Lesson 1 12
Lesson 1 12
MICROECONOMICS II
GE PAPER FOR ALL COURSES EXCEPT B.A. (HONS.) ECONOMICS
GE- ECONOMICS
SEMESTER-III
GENERIC ELECTIVE (GE)
Editors
Prof. J. Khuntia, Devender, Sarabjeet Kaur
Content Writer
Prof. J. Khuntia, Reena Bajaj, Devender,
Tanu Singh, Dyuti Agrawal
Content Reviewer from DDCE/COL/SOL
Prof. J. Khuntia, Devender
Academic Coordinator
Deekshant Awasthi
Published by:
Department of Distance and Continuing Education,
Campus of Open Learning/School of Open Learning,
University of Delhi, Delhi-110 007
Printed by:
School of Open Learning, University of Delhi
Printed at: Vikas Publishing House Pvt. Ltd. Plot 20/4, Site-IV, Industrial Area Sahibabad, Ghaziabad - 201 010 (15000 Copies)
SYLLABUS
Principles of Microeconomics II
Syllabus Mapping
CONTENTS
1.1 Introduction
1.2 Learning Objectives
1.3 Meaning and Kinds of Monopoly
1.4 Absence of Supply Curve in Monopoly
1.5 Learning Outcome
1.6 Self Assessment Questions
1.7 Recommended Readings
LESSON 2 SOME APPLICATIONS OF MONOPOLY 23–38
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Learning Objectives
3.3 Features of Monopolistic Competition
3.4 Average and Marginal Revenue Curves under Monopolistic Competition
3.5 Equilibrium of A Firm Under Monopolistic Competition
3.6 Excess Capacity under Monopolistic Competition
3.7 Perfect vs Monopolistic Competition: A Comparison
3.8 Learning Outcomes
3.9 Recommended Readings
5.1 Objective
5.2 Introduction
5.3 Models of Collusive Oligopoly
8.1 Introduction
8.2 The Demand for Factors
8.3 Supply of Factors
8.4 Learning Outcome
8.5 Terminal Questions
10.1 Introduction
10.2 Learning Objectives
10.3 What is trade?
10.4 Why do people trade?
10.5 Theory of Absolute Advantage
10.6 Glossary
10.7 Answer to In-Text Questions
10.8 Learning outcomes
10.9 Terminal Questions
10.10 Solutions to Terminal Questions
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Learning Objectives
11.3 Theory of Comparative Advantage
11.4 Sources of Comparative Advantage
11.5 Terms of Trade (TOT)
11.6 Types of Terms of Trade
11.7 Glossary
11.8 Answer to In-Text Questions
12.1 Introduction
12.2 Learning Objectives
12.3 Trade Barriers
12.4 Types of Trade Barriers
12.5 Free Trade versus Protectionism
12.6 Glossary
12.7 Answer to In-Text Questions
12.8 Learning Outcomes
12.9 Terminal Questions
12.10 Solutions to Terminal Questions
12.11 Recommended Readings
LESSON 1 MONOPOLY
LESSON 2 SOME APPLICATIONS OF MONOPOLY
LESSON 3 MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
LESSON 4 OLIGOPOLY
LESSON 5 COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY
Monopoly
LESSON 1 NOTES
MONOPOLY
Prof. J. Khuntia
Professor
School of Open Learning
University of Delhi
Structure
1.1 Introduction
1.2 Learning Objectives
1.3 Meaning and Kinds of Monopoly
1.4 Absence of Supply Curve in Monopoly
1.5 Learning Outcome
1.6 Self Assessment Questions
1.7 Recommended Readings
1.1 INTRODUCTION
Monopoly has been derived from the combination of words ‘Mono + Polein’
where ‘mono’ means single and ‘polein’ means to sell. So, monopoly can be
defined as a market structure where there is a single seller selling a product for
which there is no close substitute available and there are barriers to enter the
market. Presence of a single firm shows that there is no difference between a
firm and an industry.
Features of Monopoly: The definition of monopoly mentioned above
reveals the following characteristics of a monopolist:
1. Single Seller – In a monopoly there is just one seller of a product or
service, so there is no difference between the firm and industry. The
demand curve facing the monopolist is thus the market demand curve.
The monopolist thus fixes the price and quantity where it maximizes its
profits. However, out of the two variables that are price and quantity,
a monopolist can fix either of the variables. If it fixes the price, the
quantity is determined by the market and if it fixes the quantity to be
sold then the price is determined by the market.
2. No close Substitutes – For a monopolist to retain its position in the
long run, it is essential that the firm sells a unique product which cannot
be substituted by any other product or service.
3. No Entry – A monopolist usually earns supernormal profits in the long
run as there is no entry of the new firms in the industry. So, the profit
earned by the monopolist is not wiped out as in the case of perfect
competition where presence of supernormal profits attracts new firms
in the industry.
Self-Instructional
4 Material
Self-Instructional
Material 5
NOTES Total Revenue, Average Revenue and Marginal Revenue Under Monopoly
Take an imaginary revenue schedule of the monopolist as represented in Table 1.1.
Table 1.1 An imaginary revenue schedule of the monopolist
This schedule shows the relation between price or average revenue and
quantity in case of monopoly. It shows that as price falls quantity demanded
increases, ceteris paribus. Total revenue thus first increases, reaches its maximum
and then starts falling but it is always non-zero and positive. Average Revenue
(AR) and Marginal Revenue (MR) are falling. AR remains higher than MR as
quantity of output increases. MR is positive as long as total revenue (TR) is
increasing, when TR reaches the maximum, MR becomes zero and when TR
starts falling in absolute terms, MR becomes negative. The shapes of the TR, AR
and MR curves should be understood prior to deriving the equilibrium. Figure
1.2 is based on the values of TR, AR and MR given in Table 1.1.
Self-Instructional
6 Material
NOTES
Self-Instructional
Material 7
A monopolist earns maximum profits when the gap between Total Revenue (TR)
and Total Cost (TC) is Maximum. The condition is depicted in the Figure 1.3.
Here, TR curve starts from the origin as there is no revenue since the output is
zero and TR is inverse ‘U’ shaped because of inverse relation between price and
quantity. TC is inverse ‘S’ shaped because of Law of Variable Proportion. Total
profits are derived by subtracting TC from TR. Initially TC being greater than
TR, the firm is incurring losses. Points ‘A’ and ‘B’ are the breakeven points as
here the firm has neither the profits nor the losses. Profit is maximum where the
gap between TR and TC is the highest and it is the equilibrium quantity.
As per marginal approach there can be three cases of equilibrium that a monopolist
faces depending upon the relation between per unit revenue and per unit cost. The
two conditions that need to be satisfied to attain the equilibrium are as follows:
(1) MR = MC
(2) MC cuts MR from below or Slope of MR < Slope of MC at the point of
equilibrium
Equilibrium of a monopolist can be derived under two time periods:
• Short Run – It is a time period where there are certain costs that are fixed
in nature along with the variable costs and entry or exit of the firms is not
possible. Here a monopolist can have supernormal profits; normal profits
and can even incur losses.
• Long run – It is a time period where all costs become variable and entry or
exit of firms is also possible. Here a monopolist usually gets supernormal
profits.
Equilibrium in the Short Run
In the short run, a monopolist may earn supernormal or abnormal profit or
normal profit or even incur loss depending on the position of short run average
cost curve.
Case 1: Supernormal Profit
Figure 1.4 shows downward sloping Average revenue (AR) and Marginal revenue
(MR) curves. Short run average cost curve (SAC) and Short run marginal cost
curves (SMC) are also shown. Equilibrium is at point E where both the conditions
of MR = MC and MC cutting MR from below are being satisfied. Equilibrium
quantity is OQ* that monopolist would sell at a price of OP*. Total profits can
thus be calculated as follows:
TP = TR – TC
= (Price * Quantity) – (Average Cost * Quantity)
= (OP*) * (OQ*) – (BQ*) * (OQ*) = OP*CQ* – OABQ* = AP*CB =
Supernormal Profits Self-Instructional
Material 9
NOTES
Self-Instructional
10 Material
NOTES
Fig. 1.5
Self-Instructional
Fig. 1.6 Material 11
Self-Instructional
12 Material
NOTES
Fig. 1.7
In perfect competition the supply curve of a firm is the segment of marginal cost
curve above the minimum point of short run average variable cost curve. This
is because of the reason that the marginal revenue or the price curve is constant
(parallel to x axis) and hence it is only the marginal cost curve that is required
for determining the quantity that would be sold by a perfectly competitive firm
at a particular price. Thus, it shows that there is one to one relation between price
and quantity supplied in case of perfect competition as the firm is only the price
taker as the price is set by the industry. This is however not the case in monopoly.
A monopolist firm has no supply curve as there is no one to one relation between
price and quantity supplied due to the fact that here demand curve is not constant
but is downward sloping. So, the quantity supplied at different prices depend upon
the shape of the demand curve (elasticity) and marginal cost curve as equilibrium
is obtained by the intersection of marginal revenue and marginal cost curve. It
Self-Instructional
Material 13
NOTES can be shown by shifting the demand curves that two different quantities can be
supplied at the same price and the same quantity can be supplied at two different
prices depending upon the elasticity of the demand curve.
Case 1: Same quantity being supplied at two different prices – It
is shown in Figure 1.8. Here, initially demand curve is shown by AR and
corresponding marginal curve is MR. Equilibrium takes place at the intersection
of MC and MR, and it is obtained at point E where the monopolist is selling OQ*
units of commodity at a price of OP per unit. Now if the demand curve shifts to
AR1 with corresponding marginal revenue curve being MR1, the new equilibrium
is at the same point ‘E’ where monopolist is selling the same number of units that
is OQ* but at a reduced price of OP1 as the new demand curve is relatively more
elastic. Thus, it shows how change in the elasticity can force the monopolist to
sell the same quantity at different prices.
Fig. 1.8
Case 2: Two different quantities can be sold at same price – See Figure
Self-Instructional 1.9, where the initial demand curve is AR and corresponding marginal revenue
14 Material
curve is MR. Equilibrium is at a point where MR and MC intersect that is point E NOTES
showing that monopolist is selling OQ units of commodity at a price of OP* per
unit. Now if the demand curve shifts to AR1 with corresponding marginal revenue
curve being MR1, then equilibrium shifts to E1 where monopolist is selling a
higher quantity but at the same price of OP*. Thus, it shows how monopolist
cannot obtain any one to one relation between price and quantity supplied as here
the demand curve is downward sloping and its elasticity and shape of marginal
cost curve both have an impact on the equilibrium.
Fig. 1.9
NOTES equilibrium quantity at a point where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost.
As in perfect competition the price is constant, it is equal to marginal revenue
and hence the equilibrium is:
Price = MR = MC
But in case of monopoly demand curve is downward sloping, therefore P
> MR and equilibrium condition being MR = MC, we get a difference between
price and MC as P > MC. This gap between price and MC shows the extent of
monopoly power that a firm possesses.
Abba Lerner, an economist, gave an index in 1934 to measure this
monopoly power and it is called Lerner’s Index of Monopoly Power.
L = (P–MC) / P = – 1/ Ed where 0 ≤ L < 1
The more is the elasticity of the demand curve the lesser is the monopoly
power and the lesser is the elasticity of the demand curve the more is the
monopoly power.
For perfect competition as P = MC; L = 0, there being no monopoly power.
The closer the value of L to 1, the higher is the monopoly power.
is no one to one relation between price and quantity supplied. A monopolist can NOTES
sell two different quantities at the same price or same quantity at two different
prices depending upon the elasticity of the demand curves.
NOTES 3. How does a monopolist firm reach its equilibrium in the short run?
4. Explain the relation between Average revenue, Marginal revenue and
Elasticity of demand.
Mathematical Proof (Optional)
1. Relation between Total Revenue (TR), Average Revenue (AR) and
Marginal Revenue (MR) under Monopoly
Let demand function of a monopolist is given by
P = a – bQ .... (1)
Where P = Price, Q = Quantity, a = intercept and b = slope of the demand
curve.
Now Total Revenue (TR) = P*Q, substituting Equation (1) in TR, we get:
TR = (a – bQ) * Q = aQ – bQ2
AR = TR / Q = (aQ – bQ2)/Q = a – bQ = Price .... (2)
MR = ∂TR/∂Q = ∂ (aQ – bQ2)/ /∂Q = a – 2bQ .... (3)
Comparing AR and MR, i.e., equation (2) and (3) we get the following
results:
AR = a – bQ
MR = a – 2bQ
a. Intercept of both AR and MR is same = a, so both the curves start from
the same point on the Y axis.
b. Both have a negative sign in between showing that both the curves are
downward sloping.
c. Slope of AR is ‘b’ and MR is ‘2b’, so slope of MR is twice the slope
of AR.
2. Relation between AR, MR and Elasticity of Demand in case of a Monopoly
Total Revenue, TR = Price *Quantity = P*Q
Average Revenue, AR = TR/Q = P*Q)/Q = P
Marginal Revenue, MR = ΔTR/ΔQ = Δ (P*Q)/ΔQ = P (ΔQ/ ΔQ) +
Self-Instructional
18 Material Q (ΔP/ ΔQ)
Also, Ed = , (– ) 1/ Ed =
Substituting the value of Ed in Equation (1) we get
MR = P + P*[(– ) 1/ Ed], MR = P [1 – 1/ Ed ], MR = AR [1 – 1/ Ed ]
Above result shows relation between MR, AR and Elasticity of demand
in the below given results (Figure 1.1):
(a) If demand curve has unit elasticity i.e. Ed = 1, MR = 0
(b) If demand curve is relatively elastic i.e. Ed > 1, MR = Positive
(c) If demand curve is relatively inelastic i.e. Ed < 1, MR = Negative
3. Equilibrium Conditions
The objective of a monopolist is to earn profits and profits are maximized when
the following conditions are satisfied:
Total Profit (TP) = Total Revenue (TR) – Total Cost (TC)
To maximize profits the gap between total revenue and total cost should
be maximized, i.e., first differentiation is equated to zero
∂TP/ ∂Q = ∂TR/∂Q – ∂TC/∂Q = 0
= MR – MC = 0,
MR = MC .... 1st order condition
∂2TP/ ∂Q2 = ∂2TR/∂Q2 – ∂2TC/∂Q2 < 0
Slope of MR < Slope of MC .... 2nd order condition
4. Rule of Thumb Pricing for Monopoly Power
As shown above the equilibrium of a monopolist is at a point where marginal
revenue and marginal cost curves intersect but it is not always feasible for the
monopolist to trace the marginal revenue and marginal cost curves for all the
levels of output. Because of limited knowledge it is preferable to use a rule of
thumb for pricing as derived below. Self-Instructional
Material 19
Self-Instructional
20 Material
LESSON 2 NOTES
Structure
2.1 Learning Objectives
2.2 Introduction
2.3 Social Costs / Allocative Inefficiency of Monopoly
2.4 Comparison of Perfect Competition with Monopoly
2.5 Price Discrimination
2.6 Natural Monopoly
2.7 Antitrust Laws
2.8 Learning Outcome
2.9 Self Assessment Questions
2.2 INTRODUCTION
NOTES (raw material availability), economic barriers (economies of scale, cost advantage
or technological superiority) or legal barriers (patents, copyrights, trademarks).
Depending upon the monopoly power that a firm possesses, monopolist can
even go for price discrimination where it charges different prices from different
consumers for the same product. A pure monopoly situation can reduce the
consumer surplus (benefit of the society) to a great extent and hence it is
usually undesirable unless it is controlled by the state for welfare of the society
at large or it is a natural monopoly (where it is more efficient to let it serve the
entire market rather than to have several firms). This lesson discusses about the
difference between perfect competition and monopoly, the costs that society has
to bear because of monopoly and various types of price discrimination that a
monopolist can exercise.
In case of perfect competition, a firm sells a product at a point where Price (P) is
equal to marginal cost (MC) and there being no cost to the society. A monopolist
however sells at a price that is greater than its marginal cost as shown in Figure 2.1.
Demand curve of a perfectly competitive industry is downward sloping and supply
curve obtained from summation of the marginal cost curves is upward sloping.
Equilibrium of the industry is where demand is equal to supply, it gives OQpc,
i.e., quantity at OPpc price. If it would have been a monopoly then equilibrium
would be at a point where marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal which
is given by point A in the Figure 2.1, monopolist is selling OQm quantity at a
price of OPm. It can be seen that a monopolist sells lesser quantity as compared
to perfect competition and that too at a higher price. This leads to the cost that
society has to bear and termed as allocative inefficiency of monopoly market.
Self-Instructional
22 Material
NOTES
Fig. 2.1
NOTES To see how there is a change in the consumer and producer surplus on
conversion of a perfectly competitive industry to monopoly assuming the same
demand and cost conditions we make use of Figure 2.2.
Table 2.1
Fig. 2.2
is Qpc and price is Ppc. Here, the consumer surplus and producer surplus are NOTES
given in Table 2.1. Now if all the firms under perfectly competitive industry are
undertaken by a monopolist assuming that demand and cost conditions remain
same, the equilibrium is obtained by the intersection of MR and MC which
is at Em giving equilibrium quantity as Qm and price as Pm. It can be seen that
Monopolist is selling a lesser quantity and that too at a higher price. The new
consumer surplus and producer surplus are shown in the Table 2.1. To find out
whether consumers or producers are at loss or gain, we calculate the change in
consumer and producer surplus. It is seen that consumer surplus has reduced by
C + D + E, the reduction of C + D is because of a higher price that consumers
now have to pay while reduction in E is because of reduction in the quantity
as now few consumers have to do without the commodity. Producer surplus on
the other hand has increased by C + D but reduced by H. The increase of C +
D is because of higher price that producers get now; it is actually just a transfer
from consumers to producers (a zero sum game) and the loss in H is because of
reduction in quantity that producers sell now. To find out whether society as a
whole is at gain or loss, we add the change in consumer and producer surplus
and find out that society at large is at a loss of H+E, this being the dead weight
loss or cost to the society because of monopoly.
Self-Instructional
Material 25
NOTES 3. Entry and Exit of Firms: Pure competition provides free entry and exit to
the firms though it is possible only in the long run while monopoly prevents
entry of any new firm to the industry.
4. Profits in the Long run: In perfect competition firms earn normal profits
in the long run while monopolist usually has supernormal profits because
of barriers to entry and exit.
5. Demand curve of the firm: The firm in a perfect competition firm has no
control over the price as it is the industry which fixes the price, the demand
curve therefore is a straight line parallel to X axis at the price given by the
industry. But in the case of monopoly there is only one firm and there is
no difference between the firm and the industry and market demand curve
which is downward sloping is the demand curve of the firm itself.
6. Social cost: A perfectly competitive industry sets its equilibrium at a point
where demand and supply are equal; hence there is no cost to the society.
Monopolist sets a price according to MR = MC where P > MC which
brings cost to the society.
7. Price Discrimination: A perfectly competitive industry cannot discriminate
on the basis of price whereas a monopolist can follow price discrimination.
8. Supply curve of the firm: A perfectly competitive firm has one to one
relation between price and quantity supplied which is shown by the supply
curve which is the segment of marginal cost over and above the minimum
point of short run average variable cost curve. However, there is no supply
curve in case of monopoly as same quantity can be sold at two different
prices or two different quantities can be sold at the same price depending
upon the shape of demand curve and marginal cost curve.
9. Price and output comparison: Perfectly competitive firm sells a larger
output and that too at a lesser price as compared to a monopolist that sells
less and at a higher price as shown in Figure 2.3.
Self-Instructional
26 Material
NOTES
Fig. 2.3
Self-Instructional
Material 27
NOTES
Fig. 2.4
Self-Instructional
28 Material
First Degree Price Discrimination: There are two types of first-degree NOTES
price discrimination:
Case 1: The monopolist charges each consumer the maximum price that
he is willing to give – known as the reservation price thereby taking away all
the consumer surplus of the consumers. The demand curve here itself becomes
the marginal revenue curve. Impact of first-degree price discrimination is shown
in Figure 2.5.
