EU Climate Policy Failure
EU Climate Policy Failure
EU Climate Policy Failure
A C O S T LY FA I L U R E I N
UNILATERAL CLIMATE POLICY
John Constable
‘For they have sowen the winde, and they shall reape the whirlewinde:
it hath no stalke: the budde shall yeeld no meale:
if so be it yeeld, strangers shall swallow it up.‘
Hosea, Chapter 8: verse 7
iii
iv
Contents
Summary iv
1. Introduction 1
2. The Emissions Trading Scheme 4
3. Growth in renewable energy 9
4. Conventional electricity generation 15
5. Renewable heat and cooling 19
6. Renewable transport fuel 21
7. Total renewable energy progress 22
8. Costs and benefits 23
9. Energy efficiency 25
10. Energy prices in the EU 28
11. Energy production, consumption and productivity 31
12. Emissions in the EU 34
13. Green jobs and other jobs 37
14. Has the EU learned from its experiment? 45
15. The energy transition illusion and the future of European prosperity 54
16. Conclusion 72
About the author 73
Notes 74
Review process 78
About the Global Warming Policy Foundation 78
v
Summary
Since 1990, the European Union has pursued a rapid decarbonisation strategy, at first based largely
on emissions trading but increasingly reliant on thermodynamically incompetent renewable en-
ergy. The results have been to increase energy costs, suppress energy demand, and prevent recov-
ery after exogenous shocks such as the financial crisis of 2008 and the global pandemic of 2020.
Energy consumption, particularly electricity consumption, has been falling steadily in the EU since
about 2005, and it is reasonable to infer that these societies are regressing towards thermodynam-
ic equilibrium, with the effects temporarily buffered by fossil-fuel manufactured goods from Asia.
A selection of key findings follows.
Energy consumption
• Up to 2005, final energy consumption in the EU followed a rising trend, but has been falling
since, and is now at levels not seen since the early 1990s. Such a deep and sustained decline in
energy consumption is unprecedented in the modern era.
vi
• Electricity consumption, a strong indicator of a societal complexity and development, followed
a rising trend up to 2008, but has been falling since and is now at levels last seen in the early
2000s. This is also unprecedented.
• In the United Kingdom, electricity consumption has fallen back to levels not seen since 1970.
• Energy efficiency cannot in principle result in the observed reduction in energy and electricity
use, and the likeliest cause is price rationing and demand destruction.
vii
List of figures
1. Emissions in sectors covered by the EU ETS, 2005–20. 4
2. EU ETS emissions cap reduction, 2005–30. 5
3. EU ETS costs (general and aviation) 2013–21, by member country. 7
4. Clearing prices for auctions of general allowances, January 2013 to 30 June 2021. 8
5. EU ETS allowances, surplus of allowances and auction prices, 2005–20. 8
6. Total subsidies by energy carrier in the EU27 excluding tax expenditures, 2008–2018. 9
7. Subsidies to biomass, solar, and onshore and offshore wind in the EU27. 10
8. Total tax expenditures by energy carrier in the EU27, 2008–18. 10
9. Subsidies to renewables in the major economies, 2008–18. 11
10. All renewable electricity generation capacity: EU28 1990–2020. 11
11. Wind power capacity: selected EU states 1990–2020. 12
12. Solar power capacity: selected EU states 1990–2020. 12
13. Renewable electricity generation capacity in selected countries, 2012–21. 13
14. Renewable electricity generation in the EU28, by country: 2004–20. 13
15. Electricity generation in the EU28 by fuel type, 1990–2020 13
16. Total electricity generation capacity in the EU28, 1990–2020 by member state. 15
17. EU28 electricity generation fleet load factor 1990–2020. 16
18. Nuclear electricity generation capacity in the EU28, 1990–2020. 17
19. Combustion fuel electricity generation capacity in the EU28, 1990–2020. 17
20. Renewable energy for heating and cooling in the EU27, 2011–2020. 20
21. Renewable energy used for heating and cooling. 20
22. Renewable transport fuel in the EU27, 2011–20. 21
23. Renewable use in transport in Europe, 2005 and 2020. 22
24. Historical trends and sources on renewable energy shares. 23
25. EU abatement costs and the social cost of carbon. 24
26. Subsidies for energy efficiency in the EU27, 2008–18, by support type. 26
27. Electricity prices in the EU and the G20, 2008–19. 28
28. Natural gas prices in the EU and the G20, 2008–19. 29
29. Transport fuel costs in the EU and the G20, 2008–19. 29
30. EU27 primary energy, 1990–2020. 31
31. EU27 final energy consumption 1990–2020. 31
32. EU27 energy flows. 33
33. Energy productivity of wealth in the EU27, and selected countries, 2000–2020. 34
34. Historical trends and projections of net greenhouse gas emissions, 1990–2050. 35
35. Carbon intensity of industrial energy consumption in the EU28 1990–2019. 36
36. Carbon intensity of energy consumption for transport in the EU28, 1990–2019. 37
37. Photovoltaic module production by region 1990–2020. 38
38. Global annual photovoltaic module production by region 2010–20. 38
39. Employment in the European solar industry. 39
40. Global employment in renewables, by sector. 39
41. Employment in renewables by country and sector. 40
42. Renewable energy sector employment in selected countries, 2012–20. 40
43. Employment in renewables, Germany, the rest of the EU, and China, 2012–20. 41
44. Renewable energy capacity, Germany and the Rest of the World, 2012–21. 41
45. EU trade balance 2011–21. 42
viii
46. EU imports from and exports to China, 2011–21. 42
47. EU trade balance with China, 2011–21. 42
48. Extra-EU trade balance 2016, 2020, and 2021, by commodity type. 43
49. Extra-EU trade balance by EU member dtate, 2021. 44
50. EU27 extra-EU exports and imports by member state. 44
51. The core of the Trans-European Transport Network. 46
52. Energy targets for the EU27. 50
53. World total primary energy: 1800–2015. 58
54. World total primary energy supply: 1971–2019. 59
55. Total primary energy in the People’s Republic of China 1990–19. 60
56. Electrical energy generation fuel mix in China, 1990–2016. 60
57. EU28 total primary energy, 1990–2019. 61
58. Electricity fuel mix in the United Kingdom 2009–21. 62
59. UK electricity supplied 1920–2020. 62
60. UK energy flows 1995 (mtoe). 64
61. US primary energy: 1949–2020. 65
List of tables
1. Indirect carbon cost compensation paid out by EU member states in 2020. 6
2. Estimated abatement costs per tonne of carbon dioxide in the United Kingdom. 25
3. Proved fossil fuel reserves in Europe. 69
4. European coal as at 2012. 70
5. Wet natural gas production in Europe, and resource estimates 71
ix
x
1. Introduction
The European Union prides itself on being the global leader in at-
tempts to mitigate climate change through policies aimed at reduc-
ing the emissions of greenhouse gases. The ambition to take on this
role emerged during the later 1990s, coinciding, significantly, with
the reunification of Germany. It rapidly became prominent and, by
the early part of the new millennium, climate change mitigation had
already achieved dominance in the economic policy of the EU and its
member states. This trend has continued, and today it is no exaggera-
tion to say that climate mitigation exercises a controlling interest in
every aspect of the EU’s strategy and tactics. The depth to which the
abstract goal of emissions reduction and the particular methods, no-
tably renewable energy, are entrenched can be gauged from the fact
that four years after voting to leave the EU, and two years after actu-
ally leaving, the United Kingdom is still following the path outlined by
the Commission.
It is doubtful whether the supervenience of climate policy in EU
thinking will survive the current geopolitical crisis. This is not because
Europe’s unilateralism has been caught out by the recent resurgence
of national conflict – geopolitical strife has never been far away, and
indeed has been growing – but rather that the war in Ukraine has
brought the failures of the EU’s climate policies into sharper focus,
and sooner than might have been expected. But this does not mean
that the harm of the policies is itself of recent origin. On the contrary,
the environmental policies have been damaging to the EU’s interests
and advantageous to those of its rivals from the very beginning. As
this study will demonstrate, the enthusiastic adoption of the green
agenda in the 1990s and early 2000s has effectively produced grad-
ual industrial and economic disarmament. That makes the error all
the more extraordinary, but it also indicates that the EU must now
deal, not just with short-run damage of recent origin, but also with
the harms accumulated over two decades and its resultant enfeeble-
ment relative to Europe’s competitors. Arresting the decline will be
difficult; recovering the situation entirely may be impossible.
What was the EU Commission thinking of when they blundered
into these disastrous errors? In general, the EU’s climate policies are
an attempt, through policy, to internalise the externalities of energy
consumption, thus creating an incentive to reduce greenhouse gas
emissions and pollutants. It was hoped that this would encourage the
rest of the world to do likewise, while also – and this was not entirely
consistent – giving the EU’s member states, and Germany in particu-
lar, a commanding and unassailable lead in the emerging markets of
the new green economy. Europe had lost its global dominance in the
world of coal and oil and gas; it would recover it through wind and
solar and the suppression of fossil fuels in an historic energy transi-
tion, which after 2011 came to be known by its German title, the en-
ergiewende.
These policies were built on a long-standing interest in renewa-
ble energy flows, stretching back into the 1930s but first prominent in
response to the oil shocks of the 1970s. After 1990, this interest crys-
1
tallised as demanding targets for levels of renewable energy in final
energy consumption, starting in earnest in 2009, and the Emissions
Trading Scheme, which began in 2005. These policy instruments were
supported by a concerted and extensive program of public commu-
nications and supplementary environmental regulation, such as the
Large Combustion Plant Directive of 2001, and its successor the In-
dustrial Emissions Directive of 2016, both intended to address indus-
trial release of harmful substances.
This general environmental effort has been tremendous, but the
results are still poorly understood by the public upon whom the ex-
periment has been performed. A host of pertinent questions hang in
the air unanswered:
• Have the EU member states reduced their emissions?
• Have they reduced them in a cost-effective manner?
