Quasi-States Nation-Building and Terrorist Safe Ha
Quasi-States Nation-Building and Terrorist Safe Ha
Quasi-States Nation-Building and Terrorist Safe Ha
net/publication/237820021
CITATIONS READS
29 911
1 author:
Ken Menkhaus
Davidson College
40 PUBLICATIONS 1,641 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Ken Menkhaus on 20 August 2014.
by
Ken Menkhaus
INTRODUCTION
When conventional wisdom and empirical reality part ways, as they peri-
odically do in matters of state, the result is policy which can produce paradoxi-
cal outcomes at an astronomical cost. That is precisely what is happening in the
international community’s approach to nation-building. Current nation-building
practices may inadvertently yield exactly the kind of states – weak, ineffectual
“quasi-states” – within which terrorist networks thrive, producing the very sanc-
tuaries for terrorism which the US and its allies are seeking to eliminate.
Unintended consequences are hardly a surprise in the messy and chaotic
context of collapsed states like Somalia and Afghanistan. But in this instance the
problem is also the result of a partial misdiagnosis of the relationship between
terrorism and failed states – a product of conventional wisdom led astray by a
seemingly self-evident set of assumptions about the kinds of operating environ-
ment terrorist networks need. That misdiagnosis, combined with chronically sub-
optimal execution of nation-building – one driven by the compromises inherent
in multilateralism, financial foot-dragging, sub-contracting to the UN, risk aver-
sion, and a preference for quick fixes – is yielding half-way measures rather than
a comprehensive, strategic, and effective long-term response. When it comes to
the pursuit of nation-building in the name of combating terrorism, half-way
measures are not merely inadequate – they are actively counterproductive.
7
Fall 2003
8
The Journal of Conflict Studies
9
Fall 2003
for the simple reason that, with few exceptions, the countries in question
appeared to pose little if any threat to vital American interests. Even crisis-rid-
den Haiti, which attracted a US-led, multi-billion dollar international interven-
tion in 1994 and which has the potential to create considerable headaches for the
nearby United States, was quietly abandoned by donors in 2000 out of frustra-
tion with political corruption and paralysis. What was significant about inter-
ventions in the 1990s was not just the rate at which they occurred, but also the
rate at which the US and the West walked away.
This dynamic was a function of the fact that the interventions themselves
were driven mainly by political, not strategic, interests – by the need for admin-
istrations to “do something” about a stomach-turning humanitarian or political
crisis saturating the evening news. When the stakes are political, not strategic,
then the policy choices will also be driven by political rather than strategic con-
cerns. That tends to place decision-making authority in the hands of a US presi-
dent’s pollsters rather than the National Security Council, and focuses priorities
more on the appearance of solving a problem (until the media departs for the next
crisis) than on actual success.
10
The Journal of Conflict Studies
11
Fall 2003
12
The Journal of Conflict Studies
13
Fall 2003
14
The Journal of Conflict Studies
Kenya has now endured twice in recent years – first with the 1998 bombing of
the US Embassy, and more recently with the attack on Israeli tourists at
Mombasa.11 By contrast, the zones of state collapse – southern Somalia, south-
ern Sudan, eastern Congo, Angola – present a paucity of enticing Western targets,
unless that country’s crisis happens to attract a UN peace operation.
Third, quasi-states generally feature very corrupt security and law
enforcement agencies, but not such high levels of criminality that a terrorist cell
is especially vulnerable to lawless behavior. Bribes to police, border guards, and
airport officials allow terrorists to circumvent the law even while they enjoy a
certain level of protection from it. Whether such corruption is a function of the
economic desperation of underpaid policemen or the greed of rich civil servants,
the effect is the same – a virtual carte blanche to operate under the radar screen
of internal and external security monitors. The extraordinary denouement to the
December 2002 terrorist attack in Mombasa, Kenya – in which the suspects
“escaped” from police who are widely suspected of accepting a bribe in
exchange – is the most damning evidence of how corruption produces a permis-
sive environment for terrorists.