Fig. 2.5
A single price monopolist charges OPm and sells OQm units of the commodity
by equating marginal revenue with the marginal cost. The consumer surplus here
is shown by the area APmB. Now if the monopolist goes for price discrimination,
then he would charge the maximum price that a consumer is willing to give
which is shown by the demand curve. Thus, here MR curve becomes irrelevant
as demand curve itself is the MR curve for the discriminating monopolist. The
consumer surplus is reduced to zero as whatever price the consumer is willing
Self-Instructional
Material 29
NOTES to give is charged by the monopolist. This is the highest form of discrimination
as nothing is left for the consumers as surplus. To see how the monopolist
is benefited by the price discrimination, we calculate incremental (variable)
profits before and after the discrimination. Variable profits are calculated as the
difference between Marginal revenue and marginal cost as it is the incremental
profit and not the total profits.
Incremental profit before price discrimination is shown by the area of
triangle ACEm.
Incremental profit after price discrimination is shown by the area of triangle
ACEpd.
Thus, increase in the incremental profit = ACEpd – ACEm = Area of triangle
AEmEpd. It is shown by the shaded area in the Figure 2.5.
However, there is a limitation of perfect first-degree price discrimination,
i.e., it is very difficult if not impossible to find out the reservation price for each
and every consumer. This type of price discrimination is thus not found in real
life, what we have is imperfect first-degree price discrimination.
Case 2: In case 1 as discussed above, the monopolist charges different price
from each consumer depending on how much he is willing to pay. There is an
alternative method as well. The monopolist can also charge a few different prices
based on the reservation prices of different groups of consumers. So here, there
are certain ranges for different consumers which a monopolist can still identify.
For example, a doctor can charge different fees depending upon the locality he
is operating in. It is being explained in Figure 2.6.
Self-Instructional
30 Material
NOTES
Fig. 2.6
A single price monopolist would have sold OQ* units and charged a single
price of OP3 from all the consumers. But in case of imperfect first-degree price
discrimination, monopolist sets 5 different prices that is P1, P2, P3, P4 and P5
which is being charged from different consumers on the basis of the price that
they are willing to pay. This type of discrimination is called imperfect as there
is still consumer surplus left with the consumers unlike perfect first-degree
discrimination. The price is set by identifying what the marginal (last) consumer
of that particular group is willing to pay. There can be various price bands and
monopoly equilibrium price can be one of them.
Second Degree Price Discrimination: A form of price discrimination
where different prices are charged from consumers on the basis of quantity
being purchased. Thus, more are the units purchased lesser is the price. Block
Self-Instructional
Material 31
Fig. 2.7
is the most common type of price discrimination. For the firm to successfully NOTES
follow third degree price discrimination, following conditions should be satisfied:
1. Firm is a monopolist.
2. The whole market is divided into sub-markets/subgroups. Let us assume
that there are two sub-markets/sub-groups.
3. Price elasticity of demand is different in the different sub-markets.
4. Sub-markets should be kept separate, i.e., it should not be possible for
the consumers to shift themselves from one submarket to the other.
5. It should not be possible to transfer goods from one sub-market to
the other otherwise arbitrage opportunities would eliminate the price
differential thereby making price discrimination infeasible.
Third degree price discrimination is explained with the help of Figure 2.8
wherein the total market of the monopolist is divided into two sub-markets. In
sub-market 1 as shown in Panel 1 of the figure 2.8, AR1 is the demand curve
which is inelastic and hence it is steeper showing that this sub-market is not that
responsive towards prices. MR1 is the corresponding marginal revenue curve. In
sub-market 2 as shown in Panel 2 of the same figure, AR2 is the demand curve that
has greater price elasticity and is therefore flatter showing higher responsiveness
of the group towards price changes. MR2 is the corresponding marginal revenue
curve. The demand curves for the total market of the monopolist are derived by
adding up the demand curves of these two sub-markets. Panel 3 of the figure
shows the total AR and MR curves as AR1+2 and MR1+2 respectively where AR1+2
= AR1 + AR2 and MR1+2 = MR1 +MR2.
Self-Instructional
Material 33
NOTES Total Revenue from first sub-market + Total Revenue from second sub-
market – Total cost
Π = TR1 + TR2 – TC
As per the marginal conditions stated above, first determine the equilibrium
point at E0 where MR1+2 = MC as shown in Panel 3 of the figure 2.8. The rate of
total quantity to be produced by the monopolist is given as Q0 which corresponds
to point E0. The price for this rate of output should have been P0 as per standard
practice of price setting by a monopolist which is done on the AR1+2 curve.
However, under price discrimination, the monopolist does not charge P0 price nor
does it sell Q0 quantity. Instead the monopolist divides the total market quantity
in two sub-markets by following the condition MR1+2 = MR1 = MR2 = MC.
Diagrammatically, this is done by drawing a horizontal line through the point
E0 such that the said line cuts MR1 at point E1 in sub-market 1 and MR2 at point
E2 in sub-market 2. Accordingly, in sub-market 1, rate of quantity corresponding
to equilibrium point E1 will be Q1 and price on its inelastic AR1 curve will be set
at P1. Similarly, in sub-market 2, rate of quantity corresponding to equilibrium
point E2 will be Q2 and price on its relatively elastic AR2 curve will be set at P2.
See that Q0 = Q1 + Q2. It can also be verified that P1 and P2 are not equal; rather
P1 > P2 showing that a relatively elastic demand curve commands a lower price
as compared to relatively inelastic one. So, for the same good the monopolist is
charging two different prices in two different sub-markets which conforms to
price discrimination which is mainly made possible due to different elasticities
of demand in these two sub-markets.
In the equilibrium MR1 = MR2, thus equating equations (1) and (2) we get: NOTES
MR1 = MR2
P1 (1 + 1/ Ed1) = P2 (1 + 1/ Ed2 )
P1/ P2 = (1 + 1/ Ed2)/ (1 + 1/ Ed1) ………………………. (3)
From Equation (3) there can be two cases:
(a) If Ed1 = Ed2, then P1 = P2
(b) Ed1 │ < │Ed2│, P1 > P2
Fig. 2.8
Natural Monopoly occurs in case of Public utilities like Electricity, water supply,
telephone services, etc., where initial cost of the Plant remains higher but after
that cost starts falling and output increases. That’s why under Natural Monopoly
Average Cost and Marginal Cost Curves are downward sloping and MC is always
lower (below) Average Cost. When there are no regulations imposed on Natural
Monopoly then they will Produce Qm quantity and sell at Pm price. But if Natural
Monopoly is regulated then the firm’s Price go down to the competitive market
level Pc and quantity increases by Qc. At the Price of Pc firm would not cover
average cost and firm will shut down or go out from business. So, the ideal option
is to set the price Pn where AC, and AR intersect each other. Here firms are not Self-Instructional
Material 35
NOTES getting anormal monopoly profit but will produce large quantity of output Qn
and without driving the firm out of business.
Fig. 2.9
puts restrictions on unfair trade practices, and anti-competitive practices such NOTES
as fraudulent advertising and labelling, agreements with retailers to exclude
competing brands, and so on. Because these prohibitions are interpreted and
enforced in administrative proceedings before the FTC, the act provides broad
powers that reach further than those of other antitrust laws.
NOTES
2.9 SELF ASSESSMENT QUESTIONS
LESSON 3 NOTES
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
Prof. J. Khuntia
Professor
School of Open Learning
University of Delhi
Structure
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Learning Objectives
3.3 Features of Monopolistic Competition
3.4 Average and Marginal Revenue Curves under Monopolistic Competition
3.5 Equilibrium of A Firm Under Monopolistic Competition
3.6 Excess Capacity under Monopolistic Competition
3.7 Perfect vs Monopolistic Competition: A Comparison
3.8 Learning Outcomes
3.9 Recommended Readings
3.1 INTRODUCTION
Perfect competition and monopoly are far removed from the real world market
situations. These two extremes are only theoretical constructs made to simplify
analysis. Competition and monopoly are matters of degree rather than of
monopoly and competition in different degrees. Price taking (i.e., complete
absence of individual influence on the market price) and full freedom of entry and
exit of capital from the industry are the two basic features of perfect competition.
The conditions necessary to ensure the above-mentioned features have already
been explained in sufficient detail. Whenever, one or more of the conditions
necessary for perfect competition are violated, competition becomes imperfect.
For example, the number of buyers and sellers may not be very large and as
a result an individual buyer or seller may be able to exercise some “influence
over the market price of the product by increasing or decreasing his sales or Self-Instructional
Material 39
NOTES purchases. Number of producers may be small due to a variety of reasons such
as economies of scale, initial cost disadvantage, difficulties in mobilizing the
required quantum of capital, and so on. Secondly, the products of different sellers
may not be identical in the eyes of the buyers (i.e., there may be real or imaginary
differences between the products of different producer). Thirdly, buyers may not
have perfect knowledge about the price offers of different producers. Or they
may be aware of the price offers of different sellers but because of transport costs
involved due to the locations of different sellers or simply because of inertia or
irrational preferences), they may be reluctant to shift their purchases from one
seller to another. Finally, quite apart from inertia ignorance, customers have a
number of good reasons for preferring one seller to another. Different customers
are affected differently by factors such as the guarantee of quality provided by a
well-known name or brand, difference in facilities provided by different sellers’
quickness of service, good manners of salesmen, length of credit, attention paid
to individual wants, advertisement, etc. Thus, there can be several reasons for
imperfection of competition.
Self-Instructional
40 Material
NOTES
3.3 FEATURES OF MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
NOTES 7. There is absence of perfect mobility of factors in the market due to lack
of perfect knowledge.
Self-Instructional
42 Material
NOTES
Fig. 3.1
In-Text Questions
Choose the right answer.
A. Demand curves under monopolistic competition are Elastic/Inelastic.
B. Monopolistic competition is identified with close substitutes / no
substitutes.
Monopoly and perfect competition are two extreme market forms. As pointed out
earlier, pure monopoly and perfect competition do not represent the real world
market situations. Real world market situations are characterized by a blend
of monopoly and competition in different degrees. Like monopoly, imperfect
competition also is typically characterized by a downward sloping AR curve.
The corresponding MR curve lies below the AR curve.
We have the same set of cost curves whatever the market situation.
Self-Instructional
Material 43
Given the cost and revenue curves, equilibrium requires the satisfaction of the
same condition, that is:
(1) MC = MR
(2) MO > MR beyond the point of their equality
Figures 3.2 and 3.3 below depict two possible short-run equilibrium
positions of a firm under imperfect competition.
Unlike monopoly freedom of entry and exit of firms from the industry is the
distinguishing feature of imperfect competition. Therefore, equilibrium positions
with abnormal profits or losses are sustainable only in the short run but not in
the long run. If the firms in the industry are earning abnormal profits and if this
situation is expected to persist in the long run, this will attract new firms into
the industry. As more firms enter the industry, the given market demand for the
product will be shared by a larger number of firms so that each will have a smaller
share of the market demand. As a result, at any given price an individual firm will
be able to sell less than before. In other words, as a result of the influx of new
firms into the industry, each firm’s AR curve (i.e., the demand curve) will shift
leftward. This process will continue so long as there are any abnormal profits to
be earned in the industry. Ultimately the firm’s AR curve becomes tangential to
the U-shaped average cost curve at some point on its falling portion. When AR
curve becomes tangential to the average cost curve, price equals cost and thus,
abnormal profits are completely wiped out. Figure 3.4 shows how, because of
the influx of new firms into the industry firm’s AR curve is pushed leftward and
ultimately becomes tangential to the average cost curve.
Figure 3.2 depicts a possible short run equilibrium position in which the
firm is earning abnormal profits equal to the area of the rectangle PECB. Because
of the influx of new firms into the industry, the firm’s AR curve is pushed leftward
and ultimately (as shown in Figure 3.4) becomes tangential to the average cost
curve at B. At B price average cost and the firm earns only normal profits. When
firms in the industry earn only normal profits, there is no incentive left for new
firms to enter into the industry.
Self-Instructional
Material 45
NOTES
Fig. 3.4
On the other hand, if firms in the industry are incurring losses, and when
this situation is expected to persist in the long run, firms start leaving the industry
for better prospects elsewhere. With the exit of some of the firms from the
industry, the given market demand for the product comes to be shared by fewer
firms and their AR curves shift rightward. The process of the exit of firms from
the industry and the resulting rightward shift of the AR and MR curves continues
till the AR curves ultimately becomes tangential to the U-shaped average cost
curves on their falling portions. When AR curve becomes tangential to the average
cost curve and a firm earns only normal profits, it is said to be in its long run
equilibrium. When all firms in the industry earn only normal profits, there is no
incentive for firms to leave the industry and the number of firms neither tends
to increase nor tends to decrease. When this situation takes place, the industry
is said to be in its long run equilibrium.
We saw that the firms under both perfect as well as imperfect competitions
earn normal profits in the long run by selling at a price equal to the long run
Self-Instructional average cost (LAC). However, the difference is that while price under perfect
46 Material
competition equals minimum of LAC where output is larger, the price under NOTES
imperfect competition is determined at a point where LAC is still falling. This
means that the LAC is not minimized under imperfect competition at equilibrium.
Minimization of LAC is called productive efficiency. So, by not minimizing
LAC and producing on the falling portion of LAC the imperfectly competitive
firm produces less than competitive output by not utilizing its plant capacity.
So imperfectly competitive firm is productive inefficient while competitive firm
is productive efficient. This is also referred to as excess capacity of imperfect
competition which is measured as the difference between output produced at the
minimum point of LAC, i.e., competitive output and the output produced at some
point on the falling portion of LAC even though it corresponds to equilibrium
between MR and MC under imperfect competition.
Figure 3.5 shows the situation of excess capacity.
In the Figure 3.5, the long run average cost curve is shown as LAC. A
firm under imperfect competition produces at point A on LAC where LAC is
still falling and tangent to its demand curve ARM. The output of imperfectly
competitive firm is Q1. On the other hand, a competitive firm produces Q at the
0
minimum of LAC curve. The range AB on LAC curve showing the difference
in output as Q –Q is the measure of excess capacity.
0 1
Self-Instructional
Fig. 3.5 Material 47
NOTES
3.7 PERFECT VS MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION:
A COMPARISON
price of a commodity equals its minimum average cost. (You may recall under NOTES
perfect competition in long run equilibrium the horizontal AR/MR curve becomes
tangential to the U-shaped AC curve necessarily at its lowest point).
Even though under imperfect competition (as under perfect competition)
long-run equilibrium requires MC = MR and AC = AR. By virtue of the MR
curve always lying below the AR curve, MC will necessarily be less than AC.
MC is less than AC when the latter is falling. This implies that under imperfect
competition long-run equilibrium will take place on the falling portion of the
AC curve, in other words, in long run equilibrium under imperfect competition
price will necessarily be higher than the minimum average cost.
(4) As explained above, under perfect competition long-run equilibrium
takes place necessarily at the lowest point on the AC curve whereas under
imperfect competition it takes place to the left of the lowest point on the AC
curves. From this, it follows that level of output under perfect competition will
be optimum while under imperfect competition it will be less than optimum. In
other words, under imperfect competition productive capacity is underutilized.
Self-Instructional
Material 49
1. What are the features of monopolistic competition? How are they different
from perfect competition?
2. Explain determination of short run and long run equilibrium of firm under
monopolistic competition.
3. Write a short note on excess capacity under monopolistic competition.
Self-Instructional
50 Material
LESSON 4 NOTES
OLIGOPOLY
Prof. J. Khuntia
Professor
School of Open Learning
University of Delhi
Structure
4.1 Learning Objectives
4.2 Introduction
4.3 Features of Oligopoly
4.4 Behaviour of Oligopoly Firms
4.5 Equilibrium in Oligopoly
4.6 Models of Non-Collusive Oligopoly
4.7 Summary
4.8 Self Assessment Questions
4.9 Recommended Readings
4.2 INTRODUCTION
Monopoly and perfect competition are those types of market structures which
are at the two ends of a market continuum and do not really exist except in case
of monopolies that are owned and regulated by the state. The types of markets
Self-Instructional
that actually exist consist of firms that belong to either monopolistic competition Material 51
NOTES or oligopoly. While in monopolistic competition there are many firms selling
products that are differentiated but are close substitutes of each other and there
is no barrier to entry or exit, but in case of oligopoly there are few large firms
that sell products which can be homogeneous or differentiated and there are
strong barriers to entry and exit. Both monopolistic and oligopoly firms have
monopoly power that enables them to be the price makers unlike the firms in
perfect competition that are just the price takers. This lesson would talk about
oligopoly and its different types that are actually seen in the market along with
deriving equilibrium in case of collusive as well as non-collusive oligopolies.
Oligopoly has been derived from Oligo + Polein, Oligo meaning few and polein
means to sell. Oligopoly can thus be defined as: “A market structure characterized
by few large sellers selling homogeneous or differentiated products, having strong
barriers to entry and exit and firms recognize their mutual interdependence.”
When oligopolist firms are selling homogeneous products, it is called pure
oligopoly and if they are selling differentiated products then it is called impure
oligopoly. In case there are just two sellers in the oligopolist market structure
then it is a special case called Duopoly.
Characteristics of Oligopoly
1. Few Large Sellers: Oligopoly consists of just few sellers that control the
whole market and hence the market share of each seller is quite large.
2. Homogeneous or Differentiated Products: Oligopoly can be pure
oligopoly where the sellers are selling homogeneous products like in the
case of LPG cylinders or it can be impure oligopoly where sellers are selling
differentiated products like in case of automobile industry. An important
point to note here is that differentiation can be real (where the composition
of the products is actually different) or perceived (where there is no actual
difference between the products, but consumers perceive it to be different
because of aggressive advertisement, etc.)
Self-Instructional
52 Material
3. Strong Barriers to Entry and Exit: New firms are not prohibited from NOTES
entering the market though there are strong barriers that hinder their entry,
it can be because of the cost advantage of the existing firms, economies
of scale that existing firms enjoy or huge capital requirements or any such
reason.
4. Interdependence: This is one of the most significant and distinguishing
features of oligopoly firms, that arises because of the fact that there are few
firms and share of each firm is quite significant, thus if any firm changes
its strategy with respect to price, promotion or any such variable it is
bound to impact the other firms and they would retaliate. Therefore, each
firm before bringing a change in any of its variables should consider the
possible reaction of the rival firms.
5. Advertisement: It is one of the instruments that the oligopoly firms
frequently use and it is one of the most powerful weapons that they can
use against the rivals. Instead of changing the prices often, firms go for
this as prices are usually rigid because of the fear that price changes can
lead to a price war.
There are instances of both co-operation and competition among firms under
oligopoly. They are explained below. There could be distinctive behavioural
pattern in the long run as well.
NOTES joint profit. Such agreements at international level is called Cartel, many such
agreements have taken place in the past. The best example of a cartel in the past
is that of OPEC - Oil Producing and Exporting Countries. Saudi Arabia and other
countries after 1973 formed a cartel. An individual firm always has incentive to
cheat. Possibility of cheating is larger if the number of firms is large. Cheating
by a small firm has negligible effect on the market price.
Tacit Co-operation: When firms co-operate without any explicit agreement
is called tacit co-operation. For example, if firm A produces one-half of monopoly
output hoping that firm B will do the same and firm B does so then they achieve
the co-operative equilibrium without any formal agreement.
Self-Instructional
54 Material
In the long run, when oligopolistic firms earn abnormal profits by increasing
their prices over and above total average cost, new firms are attracted to this
industry. In such a situation, entry barriers become important for the existing
firms to sustain the abnormal profits. In the absence of natural oligopolists do
create barriers to restrict the new firms.
Some of the firm-created barriers are as follows:
(a) Brand Proliferation – It is a situation when the existing firms under
oligopoly produce multiple products with differentiated features
and capture major share in the market due to their brand image. For
example in the automobile industry all existing branded companies
produce various models of cars with different features. It becomes
difficult for a new firm to compete with the existing multi product
branded firms. New firms entering the market with single product can
fetch very share in the market. Through advertisement and innovative
marketing strategies consumers are made so brand savvy that they
do not want to buy non-branded (local) products. Branded products
are considered superior than the non-branded products.