• Are the policies setting an economically compelling example to
other countries?
• Has a self-supporting and internationally competitive green econ-
omy emerged in Europe?
• Is Europe a leading developer of low carbon technologies?
• How much has the green experiment cost?
• Have there been any unintended consequences?
• Can it continue?
• What has been learned?
An onlooker, from the United States perhaps, might note that
governmental enthusiasm for the green policies continues, and if an-
ything has grown over the thirty years since 1990. They might assume,
quite reasonably, that the EU would only forge ahead in this way if the
policies were working. But this assumption would be mistaken. Gov-
ernments persist in their folly not only because they are too close to
their own failures to bring them into focus, but sometimes because
persistence is the most effective means by which failure can be con-
cealed. There are none so blind as those that will not see.
However, for those that wish to confront the matter without prej-
udice, there is no shortage of data, and the questions sketched above
can be addressed with sufficient accuracy to permit conclusive an-
swers. This study attempts – on the basis of information published by
the renewables industry, by the EU’s own data resource, Eurostat, and
by the Commission itself – to distil an intelligible description of the
main policy instruments, their costs, and their consequences. Its con-
clusions can be briefly stated as follows. The climate policies adopted
by the European Union have:
• degraded the productivity of the energy sector, particularly the
electricity sector;
• increased the cost of energy, particularly electricity, through the
coerced adoption of thermodynamically incompetent renewables;
• created a strong price-rationing effect that has suppressed energy
demand, particularly electricity, within the EU’s member states;
2
• made the European region more dependent on goods and ser-
vices – including renewable energy generation equipment – from
without the EU, principally fossil-fuelled Asia and China;
• produced the longest sustained fall in energy consumption in the
modern period, perhaps the longest since the late Middle Ages;
the onset of societal instability cannot be ruled out.
Distressed policy correction is inevitable, but the timing is uncertain.
The harmful outcomes sketched above have, to some degree,
been offset by the adoption of more efficient end-user energy con-
version devices, improvements that would in other circumstances
have delivered positive substantial increases in societal complexity
and welfare, but in the EU have only prevented a precipitate decline.
One might say that, alongside the illusion of intrinsic prosperity cre-
ated by the import of goods from Asia, energy-efficiency measures
have anaesthetised the public to the economic damage of the last
thirty years.
Of course, it is undeniable that in terms of its principal goal the
EU’s policy has been successful. Emissions of greenhouse gases have
been reduced significantly in nearly all sectors. However, the abate-
ment cost exceeds even higher estimates of the social cost of carbon,
indicating that the environmental policies are causing more harm to
European welfare than is the climate change that they aim to prevent.
The cure is worse than the disease.
Even if the EU and its member states were to acknowledge their
error today, it is unclear whether they could recover gracefully and
without considerable societal distress. The malinvestment in renew-
able energy is on a very large scale; writing it off and rebuilding the
energy sector on thermodynamically sound lines will require sacri-
fices in household income for extended periods. However, there is as
yet no sign that the Commission is conscious of the structural harm
that it has inflicted on member states, and, in the New Green Deal put
forward in 2021, it is now proposing to proceed still further along the
same policy track.
A change in course is inevitable and will be forced on member
states sooner or later, but the deeply embedded harm of nearly thirty
years of error means even a prudent policy correction towards fun-
damentally cheaper energy will require substantial reductions in Eu-
ropean living standards. Failing to undertake this correction as soon
as possible will result in still deeper damage and even more costly
remedial action. Explaining this to the European people will form the
greatest political challenge of the next fifty years.
3
2. The Emissions Trading Scheme
The EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) began in 2005. It is no-
tionally the bloc’s principal emissions reduction mechanism and
its most powerful attempt to internalise the externalities of en-
ergy consumption. In practice, as we shall see, it has been over-
taken and marginalised by renewable energy policies, although
the ETS remains extremely and increasingly expensive.
The ETS is a cap-and-trade mechanism, covering electricity
generation, heat, and energy-intensive industry. The cap guaran-
tees the emissions reduction, while trading of allowances is in-
tended to ensure that reductions can be achieved in the lowest-
cost sectors first.
The EU proudly reports that emissions in the sectors covered
have fallen by 43% since its introduction and that the scheme is
a key contributor to the fact that EU emissions in 2020 are some
31% below 1990 levels, exceeding targets (Figure 1).1
Aviation 0.5
Estimate to reflect current scope
All industrial installations
0
Combustion of fuels 2005 2010 2015 2020
GtCO2e
2020/1722.’
Emissions 1.5
1.0
0.5
0
2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030
Table 1: Indirect carbon cost Member state Compensation Auction revenues* Percent
compensation paid out by (€m) (€m)
EU member states in 2020.
Germany 546 3146 17
Belgium (FL) 89
354 31
Belgium (WL) 20
Netherlands 110 436 25
Greece 42 503 8
Latvia 1 84 1
Sweden 4 244 2
France 266 712 37
Finland 75 217 34
Spain 61 1225 5
Lithuania 11 17 63
Poland 77 2546 3
Romania – 748 NA
Total 1302 10232 12
*2019, excluding aviation allowances. Source: EU Commission, COM(2021) 962 final.
6
The macro-economic effects of the costs of the ETS can be
assessed from the total cost of auctioned allowances, figures that
are readily available but not widely known outside expert circles.
Figure 3 is based on data published in a Commission working
document that was published alongside a report (COM(2021)
962 final) from the Commission to the European Parliament and
the Council.7
Other Spain
UK Greece
Romania Denmark
€m
Poland Germany 10
Netherlands Czechia
Italy Bulgaria
France
€/tonneCO2
20
0
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
€/tCO2e
GtCO2e
Cumulative surplus
Supply of allowances
Verified emissions 1 10
Price
by100energy carrier in
the80 EU27 excluding tax 100
expenditures, 2008–2018.
All energies
60
Source: Trinomics 2020,59 further
Fossil fuels
40
120
the author.
Electricity
Renewables
20
Fossil fuels 60
100
Renewables
0
80
All energies
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018
Nuclear
Electricity 40
All energies
60
Nuclear
40
20
Electricity
20
0
0
2008
2008 2009 2010 2010
2011 2012 2012
20132014 2015 20142017
2016 2018 2016 2018
Nuclear
9
mously over this period. Subsidies to nuclear, unlabelled in the
chart for reasons of space, are about €3 billion a year or less and
are mainly given for decommissioning purposes. Non-tax ex-
penditure, direct subsidy to fossil fuels is in large part accounted
for by measures such as price support to fossil-fuelled combined
heat and power, which amounted to €8.6 billion in 2008 and still
stood at €5.4 billion in 2018. Such measures are part of the at-
tempt to improve efficiency and reduce emissions. Thus, and per-
haps bizarrely, these subsidies to fossil fuels can be regarded as a
climate-policy cost. However, this study does not approach them
in this way.
The major recipients of subsidy in the EU27 have been bi-
omass, solar, and onshore and offshore wind, as represented in
Figure 7.
Figure 7: Subsidies to 70
biomass, solar, and 60
onshore and offshore
wind in the EU27. 50
Source: Trinomics 2020, Chart
60
Offshore wind 30
(€2018bn)
Onshore wind
Solar 20
Biomass
10
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
40
Fossil fuels 30
Renewables
All energies
Electricity 20
Nuclear
10
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
10
Needless to say, the volumes of tax expenditure to fossil fu-
els are large because the volumes of fossil fuels consumed in the
EU economies are themselves large.
Having distinguished between tax expenditures and direct
subsidies, we can now return to the data summarised in Figure 6
and estimate the total non-tax expenditure subsidy to the renew-
able sector. In the EU27 (excluding the UK, where subsidy costs
now total about £10 billion a year) in the period 2008–18 this
amounts to about €570 billion, a figure that will have been rising
at the rate of approximately €69 billion a year to the present,10
giving an approximate total to date at the end of 2021 of about
€770 billion.
The EU’s commitment of subsidies to the renewable energy
sector is nearly 70% of the total across major economies, as can
be seen in Figure 9, which compares annual subsidies (including
tax expenditures) in the EU27, Japan, the UK, the US, and China.
Over the period covered in this figure, total subsidies to renew-
ables, including tax expenditures, amounted to €893 billion, of
which the EU was responsible for €612 billion.
Figure 9: Subsidies to 140
renewables in the major 120
economies, 2008–18.
Including tax expenditures. Source: 100
Trinomics 2020,62 chart redrawn by
the author. 80
(€2018bn)
China 60
USA
UK 40
Japan
EU27 20
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
pumped storage.
80
Solid biofuels 60
Solar 200
40
Wind
Hydro 20
Sweden 80
Italy
France
UK 40
Spain
Germany
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
Figure 12: Solar power
capacity: selected EU 120
states 1990–2020.
Source: Eurostat; UK Government.
GW
000 Belgium 80
000 Netherlands
000
France
Spain
000 UK 40
000 Italy
000
Germany
000 0
000
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
000
0
Support for wind began earlier, stimulating rapid growth in ca-
pacity, but solar energy is closing the gap, reflecting the generosity
Germany Spain United Kingdom France Italy Sweden Netherlands of subsidies and its relative ease of development; wind energy pro-
Denmark
GW
Energy Agency 2022,63 further 2000
calculations and chart by the
author. 1500
Rest of the world 1000
Brazil
India
USA 500
EU
China 0
2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
Finland
Romania 600
Portugal
Poland 400
Austria
Netherlands
Italy 200
France
Spain 0
Germany 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2000
Other
Wind
Solar PV
Hydro
Waste 1000
Biofuels
Nuclear
Natural gas
Oil 0
Coal
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
only to about 1200 TWh, with the bulk of the contributions coming
from Germany, Spain, France, Italy, the UK and Sweden, countries
where subsidies have been applied most vigorously (see Figure 14).
This increase needs, however, to be seen in the context of all
electricity generation by fuel type, as charted in Figure 15. While
the expansion of the renewable sources is large and rapid after
13
2005, we must observe that, in spite of the very large subsidy
expenditures discussed above, renewables still provide only a
minority of the electricity required by the EU’s member states.
