Unit 14
Unit 14
Unit 14
Structure
14.0 Objectives
14.1 Introduction
14.2 Concept of Monopoly
14.3 Equilibrium in a Monopoly Market
14.3.1 Short Period
14.3.2 Long Period
14.4 Price Discrimination Under Monopoly
14.5 Monopoly and Economic Efficiency: Comparison with Perfect
Competition
14.6 Regulation of Monopoly
14.7. Let Us Sum Up
14.8 Key Words
14.9 Answers to Check Your Progress
14.10 Terminal questions
14.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you should be able to:
• distinguish between perfect competition and monopoly
• describe short period equilibrium and long period equilibrium
• explain price discrimination under monopoly.
• appreciate the measures that government can take to regulate monopoly.
14.1 INTRODUCTION
In Unit 13, you have learnt why a perfectly competitive market is important
for a free market economy. It really enables production of commodities at
lowest possible average cost in the long period and at prices which are equal
to marginal cost of production. There is no waste of resources since
production remains at the optimum level.
341
Theory of Price In this unit, you will learn the concept of monopoly, equilibrium of monopoly
in short and long period and price discrimination. You will also learn
monopoly and economic efficiency in comparison with perfect competition
and the ways through which the government regulates monopoly.
In fact, classical economists believed that things would necessarily work out
in this manner, increasing the economic welfare of both the individual and
the society, provided the market was not interfered with. Here you may ask a
question how and why the mere fact of some individual producers and sellers
making some personal gain or profit will bring about this transformation. The
342
answer lies in the fact that when other people find that profits are being made Monopoly
in the production and sale of a particular commodity, they feel attracted by
the prospect of making such profit themselves. In fact, as long as profits are
made by the existing producers in the market, new producers joining the
market is a natural tendency. In consequence, the number of producers will
go on becoming larger and the competition amongst them keener with time.
You can see the advantage to the society by such a competition as each
producer will now try to outsell the other and in the process minimise his cost
of production. The gain to the society would be more division of labour,
larger scale of production, larger output, lower cost and lower prices. This is
the reason why economists have regarded perfect competition as an ideal
market situation.
The more we move away from the competitive market to the monopoly one,
the gains listed above become more unlikely. On the other hand, when fear of
competition does not exist, or has been reduced, it will lead to monopolistic
market. It is likely that the producers will not feel compulsion to go for
further division of labour or raise the scale of production or minimise the cost
or to lower their prices. Thus, the gains attributed to a free market economy
begin to disappear once we move from a competitive market to a
monopolistic one.
Economists sometimes suggest that the monopolist is an unusual creature and
may not be guided solely by profit motive. He may be given to a desire to
expand his output and his scale of production even if there are no
compulsions. You may also note that a higher profit may yield high income
while a larger scale of production provides a larger command over wealth
including capital and other assets. Thus, if a person is interested in
commanding a larger amount of economic resources, he may raise the scale
of his output by looking at this total revenue rather than on the rate of return
on his investment.
You may now ask the question; Can any producer maximise his total revenue
without keeping in mind his cost of production? In fact, a monopolist tries to
maximise his ‘net monopoly revenue’ but not really the total revenue. In this
effort, he does try to handle his cost with care. (You will study in detail about
this later in this Unit.) One of the ways in which the monopolist handles his
cost is through innovation and technological change.
There can be various reasons why a producer turns a monopolist. There are,
as has been pointed out, natural monopolies resulting from exploitation of
some minerals located in small geographical areas-say a mineral like gold-
and it may not be meaningful for a large number of producers to mine and
exploit a small area. At the other end of the spectrum, there would be the
supply of a service like clean drinking water for which extensive network of
pipes is to be laid down. This is a job in which duplication by many
producers will be extremely wasteful.
Apart from natural monopolies, there are those which result from grant of
patents or other legal protections. Sometimes, the government provides
exclusive rights to particular companies to trade in particular areas and this
leads to emergence of monopoly. Lastly, there can be monopolies resulting
from progress in technology, evolution of new techniques and methods of
production or new products. It is possible that a particular firm or enterprise
has evolved a method of producing a particular commodity which no one else
knows about and this enables it to become a monopoly.
There is another aspect related to the matter of the supply curve in monopoly
which derives from the fact that as the monopolist can influence the price of
his commodity, his main interest will be in the demand curve that he
encounters in the market. We have already noted that the monopolist does not
have unlimited powers in respect of his price. He can charge the price subject
to the limits of the demand curve which he faces, the more sloping is the
demand curve which he faces, the more sharply he can vary or change his
price. On the other hand, with a flatter demand curve, the variability in price
will be smaller. The monopolist cannot charge a price which is outside these
limits.
This suggests that elasticity of demand for the monopolist's product will be
an important factor enabling him to influence the price. This does not
however mean that (only when the elasticity of demand is zero or less than
one) the monopolist will be able to charge a higher price. In order to be able
to understand this statement look at Figure 14.1 where a demand curve has
been shown.
