Joskow Tirole 2005
Joskow Tirole 2005
Joskow Tirole 2005
Paul Joskoww
JeanTirolez
I. INTRODUCTION
We would like to thank Richard Green, Shmuel Oren, Masheed Rosenqvist, Steven Stoft,
Frank Wolak, the editor and three anonymous referees for helpful comments on earlier drafts.
Joskow gratefully acknowledges research support from the MIT Center for Energy and
Environmental Policy Research and the Cambridge-MIT Institute.
wAuthors’ affiliations: MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 02142-1347, U.S.A.
e-mail: pjoskow@mit.edu
zInstitut d’ Economie Industrielle, Université des Sciences Sociales de Toulouse, Place
Anatole France, 31042 Toulouse, France.
e-mail: tirole@cict.fr
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK, and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
233
234 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
1
Similar issues are likely to arise with merchant investment in other network industries such
as natural gas pipelines, railroad infrastructure and highways. However, we have not explored
these issues in the context of other network industries.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
236 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
2
Vertical integration between transmission ownership and system operations is likely to
reduce these incentive problems and, if transmission owners are also independent of generation
and marketing of power, may be a superior organizational structure.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 237
shall assume that a nodal pricing system for electric energy is in place with
attributes similar to those being proposed by the U.S. Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (FERC) in its SMD proposals and what is in
operation in New York, New England and PJM in the U.S. This is the most
conducive framework for merchant investment because nodal prices provide
a measure of locational scarcity that is necessary to make this framework a
plausible option.
Under this model, an independent system operator (ISO) operates a real-
time balancing market and allocates scarce transmission capacity using bids
to increase or decrease generation or demand at each node. That is, the ISO
takes all of the bids (generation and demand) and finds the ‘least cost’ set of
uniform market-clearing price bids to balance supply and demand at each
generation and consumption node on the network using a security
constrained dispatch model. This establishes day-ahead quantity commit-
ments and nodal prices that reflect both congestion and marginal losses.3
The model recognizes that there are incumbent transmission owners (TO)
who own the existing transmission assets and requires that the system
operator (SO) and TO be separate entities and operate independently.4 The
incumbent TO receives some cost-of-service compensation for the usage of a
grid that it no longer controls to compensate it for legacy investments and
ongoing maintenance costs. New investments in transmission are antici-
pated to be made by competing merchant investors whose compensation is
based on the value of Congestion Revenue Rights (CRRs)5 created by their
investments. These financial rights represent the right to receive congestion
revenues defined as the difference between the nodal prices between the two
nodes (point-to-point) covered by the relevant CRR times the quantity of
CRRs held.
The separation between ownership (TO) and control (SO) functions in
this model is motivated by two considerations. First, a market driven
transmission system leads to multiple owners of parts of the grid; while the
owners can form a cooperative to operate the grid, their goals are in general
3
Generators may enter into bilateral contracts with marketers or load serving entities (LSEs)
and schedule supplies with the ISO separately from the organized day-ahead market. However,
they still have to pay any congestion charges associated with their schedules based on the
difference in nodal prices between the injection and receipt points. The day-ahead schedules,
nodal prices, and congestion charges are ‘commitments.’ They can be adjusted in real time by
submitting adjustment bids to the real time balancing markets (which again rely on bids, a
security constrained dispatch and nodal prices) to allow these schedules to be changed based on
real time economic conditions.
4
Exactly what functions are assigned to the TO and what functions to the SO is a subject of
continuing debate and depends in part on whether the TO is ‘independent’ of generators and
marketers that use its facilities to participate in the wholesale market.
5
Congestion Revenue Rights have also been referred to in the literature as Transmission
Congestion Contracts (TCCs) and Financial Transmission Rights (FTRs). These names are
interchangeable for our purposes.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
238 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
6
Incumbent owners of transmission lines that are being compensated based on congestion
rents will have incentives to oppose investments by others in generation or transmission that
reduce these congestion rents. Generators located in congested areas will have incentives to
oppose transmission enhancements that would reduce or eliminate the congestion.
7
See, e.g., Hansmann [1996].
8
In practice, due to the lack of market-based penalties for outages, dispatching does not
quite correspond to the least-cost optimization used in economic and engineering models;
rather, grid operators have substantial discretion over how much outage they are willing to take
while dispatching. This discretion in turn potentially provides incentives for system operators
to manipulate the congestion rents received by the owners (Glachant and Pignon, [2002]).