Indeed, although fossil fuels have been displaced to some de-
gree, with oil now almost unused, much of the bloc’s electrical
energy is still supplied by coal, and a very large part now comes
from gas. Moreover, it is probable that gas, not renewables, is re-
sponsible for the displacement of coal; indeed, it is arguable that
a more economically efficient displacement of coal might have
been achieved through spontaneous market decisions under the
ETS, or even through simple laissez-faire.
The contribution from nuclear was more or less stable un-
til the early 2000s, with few new plants commissioned dur-
ing the period. However, installed capacity has been declining
since 2002, when the EU28 had 138.5 GW, as compared to about
114 GW today; as a consequence, output is declining too.
A similar story can be told for coal, oil, and natural gas, which
have seen a fall in output, partly due to coercive market-share
allocation to renewables, and partly due to falling demand. Com-
bustion-fuelled generation capacity has fallen sharply in the
EU28 since 2012, the result of environmental regulations and a
constricted market opportunity. Capacity stood at about 375 GW
in 2020, down from a peak of 448 GW in 2012.
A substantial part of the renewables input is derived from
hydropower, a mature technology for which the environmentally
tolerable opportunities in the EU are largely exploited. Modern
renewables – wind and solar – make up 20% of supply, arguably
a poor return for such overwhelming market distortions.
But, and this point cannot be overstated, the principal char-
acteristic that stands out from charts such as this is the stagna-
tion and decline in electrical energy use in the EU28 since the
middle 2000s. Consumption in the bloc now stands at just over
3000 TWh, a level last seen in the year 2000. Since the peak in
2007, consumption of electricity has fallen by just over 9%. The
sharp dip in generation from 2008 to 2009 can confidently be at-
tributed to the financial crash, while the rise in demand in 2010
is the result of the economic recovery consequent on regional
and global stimulus packages. But other explanations must be
sought for the sustained decline after 2010, which is a depar-
ture from the weak but obvious rising trend evident from 1990
to 2007. It is reasonable to infer that the sharply rising renewa-
bles input and the subsidy costs required to drive it have had a
significant braking effect on the post-crash recovery, resulting in
faltering demand for electrical energy. Given the superior, low-
entropy characteristics of electricity as an energy carrier and an
index of societal complexity and sophistication, this decline must
be regarded as extremely unwelcome and deeply concerning. A
society in which electricity consumption is falling is almost cer-
tainly regressing towards thermodynamic equilibrium, with soci-
etal entropy rising across the board, implying a decline in stand-
ards of living and a rise in underlying systemic fragility.
14
4. Conventional electricity generation
Electricity generation productivity in the EU
We have reviewed renewable generation capacity increases in
the EU28 and seen highly significant rises in all technologies, no-
tably wind and solar. The widespread deployment of renewables
accounts for the overall increase in the bloc's total generation ca-
pacity, which has nearly doubled, from just over 500 GW in 1990
to just under 1000 GW in 2020. Figure 16 charts this remarka-
ble increase, which can be seen in the national fleets of nearly
all member states, but with especial prominence in Germany,
Spain, and Italy, all countries where renewable development has
proceeded at scale. France, which has only recently begun to
force renewable technologies into its electricity system, instead
relying on its substantial nuclear plant fleet, does not exhibit the
same trend.
Romania 400
Greece
Portugal Germany
Poland Denmark
Austria Czechia
Netherlands Belgium 200
0
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
Percent
Agency data.
20
0
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
80
Romania
Hungary
Lithuania
city (Combustion
France fuels)
Spain
Germany 40
Czechia
Bulgaria
Belgium
500,000
0
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
0
Figure 19: Combustion fuel 500
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
electricity generation
Belgium in the EU28,
capacity Czechia Denmark Germany Ireland
1990–2020.
Greece Spain France 400 Italy Lithuania
Source: Eurostat, Digest
Hungary of United
Netherlands Austria Poland Portugal
Kingdom Energy Statistics. Chart by
theRomania
author. Finland Sweden United Kingdom Others
300
Others Lithuania
UK Italy
GW
Sweden France
Finland Spain
Romania Greece 200
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
Portugal Ireland
Poland Germany
Germany
Austria Ireland Denmark
Italy Netherlands
LithuaniaCzechia 100
Hungary Belgium
Poland Portugal
United Kingdom Others
Electricity Generation Capacity (Combustion fuels)
00,000 0
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
0
17
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
was the result of the Large Combustion Plant Directive of 2001
(LCPD)14 and its successor, the 2016 Industrial Emissions Direc-
tive (IED).15 These directives are not part of the climate package,
but were intended to reduce the release of pollutants, particu-
larly acidifying pollutants, particulate matter, and precursors to
ozone. As the EU itself puts it:
Control of emissions from large combustion plants - those whose
rated thermal input is equal to or greater than 50 MW – plays an
important role in the Union’s efforts to combat acidification, eu-
trophication and ground-level ozone as part of the overall strategy
to reduce air pollution.16
These may have been laudable goals, but in practice they
have had damaging consequences. The LCPD limited the opera-
tion of older combustion plants unless they fitted costly equip-
ment such as flue gas desulphurisation (to reduce the release of
sulphur dioxide), selective catalytic reduction (to limit release of
oxides of nitrogen), and measures to reduce the release of fine
dust particles. Those plants that chose not to fit such equipment
opted out of the scheme and were forced to close after a further
20,000 operational hours, or by 2015 at the latest. Some mem-
ber states, such as the United Kingdom, whose coal stations were
older, had high opt-out rates, and saw quite sharp declines in
combustion-fuelled electricity generation capacity, but nearly all
EU fleets were affected to some degree, as Figure 19 shows.
The IED applies to industrial operations in general, including
electricity generation plant, and requires the use of ‘best avail-
able technologies’ to reduce the release of pollutants. The criteria
are so strict and the costs of compliance so high that investment
in new power plant has, in effect, been discouraged, and many
existing installations have applied for exemption on the grounds
that modifications required do not pass a cost-benefit analysis.
The combined effect of the LCPD and the IED, together with
the market distortions favouring renewables, can clearly be seen
in Figure 19. The EU’s fleet of combustion-based electricity gen-
erating plant has fallen from a peak of about 450 GW in 2012 to
about 375 GW in 2020, a 17% decline in less than a decade. Were
the renewables fleet dispatchable and contributing significantly
to securing supply, the erosion of thermal capacity might be a
matter of little concern, but wind and solar are inflexible and only
controllable to a limited degree, and cannot promise with any
high degree of confidence to meet demand. Consequently, the
rapid decline in thermal capacity, just as wind and solar capac-
ity reached very high levels, is a powerful indicator that the EU’s
electricity system is becoming fragile. Interruptions in supply are
not yet at levels high or widespread enough to cause public anxi-
ety, although the United Kingdom did experience a serious na-
tionwide blackout on 9 August 2019, when a lightning strike on
a transmission cable caused a voltage disturbance that resulted
in quantities of generation with inadequate fault ride through
characteristics, including one large wind farm, to disconnect.17
18
The Electricity System Operator, National Grid, was compelled
to disconnect 5% of load – about 1 million customers, including
railway networks and airports – in order to protect the remainder
of the system. Debate around the proximal causes of the event
is largely beside the point. The general and distal cause of the
blackout is system fragility. Lightning strikes on transmission ca-
bles are not uncommon, and a robust system should be able to
manage such events without consumer disconnection. In this
case it could not.
But the UK blackout was an exceptional event. For the most
part, electricity systems are revealing their fragility and the prob-
lems caused by declines in dispatchable capacity through in-
creased balancing costs. Again, the UK provides good evidence.
In the early part of the 2000s, annual balancing costs were un-
der £500 million, and they were still at this level in 2015. By 2020
they had risen to £1.3 billion,18 a trend that has continued, with
the costs in the last year, April 2021 to 2022 amounting to £2.2
billion in the Balancing Mechanism.19 Not all of this increase can
be attributed to the presence of renewables, but much of it can
be. It would be in the public interest if there were an economet-
ric study of balancing and transmission costs in the European re-
gion over the last twenty years; it could determine how much
more expensive this essential ancillary service has become as a
result of the coerced introduction of renewables and the decline
in flexible thermal plant.
Others 80
Sweden
Finland
Romania
mtoe
Portugal 60
Poland
Austria
Hungary
Italy
France 40
Spain
Germany
Denmark
Czechia 20
0
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
20
6. Renewable transport fuel
Transport fuels are the only area in EU energy and climate pol-
icy where there is a specific and mandatory share of sectoral
consumption imposed on member states. The 2009 Renewable
Energy Directive (RED; 2009/28/EC) mandated that 10% of en-
ergy used in this sector should be from renewables, but allowed
member states to make their own decisions elsewhere. The man-
datory transport percentage proved to be very difficult, and not
all member states were successful in meeting the target. Howev-
er, at the overall EU level, 10% of transport fuel was derived from
renewable sources in 2020. Growth in the sector can be seen in
Figure 22.
Others Hungary
Sweden Italy
Finland France 10
Romania Spain
Portugal Germany
Poland Czechia
Austria Belgium
Netherlands 0
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Portugal
Spain
UK
9. Energy efficiency
Energy efficiency measures have been central to the EU’s climate
policies since the introduction of regulations in 2006, but they
have become progressively more prominent, and figure very
large in the new European Green Deal (see Figure 52 and adja-
cent discussion below).
The Energy Efficiency Directive approved by the European
Parliament on 11 September 2012 set out targets for energy ef-
ficiency. It aimed to reduce EU primary energy consumption in
2020 by 20% to no more than 1,474 mtoe at the primary energy
level, or no more than 1,078 mtoe at the final energy consump-
tion level. The target was revised on the accession of Croatia to
the EU in 2013, and now specifies 1,483 mtoe of primary energy
or no more than 1,086 mtoe of final energy.
