, been greater than that in any other country of the Oecd zone. During
the same period, the average for all European countries and the average for other
Oecd country groupings experienced an essentially steady or slightly reduced
incidence of Cppit, while a significant reduction was seen in countries like Germany,
the United Kingdom and Sweden (the latter, however, started from and remains at a
considerably higher level).
This increase led to a radical and unexpected change in the composition of the
tax take in the years immediately after the reform came into effect. While in 1970,
direct taxes represented 28% of total taxes and indirect taxes accounted for 72%, by
18
Clearly, it is only with much caution that conclusions may be drawn from this and the other quantitative ratios
mentioned, both because of the shaky theoretical foundations that support the presumed effects of different tax
levels and schedules and because of the composition and measurement of the numerator and denominator. In
relation to the numerator, for instance, the resort (varied as well as variable over time) to forms of tax expenditures –
as an alternative to equivalent subsidies or transfers from the public budget – in support of families and businesses,
should be taken into account. In the cases examined in this text, the order of magnitude seems such as to throw
certain peculiar characteristics of recent experiences in Italy into sharp relief. See Pedone 2006 for a more extensive
discussion.
14
1979 the situation had already almost been reversed, with the proportion of direct
taxes (51%) in that year exceeding – albeit marginally – that of indirect taxes (49%).
This trend continued to gain strength over time and personal income tax assumed
an increasingly more prominent role.
Several conclusions can be drawn from these observations. Firstly, a tax, even if
good in theory, comes up against insuperable limits in practice when it is called on
to fulfil purposes that are too wide, and particularly when it produces an
extraordinary and uneven – rather than a moderate and constant – increase in total
revenue.
Furthermore, these limits are even more evident when an individual tax
contributes almost exclusively to an exceptional increase in total revenue19. It
should be recalled that, at the time when the reform package was being formulated,
it was proposed that Cppit be accompanied by a net wealth tax and, in particular, a
broad‐based consumption tax. The widespread and successful opposition to this
latter form of taxation was based not on theoretical analyses of what in abstract
terms was the preferable tax base, but on considerations specific to the country and
the time. In particular, reference was made to the "excessive", burden imposed by
indirect taxes up until the mid‐1970s and to the associated emergence of smuggling
and tax avoidance practices. The purported regressivity of such taxes was also
emphasised. In the end, it was decided not to increase indirect taxes given the op‐
eration of wage‐indexing mechanisms which would have exacerbated their impact
on prices at a time when inflation was already high. Whatever the reasons for this
choice, and however well‐founded they were, it should be recalled that often the
fairness of a tax is not to be judged in isolation, but in relation to other taxes within
19
"It is precisely because I am convinced that ft is not possible to expect from any one tax, not even personal
income tax, more than it can deliver, and because I am convinced that all taxes have major shortcomings, that I
believe it is necessary to have a system which incorporates different tax bases and different criteria for the
distribution of tax liability" (Steve 1984,285).
15
the system and the actual configuration of the previously mentioned constraints in a
specific situation.
7. The sharp rise in income tax revenue that occurred immediately after the
introduction of Irpef was mainly attributable to three factors that were not
accurately anticipated and were not readily foreseeable in terms of their eventual
magnitude.
The first of these factors was the immediate and extensive widening of the pool
of taxpayers. The number went from 4,800,000 taxpayers of the supplementary tax
(a kind of surtax levied in addition to the schedular taxes on income that applied in
Italy before the reform) in 1973, to 22,753,000 Irpef taxpayers in 1974. A change of
these proportions cannot merely be considered in quantitative terms, as the
extended application of income tax to a large number of taxpayers also has
qualitative consequences in that it: increases the number of personal circumstances
that are differentiated in many respects; increases the demand for Dtts, and
probably the frequency with which they are granted, with negative consequences
on voluntary compliance, which is a necessary precondition for the smooth
functioning of a mass taxation system; requires the adaptation of the resources and
working methods of tax authorities, with the adoption of selective and, in many
cases, indirect audit methods; and makes the introduction of reforms or even partial
changes to Cppit more difficult because of the possession by the same taxpayer –
even in small amounts – of different types of income (for instance, income from
work and income from property), which triggers a kind of intrapersonal distributive
conflict that paralyses attempts to change the tax treatment of various types of
income.
