ch2 Slides

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 25

A Classical Monetary Model

Adapted from Jordi Galı́’s slides


Assumptions
• Perfect competition in goods and labor markets (Neither price nor wage setting)
• Flexible prices and wages (MP has no real effects)
• Money held only for transactions
• No capital accumulation (No investment decision by firms)
• No fiscal sector
• Closed economy

Outline
• The problem of households and firms
• Equilibrium: money neutrality and the determination of nominal variables
• A model with money in the utility function
• Optimal policy
Households
Representative household maximizes inter-temporal utility function
X ∞
max E0 β tU (Ct, Nt) (1)
t=0
subject to inter-temporal budget constraint
PtCt + QtBt ≤ Bt−1 + WtNt + Dt (2)
for t = 0, 1, 2, ...and the solvency constraint
lim Et {Λt,T (BT /PT )} ≥ 0 (3)
T →∞

where Λt,T ≡ β T −tUc,T /Uc,t is the stochastic discount factor.


Optimality conditions(Solve by using Lagrange)
Un,t Wt
− = (4)
Uc,t Pt
(Static consumption-leisure choice)
 
Uc,t+1 Pt
Qt = β E t (5)
Uc,t Pt+1

(Derive it from pure intuition about trade-off between current consumption/future con-
sumption: utility gains of current consumption vs. utility gains of future consump-
tion)
Specification of utility:

Ct1−σ −1 Nt1+ϕ

1−σ − 1+ϕ for σ 6= 1
U (Ct, Nt) = Nt1+ϕ
 log Ct − 1+ϕ for σ = 1

implied optimality conditions:


Wt
= Ctσ Ntϕ (6)
Pt
( −σ )
Ct+1 Pt
Qt = βEt (7)
Ct Pt+1
Log-linear versions

wt − pt = σct + ϕnt (8)

1
ct = Et{ct+1} − (it − Et{πt+1} − ρ) (9)
σ
where πt ≡ pt − pt−1, it ≡ − log Qt and ρ ≡ − log β
Steady state (zero growth):
i=π+ρ
implied real rate
r ≡i−π =ρ

Ad-hoc money demand


mt − pt = ct − ηit
Firms
Representative firm with technology
Yt = AtNt1−α (10)
where at ≡ log At follows an exogenous process
at = ρaat−1 + εat

Profit maximization:
max PtYt − WtNt
subject to (10), taking the price and wage as given (perfect competition)

Optimality condition:
Wt
= (1 − α)AtNt−α
Pt

In log-linear terms
wt − pt = at − αnt + log(1 − α)
Equilibrium
Goods market clearing
yt = ct

Labor market clearing


σct + ϕnt = at − αnt + log(1 − α)

Asset market clearing:


Bt = 0
rt ≡ it − Et{πt+1}
= ρ + σEt{∆ct+1}

Aggregate output:
yt = at + (1 − α)nt
Implied equilibrium values for real variables:
nt = ψnaat + ψn
yt = ψyaat + ψy
rt = ρ − σψya(1 − ρa)at
ω t ≡ wt − p t
= at − αnt + log(1 − α)
= ψωaat + ψω

1−σ log(1−α) 1+ϕ


where ψna ≡ σ(1−α)+ϕ+α ; ψn ≡σ(1−α)+ϕ+α ; ψ ya ≡ σ(1−α)+ϕ+α ;
ψy ≡ (1 − α)ψn ; σ+ϕ
ψωa ≡ σ(1−α)+ϕ+α ; ψω ≡ (σ(1−α)+ϕ) log(1−α)
σ(1−α)+ϕ+α

=⇒ neutrality: real variables determined independently of monetary policy


=⇒ optimal policy: undetermined.
=⇒ specification of monetary policy needed to determine nominal variables
Monetary Policy and Price Level Determination
Example I: An Exogenous Path for the Nominal Interest Rate
it = i + vt
where
vt = ρv vt−1 + εvt
Implied steady state inflation: π = i − ρ
Particular case: it = i for all t.
Using definition of real rate:
Et{πt+1} = it − rt
= π + vt − rbt
Equilibrium inflation:
bt = vt−1 − rbt−1 + ξt
π
for any {ξt} sequence with Et{ξt+1} = 0 for all t.
⇒ nominal indeterminacy
Example II: A Simple Interest Rate Rule
it = ρ + π + φπ (πt − π) + vt
where φπ ≥ 0. Combined with definition of real rate:
bt = Et{π
φπ π bt+1} + rbt − vt
If φπ > 1,

X
π
bt = φ−(k+1)
π Et{rbt+k − vt+k }
k=0
σ(1 − ρa)ψya 1
= − at − vt
φπ − ρ a φ π − ρv
If φπ < 1,
π bt−1 − rbt−1 + vt−1 + ξt
bt = φπ π
for any {ξt} sequence with Et{ξt+1} = 0 for all t
=⇒ nominal indeterminacy
=⇒ illustration of the ”Taylor principle” requirement
Responses to a monetary policy shock ( φπ > 1 case):
∂πt 1
v = − <0
∂εt φπ − ρ v
∂it ρv
=− <0
∂εvt φπ − ρ v
∂mt ηρv − 1
= ≶0
∂εvt φπ − ρ v
∂yt
v =0
∂εt
Discussion: liquidity effect and price response.
Example III: An Exogenous Path for the Money Supply {mt}
Combining money demand and the definition of the real rate:
   
η 1
pt = Et{pt+1} + mt + ut
1+η 1+η
where ut ≡ (1 + η)−1(ηrt − yt). Solving forward:
∞  k
1 X η
pt = Et {mt+k } + ut
1 + η k=0 1 + η
P∞  η k
where ut ≡ k=0 1+η Et{ut+k }

⇒ price level determinacy


In terms of money growth rates:
∞  k
X η
pt = mt + Et {∆mt+k } + ut
k=1
1+η
Nominal interest rate:
it = η −1 (yt − (mt − pt))
∞  k
X η
= η −1 Et {∆mt+k } + ut
k=1
1+η
where ut ≡ η −1(ut + yt) is independent of monetary policy.
Example
∆mt = ρm∆mt−1 + εm
t

Assume no real shocks (rt = yt = 0).