Considerable quantities of public funds have been directed
towards encouraging energy efficiency. Figure 26 charts subsi-
dies for energy efficiency in the EU27 from 2008 until 2018, ana-
lysed by support type.
For 2008 to 2018, the total committed amounts to about
€120 billion. As can be seen, tax expenditures are the single larg-
est type of support, amounting to €5.3 billion in 2018, or about
36% of the total in that year. Tax expenditures in this case seem
25
Figure 26: Subsidies for 16
energy efficiency in the EU27, 14
2008–18, by support type.
12
Source: Redrawn from Trinomics
2020.68 10
(€2018bn)
Energy efficiency obligations 8
Soft loans
6
Grants
Tax credits 4
Tax allowances
2
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
entirely legitimate since they remove an artificial discourage-
ment and leave individuals and companies to decide whether
and how to make use of the opportunity. Grants, soft loans, and
energy-efficiency obligations, on the other hand, run the consid-
erable risk of prejudicing judgment and creating the conditions
for suboptimal decisions. Such potentially counterproductive
and counter-economic interventions represent the majority of
the EU's support for efficency measures – some €79 billion – in
the eleven years under consideration. Since there is no reason for
believing that households or businesses will neglect energy ef-
ficiency – it is, after all, cash on the table – the present author re-
gards this expenditure as either redundant or positively harmful.
However, the deepest problem with the Commission’s ap-
proach to energy efficiency lies in what was expected and prom-
ised from the widespread adoption of measures in this area. From
the outset – the 2006 Action Plan for Energy Efficiency27 – the
Commission has believed that improvements in energy efficien-
cy would deliver energy conservation and reduce consumption,
writing that ‘Europe continues to waste 20% of its energy due to
inefficiency’:
A paradigm shift is required to change the behavioural patterns of
our societies, so that we use less energy while enjoying the same
quality of life. Producers will have to be encouraged to develop
more energy-efficient technologies and products, and consumers
will need stronger incentives to buy such products and use them
rationally. (p. 3)
28
Figure 28: Natural gas 80
prices in the EU and
the G20, 2008–19.
Comparison of weighted average 60
natural gas prices in the EU27 with
weighted average prices in the G20
(€2018/MWh)
(trade).70
EU27 households 40
G20 households
EU27 industry
G20 industry
20
EU27 wholesale
G20 wholesale
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
though the latter have exhibited a falling trend since 2012, which
has to some degree closed the gap.
But once again, EU27 and G20 wholesale prices are similar
and closely correlated across the study period, indicating that
the differences in retail prices to consumers of all types result in
large part from EU policy.
0.2
0
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
29
Conclusion: energy prices in the EU27 and the G20
Combining these three price comparisons, we can see that ener-
gy and climate policies in the EU27 have put it at a marked disad-
vantage. High household prices for gas, electricity and transport
fuel will also have placed strong upward pressure on wage de-
mands, while high energy input costs for industry will have made
it extremely difficult for manufacturers, in particular, to remain
internationally competitive.
The Commission’s own study of these matters seeks con-
solation in the fact that, over the period 2008–17, energy costs
were typically only 1–10% of total operational costs (p. 14). But
reasoning of this kind is misleading. As already noted, high en-
ergy costs to households will have increased manufacturing op-
erational costs indirectly via wage demands, and this point can be
extended to all other input costs. Since all resources are improb-
able states of matter, the improbability being the result of energy
conversion at points in time both distant and close at hand, high
energy costs contribute to the cost of future non-energy inputs.
The EU’s high energy costs will therefore sooner or later be re-
sponsible for an increase in many non-energy input costs.
This may already be a concern, as suggested by the Com-
mission’s consultant’s note that while ‘energy costs increased in
absolute terms…total operating production costs increased at a
larger scale’, resulting in a falling energy cost share in total costs.
Unfortunately, the consultants fail to recognise that the rise in
total operating production costs will be the result of the delayed
pass-through of higher energy costs. But that pass-through is a
crucial consideration, and probably plays a very large part in lim-
iting the gross operating surplus of most manufacturing sectors
in the EU to a modest 5–10%, meaning that direct energy costs
are relatively large in comparison, and that further increases in
those energy costs place considerable short-run pressure on
profits. Overall, it is not surprising that, as the Commission’s au-
thors candidly report:
EU manufacturing sectors are on average less profitable than non-
EU G20 counterparts.33
mtoe 1500
1000
500
0
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
920
mtoe
880
840
800
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 2018
31
As with primary energy input, there is a rising trend up to
2005–06 and the onset of the 2008 crash, a short rally, then a
marked downturn, and substantial slump caused by coronavirus.
We cannot say with any confidence that the rising energy costs
resulting from European and global energy and climate policies
had a causal role in the 2008 crash, and it should be emphasised
that, given the then moderate level of cost impacts, it is unlikely.
But we know that costs were rising sharply after the crash, and
that prices to EU consumers were high relative to the G20. It is
likely that these prices have suppressed and impeded recovery,
and there is therefore good reason to fear that they will have the
same braking effect on the post-pandemic recovery.
Direct use
Total inputs
Total outputs
493
995
Final con-
sumption
1020
Imports
1773
1430
Energy
sector
1279
use
Other
Production
743
Exports
Transformation
275
Transformation
Other
343 losses
(b) 2020
975
sumption
633
1203
1203
Imports
1542
1804
Energy
sector
use
1171
Other
Production
575
575
Transformation
410
Exports
Other Transformation
262
losses
33
Energy productivity
The EU is keen to draw attention to what appears to be the rising
energy productivity of its aggregate economy and of individual
member states, pointing to data (see Figure 33) indicating that
the ratio of Euros per kg of oil equivalent has been rising since
2000.
UK 8
Italy
Germany 6
France
Spain 4
EU27
0
2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
Historic 3
Gt CO2e
Projected:
Existing policy measures
2
Additional policy measures
gCO2/MJ
20
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
gCO2/MJ
40
20
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
Percent
60
Rest of World 40
North America
Europe 20
Asia
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
The point at which Asian production came to dominate the
sector coincides with the increase in EU energy costs, particularly
for households, leading to the suspicion that much of the nega-
tive impact of the climate policies has been an indirect one, via
upward pressure on wages. In Germany, in fact, industries were
protected against direct impacts, since renewable subsidy costs
were disproportionately loaded onto domestic consumers.
It is also relevant that Asian dominance of the solar panel
markets coincided with the absence of a recovery in energy con-
sumption, and by implication a lack of fundamental economic
health, after the 2008 crisis. It was not simply that the climate
policies harmed European businesses, but that they prevented a
vigorous recovery after the crisis. The competition, mainly in Asia,
was able to benefit both from supplies of cheap energy and also
from rising demand in Europe, prompted by various economic
stimulus packages, including subsidies to renewables.
The absolute quantities of solar panels manufactured from
2010 onwards reveal a disastrous picture. While PV manufactur-
ing has grown slightly in Europe, growth in Asian output has
been overwhelming (see Figure 38).
It is clear that renewable energy equipment manufacturing
has no future in the EU, and indeed manufacturing of any kind
exposed to international competition will struggle to survive, ex-
cept in niche areas. The causes of this constriction were not the
result of technological disadvantage, although as China (and Asia
generally) bank their fossil-fuelled wealth as progressively great-
160
Figure 38: Global
annual photovoltaic
module production by 120
region 2010–20.
GWp
0
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
38
er societal sophistication, this is likely to become an increasingly
important factor. In the period with which we are concerned, the
EU's disadvantage is simply one of proximal input cost, notably
through household prices and the upward pressure on wages
exerted indirectly by its renewables policies. Circumstantial evi-
dence in favour of this interpretation is that the German PV in-
dustry, including installers and other non-manufacturing jobs,
has responded to its problems by aggressive improvements in
labour productivity, reducing its employee base from 60,000 in
2008 to 20,000 in 2016, a trend that was replicated throughout
the European solar industry (see Figure 39).
The all-but-total collapse of the Spanish solar industry in
the space of eight years is quite extraordinary, and is doubtless
in large part explained by the curtailment of subsidies, which
caused a rapid contraction in the installation as well as manufac-
turing of solar generation. The recovery of employment through-
out the EU in the period 2016 to the present is probably the result
of an increase in the construction of new solar sites, well-docu-
mented in the UK for instance,37 typically using cheap imported
solar panels, but employing Europeans in posts related to devel-
opment permitting and construction.
Nevertheless, these industries have not been able to recover
market share. Global employment in the renewable energy in-
dustries is dominated by markets where labour costs are low:
China, India, Brazil, and the Rest of the World. High labour cost
areas, such as the USA and the EU27, fare less well (see Figure 40).
Romania UK
Belgium Rest of EU
Poland Italy 100
Greece Germany
Netherlands Spain
France
0
2008 2016 2021
2
Solar PV Solid biomass
Liquid biofuels Biogas
Hydro Geothermal 1
Wind CSP
Solar heating/ 0
cooling China Brazil India USA EU27 RoW
39
Tellingly, as can be seen in Figure 41, the EU has dominant
and substantial market share only in those areas where, due to
the nature of the business, there is little international competi-
tion, for example biomass.
(€bn)
100
-100
2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
Exports
200
100
0
2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
Figure 47: EU trade balance 0
with China, 2011–21.
Source: Eurostat. Chart by the author.
-100
(€bn)
-200
-300
2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
42
Furthermore, the EU’s overall trade balance would appear to
be fragile and vulnerable to its climate policies, since it is heavily
dependent on exports of chemicals and related products, and on
machinery and transport equipment (Figure 48).
Figure 48: Extra-EU trade
balance 2016, 2020, and 400
2021, by commodity type.
Source: Eurostat. Chart by the author.
Other manufactured goods
Machinery and transport equipt. 200
(€bn)
Chemicals and related prod.