The second factor, which is particularly significant for the purposes of this
discussion, is the introduction of new methods of tax assessment and, above all, of
16
tax collection, including the extension of withholdings at source, forms of self‐
assessment and the payment of tax instalments on account. Some of these
innovations were very effective in securing a high and regular flow of tax revenue,
but because of their varied application to different types of income, they actually
accentuated the differentiation of tax treatments of such income, due also to the
methods used to check tax returns, the conducting of tax audits and the imposition
of penalties by tax authorities.
The third factor which contributed to the extraordinary increase in revenue, at
least until the beginning of the 1990s, was the high inflation triggered by the 1973
oil crisis which, through its interaction with the progressivity of Irpef, gave rise to a
huge fiscal drag. This led to a sudden increase in average and marginal tax rates
levied on the income of those unable to avoid the application of the tax. The result
was an exacerbation of the difference in tax treatment between those, on the one
hand, who were fully caught, and those, on the other, who had been safeguarded
and protected from the full and effective application of the progressivity of the tax
since the introduction of the reform, or who had succeeded in sheltering behind
legal forms of avoidance (exploiting and widening the gaps and loopholes in the tax
system), or who had been driven to or had hidden themselves within the maze of
tax evasion, helped along by the small scale of their activities, the difficulty of
tracing their transactions and the lack of skills on the part of tax authorities needed
to manage a mass taxation system.
Here too, a further brief conclusion may be drawn, namely: that a tax that is
theoretically good may only remain so in practice if it does not apply to a pool of
taxpayers that is too wide and too differentiated; if it allows for the adoption of
technical assessment and collection methods that are, as much as possible,
automatic, uniform and effective; and if it is able to adapt to profound and
17
unforeseen changes in external circumstances that substantially alter its
development and the distribution of its tax base.
8. One of the causes for the radically different effects – than those anticipated
– of the original reform plan, or what was left of it in the laws that were actually
enacted, was in fact the gap between the socio‐economic conditions used as a
reference point for the underlying model adopted during the formulation stage of
the reform and the profoundly changed circumstances in which the reform came to
be applied.
In this regard, one need only recall that during the gestation period of the tax
reform package, the Italian economy was characterised by: integration within a
relatively stable, framework of international economic and financial relations
(which, among other things, provided for controls over capital movements); a rather
high and not overly variable Gdp growth rate; a relatively low rate of inflation; a still
modest level of public expenditure which was well below that prevailing in other
major European countries; a current account surplus of the public budget close to
the average for industrialised nations; and a trend towards growth in the size and
organisational capacity of businesses.
However, around the mid‐1970s when the tax reform package came into force,
the Italian economy was facing radically altered and, to some extent, opposite
conditions to those that had previously prevailed. The international economic and
financial situation was very troubled and uncertain, and de facto capital mobility
pressures were growing, heralding the full‐scale liberalisation that would be
undertaken in the second half of the 1980s; the rate of Gdp growth was slowing and
had become more uneven; the rate of inflation exploded and stayed very high
because of pressures from increases in raw material prices and the cost of labour;
growth in public spending accelerated until it exceeded, in Gdp terms, the average
18
for European countries; the budget deficit grew rapidly despite strong growth in tax
revenue; and the trend towards industrial concentration was curbed while certain
large companies had run into difficulties.
It is unlikely that the same theoretical tax model could be equally valid in
situations so profoundly different and in the face of such a different configuration of
the significant constraints referred to in paragraph 1 above. There were major
changes in certain constraints that would have impacted on the applicability in
practice of any income tax model. These included: the degree of monetary freedom
(which was affected by international economic and financial integration) and
national autonomy in taxing income from capital; the increase in well‐organised
companies that could act as large tax collectors on behalf of the State (despite
seeking to avoid payment of taxes they owed); and, more generally, the variety of
productive or organisational structures adopted by businesses of different sizes
which required differentiated assessment methods, each of which involved their
own problems.