9
We focus on transmission investments that affect congestion on the high voltage network.
Regulators in the U.S. often break transmission investments down into additional categories.
First, there are local transmission investments ‘inside’ the demand node. These investments are
sometimes called ‘reliability’ investments. Second, interconnection investments are invest-
ments that must be made by an incumbent grid owner to connect new generators with the rest of
the network. These are often treated like radial links and are typically paid for by the generators
seeking interconnection. However, it is hard to draw bright lines between reliability
investments, interconnection investments, and investments that affect network congestion.
We recognize that, in practice, there may not always be a bright line between network
deepening and network expansion investments.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 239
investments’ policy is likely to be extremely difficult. First, adding third-party
facilities that are fully integrated with the existing network from a
physical and maintenance perspective creates significant incentive
problems with decentralized ownership. The problems of defining a good
set of rules for investing in and maintaining facilities of this type with
decentralized ownership is further exacerbated by the heterogeneous nature
of transmission facilities. While it is theoretically possible to devise
contractual arrangements that will solve the incentive problems, including
opportunistic behavior of one or more parties, writing and enforcing such
contracts will be very difficult as a practical matter. Second and relatedly,
one would need to allocate carefully the new capacity of the line between the
initial design and maintenance choice of the original owner and the actions
of the renters who make deepening investments. This ‘moral hazard in
teams’ problem is a substantial obstacle to the design of an effective third
party access policy for this type of transmission investment. Third, the
merchant investment model effectively requires that there be free entry into
the development of new transmission capacity; entrants, though, are likely
to have less information about existing transmission lines than their owners.
These considerations suggest that network deepening investments can, as a
practical matter, only be implemented efficiently by the incumbent
transmission network owner.
Let us start from the theoretical case for market driven or ‘merchant’
transmission investment. This rationale has been developed, inter alia, by
Hogan [1992] and Wu et al. [1996], Chao and Peck [1996] and examined
further by Bushnell and Stoft [1996, 1997] for simple cases. The basic
argument is conveyed in the two-node framework of figure 1. [This paper
focuses on the two-node framework for expositional simplicity. See our
discussion paper (Joskow-Tirole [2003]) for an analysis of transmission
investment when there are loop flows.]
Figure 1 depicts a simple situation in which load serving entities
(distribution companies or marketers buying on behalf of retail consumers,
or large industrial customers buying directly) in the South (say, a large city)
buy their power from cheap generation sources in the North and, possibly, in
addition, more expensive sources in the South. Alas, the capacity of the line
from North to South is limited to K and, faced with net demand/supply
curves in the North and the South, the system operator is forced to dispatch
‘out of merit’. For example, the system operator calls on expensive
generators in the South while generators in the North would be willing to
supply this amount at a lower price if more transmission capacity were
available. The rationing of the scarce North-South capacity is implemented
by setting two nodal prices, pS and pN that clear the markets in the South and
the North, respectively. The difference, Z 5 pS –pN, is the shadow price of the
transmission capacity constraint. The area ZK is the congestion rent and the
{
North
North SN
B
η
Κ
C Net Demand in
pN South DS
South
No Congestion
δΚ
Κ Κ Quantity
Figure 1
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 241
triangle ABC is the congestion or redispatch cost. The latter represents the
cost of running more costly generation in the South because less costly
imports from the North are limited by transmission congestion. The
congestion rent and the congestion cost are sometimes confused and it is
important to recognize their appropriate definitions and meaning.
Now consider a marginal (unit) increase in transmission capacity (dK).
This unit increase allows one more kWh to flow from North to South,
replacing a marginal generator in the South with cost pS by a cheaper
generator in the North producing at cost pN. That is, the social value of the
investment is given by the reduction in the area ABC in Figure 1.