All this means that a terrorist network in a region such as East Africa would
have a strong and logical preference to work out of Nairobi, Dar Es Salaam, or
even Kampala rather than Somalia. And that is precisely what has occurred – the
weak quasi-state is repeatedly preferred over the zone of complete state collapse
as a base of operation, a lair for evading detection, and a setting for terrorist
attacks.12
That is not to argue that the world can rest easy about terrorist exploitation
of anarchic zones of collapsed states such as Somalia. Areas of state collapse
clearly appear to have a niche role to play in the terrorist playbook. Available evi-
dence suggests they are useful primarily as transit stations, through which the
movement of men, money, and materiel can be arranged into neighboring states
with little fear of detection.13 The Horn of Africa is currently awash in unpo-
liced, cross-border smuggling of small arms, people, and goods; indeed, the top
commercial activity in Somalia has for a number been transit trade of basic con-
sumer goods from Mogadishu beach ports overland into Kenya’s lucrative mar-
ket. The use of collapsed states for terrorist transit operations has the advantage
of exploiting the already flourishing smuggling networks (so little suspicion is
aroused, and hiring of trucks and agents is routinized) while keeping such
involvement in the collapsed state short-term in duration, thereby minimizing
risks. Local agents need not be members or sympathizers of a terrorist move-
ment; for a fee, virtually any merchant or local warlord will assist in the transit
of a shipment, a money transfer, or a convoy of people with no questions asked.
This underscores the fact that careful monitoring and surveillance of zones of
state collapse is an entirely justifiable component of the war on terrorism. But it
suggests that monitoring in those areas should focus more on beach ports and
15
Fall 2003
cross-border smuggling than on a search for terrorist cells and training camps. It
is not what is in these zones of anarchy, but what passes through them, which is
of greatest immediate danger.
There is also the risk that individual terrorists, either indigenous or foreign,
will, like Suleiman Abdulla, seek to safe haven in collapsed states. Indeed, the
more successful counter-terrorism measures are elsewhere, the more likely indi-
vidual terrorists are to turn up in places like Somalia, where they will assume a
role in business or an Islamic charity in hopes of remaining undetected. Recourse
to such environments is hardly a first choice, however; it is reasonable to pre-
sume that a growing presence of foreign terrorists in places like Mogadishu sug-
gests a measure of weakness and lack of alternatives. Still, this scenario demands
much closer scrutiny of and transparency on the part of business partnerships and
Islamic aid agencies.14
Swamps of Concern
If an important component of the Western counter-terrorism strategy is to
“drain the swamp,” and if collapsed states are among the “swamps of concern,”
then the obvious prescription is to promote vigorous state-building and post-con-
flict reconstruction in collapsed states. Leaving states like post-Taliban
Afghanistan in a state of chaos would clearly be self-defeating. Hence, the US
and its allies have pledged billions of dollars in post-conflict reconstruction to
Afghanistan, a commitment which attracts the usual armada of international
agencies crowding the state-building playing field wherever states have col-
lapsed and funding is promised. By the same logic, a current Kenyan-sponsored
peace initiative to resolve the Somali crisis and create a government of national
unity there has attracted much more active support from the US, the European
Union, and some international advocacy groups. The promise of substantial
assistance for post-conflict reconstruction is being used to entice Somali leaders
to agree to the revival of a central government which would presumably devel-
op a police and security capacity to control terrorist elements within its borders.
In practice, there are a number of distinct problems with the enterprise of
rebuilding functional governments in collapsed states with the expectation that
they will grow into reliable partners in a war on terrorism. First, many local fig-
ures in places like Afghanistan and Somalia simply do not share our agenda.