9. The influence of these and other variable constraints shows that the main
cause of the problems encountered in the implementation of Irpef in Italy, and Cppit
generally, lies in some respects with the very concept of income adopted. I have
already alluded to my belief that the problems of current comprehensive
progressive personal income taxes do not solely stem from the multiplicity of
adjustments made to total income through various forms of deductions and
allowances, but result particularly from underlying difficulties in defining, measuring
and assessing the individual types of income that make up total income. These
difficulties have been exacerbated by changes in economic and financial structures
and relations that have increasingly made the definition, measurement and
19
assessment of the various types of income for tax purposes more reliant on
established conventions (such as recognised accounting standards).
The difficulties of definition and measurement increase according to the level
of complexity of the economic and financial structure. Calculating net product does
not present any particular problems in that it is obtained by comparing uniform and
constant magnitudes over time that are measurable in physical terms, such as, for
instance, the quantity of wheat input with the quantity of wheat output. However,
as is well‐known, matters become complicated with the adoption of production
processes that, for the production of individual goods, use intermediate inputs
comprising other produced goods in different proportions, necessitating the resort
to valuation criteria in order to arrive at a calculation of net income.
Different situations have become even more differentiated in cases involving
durable capital assets and unforeseeable technological innovations, which have
necessitated the use of increasingly more conventional and ad hoc criteria to
measure income or "net profit". Even these criteria, despite their being continuously
changed and updated, have proved increasingly inadequate as the level of
commensurability between input and output in terms of constant and uniform
physical units has fallen, due to product innovation, the expansion of service
industries (with the development of personal and financial services and so on) and
the key role now played by the production and exchange of information as
significant indicators of the expectations and behaviour of the various parties
involved.
In such situations, which reflect the current conditions of a continuously
evolving complex economy, the definition and measurement of various types of
income are inevitably based on conventional criteria, which, as much as it may be
sought to base them on objective and neutral factors, involve unavoidable
subjective considerations. The result is differentiated tax treatments for different
20
types of income, depending on the conventional calculation criteria adopted in
individual cases, trends in certain external conditions (such as the rate of inflation,
or technological and financial innovation), taxpayers' and tax officials' incentives and
individual behavioural responses.
In addition to these general difficulties, which apply to all modern income tax
systems, in Italy there have also been problems stemming from the laudable but
illusory decision to adopt an all‐inclusive concept of taxable income based on an
analytical determination of effective income20. The decision was praiseworthy
because it was aimed at restoring neutrality and simplicity to the tax system, which
should have led to an examination and review of the basis for the many tax
concessions that had accumulated over time and were differentiated according to
categories of taxpayers, types of income and the applicable forms of tax
withholding. Yet it was also an illusory choice because the problems of modern
income taxes arise not only once adjustments have been made to total income, but
also, and, above all, stem from the difficulties of defining and measuring "at source"
the income components that make up total income. These difficulties impact to
varying degrees on the different categories of income, depending on the extent to
which it is possible to detect gross receipts and on the varying levels of complexity
of the mutable link between gross receipts and net income.
The argument that all income is equal for the purposes of income tax and
should therefore be treated in the same manner may, from the point of view of
simplicity and neutrality, seem attractive. However, it ignores the fact that most of
such income does not exist in a "pure state". Rather, the income is "derived" and
"adjusted", according to conventional rules which leave ample margin for
discretionary assessment on the part of tax authorities and encourage opportunistic
behaviour on the part of taxpayers.
20
Longobardi and Pedone 1994, 495.
21
10. The Italian experience in the field of income taxation demonstrates the
importance of the issues associated with the definition, measurement and
assessment of tax bases in addition to those relating to the application of an optimal
tax‐rate schedule. Further analysis is required of the extent to which and the ways in
which these issues are linked to and depend on the actual country‐specific
configuration and development of the previously mentioned constraints, namely:
the prevailing economic and social structure; the degree of international
integration; institutional set‐ups; administrative organisation and the attitudes and
behaviours of taxpayers.