Assume that the builder of this marginal capacity, whether it is a new
entrant or the incumbent TO, is rewarded through a financial transmission
right that pays a dividend equal to the shadow price of the transmission
constraint. A non-incumbent merchant company will enter to build this
extra capacity as long as Z exceeds the cost of building it. By contrast, if an
incumbent grid owner is compensated through the payment of congestion
rents, it may not want to make this marginal investment as it must compare
the extra revenue Z net of the cost of expanding the capacity with the
reduction in the congestion rent on its inframarginal transmission units
( KdZ/dK). It is only when the incumbent grid owner’s capacity has been
rated at some level K not too different from actual capacity, and that the
corresponding rights, with value ZK, have been auctioned off, that the
monopoly distortion vanishes. The incremental capacity then yields
dZ
Z þ ðK K Þ dK close to Z. As in the case of Contracts for Differences,10
forward sales restore proper incentives for a player with market power.
Hogan [1992] and Bushnell and Stoft [1996, 1997] show that under certain
conditions (besides nodal pricing, no increasing returns to scale, congestion
rights satisfying feasibility constraints, no market power in the wholesale
market, well defined property rights, a complete set of competitive liquid
forward markets to provide sufficient information on long run demand and
supply conditions and risk management, etc.), all profitable transmission
investments are efficient. This powerful result appears to transform the
transmission investment problem from one that appears to be almost
intractable to one that requires a simple implementation of a property-rights
based market system.
Accordingly, merchant investment’s appeal is that it allows unfettered
competition to govern investment in new transmission capacity, placing the
risks of investment inefficiencies and cost overruns on investors rather than
consumers, and bypassing planning and regulatory issues associated with a
structure that relies on regulated monopoly transmission companies. In
addition, in theory, it allows investment in new generating capacity in the
10
See Green (1999).
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
242 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
The reasoning above assumes that the prices that clear the markets in the
North and the South reflect the marginal costs of production (and the
marginal willingnesses to pay12) at each location, so that the congestion rent
perceived by merchant investors does reflect the social savings brought
about by the investment. That is, potential investors in new transmission
capacity see the correct locational price signals in the wholesale markets.
Factors that may distort prices include market power, regulatory interven-
tions like price caps, the absence of a complete representation of consumer
demand in the wholesale market, and discretionary behavior by system
operators when the network is constrained.
Suppose for example that there is a generator with market power in the
South, and that the latter region is import constrained. The generator
exercises market power by withdrawing capacity and driving the price in the
South up. Hence
p S > cS ;
where cS denotes the marginal cost of production in the South. The
measured congestion rent then overestimates the cost savings associated
with the replacement of one unit of power generated in the South by one unit
of power generated in the North, suggesting an over-incentive to reinforce
the link, ignoring other market imperfections.13 On the other hand, the
increased transmission capacity does not replace production in the South
one-for-one; it also leads to an increase in total energy consumption in the
11
Of course, these are attributes with which any alternative investment framework, including
any regulated investment framework, must contend.
12
We will present the argument in terms of cost savings; because what matters is net supply at
each node, the same argument would apply to the demand side.
13
For example, as we discuss below, lumpiness in transmission investment leads to under-
investment.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 243
South, which yields a social benefit equal to (pS cS) times the expansion in
consumption. The box below shows that, under a weak assumption, the first
effect dominates, and therefore market power results in an over-incentive to
invest in merchant transmission. The assumption is that the Southern
monopolist’s reaction curve be downward sloping in a Cournot game.
Intuitively, the transmission line creates a Cournot ‘duopoly’ in the South, in
which the Southern firm faces a fixed output from its (transmission) rival. A
downward sloping reaction curve means that the Southern firm curtails its
output as the transmission capacity expands. This implies that the energy
consumption increase effect is smaller than the inflated signal effect (the two
effects would cancel if the output in the South were invariant to an increase
in imports from the North).14
14
Similarly, and to the extent that reinforcing the line is akin to adding production capacity
in the South, this suggests that entrants in generation have too much of an incentive to invest in
the South as well. The box verifies that this is indeed the case.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
244 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
and
cS cN < Z:
There is an over-incentive to invest if and only if
dW < ZdK;
i.e.,
Conversely, a generator with market power in the North may (while still
making full use of the link) be able to raise price pN by withdrawing
production capacity F perhaps to the level of pS if it faces no competition
in the North (Oren [1997], Stoft [1999], Joskow and Tirole [2000]). In this
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 245
case, the congestion rent underestimates the gain from expanding the line’s
capacity, resulting in an under-investment by merchant transmission
investors. At the same time, it could lead to inefficient entry of generat-
ing capacity in the North in response to the short run monopoly rents
created there.