Price response:
ηρm
pt = mt + ∆mt
1 + η(1 − ρm)

⇒ large price response

Nominal interest rate response:


ρm
it = ∆mt
1 + η(1 − ρm)

⇒ no liquidity effect
A Model with Money in the Utility Function
Preferences
∞  
X Mt
E0 β tU Ct, , Nt
t=0
Pt
Budget constraint
PtCt + QtBt + Mt ≤ Bt−1 + Mt−1 + WtNt + Dt
with solvency constraint:
lim Et {Λt,T (AT /PT )} ≥ 0
T →∞
where At ≡ Bt + Mt.
Equivalently:
PtCt + QtAt + (1 − Qt)Mt ≤ At−1 + WtNt + Dt

Interpretation: 1 − Qt = 1 − exp{−it} ' it


⇒ opportunity cost of holding money
Optimality Conditions
Un,t Wt
− =
Uc,t Pt
 
Uc,t+1 Pt
Qt = βEt
Uc,t Pt+1
Um,t
= 1 − exp{−it}
Uc,t

Two cases:
• utility separable in real balances ⇒ neutrality
• utility non-separable in real balances ⇒ non-neutrality
Utility specification:
Xt1−σ − 1 Nt1+ϕ
U (Xt, Nt) = −
1−σ 1+ϕ
where
" 1
 1−ν # 1−v
Mt
Xt ≡ (1 − ϑ)Ct1−ν + ϑ f or ν 6= 1
Pt
 ϑ
Mt
≡ Ct1−ϑ f or ν = 1
Pt

Note that
Uc,t = (1 − ϑ)Xtν−σ Ct−ν
Um,t = ϑXtν−σ (Mt/Pt)−ν
Un,t = −Ntϕ
Implied optimality conditions:
Wt
= NtϕXtσ−ν Ctν (1 − ϑ)−1
Pt
( −ν  ν−σ  )
Ct+1 Xt+1 Pt
Qt = βEt
Ct Xt Pt+1
  ν1
Mt 1 ϑ
= Ct (1 − exp{−it})− ν
Pt 1−ϑ

Log-linearized money demand equation:


mt − pt = ct − ηit
where η ≡ 1/[ν(exp{i} − 1)] .
Log-linearized labor supply equation:
wt − pt = σct + ϕnt + (ν − σ)(ct − xt)
= σct + ϕnt + χ(ν − σ) (ct − (mt − pt))
= σct + ϕnt + ηχ(ν − σ)it
1 1− ν1
  ν1
ϑ (1−β)
ν km (1−β) M/P ϑ
where χ ≡ 1 1 1
1− ν
= 1+km (1−β) ∈ [0, 1) with km ≡ C = (1−β)(1−ϑ) .
(1−ϑ) +ϑ (1−β)
ν ν

Equivalently,
wt − pt = σct + ϕnt + $it
km β(1− σν )
where $ ≡ 1+km (1−β)

Discussion
Equilibrium
Labor market clearing:
σct + ϕnt + $it = at − αnt + log(1 − α)
which combined with aggregate production function:
yt = ψyaat + ψyiit
$(1−α) 1+ϕ
where ψyi ≡ − σ(1−α)+ϕ+α and ψya ≡ σ(1−α)+ϕ+α
Assessment of size of non-neutralities
Calibration: β = 0.99 ; σ = 1 ; ϕ = 5 ; α = 1/4 ; ν = 1/ηi ”large”
kmβ km
⇒$' > 0 ; ψyi ' − <0
1 + km(1 − β) 8
Monetary base inverse velocity: km ' 0.3 ⇒ ψyi ' −0.04
M2 inverse velocity: km ' 3 ⇒ ψyi ' −0.4
⇒ small output effects of monetary policy
Response to monetary policy shocks (at = 0)

yt = Θ(mt − pt)
it = −(1/η)(1 − Θ)(mt − pt)
$(1−α)
where Θ ≡ η[σ(1−α)+ϕ+α]+$(1−α) ∈ [0, 1) (assuming $ ≥ 0)
1
yt = Et{yt+1} − (it − Et{πt+1} − $Et{∆it+1} − ρ)
σ
∞  k
η X η + $Λ
pt = mt + Et{∆mt+k }
η + $Λ k=1 1 − Θ + η + $Λ
η(α+ϕ)
where Λ ≡ η[σ(1−α)+ϕ+α]+$(1−α) ∈ [0, 1).
Prediction (independent of rule):
persistent money growth ⇒ cov(∆m, i) > 0 and cov(∆m, y) < 0
Optimal Monetary Policy with Money in the Utility Function

Social Planner’s problem


 
Mt
max U Ct, , Nt
Pt
subject to
Ct = AtNt1−α
Optimality conditions:
Un,t
− = (1 − α)AtNt−α
Uc,t
Um,t = 0

Optimal policy (Friedman rule): it = 0 for all t .


Intuition
Implied average inflation: π = −ρ < 0
Implementation
it = φ(rt−1 + πt)
for some φ > 1. Combined with the definition of the real rate:
Et{it+1} = φit
whose only stationary solution is it = 0 for all t.
Implied equilibrium inflation:
πt = −rt−1

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy