ch2 Slides
ch2 Slides
ch2 Slides
Outline
• The problem of households and firms
• Equilibrium: money neutrality and the determination of nominal variables
• A model with money in the utility function
• Optimal policy
Households
Representative household maximizes inter-temporal utility function
X ∞
max E0 β tU (Ct, Nt) (1)
t=0
subject to inter-temporal budget constraint
PtCt + QtBt ≤ Bt−1 + WtNt + Dt (2)
for t = 0, 1, 2, ...and the solvency constraint
lim Et {Λt,T (BT /PT )} ≥ 0 (3)
T →∞
(Derive it from pure intuition about trade-off between current consumption/future con-
sumption: utility gains of current consumption vs. utility gains of future consump-
tion)
Specification of utility:
Ct1−σ −1 Nt1+ϕ
1−σ − 1+ϕ for σ 6= 1
U (Ct, Nt) = Nt1+ϕ
log Ct − 1+ϕ for σ = 1
1
ct = Et{ct+1} − (it − Et{πt+1} − ρ) (9)
σ
where πt ≡ pt − pt−1, it ≡ − log Qt and ρ ≡ − log β
Steady state (zero growth):
i=π+ρ
implied real rate
r ≡i−π =ρ
Profit maximization:
max PtYt − WtNt
subject to (10), taking the price and wage as given (perfect competition)
Optimality condition:
Wt
= (1 − α)AtNt−α
Pt
In log-linear terms
wt − pt = at − αnt + log(1 − α)
Equilibrium
Goods market clearing
yt = ct
Aggregate output:
yt = at + (1 − α)nt
Implied equilibrium values for real variables:
nt = ψnaat + ψn
yt = ψyaat + ψy
rt = ρ − σψya(1 − ρa)at
ω t ≡ wt − p t
= at − αnt + log(1 − α)
= ψωaat + ψω
⇒ no liquidity effect
A Model with Money in the Utility Function
Preferences
∞
X Mt
E0 β tU Ct, , Nt
t=0
Pt
Budget constraint
PtCt + QtBt + Mt ≤ Bt−1 + Mt−1 + WtNt + Dt
with solvency constraint:
lim Et {Λt,T (AT /PT )} ≥ 0
T →∞
where At ≡ Bt + Mt.
Equivalently:
PtCt + QtAt + (1 − Qt)Mt ≤ At−1 + WtNt + Dt
Two cases:
• utility separable in real balances ⇒ neutrality
• utility non-separable in real balances ⇒ non-neutrality
Utility specification:
Xt1−σ − 1 Nt1+ϕ
U (Xt, Nt) = −
1−σ 1+ϕ
where
" 1
1−ν # 1−v
Mt
Xt ≡ (1 − ϑ)Ct1−ν + ϑ f or ν 6= 1
Pt
ϑ
Mt
≡ Ct1−ϑ f or ν = 1
Pt
Note that
Uc,t = (1 − ϑ)Xtν−σ Ct−ν
Um,t = ϑXtν−σ (Mt/Pt)−ν
Un,t = −Ntϕ
Implied optimality conditions:
Wt
= NtϕXtσ−ν Ctν (1 − ϑ)−1
Pt
( −ν ν−σ )
Ct+1 Xt+1 Pt
Qt = βEt
Ct Xt Pt+1
ν1
Mt 1 ϑ
= Ct (1 − exp{−it})− ν
Pt 1−ϑ
Equivalently,
wt − pt = σct + ϕnt + $it
km β(1− σν )
where $ ≡ 1+km (1−β)
Discussion
Equilibrium
Labor market clearing:
σct + ϕnt + $it = at − αnt + log(1 − α)
which combined with aggregate production function:
yt = ψyaat + ψyiit
$(1−α) 1+ϕ
where ψyi ≡ − σ(1−α)+ϕ+α and ψya ≡ σ(1−α)+ϕ+α
Assessment of size of non-neutralities
Calibration: β = 0.99 ; σ = 1 ; ϕ = 5 ; α = 1/4 ; ν = 1/ηi ”large”
kmβ km
⇒$' > 0 ; ψyi ' − <0
1 + km(1 − β) 8
Monetary base inverse velocity: km ' 0.3 ⇒ ψyi ' −0.04
M2 inverse velocity: km ' 3 ⇒ ψyi ' −0.4
⇒ small output effects of monetary policy
Response to monetary policy shocks (at = 0)
yt = Θ(mt − pt)
it = −(1/η)(1 − Θ)(mt − pt)
$(1−α)
where Θ ≡ η[σ(1−α)+ϕ+α]+$(1−α) ∈ [0, 1) (assuming $ ≥ 0)
1
yt = Et{yt+1} − (it − Et{πt+1} − $Et{∆it+1} − ρ)
σ
∞ k
η X η + $Λ
pt = mt + Et{∆mt+k }
η + $Λ k=1 1 − Θ + η + $Λ
η(α+ϕ)
where Λ ≡ η[σ(1−α)+ϕ+α]+$(1−α) ∈ [0, 1).
Prediction (independent of rule):
persistent money growth ⇒ cov(∆m, i) > 0 and cov(∆m, y) < 0
Optimal Monetary Policy with Money in the Utility Function