As a second example, in the case of market power in the South (this
is the situation that will generate very high prices for consumers in the
South), the regulator may be tempted to impose a price cap.15 While the
price cap improves economic efficiency if it really is about constraining
market power, it may also distort price signals if high prices are at least
sometimes due to tight competitive supply and demand conditions rather
than market power. A tight price cap in the South then reduces the
congestion rents during those hours that are very important because they
produce the bulk of the rents to support investment, yielding under-
investment in transmission.16
Third, prices may not clear supply and demand in real time because
market clearing processes are not fast enough to respond to rapid changes in
supply and demand conditions while maintaining physical requirements for
frequency, voltage, and stability on the network. To maintain physical
network parameters, administrative rationing is then substituted for prices
to balance supply and demand as a consequence of what is effectively a
problem of incomplete markets (Wilson [2002]). Moreover, the system
operator has discretion in determining the exact nature of the responses to
operating reserve deficiencies or ‘scarcity.’ For example, Patton [2002]
shows that during tight supply conditions, the system operator takes actions
that tend to depress market-clearing prices. Whether it is administrative
rationing in response to incomplete markets or price controls motivated by
efforts to constrain market power or price distortions caused by market
power or discretionary decisions by the system operator, actual prices will
depart from the efficient prices required to give the efficient signals for new
investment. These imperfections are potentially important with regard to
transmission (and generation) investment because the prices that create
significant congestion rents tend to occur in a relatively small number of
hours and these hours also happen to be the hours when these types of price
distortions are most likely to occur.
15
Or a de facto price cap as when the system operator curtails load administratively when
prices don’t clear the market.
16
Capacity payments cum capacity obligations have been introduced or proposed in some
jurisdictions to respond to the distortions caused by price caps on spot markets. We show
elsewhere (Joskow and Tirole [2004]) that under certain conditions capacity payments may
compensate for the distortions caused by spot market price caps. If capacity payments are not
properly reflected in the prices seen by potential merchant transmission investors, their
investment decisions will be distorted.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
246 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
V (i). Pre-emption
The analysis of the effects of market power on investment incentives in the
previous section, as well as most of the literature upon which the merchant
investment model relies, assumes that transmission investment is not
characterized by economies of scale or ‘lumpiness.’ However, network
expansion investments are likely to be lumpy. That is, the average cost of a
new link declines as its capacity increases, other things equal (Baldick and
Kahn [1992], Perez-Arriaga et al., [1999]). The impact of lumpiness is
illustrated in figure 2. The initial capacity is K0 and social efficiency would
command that it be brought to a level K1 in a single, discrete investment.
Assuming that the energy market participants are perfectly competitive,
so that net demand/supply curves represent the true marginal costs/
willingnesses to pay, the surplus created (or congestion cost reduced) by the
expansion of capacity from K0 to K1 is depicted by the shaded area in figure
2. The value, Z1(K1 K0) of the transmission rights (equal to the ex post
congestion rents) granted to the merchant investors building this capacity
expansion understates the social surplus S1 it creates by reducing congestion
costs. Lumpiness thus results in an underincentive to reinforce the system for
the same reason that an incumbent grid owner rewarded by congestion rents
has suboptimal incentives to remove these congestion rents.17 What is
needed to create proper incentives for investment is that the merchant
investor be granted the entire shaded area in figure 2. The corresponding
incentive mechanism requires knowledge of net supply and demand curves,
though, and does not fit directly with the merchant investment paradigm.
Another source of lumpiness for network expansion investments arises
because there may be a scarcity of rights of way, for example a unique
corridor between a cheap and an expensive area. The difficulties that new
transmission corridors face in obtaining siting authority suggests that the
available corridors for new lines through many areas will be limited in the
sense that (for example) one additional corridor may be available through
the Pyrenees between France and Spain, and it may accommodate one new
link that could be of any size between 100 MW and 1000 MW. This scarcity is
particularly problematic as demand grows. Merchant investment is then
likely to end up in a ‘pre-emption and monopoly’ situation. In a system with
growing demand, pre-emption leads to an investment at the first date at
which the discounted value of the financial rights on the additional capacity
is equal to the investment cost. The box below also contains an analysis of
the incentive to get a toehold by sinking a small investment to pre-empt
additional entry and produce monopoly rents for the merchant transmission
17
The underincentive effect associated with lumpiness is also discussed by Gans and King
[2000].