(b) Set-up Costs – Oligopolistic firms can restrict entry of new firms
by imposing high fixed cost. This becomes possible in an industry
where sales are promoted by huge advertisement. Oligopolistic firms
spend a huge amount on advertisement to shift the demand in their
favour. New firms can not afford to spend such a huge amount in the
beginning with a little share in the market. Chances of loss always
keep the new firms away in such a situation.
(c) Predatory Pricing – It is a situation when the existing firms in
oligopolistic market cut their prices below costs when they expect
that new firms will enter the market. A new firm will not enter the
market if it expects losses after entry. New firms are often discouraged
by the existing firms through predatory pricing. This strategy may
be costly since the existing firms need to cut the price below the
average variable cost in the short run but it creates profit as well as
Self-Instructional
good reputation in the long run for the existing firms. Material 55
NOTES
4.5 EQUILIBRIUM IN OLIGOPOLY
Cournot Model
The model was given by Augustin Cournot in 1838 based on only two firms that
were selling homogeneous products (spring water). It is based on the following
Self-Instructional assumptions:
56 Material
Self-Instructional
Material 57
NOTES
Fig. 4.1
Similarly, we can have the reaction schedule for Firm 2 and when the
reaction schedules are plotted on a graph, we will get the reaction curves. The
point of intersection of the two reaction curves is the Cournot Equilibrium
determining the output of the two firms as is shown in Figure 4.2.
Self-Instructional
58 Material
NOTES
Fig. 4.2
Cournot model assumed that both the firms set their output simultaneously
however Stackelberg model assumes that the firms do not take their decision
Self-Instructional
Material 59
NOTES simultaneously. There are two firms in this model where one sets its output first
and then the second firm enters. This model is based on the following assumptions:
1. Duopoly model– Two firms A and B
2. Straight linear demand curves
3. There is zero marginal cost for both the firms.
4. One firm is the leader that sets its output first and the second is the follower
who is behaving as per Cournot assumption (assumes that the leader
would keep its output constant). A firm can act as the leader because of its
knowledge, experience or sophistication.
5. There is no collusion between the firms, both the firms act independently.
6. Both the firms are selling homogeneous products.
The model is thus an attempt to find answer to two questions:
1. Is it advantageous to enter the market first?
2. How much output would each firm produce?
Cournot vs Stackelberg: A question now arises is that out of the two
models both of which belong to non-collusive oligopoly, which one is more
suitable. The answer depends on whether the industry comprises of the firms
that are similar, of equal size and none having a leadership position, Cournot
model is more suitable, whereas in an industry where one firm has a sophisticated
(leadership) position over the others, Stackelberg model should be preferred.
SWEEZY’S KINKED DEMAND MODEL
Paul Sweezy gave the kinked demand curve model in 1939 based on
the great Depression of US that showed that the prices in an oligopoly market
structure are sticky (rigid), firms here recognize their interdependence but act
without collusion. The model lays more emphasis on explaining the stickiness of
prices rather than to determine the equilibrium price and quantity. Sweezy showed
that during depression if any firm increased its price, no other firm would follow
and hence the reduction in the quantity of the firm that raised the price would
be huge as majority of the customers would shift to the competitors whereas if
firm reduced its price, all the other firms would follow and hence change in the
Self-Instructional
60 Material
quantity would be little. This is the reason behind the kinked demand curve as NOTES
it consists of two segments – one that is relatively elastic (with price increase)
and the other relatively inelastic (with price decrease). The kink is at the existing
price and that is where the prices remain stuck. This can be explained using the
Figure 4.3.
Fig. 4.3
Figure 4.3 shows that demand curve consists of two segments – one that
is relatively elastic which is above the equilibrium price of OP* showing that if
the firm increases its price above OP* then none of the other firms would follow
it and hence only its quantity would reduce. It is represented by segment ‘DA’
of the demand curve. However, the other segment is ‘AD1’ which is relatively
inelastic showing that if firm reduces its price all other firms would follow and
hence the change in its quantity would be little. Thus, combining both the demand
curves we get a kinked demand curve DAD1 where kink is at the prevailing price.
The corresponding marginal revenue curve (MR) is actually a combination of
three segments:
Self-Instructional
Material 61
1. The model is applicable in the times of depression and does not talk about
the boom period.
2. The model said that kink is at the prevailing price but how that prevailing
price is obtained is not clear.
3. Economist Stigler found the model to be empirically unfit to be tested.
4. The model talks about movement of marginal cost within the vertical
stretch, it does not talk about what would be the change in the equilibrium
if marginal cost moves beyond the vertical segment.
4.7 SUMMARY
Oligopoly is a market structure with the presence of few sellers and each seller
Self-Instructional
having a large market share. The most distinguishing feature of oligopoly is the
62 Material
recognition of mutual interdependence. Firms know that their actions would not NOTES
go unnoticed by the competitors and hence the counter strategy that the rivals
take have to be considered before bringing any changes in the existing variables.
The demand curve of an oligopolist is indeterminate because of the inability
to predict the rival’s behaviour and its impact on the firm itself. Economists
however have given various models which are based on certain assumptions
about the rival’s reaction. All these models can be broadly divided into collusive
and non-collusive. This lesson has talked about the non-collusive model in
which firms recognize their interdependence but do not collude. There are three
models under this category namely, Cournot Duopoly model, Stackelberg first
mover advantage model and Paul Sweezy’s Kinked demand curve model. All
these models talk about how firms reach their equilibrium position after taking
into consideration the rival’s action. Cournot suggested that in case there are two
firms selling identical products with zero cost of production, both firms would
simultaneously decide to produce an output that would be ultimately equal.
Stackelberg however showed that the first mover to the market is benefited as it
is able to sell an output that is double as compared to the follower. Paul Sweezy
did not only talk about the equilibrium determination but also showed that during
the times of recession, firms usually keep their prices fixed and compete on the
basis of non-price variables as frequent price changes may lead to price war
which is not beneficial for the market as a whole.
Self-Instructional
64 Material
LESSON 5 NOTES
COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY
Reena Bajaj
Guest Faculty
University of Delhi
Structure
5.1 Objective
5.2 Introduction
5.3 Models of Collusive Oligopoly
5.4 Prisoner’s Dilemma
5.5 Self Assessment Questions
5.6 Game Theory: Example
5.7 Ligopoly and the Functioning of The Economy
5.8 Contestable Markets and Potential Entry
5.9 Learning Outcome
5.10 Terminal Questions
5.1 OBJECTIVE
5.2 INTRODUCTION
Oligopoly, a market structure having few sellers with each having a large market
share, provides the firm with the power to set their prices depending upon the
monopoly power that each firm enjoys. Here the firms have the option to compete
with one another as they recognize that they are mutually interdependent, or Self-Instructional
Material 65
NOTES they can collude and enjoy monopoly benefits. The former known as non-
collusive oligopoly models have been discussed in the previous lesson and this
lesson would talk about the models of collusive oligopoly. This collusion can be
explicit or implicit. Explicit collusion is where firms have proper written, formal
agreement amongst themselves to collude, though these types of collusions are
usually not permitted by the countries. Implicit collusion on the other hand is
said to be where there is no written formal agreement between the firms but they
implicitly collude and work in tandem to avoid the costs of competition and reap
the benefits of monopoly.
OPEC is a cartel of oil and captures majority of the oil reserves of the world. It is
an explicit cartel where there is a written formal agreement between the countries
to abide by the price set and other regulations. It is an example of a cartel that
has been successful in raising the prices for the firms than what would have been
there if there was pure competition. It can be explained using Figure 5.1:
Self-Instructional
Material 67
NOTES
Fig. 5.1
DD1 is the market demand curve of oil which is relatively inelastic as there
is no substitute of oil; Snon– opec is the supply curve of all those countries (firms)
combined together that have not joined the cartel and hence are competing with
each other and the cartel. It is also relatively inelastic as the supply of oil is also
limited as it being a natural resource. It is obtained by the summation of the
marginal cost of these firms and can be seen that the cost of non-OPEC firms is
quite high. Now the first step is to locate the demand curve of the OPEC which
is obtained by setting different prices and finding out how much of the market
demand would be left for the OPEC after the rest has been supplied by the non-
OPEC firms combined together. If OPEC sets the price as P1 which is obtained
from the intersection of market demand curve and supply curve of the non-OPEC
then the whole market demand can be satisfied by them and hence nothing
would be left for the OPEC to supply. Thus here the demand from the OPEC is
zero. If however it sets the price at P2 which is so low that the non-OPEC firms
would not supply anything then the whole market demand is to be fulfilled by
the OPEC. It is shown by point A on the market demand curve. Thus the demand
curve of the OPEC is kinked ‘P1AD1’ and the corresponding marginal revenue
curve is MRopec., marginal cost curve is MCopec. The equilibrium price that would
Self-Instructional prevail in the market is given by MRopec = MCopec which is the profit maximizing
68 Material
condition for OPEC that is the price maker. Thus the equilibrium price is OP* NOTES
at which the OPEC sells OQopec units and all the competitive firms combined
sells OQnon– opec such that
OQopec + OQnon– opec = OQtotal and
OQopec > OQnon– opec
To see whether OPEC has been successful or not we compare the price
difference between what OPEC has set and what would have been there if there
was no cartelization and all firms would have competed freely. In the latter case,
price would have been where demand curve of OPEC and MCopec intersect. Thus,
the difference is huge as shown by the difference between P* and Ppc which
shows significant monopoly power that OPEC enjoys.
(i) OPEC action of restricting its output caused increase in supply of oil by
non-OPEC countries because of increase in price. This caused shift in
supply curve of these countries to the right. The share of OPEC declined.
By 1985, it reduced to 30 percent. The price fell and in order to maintain
the price OPEC had to further reduce its output.
(ii) Secondly, the long run demand curve becomes more elastic as compared
to the short-run demand curve in above diagram. This is because people
have to spend their money more on insulation of oil heated buildings,
economical diesel engines, etc. In the very long run more money was
diverted for research to develop more petroleum efficient and alternative
technologies such as solar technology, etc. All these resulted in fall of
OPEC exports. Production limitations continued to maintain the price at
high level.
(iii) Because of heavy reduction in output to maintain price, OPEC started
experiencing fall in income. Disturbed by this development, members
started violating their quotas and had to meet frequently to settle things.
Ultimately OPEC had to eliminate quotas by 1985. The price fluctuated
before settling down in the 1990s.
Self-Instructional
Material 69
CIPEC is a cartel of copper and captures only 30% of the copper producing
countries of the world. It is also an explicit cartel like OPEC where there is a
written formal agreement between the countries to abide by the price set and
other regulations. As against OPEC, it is an example of a cartel that has been
unsuccessful in raising the prices of copper in the international market. It can
be explained using Figure 5.2.
DD1 is the market demand curve of copper which is relatively elastic NOTES
because of the fact that there are substitutes of copper like aluminium, etc. Supply
curve of the non-CIPEC countries (firms) is Scipec that is also relatively elastic
because of the fact that supply of copper can be easily obtained from scrap, etc.
Demand curve and marginal revenue curve of the CIPEC is obtained in the same
manner as done for OPEC taking into consideration the non-collusive countries.
The equilibrium price is set by CIPEC which is obtained from equating marginal
revenue and marginal cost of the CIPEC. It is point E where price is set at OP*
and quantity sold by CIPEC is OQcipec and by non-CIPEC is OQnon– cipec. Here it
can be noted that the quantity sold by non-CIPEC is more than that of CIPEC as
CIPEC is a minority cartel where only 8 countries have joined the cooperation.
The monopoly power here is also very less as there is very small difference
between the price that would have prevailed in case of pure competition shown
by Ppc and cartel price OP*.
So, we can conclude by saying that though OPEC has been successful
in raising the prices of oil in the international market but CIPEC has been
unsuccessful at doing so. It can be because of the following reasons:
1. OPEC is a big cartel that consists of majority of countries that produce
oil whereas CIPEC is a minority cartel where only few firms have joined
the cartel.
2. OPEC is a cartel of oil whose demand and supply both are relatively
inelastic providing it a better scope for exploiting its monopoly power
whereas CIPEC is a cartel of copper whose demand and supply both
are relatively elastic thus providing lesser monopoly power.
3. The difference between the cost of the cartel firms and the competitive
firms (those which have not joined the cartel) is quite large as OPEC
firms produce at a much lesser cost whereas in CIPEC this difference
is not quite significant.
These reasons have led to the success of OPEC and the failure of CIPEC
and from this we can summarize a few conditions that are required for successful
functioning of a cartel:
Self-Instructional
Material 71
NOTES 1. The demand for the commodity for which cartel has been made should
be relatively inelastic.
2. The firms that join cartel should be able to control majority of the
world’s supply.
Centralized Cartel
This is an extreme form of cartel and rarely visible in real life as it assumes that
all the firms join the cooperation and none of the firms is outside the cartel. This
cartel thus acts as a monopoly where there is a centralized body that sets the price
and quantity that is equal to the monopoly and then allocates the total output and
total profits amongst different cartel members. If we assume that there are four
firms in the market, and all have same costs of production then the output and
price determination can be shown using Figure 5.3.
Dmarket is the total demand curve of the market and MR is the corresponding
marginal revenue curve. MCtotal is the summation of the marginal cost curves of
the four firms combined together. Equilibrium is obtained by the intersection of
marginal revenue and marginal cost curves and it is at point E where the price
is OP* and the quantity is OQt. The centralized authority would distribute the
output equally between the four firms such that each firm sells OQt/4 output at
a price of OP* per unit.
Above three cases of cartel showed that it is very difficult if not impossible
for a cartel to be successful as there is incentive for a firm to cheat on the cartel
and earn even higher profits than what it could have earned by being a member
of the cartel. This has been explained by a model of Game Theory known as
Prisoner’s Dilemma.
Self-Instructional
72 Material
NOTES
Fig. 5.3
Prisoner’s Dilemma is a model that explains how oligopolist firms could act
to their mutual disadvantage. The prisoner’s dilemma is a paradox in decision
analysis in which two individuals acting in their own best interest pursue a course
of action that does not result in the ideal outcome. It shows why firms cheat and
get a worse result than what would have been if they would have cooperated. It
is based on the concept of Game Theory, a mathematical technique that helps
in understanding the nature of interdependence among rival firms that are faced
with uncertainty in their pricing and output decision. A game is described by
its payoffs, strategies, number of players and information available. Prisoner’s
Dilemma can be explained with the help of following case:
Self-Instructional
Material 73
NOTES There are two friends A and B, who are suspects in a crime and are being
interrogated in separate rooms such that they cannot communicate with each
other. The two strategies available with them (to confess the crime or to not
confess) with their respective payoffs are given in the matrix below:
B
Confess Do not Confess
Confess B = 10 years B = 20 years
A = 10 years A = 2 years
A
Thus the matrix above reveals why A and B both have an incentive to cheat
(confess) while it would have been best for both of them to have cooperated
by not confessing. If both A and B confessed then both would get 10 years
imprisonment. The best however would have been where both do not confess
and get away with 4 years of imprisonment. If however one of them confesses
while the other does not confess then the one who confesses gets away with a
lesser imprisonment of just 2 years. Thus both think that it is best for them to
confess thinking that the other would not confess and both get away with 10 years
of imprisonment. This shows how prisoners thinking for their individual best
bring an outcome that is worse for them as well as for the group. The same can
be applied to the oligopoly where firms try to maximize their individual gains
by cheating on the other and hence get away with the profits that are worse for
the group as a whole. The above matrix can be modified to show the situation
for oligopoly as well if we assume that there are just two firms C and D with
the strategies available to them being that of to cheat or not to cheat on the price
being decided collectively.
D
Cheat Do not Cheat
Cheat D = Low Profits D = Very Low Profits
C = Low Profits C = Very High Profits
C
The matrix above revealed that if two firms C and D colluded, they could NOTES
have fixed up monopoly price and earned monopoly profits or high profits. If
however a firm tries to cheat on the cartel by charging a lower price assuming
that the other firm would not cheat and keep the price high as set by the collusion
then the firm which cheats or lowers the price earns very high profits and the
firm that does not cheat earns very low profits. This makes both the firms to
cheat on the cartel and both the firms reduce the price and hence they end up
earning low profits.
The prisoner’s dilemma shows that oligopolists always follow a strategy
that leads to competition amongst firms and leads to lower profit. But if the
game is repeated again and again the outcome can change as firms may learn
from their past outcome.
Self-Instructional
Material 75
The Table 5.1 above explains the dilemma faced by oligopolists of whether NOTES
to co-operate or to compete. It is called Payoff Matrix for a two firm duopoly
game. The right-side figures on each cell shows the profits of firm A and left side
figures on each cell show the profits of firm B (in Rs. Crores). It can be explained
that if the two firms co-operate and produce one half of market share each, they
will earn Rs. 20 crores of profit. In case of co-operation they can maximize their
profits. If firm A defects and produces two thirds of output and firm B produces
half of monopoly output, then firm A will earn Rs. 22 crores and firm B Rs. 15
crores. Similarly, if firm B defects and produces two-third and firm A produces
one-half then firm B will earn Rs. 22 crores and firm A will earn only Rs. 15
crores. If both decide to compete and produce two-third of monopoly output each
then profits for both will fall to Rs. 17 crores. This type of game, where they
reach a non-cooperative solution when they could co-operate, is called Prisoner’s
Dilemma. Prisoner’s Dilemma is shown in Table 5.2.
Table 5.2 The Prisoner’s Dilemma
Mr. Ram
Confess Not confess
Mr. Shyam Confess 6 6 0 9
Not confess 9 0 1 1
Two prisoners Mr. Ram and Mr. Shyam are arrested for committing a crime
and interrogated separately. They are told the following:
(a) If both are claimed to be innocent, they will get a light sentence that
is 1 year in jail.
(b) If one confesses and the other does not, then who confesses will be
released free and the other will be punished for 9 year in jail, and
(c) If both confess, then both of them will get a-punishment of 6 years
in jail.
The payoff matrix presented in Table 5.2 shows the dilemma of the
prisoners about whether to confess or not to confess. If none of them confesses
then both will get 1 year of jail, but if Ram confesses and Shyam does not then
Self-Instructional
Material 77
NOTES Ram will be left free and Shyam will get 9 year of imprisonment and the vice-
versa. And if both of them confess then both will get 6 years of imprisonment.
Not confessing is the best solution in this game (Pareto efficient solution) but
this leaves one always in uncertainty. This solution is not a stable solution as one
gets an imprisonment of 9 years if he/she does not confess and the other does.
Therefore, confession dominates in the mind of both the prisoners. If both of
them confess then they end up with 6 years jail each. This kind of equilibrium
is called Nash equilibrium. From both the figures above it is clear that if they
co-operate, they will earn the maximum profit than if they compete.
the new firms, unless natural and/ or firm-created barriers exist to restrict entry NOTES
of new firms in the market.
3. Very long-run competition
To survive in the long run, oligopolists keep on innovating to upgrade the quality
of product and minimize their cost of production. Each firm spends significant
amount on Research and Development to produce better quality at minimum
costs. Differentiated products with different character are available in oligopoly
market. Consumers get more choice in the market. Consumers get quality
products at competitive rates. Oligopoly market structure is more conducive to
economic growth in the long-run.
The theory of contestable markets explains that in the long-run, abnormal profits
earned by oligopolists can be eliminated without actual entry. Potential entry can
also affect the market as much as an actual entry does. It is possible only when
the following two conditions are fulfilled
1. Entry must be easy to accomplish: There should not exist any barriers
to entry, either natural or firm-created.
2. The existing firms must consider potential entry while making price
and output decisions: The existing firms must react when new firms try
to enter into the market. They must cut their prices and sacrifice profits
(short run) to restrict the new entrants.
Contestable markets always expect potential entry because of huge profits
earned by the existing firms in the market. But entry to such markets is too
costly. Fixed costs are very high. To develop, design, and sell a new product in
such a market involve huge sunk cost. Sunk costs are those costs which cannot
be recovered if a firm leaves the market soon. Firms which produce multiple
and differentiated products can easily distribute these costs among those many
products. For new firms, producing huge number of differentiated products is
Self-Instructional
Material 79
NOTES not easy. Therefore, these costs are very high for a firm which produces single
product in the market.