Setting aside the many local authorities with little stomach for a war on terror-
ism or with lingering sympathies to terrorist causes, the bigger concern are the
many more who are not even interested in the revival of effective government
and rule of law. Many contemporary crises of collapsed government are products
of warlordism and war economies, in which powerful local (and sometimes
external) actors profit economically or politically from a continued state of law-
lessness, armed conflict, and state collapse. These conflict constituencies – often
including the very individuals whom external mediators repeatedly convene to
16
The Journal of Conflict Studies
the negotiating table in hopes of brokering a peace – risk losing out on lucrative
illicit business ventures were rule of law to be reintroduced. “Blood diamonds”
in several of Africa’s complex emergencies are the most famous but hardly the
sole commodity associated with crises wherein war is an instrument of enterprise
and “durable disorder” a desired outcome for parochial political or economic rea-
sons.15
This sobering observation is even more worrisome when one takes account
of the fact that these same conflict constituencies exist and operate in some rather
strategic quasi-states. In Kenya, for instance, efforts to improve the state’s capa-
city to crack down on endemic lawlessness are stymied in part because impor-
tant sections of the Kenyan police are themselves complicit in criminal behavior
ranging from corruption to extortion to murder. Likewise, efforts to mediate
peace in some of Kenya’s extraordinarily violent pastoral clashes – conflicts
which have rendered much of the northern portion of the country beyond the rule
of law and hence a zone of concern in the war on terrorism – fail not because
these clashes are captive to timeless tribal hatreds but because Kenyan elites at
the highest levels have profited from and orchestrate these bloody, commercial-
ized cattle raids.16
In these situations, nation-building projects which aim to produce rule of
law and a robust police and security capacity to enforce the law will either
encounter active resistance and sabotage by powerful political actors, or will be
quietly subverted by local authorities who will gladly go through the motions
required by externally-funded capacity-building programs, but with no intention
of allowing them to become effective. This game of charades is distressingly
familiar to aid workers and diplomats who have worked in post-conflict settings
from Haiti to Sierra Leone.
17
Fall 2003
18
The Journal of Conflict Studies
19
Fall 2003
transition from collapsed state to fully functional government. The long stretch
of time which passes between state collapse and effectively rebuilt government
constitutes a dangerous transitional stage, a period when the government on the
receiving end of nation-building efforts is weak, vulnerable, but sovereign – in
other words, a quasi-state. Hence the security paradox of nation-building: the
very success of post-conflict reconstruction in a collapsed state will produce a
temporary political situation in which terrorist networks appear to thrive.
Paradoxes associated with transitional phases in development are not new.
Samuel Huntington argued over three decades ago that while both traditional and
modern polities are stable, political instability is endemic in countries in transi-
tion from traditional to modern society.17 Likewise, economists have long been
aware of the paradoxes of transition in economic development, noting, for
instance, the tendency for gaps in income to actually widen as an economy devel-
ops before closing again around a larger middle class in a developed economy.
If this same transitional dynamic is true in nation-building and public security,
then we can expect that current sites of nation-building initiatives will likely
become more, not less, dangerous as terrorist safe havens in the short-term. This
outcome is possible even if post-conflict reconstruction initiatives are strategi-
cally coherent, vigorous, seamlessly coordinated, and flawlessly executed. But it
is almost a certainty if current nation-building systems and practices are left in
place, delivering the half-way measures which can do no better than produce
quasi-states.
Policy Implications
At the heart of the security dilemma of nation-building lies two proposi-
tions, both of which are disquietingly true. The first proposition, voiced by advo-
cates of nation-building, correctly identifies collapsed states as a major security
threat in the war on terrorism. The second proposition, offered by critics of
nation-building, correctly argues that nation-building as currently conceived is a
fool’s errand.
There are several potential policy responses to this dilemma. One is to qui-
etly abandon the nation-building enterprise and accept that the war on terrorism
will be reactive, not preventive, executed as a protracted military and counter-ter-
rorist operation against threats which thrive in swamps we have opted not to try
to drain. There are obvious costs and shortcomings with this approach, but it has
attractive virtues too. It has the simplicity of a duck hunt, and because it calls for
responses for which the US is well-equipped, it is entirely plausible that this
approach will win favor if and when frustration levels with nation-building hit
critical mass. A recent comment by US Senator Joseph Biden hints at this pos-
sibility. “Some of these guys [defense officials] don’t go for nation-building,” he
observed. “They think it’s cheaper to just go back in and empty the swamp again
if you have to.”18
20
The Journal of Conflict Studies
21
Fall 2003
Endnotes
1. Marina Ottaway, “Nation-Building,” Foreign Policy 18, no. 5 (September-October 2002), p. 18.
2. The White House, “National Security Strategy of the United States of America” (17 September
2002), p. 1 (http://www.whitehouse.gov/nsc/nss1.html).