It is clear from the above figure that as long as the monopolist's equilibrium
is determined at any point above E1 the price that he would charge would be
higher but the elasticity of demand of the product will also be more than one.
In fact, if we were to move down in some point below E the equilibrium price
would be very low and also the elasticity of demand will be much less than
unity. Thus, it would not be correct to suggest that it is only when the
demand is inelastic that the monopolist is able to charge a higher price.
346
Monopoly
Look at Figure 14.1 where at point E2 ,marginal revenue will be negative and
equilibrium will not be possible. In fact, even at point E3 where the marginal
revenue is zero, equilibrium will not be possible because it would imply that
the marginal cost of the monopolist is zero (equilibrium necessarily means
equality between marginal revenue and marginal cost) which is a ridiculous
situation.
We will thus see that the monopolistic equilibrium leading to the charging of
a higher price is best determined when the elasticity of demand for the
product is either equal to or greater than one but not so low as to be zero or
near zero.
Having seen thehe importance of the demand curve and the elasticity of demand
for the product, we may now refer to the kind of considerations that
characterise the determination of monopoly price in the short period. The
monopolist would not accept a price which does not cover his average
variable cost of production. In case the price is less than average variable
cost, his total revenue will be less than his total variable cost. In such a
situation, he will prefer not to produce the commodity.
This, of course, is possiblee when his price is equal to average variable cost
and he, therefore, continues to produce the commodity. The prices can be
either equal to or lower than or higher than his average cost (average of both
the fixed and variable costs). If the price is equal to average cost, total
revenue is equal to total cost (both variable and fixed) and monopolist will
neither be suffering a loss nor earning a surplus. On the other hand, if his
price is more than average cost, his total revenue will be more than total cost
and he will be making abnormal gains. The monopolist will be suffering a
loss only when the price is less than average cost of production and,
therefore, the total revenue is less than total cost.
347
Theory of Price The thing that has to be kept in mind is that the average and marginal cost
curves that will help in determining monopolist's equilibrium price will both
relate to a short period. Look at
Figure 14.2 where equilibrium characterised by abnormal gains has been
shown.
348
Monopoly
Figure 14.4 : Short Period Equilibrium under Monopoly neither by Abnormal Gains or
any Losses
Remember that in all cases of equilibrium, the marginal cost curve has to cut
the marginal revenue curve from below otherwise as was pointed out, in Unit
12, the equilibrium achieved will not be stable. Further, the short period
equilibrium is at all one which has to remain valid only for a short period and
in course of time, shouldd change. It is because of the possibility of change
(one short period gives way to another) that the monopolist in spite of all his
power, will tolerate losses or a no-profit
profit-no-loss situation.
349
Theory of Price
Quantity
Price
Figure 14.6 : Long Period Equilibrium Under Monopoly with various Output
350
The net monopoly revenues for these outputs OQ1OQ2 and OQ are AC1, P1,F, Monopoly
BCPE and GC2 P2D respectively. Since the rectangle BCPE is the largest,
the. monopolist will produce OQ output and charge PQ price.
Post Marshall economists say that the long period equilibrium of the
monopolist can be found through intersection of marginal revenue and
marginal cost curves, which has been shown in Figure 14.7.
Figure 14.7 :Long Period Equilibrium Under Monopoly by Marginal Revenue and
Marginal Cost Curve
It can be seen from Figure 14.7 that corresponding to the point where
marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost, the monopoly output is sold at a
price which is higher than the average cost of production. And so he
necessarily earns a surplus. Not only that, since marginal revenue is equal to
marginal cost, profit is maximum. The surplus of the monopolist is also
maximum here.
In the short period at the point of intersection of the marg
marginal revenue and
marginal cost curve, the price of his commodity turns out to be higher than
the average cost, he makes a profit, he may prefer to remain at the same
position of equilibrium in the long period as well.
If he does that, the short period equi
equilibrium will also become his long period
equilibrium. He would not like to change because there is no compulsion to
do so. Look at Figure 14.8 where long period equilibrium of a monopolist has
been shown.
351
Theory of Price
Figure 14.8 :Long Period Equilibrium Under Monopoly showing Maximum Net
Monopoly Revenue
352 ……………………………………………………………………………
3) State whether the following statements are True or False. Monopoly
While ‘no resale' or ‘no transfer of demand' is a necessary condition for price
discrimination, they are not sufficient for inducing the practice. In order that
a producer does in fact charge different prices for a given commodity, he
should be assured that this way he is able to maximise his profits as well.
Let us first understand why only one marginal cost curve would be
meaningful. What needs to be appreciated is that a producer would not put up
market-wise production units otherwise he will deprive himself of the
advantage of economies of scale for supplying the commodity to the two
353
Theory of Price markets. He will rather produce at one place (unless there are some very
special local advantages in respect of factors of production used) and then
distribute his supplies market-wise. And since there will be one aggregate
production for both the markets, there will be only one marginal cost curve to
be considered for determining the point of maximum profit.
Now since the demand curves are different, the average revenue curve, being
another name for the demand-price curve, will also be different in different
markets. Following this, the marginal revenue curves will also be different.
Since for reasons of analytical convenience, we are assuming two markets,
we will have two marginal revenue curves to consider along with just one
marginal cost curve. What is it that we have to do next?
Step one, is to first determine the aggregate output at which marginal cost
would be equal to marginal revenue. But how do we know the marginal
revenue for an aggregate output for the two markets? The answer is simple:
we just add up the individual marginal revenue curves of the two markets.
b
M P
Price
a
M
MR AM
MR c
Q 11 Q12
1
O Quantity Q Q
Q
u
Figure 14.9 : Price Discrimination Under Monopoly
Step three. Once the aggregate ou output in the two markets has been
determined, we have only to work out the distribution within the limits of the
demand curve pertaining to each of the two markets.
Step four From the point of intersection of the aggregate' marginal revenue
curve and the marginal
arginal cost curve, we draw a horizontal straight line cutting
the marginal revenue curves of market 1 and market 2 at points M1 and M2.
Step five At point M1 we draw a vertical line P, S, from the demand curve of
market 1. Likewise at point M1 we draw a vertical straight line P,S, from the
demand curve of market 2
OS1, will be the output supplied by the monopolist in market 1 at price P1, S1,
and ..:: OS2, the output supplied in market 2 at price P2,S2.
It may be noted that in market 1, the marginal revenue is MS, which is the
same as the marginal cost MS. By drawing a horizontal straight line from the
point of intersection of ‘aggregate' marginal revenue and marginal cost curve
i.e., M we have assured that MS, = MS i.e., in market 1, marginal revenue is
equal to marginal cost. Likewise, we can see that in market 2 also, marginal
revenue M11S2 = MS, the marginal cost.
355
Theory of Price The significant thing that is to be noted is that price P1,S1,, of market 1 is
different from price P2,S2, of market 2. That is why it is a case of price
discrimination
discrimination-same
same commodity, same producer but two different prices
because the demand curves in the two markets have different elasticities.
would be lying below the average revenue curve. Another point to be noted is
that the marginal cost curve of the monopolist may either be the same as in
the case of competitive industry or different. If it is different (and there could
be valid reasons for the difference) it will have its own implications for the
equilibrium of the monopolist. However, if the margina
marginal cost is the same, the
total output supplied by the monopolist would be lower than what the
competitive industry would have supplied. (competitive industry's
equilibrium would have taken place at point P where the price is equal to the
marginal cost of pr
production.)
oduction.) The monopoly price Q1P1 will be higher than
the competitive industry's price QP.
356
It may, however, be repeated that the higher monopoly price and the lower Monopoly
monopoly output (as compared to what could happen in conditions of perfect
competition) are due to the fact that the marginal cost curve of the
monopolist has been assumed to be the same as that of the competitive
industry.
Marginal cost, after monopoly has replaced competition can be different, for
the following reasons:
Thus, it is not always true that monopoly would result in a higher price and a
lower output.
There are other reasons also why monopoly price may not be higher than
price under perfect competition.
The monopolist may be afraid that if he charged high price, the consequent
surplus that he would earn may induce potential producers to try to produce if
not the same, then a similar commodity. In such a situation, the monopolist's
own sale and profit could be adversely affected. Therefore, the monopolist
may avoid charging a higher price for his commodity. Secondly, the
monopolist may have a name and prestige resulting from his command over
resources which he would not like to see spoiled by the impression that
would go round that he was a greedy, profit-seeking person. In order not to
be known as a producer out to exploit his customers, he may keep his price
low.
Firstly, since the monopoly price is always higher than marginal cost of
production, the monopolist gains at the cost of his customers. We have
already seen that in conditions of perfect competition, the producer earns no
357
Theory of Price surplus at the cost of his customers because he keeps his price equal to
marginal cost.
358
Monopoly
While the forces helping to determine equilibrium price in monopoly are the
same as in perfect competition, namely, those of demand and supply, their
relative roles do change in between these two markets. For example, the
marginal cost curve which plays such a vital role in perfect competition,
ceases to be that important. It no longer serves as a supply curve because
price charged by a monopolist always tends to be higher than marginal cost.
360
Thus the only use of the marginal cost curve is that it helps to fix up the point Monopoly
of intersection between itself and the marginal revenue curve. The
monopolist takingadvantage of his monopoly power likes to fix his price in a
way that his net monopoly - revenue is maximum. And such a price can be
only the one at which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. So a
marginal cost curve is necessary for determining a monopolist's equilibrium
but it does not truly serve as his supply curve.
Note: These questions and exercises will help you to understand the unit
better. Try to write answers for them. But do not send them for
assessment to the university. These are for your practice only.
362