If a new firm can enter and leave the market without any sunk costs of
entry, such markets are called perfectly contestable markets. A market can be
perfectly contestable, even if, firms have to pay some costs of entry if these
costs are recovered when firms leave the market. If the sunk costs are lower, the
market will be more contestable and vice-versa.
Sunk costs of entry constitute entry barriers. Higher the sunk costs, larger
will be profits earn by the existing firms. If the firms operate in the market
without, large sunk costs of entry, then they will not earn large profits. As part
of strategy, existing firms keep their prices as low as that can only cover the total
costs. If they charge high prices and earn abnormal profits then the new firms will
enter and may capture the profits and leave until it is vanished. Contestability
forces the existing firms to keep the prices low. Potential entry works as good as
actual entry in a contestable market to limit the profits of existing firms.
Oligopoly, a market structure that is most common in the real world consists of
two different categories – collusive and non-collusive. This lesson talked about
collusive oligopoly where collusion can be explicit and there is a proper written
formal agreement between the firms to decide the price and output that each
firm would produce and sell. Its most common form is Cartel, but this type of
collusion is usually not allowed by the countries’ legislation as it can lead to the
creation of monopoly that can exploit the consumers. Two most famous cartels
are OPEC – cartel of oil producing countries and CIPEC – a cartel of copper
producing countries. While OPEC has been successful in raising the prices by
cartelization, CIPEC is an unsuccessful cartel because of the reason that demand,
and supply of oil is relatively inelastic whereas that of copper is elastic. The
lesson also discussed about Implicit form of collusion that is price leadership
by a dominant firm where there is no agreement between the firms to collude
Self-Instructional
80 Material
but still firms follow the price set by a leader firm as that avoids the uncertainty NOTES
and reduces the chances of a price war. However, in spite of the benefits of
cartelization, firms still cheat as that brings them more profits and it has been
highlighted by Prisoner’s Dilemma which shows that why firms in an oligopoly
cheat while they would have been better off if they would have colluded.
Game theory is applied to explain co-operative and non-cooperative
behaviour of oligopolistic firms.
Self-Instructional
Material 81
LESSON 6 NOTES
Structure
6.1 Learning Objectives
6.2 Cost Changes
6.3 Comparative Statics
6.4 Changes in Input Prices
6.5 Changes in Technology
6.6 Effects of Taxation on Competitive Industry
6.7 Learning Outcome
6.8 Terminal Questions
3. Another common reason for a change in costs is a change in taxes paid by NOTES
the firms in the industry. In India, every year industry watchers eagerly wait
for the budget speech of the Finance Minister in the Lok Sabha to analyze
the impact of changes in excise and customs duties on a wide variety of
industries like iron and steel, cement, cars, petroleum products, etc.
4. Acts of nature might also be an important source of costs changes for some
industries. Winter fog in Delhi, for instance, increases the costs for aviation
industry because it leads to delays in landing and take-off of aircrafts and
sometimes might even result in cancellation of flights. Massive rains that
lead to widespread flooding in Mumbai a few years ago resulted in an
increase in the costs for the insurance industry. On the other hand, adequate
rain in the months of July and August in states like Punjab and Haryana
might lower the costs of paddy production for farmers since they might
not be required to use diesel-run pump sets for irrigation.
In this lesson, we use the comparative static technique. We start with a market
that is in long run equilibrium. We then introduce a cost change that leads the
market to a new equilibrium (i.e., a new state of rest or no change for the system
when all the adjustments to cost changes have taken place). We compare these
two equilibrium states to study the impact of cost changes. Comparative statics
is to be contrasted with static analysis that looks at equilibrium in a market that
does not receive any external shocks or disturbances (i.e., a change in a variable
fixed from outside). Both these methods are to be contrasted with dynamic
analysis that looks at the path of evolution of the state of a system when it is not
in equilibrium.
Long run response might be very different from what happens in the
short run
We shall first see how the economy adjusts to changes in costs in the short run.
In the long run, however, the response of a competitive industry can be very
Self-Instructional
Material 87
NOTES different. We will analyse the long run response next. A large part of the difference
in our analysis and conclusions between the short run and long run effects is
explained by free entry and exit of firms in a competitive industry in the long
run in response to abnormally high or low profits.
Freedom of entry and exit of firms is one of the most important characteristics
of competitive markets. Most of the efficiency results of competition stem from
this. Freedom of entry and exit of firms lies at the heart of adjustment process
in a competitive market and we try to illustrate it in a wide variety of situations.
At times our conclusions are quite different from the answers of those who have
not received a formal training in economics. A little investment of time and
energy on your part will, we hope, change the way you think about major issues
of public concern.
NOTES
Fig. 6.1
Since each firm’s MC has shifted down, the industry supply curve also shifts
down to S1, market price falls to P1 and industry output rises to Q1 in Panel A
of Figure 6.1. Notice that the fall in market price is less than the one Rupee
fall in costs given by P0P2, the vertical distance between S0 and S1 in Panel A
of Figure 6.1.
In Panel B we see that when the market price is P1 and the costs for each
firm have declined (by more than the decline in market price). Each firm in
Self-Instructional
Material 89
NOTES the industry increases its optimal quantity supplied to q1 a level higher than the
efficient one at which AC is minimum. Moreover, each firm in the industry makes
supernormal profits in the short run since price is greater than AC. The area of
the shaded rectangle in Panel B of Figure 6.1 gives the magnitude of this profit.
An alternative way of analysing the long run impact is to look at how the long run
industry supply curve shifts. With free entry and exit of firms and with identical
cost curves for all the firms, the long run industry supply curve is a horizontal
straight line whose vertical intercept is equal to the lowest AC for a typical firm.
This is shown in Panel A of Figure 6.2 The long am industry supply curve shifts
from S to S*. The market price drops from P to P*, the full extent of drop in
costs, and industry output rises from Q to Q*.
In Panel B Figure 6.2, we see that each firm continues to produce output q,
the efficient output level, when market price and costs decline. Moreover, each
firm continues to make zero economic profits in the long run.
Self-Instructional
90 Material
NOTES
Fig. 6.2
In the long run, under perfect competition, the price declines by the full
extent of the decline in the lowest AC. The output is higher and the price is lower.
The firms are still making zero economic profits. All the benefits of lower input
prices are passed on to consumers.
We shall first see how the economy responds in the short run as well as in the
long run to shifts in supply that are brought about by technological changes in
an industry.
We noted in the previous lesson that technological changes are frequently
major sources of changes in costs in the real world. In this lesson, we will analyse
the short run and long-term impact of two kinds of technological changes.
1. A once-for-all-change in technology
2. A continuous process of technological change
A once-for-all-change in technology
Assume that the industry starts from a situation where there has been no change
in technology for a long time and all firms have the same cost curves. Further,
suppose that the industry is initially in a state of long run equilibrium.
This is shown in Figure 6.3. We start from a position of long run equilibrium.
In Panel A of Figure 6.3, initial industry equilibrium is at E0 where the industry
demand curve D and initial industry supply curve S0 intersect. The initial market
price is P0 and the quantity demanded and supplied in the industry is Q0.
Self-Instructional
92 Material
NOTES
Fig. 6.3
Self-Instructional
Material 93
NOTES The initial equilibrium for a typical firm in the industry is at e0 in Panel B
Figure 6.3, where price = MC = ATC. Each firm supplies q0, a quantity at which
ATC is minimized and every firm makes zero economic profit (i.e., it earns normal
profits) and hence there is no incentive for an existing firm to exit or for a new
firm to enter the industry. Notice that P is greater than AVC, hence the firm is
making positive operating profits (the difference between total revenue and total
variable costs) that just cover its fixed costs.
Now suppose that a single advance in the industry’s production technology
takes place that lowers the costs of production for newly built plants. We assume
that existing plants can not take advantage of this technological advance since
the new technology has to be embedded in new plant and equipment. In the short
run there will be no change in the industry since it takes time to build new plant
and equipment.
In the medium run, since new technology lowers the average total cost
curve to ATC1 and the original price P0 was equal to the average total cost for
the existing plants; new plants are profitable and will be built soon. With this
capacity expansion, the industry’ supply curve shifts to the right to S1, market
price falls to P1 and industry output rises to Q1 in Panel A of Figure 6.3. Notice
that capacity expansion and fall in market price continues till price has fallen to
the lowest AC for the new plants and further entry is not profitable,
At price P1, the new plants are operating at the most efficient scale where
they are producing an output at which AC is minimized. Firms with new plants
are making zero economic profits since their operating costs just cover their fixed
costs. This is shown in Panel C of Figure 6.3.
Firms with old plants, however, will not be covering their total costs. If the
costs for the new plants are sufficiently lower than that of the old plants, the new
market price PI will be lower than minimum AVC of old plants. Old plants will
be shut down immediately and all surviving firms will use the new technology.
A more interesting case, however, is where the new market price P1 is
higher than minimum AVC of old plants. This is shown in Panel B of Figure
6.3. At price P1 firms with old plant produce output q2, a level of output at which
price = MC and since price is less than ATC, each firm with an old plant makes
Self-Instructional
94 Material
a loss given by the area of rectangle P1CDE. It is, however, optimal to produce NOTES
output q2 since price is higher than AVC and the firm is making an operating
profit given by the area of the rectangle ABC P1. Had the firm shut down its loss
would have been higher. Its revenue would have been zero, it would still have
to incur the fixed cost of production (given by the area of the rectangle ABDE)
and losses would have been greater since the firm would not have been able to
use its operating profits to at least partially offset its fixed costs.
Old plants will continue to coexist with new ones and firms with old plants
will be making losses. A non-economist might think that operating loss-making
old plants is inefficient and it would be advantageous to discard them. He could
not be more wrong! As long as old plants recover their variable costs, it is optimal
to operate them. Fixed costs are sunk; they can not be avoided by shutting down
old plants. One of the first lessons in economics is to ignore sunk costs. Let us
try to understand this by looking at an example from everyday life. If you go to a
restaurant and happen to order a lousy meal, don’t force it down your throat just
because the price you paid is very high. You have to pay the price whether you
finish the meal or not. It is a sunk cost. The decision whether to eat all of what
you ordered or to leave it in the plate depends not on the size of the bill (you have
to pay that in either case), but on whether not eating (or eating something else
or somewhere else and paying something additional for it) makes you happier
than eating what is in front of you. Let bygones be bygones.
With the passage of time, however, old plants will wear out. They will
now be replaced by plants using new technology. At the time of replacement,
the cost of plant is not sunk. Profit maximizing firms will choose plants with
lower costs. Plants with old (higher cost) technology will gradually disappear.
In the long run a new equilibrium will be attained in which all plants use the
new technology. As shown in Panel A of Figure 6.3 output will be Q1, higher
than output Q0 in the original equilibrium. Price will be P1 lower than P0 in the
original equilibrium. The new plants will be operating at an efficient scale and
will be just covering their costs.
All the benefits of lower costs due to technological advancement will be
passed on to the consumers in the long run.
Self-Instructional
Material 95
We can generalize the analysis of the previous section to consider the outcome in
a competitive industry where there is a continuous technological change. Plants
built today have lower costs than plants that were built in the past. However,
costs are expected to be even lower for plants that might be built at a future date.
It is clear from the analysis of previous section that ongoing technological
progress will lead to a continuous process of entry of newer lower cost firms. The
market price will continually decline. However, older plants will not necessarily
be shut down as soon as plants with better and lower cost technology make an
appearance. Owners of old plants will continue to operate them as long as they
cover their variable costs.
This situation is described in Figure 6.4. The Plant shown in Panel A of
Figure 6.4 is the oldest plant that is on the margin of shutdown. It is making
a loss since market price is lower than its average total cost. The plant is just
covering its AVC and is indifferent between shutting down and continuing to
produce output q1. If the price drops any further, the plant will be shut down.
Self-Instructional
96 Material
NOTES
Fig. 6.4
NOTES their variable costs. They produce goods that are valued more by the consumers
than the resources currently used up by operating the old plants (their variable
costs). It is in the interest of the firms with old plants and also in the social interest
to continue to use these old plants as long as the variable costs are covered.
Another point to be noted is that market price paid by consumers is
determined not by the average costs of the old inefficient plants, but by the costs
of the firms with the newest and the most efficient plants. Entry of firms with the
most efficient technology into the industry will continue and supply will keep on
increasing till the price has dropped to a level where latest entrants can barely
cover the opportunity cost of their capital over the expected lifetime of their
plants. It implies that new entrants today must earn positive economic profits
for some time to offset the losses that they expect to earn later when firms with
even more efficient technology enter the industry and push down the market
prices to a level lower than the ATC of these current entrants. The full benefit
of new technology is passed on to the consumers as soon as it begins to be used
by the new entrants even though a vast majority of firms in the industry might
still be using old technology. The price paid by the consumers depends only on
the costs of the most efficient firms. As Paul Samuelson once said, it is the tail
that wags the dog in economics. Owners of older firms have to sell their goods
at the same lower price that is charged by the new firms. Their operating-profits
keep on declining as entry of lower cost firms keeps on driving down the market
price. These firms will ultimately quit the industry when they can not even cover
their variable costs.
This brings us to the final point that we want to make in this lesson. The
concept of economic obsolescence is different from that of physical wear and tear.
We emphasized above that old machinery should not necessarily he discarded
just because firms using it have higher costs and might even be making losses
since market price depends on the costs of the most efficient firms. Just as one
should not be overenthusiastic about discarding old machinery, one should not
continue to use an old machine because it is still functional. When the price
drops below average variable costs the machine is economically obsolete even
though it may not be physically worn out. Old capital equipment is obsolete and
Self-Instructional
98 Material
should not be operated if by using it the firm can not even cover the variable NOTES
costs. This might happen well before the equipment is physically worn out. The
concept of economic efficiency should be understood both by those who have
a fetish for new technology and want to discard old equipment as soon as they
see something more modern and also by those who would never discard old
equipment, as long as it works.
There are various kinds of taxes that the government imposes which ultimately
affect the costs of firms and industry. We will consider three different types of
taxes-per-unit tax, lumpsum tax and profit tax.
(1) Per-unit tax: It is a tax that is levied on each unit produced by the firm. In
a way it can be said to be another cost to the firm. As a result of per unit
tax (say sales tax) the marginal cost of the firm shifts up by the amount of
the tax. At the industry level the supply curve shifts up by the amount of
the tax. Accordingly, the effects of a per-unit tax on output of a competitive
industry can be listed as follows:
(i) In the short run the price of the output will rise but by less than the
amount of the tax. So, the tax burden will be shared by consumers and
Self-Instructional
Material 99
NOTES producers. The consumers pay higher price than before and producers
do not cover their average total costs.
(ii) In the long run, some firms who do not cover their costs may leave
the Industry. The industry will contract (fall in size) and losses will
disappear. If the cost curves of existing firms remain unaffected due
to contraction of the industry then price will rise by full amount of
the tax. In such a case the burden of the tax will be totally on the
consumers. This also implies that government intervention in the
competitive industry may affect its size, volume of sales and price in
the short run but it cannot influence its long-run profitability effects
of per-unit tax as shown in Figure 6.5.
Figure 6.5 shows the effect of per-unit tax on price and quantity by
shifting the supply curve upwards. The original equilibrium point is E0
with price P0 and quantity Q0. A per-unit tax supply shifts from S0 to S, so
that new equilibrium is now at point E1. Tax equals S0S1 or E1T or P1P2.
Price increases to P1 since increase in price is P0P1 which in less than the
tax E1T, the tax burden is shared by consumers and producers in the short
run. After tax quantity has also fallen to Q0.
In Figure 6.6, the effect of per-unit tax is shown by shifting the demand
curve down by the amount of tax. It shows that after tax producer gets
price P2 after tax which is less than the market price P1.
Self-Instructional
100 Material
(2) Lump-sum tax: Lump sum tax is a kind of fixed cost of the firm. It NOTES
increases the total cost of the firm and industry. The marginal costs and
marginal revenues remain unaffected. The average cost curve shifts up due
to tax at the existing level of output. Lumpsum tax reduces the revenue.
As long as the firm is able to recover its variable costs, it will remain in
business otherwise it will shut down in the short run. Lump sum tax does
not affect price and output in the short run. However, in the long run some
firms, who do not cover their increasing costs leave the industry and the
size of the industry will fall. Price will rise and output will fall until the
whole of tax burden is passed on to the consumers.
(3) Tax on profits: From the economists’ point of view the firm in perfect
competition earns normal profit or zero economic profit in the long run.
So, on this basis a tax on profits will neither affect price nor output of a
competitive industry in equilibrium. So, it will also not affect allocation
of resources.
However, in reality profits are defined in tax laws according to accountants,
usage which includes returns to capital, reward for risk-taking and could be taxed.
Self-Instructional
Material 101
NOTES
6.8 TERMINAL QUESTIONS
1. Explain effect of per-unit tax on price and quantity from the demand side
of the market.
2. Explain effect of per-unit tax on price and quantity from the supply side
of the market.
Self-Instructional
102 Material
LESSON 7 NOTES
MARKET FAILURE
Devender
Assistant Professor
School of Open Learning
University of Delhi
Structure
7.1 Learning Objective
7.2 Introduction
7.3 Allocative Efficiency under Perfect Competition
7.4 Market Failure
7.5 Externalities
7.6 Public Goods
7.7 Self Assessment Questions
7.8 Functions of Government
7.9 Public Policy Towards Monopoly and Competition
7.10 Learning Outcome
7.11 Terminal Questions
Self-Instructional
Material 103
NOTES
7.2 INTRODUCTION
Self-Instructional
104 Material
NOTES
7.3 ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY UNDER PERFECT
COMPETITION
Self-Instructional
Material 105
NOTES
Fig. 7.1
(iv) Asymmetric information which creates a situation where one party to NOTES
a market transaction has more knowledge of its consequences than the
knowledge available to the other party. For example in the market for
second-hand cars, only the seller knows the actual condition of the car
and buyer has no information about the quality of the product.
(v) If there are missing markets, i.e., needed markets do not exist at all.
Market failure does not mean that nothing good is happening in the market
but it means that the best possible outcome has not been attained. It arises in
the following cases:
1. Asymmetric Information
2. Insurance Market
3. Market Signalling
4. Moral Hazard Problem
5. Principal Agent Problem
1. Asymmetric information: Asymmetric information means that the
buyers and sellers do not possess the same set of information, one
having a better or more set of information as compared to the other
and hence is better off. The problem is also known as Lemons Problem
given by Ackerlof. A ‘lemon’ is a derogatory term for a poor quality
second-hand car. However, the lemon’s problem has many wider
implications in terms of understanding information failure in general.
It can be explained with the help of an example as given below:
Example 1 – Let us assume that there is a car dealer who deals in
second-hand cars and is aware about the conditions of the car and does
not pass on the entire information to the buyers. Here the car dealer
is thus having better and more information and takes the advantage
of the information by selling the cars at a higher price then what they
are worth off. The buyers would purchase it once but after becoming
aware of the situation of the second-hand cars, they would not go for it
the second time at the same price as they are suspicious of the seller’s
intention and hence the market and the demand for second-hand cars
Self-Instructional
Material 107
NOTES reduce because of asymmetric information as all the good quality cars
are driven out of the market because of the lesser price being paid for
it and only low quality cars would be left in the market. After a short
period, it can be predicted that all cars sold in the second-hand car
market will be lemons. When applying this concept to other markets
it can be suggested that, whenever there is information failure, there
is the possibility that markets will become lemons markets. If so, the
supply of good quality products will fall and the supply of poor quality
products will rise.
This problem of asymmetric information can be reduced by getting more
information, like in the above case the buyers can get the second-hand
cars evaluated by an independent car evaluator to find the correct status
and price of the used cars.
2. Insurance market: Here also the problem is because of asymmetric
information but unlike the used cars, here it is buyer of the insurance
policy that is in possession of better and more information. It also leads
to adverse selection as can be explained using the following example:
Example 2 – Let us assume the case of a medical insurance where the
buyer of the policy has more information about his health. The premium
set by the insurance company is according to the average individual
that includes both the healthy and unhealthy individuals, but it is the
unhealthy ones that are more likely to go for insurance and it increases
the losses of the insurance company because of which the premiums
increase and it further rations out the healthy individuals out of the
insurance market as they are not willing to buy the insurance at such
high premiums. Thus the market now has only unhealthy individuals
which further increases the losses and hence forces the insurance
companies to go out of the market. This is also because of asymmetric
information.