3. John J. Hamre and Gordon R. Sullivan, “Toward Postconflict Reconstruction,” The Washington
Quarterly 25, no. 4 (Autumn 2002), p. 85.
4. For a recent conservative critique, see Gary T. Dempsey, “Old Folly in New Disguise: Nation
Building to Combat Terrorism,” Cato Policy Analysis no. 429 (21 March 2002)
(http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-429es.html).
5. See the cover of the September-October 2002 issue of Foreign Policy.
6. US Government, “National Strategy for Combating Terrorism” (February 2003) (http://usin-
fo.state.gov/topical/pol/terror/strategy).
7. This conclusion tracks closely with the assessment reached by Matt Bryden in his article in this
issue of the journal.
8. Quoted in a background report, “Somalia/Terror,” Voice of America (29 May 2003).
9. See “Terror Suspect Flown to US,” The Nation (Nairobi), 27 March 2003, posted on
http://allAfrica.com. Like many aspects of this case, the details of the operation which appre-
hended Suleiman has been the subject of contradictory reports. Some reports portray the
episode as a Somali police operation, in which Suleiman was handed over to the Kenyans and
US. Others report it as a kidnapping by Somalis. Still others suggest a more direct role by
Kenyan and/or American forces. Suleiman’s whereabouts were subsequently the subject of
even more mystery, with Kenyan officials claiming that he was handed over to the US while
US officials suggest that Suleiman remains in the hands of East African authorities. For an
account of conflicting statements on the incident, see Kevin Kelley, “Gov’t, US Disagree Over
Terror Suspect,” The East African (Nairobi), 2 June 2003.
22
The Journal of Conflict Studies
10. Thomas Friedman, Longitudes and Attitudes: Exploring the World After September 11 (New
York: Farrar Straus and Giroux, 2002), p. 57.
11. Kenya was also the site of a terrorist attack in 1980, when the Norfolk Hotel was bombed.
12. This is also the conclusion reached by a US Institute of Peace workshop, “Assessing Terrorism
in the Horn of Africa: Threats and Responses,” Washington DC (28 May 2003).
13. See Ken Menkhaus, “Somalia: Next Up in the War on Terrorism?” CSIS Africa Notes no. 6
(January 2002), pp. 1-9; and International Crisis Group, “Somalia: Combating Terrorism in a
Failed State,” (Brussels: ICG, May 2002).
14. Ken Menkhaus, “Terrorism in Somalia: Threat Assessment and Policy Options,” presented at
the US Institute of Peace, “Assessing Terrorism on the Horn of Africa: Threats and Responses”
workshop, Washington DC (28 May 2003).
15. Mats Berdal and David Malone, eds., Greed and Grievance: Economic Agendas in Civil Wars
(Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2000).
16. Sam E. Kona, “Conflict and Insecurity Among the East African Pastoralists: The Kenyan
Experience,” presented at the Oxfam GB Regional Pastoral Programme Workshop, Arusha
Tanzania (28 February 2000); and Centre for Conflict Research, “A Conflict Map of Kenya: An
Overview of the Conflict Situation in Kenya, Issues Extent, and Effect,” The Great Lakes
Parliamentary Forum on Peace (Amani Forum) (August 2002).
17. Samuel Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press, 1968).
18. Quoted in Bill Keller, “The I-can’t-believe-I’m-a-hawk Club,” The New York Times (8 February
2003).
19. Martin Indyk recently broached the subject in reference to Palestine; see “A Trusteeship for
Palestine?” Foreign Affairs 82, no. 3 (May-June 2003), pp. 51-66.
23