Food, drink, tobacco 0
Raw materials
Mineral fuels, lubricants
-200
-400
2016 2020 2021
43
Figure 49: Extra-EU Germany
trade balance by EU Italy
member state, 2021. Ireland
Sweden
Source: Eurostat. Chart by the author. France
Denmark
Austria
Finland
Lithuania
Latvia
Estonia
Luxembourg
Cyprus
Malta
Croatia
Slovakia
Portugal
Bulgaria
Slovenia
Romania
Hungary
Czechia
Belgium
Greece
Poland
Spain
Netherlands
-200 -100 0 100 200
(€bn)
2500
Figure 50: EU27 extra-
EU exports and imports
by member state.
Source: Eurostat. Chart by the author. 2000
Other Denmark
Netherlands France
Spain Sweden 1500
Poland Ireland
(€bn)
Belgium Italy
Austria Germany
1000
500
0
Exports Imports
44
14. Has the EU learned from its experiment?
In spite of the clear evidence that climate policies have result-
ed in falling productivity in the energy sector in the European
region, there is no sign that the Commission has even recog-
nised the facts, let alone learned from the experience. Indeed,
from their response, one would think it had been a resounding
success. In December 2019, the Commission declared that the
member states would achieve climate neutrality by 2050 and an-
nounced that the policies necessary to this end would be known
as the ‘European Green Deal’.39 This commitment was made le-
gal in March 2020 with the introduction of the European Climate
Law (ECL), and in December of that year an interim target of a
55% reduction in emissions by 2030 compared to 1990 levels
was added to the obligations imposed.
The ECL entered into force in June 2021, and in July the Com-
mission presented a package of new policies, and reinforcements
of existing ones, ‘to transform our economy’. This confirmed the
legally binding targets, and added the ambition that economic
growth will be ‘decoupled from resource use’.40 This is surely wish-
ful thinking, and without theoretical foundation.
However, the Commission believes that climate change is
not only ‘the biggest challenge of our time’, but ‘an opportunity to
build a new economic model’, comprising a transformation that
will ‘reduce emissions…create jobs and growth…address energy
poverty…reduce external energy dependency and improve our
security of supply [and] improve our health and wellbeing’.41 In
pursuit of these outcomes, the Commission proposes: ‘greater re-
newable energy use’, ‘clean new cars and cleaner fuels for cars,
planes and ships already on the market’, ‘an extension of Europe-
an carbon pricing to more sectors’, ‘targets to save energy’, ‘taxa-
tion [of ] energy sources in line with climate goals’, and ‘support
for vulnerable citizens, to protect them against additional costs
during the transition’.
The regulatory and legal framework required to deliver the
targets includes:
• revisions to the Renewable Energy Directive (RED)
• revisions to the Energy Efficiency Directive (EED)
• an energy taxation directive (ETD)
• a carbon border adjustment mechanism (CABM)
• the FuelEU Maritime Initiative
• a new Social Climate Fund (SCF) to mitigate cost increases to
those on low incomes
• revisions to the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS)
• the Alternative Fuels Infrastructure Directive (AFID)
• the ReFuelEU Aviation Initiative
• a new emissions trading scheme for road transport and build-
ings
45
• revisions to the Land Use, Land Use Change, and Forestry
(LULUCF) regulations
• the Effort Sharing Regulation (ESR), to set annual emissions
targets for member states
• new emissions standards for cars and vans
• a new EU forest strategy.42
The Commission chooses to group its policy instruments
and detailed targets under the headings Transport, Industry, En-
ergy, Buildings, the Sustainable Use of Natural Resources, and Re-
search and Innovation Actions. The main features of the European
Green Deal are summarised under these titles below.
Transport
The Commission proposes that emissions from cars should be re-
duced by 55% by 2030, and that new cars should be zero-emis-
sion by 2035. An emissions-reduction target of 50% by 2030 ap-
plies to vans, and new vans must have zero emissions by 2035.
The Alternative Fuels Infrastructure Directive will introduce
targets for alternative fuel infrastructure, for example electrical
charging and hydrogen refuelling stations. One refuelling station
will be available every 150 km along the still-to-be-completed
Trans-European Transport Network and in every urban node. The
scale of this ambition can be gauged from the nine ‘Core Net-
work Corridors’, which are due to be completed by 2030, and
then supplemented by a comprehensive network that covers all
European regions. This is planned for completion by 2050 (see
Figure 51).
The Commission expects 30 million zero-emission vehicles
to be on European roads by 2030, and notes that 1 million EVs
were registered in Europe in 2020, three times the number regis-
tered in 2019.
From 2026, road transport will be covered by emissions trad-
ing, and fossil fuels used for air travel, maritime transport, and
46
fishing within the territory of the EU’s member states will not be
fully exempt from energy taxation.
The EU ETS already applies to domestic aviation and has
done so since 2013. The Commission now proposes to extend the
scheme to all international aviation departing from EU airports.
In addition, these airports will be required to provide electrical
power to all departure gates to reduce aeroengine use while dis-
embarking, refuelling, and boarding.
Carbon pricing will also be extended to the maritime sec-
tor, and will apply to any ship arriving at or departing from an EU
port. Penalties will be levied on vessels that do not meet certain
regulatory requirements. The Commission will also compel ports
to provide electrical power to all docked vessels, to reduce fuel
use while loading and unloading.
There will be a mandatory blending target for sustainable
aviation fuel used by all operators in Europe, a minimum tax on
kerosene, and free allowances for aviation will be phased out.
Industry
The EU ETS will be strengthened, with a view to increasing rev-
enues, and a revised Innovation Fund, doubled in size, will aim to
ensure that those revenues are directed towards creating further
emissions reductions. The fund is currently designed to be sup-
ported by the 450 million industrial emissions allowances due to
be issued between 2021 and 2030. Under the revised plan, that
figure will be increased to 500 million, and the fund will also ben-
efit from 150 million new allowances relating to road transport
and buildings, and an unspecified number of allowances ‘freed
up by the Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism’. The extended
Innovation Fund will have more funding instruments to encour-
age early uptake of innovative technologies and a selective focus
only on those ‘projects aligned with the European Green Deal’.
The Commission expects these changes to compel the reno-
vation of 35 million industrial buildings and create 160,000 ad-
ditional ‘green’ jobs in the construction sector alone, with many
more created across the industrial value chain. The electrifica-
tion of the economy and the transition to renewable energy are
expected to create many of these positions, with the transport
regulation ‘providing major opportunities for the European car in-
dustry’ (the Commission’s emphasis, not mine). The failure of the
renewables industry to seize global market share, as described
above, does not suggest that these hopes are well-founded.
Revisions to the state-aid rules will permit member states
to intervene more forcefully to ‘support business to decarbon-
ise their production processes and adopt greener technologies’,
a tacit admission that spontaneous adoption will not meet the
Green Deal targets and that subsidy – that is to say, a coerced
transfer of wealth – will be required.
Participants in the EU ETS will be required to cut emissions
by 61% by 2030, with a one-off reduction in the annual limit on
total emissions to align this cap with actual emissions observed.
47
The annual rate of reduction required in the ETS will be 4.2%.
Allocation of free allowances will be made conditional on
decarbonisation efforts, and there will be new measures to en-
courage energy-intensive industries to use innovative clean
technologies.
The Modernisation Fund, which draws revenue from the ETS,
and supports the eleven lower-income member states in their
efforts to reduce emissions, will be doubled in size, a clear sign
that the Commission recognises that cross-subsidy from richer to
poorer member states is required to maintain consensus support
for the agenda. The fund’s share of ETS revenues will more than
double, to 4.5%.
EU industry will be protected, and we can use the term advis-
edly, by a Carbon Border Adjustment Mechanism, which will put
a carbon price on imports ‘of a targeted selection of products’ –
in the first instance: cement, iron and steel, aluminium, fertiliser,
and electricity – to prevent carbon leakage. The Commission be-
lieves that ‘this will ensure that European emissions reductions
contribute to a global emissions decline’, a claim that can be in-
terpreted as a tacit admission that the emissions reductions since
2005, and the introduction of the ETS, have in fact only exported
emissions to overseas production. Whether the mechanism will
deliver the required outcome is doubtful, particularly in the con-
text of a widening gulf between the Western and Asian econo-
mies (China, Russia, India), which may result only in the higher-
carbon Chinese and Indian economies preferring to trade with
each other rather than face what are in effect hostile and exclu-
sionary tariffs in Europe.
The mechanism will be introduced in a transitional phase by
the end of 2025, and will be fully operational in 2026. From that
point onwards, EU importers of goods affected will be required
to register with national authorities to purchase certificates to
cover their imports. The price will be determined by the weekly
average auction price of emissions allowances. Importers can re-
duce the cost by demonstrating that the goods have a low car-
bon footprint or that a carbon tax has already been paid in the
country of manufacture.
European industries will also be required to increase their re-
newable energy use by 1.1 percentage points per year, presum-
ably up to 2030, with a separate annual target of a 1.1 percentage
points increase in renewable energy for heating and cooling.
There will be a binding target, of an as-yet unspecified mag-
nitude, requiring industry to use a certain quantity of non-bio-
logical renewable fuel– such as hydrogen – as a feedstock or en-
ergy carrier. This measure is intended to prevent switching from
natural gas and coal to biomass for process heat. It seems likely
to impose very high costs, encouraging closure and relocation
to more favourable jurisdictions, probably in Asia where coal use
will be tolerated and perhaps even encouraged. As noted above,
biomass accounts for some 60% of all the EU’s renewable ener-
gy and has been preferentially selected by industries for process
48
heat where possible as an alternative to electricity. The Commis-
sion presumably wishes to restrict this avenue in the interests of
forestry sustainability. That may be admirable in itself, but the
economic consequences seem likely to be adverse.