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 247
surplus S1
Net supply in
η0 η1
the North
Net demand
in the South
K0 K1
Figure 2
η′2 η2
Net supply in
η0 η ′ η1 the North
Net demand
in the South
(before date T )
K0 K′ K1
Figure 3
ðK1 K0 Þ ðK 0 K0 Þ
Z2 I 00 > Z02 ;
r r
which we will assume. Let us look for an equilibrium in which a
merchant investor preempts at date t o T by investing a little (I 0 ) and
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 249
then upgrades the line at time T:
1 erðTtÞ 0 0 Z ðK1 K0 Þ
I0 ¼ Z ðK K0 Þ þ erðTtÞ 2 I 00 :
r r
For this, it must be the case that preemption at (t e) with the full
investment does not pay off:
1 erðTtÞ erðTtÞ
I* Z1 þ Z2 ðK1 K0 Þ;
r r
or h i 1 erðTtÞ
I I 0 þ erðTtÞ I 00 * ½Z1 ðK1 K0 Þ Z0 ðK 0 K0 Þ:
r
The right-hand side of this inequality is negative if the total value of
the rights (the total congestion rent) decreases with the capacity of the
link in the relevant region. The left-hand side represents the cost of
building all the links at once rather than in two steps, and may be
positive or negative.
Aside from the timing considerations discussed above, note that
given an entry at t, a social planner might want to jump to capacity K1
directly, as the difference in social surplus for capacities K1 and K 0
exceeds the increase (or decrease) in the flow revenue of rights
holdings. Thus, there may be too small an investment.
18
Transmission lines do not take very long to build once they have obtained siting permits.
However, for major new transmission corridors, the permitting process can be very lengthy.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
250 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
the transmission project even if the merchant investor has announced his
intention and has started (limited) work on this project.19
V (ii). Gaming between merchant investment projects
Section 5.1 argued that substitute merchant investments give rise to
preemption games. By contrast, complementary merchant investments,
assuming that they are best undertaken by separate entities, may give rise to
wars of attrition. As illustrated in the following example, with complemen-
tary investments each owner has an incentive to dimension his project
slightly smaller than the other owner’s project; the former project then is the
bottleneck and receives the entire congestion rent while the latter exhibits
excess capacity and generates no rent. Such a situation is conducive to wars
of attrition in which no owner wants to move first by fear of being ‘under-
dimensioned’ by the rival owner.
19
Such timing issues are of course not specific to transmission investments. But the latter are
particularly vulnerable to pre-emption strategies due to their long lead time.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 251
N pN
KNM
M pM
KMS
S pS
Figure 4
IT > IG ;
20
The import capacity of Path 15 (connecting Northern and Southern California) when all of
the associated AC lines are operational varies between about 2600 MW and 3950 MW
depending upon the ambient temperature and remedial action schemes that are in place to
respond to unanticipated outages of generating plants and transmission lines. The variance
reflects both thermal limits and the application of a set of reliability criteria based on complex
system contingency studies. The rated capacity of Path 15 falls by about 600 MW as the
ambient temperature rises, other things equal. The rated capacity of Path 15 varies by about
1300 MW depending on the availability of various remedial action schemes to respond to
transmission and certain generation outages. California ISO, Operating Procedure T-122A,
November 6, 2002. It is also important to recognize that in the U.S. and Europe, there is not a
single SO controlling the network, but multiple SOs controlling independent segments of the
network. To maintain reliability and avoid free riding, less flexible contingency criteria must be
defined than might be the case if there were a single SO operating the network in real time.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 255
answers to these questions necessarily affect the incentives merchant
investors will have to make transmission investments.
The impact of a generous [K(o þ ), say] or conservative [K(o ), say]
distribution of rights on investment incentives depends on the way the
resulting shortfall or surplus is financed or redistributed. Suppose, first, that
one appeals to the taxpayer. Even if taxation were lump-sum, there would
still be distortions in investment behavior; generous distributions over-
incentivize merchants, while conservative ones under-incentivize them. By
contrast, appropriate taxes on users of the transmission network21 make
biased distributions of rights neutral in this radial network, provided that
the dispatch is efficient: An efficient dispatch implies that in each state of
nature, the cum-tax (or subsidy) price at a given node fully utilizes the link.
