Duration - Convexity and Immunization
Duration - Convexity and Immunization
w t = [CF t ( 1 + y ) ] Price
t
T
D = t w t
t =1
𝐷 ∗ = 𝐷 × 1ൗ 1 + 𝑦
Duration and Modified Duration
Duration and Modified Duration
Duration and Modified Duration
Issue Date 01-03-2024
Start Date 03-03-2024
End Date 01-03-2034
Coupon 0.0825
Interest Rate 0.0775
Coupon pmt frequency 1
Price 105
Duration
Yield
Convexity
Modify the pricing equation:
DP
= - D D y + 1 Convexity ( D y ) 2
P 2
Convexity is Equal to:
CF t
( + t )
N
1
2
t
P (1 + y) (1 + y )
2 t
t =1
Where: CFt is the cash flow (interest and/or
principal) at time t.
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Price Convexity
Bond Pricing with Convexity
Using PDEs similar to Balck Scholes we can work out no-arbitrage risk-
neutral pricing for the bonds such that it considers their convexity
Assumptions:
1. There is a short and a long default-free discount bond with maturities T
s
and T, respectively and both bonds are liquid and can be traded
without any transaction costs.
2. The two bond prices depend on the same risk factor denoted by r . This
t
Since the position in Long Bond resembles an option position we can use
the concept of delta hedging to hedge the downside risk of the portfolio.
{Long maturity T bond, Borrow B(t, T) funds and Short delta units of maturity S Bond}
Bond Pricing with Convexity
Bond Pricing with Convexity
Bond Pricing with Convexity
The change in the value of this portfolio due to a small change in the spot rate Δrt
only is given by
Bond`s Partial Differential Equations
𝑟𝑡 = 𝜇 + 𝜎𝑤𝑡
ⅆ𝑟𝑡 = 𝜇 ⅆ𝑡 + 𝜎 ⅆ𝑤𝑡
ⅆ𝑟𝑡 = 𝜇𝑟𝑡 ⅆ𝑡 + 𝜎𝑟𝑡 ⅆ𝑤𝑡
ⅆ𝑟𝑡 = 𝜆(𝜇 − 𝑟𝑡 ) ⅆ𝑡 + 𝜎𝑟𝑡 ⅆ𝑤𝑡
ITO`s Lemma
1
ⅆ𝑓(𝑟𝑡 ) = 𝑓𝑟 ⅆ𝑟𝑡 + 𝑓𝑟𝑟 𝜎 2 𝑟𝑡2 ∆
2
Bond`s Partial Differential Equations
Convexity gains for a small Δ
1 𝜕 2 𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇) 2𝑟2∆
2 𝜎(𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡) 𝑡
2 𝜕𝑟𝑡
Where 𝜎(𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡) is a % short rate volatility
The risk-neutral dynamics says
𝑟𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)∆
The change in Bond`s value with time will be
𝜕𝐵(𝑡, 𝑇)
∆ = 𝐵𝑡 ∆
𝜕𝑡
The last component will be due to the impact of drift in 𝑟𝑡 on the underlying
𝜇(𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡) 𝐵𝑟 ∆
Bond`s Partial Differential Equations
Therefore, the total gains/losses will be
1
𝐵𝑟𝑟 𝜎 2 𝑟𝑡2 ∆ − 𝑟𝐵 𝑡, 𝑇 ∆ + 𝐵𝑡 ∆ + 𝜇(𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡) 𝐵𝑟 ∆
2
This term should be equal to 0 to ensure no-arbitrage
1
𝐵𝑟𝑟 𝜎 2 𝑟𝑡2 ∆ − 𝑟𝐵 𝑡, 𝑇 ∆ + 𝐵𝑡 ∆ + 𝜇 𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡 𝐵𝑟 ∆ = 0
2
1
𝐵𝑟𝑟 𝜎 2 𝑟𝑡2 − 𝑟𝐵 + 𝐵𝑡 + 𝜇 𝑟𝑡 , 𝑡 𝐵𝑟 = 0
2
With the boundary condition as B(T,T) = 1
Bond Pricing with Convexity (Vasicek Model)
Where,
Where,
α = speed of reversion; Ϗ = Long Term Mean; rt = short rate; σ = volatility at time t
Sources of Convexity
Mark-to-Market
Bonds
• Contract prices are specified as a non-linear function of the
underlying risks.
Sources of Convexity
Swaps
𝑄
𝑉𝑡0 = 𝐸𝑡0
Sources of Convexity
Assuming flat and parallel shifting rate curve.
Sources of Convexity
Sources of Convexity
CBOT in the Mid-90s had to delist an IRS swap futures contract.
They made 2 mistakes while listing the swap futures
• Convexity of the contract was ignored and was priced as a linear
instrument
• It was based on the 3 and 5-year swaps whereas more popular ones
are 5 and 10-year swaps.
The primary reason for delisting and relisting is that it was observed that
such swap curves are frequently used for pricing other instruments.
Sources of Convexity
FRAs
Sources of Convexity