3. Market signalling: The problem of adverse selection can be reduced or
even eliminated by market signalling wherein the producer gives signals
about better quality of its products to the buyers thereby preventing
Self-Instructional the outflow of such goods from the market as happened in the Lemons
108 Material
problem. Thus the buyers are able to differentiate between high quality NOTES
and low quality products and it gives the sellers an advantage as they
are able to sell high quality products at a higher price. This can be done
by branding the product or providing guarantees and warranties that
assure the buyer about the quality of the product and helps in reducing
the suspicion that buyers have about seller’s description of the product
or service.
4. Moral Hazard problem: This problem generally arises in case of
insurance where if an individual is insured then there are greater chances
of him being negligent about the subject matter of the insurance. Moral
hazard refers to a situation where you do not behave in a manner that
you are expected to in case there has been no one else to share the loss.
For example if an individual gets his building insured for fire then if
he does not take proper care to ensure that there is no fire then it is a
case of moral hazard. Similarly, if an individual after taking medical
insurance does not take preventive measures for his health, it also
leads to issue of moral hazard. Such situations lead to market failure,
because if the moral hazard is not reduced or eliminated then it leads
to increased premiums of insurance thereby defeating the very purpose
of insurance. The issue of moral hazard can be tackled by going for
Coinsurance wherein the insurance company bears a part of the loss
and the rest is borne by the beneficiary himself. For example in case
of an insurance by an individual wherein the insurance company
would bear 70% of the losses subject to a maximum limit in case of
a mishap and the remaining 30% of the total loss would be borne by
the insurance policy holder. Thus, in this case as the entire loss is not
covered up by the insurance company, the beneficiary is bound to take
care which he would have otherwise not assumed. Another way is to
ensure that enough precautions have been taken to avoid the loss, for
example in case of fire insurance even after taking the insurance it has
to be made sure that enough safety provisions were made and loss is
unavoidable. However, if the insurance company finds out that enough
safety provisions were not there then no compensation of loss is made
to the policy holder. Self-Instructional
Material 109
7.5 EXTERNALITIES
Till now all the lessons and the discussions are concentrated on the buyer and
the seller, there is however a third party also that is affected by the production
and/or consumption of the goods or services though not being directly a part of
the production or exchange process. The impact on such third party is known
as externality as it is external to the parties that are directly involved in the
generation process. Such effects can be positive or negative that is beneficial
or harmful, the former being external benefit and the latter being external cost.
Self-Instructional
110 Material
A simple example of external benefit can be getting oneself immunized for a NOTES
communicable disease; it is called external benefit as it will reduce the spread
of the disease to others who have not got themselves immunized. External cost
can be the effects of pollution that is being felt by the parties that reside near the
factories in spite of not being a part of the generation process. While individuals
who benefit from positive externalities without paying are considered to be free-
riders, it may be in the interests of society to encourage free-riders to consume
goods which generate substantial external benefits.
Positive Externality in Production: A farmer grows apple trees. An external
benefit is that he provides nectar for a nearby bee keeper who gains increased
honey as a result of the farmer’s orchard.
Negative Externality in Production: Making furniture by cutting down
rainforests in the Amazon leads to negative externalities to other people. Firstly,
it harms the indigenous people of the Amazon rainforest. It also leads to higher
global warming as there are fewer trees to absorb carbon dioxide.
Positive Externality in Consumption: If you take a three-year training
course in IT. You gain skills but also other people in the economy can benefit
from your knowledge.
Negative Externality in Consumption: If you smoke in a crowded room,
other people have to breathe in your smoke. This is unpleasant for them and can
leave them exposed to health problems associated with smoking.
Now government should try to encourage positive externalities and
discourage negative externalities which can be done by providing subsidies or
imposition of taxes as shown below:
Self-Instructional
Material 111
NOTES
Fig. 7.2
Self-Instructional
112 Material
Fig. 7.3
In Figure 7.3, D is the demand curve that the firms take into consideration
for determining their equilibrium level of output; it includes only the marginal
private benefit. MEB is the marginal external benefit and S is the supply curve
of the firm derived from the marginal cost. The equilibrium is where demand
and supply curves intersect that is at point E where the firm is producing OQ
level of output. But this is not what the firm should be actually producing as it is
not taking into account the external benefit. Ds is the demand curve after adding
the marginal private benefit and marginal external benefit and the actual output
that should be produced should be where Ds and S intersect, it is at point E’ and
firm should be producing OQ’. To increase the output, government can provide
subsidy that reduces the cost of production and supply curve shifts downwards
to S’ and output increases to OQ’. Thus, increase in the output brings an increase
in the total external benefit.
Self-Instructional
Material 113
NOTES
7.6 PUBLIC GOODS
Self-Instructional
114 Material Fig. 7.4
Here, let us assume that there are two consumers A and B and their demand NOTES
curves that show marginal private benefit, DA and DB, respectively. To get the
market demand curve or the total demand curve we need to add the two individual
demand curves vertically that gives DS as the demand curve. The equilibrium
is where DS intersects MC and it provides that OQ units of output would be
produced in the economy that would give the benefit of OA’ to consumer A
and OB’ to consumer B. Public goods are not normally provided by the private
sector because they would be unable to supply them for a profit. It is up to the
government to decide what output of public goods is appropriate for society. To
do this, it must estimate the social benefits from making public goods available.
Because public goods are non-excludable, it is difficult to charge people for
benefiting from a good or service once it is provided. The free-rider problem
leads to under-provision of a good and thus causes market failure.
Self-Instructional
Material 115
Exercise 3: Questions
Self-Instructional
116 Material
Self-Instructional
Material 117
NOTES
Fig. 7.5
(ii) Even controlling price at average cost level may be inefficient again for
natural monopoly. As in panel-2 of Figure 7.5 P1 is average cost price
which is higher and the corresponding output, is below competitive level
of Q0.
(iii) Since both marginal cost and average cost pricing do not yield desired
result for natural monopolies, they are directly taken over by government
itself in many countries.
(iv) Technological changes have made many natural monopolies behave
like competitive industry. So, government policies must adjust itself to
continuous technological change.
(v) Due to failure of government as business organization there have been a
wave of privatization recently in many countries including India. Many
nationalized industries have been privatized in the UK. Disinvestment of
public sector units in India is another example. While allowing privatization
to be implemented rapidly governments are also creating public regulatory
authorities to look into the functioning of these natural monopolies. In
the UK, example of such bodies are OFTEL (Telephones), OFGAS (gas),
etc. Security Exchange Board of India SEBI is a regulatory body in India.
Privatization reduces governments’ role in business and allows innovations
to take place faster. It is expected that government’s intervention as
Self-Instructional controller and regulator must allow competition to grow among firms.
118 Material
NOTES
7.10 LEARNING OUTCOME
1. Give the meaning of market failure. What are the causes of market failure?
Explain.
2. Differentiate between positive and negative externalities with the help of
examples. How can they be dealt with to ensure better market outcomes?
3. What are the features of public goods? How are the public goods responsible
for market failure? Determine the efficient amount of public good that
should be produced?
Self-Instructional
Material 119
LESSON 8 NOTES
Structure
8.1 Learning Objectives
8.2 Introduction
8.3 The Demand for Factors
8.4 Supply of Factors
8.5 Learning Outcome
8.6 Terminal Questions
8.2 INTRODUCTION
The total output of an economy is the result of the joint productive efforts of
the various factors of production; land, labour, capital and enterprise. This
total output ultimately gets distributed among the factors that contributed to its
production in the form of wages, rent, interest and profit. The purpose of the
theory of distribution is to explain the principles that govern this distribution.
The distribution of total product depends on how the various factors are priced
Self-Instructional
Material 123
NOTES in the market. Thus, pricing of the various factors of production is the subject
matter of the theory of distribution.
There are two aspects of the factorial distribution of national income; (i)
determination of the per unit prices of the different factors and (ii) the division
of the national income as between the different factors, i.e., absolute and relative
shares of different factors in national income. The first question is essentially
a micro-economic problem concerning the determination of equilibrium at the
level of an individual firm or an industry. The second question concerns the
factorial distribution of income at the level of the economy and, therefore, forms
part of macro analysis. Thus, we have micro and macro theories of distribution.
In the present set of lessons we are concerned only with the micro theories of
distribution, i.e., the question of factor-price determination.
Just as the price of any commodity is determined by the interaction of the
forces of supply and demand, similarly the price of a factor is determined by the
interaction of the forces of supply and demand for it. The theory of distribution is,
thus, a special case of the theory of price determination discussed in the earlier set of
lessons. However, the supply and demand for factors exhibit some peculiarities which
have to be taken into account while considering the pricing of particular factors.
Herein lies the justification for a separate theory of factor price determination. Let
us first examine the demand for and supply of factors in some detail.
Why does a producer demand a factor? The demand for a factor is derived (or
indirect) and not direct demand. The demand for a commodity is direct in the
sense that it directly satisfies some human want. The demand for a factor, on
the other hand, is not direct in this sense. A factor is demanded not for its own
sake, but simply because it can contribute to the production of some commodity
demanded by the consumers. For example, a farmer pays rent for the use of
land simply because it helps to produce, let us say, wheat which is demanded
Self-Instructional
by the consumers. Similarly, he pays for seeds and fertilizers because they help
124 Material to produce commodities, which are demanded by the consumers.
When a producer employs an additional unit of a factor it yields him some NOTES
extra output. While demanding a factor, the producer is not so much interested
in the extra output that it yields him as in the amount of the extra revenue he
will get from the sale of that output. In other words, he demands a factor simply
because it ultimately contributes to his revenue. Hence the price a producer
will be willing to pay for a factor unit will depend upon the addition to his total
revenue which results from the employment of an additional unit of that factor.
The additional revenue yielded due to the employment of an additional unit of a
factor is called the marginal revenue product (MRP). For example, suppose that
by employing 10 labourers on a given plot of land a farmer gets 100 quintals of
wheat which sell for Rs. 20,000 in the market and by employing 11 labourers
instead of 10 he is able to raise 110 quintals of wheat which sell for Rs. 22,000.
It is evident that due to the employment of an additional labourer total revenue
of the producer rises from Rs. 20,000 to Rs. 22,000. Rs. 2000 is, thus, the MRP
of the 11th unit of labour. While demanding a factor the producer has his eyes
set on this quantity. It is in this sense that the demand for factors is derived out
of the demand for the commodities that they help to produce.
There are three different senses in which the concept of marginal product (MP)
is used. Firstly, it may be used to express the addition made to the total physical
product of a producer due to the employment of an additional unit of a factor, the
amounts of all other factors remaining constant We call this additional physical
product as the marginal physical product (MPP). For example, if by employing 11
labourers on a given piece of land instead of 10, the total wheat output of a farmer
increases from 200 quintals of rice to 220 quintals, then the MPP of the 11th unit
of labour will be said to be 20 quintals. Thus, the MPP of a factor is the addition
made to the total physical output of a producer due to the employment of an
additional unit of a factor while keeping the amounts of all other factors constant.
Secondly, the concept of MP may be used in value productivity sense.
The addition to the total revenue of a producer made by the employment of an
additional unit of a factor, with amounts of all other factors remaining constant,
is called the marginal revenue product (MRP) of the variable factor in question.
Self-Instructional
According to this above example, the total physical product of the producer Material 125
NOTES increases from 200 quintals to 220 quintals when he employs 11 labourers
instead of 10 on the same plot of land. Now if the total revenue of the producer
increases from Rs. 40,000 to Rs. 42,000 when he sells 220 quintals instead of
200, the MRP of the 11th labourer will be said to be Rs. 2,000.
It is evident that the MRP of a factor depends upon two things: (a) the
additional units of output produced and (b) the contribution of each unit of
output to the total revenue of the producer. The additional output produced
by the employment of an additional unit of a factor is called the MPP and the
contribution of an additional unit of output to the total revenue of a producer is
called the marginal revenue (MR). Thus:
MRP = MPP × MR
Thirdly, the concept of marginal product may also be used to denote the
market value of the MPP of a factor. For instance, the MPP of the 11th labourer
according to the above example is 20 quintals of wheat. Now if the ruling market
price of wheat, when the larger output is sold (220 quintals instead of 200 quintals)
is Rs. 200 per quintal, the market value of the additional output will equal Rs.
4,000, Rs. 4000 then will be said to be the value of marginal product (VMP) of
the 11th labourer. VMP is simply the MPP multiplied by the market price of the
commodity. As already explained in the context of the theory of firm, market
price and average revenue (AR) are one and the same thing. Thus:
VMP = MPP × AR
MRP equals MPP × MR while VMP equals MPP × AR MPP is common to both
concepts. MPP depends solely on the technical conditions of production while
MR and AR depend upon the structure of commodity market where the firm
sells its output. If the firm sells its output on a perfectly competitive commodity
market, it will be faced with a perfectly elastic demand curve and its AR and MR
will then be identical. Thus, in the event of perfect competition in the commodity
market the MRP (=MPP × MR) and VMP (=MPP × AR) of a factor to a firm will
be the same because AR and MR are identical. But if the firm is faced with an
imperfectly competitive commodity market, then MRP and VMP will not be the
Self-Instructional same. In the event of imperfect competition in the commodity market, as we have
126 Material
already studied, MR will necessarily be less than AR. From this, it follows that NOTES
in the event of imperfect competition in the commodity market, MRP (which
equals MPP × MR) will necessarily be less than VMP (which equals MPP ×
AR) because MR is less than AR. Thus, in conclusion we note that in case of
perfect competition in the commodity market MRP equals VMP and in case of
imperfect competition MRP will necessarily be less than VMP. Thus:
MRP (=MPP × MR) VMP (=MPP × AR) in case of perfect competition
in commodity market.
MRP (=MPP × MR) < VMP (=MPP × AR) in case of imperfect competition
in the commodity market.
We clarify the point further with a simple example. Suppose the total
physical product of a farmer per year increases from 200 quintals to 220
quintals of rice when he employs 21 labourers instead of 20, on a given piece
of land. The MPP of the 21st labourer, according to this example, would be
20 quintals. Further, suppose that the farmer sells his output on a perfectly
competitive commodity market so that the price of rice remains constant at Rs.
100 per quintal even when he sells the larger output. MRP of the 21st labourer
in this case would equal the change in the total revenue of the producer due to
the sale of the larger output, i.e., 220 × 100-200 × 100 = 22000–20000 = Rs.
2000. VMP (MPP × AR) in this case would also equal Rs. 2000 (=20 × 100 =
2000). Now suppose the farmer is faced with an imperfect commodity market
so that he is able to sell the larger output at Rs. 98 per quintal and not at Rs. 100
per quintal. In this case MRP of the 21st labourer would equal 220 × 98 – 200
× 100 = 21560 – 20000 = Rs. 1560. And VMP would equal MPP (=20) × AR
(=Rs. 98) = Rs. 1960. Why is MRP in this case smaller than VMP? The reason
is very simple. When the price falls from Rs. 100 to Rs. 98, this reduction in
price applies not only to the extra output but also to the earlier output (i.e., 200
quintals) which was earlier sold at Rs. 100 instead of Rs. 98. Thus, while the
producer gets additional revenue from the sale of the extra output (=20 quintals)
at the current market price equal to Rs. 1960, at the same time he suffers a loss
in his earlier total revenue equal to the fall in price (i.e., Rs. 2) multiplied by the
earlier total output (i.e., 200 quintals) i.e., output but also to the earlier output
(i.e., 200 quintals) i.e., Rs. 400. The MRP (or the net addition to the earlier Self-Instructional
total revenue of the producer) would thus equal Rs. 1960 – Rs 400 = Rs. 1560. Material 127
NOTES Thus as a general rule we note that in the event of imperfect competition in the
commodity market MRP will be less than VMP by the amount of loss of revenue
suffered by the producer on his earlier output due to the fall in price. In the
present case when, in order to sell the larger output (220 quintals instead of 200.
quintals), price falls from Rs. 100 to Rs. 98, he is compelled to sell the earlier
output (200 quintals) also at Rs. 98 per quintal and thus suffers a loss of revenue
of Rs. 400/-. Therefore, MRP of 21st unit will be less than its VMP by Rs. 400.
The demand for a factor is derived from its MRP. MRP, as we have seen above
depends upon MPP and MR. The behaviour of MRP will thus depend upon the
behaviours of its components with changes in the quantity of the variable factor
employed. Under a given set of conditions, the behaviour of MPP is determined
by the operation of the law of diminishing returns (or the law of variable
proportions). The law states that as more units of a variable factor are used
with a given amount of other factors, after a point its MPP starts diminishing,
provided there is no change in the state of technology. We can explain this law
with a simple numerical example. Imagine a farmer employing more and more
labourers on a given plot of land. The Table 8.1 below records total, average and
marginal products as the farmer employs more and more labourers on the given
plot of land and other equipment, etc.
Table 8.1
The figures in the above Table 8.1 show that both the average and marginal NOTES
products increase at first and then decline. The marginal product falls faster than
the average. The important point to note is that with the employment of the fifth
unit the marginal product starts diminishing. The same phenomenon is depicted
in Figures 8.1 and 8.2.
In the Figure 8.1 below the MPP curve rises till the employment of OA
units of labour and thereafter it falls continuously. The APP curve rises till the
employment of OB units and thereafter starts declining. The relationship between
APP and MPP is the same as that between AC and MC explained in the earlier
set of lessons.
NOTES Carefully note the fact that just like the MPP curve the MRP curve is also
downward sloping. The reason for this is the diminishing marginal productivity
of the factor. Also note the fact that in this particular case MRP curve is also the
VMP curve.
However, as already explained, if the firm is confronted with an imperfectly
competitive commodity market, it will be able to sell larger outputs only by
reducing the market price so that MR will be less than AR. As a result two things
happen. Firstly, as the firm is able to sell its extra output at a lower price, the VMP
curve (which is derived from the technically given MPP curve by multiplying
MPP corresponding to each level of employment of the factor by the market price
of the product) will fall more sharply than the MPP curve. Secondly, since MR
will be less than AR, the MRP curve will lie below the VMP curve and slope
more sharply than the latter. Figure 8.3 depicts the VMP and MRP curves of a
firm selling its product in an imperfectly competitive commodity market.
Fig. 8.3
Self-Instructional
130 Material
Table 8.2 Difference between MRP and VMP under Perfect NOTES
and Imperfect Competition in the Commodity Market
Explanatory Notes:
1. MPP = Difference between two successive total products.
2. T.R, = Total revenue = Total product × price at which it is sold:
3. MRP = Marginal revenue product = Difference between two successive
total revenues.
4. VMP = Value of MPP = MPP × the price at which total product sells.
Carefully note the following:
1. Total product and MPP figures are the same because they are determined
purely by technical factors.
2. In case of perfect competition in the commodity market, MRP and VMP
figures are identical.
3. In case of imperfect competition in the commodity market MRP is
always less than VMP.
Self-Instructional
Material 131
Just as it is true that a profit maximizing firm, whether it is selling its product
under conditions of perfect competition, imperfect competition or monopoly,
will produce to the point at which its MC equals its MR, so it is true that a profit-
maximizing firm will purchase units of a variable factor up to the point at which
the addition to its total cost resulting from the employment of an additional unit
(i.e., marginal factor cost, MFC) equals the MRP of the factor in question. Thus,
in the purchase of a single variable factor a firm will be in equilibrium when
MFC equals MRP of the factor.
Thus, in equilibrium:
MFC = MRP (1)
The above condition is a perfect general equilibrium condition applicable
to all market situations. If we further assume that the firm is able to purchase
any amount of the factor without influencing market price (i.e, purchases in a
competitive factor market), the MFC of the factor to the firm is simply the market
price (AFC). Therefore, for firms that purchase their factor supplies in a perfectly
competitive market the above equilibrium condition (1) can be alternatively
stated as follows:
AFC = MRP (2)
This condition allows us to derive a firm’s demand curve for a factor from
the MRP curve. The factor’s MRP curve shows different MRPs corresponding
to the different amounts of the factor employed with given amounts of all other
factors, Firm’s demand curve for a factor would show the different amounts of
the factor that the firm would be willing to purchase at different prices of the
factor. Therefore, when a firm purchases its factor supplies in a competitive factor
market (so that MFC = AFC) the MRP curve of the factor becomes the firm’s
demand curve for the factor as shown in the Figure 8.4.