Energy
Energy accounts for about 75% of the total emissions of the EU,
and has been a principal focus of its climate policies, as discussed
above. The EU currently generates about 20% of its energy from
renewable sources, but has a target for that figure to rise to 30%
by 2030. However, this is judged to be insufficient to put the EU
on course for the Green Deal targets, so the Commission propos-
es that the target be increased to 40%. Specifically, there will be
a binding increase of 1.1 percentage points per year in the use of
heating and cooling at a national level, and an indicative target
of 2.1 percentage points per year of renewable energy and waste
heat and cold in district heating and cooling. A 13% greenhouse
gas intensity target in transport will be introduced and, as noted
above, industry will be required to increase its use of renewable
energy by 1.1 percentage points per year. A new benchmark tar-
get requiring a 49% share of renewable energy use in buildings
will also be introduced.
A ‘credit mechanism’ will support electrification of transport,
and there will be sub-targets for, and certification of, renewable
hydrogen. The Commission will also act to compel member states
to accelerate permitting for renewable energy projects and pro-
mote cross-border co-operation through the renewable energy
financing mechanism.
The Commission will also act to facilitate renewable power
purchase agreements, an important development that is like-
ly to be used to provide hidden subsidies to generators, with
above-market prices concealed in the costs of goods and ser-
vices. Commercial consumers will come under great pressure,
as they already are in the United Kingdom, to enter into these
bilateral deals with renewable energy generators as a means
of demonstrating compliance with environmental, social and
governance (so-called ‘ESG’) guidelines. Prices to consumers of
goods and services will inevitably rise, but these end-purchasers
will be unaware of the causes and will inevitably blame retailers
and service providers, who should take warning. Energy compa-
nies, particularly in the UK, are now paying the price of having
in effect collected green taxes through consumer bills to fund
renewables. Shops and businesses who wish to avoid a similar
problem should insist that governments levy and collect taxes
themselves.
The Commission notes (their emphasis) that ‘reducing energy
consumption is essential’ to achieving these targets, and proposes
a reduction of 39% in total primary energy input, and a reduc-
tion of 36% in final energy consumption, as against projections
made in 2007. Member states will be required to reduce con-
sumption at a mandatory rate of at least 1.5% per year overall,
49
with the public sector required to deliver reductions of 1.7% per
year. This represents a 9% increase in the scale of demand reduc-
tion required over the levels pledged in 2020 in member states’
National Energy and Climate Plans.
Indicative member state contributions to the demand re-
duction requirement will be introduced. An ‘Energy Efficiency
First Principle’ is to be applied in policy and investment decisions,
although the details are not currently known.
In practice, the Commission calculates that these plans will
mean that total primary energy must fall to 1023 million tonnes
of oil equivalent (mtoe) in 2030, and that final energy consump-
tion must fall to 787 mtoe.43 These are very surprising values.
Figure 52 displays empirical data for these two measures for the
EU27 (i.e. not including the UK) from 1990 to 2019, and indicates
the target levels and the percentage reduction required on 2019
levels. A 27% reduction in total primary energy and a 22% reduc-
tion in final energy consumption are required in less than a dec-
ade. Bearing in mind the demand decline already observed, it is
difficult to see how further reductions can be achieved without
severe adverse effects on European wealth and standards of liv-
ing.
The twin goals of increasing the use of renewable energy
and reducing total demand are to be supported by revisions to
the tax system, specifically aligning the minimum rates for heat-
ing and transport, thus removing the exemptions widely offered
in the EU at present to heating fuels. The Commission also pro-
poses to remove exemptions and entitlements to reduced rates
for fossil fuels used in industry and commerce, for example in avi-
ation and shipping.
As also noted above, the Commission is concerned, quite
reasonably, that heavy dependence on cheap biomass may have
undesirable environmental consequences. It therefore proposes
to prohibit the use of primary forests, peatlands, and wetlands as
biomass sources. There will be no support for forest biomass for
electricity-only generators after 2026, and there will be a prohibi-
tion on national support for the use of saw or high-quality ‘veneer’
logs, or stumps or roots, for energy generation. All biomass heat
1800
Figure 52: Energy targets
for the EU27. 1600 1572
1436 1408
Source: Empirical data: International 1400
Energy Agency; Target magnitude,
European Commission.77 Chart by the 1200
1023
author. 1000
Mtoe
1092
995 1015
Total primary energy 800
Final energy consumption 787
600
400
200
0
1990 2000 2010 2020 2030
50
and power installations will be required to meet new minimum
greenhouse-gas saving thresholds.
We have already seen that hydrogen is to be supported,
both for transport and as an alternative to biomass for heat. The
Commission will introduce targets for at least 40 GW of renew-
ably fuelled hydrogen electrolysers, with the goal of producing
10 million tonnes of renewable hydrogen per year by 2030. 2.6%
of transport fuels must be renewable fuels of non-biological ori-
gin – in other words, hydrogen or wind or solar electricity – and
industry will be required to show that 50% of the hydrogen it
uses has been derived from renewable sources. This is important,
since it constricts the market available to the use of steam meth-
ane reforming with carbon capture, which is already central to
some national plans because it is by far the cheapest means of
generating hydrogen. The UK, for example, hopes to produce
about 200 TWh of hydrogen from methane in 2050, mostly to
decarbonise tricky areas such as agricultural traction and marine
transport.
The Energy Taxation Directive will set preferential rates for
the use of renewable and low-carbon hydrogen. The directive
will also set revised rates for all fuels according to their energy
content, rather than their volume, and their environmental im-
pact. Tax exemptions that favour fossil fuels and polluting eco-
nomic sectors will be removed.
Exemptions for home heating will be phased out, so that
member states will be unable to tax heating fuels at lower rates,
requiring them to find alternative means to support low-income
households. As noted above, fossil fuels used by air, maritime
transport and fishing within the EU will not be fully exempt from
energy taxation.
Buildings
On the basis that buildings account for 40% of the EU’s final en-
ergy consumption, and 36% of its greenhouse gas emissions,
the Commission proposes a broadscale ‘renovation’ programme.
Member states will be required to renovate 3% of the total floor
area of all public buildings annually, to set a benchmark of 49%
of renewable energy supply for buildings in 2030, and to legis-
late so as to increase the use of renewable energy in heating and
cooling by 1.1 percentage points per year until 2030.
In the interests of social justice, these measures will also be
supported by grants from the Social Climate Fund, amounting
to €72.2 billion over seven years. However, some of this will be
spent on access to zero- and low-emission transport and ‘even to
income support’.
400
Exajoules
200
0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 2015
Modern biofuels Wind and solar Nuclear Gas
Oil Coal Hydro Traditional biofuels
58
highly productive and permitting vast wealth creation outside
it. Organic economies in the past relied on low-ERoEI renewable
flows, mostly from farmed crops, and were compelled to reinvest
the majority of the available wealth in the energy sector itself, for
example in farm wages and the management of land, leaving lit-
tle over for wealth creation in other areas. An economy based on
modern renewables would necessarily be very similar in struc-
ture, with wealth and socio-political power concentrated in the
hands of those owning the low-productivity energy generation
assets. This would be politically unstable.
Energy expansion, not transition, can be confirmed by ref-
erence to another data source, that of the International Energy
Agency (Figure 54).
Nuclear
Gas 400
Crude, NGL feedstocls
Coal, peat, shale oil
Renewables, waste
200
0
1971 1981 1991 2001 2011
Exajoules
Wind, solar etc
Nuclear 80
Gas
Oil
Coal 40
Hydro
Biofuels
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Wind 6
Solar
Biofuels 5
Waste
Nuclear 4
Hydro
Coal and oil
3
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
60
This is exactly what would be expected from the historical
record of energy expansion, not least because the progressively
wider adoption of electricity as an energy carrier is a basic in-
dex of modernity. China is generating just short of 8000 TWh of
electrical energy per year at present, mostly from coal and envi-
ronmentally controversial large hydro. For comparison and scale,
the UK generates about 300 TWh per year, and is on a falling con-
sumption trend (discussed below; see Figure 59). Generously as-
suming a load factor of about 40%, we can estimate the output
of the 26 GW of Chinese offshore wind at just under 100 TWh, or
about 1% of its electricity generation.
Overall, Chinese energy demand appears to be increasing
rapidly in every area, and with all fuels except traditional biomass
showing signs of growth. In the EU28, by contrast, energy con-
sumption is falling (Figure 57).
Nuclear 40
Gas
Oil
Coal
Hydro 20
Biofuels
0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
TWh
generation only.
Interconnectors 150
Biomass
100
Wind, solar etc
Hydro 50
Nuclear
Coal 0
2018 2019 2020
Gas 2021 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019
Dutch Int Nemo Int Nor Int
stations such as Drax), the decline of nuclear, and the expansion
of renewables and imports over interconnectors with Europe.
However, interesting though these changes in fuel mix undoubt-
edly are, the most important macroscopic feature of this figure is
the overall decline in electricity generation, making a sharp con-
trast with China. In historical context, this is even more striking.
Figure 59 charts electricity supplied in the UK in the century from
1920 to 2020.
200
TWh
100
0
1920 1940 1960 1980 2000
Direct use
Total inputs Total outputs
Imports Final con-
74
144
sumption
150
287
Energy
339 sector use
Other
257
Production
188
Exports
111
Transformation
Other 52 Transformation
losses
(b) 2019
Direct use
Total inputs Total outputs
Final con-
129
sumption
132
140
Imports
234
Energy
263
sector use
188
Other
Production
121
Exports
76
Transformation
Other 29 Transformation
losses
64
lateral damage. Even the United States, long resistant to the EU’s
global decarbonisation arguments, now also exhibits stagnat-
ing energy consumption. However, it is also markedly more fuel
diverse than many parts of the EU, with a substantial, though
declining, residual input from coal, and an increasing share of
natural gas, much of which is produced from within-country re-
sources such as shale deposits (Figure 61).
Croatia — 300
Macedonia — 632
Albania — 727
Bosnia 630 4,182
Norway 78 —
Serbia 855 31,012
Turkey 1,190 12,114
Ukraine 81,045 —
Total other European countries 83,798 48,967
Source: EU Commission DG Energy (2012). https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/
documents/20121217_eu_co_res_report.pdf.