In the case of Italy, the general difficulties involved in administering modern
income taxes have been exacerbated to the extent they have been because, from
the outset, structural constraints have been ignored that are linked to the distinctive
characteristics of Italy's business environment, which, more so than in other
countries, is composed predominantly of small businesses, self‐employed workers
and a high level of fragmentation, heterogeneity and variability in the productive
system21.
Similarly, from the outset there have inevitably been highly differentiated tax
treatments according to the classification of various types of income (cases in point
include forms of income from capital or the catchall category of "other income"22),
the criteria used to determine the relevant tax base (for instance, income from land
and buildings, or business income), and the assessment methods and rules used23. In
21
This was acknowledged by one of the principal architects of the Italian tax reform package (Visentini 1993), who
considered it "positive, on the whole, except in relation to the important issue of taxation of the income of small
businesses" and freelance professionals, who, however, quantitatively make up a very significant proportion of the
Italian business landscape.
22
For a detailed analysis of the development of the highly differentiated and variable tax treatment of capital and
investment income, according to the nature and characteristics of the relevant investment vehicle, the issuer and the
recipient, see Ricotti and Sanelli 2006.
23
In relation to which, what matters is their actual uniform application, including the case of simple tax bases such
as income from work. For instance, the structure of employment can have an effect on the uniform application of the
tax even in respect of similar types of income from work, in that "an accurate assessment of income from work is
22
relation to the latter, various simplified or special tax regimes have been introduced
in order to deal with certain characteristics of the Italian business environment.
These measures have included: the introduction of flat‐rate schemes for deter‐
mining turnover; the use of presumptive turnover coefficients and, without regard
to the latter, presumptive income coefficients; various versions of the so‐called
"redditometro" (an indirect income calculator tool); and, finally, the now long‐
running, tortuous and as yet unfinished saga of the so‐called "studi di settore"
(Business Sector Studies for the estimation of turnover, costs and income of firms in
specific industries).
These developments merit further detailed examination in order to highlight,
on one hand, the reasons for and the consequences of the resort to different (direct
and indirect) assessment methods for determining the tax base during the audit
stage, and on the other hand, to identify the minimum necessary conditions
regarding the quality of data, the formulation of the analytical model and estimate
methods, which would enable a correct and effective use of statistical indicators for
the selection of audit targets, thereby preventing forms of "econometric
avoidance"24.
The different methods and options used for assessing similar types of income
(including within the categories of labour income, income from capital and business
income) confirm that the problems associated with personal income taxes do not
only stem from the important aspects most frequently analysed – which relate to
the largely arbitrary choice of tax unit (individual or family) and adjustments made
more likely for employees of firms that have a well‐formalised organisational structure, a requisite found more
frequently in large firms than small ones". Consequently, given the existence of employment structure differences,
"an income taxation model that functions with tolerable error margins in the United Kingdom may on the contrary be
completely inappropriate – as it is riddled with loopholes – in Italy" (Fuà 1985, 39).
24
The report of the committee appointed to examine "legal and business issues arising in the field of Business
Sector Studies" highlighted a "massive and documented manipulation of significant information for the calculation of
income conformity thresholds" (the so‐called soglie di congruità, used in Italy to determine the conformity of declared
turnover with the minimum presumed turnover for the specific type of business activity conducted). The committee
also noted that the approach used to define and determine the associated indicators and parameters could "introduce
major disparities between businesses, often to the disadvantage of small taxpayers or those deemed to be so" (Rey
2008, 7).
23
to total income (deductions) or gross tax (allowances and tax credits) – but are also,
above all, linked to the difficulties in defining, measuring and assessing the
individual types of income that make up total income.
In particular, for business income tax, the differentiations in tax bases are not
only the result of the more or less strict reference made by tax laws to different
accounting standards depending on the type of taxpayer to whom they apply (one
need only look at the differentiation produced by the introduction of the lass for
certain types of companies) and the resort to alarming practices involving tax‐base
shifting between different jurisdictions by multinational companies. Rather, they
also stem from the application, particularly with regards to small businesses25, of
presumptive indicators for the purposes of defining, measuring and assessing tax
bases or to break the tax bases down into constituent components (for instance,
labour income and income from capital) that are subject to different tax treatments.