In the Figure 8.4, amount OA of the factor equates its MRP at point ‘a’
with the price OW. Therefore, at OW price the firm would be willing to purchase
OA amount of the factor. Amount OB of the factor equates its MRP at point ‘b’
with price OWS. Therefore, with OW, as the price the firm would be willing
Self-Instructional
132 Material
to purchase OB amount of the factor. Similarly, at OW2 price the firm would NOTES
be willing to purchase OC amount of the factor. However, at this stage let us
carefully note that the MRP curve is the firm’s demand curve for the variable
factor in question on the assumption that the price of the product and the price
of the factor are both given for the firm.
Fig. 8.4
In the preceding Figure 8.4, the MRP curve is the firm’s demand curve for the
factor in question on the assumption that changes in the price of the factor do
not, directly or indirectly, affect the price of the commodity produced and hence
the given MRP curve. This assumption would be valid only if all other firms in
the industry keep their outputs fixed. However, this is not a realistic assumption.
In the event of a fall in the price of a variable factor we would expect all firms
in the industry to employ more of this relatively cheaper factor. This would
increase the total output of the industry and cause the price of the commodity
to fall. A fall in the price of the commodity would cause the MRP curves of all
the firms (based on the higher price of the commodity) to shift leftward. Firms
will adjust their purchases of the factor with reference to the new MRP curve Self-Instructional
Material 133
NOTES (corresponding to the lower commodity price). Thus, each fall in the price of a
variable factor (via its effects on the factor’s total employment, total output and
hence the price of the commodity produced) will give rise to a new lower MRP
curve with one equilibrium point corresponding to the new factor price. The line
joining such equilibrium points on the different MRP curves will be the firm’s
demand curve for the variable factor in question when the reactions of other
firms in the industry to changes in the price of the factor are allowed for. This
is shown in the Figure 8.5.
Fig. 8.5
The lateral summation of the demand curves of all firms for a factor, as NOTES
derived above, gives us the market demand curve for the factor in question. Just
like the firm’s demand curve, the market demand curve for a factor will also be
downward sloping.
Self-Instructional
Material 135
NOTES
8.4 SUPPLY OF FACTORS
At first glance it may appear that quantities of most factors are fixed in an
economy. For example, there is an upper limit to the number of workers.
Similarly, there are upper limits to quantities of coal, oil, copper, iron ore, etc.,
available in the economy. However, in practice we are never near these limits.
Often a large undiscovered or unexploited quantity exists, and a shortage of the
resource that raises its price encourages exploration and the development of
previously unprofitable sources. Thus, the supply of a resource to the economy
usually varies considerably with changes in the price of the resource. With this
brief introduction we now come to a discussion of the characteristic features of
the supplies of individual factors.
2. Supply of Land
Land in economics includes all natural resources provided free by nature. The
quantity of a particular natural resource existing in the world is, of course,
limited. But we are never near these upper limits. Generally large undiscovered
(or unexploited) sources exist and a shortage that raises their prices encourages
exploration, research and development of previously unprofitable sources.
Therefore, the supply of any natural resource usually varies considerably with
changes in its price. A high return to land provides incentives for the development
of its productive powers through irrigation, drainage, fertilization, etc., which
greatly increase the supply of arable land. On the other hand, if the return to
land is low, its fertility may be allowed to be exhausted within a short period
of time. Traditionally, however, the supply of land (which includes all natural
resources besides mere space) to the whole economy has been assumed to be
absolutely inelastic.
Self-Instructional
136 Material
By the supply of labour (or the supply of effort) we mean the total number of
hours of work that the population is willing to supply. The supply of effort depends
upon the following factors:
(i) The size of the population: The size of the population sets the upper
limit to the total of labour. While there is some evidence that the birth
and immigration rates are higher in good times than in bad times, it is
doubtful especially in advanced economies, whether economic factors are
of paramount importance in determining the growth of population. It is
difficult to establish any definite relationship between the reward of labour
and growth of population. The reasons for which population varies are at
the moment largely unexplained. Therefore, for our purpose we may take
the size of population as fixed.
(ii) The proportion of the population willing to work: The proportion of
the population entering the labour market varies considerably in response
to variations in the wage rate. Generally, a rise in the wage rate results in
an increase in the proportion of the population willing to work. Women,
old people and even young boys are induced to join the labour force when
the wage rate is high. For example, the proportion of married women and
old persons in the labour force increased dramatically during the Second
World War. In addition to the rate, the proportion of the population entering
the labour market also depends on the age composition of population,
social institutions, customs and distribution of wealth in the economy. For
example, the extent to which women, especially married women, enter
the labour market partly depends on customs and opportunity. Customs
and opportunity can vary from one time to another and from one place to
another even within the same country. Greater equality in the distribution
of property in a society, by reducing the number of those who live on
unearned incomes and consequently do not need to work, will increase
the supply of labour in an economy.
Self-Instructional
Material 137
NOTES (iii) The number of hours of work offered by each individual worker: By
hiring out his services a labourer gets some money as his wage. With this
money he purchases goods and services for his consumption. Thus, the
labourer trades his leisure for goods, by giving up leisure (i.e., by working)
he gets money, and hence, goods. A rise in the wage rate means that there
is a change in the relative price of goods and leisure. Leisure becomes
dearer- relative-to goods (since each hour of leisure consumed now is at
the cost of more goods forgone), or alternatively, goods become cheaper
relative to leisure since each hour worked (i.e., leisure traded for goods)
now results in more goods than before. In the context of the theory of
consumer’s demand we noted that a consumer tends to substitute a cheaper
good at the cost of a dearer good when their relative prices change. The
same logic applies to change in the wage rate also. Due to rise in the wage
rate, goods become cheaper relatively to leisure and as a result a labourer
tends to substitute goods at the cost of his leisure; he tends to have more
goods by reducing his leisure. This is known as the, ‘substitution effect’
of wage increase.
The substitution effect of a wage increase will tend to expand the supply
of effort in two ways. Firstly, some of those who were not willing to work at
the lower wage rate would now like to work because leisure has now become
costlier in terms of goods forgone. Secondly, for the same reason those who
were already working would now like to put in more hours of work per day or
per week by reducing their leisure. Thus, the total supply of effort will tend to
expand due to these two factors.
Quite apart from the substitution effect discussed above, a wage increase
also generates an income effect. With an increase in the wage rate a labourer
grows richer than before even if he continues to work the same number of hours
per day or per week as he did when the wage rate was lower. Being richer the
worker would demand more of all normal goods including leisure. He will spend
a part of the increase in his real income in the purchase of leisure. He can do so
by reducing the number of hours worked. So, the income effect of a higher wage
rate induces the worker to reduce the number of hours worked per day or per,
week. Thus, the substitution and income effects of a wage increase tend to pull in
Self-Instructional
138 Material
opposite directions; the substitution effect tending to increase the number of hours
worked while the income effect tending to reduce the number of hours worked. NOTES
The net effect of a wage increase on the supply of effort will, therefore, depend
on the relative strengths of the two opposing tendencies. If the substitution effect
is stronger than the income effect, labourers will put in longer hours of work in
response to a rise in the wage rate. But if at any stage income effect becomes
stronger than the substitution effect, labourers will put in shorter hours of work
consequent upon arise in the wage rate. The supply curve of effort in this case
will be backward rising as the one shown in Figure 8.6 below.
In figure 8.6 (A), as the wage rate rises from W1 to W2 and then to W3.
The supply of effort expands from OA to OC and then to OD. In other words,
upto the wage level W3 substitution effect is stronger than the income effect
and as a consequence supply of effort expands in response to increases in the
wage rate. But when the wage rate rises beyond W3 the income effect becomes
stronger than the substitution effect and consequently the supply curve of labour
starts sloping backwards to the left. In the Figure 8.6 (B) when the wage rate
increases from W3 to W4 instead of expanding, the supply of effort actually
contracts from OD to OB.
Fig. 8.6
Concluding our discussion of the supply of effort we can say that the
backward rising supply of effort curve presents a strong possibility but cannot
be taken as the typical case. There is no conclusive evidence available in support
of a backward labour supply curve. Therefore, we assume that normally labour
supply curve will be upward rising bending.
Self-Instructional
Material 139
Capital is a man-made factor of production and interest is its cost. The supply
of capital in a country consists or the existing machines plants, equipment,
buildings, etc., and is called the Capital Stock. In the course of production during
the year a part of the existing capital stock is used up and to that extent the supply
diminishes. On the other hand, new machines, buildings, plant and equipment are
produced every year which go partly to replace the worn-out part of the capital
stock and partly to add to the stock. Ignoring cyclical fluctuations, the supply of
capital has been increasing over time in all modern economies.
Self-Instructional
140 Material
NOTES
Fig. 8.7
But when the price offered rises to OW2, amount supplied increases to OB.
And when the price offered rises to OW3 amount supplied increases further to OC.
As explained previously, the supply curve of any factor to the economy
as a whole will be normally more than perfectly inelastic. However, even in a
case where the supply curve of a factor to the economy as a whole is perfectly
inelastic (as for example, classical economists assumed the supply of land to
be), its supply to a particular industry will not be perfectly inelastic, it will be
more classic because the industry will always be able to attract more units of the
factor from other industries by offering a slightly higher price. Therefore, the
supply curve of a factor to an industry will normally be more elastic compared
to its elasticity of supply for the whole economy.
In a factor market a firm may be either one of a large number of purchasers or one
of the few purchasers of a particular factor. If the firm is one of a large number
of purchasers of the same factor, its purchases will constitute a negligibly small
fraction of the total market supply of the Factor. As a result, the firm would be
able to purchase any amount of the factor at the going market price. In other
words, the supply of the factor to such a firm will be perfectly elastic at the
Self-Instructional
price determined by the forces of market supply and demand for the factor. As Material 141
NOTES already explained, when the supply of a factor is perfectly elastic, price (AFC)
and marginal factor cost (MFC) to the firm are identical. On the other hand, if
the firm in question is one of the few big purchasers of a factor, its purchases
will constitute a sizeable fraction of the market supply of the factor and as a
result when the firm buys a large amount of the factor, its price is raised. Thus,
in such a case the firm is able to buy more units of the factor only at higher and
higher prices. The supply curve of the factor to the firm in such a case will rise
upward. When the supply curve is upward rising, as already explained, MFC is
higher than AFC and therefore, the MFC curve lies above AFC curve.
We may conclude our discussion by observing that normally the supply
of all factors to an economy is responsive to factor prices in the long run. In the
short run the same factor can have supply curves ranging from the vertical (i.e.,
perfectly inelastic supply curve) to the horizontal, depending on which demand
curve is coupled with supply-the demand curve of a small firm, of an industry
(or a big firm) of a group of industries (i.e., the whole economy). This is shown
in the Figure 8.8.
It is thus evident that even when the supply of a factor to the economy as
a whole is rigidly fixed (as in Figure 8.8 (A) below), it will be more elastic to a
particular use (as shown in Figure 8.8 (B) below), and will be perfectly elastic
to a small user of the factor (as shown in Figure 8.8 (C) below).
Fig. 8.8
Self-Instructional
142 Material
NOTES
8.5 LEARNING OUTCOME
1. What are the determinants of demand for factor? Derive individual and
market demand curve of factor.
2. What are the determinants of supply of factors in the economy and for
firms? Discuss.
Self-Instructional
Material 143
LESSON 9 NOTES
FACTOR PRICING
Tanu Singh
Assistant Professor
Delhi College of Arts & Commerce
University of Delhi
Structure
9.1 Learning Objectives
9.2 Introduction
9.3 Marginal Productivity Theory
9.4 Self Assessment Questions
9.5 Economic Rent
9.6 Self Assessment Questions
9.7 Learning Outcome
9.8 Terminal Questions
9.2 INTRODUCTION
Till now all the lessons have discussed about output market, that is, how
equilibrium price of a commodity is determined by the analysis of its demand
and supply. This lesson concentrates on the input market, that is, how pricing of
Self-Instructional
Material 145
NOTES the factors of production that are used to produce the commodity is determined.
It is not only dependent on the demand and supply of the factor itself but also
on the productivity of the factor. There is however few differences between the
pricing of a commodity and a factor of production like:
1. Demand for a factor of production is not direct but indirect demand as
it is dependent on the demand for the commodity for which it is used. If
there is no demand for that commodity then the factor too would not be
demanded. For example if a particular type of labour is used in manufacture
of tyres and if demand for tyres increases then the demand for the labour
too would increase and vice versa.
2. Demand for a factor of production is a joint demand as no commodity can
be produced by using just one type of factor of production. A particular
combination of different factors of production is needed to produce a
commodity. Though the factors of production can be substituted for each
other but this substitution is not infinite.
As done in the commodities market that there can be various types of market
structures starting from perfect competition on one extreme and monopoly on
the other extreme, similarly in the factor market too price determination is done
under the following conditions:
1. Perfect competition in both the product (commodity) market and factor
market.
2. Imperfect Competition in product market and perfect competition in
factor market.
3. Perfect Competition in product market and imperfect competition in
the factor market.
4. Imperfect competition in both product and factor market.
Pricing of a factor of production say land, labour, raw material or other
inputs is explained by Marginal Productivity theory as given below.
Self-Instructional
146 Material
NOTES
9.3 MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITY THEORY
Self-Instructional
Material 147
Self-Instructional
148 Material
The theory explains the demand for factors of production based on the belief that
a profit maximizing firm would employ a factor of production after analyzing
its marginal productivity (benefit to the firm) and its cost to the firm. The theory
is based on the Law of diminishing marginal returns which states that as more
and more variable factors of production are employed along with a fixed factor
of production, the output first increases at increasing rate then at diminishing
rate and ultimately the marginal product of the variable factor declines.
NOTES physical product is falling. Thus, the shape of marginal physical product (MPP)
is downward sloping as shown below in Figure 9.1:
Fig. 9.1
Figure 9.1 reveals what happens in the factor market. Now moving to the
product market, here also the firm is operating under perfect competition, thus its
demand curve is a straight line parallel to X axis and price is equal to marginal
revenue as it is fixed by the industry. It is shown in Figure 9.2. It is because of
this that marginal revenue product and value of marginal product coincide as
shown in Figure 9.1.
Fig. 9.2
Self-Instructional
150 Material
Now to get the demand curve of labour (it being the only variable factor), NOTES
we assume that wage rate is w1, at this rate the firm demands OL1 units of labour
where the cost of employing labour is equal to its benefit to the firm which is
measured by its productivity (given by VMPl). If wage rate changes to w2 or w3,
the demand of the variable factor (in this case labour) changes to OL2 and OL3
respectively. Thus, the VMPl curve is the demand curve of labour (variable factor)
for the firm in case of perfect competition in the product and factor market and
when labour is the only variable factor as shown in Figure 9.3.
Fig. 9.3
According to Gould and Lazear, “Thus the individual demand curve for a
single variable productive service is given by the value of the marginal product
curve of the productive service in question.”
Case 2: When there are several variable factors of production.
In case of firms carrying on production with various factors such that
more than one factor is variable, then the VMP or MRP is not the demand curve
as now there are multiple variable factors and they are interdependent. This is
because a change in the price of any one factor brings relative changes in price
that brings adjustment in all the variable factors of production. There are three
effects that work behind this adjustment: Income effect, Substitution effect and
profit maximizing effect. This is being explained with Figure 9.4.
Self-Instructional
Material 151
NOTES
Fig. 9.4
Initially if the wage rate is w1 the iso cost line is AB’ and producer is at e1
equilibrium using OL1 units of labour. If we assume that there are only two factors
of production that are variable namely labour and capital then with reduction in
the wage rate of labour to w2, the iso cost line pivots to AB’ and producer moves
to higher isoquant using OL2 units of labour. The increase in labour from OL1
to OL2 in fact consists of two effects namely substitution and output effect. To
divide the total effect into these two effects we draw an iso cost line parallel to
AB’ and tangent to old isoquant. The movement from e1 to e3 on the same isoquant
shows the substitution effect as labour that has become relatively cheaper is being
substituted for capital to produce the same level of output. The remaining that
is OL3 to OL2 is the output effect showing how higher output can be produced
because of cheaper labour that gives the firm higher purchasing power. E3 the
new equilibrium where firm produces Q2 units of output is however not the profit
maximizing level as with reduction in the wage rate the marginal cost of the firm
reduces and firm’s profit maximizing level of output increases to Q3 which is the
final equilibrium showing the impact of reduced wage rate in both the product
market and factor market. It is being shown in Figure 9.5.
Self-Instructional
152 Material
NOTES
Fig. 9.5
The impact of all these three effects shifts the VMP curve. Because of
the substitution effect more of labour is being used with lesser units of capital
that reduces the marginal physical productivity of labour and shifts the MPP or
VMP curve to the left. Output effect and profit maximizing effect that brings
increase in both the labour and capital shifts the MPP or VMP curve to the right
as it increases the productivity because both the factors are increased. Thus, the
final shift in the VMP curve is to the right with reduced wage rate as shown in
Figure 9.6.
The demand curve in case of more than one variable factor is thus the loci
of equilibrium points joining the wage rate and shifting VMP curves.
Self-Instructional
Fig. 9.6 Material 153
All similar firms when combined together form the industry. In the product
market horizontal summation of the demand of all firms is equal to the demand
of the industry but the same is not the case in factor market. It can be explained
using Figure 9.7:
Fig. 9.7
Initially with wage rate OW1, firm is using OL1 units of labour and if we
assume that there are ‘n’ firms in the industry then the total demand of labour
is horizontal summation of the demand of labour by all the firms that is n*OL1.
If wage rate reduces to OW2 then all firms demand more of labour and produce
more of the commodity. With increased supply the price of the commodity in
the product market reduces which shifts the VMP curve to the left and hence at
reduced price the demand of labour is OL2’ and not OL2. Thus, cs demand for
the whole industry is n*OL2’. So we see that in factor market the demand of
the industry is not simply the horizontal summation as is the case in the product
market because of interaction between factor market and product market.
increase in the wage rate the individual substitutes leisure for work and reduces NOTES
the supply of labour to enjoy the wage that he has earned. It is explained with
the help of indifference curve analysis.
Fig. 9.8
Figure 9.8 has leisure hours on X axis measured from left to right and
hours worked from right to left, and money income on Y axis. When wage rate
is W1 the income-leisure line is AM1 and individual is at equilibrium e1 where
IC1 is tangent to AM1 where he is having OL1 leisure hours and working for AL1
hours. Now if wage rate increases then income-leisure line pivots to AM2 where
individual moves to new equilibrium at e2 working for more number of hours
that is AL2 to earn higher income. With further increase in wage rates individual
moves further to e3 where he reduces hours worked and increases leisure hours
to OL3. Joining the successive equilibrium points we get the wage offer curve
which shows that initially with increase in wage rate, an individual works more to
earn higher income and with further increase in the wage rate consumer reduces
hours worked to enjoy the income that he has earned. Figure 9.8 can also be
presented as Figure 9.9.
Self-Instructional
Material 155
NOTES
Fig. 9.9
The individual supply curve of labour is backward bending but for the market
as a whole the supply curve (Figure 9.10) is upward sloping because of the
following reasons:
1. Geographical Mobility – With increased wage rate labour may move from
location to another thereby increasing the supply with increase in the wage
rate.
2. Occupational Mobility – Individuals may also shift from one occupation
to another with increase in the wage rate thereby increasing the supply.
3. Retired individuals may also join the work force with increased wage rate.
4. Youngsters too join the work force as part time with increase in the wage
Self-Instructional rate.
156 Material
NOTES
Fig. 9.10
Fig. 9.11
Self-Instructional
Material 157
NOTES The market demand for labour which is obtained from step 2 above is
downward sloping. The market supply curve of labour obtained from step 4 above
is upward sloping. The intersection of these two curves gives the equilibrium
factor price (wage rate in this case) which is OW* and OL* units of labour would
be demanded and supplied.