70
In summary, proven reserves are very substantial, and con-
tingent and prospective resources are still greater. As Table 4
demonstrates, there is a great deal of coal in Europe, and even
if consumption were increased considerably there would be suf-
ficient for several centuries.
In 2014, and in response to an earlier phase of the Ukraine
crisis, the EU undertook research into regional energy security.50
This reported work by the German Federal Institute for Geoscienc-
es and Natural Resources to the effect that technically recover-
able shale gas resources in Europe amounted to some 14 trillion
cubic metres (494 trillion cubic feet), between four and five times
greater than the proven reserves of natural gas reported for 2020
in the BP Statistical Review quoted above. Most of these resources
are thought to be concentrated in France and Poland, but the
figures for the UK, Germany, the Netherlands, and Denmark add
up to a substantial additional resource, equivalent to about half
of the French total. Similar findings are reported in work by the
United States Energy Information Administration (US EIA) pub-
lished in 2013 (see Table 5).
This substantial resource remains all but completely unex-
plored at present due to successful campaigning by environ-
mental pressure groups.
The two most significant holdings of oil and gas in the North
Sea are in UK and Norwegian waters. BP’s Statistical Review re-
ports, for 2020, proven reserves of 7.9 billion barrels of oil and
1.4 trillion cubic metres of natural gas in Norwegian waters, and
2.5 billion barrels of oil and 0.2 trillion cubic metres of natural gas
in UK waters.
Bulgaria 0 0 17
Denmark 0 2 32
France 0 0 137
Germany 0 4 17
Netherlands 3 43 26
Norway 4 73 0
Poland 0 3 148
Romania 0 4 51
Spain 0 0 8
Sweden - - 10
United Kingdom 2 9 26
*TRR, technically recoverable resources. †2013 EIA/ARI estimate. ‡2012 US Geological Survey estimate, including reserve growth. Source: Extract
from US Energy Information Administration 2013.
71
Norwegian Petroleum reports that contingent resources –
in fields and discoveries and undiscovered resources – probably
amount to about 2.5 times proven reserves of oil, and about 1.6
times proven reserves of gas.51
The UK’s Oil & Gas Authority (recently renamed the North
Sea Transition Authority) reports that its contingent resource lev-
el of 6.8 billion barrels of oil equivalent of oil and gas (of which
about 70% is oil and 30% gas) is about one and a half times larger
than the proven reserves that could sustain UK Continental Shelf
production to 2030, implying that another decade or more of
production at current levels might be sustained from these re-
sources.52
In passing, it is interesting to note that other sources report
natural gas reserves in Ukraine only slightly smaller than those of
Norway.53
In reviewing the potential of shale gas to contribute to en-
ergy security, in 2014 the European Commission concluded that
‘the volumes produced will not make Europe self-sufficient in gas
but could help to reduce prices’.54 That conclusion is obviously
correct, and applies with equal force to coal, oil, and conven-
tional natural gas resources. No-one would argue from the data
reviewed in this study that the European region can become
self-sufficient in fossil energy, but it is equally clear that further
exploration of the very substantial resources of these fuels could
enlarge proven reserves, increase production, and have a signifi-
cant effect on regional prices and overall security.
16. Conclusion
The prosperity generated from even a modest increase in domes-
tic fossil fuel production in Western Europe could be the basis for
a reversal of energy policy and a return to the gas-to-nuclear tra-
jectory that alone has thermodynamic theory on its side and was
being spontaneously adopted by the markets in the early 2000s,
but which was mistakenly cancelled by policy intervention. This
will require a recognition that the attempt to induce an energy
transition by means of intense support for renewable energy
has been a mistake and that emergency measures are needed
to support a corrective course. Writing off the malinvestments
made in wind and solar, many now owned by European pension
funds, will be painful in itself, but providing resources to support
the required remedial investment in conventional fossil fuels and
advanced nuclear will also require considerable sacrifices in Eu-
ropean standards of living. There is much lost ground to be made
up. Consequently, there is no easy path out of the difficulties, and
the future for the European peoples is arduous whichever course,
wise or foolish, is taken.
72
About the author
John Constable is an independent energy policy analyst, and the Energy Director for the Glob-
al Warming Policy Foundation (GWPF) in London. Dr Constable has appeared before several par-
liamentary select committees, including the House of Commons Environmental Audit Commit-
tee and the House of Lords Committee on Economic Affairs. He is a frequent invited and plenary
speaker on energy and climate policy to both mixed and specialist audiences. In 2009 he deliv-
ered the Alworth International Lectures at the University of Minnesota, in 2015 he was a plenary
speaker at Kyoto University’s ‘Global Energy Problems’ conference (2015), and in 2016 he delivered
a Newcastle University ‘Insight’ public lecture, now published as Energy, Entropy, and the Theory of
Wealth (2016). In 2021 he was an invited speaker at the 21st Mont Pelerin Society conference, held
in Guatemala City, where he spoke on the relationship between low-entropy energy sources and
the emergence of liberal societies. Dr Constable has also worked with the Hartwell Group of inter-
national climate policy analysts, being an author in the third Hartwell study, The Vital Spark (2013).
The following articles and monographs are a selection from Dr Constable’s many other publi-
cations on energy policy ‘US Offshore Wind Prospects: Overblown Promises and Blown-Up Costs’,
National Review (February 2021); A Little Nudge with a Big Stick (2021); Hydrogen: The once and future
fuel? (2020); The Brink of Darkness: Britain’s fragile power grid (2020); Offshore Wind Strike Prices: Be-
hind the Headlines (with Gordon Hughes and Capell Aris, 2017); Energy Intensive Industries: Climate
policy casualties (2016); ‘Economic hazards of a forced energy transition: inferences from the UK’s
renewable energy and climate strategy’, Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review (with Lee
Moroney, June 2016); Shortfall, Rebound, Backfire: Can we rely on energy efficiency policies to offset
climate policy costs? (2012), Energy Policy and Consumer Hardship (2011), and The Green Mirage: Why
a low carbon economy may be further off than we think (Civitas: London, 2011).
73
Notes
1. COM(2021) 962 final, p. 3.
2. ETC/CME Eionet, Trends and projections in the EU ETS in 2021, 18.
3. ETC/CME Eionet, Trends and projections in the EU ETS in 2021, 32.
4. See Table 5.1 in EC SWD(2021) 308 final: https://ec.europa.eu/clima/system/files/2021-10/
swd_2021_308_en.pdf.
5. COM(2021) 962 final, p. 14–15.
6. EU Commission, Industry Factsheet, ‘Leading the Clean Industrial Revolution’ (July 2021):
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/fs_21_3675.
7. https://ec.europa.eu/clima/eu-action/eu-emissions-trading-system-eu-ets_en.
8. Calculated from figures in SWD(2021) 308 final.
9. Much EU and Commission data now removes the UK from its records, though sometimes pro-
viding the data in a separate line in the statement. It is not always possible or desirable to recom-
bine the data to provide statements for the EU28, and this study reports data for both the EU27
(excluding the UK) and the EU28 (including the UK) as seems appropriate.
10. The annual increment could begin to decline in the near future if subsidy entitlements expire
and no new subsidies are introduced.
11. See Gordon Hughes, Wind Power Costs in the United Kingdom (REF: London, 2020), and The
Performance of Wind Power in Denmark (REF: London, 2020): https://www.ref.org.uk/ref-blog/365-
wind-power-economics-rhetoric-and-reality.
12. https://energy.ec.europa.eu/topics/markets-and-consumers/capacity-mechanisms_en.
13. https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/electricity-market-reform-capacity-market.
14. https://ec.europa.eu/environment/archives/industry/stationary/lcp/legislation.htm.
15. https://ec.europa.eu/environment/industry/stationary/ied/legislation.htm.
16. https://ec.europa.eu/environment/archives/industry/stationary/lcp/legislation.htm.
17. https://www.nationalgrideso.com/information-about-great-britains-energy-system-and-
electricity-system-operator-eso.
18. https://www.elexon.co.uk/article/bsc-insight-increasing-costs-for-balancing-the-gb-system/.
19. https://data.nationalgrideso.com/balancing/mbss.
20. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/products-eurostat-news/-/edn-20220211-1.
21. https://www.eea.europa.eu/ims/use-of-renewable-energy-for.
22. https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/fs_21_3665.
23. Rögnvaldur Hannesson, ‘How much do European households pay for green energy?’, Energy
Policy 131 (2019), 235–239.
24. Trinomics, Final Report Summary: Energy Costs, taxes, and the impact of government interven-
tions on investments (2020). Doi: 10.2833/827631. See page 12.
25. Marten AL (2011) Transient Temperature Response Modelling in IAMs. Econ E-J 5:2011–2018.
26. United States Environmental Protection Agency (2015). http://www3.epa.gov/climatechange/
EPAactivities/economics/scc.html.
27. ‘Communication from the Commission: Action Plan for Energy Efficiency Potential: Realising
the Potential’ (Brussels 19.10.2006) COM(2006)545 final.
28. W. S. Jevons, The Coal Question (1865), p.103.
74
29. Coal Question (1865), p.105. Liebig’s remark appears in Justus von Liebig, Familiar Letters on
Chemistry (Taylor, Walton, & Maberly: London, 1851), p. 462, and reads: ‘Cultivation is the economy
of force. Science teaches us the simplest means of obtaining the greatest effect with the smallest
expenditure of power, and with given means to produce a maximum force’.
30. As the authors explain: ‘The G20 weighted averages are calculated on the basis of all available
data for a particular year, weighted in total price by the share a country had in EU imports + exports
2017–2019. Coverage ratios of total trade range from 84–99% (household prices), 76–99% (indus-
trial prices) and 36–74% (wholesale prices).’
31. On the weighting used to construct the G20 averages, the authors comment that these are ‘cal-
culated on the basis of all available data for a particular year, weighted in total price by the share a
country had in EU imports + exports 2017–2019. Coverage ratios of total trade range from 84–98%
(household prices), 77–99% (industrial prices) and 60–97% (wholesale prices)’.