And so end-users are unaffected by a generous or conservative distribution
of rights on the line. Because there is no source or sink of money outside of
the industry, rights owners receive the same overall dividend (for example,
through a smaller per-unit dividend in the case of a generous distribution).
This taxation solution is however complex, since the taxes have to be state
contingent.
Rather than dealing with the payment shortfall or surplus problems
associated with the kinds of property rights that have been proposed, it
seems more natural simply to divide the merchandizing surplus proportio-
nately among the rights’ owners based on their relative ownership shares.
The next box analyzes the optimal relative allocation rule (in the same way
percentage ownership, but not the total number of shares, matters to
determine one’s proceeds from the distribution of a firm’s dividend, the exact
number of rights does not matter as long as the merchandizing surplus is
distributed proportionately among rights’ owners). It shows that the
optimal allocation rule derives from standard asset pricing (CAPM)
principles in finance. An addition to an existing link is particularly valuable
if its actual capacity remains high when the primary link is very congested.
Its construction then creates a diversification benefit. These diversification
benefits are ignored both in the traditional definition of fixed MW point-to-
point property rights payment obligations and with a simple proportional
allocation rule.
For example, suppose that the primary North-South AC line exhibits
reduced capacity (or breakdowns) during very hot weather. Then an
addition along the same path has less social value if it is an aerial AC line
than if it is an underground DC line not subject to the same climatic shocks
21
We here have in mind proportional taxes on electricity in the South (so the price is pS þ tS,
where pS is the nodal price in the South) and a tax on exports from the North (where generators
receive pN tN ). When actual capacity (Ka) is larger than the number of rights K, this
effectively reduces the net dividend paid to rights holders so that there is sufficient revenue to
compensate them.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
256 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
even if average line availability is the same for both. Allocations of rights
based only on expected link capacity therefore miss the point that, for a given
capacity, some lines may provide better insurance than others. More
generally, an allocation of rights solely in proportion to (or equal to)
expected capacities provides insufficient incentives to build lines whose
availability covaries with the shadow price less (in absolute value) than that
of the existing lines.22
22
This point applies as well to the case of networks with loop flow. That is, if a transmission
investment has a diversification benefit, it must be reflected in the allocation of rights if the
rights are relied upon to stimulate efficient transmission investments.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 257
proportional to average capacities; and so the merchant investor receives
dK
K rights:
K þ dK
The merchandizing surplus is distributed to rights owners. Needless
to say, distributions of rights that would not reflect expected capacities
could by themselves introduce a bias in merchant investors’ incentives.
For example, suppose that the incumbents in the past received a very
generous rating of the existing lines from North to South, while rating
standards are strengthened for new comers. The latter then receive a
disproportionately small share of total rights, which penalizes them
when the merchandizing surplus is distributed among rights’ owners,
and thereby gives little incentive to sink new investment. To avoid such
obvious biases, we assume an allocation of rights proportional to
average capacity. Even so, merchant incentives may be inappropriate,
as we will see shortly.
The congestion dividend, d(o) paid to the owner of a right is therefore:
SN ¼ aN þ bN pN þ eN
:
DS ¼ aS bS pS þ eS :
This implies that the analysis above generalizes when line availabilities
are independent of demand and supply shocks (cov (ei, y) 5 cov
(ei, m) 5 0 for i 5 N, S).
On the other hand, line availability may be related to demand and
supply shocks. For example, it may be that a line (old or new) is subject
to the same climatic shock as the demand node. Hot weather may
simultaneously increase demand and limit the capacity of the line
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 259
bringing electricity from a cheaper node (precisely when the line is most
needed). Such a line obviously has a lower social worth than one whose
availability is less negatively correlated with increases in demand at the
expensive node.
Example 2 (uncertainty about energy market players only). Suppose
that there is no uncertainty about the actual capacities of the lines:
yðoÞ ¼ ZðoÞ ¼ 0 for all o:
Hence all uncertainty comes from generation and consumption. In
this case, the private and social incentives coincide:
R ¼ dW:
The difficulty in putting a number in front of a line’s ‘capacity’ (in the two-
node case) raises other issues. In a nutshell, the actual capacity of the line
depends on discretionary choices, and under a merchant transmission model
control is likely to be separated from ownership due to the conflict of interest
associated with the measurement of congestion rents. This section considers
one such discretionary action: dispatching.