Thus, marginal productivity theory explained how the pricing of factors
of production is done in factor market and how it is different from the pricing of
commodities in the product market. However, the theory suffers from various
limitations which are given below:
Self-Instructional
158 Material
Exercise 3: Questions
The concept of Economic rent was first given by David Ricardo (1772– 1823)
“Rent is that portion of the produce of earth which is paid to landlord for the use
of original and indestructible powers of the soil.”
Ricardo gave two reasons for the existence of rent:
1. Scarcity of resources and
2. Alternative use of the resources
Modern Economists like Joan Robinson, etc., however were of the opinion
that rent is not only attributable to land but any and every factor of production
can earn rent, whereby it is defined as the excess of actual earnings over the
amount that is needed to keep the factor of production in its present use, the
latter being termed as transfer earning. To understand the concept of Economic
rent the concept of transfer earnings needs to be understood. It is the minimum
amount that is to be paid to a factor of production to prevent it from moving to
an alternative.
Example: If a worker is being paid Rs 2000 per day for working as an
executive whereas for working as an officer he would have been paid Rs 1500,
thus Rs 1500 is the transfer earnings. Thus, rent in this case can be calculated as:
Economic Rent = Actual Earnings – Transfer Earnings
= Rs 2000 – Rs 1500
= Rs 500
Self-Instructional
160 Material
The amount of economic rent depends upon the elasticity of supply of the NOTES
factor of production such that there can be following three cases:
1. Perfectly Inelastic Supply – If a factor of production is perfectly
inelastic then its transfer earnings are zero as it has no opportunity cost
or alternative use, thus whatever the factor earns it is all economic rent.
It is shown in Figure 9.12.
Such a situation is usually found in case of specialists like singers,
professionals etc., who earn all the rent in the form of economic surplus.
2. Perfectly Elastic Supply – When a factor of production is perfectly
elastic then it can be easily shifted to its alternative and hence whatever
it earns is the transfer earning and it is equal to actual earnings and hence
economic rent is zero Figure 9.13. It takes place in case of unskilled
labourer, rickshaw pullers, etc.
3. Relatively Inelastic Supply – When the supply is relatively inelastic
then a part of actual earning is paid to prevent its transfer to the
alternative use and the remaining that is in excess is the economic
rent. Thus, here actual earnings are more than the transfer earnings as
is shown Figure 9.14.
Self-Instructional
Fig. 9.12
Material 161
NOTES
Fig. 9.13
Fig. 9.14
Self-Instructional
162 Material
Self-Instructional
Material 163
NOTES
9.7 LEARNING OUTCOME
Self-Instructional
164 Material
LESSON 10 NOTES
Structure
10.1 Introduction
10.2 Learning Objectives
10.3 What is trade?
10.4 Why do people trade?
10.5 Theory of Absolute Advantage
10.6 Glossary
10.7 Answer to In-Text Questions
10.8 Learning outcomes
10.9 Terminal Questions
10.10 Solutions to Terminal Questions
10.1 INTRODUCTION
Let us look at our typical day. We wake up in the morning and get dressed in
clothes that have been stitched in Bangladesh. We have a cup of tea that has been
grown on a tea estate in Assam. We decide to study economics from a book that
has been written by an author in the United States and make notes in a notebook
that has been made in a factory in Maharashtra.
Every day, we rely on many people, most of whom we have never met, to
provide us with the goods and services that we enjoy. Such interdependence is
possible because people trade with one another.
Self-Instructional
Material 167
NOTES
10.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVES
People trade because there are gains from trade, that is, when countries sell goods
and services to one another, this exchange is to their mutual benefit. This means
that if there are 2 parties trading with each other, then trade makes them better
off than they were before trading. But how does that happen? Let us understand
this with the help of an example.
Example 1: Two parties and each party can produce only one good.
Consider that there are only two goods in the world – milk and potatoes.
Further, consider there are only two people in the world – Usha, who owns a
cow; and Raj who is a potato farmer.
Self-Instructional
168 Material
Case I: Usha can produce only milk and Raj is able to produce only potatoes. NOTES
Therefore, without trade, Usha consumes only milk and Raj consumes only
potatoes. Suppose after some time, Usha gets bored of just being able to drink
milk and Raj gets bored of just eating potatoes. However, if both start trading with
each other, both will be able to have both milk and potatoes. So, their consumption
set increases. This makes both better off. Hence, trade is advantageous.
Example 2: Two parties and each party can produce two goods.
Consider two countries – United States and Colombia.
One can assume that in Colombia, which is a developing nation, workers
are less efficient than their U.S. counterparts at making sophisticated goods such
as computers. This means that a given amount of resources used in computer
production yields fewer computers in Colombia than in the United States.
Also, around Valentine’s Day (which falls in February), there is a lot of
demand for roses in the United States. However, the climate is not as conducive
for growing roses in the United States as it is in Colombia. For one thing, it is a
lot easier to grow February roses in the Southern Hemisphere, where it is summer
in February rather than the winter that is there in Northern Hemisphere.
Hence, more resources are required to grow roses in the United States than
in Colombia, in the form of heated greenhouses, which is at a great expense in
terms of energy, capital investment, and other scarce resources. Those resources
could be used to produce other goods, like computers. Inevitably, there is a
tradeoff. To produce winter roses, the U.S. economy must produce fewer of
other things, such as computers. Economists use the term opportunity cost to
describe such trade-offs: The opportunity cost of roses in terms of computers is
the number of computers that could have been produced with the resources used
to produce a given number of roses.
Suppose, that the United States currently grows 10 million roses for sale
on Valentine’s Day and that the resources used to grow those roses could have
produced 100,000 computers instead. Then the opportunity cost of those 10
million roses is 100,000 computers. (Conversely, if the computers were produced
Self-Instructional
Material 169
NOTES instead, the opportunity cost of those 100,000 computers would be 10 million
roses.)
Furthermore, since we have assumed that Colombian workers are likely to
be less efficient than their U.S. counterparts at making capital intensive goods like
computers, a given amount of resources used in computer production yields fewer
computers in Colombia than in the United States. So, the trade-off in Colombia
might be something like 10 million winter roses for only 30,000 computers.
This difference in opportunity costs offers the possibility of a mutually
beneficial rearrangement of world production. Let the United States stop growing
winter roses and devote the resources this frees up to producing computers;
meanwhile, let Colombia grow those roses instead, shifting the necessary
resources out of its computer industry. The resulting changes in production can
be shown in the form of Table 10.1.
Table 10.1 Hypothetical Changes in Production
We see that the world is producing just as many roses as before, but it is
now producing more computers. So, this rearrangement of production, with the
United States concentrating on computers and Colombia concentrating on roses,
increases the size of the world’s economic pie. Because the world as a whole is
producing more, it is possible in principle to raise everyone’s standard of living.
Hence, we see that trade can make people better off, and that is why people trade.
Self-Instructional
170 Material
to show how countries can gain from trade by specializing in producing and NOTES
exporting the goods that they can produce more efficiently than other countries.
According to this theory, a country, person or firm that can produce a good
more cheaply than others is said to have an absolute advantage in producing
that good. Here, when we say ‘more cheaply’ we mean, being able to produce
one unit of the good with the least quantity of inputs or given a quantity of input,
producing the highest quantity of output. The theory further propounds that a
country, firm or person should specialize in the production of that commodity
in which it has an absolute advantage and trade it for the commodity in which
the other country, person or firm has an absolute advantage. In such a case, trade
can be beneficial for both the parties. Note, here when we say a country should
specialize in a particular commodity, we mean that it should allot all or most
of its resources towards the production of that good. The Theory of Absolute
advantage is applicable when there are absolute differences in the costs of
production of the goods in different countries.
In-Text Questions 1
1. Fill in the blanks by choosing one correct option.
If a nation has an absolute advantage in the production of a good,
____________.
a. It can produce that good at a lower opportunity cost than its trading
partner.
b. It can produce that good using fewer resources than its trading
partner.
c. It can benefit by restricting imports of that good.
d. It will specialize in the production of that good and export it.
e. None of the above is true.
Let us understand this further with the help of an example. Let us consider
another case of the example 1 discussed earlier.
Case II: Both Usha and Raj can produce milk as well as potatoes.
Self-Instructional
Material 171
NOTES Let, for simplicity, consider that there are only 2 units of input/factor(s)
of production/resources (input can be in the form of labour, time or anything
else). Let, for these 2 units of input, Usha produces 6 units of milk or 2 units of
potatoes. Further, for the same 2 units of input, assume that Raj produces 4 units
of milk or 10 units of potatoes. This means, if Usha used all the inputs available
to her towards production of milk, she would be able to produce 6 units of milk
and if she puts all her inputs towards production of potatoes, she will be able
to produce 2 units of potatoes. Similarly, if Raj used all the inputs available to
him towards production of milk, he would be able to produce 4 units of milk
and if he put all his inputs towards production of potatoes, he would be able to
produce 10 units of potatoes.
These production possibilities are represented in Table 10.2.
For 2 units of inputs/factor(s) of production-
Table 10.2 Production possibilities available to Usha and Raj if they have 2 units of input.
Milk Potatoes
Usha 6 2
Raj 4 10
As it can be seen by comparing the quantity of milk for Usha and Raj in
Table 10.2 (second column), Usha produces more amount of milk than Raj (6 >
4). This means, Usha has an absolute advantage in producing milk. Also, we see
that Raj produces more quantity of potatoes as compared to Usha (10 > 2) and
hence, Raj has an absolute advantage in producing potatoes. Thus, according to
the Absolute Advantage Theory, Usha should produce only milk and Raj should
produce only potatoes and then trade with each other.
Self-Instructional
172 Material
2. The following table shows the units of output a worker can produce per
month in Australia and Korea. Use this table to answer the question.
Food Electronics
Australia 20 5
Korea 8 4
At this juncture, we shall analyze how both parties will be better off
according to the theory of absolute advantage. For this, let us dive deeper.
Since in our example, 2 units of input Usha produces 6 units of milk or 2
units of potatoes, therefore in 1 unit of the input, she will produce 3 units of
Self-Instructional
Material 173
NOTES Table 10.3 Production possibilities available to Usha and Raj if they have 1 unit of input.
Milk Potatoes
Usha
Raj
Fig. 10.1(a) Combinations of milk and potatoes that Usha can produce
Self-Instructional
Material 175
NOTES
Fig. 10.1(b): Combinations of milk and potatoes that Raj can produce
Fig. 10.1(c): Combinations of milk and potatoes that Usha and Raj can produce,
Self-Instructional
176 Material
drawn together
It is likely that each individual will prefer to consume some combination of NOTES
both goods and not just one good (either milk or potatoes). Let us, for instance,
suppose that if there was no trade. Usha would produce and consume 3 units of
milk and 1 unit of potatoes. Similarly, Raj would produce and consume 2 units of
milk and 5 units of potatoes. Keep in mind that without trade they will consume
whatever they produce.
Alternatively, suppose Usha produces only milk, in which she has an
absolute advantage, and Raj produces only potatoes, in which he has an absolute
advantage and then they trade with each other. Say, they exchange 2 units of milk
for 4 units of potatoes. Usha will have 4 units of milk and 3 units of potatoes to
consume. Raj will have 2 units of milk and 7 units of potatoes to consume. This
is more than what they had before trade, because each person gets more of one
good and no less of the other. Thus, we can see that both parties are better off
by following the theory of absolute advantage. This is shown in tabular form in
Table 10.4 below.
Table 10.4 Gains from trade for Usha and Raj
Usha Raj
Milk Potatoes Milk Potatoes
Without trade Production and 3 1 2 5
consumption
After trade Production 6 0 0 10
Trade Gives 2 Gets 3 Gets 2 Gives 3
Consumption 4 3 2 7
Gains from +1 +2 0 +2
trade
Additionally, Figure 10.2(a) and Figure 10.2(b) show the production and
consumption of Usha and Raj before and after trade. The proposed trade between
Usha and Raj offers each of them a combination of milk and potatoes that would
be impossible in the absence of trade. In Figure 10.2(a), after trade, Usha gets to
consume at point B* which is above her PPF, rather than point B which is on her
PPF. Hence, through trade, she is able to consume more than she would have ever
been able to produce. Correspondingly, in Figure 10.2(b), Raj gets to consume at
Self-Instructional
Material 177
NOTES point A* after trade, which lies above his PPF. Hence, he too is able to consume
a bundle of goods that was impossible for him to consume without trade.
Fig. 10.2(a): Usha’s production and consumption before and after trade
Fig. 10.2(b): Raj’s production and consumption before and after trade
Self-Instructional
178 Material
NOTES
10.6 GLOSSARY
In-Text Question -1
Self-Instructional
Material 179
In-Text Question -2
Answer: The correct answer is c. because the amount of food that Australia
produces (20 units) is more than that of Korea (8 units). Similarly, the amount of
electronics that Australia produces (5 units) is more than the amount of electronics
that Korea produces (4 units). Hence Australia has an absolute Advantage in
both the goods.
Self-Instructional
180 Material
an absolute advantage and trade it for the commodity in which the other NOTES
country, person or firm has an absolute advantage.
Q.1 Consider two people, Frank and Ruby. Each of them works 8 hours per day
and can devote this time to producing wheat or rice or a combination of the
two. Table A shows the amount of time each person requires to produce
1 kilogram of each good. Frank can produce one kilogram of wheat in 15
minutes and a kilogram of rice in 60 minutes. Ruby can produce a kilogram
of wheat in 10 minutes and a kilogram of rice in 20 minutes. Table B shows
the amounts of wheat or rice Frank and Ruby can produce if they devote
all 8 hours to producing only that good.
Table A
Table B
NOTES Q.2 Let, for the same amount of labour (say L units), India produces 10 units
of wheat, and 5 units of computers and USA produces 7 units of wheat
and 11 units of computers.
a) Does India have an absolute advantage in producing any of the two
goods?
b) Does the USA have an absolute advantage in producing any of the
two goods?
c) What should the countries do based on the theory of Absolute
Advantage?
Q.3 Angela is a college student. She takes a full load of classes and has only 5
hours per week for her hobby. Angela is artistic and can make 2 clay pots
per hour or 4 coffee mugs per hour.
(a) Draw Angela’s production possibilities frontier for pots and mugs.
(b) What is Angela’s opportunity cost of 1 pot? 10 pots?
(c) What is Angela’s opportunity cost of 1 mug? 10 mugs?
(d) Why is her production possibilities frontier a straight line instead of
being bowed out?
Solution 1
(a) No, Frank does not have an absolute advantage in producing any of the
goods as compared to Ruby.
Table B shows that Frank produces 8 kg of wheat in 8 hours which is less
than the 24 kg of wheat that Ruby produces in the same time. Hence, he
does not have an absolute advantage in producing wheat. Further, from
Table B we see that Frank produces 32 kg of rice in 8 hours as compared
to 48 kg that Ruby produces. Since 32 < 48, he does not have an absolute
advantage in producing rice either.
Self-Instructional
182 Material
The same conclusion is reached when we analyze the same data written in NOTES
the form of Table A. Table A indicates that Frank takes more time (which is
out only input/ factor of production, in this case) to produce one kilogram
of wheat as compared to Ruby (60 mins/kg for Frank versus 20 mins/kg
for Ruby). Hence, Frank does not have an absolute advantage in producing
wheat. Similarly, Frank takes 15 minutes to produce a kilogram of rice
which is more than the 10 minutes that Ruby takes to produce the same
one kilogram of rice. Hence, Frank does not have absolute advantage in
producing rice either.
(b) As a corollary to Solution 1(a), Ruby has an absolute advantage in
producing both wheat and rice.
(c) Frank’s PPF is-
NOTES Solution 2
The information in the question can be represented in the form of the following
table-
Table C
Wheat Computers
India 10 5
USA 7 11
(a) Since India produces more amount of wheat (10 units) as compared to
USA (7 units) in the same amount of inputs (labour), India has an absolute
advantage in producing wheat.
(b) Since USA produces more amount of computers (11 units) as compared to
India (5 units) in the same amount of inputs (labour), USA has an absolute
advantage in producing computers.
(c) According to the theory of absolute advantage, India should specialize in
the production of wheat and trade it with USA which should specialize in
the production of computers.
Solution 3. The information given in the question can be represented in
tabular form as-
Table D
(a) Table D shows the number of pots or mugs she can make in 1 hour.
However, she has a total of 5 hours. Therefore, in 5 hours she will be able
to make 5 times the number of pots or mugs she made in 1 hour. Therefore-
Table E
This implies, on a graph where X axis shows the quantity of pots Angela NOTES
made and Y axis shows the quantity of mugs that she produced, the X intercept
of her PPF will be 10 and the Y intercept will be 20. Thus, her PPF is-
(b) From Table D, it can be inferred that the opportunity cost for 2 pots is 4
mugs.
This implies that the opportunity cost for 1 pot will be mugs.
This further implies that the opportunity cost of 10 pots will be 2 x 10 =
20 mugs.
(c) Similarly, from Table D, it can be inferred that the opportunity cost of 4
mugs is 2 pots.
This implies that the opportunity cost for 1 mug will be pot.
Self-Instructional
Material 185
Self-Instructional
186 Material
LESSON 11 NOTES
Structure
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Learning Objectives
11.3 Theory of Comparative Advantage
11.4 Sources of Comparative Advantage
11.5 Terms of Trade (TOT)
11.6 Types of Terms of Trade
11.7 Glossary
11.8 Answer to In-Text Questions
11.9 Learning Outcomes
11.10 Terminal Questions
11.11 Solutions to Terminal Questions
11.1 INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this lesson is to demonstrate how everyone can gain from trade.
Trade allows people to specialize in the production of goods for which they have
a comparative advantage and then trade it for goods that other people produce.
Because of specialization, total output rises, and through trade, we are all able
to share in the bounty. This is as true for countries as it is for individuals.
Self-Instructional
Material 187
NOTES
11.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVES
The concept of Comparative Advantage was given by David Ricardo in the year
1817 to show how countries can gain from trade by specializing in goods that
they can produce more efficiently than other countries.
According to David Ricardo, it is not the absolute but the comparative
differences in costs that determine trade relations between two countries.
Production costs differ in countries because of geographical division of labour
and specialization in production. Due to differences in climate, natural resources,
geographical situation and efficiency of labour, a country can produce one
commodity at a lower cost than the other. Hence, comparatively, that country
will have an advantage in producing that commodity vis-a-vis another country.
A country is said to have a comparative advantage in producing a good
if the opportunity cost of producing that good in terms of the other good is lower
in that country as compared to the other country. Recall that opportunity cost
refers to the cost of the next best alternative. It represents the potential benefits
that a party misses out on when choosing one alternative over another.
Ricardo shows that trade is possible between the two countries even when
a country does not have an absolute advantage in the production of any of the
Self-Instructional commodities but has a comparative advantage in the production of one commodity
188 Material
than in the other. The theory propounds that a country, firm or person should NOTES
specialize in the production of that commodity in which it has a comparative
advantage and trade it for the commodity in which the other country, person or
firm has a comparative advantage. In such a case, trade can be beneficial for
both the parties.
Let us understand this with the help of an example. Consider two people,
Frank and Ruby. Each of them works 8 hours per day and can devote this time
to producing wheat or rice or a combination of the two. If Frank produces only
wheat, he can produce 8 kilograms of wheat and if Frank produces only rice, he
can produce 32 kilograms of rice. Similarly, if Ruby produces only wheat, she
can produce 24 kilograms of it and if she produces only rice, she can produce
48 kilograms of it. Table 11.1 shows this in tabular form.
Table 11.1
For Frank-
• Opportunity cost for 8 kg of wheat = 32 kg of rice
Self-Instructional
Material 189
Ruby 2
Now, let us see how both parties will be better off by following the theory NOTES
of comparative advantage.
The PPFs of Frank and Ruby are shown in Figure 11.1(a) and Figure
11.1(b), respectively. The PPFs are straight lines instead of being bow shaped
for reasons discussed in the previous chapter. Y axis represents the quantity of
wheat and X axis represents the quantity of rice.