32. The authors explain that the G20 weighted averages ‘calculated on the basis of all available
data for a particular year, weighted in total price by the share a country had in EU imports + exports
2017–2019’.
33. Trinomics, p. 16.
34. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/cache/infographs/energy/bloc-2c.html#carouselControls?lang
=en.
35. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/3859598/13590301/KS-GQ-21-014-EN-N.
pdf/11cc1e2f-49b6-14d3-4102-5ecaa4c91049.
36. https://www.nordex-online.com/en/2022/02/nordex-se-nordex-group-plans-to-cease-rotor-
blade-production-at-rostock-site-in-germany/.
37. John Constable, Solar and the threat to food security (Net Zero Watch: London, 2022). https://
www.netzerowatch.com/content/uploads/2022/02/Constable-Solar-Update.pdf.
38. European Commission, European Green Deal: Delivering on our targets (2021): https://ec.europa.
eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/fs_21_3688, p. 25.
39. https://eur-lex.europa.eu/resource.html?uri=cellar:b828d165-1c22-11ea-8c1f-
01aa75ed71a1.0002.02/DOC_1&format=PDF, and https://eur-lex.europa.eu/resource.
html?uri=cellar:b828d165-1c22-11ea-8c1f-01aa75ed71a1.0002.02/DOC_2&format=PDF.
40. https://ec.europa.eu/info/strategy/priorities-2019-2024/european-green-deal_en.
41. European Green Deal: Delivering on our targets.
42. European Green Deal: Delivering on our targets, p. 9.
43. https://ec.europa.eu/info/news/commission-proposes-new-energy-efficiency-directive-2021-
jul-14_en.
44. European Green Deal: Delivering on our targets, 25.
45. European Commission, European Green Deal: Delivering on Our Targets (July 2021), p. 4. See also
the speech by President von der Leyen: https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/
speech_21_1361.
46. See Gordon Hughes, Wind Power Costs in the United Kingdom (REF: London, 2020), and The
Performance of Wind Power in Denmark (REF: London, 2020). https://www.ref.org.uk/ref-blog/365-
wind-power-economics-rhetoric-and-reality.
47. https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_
data/file/1064799/Energy_Trends_March_2022.pdf.
48. https://www.netzerowatch.com/radical-plan-to-end-the-energy-crisis/.
49. https://www.worldcoal.com/coal/31032014/coal_discovered_in_north_sea_674/.
75
50. https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/documents/20140528_energy_security_study.
pdf.
51. https://www.norskpetroleum.no/en/petroleum-resources/resource-accounts/.
52. https://www.nstauthority.co.uk/media/7764/rr-report_final-22-september-2021.pdf.
53. https://hir.harvard.edu/ukraine-energy-reserves/.
54. h t t p s : / / w w w. e u ro p a r l. e u ro p a . e u / R e g D a t a / e t u d e s / B R I E / 2 0 1 4 / 5 4 2 1 6 7 / E P R S _
BRI(2014)542167_REV1_EN.pdf.
55. https://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/the-eu-emissions-trading-system-2/the-eu-
emissions-trading-system.
56. https://ec.europa.eu/clima/system/files/2021-10/com_2021_962_en.pdf.
57. https://ec.europa.eu/clima/system/files/2021-10/com_2021_962_en.pdf.
58. ETC/CME Eionet, Trends and Projections in the EU ETS in 2021: The EU Emissions Trading System in
Numbers (2021). https://www.eionet.europa.eu/etcs/etc-cme/products/etc-cme-reports/etc-cme-
report-9-2021-trends-and-projections-in-the-eu-ets-in-2021-the-eu-emissions-trading-system-in-
numbers.
59. Trinomics for the EU Commission, Final Report Energy Subsidies: Energy costs, taxes and
the impact of government interventions on investments (2020): http://trinomics.eu/wp-content
/uploads/2020/11/Final-Report-Energy-Subsidies.pdf.
60. Trinomics for the EU Commission, Final Report Energy Subsidies: Energy costs, taxes and the
impact of government interventions on investments (2020): http://trinomics.eu/wp-content/
uploads/2020/11/Final-Report-Energy-Subsidies.pdf.
61. Trinomics for the EU Commission, Final Report Energy Subsidies: Energy costs, taxes and the
impact of government interventions on investments (2020): http://trinomics.eu/wp-content/
uploads/2020/11/Final-Report-Energy-Subsidies.pdf.
62. Trinomics for the EU Commission, Final Report Energy Subsidies: Energy costs, taxes and the
impact of government interventions on investments (2020): http://trinomics.eu/wp-content/
uploads/2020/11/Final-Report-Energy-Subsidies.pdf.
63. https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/Publication/2022/Apr/IRENA_RE_
Capacity_Statistics_2022.pdf.
64. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/documents/4187653/13722717/Renewable_energy_heating_
cooling_2020.png/.
65. https://www.eea.europa.eu/ims/use-of-renewable-energy-for.
66. https://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/trends-and-projections-in-europe-2021. The EEA
appends a note to this chart: EEA note: ‘The current 2030 target, adopted from the Renewable En-
ergy Directive (2018/2001/EU), is a 32% renewable energy share of gross final energy consumption
(RES share). The proposed target from the ‘Fit for 55 package’ is a more ambitious 40% RES share
in 2030. The 2050 values represent the indicative share of renewable energy in the EU’s gross final
consumption as presented in figures 5 and 8 in a Commission staff working document (EC, 2020a)
of scenarios that achieve a reduction of at least 55 % in 2030.’
67. Constable, J., Moroney, L. Economic hazards of a forced energy transition: inferences from the
UK’s renewable energy and climate strategy. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 14, 171–192 (2017). https://doi.
org/10.1007/s40844-016-0041-6.
68. http://trinomics.eu/wp-content/uploads/2020/11/Final-Report-Energy-Subsidies.pdf.
69. https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/16e7f212-0dc5-11eb-bc07-
01aa75ed71a1/language-en.
76
70. https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/16e7f212-0dc5-11eb-bc07-
01aa75ed71a1/language-en.
71. https://op.europa.eu/en/publication-detail/-/publication/16e7f212-0dc5-11eb-bc07-
01aa75ed71a1/language-en.
72. https://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/trends-and-projections-in-europe-2021. EEA note:
‘The historical development of greenhouse gas emissions is shown excluding land use, land use
change and forestry (LULUCF) (light blue solid line, labelled ‘emissions’) and including LULUCF (dark
blue solid line, labelled ‘net emissions’). Both of these trend lines include approximated values for
2020. The light blue line relates to the scope of the 2020 target, while the dark blue line reflects the
2030 target’s scope; both include international aviation. Projections are shown in dashed and dot-
ted lines according to the 2030 target’s scope, starting from 2019. The projections reflect the most
recent data submitted by all Member States; Germany’s projections are only preliminary. The pace
notations in the bar at the top indicate the actual average annual change in net emissions (includ-
ing LULUCF and international aviation) for 1990-2020. The necessary future change to achieve the
net 55 % reductions between 2020 and 2030 is calculated on an average annual basis, assuming a
maximum LULUCF contribution of 225 Mt CO2e (carbon dioxide equivalent) in 2030.’
73. https://www.ise.fraunhofer.de/content/dam/ise/de/documents/publications/studies/
Photovoltaics-Report.pdf.
74. https://www.ise.fraunhofer.de/content/dam/ise/de/documents/publications/studies/
Photovoltaics-Report.pdf.
75. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php?title=International_trade_in_
goods.
76. https://transport.ec.europa.eu/transport-themes/infrastructure-and-investment/trans-
european-transport-network-ten-t_en.
77. https://ec.europa.eu/info/news/commission-proposes-new-energy-efficiency-directive-2021-
jul-14_en.
78. Vaclav Smil, Energy Transitions: Global and National Perspectives 2nd Edition (Praeger: Santa
Barbara, 2017), 240–241.
79. EIA, Monthly Energy Review (July 2018), Table 1.3.
80. United States Energy Information Administration, Technically Recoverable Shale Gas Resources:
An Assessment of 137 Shale Formations in 41 Countries Outside the United States (June 2013), p. 6.
https://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/worldshalegas/pdf/overview.pdf.
77
Review process
GWPF publishes papers in a number of different formats, with a different review process pertaining to
each.
• Our flagship long-form GWPF Reports, are all reviewed by our Academic Advisory Panel.
• GWPF Briefings and Notes are shorter documents and are reviewed internally and/or externally as
required.
Part of the function of the review process is to ensure that any materials published by the GWPF
are of a proper academic standard, and will serve the GWPF’s educational purpose. As a charity, we
recognise that educational material should provide any reader the opportunity to understand, and ex-
plore different perspectives on a subject.
This means that, for most publications, we also invite an external review from a party who we
would expect to take a different view to the publication’s author. We offer to publish any substantive
comments alongside the main paper, provided we are satisfied they will enhance the educational ex-
perience of the reader. In this way, we hope to encourage open and active debate on the important
areas in which we work.
This enhanced review process for GWPF papers is intended to take the content and analysis be-
yond a typical review for an academic journal:
• More potential reviewers can be involved
• The number of substantive comments will typically exceeds journal peer review, and
• The identity of the author is known to the potential reviewers.
As an organisation whose publications are sometimes the subject of assertive or careless criti-
cism, this review process is intended to enhance the educational experience for all readers, allowing
points to be made and considered in context and observing the standards required for an informed
and informative debate. We therefore expect all parties involved to treat the reviews with the utmost
seriousness.
Final responsibility for publication rests with the Chairman of the Trustees and the GWPF Director.
But in every case, the views expressed are those of the author. GWPF has never had any corporate posi-
tion beyond that dictated by its educational objectives.
BOARD OF TRUSTEES
Dr Jerome Booth (Chairman) Professor Michael Kelly
Steve Baker MP Terence Mordaunt
Professor Peter Edwards Graham Stringer MP
Kathy Gyngell Professor Fritz Vahrenholt