As we have already noted, rewarding merchant investment through
congestion rents requires separating ownership and dispatch in order
to obtain an unbiased measure of this rent. But this separation of owner-
ship and dispatch raises a moral-hazard-in-teams problem. The electric
system’s state-contingent output (to simplify, the intensity of power in the
absence of outage and the probability and duration of an outage) depends on
both the care and the forecasts of the owner (the quality of the line, its
maintenance, and its adequacy to consumers’ needs) and the quality of the
management of the grid by the system operator, as the latter must use her
acumen to get lots of power through without creating a high risk of outage.
This raises two points: First, one cannot consider incentives given to
merchant investors without also specifying those of the system operator.
Second, moral hazard in teams reduces accountability. An outage can be
claimed to result from poor line maintenance or from imprudent
dispatching. Conversely, high power prices may be due to an undue
conservatism of the system operator or to a proper dispatching motivated by
low line quality.
There is also a potential moral-hazard-in-teams problem among line
owners. Recall that merchant investment incentives are better aligned with
the public interest when merchants own inframarginal transmission facilities
whose congestion rent is to be preserved. The total North-South capacity
may then belong to different owners. The same value of a given actual
capacity K selected by the independent system operator may correspond to
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
260 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
23
At an abstract level, one can view transmission owners and the SO as a team (in the sense of
Holmström [1982]) jointly delivering an output F state-contingent powerF to the final
consumers. A general principle is that proper incentives require that each member of the team
be made the residual claimant for the team performance ðxLð0Þ þ ½1 xL Kb in the notation
of the next example). Making each member residual claimant may however be very costly
because of adverse selection and collusion.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 261
Dispatcher with conservative incentives.
Turn now to the system operator’s incentives. Suppose that the SO
is penalized more for outages than she is rewarded for increases in the
amount of power flowing through the network ; that is, she solves:
n h i o
min x Kb K yLð0Þ þ 1 x Kb K L Kb ;
b
K
dW h i d Kb
¼ x0 Lð0Þ L Kb x0 ð1 yÞLð0Þ :
dK dK
And so
" #
dW d b
K
¼ ð1 xÞZ þ x0 ð1 yÞLð0Þ 1 ;
dK dK
d Kb
< 1:
dK
In words, the system operator takes less risk as K increases, because
the marginal gain from increased throughflow decreases. We therefore
conclude that
dW
< ð1 xÞZ;
dK
and so congestion rent payments over-incentivize merchant investors.
In a sense, the SO’s conservative behavior implies that insufficient use
will be made of the added capacity and so the shadow price of the link
overstates the value of additional capacity. This result shows that one
cannot properly analyze merchant investment (or, for that matter, the
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
262 PAUL JOSKOW AND JEAN TIROLE
VIII. CONCLUSION
REFERENCES
Aghion, P. and Bolton, P., (1987), ‘Contracts as a Barrier to Entry,’ American Economic
Review, 77(3), 388–401.
r Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 2005.
MERCHANT TRANSMISSION INVESTMENT 263
Baldick, R. and Kahn, E., (1992), ‘Transmission Planning in the Era of Integrated
Resource Planning: A Survey of Recent Cases,’ Lawrence Berkeley Laboratory, LBL-
32231.
Bohn, R. E.; Caramanis, M. C. and Schweppe, F. C., (1984), ‘Optimal Pricing in Electrical
Networks over Space and Time,’ Rand Journal of Economics, 15(3), 360–376.
Bushnell, J., (1999), ‘Transmission Rights and Market Power,’ Electricity Journal, 12(8),
77–85.
Bushnell, J. and Stoft, S., (1996), ‘Electric Grid Investment Under a Contract Network
Regime,’ Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10, 61–79.
Bushnell, J. and Stoft, S., (1997), ‘Improving Private Incentives for Electric Grid
Investment,’ Resource and Energy Economics, 19, 85–108.
Celebi, M., (undated), ‘An Analysis of Incentives to Provide Line Capacity and
Reliability in Deregulated Power Networks,’ mimeo, Brattle Group.