Given that Frank produces 8 kg of wheat if he puts all its resources/inputs
towards wheat production, the Y intercept for his PPF will be 8. Alternatively,
if he produces only rice, he will be able to produce 32 kg of rice, hence, the X
intercept of his PPF will be 32. Further, since we know the x and y intercepts,
and the PPF is a straight line, we can calculate the equation of Frank’s PPF to
be x + 4y = 32. Any combination of wheat and rice that falls on this line is the
maximum that Frank can produce given his factors of production.
Similarly, we have calculated the equation of Ruby’s PPF to be x + 2y = 48.
Self-Instructional
Fig. 11.1(b): Ruby’s PPF Material 191
NOTES It is likely that each individual will prefer to consume some combination
of both the goods. Let us say, without trade, Frank produces and consumes 4 kg
of wheat and 16 kg of rice. This bundle lies on his PPF as it satisfies the equation
x + 4y = 32, where x represents quantity of rice and y represents quantity of
wheat. Also, suppose, Ruby produces and consumes 12 kg of wheat and 24 kg
of rice before trade. This bundle lies on Ruby’s PPF as well, since it satisfies the
equation of her PPF, x + 2y = 48.
Now, let us look at an alternative that is available if the two decide to trade
with each other. Recall, when an individual or a country allocates most or all of
its resources towards the production of a particular good or service, they are said
to specialize in the production of that good or service. Suppose Frank decides
to specialize in the production of rice, in which he has a comparative advantage
such that he produces only rice, and no wheat. Also suppose, Ruby decides to
specialize in the production of wheat, in which she has a comparative advantage,
such that, she produces 18 kg of wheat and 12 kg of rice. Further, say, they trade
such that Ruby gives 5 kg of wheat for 15 kg of rice from Frank. Frank will have
5 kg of wheat and 17 kg of rice to consume. Ruby will have 13 kg of wheat and
27 kg of rice to consume. This is more than what they had before trade, because
each person gets more of one good and no less of the other. Thus, we can see
that both parties are better off by following the theory of comparative advantage
and have gains from trade. This is shown in tabular form in Table 11.3 below.
Table 11.3 Gains from trade for Frank and Ruby
Frank Ruby
Wheat Rice Wheat Rice
Without Production and 4 16 12 24
trade consumption
After trade Production 0 32 18 12
Trade Gets 5 Gives 15 Gives 5 Gets 15
Consumption 5 17 13 27
Gains from +1 +1 +1 +3
trade
Self-Instructional
192 Material
This has been shown diagrammatically in the form of Figure 11.2(a) and NOTES
Figure 11.2(b). Figure 11.2(a) shows Frank’s production and consumption without
trade and with trade. Figure 11.2(b) shows Ruby’s production and consumption
with and without trade. In Figure 11.2(a), point A shows Frank’s consumption
and production bundle without trade and point A’ and A* show his production and
consumption bundles respectively after trade. In Figure 11.1(b), point B shows
Ruby’s consumption and production bundle without trade and point and point B’
and B* show her production and consumption bundles after trade. Since A* lies
above Frank’s PPF and B* lies above Ruby’s PPF, Figures 11.2(a) and 11.2(b)
show that through trade both Frank and Ruby are able to consume a bundle of
wheat and rice that they could not have ever produced.
Fig. 11.2(a): Frank’s production and consumption before and after trade
Fig. 11.2(b): Ruby’s production and consumption before and after trade Self-Instructional
Material 193
NOTES Notice from Table 11.1 that Ruby has an absolute advantage in producing
both the goods. Hence, the theory of absolute advantage will not suggest trade.
However, we can see that both Ruby and Frank are better off through trade. This
is because Ruby has a comparative advantage in producing one good and Frank
has a comparative advantage in producing the other.
Observe that though it is possible for one person to have an absolute
advantage in both goods (as Ruby does in our example), it is impossible for one
person to have a comparative advantage in both goods. Because the opportunity
cost of one good is the inverse of the opportunity cost of the other, if a person’s
opportunity cost of one good is relatively high, the opportunity cost of the
other good must be relatively low. Comparative advantage reflects the relative
opportunity cost. Unless two people have the same opportunity cost, one person
will have a comparative advantage in one good, and the other person will have
a comparative advantage in the other good.
Therefore, even if countries do not have absolute advantage in producing
any good, they can still trade because they will have a comparative advantage
in producing some good(s).
In-Text Questions
4. Which of the following statements is true?
a. Self-sufficiency is the road to prosperity for most countries.
b. A self-sufficient country consumes outside its production
possibilities frontier.
c. A self-sufficient country at best can consume on its production
possibilities frontier.
d. Only countries with an absolute advantage in the production of
every good should strive to be self-sufficient.
5. Suppose the world consists of two countries – the United States and
Mexico. Furthermore, suppose there are only two goods – food and
clothing. Which of the following statements is true?
a. If the United States has an absolute advantage in the production
of food, then Mexico must have an absolute advantage in the
Self-Instructional
194 Material
production of clothing.
Now, since country A has a higher supply of capital relative to labour, the
price of capital relative to labour is lower in it as per the theory of supply
and demand. The price of labour is measured in wages (denoted by w)
while the price of capital is rent (denoted by r). So, the rent to wage ratio
will be lower in country A compared to country B.
Because the rent to wage ratio of country A is lower, therefore, its ratio
of cost of production for capital intensive good (good X) to the labour
Self-Instructional
196 Material intensive good (good Y) will be lower as compared to country B. Since
• The terms of trade refer to the rate at which the goods of one country
exchange for the goods of another country.
• It is a measure of the purchasing power of exports of a country in terms
of its imports and is expressed as the relation between export prices and
import prices of its goods.
Self-Instructional
Material 197
NOTES • When the export prices of a country rise relative to its import prices, its
terms of trade are said to have improved. The country gains from trade
because it can have a larger quantity of imports in exchange for a given
quantity of exports.
• On the other hand, when its imports prices rise relative to its export prices,
its terms of trade are said to have worsened. The country’s gains from trade
are reduced because it can have a smaller quantity of imports in exchange
for a given quantity of exports than before.
• If TOT is above 100, it is said that the TOT is favourable and if it is below
100, it is said to be unfavourable.
Fig. 11.3
Self-Instructional
198 Material
If we compare current year prices with the base year prices, then, NOTES
Self-Instructional
Material 199
3. Income TOT
• Given by Dorrance
• It shows a country’s changing import capacity in relation to changes
in its exports.
• Thus, the income terms of trade is the net barter terms of trade of a
country multiplied by its export volume index.
= Commodity TOT
= Quantity of exports
Self-Instructional
200 Material
NOTES
where = Single Factoral TOT
= Commodity TOT
= Productivity index of export industries
Self-Instructional
Material 201
NOTES
Self-Instructional
202 Material
If we compare current year prices with the base year prices, then,
NOTES • Thus, the utility terms of trade index can be expressed as:
11.7 GLOSSARY
Self-Instructional
204 Material
1. b
2. True
3. True
4. c
5. b
6. False
7. True
8. False. A low opportunity cost of producing one good implies a high
opportunity cost of producing the other good.
9. The Commodity TOT will be:
It implies that India’s terms of trade is unfavorable as it is less than 100.
10.
Self-Instructional
Material 205
NOTES
11.9 LEARNING OUTCOMES
Self-Instructional
206 Material
• On the other hand, when its imports prices rise relative to its export prices, NOTES
its terms of trade are said to have worsened. The country’s gains from trade
are reduced because it can have a smaller quantity of imports in exchange
for a given quantity of exports than before.
• If TOT is above 100, it is said that the TOT is favorable and if it is below
100, it is said to be unfavorable.
• There are various types of terms of trade/ various ways of calculating terms
of trade. Some of them are as follow:
o Gross Barter TOT
o Net Barter TOT
o Income TOT
o Single Factoral TOT
o Double Factoral TOT
o Real Factoral TOT
o Utility TOT
Question 1
You are watching an election debate on television. A candidate says, “We need to
stop the flow of foreign automobiles into our country. If we limit the importation
of autos, our domestic auto production will rise and India will be better off,”
1. Is it likely that India will be better off if we limit auto imports? Explain.
2. Will anyone in India will be better off if we limit auto imports? Explain.
3. In the real world, does every person in the country gain when restrictions
on imports are reduced? Explain.
Self-Instructional
Material 207
NOTES Question 2
the absolute advantage in producing computers? Which country has the NOTES
absolute advantage in producing grain?
k. After the doubling of productivity in Poland, which country has a
comparative advantage in producing computers? Which country has the
absolute advantage in producing grain? Has the comparative advantage
changed? Has the material welfare of either country changed?
I. How would your analysis change if you assumed, more realistically, that
each country had 10 million workers?
Question 3
Question 4
Take 1971 as the base year and let, India’s both export prices and import prices
be 100 in it. If we find that by the end of 1981 its index of export prices had
risen to 180 and the index of import prices had risen to 150, what will be the Net
Barter TOT? What does it indicate?
Question 5
Take 1971 as the base year and let, India’s both quantities of imports and exports
as 100 in the base year. If we find that the index of quantity imports had risen to
130 and that of quantity exports to 180 in 1981, then, what would be the Gross
Barter TOT? What does it imply?
Solution 1
Solution 2
a.
Computers Grain
Germany 15 5
Poland 4 4
b. See diagrams below:
g. Germany should produce computers while Poland should produce grain NOTES
because the opportunity cost of computers is lower in Germany and the
opportunity cost of grain is lower in Poland. That is, each has a comparative
advantage in those goods.
h. Grain must cost less than 3 computers to Germany. Computers must cost
less than 1 ton of grain to Poland.
i. They are consuming outside their production possibilities frontier. See
figures below:
Solution 3
This is not true. All countries can gain from trade if their opportunity costs of
production differ. Even the least productive country will have a comparative
Self-Instructional
Material 211
NOTES advantage at producing something, and it can trade this good to the advanced
country for less than the advanced country’s opportunity cost.
Solution 4
Solution 5
Self-Instructional
212 Material
LESSON 12 NOTES
Structure
12.1 Introduction
12.2 Learning Objectives
12.3 Trade Barriers
12.4 Types of Trade Barriers
12.5 Free Trade versus Protectionism
12.6 Glossary
12.7 Answer to In-Text Questions
12.8 Learning Outcomes
12.9 Terminal Questions
12.10 Solutions to Terminal Questions
12.11 Recommended Readings
12.1 INTRODUCTION
So far, we have established that there are gains from trade. In this lesson, we
shall explain how the international marketplace achieves these gains from trade
and how the gains are distributed among the various economic participants. We
shall analyze who gains and who loses from free trade among countries, and
how the gains compare to the losses.
Self-Instructional
Material 213
NOTES
12.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVES
1. Natural Barriers
Natural barriers to trade can be either physical or cultural. For instance, even
though raising beef in the relative warmth of Argentina may cost less than
raising beef in the bitter cold of Siberia, the cost of shipping the beef from South
America to Siberia might drive the price too high. Distance is thus one of the
natural barriers to international trade.
2. Tariff Barriers
A tariff is a tax or duty levied on goods when they enter and leave the national
Self-Instructional
214 Material
frontier or boundary. In this sense, a tariff refers to import duties and export
duties. But for practical purposes, a tariff is synonymous with import duties or NOTES
custom duties.
In-Text Questions
1. Which of the following statements about tariffs is true?
a. A tariff increases producer surplus, decreases consumer surplus,
increases revenue to the government, and reduces total surplus.
b. A tariff increases consumer surplus, decreases producer surplus,
increases revenue to the government, and reduces total surplus.
c. A tariff increases producer surplus, decreases consumer surplus,
increases revenue to the government, and increases total surplus.
d. A tariff increases consumer surplus, decreases producer surplus,
increases revenue to the government, and increases total surplus.
3. Non-Tariff Barriers
NOTES to make more profit by exporting less at higher prices, it may agree
voluntarily to restrict its exports. VERs have been used by U.S., EEC and
other industrialized countries to restrict exports of steel, TVs, automobiles,
textiles, etc., from Japan and developing countries.
In-Text Questions
2. Which of the following statements about import quotas is true?
a. Import quotas are preferred to tariff because they raise more
revenue for the imposing government.
b. Voluntary quotas established by the exporting country generate
no deadweight loss for the importing country.
c. For every tariff, there is an import quota that could have generated
a similar result.
d. An import quota reduces the price to the domestic consumers.
Free Trade Policy refers to a trade policy without any tariffs, quantitative
restrictions and other policy devices obstructing the movement of goods between
countries. Prof. Jagdish Bhagwati defines free trade policy, “as absence of tariffs,
quotas, exchange restrictions, taxes and subsidies on production, factor use and
consumption”. Thus, the policy of free trade means simply complete freedom of
international trade without any restrictions on the movement of goods between
countries.
The term protection refers to a policy whereby domestic industries are to
be protected from foreign competition. The aim is to impose restrictions on the
imports of low-priced products in order to encourage domestic industries. They
can be protected by either tariff or non-tariff barriers.
Typically, when a country opens itself to trade and if the domestic price of a
Self-Instructional
216 Material commodity is higher than the price prevailing in the rest of the world (world
price), then, through trade, the country will be importing that commodity. The NOTES
domestic producers will lose out and the producer surplus will decrease. But
the domestic consumers will gain, and the consumer surplus will increase. This
change happens in such a way that the gains of the winners exceed the losses of
the losers thereby giving overall gains to the economy. Thus, there are winners
and losers when a nation opens itself up to trade, but the gains of the winners
exceed the losses of the losers.
In-Text Questions
3. Answer whether the following statement is true or false. If it is false,
explain.
“Trade makes everyone better off.”
4. Answer whether the following statement is true or false. If it is false,
explain.
“If free trade is allowed and a country imports wheat, domestic buyers
of bread are better off and domestic farmers are worse off when
compared to the before-trade domestic equilibrium.”
To understand this, let us consider the textile market in the imaginary country of
Isoland. Say, before trade, the price of textiles is higher in Isoland than it is in the
rest of the world. That is, before trade, the domestic price is higher than the world
price. So, in our example, when the economy opens up and trade happens with
the rest of the world, the domestic consumers will be able to buy the textiles at a
lower price (i.e., the world price) than they did before the trade. Thus, free trade
in textiles would cause the price of textiles to fall in Isoland, reducing the quantity
of textiles produced in Isoland and thus reducing employment in the Isolandian
textile industry. Some Isolandian textile workers would lose their jobs. Yet free
trade creates jobs at the same time that it destroys them. When Isolandians buy
textiles from other countries, those countries obtain the resources to buy other
goods from Isoland. Isolandian workers would move from the textile industry to
those industries in which Isoland has a comparative advantage. The transition may
impose hardship on some workers in the short run, but it allows Isolandians as a
whole to enjoy a higher standard of living. Opponents of trade are often skeptical
that trade creates jobs. They might respond that everything can be produced more
cheaply abroad. Under free trade, they might argue, Isolandians could not be
profitably employed in any industry. However, the gains from trade are based
on comparative advantage, not absolute advantage. Even if one country is better
than another country at producing everything, each country can still gain from
trading with the other. Workers in each country will eventually find jobs in an
industry in which that country has a comparative advantage.
Self-Instructional
218 Material
New industries sometimes argue for temporary trade restrictions to help them
get started. After a period of protection, the argument goes, these industries will
mature and be able to compete with foreign firms. Similarly, older industries
sometimes argue that they need temporary protection to help them adjust to new
conditions. Economists are often skeptical about such claims, largely because
the infant-industry argument is difficult to implement in practice. To apply
protection successfully, the government would need to decide which industries
will eventually be profitable and decide whether the benefits of establishing
these industries exceed the costs of this protection to consumers. Yet “picking
winners” is extraordinarily difficult. It is made even more difficult by the political
process, which often awards protection to those industries that are politically
powerful. And once a powerful industry is protected from foreign competition, the
“temporary” policy is sometimes hard to remove. In addition, many economists
are skeptical about the infant-industry argument in principle. Suppose, for
instance, that an industry is young and unable to compete profitably against
foreign rivals, but there is reason to believe that the industry can be profitable
in the long run. In this case, firm owners should be willing to incur temporary
losses to obtain the eventual profits. Protection is not necessary for an infant
industry to grow. History shows that start-up firms often incur temporary losses
and succeed in the long run, even without protection from competition.
A common argument is that free trade is desirable only if all countries play by
the same rules. If firms in different countries are subject to different laws and
regulations, then it is unfair (the argument goes) to expect the firms to compete
in the international marketplace. For instance, suppose that the government of
Neighborland subsidizes its textile industry by giving textile companies large tax
breaks. The Isolandian textile industry might argue that it should be protected
from this foreign competition because Neighborland is not competing fairly.
Would it, in fact, hurt Isoland to buy textiles from another country at a subsidized
price? Certainly, Isolandian textile producers would suffer, but Isolandian textile
Self-Instructional
220 Material
consumers would benefit from the low price. The case for free trade is the same NOTES
as before: The gains of the consumers from buying at the low price would exceed
the losses of the producers. Neighborland’s subsidy to its textile industry may be
a bad policy, but it is the taxpayers of Neighborland who bear the burden. Isoland
can benefit from the opportunity to buy textiles at a subsidized price. Rather than
objecting to the foreign subsidies, perhaps Isoland should send Neighborland a
thank-you note.
12.6 GLOSSARY
1. a
Self-Instructional
222 Material 2. c
3. False. Some gain and some lose but the gains of the winners outweigh the NOTES
losses of the losers.
4. True
5. False. The country should export that good.
6. d
7. b
8. d
NOTES • When a country imports a good, the producer surplus decreases and the
consumer surplus increases. So, the consumer wins and the producer loses
when a country imports a good.
• When a country opens itself to trade and it imports a good because the
world price is less than the domestic before-trade price, the gains of the
consumer exceed the losses of the producer when a country imports a good.
• There is a deadweight loss associated with a tariff.
• There is often a debate in policy circles whether to impose trade restrictions
or to allow free trade. Different arguments are made for both.
• Arguments for free trade-
o The gains of the winners exceed the losses of the losers thereby giving
overall gains to the economy.
o Increased variety of goods
o Lower costs through economies of scale
o Increased competition
o Enhanced flow of ideas
• Arguments for restricting trade/arguments against free trade-
o The Jobs Argument- Free trade will cause loss of jobs in the domestic
industry which produces the goods that are being imported.
o The National-Security Argument- Some industries argue that their
product is vital for national security so it should be protected from
international competition. They argue that if a war later broke out and
the foreign supply was interrupted, the country may not be able to
defend itself.
o The Infant-Industry Argument- New industries argue that they need
temporary protection from international competition until they become
mature enough to compete.
o The Unfair-Competition Argument- Opponents of free trade argue
that other countries provide their industries with unfair advantages such
as subsidies, tax breaks, and lower environmental restrictions, thereby
Self-Instructional
224 Material making the competition unfair.
NOTES again, consumers are less likely to organize and lobby the government to
restrict exports, so exports are rarely restricted.
• The overwhelming majority of economists find no sound economic
argument in opposition to free trade. The only argument against free trade
that may not be defeated on economic grounds is the national-security
argument. This is because it is the only argument against free trade that is
not based on economics but rather it is based on other strategic objectives.
Self-Instructional
226 Material
NOTES ii. If a tariff is placed on this good, consumer surplus is the area
a. A.
b. A + B.
c. A + B + C.
d. A + B + C + D + E + F.
e. A + B + C + D + E + F + G.
iii. Government revenue from the tariff is the area
a. C + D + E + F
b. D + E + F
c. D + E
d. G
e. E
iv. If a tariff is placed on this good, producer surplus is the area
a. G
b. G + C
c. G + C + D + E + F
d. G + C + D + E + F + B
e. G + C + E
v. The deadweight loss from the tariff is the area
a. B + D + E + F
b. B
c. D + E + F
d. D + F
e. E
Self-Instructional
228 Material
NOTES
12.10 SOLUTIONS TO TERMINAL QUESTIONS
Solution 1
Solution 2
Solution 3
1. d
2. b
3. e
4. b
5. d
Self-Instructional
Material 229
NOTES
12.11 RECOMMENDED READINGS
Self-Instructional
230 Material