These various factors, in addition to those previously mentioned, should be
taken into account and analysed carefully when tax changes or tax reforms
(hopefully of an increasingly more far‐reaching nature) are proposed aimed at
improving the efficiency and equity of the tax system, which depend not just on the
tax‐rate schedule adopted but also on differences in tax treatments resulting from
the definition, measurement and assessment of tax bases. Research dedicated to
further examining these aspects could contribute to a better understanding of the
rationale, causes and effects of many differentiated tax treatments, thus helping to
bridge the gap between tax theory and tax practice in very important fields for our
discipline, such as the relationships between taxation and economic growth or the
various forms of tax competition and tax harmonisation.
25
A recent broad overview of the problems associated with defining and measuring taxable income in the case of
owner‐managed businesses and of tax treatments differentiated according to the various legal forms that businesses
may take can be found in Crawford and Freeman 2008.
24
References
Aaron H. J. (eds.) (1981), The Value‐Added Tax: Lessons from Europe, Washington,
The Brookings Institution.
Aaron H. J., Slemrod, J. (eds.) (2004), The Crisis in Tax Administration, Washington,
Brookings Institution Press.
Aaron H. J., Galper H., Pechman J. A. (eds.) (1998), Uneasy Compromise. Problems of
a Hybrid Income – Consumption Tax, Washington, The Brookings Institution.
Artoni R., Micheletto L., Zanardi A. (2007), "Equità ed efficienza nella tassazione dei
redditi personali: fondamenti teorici e linee di riforma", in Dosi G, Marcuzzo M.
C. (a cura di), L'economia e la politico, Bologna, il Mulino.
Banca d'ltalia (2003), Tax Policy, Papers presented at the Bank of Italy workshop
held in Perugia, 3‐5 April.
Berlin L. V. (1949), L'imposta di ricchezza mobile. Incontri e scontri di dottrina e
giurisprudenza, Milano, Giuffrè.
Bernardi L., Profeta P. (eds.) (2004), Tax Systems and Tax Reforms in Europe,
London, Routledge.
Buchanan J. M. (1960), "La Scienza delle Finanze: The Italian Tradition in Fiscal
Theory", in Fiscal Theory and Political Economy, Chapel Hill, The University of
North Carolina Press.
Buchanan J. M., Musgrave R. A. (1999), Public Finance and Public Choice. Two
Contrasting Vision of the State, Cambridge, The Mit Press.
Cnossen S. (2002), Tax Policy in the European Union: A Review of Issues and Options,
Munich, CESifo Paper, no. 758.
Cosciani C. (1984), "I principi informatori della riforma tributaria nei lavori
preparatori: validità e limiti nella situazione attuale", in Gerelli E., Valiani R. (a
cura di), La crisi dell'imposizione progressiva sul reddito, FrancoAngeli, Milano.
25
Crawford C, Freedman J. (2008), Small Business Taxation, prepared for the "Report
of a Commission on Reforming the Tax System for the 21st Century" chaired by
Sir James Mirrlees, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
D'Albergo E. (1931), La crisi dell'imposta personale sul reddito, con prefazione di B.
Griziotti, Padova, Cedam.
De Vincenti C, Paladini R. (a cura di) (2008), Libro bianco sull'imposta sui redditi delle
persone fisiche e il sostegno alle famiglie, Roma, Scuola Superiore di Economia
e Finanza.
Fuà G, Rosini E. (1985), Troppe tasse sui redditi, Bari‐Roma, Laterza.
Gerelli E., Vitale M. (1979), Efallita la riforma tributaria?, Milano, FrancoAngeli,
pp.13‐127.
Gerelli E., Valiani R. (1984) (a cura di), La crisi dell'imposizione progressiva sul
reddito, FrancoAngeli, Milano.
Goode R. (1976), The Individual Income Tax, rev. ed. Washington, Brookings In‐
stitution.
Groves H. M. (1948), Trouble Spots in Taxation, Princeton, Princeton University
Press.
Hicks J. (1981), "The Concept on Income in Relation to Taxation and to Business
Management", in Roskamp K., Forte F. (eds.), Reforms of Tax Systems, Detroit,
Wayne University.