Chao, H. P. and Peck, S., (1996), ‘A Market Mechanism for Electric Power
Transmission,’ Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10(1), 25–59.
Chisari, O., et al. (2001), ‘High-Tension Electricity Network Expansion in Argentina:
Decision Mechanisms and Willingness-to-pay Revelation,’ Energy Economics, 23,
697–715.
Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J., (1985), ‘Preemption and Rent Equalization in the Adoption
of a New Technology,’ Review of Economic Studies, 52(170), 383–401. Reprinted in
Readings in Industrial Economics, L. Cabral ed. (2000), Blackwell Publishers.
Gans, J. and King, S., (2000), ‘Options for Electricity Transmission Regulation in
Australia,’ Australian Economic Review, 33, 145–160.
Glachant, J-M. and Pignon, V., (2002), ‘Nordic Electricity Congestion’s Arrangement as
a Model for Europe: Physical Constraints and Operators’ Opportunism’, mimeo.
Green, R., (1999), ‘The Electricity Contract Market in England and Wales,’ Journal of
Industrial Economics, 47(1), 107–124.
Green, R., (1997), ‘Transmission Pricing in England and Wales,’ Utilities Policy, 6(3),
185–93.
Hansmann, H., (1996), The Ownership of Enterprise, Belknap Harvard.
Hogan, W., (1992), ‘Contract Networks for Electric Power Transmission,’ Journal of
Regulatory Economics, 4, 211–242.
Hogan, W., (2002), ‘Financial Transmission Rights Formulations,’ mimeo, Harvard
University.
Holmström, B., (1982), ‘Moral Hazard in Teams,’ Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324–340.
Holmström, B. and Tirole, J., (2000), ‘Liquidity and Risk Management,’ Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 32(3), 295–319.
Joskow, P., (2002), ‘Electricity Sector Restructuring and Competition: A Transaction
Cost Perspective,’ in Eric Brousseau and Jean-Michel Glachant (eds.) The Economics of
Contracts: Theories and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Joskow, P. and Schmalensee, R., (1983), Markets for Power, MIT Press.
Joskow, P. and Tirole, J., (2000), ‘Transmission Rights and Market Power on Electric
Power Networks,’ Rand Journal of Economics, 31(3), 450–487.
Joskow, P. and Tirole, J., (2003), ‘Merchant Transmission Investment,’ mimeo, MIT and
IDEI.
Joskow, P. and Tirole, J., (2004), ‘Reliability and Competitive Electricity Markets,’
mimeo, MIT and IDEI.
Laffont, J-J. and Tirole, J., (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation,
MIT Press.
Léautier, T., (2000), ‘Regulation of An Electric Power Transmission Company,’ The
Energy Journal, 24(1), 61–92.
Nasser, T. O., (1997), ‘Imperfect Markets for Power: Competition and Residual
Regulation in the Electricity Industry,’ PhD Dissertation, MIT Department of
Economics.
Oren, S., (1997), ‘Economic Inefficiency and Passive Transmission Rights in Congested
Electric Systems with Competitive Generation,’ The Energy Journal, 18, 63–83.
Oren, S.; Spiller, P.; Varaiya, P. and Wu, F., (1995), ‘Nodal Prices and Transmission
Rights: A Critical Appraisal,’ The Electricity Journal, 8(3), 24–35.
Patton, D., (2002), ‘Summer 2002 Review of New York Electricity Markets’, October 15,
2002, pp.25, 42–64, New York Independent System Operator.
Perez-Arriaga, I. J., et al. (1995), ‘Marginal Pricing of Transmission Service: An Analysis
of Cost Recovery,’ IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, 10(1), 546–553.
Stoft, S., (1999), ‘Financial Transmission Rights Meet Cournot: How TCCs Curb Market
Power,’ The Energy Journal, 20, 1–23.
Tirole, J., (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press.
Vogelsang, I., (2001), ‘Price Regulation for Independent Transmission Companies,’
Journal of Regulatory Economics, 20(2), 141–165.
Wilson, R., (2002), ‘Architecture of Power Markets,’ Econometrica, 70(4), 1,299–1,340.
Wu, F. P.; Varaiya, P.; Spiller, P. and Oren, S., (1996), ‘Folk Theorems on Transmission
Access: Proofs and Counterexamples,’ Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10(1), 5–24.