Keynes J. M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,
London, Macmillan.
Longobardi E., Pedone A. (1994), "La politica tributaria", in Pizzuti F. R., L'economia
italiana dagli anni Settanta agli anni Novanta, Milano, McGraw‐Hill, pp.487‐
504.
Longobardi E. (2009), Economia tributaria, II ed., Milano, McGraw‐Hill.
26
Lupi R. (2007), Diritto tributario. La determinazione giuridica della capacità
economica, Milano, Giuffrè.
Meade J. E. (1978), The Structure and Reform of Direct Taxation, London, Allen and
Unwin.
Messere K. (1993), Tax Policy in Oecd Countries. Choices and Conflicts, Amsterdam,
Ibfd Publications.
Morag A. (1957), "Some Economic Aspects of Two Administrative Methods of
Estimating Taxable Income", National Tax Journal, vol. X, pp.176‐185.
Pechman J. A. (1990), "The Future of the Income Tax", American Economic Review,
March.
Pedone A. (1969), "The Ricardian Tax Incidence Analysis in the Light of Optimum
Growth Theory", Economia Internazionale, vol. XXII, n. 1.
Pedone A. (1981), "Payroll Taxes, Value Added Taxes and Income Taxes", in
Roskamps K. W., Forte F. (eds.), Reforms of Tax Systems, Detroit, Wayne State
University.
Pedone A. (1984), "I problemi di gestione di un'imposta personale progressiva sul
reddito estesa ad un elevato numero di contribuenti", in Gerelli E., Valiani R. (a
cura di), La crisi dell'imposizione progressiva sul reddito, FrancoAngeli, Milano.
Pedone A. (2006), "Su alcuni problemi ricorrenti della politica tributaria italiana",
Economia Italiana, n. 3; English version in Review of Economic Conditions in
Italy, 2006, n. 3, pp. 315‐343.
Rey G. M. (a cura di) (2008), Le problematiche di tipo giuridico ed economico inerenti
alla materia degli studi di settore, Roma, Scuola Superiore di Economia e
Finanza.
Ricotti G, Sanelli A. (2006), "Conti finanziari e fiscalita: un'analisi storica", in Banca
d'ltalia, I conti finanziari: la storia, i metodi, I'ltalia, i confronti internazionali,
Roma, Banca d'ltalia.
27
Roberti P. (ed.) (1998), Financial Markets and Capital Income Taxation in a Global
Economy, Amsterdam, North‐Holland.
Santoro A. (2007), Taxpayers Choices Under "Studi di Settore": What Do We Know
and how We Can Interpret It, Mimeo.
Simons H. C. (1938), Personal Income Taxation. The Definition of Income as a
Problem of Fiscal Policy, Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Simons H. C. (1950), Federal Tax Reform, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.
Slemrod J. (ed.) (1999), Tax Policy in the Real World, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
S0rensen P. B. (2007), Can Capital Income Taxes Survive? And Should They?, CESifo
Economic Studies, 53.
Steinmo S. (1993), Taxation and Democracy, New Haven‐London, Yale University
Press.
Steve S. (1984), "Conclusioni", in Gerelli E., Valiani R. (a cura di), La crisi
dell'imposizione progressiva sul reddito, FrancoAngeli, Milano.
Tanzi V. (1995), Taxation in an Integrating World, Washington, The Brookings
Institutions.
Tanzi V, Schuknecht L. (2000), Public Spending in the 20th Century. A Global
Perspective, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Tremonti G, Vitaletti G. (1991), La fiera delle tasse, Bologna, il Mulino.
Visco V. (1979), "Politica economica ed evasione fiscale", in Andriani S., Violante L.,
Le evasioni fiscali, De Donato, Bari.
Visentini B. (1993), "La babele del fisco", La Repubblica, 13 giugno.
Vitaletti G (1984), "La struttura e la dinamica dell'imposizione diretta", in Gerelli E.,
Majocchi A. (a cura di), Il deficit pubblico: origini e problemi, FrancoAngeli,
Milano.
28